Public Opinion Polling and Presidential Responsiveness: Effects on Policymaking and Democracy LOUIS T. SHERNISKY Gannon University How does public opinion affect American presidential policymaking, and what are the effects of such a relationship on the institution of democracy? This paper will attempt to examine the irony that exists within the American publics’ perception of US democracy, which is the belief that the modern president “panders” to the people, while the government is simultaneously accused of being more unresponsive to the wishes of the public than ever. The argument put forth is that, ironic in itself, the American public is collectively correct on both of these points, as contradictory as they may appear on the surface. A great deal of research and a large body of literature have been devoted to the subjects of public opinion poll usage, presidential responsiveness, and the dynamic relationship that exists between the two. Why? Before attempting to analyze the political theory that exists concerning the subject, it might be worthwhile to first look at the significance polling, and its subsequent effects on leadership, for American democracy. Nearly 85% of Americans, policy leaders, and members of the media agree that, while imperfect, polling is one of the best means of conveying the publics’ views to the government.1 This statistic would indicate that large majorities of both lay persons, the public, and policy professionals, policy leaders and media members, see the science of polling as potentially useful to the processes of American democracy. Further analysis will then be conducted of both the positive and negative effects polling, as well as its relationship to presidential responsiveness in both first and second terms, and the effects polling can have on the institution of democracy and what steps might be taken to foster a more positive association between the two. Upon establishing the sufficiency of the argument that study of public opinion polling and presidential responsiveness is indeed significant to the study of democracy, the focus of this paper will then turn to the issues at hand. Limited time and ability, as well as space within this paper, will not allow for an extremely in depth analysis of all prior research that has been conducted, but perhaps a critical examination of two popular studies on the matter, one qualitative and the other quantitative, would be satisfactory in the attempt to draw several general conclusions concerning poll usage and leadership. The studies to which the paper will primarily refer are those conducted by Brandice Canes-Wrone and Kenneth Shotts, as well as Lawrence Jacobs and Robert Shapiro. In his work, “Rethinking Presidential Responsiveness: The Public Presidency and Rhetorical Congruency, 1953-2001,” Brandon Rottinghaus notes that while much of the study on the subject has advanced understanding of the relationship between public opinion and presidential behavior, it has been limited in explanatory power by constraints in appropriate measurement of public presidential action and public opinion.2 This is something Canes-Wrone and Shotts attempt to correct for in their statistical analysis of an earlier set of hypotheses they developed in conjunction with Michael Herron, hereafter known as the CHS theory.3 The set of hypotheses that comprise the theory were tested using annual presidential budgetary proposals, as well as the prior year’s enacted budgetary authority, in conjunction with information collected through the National Opinion Research Center (NORC) and the Roper Organization on a set of eleven of the budgetary issues.4 The Canes-Wrone and Shotts study as well as the CHS hypotheses will be examined in far greater detail in the subsequent pages of this work, but for the moment it is worth noting why their effort is so significant. The test examined data on which there existed annual presidential proposals as well as annual and consistent public opinion polls. While this quantitative analysis approach is not bulletproof, it is far from imperfect either. It also makes for an interesting contrast in methodology in comparison to the qualitative study conducted by Jacobs and Shapiro.5 Herein lies the value of examining and reconciling the conclusions of each of these works. Though they study different examples and use very different methods of research to develop their conclusions, it appears as though some of the conclusions drawn are similar in nature, albeit the manipulation theory of Jacobs and Shapiro observes its finding through a somewhat negatively slanted, although not entirely inaccurate lens. The hope is that by examining these theories, each being seen as a very significant contribution to the debate on polling and presidential responsiveness, certain points of contention within the debate can be more generally agreed upon, allowing future students of the subject to bypass the work required to explain why they make certain assumptions as to presidential behavior in regards to opinion polls, elections, etc. Before returning to the question of why the study of the relationship of polling and presidential policymaking is significant to the debate on the quality of democracy in America today, it would be worthwhile to briefly describe the manipulation theory of Jacobs and Shapiro and examine the notion of pandering. In the Jacobs and Shapiro study, the authors examine, in substantial detail, the attempted health care reform initiatives of the Clinton Administration between 1993 and 1994 as well as the speakership of New Gingrich in the following years, as it related to, and was defined by, the Clinton health care reforms. Using this period in American politics as their case study, the authors’ work provides a large body of evidence in support of their theory that public opinion’s influence on government is less than in the past and much less than commonly assumed.6 “Pander” is a term much used within the current, popular debate on the issue of poll influence on policymaking. It is overused even. Due to its negative connotation, it is perhaps best to refrain from using the word within the contexts of a scholarly assessment of the issue. But for clarification purposes, it is best to define the action of “pandering,” and then address the connotation associated with it as used in the public as well as mainstream media. For the practical purposes of this paper, pandering might best be defined as an instance in which a president takes a policy position due to its public popularity despite knowledge that said policy might not be in the long term interest of the country.7 Jacobs and Shapiro take a much more cynical view of the term. Rather than merely focusing on what actions define pandering, they explain, “the term is deliberately deployed by politicians, pundits, and other elites to belittle government responsiveness to public opinion and reflects a long-standing fear, uneasiness, and hostility among elites toward popular consent and influence over the affairs of government,”8 and trace the words’ lineage from its sixteenth century use as a description for a pimp to its more common usage as a disparaging term in politics, which they note as being widespread by the 1970s.9 With this in mind, the term will be avoided for the sake of preventing unwarranted or unnecessary controversy. A good segue into the issue of democracy and how polls and policymaking relate might be an abbreviated explanation of the normative implications of the conclusions drawn from prior research that has been conducted on the topics at hand. Perhaps the most interesting findings have to do with the nature of the presidential decision-making in relation to the period of time within the term that the policymaking occurs. There is evidence that supports the claim that there are indeed instances in which presidents will commit the sin of pandering by choosing a policy position that is popular regardless of information that suggests the policy will not be in the country’s best interest.10 Conversely though, there are many times in which presidents will disregard public opinion on issues when they feel their policy goals are more significant than their political goals of personal or party reelection.11 What is interesting is the strong correlation between the election cycle, more specifically the proximity of an imminent election, and a president’s decision to either accept or reject popular opinion. This might suggest that there are institutional factors that have a stronger influence on presidential policy positions than the individual characteristics of the particular president. If this analysis is correct then it suggests democratic accountability can thrive despite political strategies developed to elude such answerability, which would in turn suggest the study of polling’s influence on presidential policymaking can lead to changes of the status quo that would not only strengthen American democracy, but be beneficial to the health of the spirit of democracy in America. It is the dire condition of this democratic spirit that has caused many students of democracy a great deal of concern in recent years. Though the subject of how a lack of responsiveness has attributed to such ill feelings within the American people will later be discussed, the notion that this trend can be corrected and that leadership can be of both the “trustee” and “delegative” models with real democratic accountability working to ensure fluidity of the system is not only the goal of this study and the hope of its author but a real possibility.12 This seems as though a good point to return to the discussion of just whether or not polls and their effects, or lack thereof, are or can be useful, and therefore intrinsically good, for the processes of democratic government. In his essay, “Why Respond to Polls? Public Opinion Polling and Democracy,” Robert Shapiro argues that polls are a public’s best means for balancing the power and influence on Washington of interest groups and political action committees. “Polls, in principle, can be stunningly democratic and, especially, egalitarian, because they attempt to find out the opinions of a sample of everyone, not just those who have the opportunity and economic or other interest in being engaged actively in politics.” In making that argument he touches on another significant and positive aspect of polling, the equality inherent in the notion of random sampling. A final, less practical point Shapiro makes in this particular work is the idea that poll results constitute data which can be assessed in the future by scholars in hopes of better understanding US history and thus draw conclusions from such understanding. 13 These ideas are merely a summation of those presented in an earlier work in which Shapiro, working with Benjamin Page, elaborates on the idea of collective wisdom. The argument for collective wisdom seems to hold much weight and, if accepted, would lend itself to the point that polls are in fact a legitimate and useful means for harnessing the collective policy preferences of the public. If this point is then accepted, a reader can subsequently see that the problems associated with polling are not inherent in the science of polling itself, but rather the use of the polls for illegitimate purposes, and that therein lays the detriment to democracy. From this point it will be easier to ascertain how polls can be used to positively influence democratic debate on policymaking and fulfill to greater extents the American democratic process. The concept of collective wisdom is based on the assumption that the average person’s policy preferences are not fully informed and permanent, nor completely uninformed and haphazard. Rather, the average person bases their policy preferences on uncertain and incomplete information that tends to support their personal beliefs. This lack of confidence in the individual’s own knowledge disposes the average person to instances in which their opinion can be changed, but over a long period of time a pattern of “long-term preferences” emerges. Thus, the population can be said to have stable, collective policy preferences that can be accurately measured, with those who deviate from their long-term opinions canceling out over a large sample.14 This is not to say that the majority is always right in its assessment of policy issues, far from it. Although a Kaiser study does suggest that Americans as well as policy leaders and the media all tend to put a great deal of emphasis on the idea of majority rule, and though they respect officials’ use of their own judgment, nearly 40% of the public still favored following the majority opinion despite acknowledgement of occasions on which the majority was erroneous.15 The point is that a collective opinion can be ascertained and used as representative of the will of the people in policymaking decisions. The above represent but a few of the reasons put forth by proponents of polling and only serve as a general introduction to the claim that public opinion polling is, in itself, a legitimate practice. While there are critics of polling, the debate within this paper does not focus on this subject and therefore will not go into further detail on it. So if a reader accepts that the practice of polling can be a useful tool in the methods of democracy, from where then does the disdainful notion of “poll-driven” leadership stem? Jacobs and Shapiro would claim, “The irony of contemporary politics is that politicians both slavishly track public opinion and, contrary to the myth of “pandering,” studiously avoid simply conforming policy to what the public wants.”16 In fact, one of the main points of the work by Jacobs and Shapiro is that there has been a general decline in responsiveness of politicians since the 1970s, an assertion supported not only by the work of Canes-Wrone and Shotts, but also a 1998 study that found government policies to be less consistent with the preferences of the majority between 1980 and 1993, with a policy congruence of 55% on over five hundred issues, than between 1960 and 1979 when the policy congruence on the same set of issues was 63%.17 And what's more, the results of the aforementioned Kaiser study would also suggest that Jacobs and Shapiro are correct in their analysis. Not only did the study conclude that nearly half of those tested saw their own influence on decisions made in Washington as negligible (in contrast to the majority of policy leaders who felt public opinion had “a fair amount” to “a great deal” of influence) and felt the government did not understand them, but 83% felt the main reasons public officials employ polls is to, “stay popular,” “get reelected,” and “further their own ends.”18 And more than one study suggests this cynicism extends to the political elite, who agree with the public that poll numbers can be manipulated a number of ways and can be tailored to any pre-desired outcome.19 With so much evidence suggesting exactly the opposite of the idea of polldriven leadership, the question should be asked again, where does this perception come from? From personal research of the subject there is no clear answer. While some studies suggested that presidents do allow polls to influence policymaking, sometimes significantly, not a single one suggested that there was a significant increase in policy congruence.20 If anything, the trend is exactly the opposite.21 The decline in responsiveness would perhaps account for much of the cynicism within society on the subject of polling if one considers the significant increase in the amount of polling that has taken place since the 1960s. While being simultaneously “beat over the head” with polls and poll numbers by the national media, and seeing the proliferation of polling within the White House, while feeling the effects of a real, decreasing trend in democratic responsiveness in its government, the public has lost confidence in its leadership and it would seem as though this effect has translated into ill feelings. In a paper explicitly titled, “Debunking the Pandering Politician Myth,” Jacobs and Shapiro conclude, “[D]espite the nearly universal acceptance of the notion that today’s politicians pander, no systematic evidence supports it. …The notion that today’s politician panders to polls when making significant policy is a myth built on scattered anecdotes and ungrounded presumptions.”22 While there is debate over the reasons behind the popular perception of poll driven leadership, one need not accept the theories of Jacobs and Shapiro to move beyond this debate. There seems to be general consensus that policy congruence with public opinion has decreased in the past thirty years, with statistical analysis supporting this claim.23 That alone should be sufficient to continue past such debate over the origin of negative public perception of polls, to the more important questions of how a lack of presidential responsiveness and an American public disillusioned with its leadership can have injurious effects on democracy and what can be done to reverse such trends. If presidential polling has indeed evolved away from responsiveness, toward attempted use of policy polling to move public opinion, then this phenomenon poses serious threats to American democracy. First, the cycle that has developed lends itself to the depression of responsiveness by presidents to the publics’ policy preferences as it has only become important for congruency when reelection draws near, and to a lesser degree, the election following a president’s second term. (Second terms will later be discussed separately) Second, audaciousness on the part of the president in his ability to persuade public opinion, especially in the realm of foreign policy, can lock the country into policies that lack the support of the public or Congress. Finally, the institution of the president gives him an advantage unparalleled by any other government leader to influence public opinion.24 An example of this would be the notion of the “bully pulpit.” Furthermore, if the basis for democratic society and government is an informed public that actively participates in open discussion and reasonable debate then communications between the government and the people are important. Whether or not an informed citizenry is, in fact, the basis for such democracy can be debated, although it seems reasonable to assume that it is most certainly at least significant or advantageous to the process. If the vertical communication between the public and the government is purposefully distorted by the administration to persuade the public to agree with those policy goals already chosen by the White House, then of course the quality of the public opinion will be diminished as it is not truly independent thought based on well-informed, critical reasoning and debate.25 The implications of such manipulation are not only troublesome in consideration of policy and opinion making, but it is argued that these strategies of manipulation are also directly responsible for the low levels of public trust in the government. Thus, the effects of manipulation would account for the latter half of the aforementioned paradox that exists in American politics today. In January 1999, a study conducted by the Center on Policy Attitudes asked a question, used by the American National Election Studies (NES) since the 1950s, as to whether respondents trusted the government “to do what is right.” Only 19%, the lowest level recorded in the forty years of polling data on the question, trusted the government “just about always” or “most of the time.”26 Opposite this trend is an increase in the amount of citizens who feel as though the government does not care about their views, or they are being misunderstood, and therefore they do not have much say in policymaking decisions. This is exemplified in the earlier referenced Kaiser study, where only 49% of respondents felt as though the government understood them.27 These converse tendencies are disturbing when one considers they have been simultaneous and, it seems reasonable to assume, detrimental to the health of public reason, debate, opinion, and relationship with its government. While the arguments presented here as to the ill effects of manipulation on policymaking and public opinion are not the only reasons for declining public trust in the government, etc. they do serve as solid examples sufficient to establish the point that, if manipulation does occur, then it is harmful to the spirit of democracy as well as the institutions of democracy and solutions should be sought out to remedy the situation. Such solutions will be examined in the final sections of this paper. At this point, having established to at least a minimal degree that polling can be useful for democracy, while its misuse can be harmful, attention must be given to the theories on which this argument is based. Once these parameters are understood, the points contained within this paper might become clearer to a reader, allowing the conclusions drawn to more logically follow. The first study examined and used for the purposes of this paper was that of Canes-Wrone and Shotts. In their paper, “The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion,” they test their previous hypotheses of electoral proximity and popularity. In an earlier work they theorized that a president would be most likely to endorse a popular policy when his popularity is at such a level that the decision may positively affect his chances for reelection. 28 As was mentioned early on in the paper, the CHS hypotheses were tested by comparing presidents’ proposals and public opinion for a set of eleven budgetary issues between the years 1972 and 1999. A study such as theirs had not been conducted before and it is considered to be an important addition to the study of presidential policymaking. The advantages to the Canes-Wrone and Shotts test included: an ability to examine presidential action on individual issues and whether those actions corresponded with public opinion on said issues, whether presidential responsiveness varies across policy domains, variations between presidents, and to control for outside influences on responsiveness.29 The testing of their data showed that the overall level of congruence was 51%, and interestingly enough, remained relatively constant over the nearly thirtyyear period and six administrations. Although, this overall percentage is somewhat skewed. Policy congruence was highest on the issues of crime, health, and social security at over 90% and issues that follow the liberal-conservative ideological spectrum at 71%, while being lower on foreign policy issues at 32%. This suggests that presidents are more likely to take popular positions on “doorstep” issues that the citizens are better informed about and on which they have stable preferences, while often ignoring public opinion on those issues on which the public is less informed.30 Realizing that factors such as elections, or lack thereof in a second term, and public approval can influence a president’s decision to conform policy to public opinion, Canes-Wrone and Shotts test their hypotheses of electoral proximity and popularity. The Electoral Proximity Hypothesis states, “Policy congruence between presidential positions and public opinion is more likely the sooner the next election.”31 Their findings suggested this is indeed the case, and this puts their research in line with that of Jacobs and Shapiro. In a four-year term, presidential policy congruence was 45% in the first two years and 57% in the latter half. Additionally, congruence was found to be highest in the final year at 66%.32 The authors of the study expound on this hypothesis in the CHS Popularity Hypothesis, which challenges previous research on the subject. Their theory was that when the next election is distant, essentially the first two years of a term, a president’s policy choice is often unaffected by public approval. In addition, when a president’s approval is sufficiently high he can choose unpopular policy without fear of losing an imminent election and when it is sufficiently low he can ignore public opinion if he feels it is best to do so for it is unlikely he will win the election without a major policy success. Thus, it is at average levels, high or low, that a president is most likely to choose policy that is publicly popular in hopes that it will increase his chances of winning the upcoming election.33 Testing supported this theory. Figure 1. Monotonic Popularity Hypothesis Source: Canes-Wrone and Shotts, 2004, Figure 1. This graph shows the results of prior work on the subject. Figure 2. CHS Popularity Hypothesis Source: Canes-Wrone and Shotts, 2004, Figure 2. Do not read the graph linearly. Rather, the solid lines representing Late term policy making move from opposite sides to come together in the middle. Canes-Wrone and Shotts is so important because it proves the significance that electoral proximity plays in the decision of a president to follow or reject public opinion on a particular policy issue. What’s more, it acknowledges the issue of presidential popularity and explains its effects on the policymaking decision. Finally, the study supports Jacobs and Shapiro in their analysis of a decline in presidential responsiveness since the 1970s while simultaneously concluding that many of the factors that affect policy congruence are institutional rather than personal (though personal differences exist between presidents, only less significantly) and it is perhaps the system that has changed. If this is the case, then it can be reasoned that the system can be corrected, if there is the will to do so. The other major theory that has been exceptionally significant in the study of the relationship between presidential responsiveness and public opinion, as well as to this particular paper, is that of Jacobs and Shapiro. Both have written prolifically on the subject and their theory of manipulation takes into account the complexities and contradictions within the prior and current research on the topic. Taking this broad, qualitative, overriding theory into account with respect to the results of Canes-Wrone and Shotts’ results of a quantitative test of the electoral proximity hypothesis allowed for a synthesis of the two; the findings of which seem to indicate that the most powerful device to correcting those instances in which manipulation occurs, as this paper assumes it does, and those instances in which pandering occurs, as this paper also assumes it does, is the election. But before this point can be made, manipulation theory should be better understood. The most basic tenet of Jacobs and Shapiro’s manipulation theory is that a president’s policy goals will outweigh his political goals, and this will lead to a disregard for public opinion.34 The most significant reason behind this belief is the documented increase in ideological polarization of the American electorate and its parties.35 Correlating to the results of Canes-Wrone and Shotts, Jacobs and Shapiro note that there are periods of increased responsiveness that coincide with the oncoming of imminent elections. Though they come to this conclusion on different grounds, believing that in these instances it is easier for a president or other politician to accept a popular opinion that does not correspond with his or her own position due to the short amount of time before the election than it would be to change public opinion.36 Their idea of “crafted talk” explains that with the increase in polling, as politicians track public opinion they do so not to make policy, but to represent and win support for their policies. Crafted talk is associated with the concept of “staying on message.” Though they acknowledge and accept limitations on this concept, such as that it is often times more effective in opposition than in promotion of new policy or that it is difficult to affect people’s values or preferences on wellestablished programs. As crafted talk deals with communications, a significant portion of the debate contained within the work deals with the fourth estate, the media. It is through the media that the public forms its opinions. Unfortunately, today’s press coverage is driven by polarization and the “horse-race” mentality of electoral races, rather than critical debate on substantive policy issues. What’s more, the press acknowledges the president’s attempts to institute his own policy goals by changing public opinion and this leads to closer scrutiny by the press. This scrutiny, in turn, leads to stronger, more widespread public distrust.37 Manipulation theory reasons that the motivations of politicians, in this case, presidents, are enacting desired policies and securing their reelection. These are two very basic political goals that have been researched for decades.38 The problem with electoral accountability is that methods have been developed to shirk negative opinion and evade punishment for unpopular policy choices. This presents a problem for longstanding theories such as the median voter theory and retrospective voting model, which suggest the personal benefits of electoral goals dominate the calculations of candidates.39 While this consideration appears to remain true, if the system does not cast out those who act in a manner inconsistent with the safeguards that protect against such manipulation then there is little incentive to follow public opinion when policy preferences are not already inline with those of the public There are a number reasons for the dodging of centrist opinion. Foremost, a president will likely believe in his policy goals and see them as important; he sees his policy as good public policy. Less noble is the reality that, with the status quo of the current system, a president often owes many people for their help in his election and subsequently can be more sensitive and more easily influenced by a narrow constituency that gave him significant support on the campaign trail.40 Finally, the advantages to simulating responsiveness and attempting to change public opinion give a president further reason to attempt to do so. The unsettled nature of public opinion, for example, makes it more susceptible to manipulation. Such action does not require the president to modify his policy goals or absorb the cost of compromise. Additionally, presidents have an unparalleled ability to circulate their political messages widely and visibly via the bully pulpit.41 Such a brief interpretation of the theory of manipulation barely skims the surface of the intricacies involved within it, as it is indeed a very complete and complex theory. For the reasons of this discussion though, this serves as a basic introduction to the arguments made based upon it. That is, while maybe not going as far as to explicitly reward president’s for attempting to win public opinion for a policy goal through the use of focus group tested phrases and the like, the system is neither likely to punish a president when his policymaking is out of line with the public’s preferences, except in those instances when it is so egregious that the public cannot help but act in a manner consistent with prior democratic theories of accountability. Before returning to the issue of what can be done to correct the system, and arguing that all it takes is a slightly more informed citizenry to strengthen the abilities of electoral accountability, the question of second term presidencies should be addressed. The tests conducted by Canes-Wrone and Shotts focused on reelection seeking presidents, as do their hypotheses of electoral proximity and a nonmonotonic popularity-congruence relationship. Neither theory explained presidential action in a second term, although they do conclude that second term presidents’ policy proposals will be more likely to correspond with public opinion when the public agrees with his ideological leanings.42 This result seems hardly surprising though and does not really address what motivates a second term president other than his predisposition to a particular ideology. Jacobs and Shapiro offer the idea that a second term president is expected to keep his policies in some semblance of agreement with those of public opinion in order to preserve his party’s control of the White House as well as gain seats in Congress.43 This seems like a reasonable assumption and is supported by the conclusions draw by Rottinghaus. In his study he concludes that the second half of a president’s second term is roughly equivalent to that of his first as the president attempts to campaign for his party’s candidates in midterm and presidential elections. He reasons that a president is concerned with his historical legacy and the election of a successor from his party will allow his policy agenda to be perpetuated, and likens it to the notion of the “permanent campaigning” of Congress.44 While his theories have yet to be tested, he does conclude some excellent points, although it seems as if he may be guilty of overreach. It seems likely that historical legacy and the continuation of policy to achieve such legacy would influence the actions of an outgoing president, but the idea that presidents cater policy decisions to midterm elections seems as though it might depend mostly on the circumstances surrounding the elections, and in general the president would be less concerned with such elections in comparison to major policy initiatives. So what then are the implications of all this research on the issue of presidential responsiveness as it relates to public opinion polling? Shapiro offers a very practical assessment of the situation. “What existing research shows is that the opinion-policy relationship is very far from perfect. While we can debate many aspects of the data, there is no support for the extreme claims in one direction or the other: Policymakers do not purely respond to public opinion, nor do they purely attempt to lead it… There [is] a fine line between leading and manipulating.”45 His counterpart, Jacobs, offers a similar opinion. “[P]residential polling has important consequences for the shifting democratic character of the public presidency. In the abstract, polls are neither good nor bad for representative democracy. Polls can be used as a tool to enhance substantive responsiveness… or to manipulate public debate and move public opinion.”46 While these authors come to very pragmatic conclusions regarding the public opinion-presidential responsiveness relationship, the criticism of exaggeration could be leveled at their solutions as to how to correct the problems that do arise within the current system. This paper concludes that Jacobs and Shapiro are correct in their deductions that a healthy democracy requires a system of rewarding presidents for legitimately considering public opinion in the policymaking process, rather than discounting the preferences of the public and attempting to persuade the people with what could be likened to a marketing campaign. Additionally, if the public opinion is to be of value to the policymaking process, its quality needs to be improved.47 As Jacobs and Shapiro write at length of an overhaul of the media and public communications, they seem too quickly and too willing to dismiss those processes already in place. This is not to downplay the difficulty inherent in attempting to solve the problem of manipulation, but rather a more realistic goal should be put forth. The question of how to better the quality of public opinion is a tricky one and one that has been subject of much debate. There is little doubt that a media, which focused less on the horse-race nature of polarized political races and policymaking, and instead on substantive policy issues would make for a betterinformed public. Having little study of the media, how plausibly this change could be implemented into the evening broadcasts of network and cable news shows seems questionable, though not entirely unrealistic. It seems, though, that those citizens who watch the news at all tend to more likely be the ones who will do research on substantive policy issues. Of course the media would facilitate, but it seems doubtful that a large percentage of the population that never cared to debate public policy would suddenly take an interest even with this facilitation. It tends to take the public, as a whole, a bit longer than those citizens who study politics as profession or passion to come to conclusions on policy issues, and the best hope for the quality of public opinion is the revolutions of modern communications and the rise of alternative media outlets, as well as an awakening of sorts of the population. On the first point, citizens are more interconnected than ever before and the hope is that this connectedness will foster qualitatively better and quantitatively larger debate on public policy. The rise of alternative news sources, such as blogs and respectable news websites may perhaps put pressure on the mainstream media to acknowledge there are issues in critical need of public debate, and there is a desire within society to learn about such issues and thus a market for this sort of substantive discussion. Finally, the last of the baby boomers are a generation that has accomplished much, but has yet to really positively define themselves within history. There are serious issues facing the nation both at home and abroad in the very near future. Such issues include: social security, Iraq, health care, terrorism, energy policy, globalization, and the list goes on. How the nation handles these problems remains to be seen, but they are, assuredly, issues that affect every US citizen. The question then becomes just how long it will take the public to realize its position and whether it will do so in enough time to effectively evaluate potential solutions. The shorter answer for the restoration of a healthy balance within the public opinion-presidential responsiveness correlation is, “elections.” We have seen instances throughout history, twice in the past twelve years, that when policy is so far out of line with the views of the people, the people will indeed come out to vote and show their disapproval. As this relates directly to presidential elections, things are a bit more complicated. Given the presidents ability to get his messages out and having the support of winning a national election on his side (If discussing electoral accountability and punishment it’s assumed the president is up for reelection in this instance) the president is the most difficult incumbent to defeat. But if one examines much of the research conducted on the nature of responsiveness to public opinion they would see that everything from the electoral proximity hypothesis to the manipulation theory’s notion of crafted talk is based on avoiding losing elections. As was shown, increases in policy congruence coincide with approaching elections, and all it would take for a bit more accountability is the public to vote in larger numbers. Even if the public were not any better informed, just by showing up on election day the a candidate would feel that much more responsible for winning those voters. Recent elections have been marked with a strategy of base mobilization that has proved itself effective in the short term but is now seen as unlikely to survive. Come 2008 it will be interesting to see whether the country shapes the candidates or they shape the country. One final note, this paper has drawn on a significant amount of prior research, most especially the studies of Canes-Wrone and Shotts, and Jacobs and Shapiro. The CHS theory and the multiple works of each Jacobs and Shapiro are extremely significant within this niche in public policy research. They were personal favorites as well. Quoting a review of Politicians Don’t Pander that applies adequately to the CHS theory as well as Jacobs and Shapiro’s book, “[They incorporate and marry] the seemingly parallel scholarly universe of electoral demands with the findings of disjunction between policy and public opinions since the 1970s [essentially creating] a continuum of responsiveness. In this conception, politicians do not pander all the time, nor can they ignore the public all the time.”48 Notes 1 Brodie, Mollyann, Lisa Ferraro Parmelee, April Brackett, and Drew E. Altman. “Polling and Democracy.” Public Perspective. 12.4 (2001): 14. 2 Rottinghaus, Brandon. “Rethinking Presidential Responsiveness: The Public Presidency and Rhetorical Congruency, 1953-2001.” Journal of Politics. 68.3 (2006). 3 Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Michael C. Herron, and Kenneth W. Shotts. “Leadership and Pandering: A Theory of Executive Policymaking.” American Journal of Political Science. 45(July) (2001). 4 Canes-Wrone, Brandice, and Kenneth W. Shotts. “The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion.” American Journal of Political Science. 48.4 (2004): 691. 5 Jacobs, Lawrence R. and Robert Y. Shapiro. Politicians Don’t Pander: Political Manipulation and the Loss of Democratic Responsiveness. Chicago: U of Chicago P, 2000. 6 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, xvi. 7 Canes-Wrone and Shotts, 2004, 702 8 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2001, xiv. 9 -- 359 10 Geer, John G. From Tea Leaves to Opinion Polls: A Theory of Democratic Leadership. New York: Columbia UP, 1996. 11 Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Robert Y. Shapiro. “Debunking the Pandering Politician Myth.” Public Perspective. 8.3 (1997): 3. 12 Key, V. O. Public Opinion and American Democracy. New York: Knopf, 1961. Geer, 1996. 13 Shapiro, Robert Y. “Why Respond to Polls? Public Opinion Polling and Democracy.” Public Opinion Pros. (2004): 6 pp. 28 Oct. 2006 <http://www.publicopinionpros.com/features/2004/nov/shapiro.htm>. 14 Page, Benjamin I., and Robert Y. Shapiro. The Rational Public: Fifty Years of Trends in Americans’ Policy Preferences. Chicago: U of Chicago P, 1992. 15 Brodie et al., 2001, 11-12. 16 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2001, 8. 17 -- 7. 18 Brodie et al., 2001, 12-14. 19 See either Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Robert Y. Shapiro. “Debunking the Pandering Politician Myth.” Public Perspective. 8.3 (1997) or Brodie et al, 2001 as examples. 20 Stimson, James A. “Tides of consent.” How public opinion shapes American politics. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2004. Geer, 1996. 21 Jacobs and Shapiro, 1997, 5. -- 3. 23 -- Rottinghaus, 2006. 24 Jacobs, Lawrence R. and Melanie Burns. “The Second Face of the Public Presidency: Presidential Polling and the Shift from Policy to Personality Polling.” Presidential Studies Quarterly. 34.3 (2004): 553. 25 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 306. 26 -- 314. Kull, Steven. “Expecting More Say: A Study of American Public Attitudes on the Role of the Public in Government Decisions.” Center on Policy Attitudes. 9 February (1999). 27 Brodie, et al., 2001, p. 13. 28 Canes-Wrone et al., 2001. 29 Canes-Wrone and Shotts, 2004, 691. 30 -- 693. 31 -- 694 32 -- 702. 33 -- 695 34 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 10. 35 American National Election Studies (NES). 36 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 3. 37 -- 27-34 38 -- 9 Fenno, Richard. Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Addison-Wesley (1973). 39 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 20 40 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 19. 41 -- p. 45 42 Canes-Wrone and Shotts, 2004, 702. 43 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 15. 44 Rottinghaus, 2006. 45 Shapiro, 2004. 46 Jacobs, 2004, 553. 47 Jacobs and Shapiro, 2000, 325. 48 Heith, Diane J. “Book Reviews.” Presidential Studies Quarterly. 31.4 (2001). References 22 References Brodie, Mollyann, Lisa Ferraro Parmelee, April Brackett, and Drew E. Altman. “Polling and Democracy.” Public Perspective. 12.4 (2001): 11-24. Canes-Wrone, Brandice, and Kenneth W. Shotts. “The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion.” American Journal of Political Science. 48.4 (2004): 690-706. Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Michael C. Herron, and Kenneth W. Shotts. “Leadership and Pandering: A Theory of Executive Policymaking.” American Journal of Political Science. 45(July) (2001). Fenno, Richard. Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Addison-Wesley (1973). Geer, John G. From Tea Leaves to Opinion Polls: A Theory of Democratic Leadership. New York: Columbia UP, 1996. Heith, Diane J. “Book Reviews.” Presidential Studies Quarterly. 31.4 (2001). Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Robert Y. Shapiro. “Debunking the Pandering Politician Myth.” Public Perspective. 8.3 (1997): 3.5. Jacobs, Lawrence R. and Robert Y. Shapiro. Politicians Don’t Pander: Political Manipulation and the Loss of Democratic Responsiveness. Chicago: U of Chicago P, 2000. Jacobs, Lawrence R. and Melanie Burns. “The Second Face of the Public Presidency: Presidential Polling and the Shift from Policy to Personality Polling.” Presidential Studies Quarterly. 34.3 (2004): 536-556. Key, V. O. Public Opinion and American Democracy. New York: Knopf, 1961. Kull, Steven. “Expecting More Say: A Study of American Public Attitudes on the Role of the Public in Government Decisions.” Center on Policy Attitudes. 9 (February) (1999). Page, Benjamin I., and Robert Y. Shapiro. The Rational Public: Fifty Years of Trends in Americans’ Policy Preferences. Chicago: U of Chicago P, 1992. Rottinghaus, Brandon. “Rethinking Presidential Responsiveness: The Public Presidency and Rhetorical Congruency, 1953-2001.” Journal of Politics. 68.3 (2006). Shapiro, Robert Y. “Why Respond to Polls? Public Opinion Polling and Democracy.” Public Opinion Pros. (2004): 6 pp. 28 Oct. 2006 <http://www.publicopinionpros.com /features/2004/nov/shapiro.htm>. Stimson, James A. “Tides of consent.” How public opinion shapes American politics. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2004.