Red Square MONEY CREATION IN A BANKING SYSTEM WITH A SINGLE MONOPOLY BANK The process of money creation is perhaps the most intriguing aspect of the economic system. It has given rise to the most extraordinary and extravagant theories. Beyond economists, it has attracted the attention of all sorts of people, from majors in the army to Chemistry Nobel Laureates. Still, the process of money creation, as well as the process of money destruction, are highly simple and can be easily understood by all. Money creation, or rather bank deposit creation as we will analyse it here, is no alchemy. It relies mainly on three features of the banking system: the willingness of banks to grant loans, the creditworthiness of borrowers, and the willingness of borrowers to take on loans. Yellow Square The Main Money Creation Channel To understand how money deposits are being created, it is best to start by imagining that the banking system is made up of a single bank, that has a total monopoly on the provision of loans and deposits in the economy, a system that 1982 Nobel Price Laureate John Hicks (1904-1989) called a monocentric banking system. All financial transactions have to transit through this single bank. Every economic agent has an account at this bank. Some agents have a negative account, in which case they have outstanding loans at the bank; other agents have a positive account, in which case they have deposits at the bank. How do new bank deposits get created? There are basically two ways in which deposits get created. Let us start with the most obvious one. Suppose that some individual wishes to purchase some goods or services, but without having the funds to do so. It may be a student who desires to purchase a new car, or an entrepreneur who is keen to hire new workers and increase production, having just received additional orders for his or her product. To go forward with their project, both the student and the entrepreneur have to borrow from the bank. They have to ask for a bank loan. Will the loan be granted? The answer is yes, as long as the borrowers are creditworthy – they are worthy of credit. The word credit comes from the Latin word credere, which means to believe or to trust. Trustworthy people or organizations can get bank credit. How can the borrowers demonstrate their creditworthiness? They may show that their past credit record is impeccable, that they have paid the interest due on their previous loans, and that they have reimbursed past loans. They may indicate that their current income is high compared to the interest payments involved with the loan that they are asking for (such ratios are now generated automatically by bank computer programs, which either flag the customer or tell the loan officer how much can be lent, and at what rate). They may show proof that the goods that they are about to produce have already been ordered by some other firm, and promised to be paid for. They may provide some guarantee – collateral – that the bank can seize in the unlikely case that they will be unable to pay interest and pay back the amounts due. In the case of a loan to purchase a house – a mortgage loan – the collateral is the house being purchased. In the case of a car loan, the collateral is likely to be the car itself. Sometimes the collateral can be financial assets – stocks, corporate bonds, government securities. If all of this is not enough, someone else may back the loan, the mother of the student, in which case she is the creditworthy person prompting the bank to grant the loan. SIDEBAR Creditworthiness is at the core of the bank lending system. It can be demonstrated by providing collateral, or by demonstrating the ability to face the loan obligations. Collateral is property (car, house, inventories, government securities) that is pledged by the borrower as guarantee for the repayment of a loan. So let us suppose that indeed the borrower is creditworthy. What happens next? The answer to this query is simple. A bank loan gets created ex nihilo – out of nothing – at the stroke of a pen; or rather, in our modern world, the bank loan gets created by punching a key on the computer. Simultaneously, as the bank loan gets created, a new bank deposit also gets created. Let us suppose that on January 2, 2008, a creditworthy borrower is being granted a new loan of $40,000 (for quite a nice car!). The effects on Bank-a-mythica, who holds a monopoly on banking services, are shown in Table 3. The bank now has $40,000 more in loans on the asset side of its balance sheet, but simultaneously, on the liability side, there is an increase of $40,000 in the bank deposits. The minute the loan has been granted, the car purchaser gets credited with a money deposit of $40,000. This is money that the bank now owes to the car purchaser. This is why it is on the liability side of the bank. Tables such as this one, which shows changes in balance sheets rather than the balance sheets themselves, will help us follow the process of money creation and destruction. Table 3 Changes in the Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, January 2, 2008 Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Loans to car purchaser +$40,000 Deposits of car purchaser +$40,000 There is nothing more to money creation. Since chequable bank deposits are part of M1, the most strictly defined money aggregate as we saw on page 234, Table 3 has shown how most money gets created in the modern world. {IN RED} For money creation to occur, all we need is the willingness of a bank to lend and a creditworthy borrower who is willing to borrow. {END Of RED INK} Box Lines of credit The money-creating process can be made even more efficient when banks grant lines of credit (also called overdrafts) to their customers. As Keynes explained in 1930 in his Treatise on Money, an overdraft is “an arrangement with the bank that an account may be in debit at any time up to an amount not exceeding an agreed figure, interest being paid not on the agreed maximum debit, but on the actual average debit”. There may be a fee for this line of credit. Take the case of our car purchaser. She may have already negotiated an agreement with the bank, entitling her to borrow up to a certain maximum amount, say $100,000, depending on her annual income and her existing net wealth. The bank client can then draw on her line of credit whenever she wants, up to the indicated limit. For instance, in the present case, assuming a $100,000 line of credit, she would draw $40,000 to pay for her new car, paying interest on that amount (the utilized portion of the credit line). The remaining $60,000 would constitute the unused portion of the line of credit. Because this part of the credit line is not used, no interest is charged on the remaining $60,000. However, if the car purchaser were to need to borrow some additional amounts, say $5000 for new kitchen major appliances, she would not need to go back to the bank loan officer to obtain yet another loan. All she needs to do is draw on an additional $5,000 off the unused portion of her existing credit line. Many businesses have these lines of credit. It gives them flexibility in handling payments to workers and suppliers, because businesses usually sell their ware after they have been produced and paid for, so that businesses need bank advances. Lines of credit have now been generalized to individuals, thus also providing them with more flexibility when their expenses, for whatever reason, run (temporarily!) at a faster pace than their income. {END OF BOX} What then happens next? Suppose that the car is being purchased the next day, on January 3rd. The purchaser goes to the car dealer, most likely with a certified cheque in hand, and after having given the cheque and signed all the papers, she drives off with the car. The car dealer deposits the cheque, still at Bank-a-mythica, since we assumed that this was the one and only bank of the country. The balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica will show the changes indicated in Table 4. Table 4 Changes in the Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, January 3, 2008 Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Deposits of car purchaser Deposits of car dealer -$40,000 +$40,000 By combining Tables 3 and 4, we arrive at Table 5, which summarizes the bank’s overall transactions for those two days. The car purchaser still owes $40,000 to the bank, but all the money deposits are now in the account of the car dealer. Table 5 Changes in the Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, January 2-3, 2008 Assets Loans to car purchaser Liabilities and Net Worth +$40,000 Deposits of car dealer +$40,000 As we pointed out in page 239, all of our balance sheet tables, such as Table 2 or 5, must balance. In all such tables, which are called T-accounts, the two sides of the ledger must carry equal total amounts. This balance is required because changes in assets and liabilities must be equal if the balance sheet is to balance both before and after the transactions. But Table 5 is unlikely to be the end of the story. Although the car dealer may be quite happy to be loaded with a $40,000 bank deposit, it is most likely that the car dealer was forced himself to take a loan when the car was initially brought into the dealership. Indeed, the car dealer usually holds a large inventory of cars, the cost of which has to be financed by bank loans. So it is most likely that the car dealer will use the proceeds of his sale to diminish the amount of his outstanding loans at Bank-a-mythica. Thus, the following change, as shown in Table 6, is likely to appear on the bank’s balance sheet. Table 5 Changes in the Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, January 4, 2008 Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Loans to car dealer -$40,000 Deposits of car dealer -$40,000 The car dealer uses his newly acquired deposits to pay back the bank. The money gets destroyed! When borrowers reimburse their loans, money gets destroyed. At the end of the week, adding Tables 3, 4, and 5, we obtain Table 6. In the end, despite all the action, there has been no change in the stock of money deposits. But the composition of the balance sheet of the bank has changed, with car purchasers owing more funds to the bank, while car dealers owe less. Table 6 Changes in the Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, January 2-5, 2008 Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Loans to car purchaser +$40,000 Loans to car dealer -$40,000 Total No change No change Yellow Square A Subsidiary Money Creation Channel We said in the previous section that there were two main channels of money creation. The first one is through banks granting new loans. The second channel is tied to changes in the composition of financial portfolios. Money is not the only financial asset that agents can hold. People can hold banknotes (about which more will be said later), chequable and non-chequable bank deposits – these assets being defined as M1 money stock – as well as chequable deposits from other financial institutions, certificates of deposits, stock market shares, mutual fund shares, bonds, etc. Money is being created when non-financial economic agents, such as manufacturing corporations or households, transform some of their non-monetary assets into deposits that are defined as being money (M1, M1+, M2, M2+, etc.). This can occur either because these nonfinancial agents decide to hold a greater proportion of their financial wealth in the form of deposits, or when banks wish to hold a bigger proportion of their assets in the form of securities rather than in the form of outstanding loans. For this kind of money creation to occur, there has to be a double coincidence of wants: on the one hand, non-financial agents wish to hold more deposits; and on the other hand, banks wish to hold more assets beyond loans. Table 7 shows how such a creation of money would occur. The non-financial agent, here Toy Manufacturer, sells securities (for instance, government bills that it holds) and gets bank deposits in exchange; Bank-a-mythica purchases the government bills, and credits the sale proceeds to the deposit account of Toy Manufacturer. We may call this the portfolio-change process. The nonfinancial agent is no richer than it was before – its wealth does not change, only the composition of its wealth has changed – but note that the size of the balance sheet of the banking system has now risen by $1000. Both the assets and the liabilities of Bank-a-mythica have risen by $1000. Table 7 A subsidiary money creation channel: Changes in balance sheet composition B Manufacturer Toy a n k a m y t h i c a Assets Securities +$1000 Liabilities Deposits +$1000 Assets Securities -$1000 Deposits +$1000 Liabilities No change Of course the portfolio-change process may operate in reverse gear. Manufacturer Toy may be unhappy about the interest rate it is getting on its bank deposits at Bank-a-mythica. It may be want to hold more of its financial assets in the form of securities, which may be slightly less convenient but which carry a slightly higher rate of return than the interest rate on money deposits. In this case, Manufacturer Toy may offer to buy securities at a price that will induce Bank-a-mythica to sell them. Money, therefore, gets destroyed. The deposits of Manufacturer Toy diminish by $1000, while its holdings of securities rise by $1000, and the size of the balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica diminishes by $1000. In the rest of this chapter, we will concern ourselves with the first of these two money creating channels. From a macroeconomic point of view, the lending channel by which money gets created is a more interesting one as it generally involves changes in income, sales and production., which is usually not the case of the portfolio-change process. Yellow Square The Limits to Money Creation One of the most striking feature of the money-creation process, especially through the lending channel, is that there seems to be no limit to the creation of money. In a sense this is true. The creation of money is not limited by some scarce resource such as the amount of gold that banks have accumulated in their vaults. It is sometimes argued that this was the case in the past, and it may have been, although economic historians argue with each other about that, but it is certainly not the case in modern banking systems. Nowadays banks are free to lend as much as they want. This is certainly true of our monopoly bank, but as we shall see in the next section, it is also true even in the general case, when there are several competing banks. Take first the case of our monocentric banking system. What could its restrictions on lending be? The amount that the monopoly bank can lend is only limited by the three crucial features of the banking system that we identified earlier: the willingness of the bank to grant loans, the creditworthiness of borrowers, and the willingness of borrowers to take on loans. As in all economic transactions, both partners to the transaction need to be willing to engage in the transaction. For a loan to be granted, and for bank deposits to be created as a consequence of this new loan, both the bank and the borrower have to be willing to go ahead with this operation. Why would economic agents refuse loans that they are being offered? The reason is that they may be unwilling to get into debt and pay interest on this debt. They may also see no reason to spend more, or they may be scared of going bankrupt if they borrow too much or borrow any more. Thus borrowers, on their own, may willingly put limits on the amounts they want to borrow. By borrowing too much, they are afraid that they may lose their entire wealth or a large part thereof. This is sometimes called the borrower’s risk. Why would a monopoly bank be unwilling to lend? For exactly symmetric reasons. The bank may fear that some of its clients may be unable to reimburse their loans or make the interest payments that are due. This is the lender’s risk. If too many of the borrowers of the bank are in this situation, the bank may become insolvent and may be closed down, as we will explain in a short time. This is why the bank is on the look for creditworthy customers. Unless the bank is really pessimistic about future prospects, for instance, fearing an economic recession in the near future, thus being reluctant to increase the size of its balance sheet, the bank is always looking for new creditworthy borrowers, or willing to increase the size of loans granted to previous creditworthy borrowers. But why is the bank looking for creditworthy borrowers and not just any kind of borrower? Why does the bank fear customers who do not make their interest payments or reimburse their loans? First, as pointed out in page 237, banks are in the business of making profits. Besides service fees, banks make their profits on the difference between: their revenues – the interest payments that they receive on their assets (on their loans and the securities that they hold) and their costs – the interest payments that they have to make on their liabilities (essentially on the deposits that people hold at the bank) plus the costs of operating a bank (the salaries of clerks and loan officers, rentals, the costs of running the automatic teller machines, etc.). If borrowers don’t fulfill their interest payment obligations, banks will make losses, not profits. Bad loans have a second, less obvious, implications. Suppose the bank, by mistake, makes a loan of $200,000 to a non-creditworthy person, and that this person turns out to be a crook. Instead of building a prosperous business with the borrowed money, the crook spends it all in bars, cars, and casinos. At the end of the year, the bank manager wakes up and finds out about all this. The borrower has defaulted on the loan and has vanished; the collateral that had been offered to get the loan is worthless. There is no way the loan can be recovered. It has to be considered as a “bad loan”, and thus must be entirely “written off”. While this is an extreme case, small businesses regularly go bankrupt (as sometimes do large corporations), because of poor planning, bad luck, or changing economic conditions. Their banks can only recover a portion of the loans that they granted. The rest has to be written off. How will the accountants of the bank take care of this? Table 8 shows how a $200,000 bad loan is written off. Since the loan is now worth nothing, it must be removed from the assets of the bank on its balance sheet. A minus $200,000 entry will thus need to be recorded into the changes of the balance sheet. But a T-account must always balance by definition. What other change must we make for the balance sheet to balance? The answer is to be found in the bank’s capital. The bank has suffered a $200,000 capital loss, which must be subtracted from the bank’s own funds. Table 8 Writing-off a bad loan, Changes in the Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Assets Liabilities Securities no change Chequable deposits no change Loans outstanding -$200,000 Total -$200,000 Net Worth Bank’s capital -$200,000 Total -$200,000 Table 9 Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, December 31, 2007, after accounting for bad loan Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Assets Liabilities Currency $100,000 Chequable deposits $5,000,000 Securities $1,000,000 Loans outstanding $4,200,000 Net Worth Bank’s capital $300,000 Total $5,300,000 Total $5,300,000 The new balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, once the loan loss has been taken into proper account, will thus look like Table 9, with Table 9 being the sum of Table 2, before the loss was recorded, and Table 8, which records the change induced by the loss. In Table 9, compared to Table 2, Bank-a-mythica has a smaller net worth, but this net worth is still positive, standing at $300,000. Although Bank-a-mythica is not in as good a shape as it appeared in Table 2, it is still solvent. In other words, despite the bad loan, the bank’s capital is still positive, as its assets are still larger than its liabilities. The bank could still face a string of bad loans. Nonetheless, most likely, the bank would be concerned about the decline in its own funds and would make an effort to increase its capital (for instance by issuing new shares), or by being more prudent in its future dealings and in the choice of its borrowers. Sidebar A solvent bank is a bank that has positive net worth. The bank’s capital is positive, so that its assets are larger than its liabilities. An insolvent bank has negative net worth. Suppose however that more borrowers have defaulted on their loans, for instance because their businesses did much more poorly than what was predicted in the marketing plan. Suppose that $900,000 worth of loans turned out to be bad loans that year. $900,000 worth of loans must thus be subtracted from the asset side of the balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, as shown in Table 10, and $900,000 must be subtracted from the bank’s capital. But wait! The own funds of the bank, the bank’s capital, were only $500,000. What happens now? The net worth of the bank becomes negative, standing at -$400,000. The bank is insolvent. Its liabilities – the deposits of its customers – are not covered by enough assets (the sum of the securities and loans). The bank must go under and declare bankruptcy, or its assets and liabilities have to be taken over by some other bank. To try to avoid such bank failures, there are minimum requirements that are applied world-wide regarding the size of bank capital relative to the value of assets (especially the value of risky loans). These requirements are known as capital adequacy requirements, and their generalization to banks of many countries has been spearheaded by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), an international organization located in Basel, Switzerland. Table 10 Balance sheet of Bank-a-mythica, December 31, 2007, after accounting for huge bad loans Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Assets Liabilities Currency $100,000 Chequable deposits $5,000,000 Securities $1,000,000 Loans outstanding $4,200,000 - $900,000 Net Worth = $3,500,000 Bank’s capital = -$400,000 Total $4,500,000 Total $500,000 - $900,000 $4,500,000 The lesson to be drawn from this is that Bank-a-mythica faces no limit as to the amount of loans it can make, and therefore to the amount of money it can create, save for its own fear of making losses and failing. What limits the creation of money is the number of creditworthy borrowers and the willingness of these potential borrowers to borrow. If no one is willing to go into debt, no new loan will be granted and bank deposits will not grow. As the saying goes, you can bring a horse to water, but you cannot force it to drink! It should also be clear that monetary relations are based on conventions – on customs. The definition of a creditworthy borrower will not be the same in all time and space. Someone classified as a creditworthy person today in Canada may not have been in the past or in some other country. For instance, criteria to obtain mortgage loans are now much less stringent than they were in the past. Also, different banks may have different opinions with regard to the creditworthiness of the same person. Since we are talking about different banks, this is a good time to consider the limits of money creation when several banks are operating within the monetary system. Box Bank Failures Thousands of American banks failed during the Great Depression, as they became insolvent when the value of their assets plummeted with the downfall in economic activity, with other banks refusing to make transactions with them when insolvency was suspected, and with these banks often being subjected to bank runs. The surviving banks became overly cautious during the Great Depression, denying loan demands and recalling loans that had been previously made. This made the recession even worse, as producers lacked the financial means to produce, thus reducing production and paid wages. As wages received diminished, household consumption also fell. In addition, when banks went under, depositors lost the money that they had in these banks, further reducing consumption and hence economic activity. In Canada, not a single bank failed during the Great Depression. Still, in Canada as elsewhere, many bank loans to companies and entrepreneurs must have turned bad, becoming worthless as these companies and individuals went bankrupt. Most probably, some Canadian banks, as many other surviving banks in the rest of the world, were insolvent then – a point that was made by Keynes himself in 1931. But as long as nobody takes notice, or as long as everyone turns a blind eye, the bank can continue to operate. This shows once more that monetary systems rely on trust and conventions. By contrast, as was mentioned earlier and listed in Table 1, in 1985 two Alberta-based banks failed – the Canadian Commercial Bank and the Northland Bank, causing a bank run on at least three other small Canadian banks. The big recession of 1981-1982, the slowdown in the oil and gas sectors, and the concomitant large increase in interest rates are sometimes blamed for these two failures, as the two Alberta banks were heavily involved in the regional real estate market in Western Canada. The Estey Commission, which, as noted on page 238 was set up by the Canadian federal government to investigate the causes of the failures, concluded that bank management pursued imprudent lending policies and bizarre banking procedures, along with misleading financial statements. Indeed, the failures of these two Canadian banks show some similarities with the Savings and Loans (S&L) debacle in the United States, also in the 1980s. S&L institutions were financial institutions similar to our credit unions or Caisses populaires. The cause of the failure of S&Ls is well-documented. Besides difficulties caused by a mismatch between short-term liabilities and short-term assets at a time of rising interest rates, evidence of fraud and insider abuse, tied in particular to real estate swindles, has been uncovered, leading to convictions of fraud and racketeering. Regulation and bank supervision is needed, not only to restrict overly enthusiastic bankers, but also to create an environment where financial fraud is more difficult, just like banknotes issued by the Bank of Canada are made in such a way that they are difficult to reproduce, to avoid counterfeiting. {End of Box} Red Square MONEY CREATION IN A BANKING SYSTEM WITH SEVERAL BANKS We have seen that loans made to individuals or corporations, and hence money creation, depend on trust. The same is true of the relations between banks. Whenever they engage in transactions with each other, banks must trust each other, otherwise the banking system would grind to a halt, or the banks which are not trusted by the other banks would quickly be unable to operate and their clients would suffer great inconvenience. Well-functioning banking systems have institutions that allow banks to make their transactions with each other with great confidence. In Canada, transactions between banks are regulated through the Payment Clearing and Settlement Act, which was proclaimed in 1996, and through the by-law of the Canadian Payments Association. The Bank of Canada is a key player in this institutional setup, in particular it oversees the payment system, but its role will be mainly discussed in the next chapter. As is the case for individuals, the transactions between banks are closely monitored with the help of credit ratios. These ratios depend on the amount of collateral that each bank is willing to provide to the LVTS, and on the amount of bilateral credit limits that participants grant to each other. The purpose of these controls is to insure that the troubles of one bank will not snowball into other banks running into trouble – the issue of systemic risk. Collateral and trust, or creditworthiness, are thus the kingpin of a monetary system. Sidebar: There is systemic risk in a payment system when the failure of one bank to meet its obligations could lead to the failure of other banks to meet their obligations, thus jeopardizing the functioning of the entire payment system. Yellow Square The Canadian Clearing and Settlement System To understand the functioning of a banking system with multiple banks – a polycentric banking system as Hicks would call it – let us go back to a situation which is very similar to that of our initial example. Let us suppose that a Chevrolet car dealer must now pay for an allotment of cars that was sent to him by the car producing company. Suppose that in order to do so the car dealer must draw on his line of credit (See the earlier Box, “Lines of Credit”), for an amount of $400,000, thus increasing the amounts borrowed from his bank, say the Bank of Montreal, by an amount of $400,000, and ordering his bank to pay this amount to GM Canada. Let us suppose that GM Canada does business with another bank, say, the Toronto Dominion Bank. Sidebar A line of credit is an arrangement with the bank that allows someone to borrow freely up to an amount not exceeding an agreed figure, interest being paid not on the agreed maximum, but on the actual average loan. Because the amount involved is large, the payment will go through an electronic-only payment system (instead of a paper payment system, such as is the case with ordinary cheques). In Canada, this electronic-only wire system is called the large-value transfer system (LVTS). It has been operating since 1999. This is a clearing and settlement system, in which banks and a few other participants in the LVTS, such as the Fédération des caisses Desjardins and more importantly the Bank of Canada, clear their payments and settle their accounts. About 90 percent of the value of bank payments go through the LVTS. From now on, the participants to the LVTS, save the Bank of Canada, will simply be referred to as “banks”. SIDEBAR Clearing is the continuous daily process by which banks exchange and deposit payment items for their clients, and determine the net amounts owed to each. Settlement is the end-of-day procedure by which banks use borrowing and deposit facilities at the Bank of Canada to fulfill their net obligations to all other banks. Before any large transaction goes through between two banks (before it clears), a computerized system verifies that the debit position of the paying bank is not too large. Once the controls within the system are all satisfied, the transaction clears and the payment is irrevocable. It cannot be reversed. If a bank were to fail by the end of the day, before final settlement, the collateral pledged by the failing bank or the collateral pledged to the LVTS by the remaining banks would be enough to cover any amount due by the failing bank. In our car dealer example, as soon as the $400,000 payment from the Bank of Montreal to the Toronto Dominion bank is cleared, a $400,000 amount is deposited in the bank account of the car producer, GM Canada, and that payment is final. It cannot be revoked. Thus a loan is initially granted by the Bank of Montreal, with deposit money created therein, but the deposit eventually ends up in an account at the Toronto Dominion Bank. How will all this be entered in the balance sheets of the two banks at the moment that the transfer to the account of GM Canada occurs? Let us look at Table 11. Table 11 The money creation channel with two different banks: Intraday Changes in balance sheets Bank of Montreal Assets Liabilities Loans to Chevrolet car dealer +$400,000 Toronto Dominion Bank (TD) Assets Liabilities LVTS balances Deposits of GM +$400,000 Canada +$400,000 LVTS balances -$400,000 Assets LVTS Liabilities and Net Worth Balances of Toronto Dominion Bank +$400,000 Balances of Bank of Montreal -$400,000 The trick to understand what is going on is to remember that all balance sheets must balance. If the Bank of Montreal has made more loans than it has collected deposits, and if the Toronto Dominion Bank has collected more deposits than it has made loans, as is the case in our instance illustrated by Table 11, there has to be some adjustment mechanism that will make the T-accounts balance. The Chevrolet car dealer has ordered his bank to transfer $400,000 of his newly acquired money to the deposit account of GM Canada at the Toronto Dominion Bank. Now, as shown in the bottom part of Table 11, once the transfer is recorded through the LVTS, the Bank of Montreal owes this $400,000 amount to the clearing system – it is said to have a negative LVTS balance or to have a debit LVTS position – while the Toronto Dominion Bank is said to hold a positive LVTS balance or to have a credit LVTS position. The system owes the Toronto Dominion Bank $400,000. SIDEBAR The LVTS balance of a bank is the multilateral clearing position that the bank has accumulated within the large-value transfer system in the course of the day. When the bank is in a net credit position, the balances are positive; when the bank is in a net debit position, the balances are negative. Things may change quite rapidly however. During the same day, it may be that GM Canada has to pay its suppliers, producers of metals or plastics, several of whom may be holding accounts at the Bank of Montreal. In that event, payments will have to flow from the Toronto Dominion Bank towards the Bank of Montreal, and the positive LVTS balances of the Toronto Dominion Bank may get reduced close to zero, or may even become negative. And as further payment orders come in during the day, there will be further changes to the net position of each of bank. These changes can be quite large, so that each morning each participant decides how big a bilateral credit line it grants to each of the other participants, on the basis of their credit assessment. In addition, a central computer calculates the position of each participant on a payment-by-payment basis, so that each bank is aware of its overall position and that of every other bank. The net amount that each participating financial institution is permitted to owe is subject to bilateral and multilateral limits. Various whistles go off when one bank goes too far in a negative position. In that case, the bank with the excessive negative position will have to wait till it receives transfers from the other banks before it can go ahead with the payments ordered by its depositors . Box Gross Flows of Payments and Net Balances in the Large-Value Transfer System The Canadian LVTS is unique among clearing and settlement systems in the world, and is highly cost efficient. In other countries, to insure payment finality, large-value payments involve an immediate transfer of funds on the settlement accounts of banks, on the books of the central bank. But each clearer must hold central bank deposits that are sufficiently large to cover any possible outgoing payment. In Canada, settlement only occurs at the end of the day, on a multilateral basis, but payment finality is guaranteed as soon as the payment is being accepted by the system and thus clears, thanks to the collateral arrangements mentioned above. The following numerical example may help to explain how the main Canadian clearing and settlement system – the LVTS – works. Suppose the following transactions occur between three banks that participate in the LVTS during the day (the numbers are not unreasonable, given that on average, in 2006, no less than $166 billion worth of payments did transit through the LVTS every day – about one ninth of Canada’s annual GDP!) The Bank of Montreal (BMO) makes payments of $30 billion to depositors of the Toronto Dominion Bank (TDB). The Bank of Montreal (BMO) makes payments of $30 billion to depositors of the Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce (CIBC). The Toronto Dominion Bank makes payments of $22 billion to depositors of the Bank of Montreal. The Toronto Dominion Bank makes payments of $20 billion to depositors of the Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce. The Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce makes payments of $40 billion to depositors of the Bank of Montreal. The Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce makes payments of $18 billion to depositors of the Toronto Dominion Bank. The following table sums up these transactions and their implications with regards to the settlement balances of the three banks. Owed to 6 Owed by BMO TD CIBC Ó Amounts owed to BMO 22 40 62 TD CIBC 30 30 20 18 48 50 Ó amounts owed by (debits) 60 42 58 150 Ó amounts owed to (credits) 62 48 50 150 LVTS balances +2 +6 -8 0 Although there have been transactions reaching a total gross amount of $150 billion, the net amounts involved are much smaller, with the Bank of Montreal being left with $2 billion of positive LVTS balances. In other words, the Bank of Montreal is here in a net credit LVTS position. The Toronto Dominion Bank has a LVTS positive balance of $6 billion, while the Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce holds the difference, a $8 billion negative LVTS balance (a net debit LVTS position). It would be easy to build other examples where the total amount of positive balances is even smaller, despite actual daily transactions being of a larger size. Thus the size of positive LVTS balances is only very indirectly related to the amount of monetary transactions or the volume of economic activity. It is a random number that depends on the relative size of incoming and outgoing payments for each LVTS participant. {END OF BOX} But suppose now that we have reached the end of the day, and that the situation is that described by Table 11, with the Bank of Montreal still being in a $400,000 debit LVTS position (a negative LVTS balance). Can such a situation last? As we will see in the next chapter, in a sense it could. But there are economic incentives for this situation to be reversed. The banks that have positive LVTS balances will usually lend them to the banks that have negative balances! This will occur on a segment of the overnight market – the interbank market – where banks make loans to each other. In the present case, at the end of the day, the Toronto Dominion Bank can grant a one-night loan of $400,000 at the overnight rate of interest to the Bank of Montreal. This generates a LVTS credit (positive) flow of $400,000 for the Bank of Montreal, and a negative LVTS flow of $400,000 for the Toronto Dominion Bank, as shown in Table 12, thus allowing both banks to bring their LVTS balances to zero (when Tables 11 and 12 are added). The end result for the balance sheet of each bank is shown in Table 13. SIDEBAR The interbank market is the financial market where banks lend and borrow surplus funds between themselves for one night. The overnight market is the financial market where banks and other financial market participants (investment dealers, pension funds, large corporations, trust companies, the Government of Canada) lend and borrow surplus funds for one night. The overnight market has three components, one of which is the interbank market. Table 12 The Toronto Dominion Bank Grants an Overnight Loan to the Bank of Montreal: Change in LVTS balances LVTS Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Balances of Toronto Dominion Bank -$400,000 Balances of Bank of Montreal +$400,000 Table 13 The Money Creation Channel with two Different Banks: Overnight Changes in balance Sheets Bank of Montreal (BMO) Toronto Dominion Bank (TD) Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Loans to Chevrolet car Funds borrowed from Advances made to Deposits of GM dealer +$400,000 TD Bank of Montreal Canada +$400,000 +400,000 +$400,000 LVTS balances LVTS balances $0 $0 Once again we can draw lessons from this example. First, it is clear that the polycentric banking system relies on trust and creditworthiness. Banks have to be sufficiently confident in other banks and in the clearing and settlement system to accept that other LVTS participants run temporary negative balance positions during the day, and to grant overnight loans to banks that end the day with a deficit LVTS position. Indeed, as we noted earlier, institutions have been set up so that transactions can be carried with very little risk. In addition, as long as all banking institutions are “moving in step”, granting loans and collecting deposits at approximately the same pace, the situation of a polycentric banking system is not very much different from a monocentric one, because on average, over a period of weeks, the positive and negative positions will compensate each other for each bank, although they will not on an hour per hour basis. When some banks are growing faster than others, with their loans growing faster than those of other banks, things are more complicated, as these fast-growing banks will show net debit LVTS positions systematically, unless they find other means to compensate for the discrepancy between loans and deposits. In the United States, New York City banks systematically run deficit clearing positions, and so do some banks in Europe. There are basically two ways through which banks that run systematic clearing deficits avoid borrowing extensively from other banks. First, they can offer certificates of deposits, at attractive interest rates, that are purchased by the banks or other financial market institutions that have surplus funds. This is called liability management. This often involves another segment of the overnight market – the market for overnight wholesale deposits. Second, once they have granted new loans, they can sell bunches of loans to banks or financial institutions that are in a surplus position. This is an instance of securitisation, whereby a loan is transformed into a financial vehicle that can be sold, just like a security. SIDEBAR Liability management is the process through which banks attempt to obtain funds, for instance by offering certificates of deposits at attractive interest rates, and hence attracting wholesale deposits. Securitisation is the process through which illiquid financial assets – assets that cannot be sold easily, such as mortgages – are transformed into marketable instruments – financial assets that can easily be sold and purchased. At this stage it should be clear that, in a modern monetary system such as the Canadian one, nothing, besides the prudence of bankers and the self-restraint of borrowers, limits the creation of credit and that of money. This feature of our monetary system, the fact that the creation of money is essentially endogenous, has advantages. It provides flexibility to the monetary system: monetary units get easily created when the economy is expanding and there is a need for additional units of money for production and transaction purposes. However, as for most things, there is a downside to this flexibility. In all likelihood, when the economic perspectives are bad, bankers and their customers will tend to be extra prudent. However, when economic perspectives look good, both bankers and their clients may become overly enthusiastic. Demand for credit may quickly rise and bankers are likely to grant new loans at an accelerating pace, attributing creditworthy status to nearly all income earners. With loans increasing, so will the stock of money. On the basis of supply and demand analysis, one could then argue that this process ought to lead to rising interest rates – the cost of loans – and that this would then somewhat restrain the demand for loans and the growth of the money supply. But what happens is that both the demand for and the supply of loans increase in tandem, as bankers are just too happy to finance the expenditures that their customers desire. Hence, with demand and supply growing together, under these circumstances there is no inherent market force pushing interest rates upwards. If such a process persists, at some stage the rising demand for credit and money will outpace the growth of potential output. An inflationary gap will appear, and the inflation rate will start rising. In addition, as has happened in the past, speculative bubbles may erupt, leading to fast-rising prices in the stock market or in the real estate market which may further disrupt the economy. Some outside intervention is necessary. THE BANK OF CANADA: MONETARY POLICY IMPLEMENTATION Monetary policy can be conceptually divided into two components: monetary policy strategy and monetary policy implementation. Monetary policy strategy is closely tied to monetary macroeconomics. It deals with the macroeconomic goals of the central bank, for instance achieving a target inflation rate or a given growth rate of economic activity, and how best to achieve them, especially when goals may be conflicting over the short run. It also deals with the monetary stance and the transmission mechanism of monetary policy – the decision to change the value of some monetary variable under the control of the central bank and how this change will impact the macroeconomic objectives. In other words, monetary policy strategy depends on the macroeconomic model that lies behind the actions of the central bank. SIDEBAR: Monetary policy strategy is the decision that the central bank takes about some monetary variable that constitutes its operational target, for instance a short-term rate of interest that it can control, with the view of influencing or achieving some macroeconomic outcome or target, for instance a certain rate of inflation. Monetary policy implementation is the set of rules, instruments and day-to-day actions that allow the central bank to implement its operational target. By contrast monetary policy implementation deals with the day-to-day, or even the hourper-hour, operations of the central bank. We can say that it corresponds to the nitty-gritty aspects of monetary policy. Monetary policy implementation is made up of two elements – the operational target and the operational instruments – both of which must be under the control of the central bank if monetary policy implementation is to be successful. Today, there is a wide consensus among central bankers that the operational target ought to be a short-term interest rate. In Canada, this operational target is the overnight interest rate on collateralized transactions. This is the rate of interest that arises from the overnight market, which we already encountered in Chapter 12 when discussing the clearing and settlement system of Canadian banking. It is the rate at which banks and other financial market participants lend and borrow from each other for one night, using or searching for surplus funds fully secured by acceptable collateral. The operational target of the Bank of Canada is thus the target overnight interest rate. SIDEBAR: The overnight interest rate is the interest rate that banks and other financial market participants pay and receive when they borrow and lend surplus funds from each other for one day, in particular when banks borrow and lend LVTS balances from one another. The target overnight interest rate is the operational target of the Bank of Canada; it is the overnight rate that the central bank would like to see realized. In what follows we examine the operational framework – the technical instruments that allow the Bank of Canada to achieve its operational target. In other words, we first deal with monetary policy implementation. Monetary policy strategy – the choice of the value taken by the operational target – will be studied once we know how the central bank implements its decisions. Yellow Square The Corridor System How the operational target gets implemented in the Canadian monetary system is a simple story. Unless there are special circumstances, the Bank of Canada makes an announcement eight times a year, in the early morning at specific dates, as to what its target overnight interest rate will be until the next announcement. Et voilà! The Bank of Canada accompanies its new rate announcement with an explanation of its decision to decrease, increase or keep constant the target overnight rate (See the Box “Bank of Canada Press Release”). These justifications have more to do with monetary policy strategy, and hence they will be dealt with later. In the meantime what must be noted is that the target overnight rate is accompanied by an operating band, which is made up of two additional interest rates that stand below and above the target overnight rate. These two rates are respectively the interest rate on deposits at the central bank and the interest rate on advances made by the Bank of Canada to the banks that participate in the Large Value Transfer System (the LVTS, as we called it in Chapter 12). This latter rate is also called the Bank rate. These two interest rates thus determine the operating band. This band looks like a corridor – a channel or a tunnel – thus leading this operating framework to be called the corridor system, as shown in Figure 1. SIDEBAR The Bank rate is the interest rate charged to banks that still have negative LVTS balances at the end of the day, and hence that must take advances (borrow funds) for one night from the Bank of Canada in order to settle with the LVTS. The interest rate on deposits at the central bank is the rate of interest that banks get on their deposits at the Bank of Canada as a result of the operation of the LVTS. Banks with positive LVTS balances must deposit them in their account at the Bank of Canada when settlement occurs at the end of the day. The operating band is the zone of overnight rates comprised between the Bank rate and the interest rate on bank deposits at the central bank. The corridor system is the operating framework adopted by the Bank of Canada which forces the overnight interest rate to remain within the operating band and close to the midpoint of the band, as defined by the target overnight rate. Figure 1 The Target Overnight Interest Rate with its Operating Band Figure 1 illustrates the case where the target overnight rate of interest is 4.25 percent. As a result, the Bank rate is set at 4.50 percent, since the Bank rate is always set at one quarter of one percent (or 25 basis points, as financial market specialists say) above the target overnight rate. Symmetrically, the interest rate on deposits at the Bank of Canada is set at 25 basis points below the target overnight rate. As a result, the operating band is 50 basis points wide. The Bank of Canada thus acts as a price-fixer with respect to the short-term interest rate. It constrains the values that the overnight interest rate can take by setting both a floor and a ceiling to the values that can be taken by the overnight interest rate. The Bank of Canada promises to take as a deposit, paid at a 4 percent rate, any amount of positive LVTS balances held by an individual bank; and it promises to grant advances, at a 4.5 percent cost, to any individual bank that has negative LVTS balances (provided the bank has adequate collateral). The overnight rate can, in theory, take any value within the operating band, the range of which is given by the grey area in Figure 1. But it cannot get outside this band. It is constrained within a corridor. Why is this so? Why does the Bank of Canada have the power to influence so much the overnight rate? The essential reason for this is that in Canada, as in virtually all countries, all payments must eventually settle on the books of the central bank, here the Bank of Canada. {In RED} Recall from Chapter 12 that payments go through two steps: first they are cleared, then they are settled. The main clearing system is the Large-Value Transfer System (LVTS). Clearing is the daily process by which banks exchange and deposit payment items for their clients, and determine the net amounts owed to each. Settlement is the procedure by which banks use claims on the Bank of Canada to fulfill their net obligations to all other banks at the end of the day. The Bank of Canada is the settlement agent of the LVTS. Banks need to settle with the LVTS at the end of the day, and they must do so on the books of the Bank of Canada. The Bank of Canada provides settlement accounts to LVTS participants; it provides funds to those that need to cover their settlement obligations (those that have negative LVTS balances at the end of the day); and it transfers claims on itself for those banks ending the day with positive LVTS balances. {End of Red} Suppose, as was the case in the example of Table 11 in Chapter 12 which we partly reproduce here as the top of Table 1, that the Bank of Montreal has a net debit LVTS position (negative LVTS balances) by the end of the day. How much is it willing to pay other banks to borrow balances from them and bring its LVTS balance position back to zero? Clearly it is not willing to pay an interest rate higher than 4.50 percent since this is the rate that the Bank of Canada will charge to banks with negative LVTS balances. If all other banks were offering to charge more than 4.50 percent to lend LVTS balances, the Bank of Montreal would turn down these offers and would simply take an advance from the Bank of Canada at the Bank rate of 4.50 percent. Now, what about the banks that have positive LVTS balances? What is their reasoning? Suppose, as shown in the top part of Table 1, that the Toronto Dominion Bank has a net credit LVTS position. What is the minimum interest rate that will induce the TD Bank to lend its balances to other banks (thus also bringing its LVTS balance position back to zero)? Clearly, it needs to get paid more than 4.00 percent, since this is the rate that it would get anyway if it were to leave its LVTS balances as a deposit at the Bank of Canada. If no deal can be struck between the Bank of Montreal and the Toronto Dominion Bank, then the balance sheet of the Bank of Canada will be as shown in Table 2. The Toronto Dominion Bank will be granted a claim on the Bank of Canada – its LVTS balances will be brought down to zero and transformed into an overnight deposit at the Bank of Canada; as to the Bank of Montreal, it will have to borrow $400,000 from the Bank of Canada to bring its LVTS balances back to zero. Table 1 Balance Positions of Banks in the LVTS Intra-day LVTS, Before Settlement Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Balances of Toronto Dominion Bank +$400,000 Assets Balances of Bank of Montreal -$400,000 End-of-day LVTS, After Settlement Liabilities and Net Worth Balances of Toronto Dominion Bank +$0 Balances of Bank of Montreal +$0 Table 2 Balance Sheet of Bank of Canada, with no Deal Struck Between Banks Bank of Canada Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Advance to the Bank of Montreal, Deposits of Toronto Dominion Bank, at 4.50 percent at 4.00 percent +$400,000 +$400,000 The overnight interest rate, that will arise out of the negotiations between potential lenders and borrowers of overnight funds will thus have to be somewhere between 4.00 and 4.50 percent. Indeed, unless there are some unusual circumstances, the realized overnight rate will turn out to be very close to the middle of the operating band, at the target overnight rate – in the case of Figure 1 it will stand at 4.25 percent, or very close to it, say at 4.23 or 4.24, or perhaps 4.26 percent. There are essentially two reasons for this. First, the banks know that the Bank of Canada wishes the overnight rate to be around 4.25, and that it will intervene if the actual rate keeps drifting away from the target rate. Secondly, competition should bring the overnight interest rate near the middle of the operating band, because at that point the opportunity gain of the lenders and that of the borrowers are precisely the same, being equal to 25 basis points for both groups of participants to the overnight market. Figure 2 shows the evolution of the daily differences between the actual overnight rate and the target overnight rate since 2006, expressed in basis points. Obviously, except for a few hiccups, the actual rate is equal, or nearly equal, to the target rate. On average, throughout 2006 for instance, the actual rate was 2 basis points lower than the target rate (the discrepancy was negative on average). Figure 2: The Actual Overnight Interest Rate Versus the Target Overnight Interest Rate in Canada, 20062007 Source: Statistics Canada, series v39079 and v39050 Note: Difference is in basis points (A 100 basis point difference equals an interest rate difference of 1 percent: 4.30 percent versus 4.25 percent is 5 basis points) {In RED} The Canadian monetary policy implementation framework is such that the realized overnight interest rate is always, or nearly always, at the mid-point of the operational band, at the target overnight rate, or within just a few basis points of the target set by the Bank of Canada. The operational target of the Bank of Canada – the overnight interest rate – is well under its control. {END RED INK} Although several countries in the rest of the world have implemented operating procedures that are highly similar to those of the Canadian monetary system, few manage to drive the realized overnight rate towards its target level with as much consistency and precision as the Bank of Canada does. Why is this? It may be because there are very few participants to the LVTS, which simplifies things for the Bank of Canada. But the main reason is that the operational instruments create incentives for each bank to target a zero LVTS balance position, while the Canadian clearing and settlement system allows the Bank of Canada to know with perfect certainty its own LVTS position by the end of the day. This is not the case in most of the other monetary systems in the rest of the world, which explains why most other central banks are not as successful as the Bank of Canada in achieving their operational target interest rate on a day-to-day basis. However, these other central banks, such as the Federal Reserve System in the United States, usually manage to achieve overnight rates (called the federal funds rate in the United States) which are equal, on average over a monthly basis, to their target. The overnight interest rate is thus nowadays the operational target of virtually all central banks. Yellow Square Government Deposit Shifting As long as LVTS transactions only involve banks, and not the public sector, whenever a bank is in a deficit position, i.e., whenever it has negative LVTS balances, there is another bank, or a group of other banks, that has an identical surplus position, i.e., positive LVTS balances, as described by Table 1. In other words, under the above condition, the net overall amount of LVTS balances held by banks – the sum of positive and negative LVTS balances of each bank – is zero at all times. Things are entirely different when payment transactions involve the federal government or the central bank. This will be the case when the federal government pays its employees, when it collects taxes, when the Bank of Canada purchases or sells foreign currencies on foreign exchange markets on behalf of government, when it provides banks with currency, or when it undertakes transactions in government securities with banks or dealers. In all these instances, one bank may be in a LVTS deficit position without any other bank being in a surplus position; or one bank may be in a LVTS surplus position, with none of the other banks being in a deficit position. In this case, the net overall amount of LVTS balances held by banks – the amount of settlement balances as they are called at the Bank of Canada – will be different from zero. Sidebar: Settlement balances are the net aggregate amount of LVTS balances held by banks, that is the sum of positive and negative LVTS balances of each bank. Why do monetary transactions involving the federal government or the central bank disrupt the symmetric behaviour of positive and negative LVTS balances? To examine the peculiarity of federal government transactions, let us suppose that we are around the end of April, when taxpayers are sending in their tax returns with their tax payment. Take the example of a wealthy taxpayer who has to send in an additional $60,000 in federal tax, assuming that it goes through the LVTS. Table 3 summarizes what happens in the payment system. Table 3 The Impact of Federal Government Collecting Tax Revenues on Intraday Changes in Balance Sheets Bank of Montreal (BMO) LVTS Bank of Canada (BofC) Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities LVTS Deposits of Balances of Deposits of balances taxpayer BMO Canadian -$60,000 -$60,000 $-60,000 government +$60,000 Balances of LVTS BofC balances $+60,000 +$60,000 We assume here that the wealthy taxpayer is a customer of the Bank of Montreal. The Bank of Canada is the fiscal agent of the Canadian government; in other words the Bank of Canada handles the payments of the federal government. When the taxpayer orders the Bank of Montreal to make the $60,000 payment, the account of the federal government at the Bank of Canada gets credited with $60,000 while the LVTS balances of the Bank of Montreal get diminished by $60,000. The net aggregate amount of LVTS balances held by banks thus diminishes. Payments to the federal government thus constitute a drain on settlement balances. If nothing else occurs, the Bank of Montreal will be looking in vain for a counterparty in its efforts to borrow funds in the overnight market since no bank has compensatory positive LVTS balances. This will tend to push the overnight rate above the target overnight rate, towards the Bank rate, since some banks, here the Bank of Montreal, will be forced to borrow from the Bank of Canada at the Bank rate. The target overnight rate would not be achieved. What can the Bank of Canada do to avoid such a situation? The Bank of Canada must pursue neutralizing operations that will neutralize the impact of government transactions on settlement balances. In other words, the Bank of Canada will take measures to bring back to zero the amount of settlement balances. The actions taken to modify settlement balances are described as settlement-balance management, or in short cash setting. SIDEBAR: Cash setting, or settlement-balance management, is the action that the Bank of Canada takes to bring back the supply of settlement balances to their desired level, usually zero. Cash setting is usually carried by shifting government deposits between the central bank and banks. In the present case, the Bank of Canada shifts Canadian government deposits back to the banks. Suppose that it does so, with $60,000 worth of government deposits being shifted to the government account at the Bank of Montreal, as shown in Table 4. In reality the deposits are auctioned off, with the banks offering the highest rate getting the government deposits. Suppose that in this case, the Bank of Montreal acquires $60,000 worth of LVTS balances when the auction is completed. Adding Tables 3 and 4, we obtain Table 5, which shows that the system is back to a situation with a zero amount of settlement balances. The payment flows have been entirely neutralized. Table 4 The Impact of a Shift of Government Deposits into Banks on Intraday Changes in Balance Sheets Bank of Montreal (BMO) Assets Liabilities LVTS Deposits of balances government +$60,000 +$60,000 LVTS Assets Liabilities Balances of BMO $+60,000 Balances of BofC $-60,000 Bank of Canada (BofC) Assets Liabilities Deposits of Canadian government -$60,000 LVTS balances -$60,000 Table 5 The Neutralizing Impact of a shift of Government Deposits into Banks Following a Federal Government Revenue Inflow Bank of Montreal (BMO) Assets Liabilities LVTS Deposits of balances taxpayer $0 - $60,000 LVTS Assets Deposits of government +$60,000 Liabilities Balances of BMO $0 Balances of BofC $0 Bank of Canada (BofC) Assets Liabilities Deposits of Canadian government $0 LVTS balances $0 The process is quite similar when banks need additional banknotes issued by the Bank of Canada – so they can feed their automatic teller machines and respond to the demand of their customers who wish to hold and make use of more banknotes. Withdrawals of banknotes from the central bank are made as needed by the banks. In other words, whenever the demand for banknotes rises, more banknotes are being supplied by the Bank of Canada. Banks receive the banknotes and are debited with negative LVTS balances. These are then neutralized at the end of the day by shifting the appropriate amount of government deposits from the central bank to the banks. We may now examine, more quickly, what happens when the federal government makes a payment, for instance when it pays for the report of a private-sector economist on the future competitiveness of the Canadian economy. This time the bank winds up with positive LVTS balances as a result of the government payment, as shown in Table 6. If the public sector and the bank of Canada engaged in no further transactions, the Bank of Montreal would be forced to deposit its LVTS balances at the Bank of Canada, and the actual overnight rate would tend to fall towards the rate on deposits at the central bank. To stop this, the Bank of Canada must bring the amount of settlement balances back to zero. Once again, it will do so by shifting the deposits of the federal government, but this time from its accounts at banks towards its account at the central bank, as shown in Table 7.2 As a result, as can be seen in Table 8 (which adds Tables 6 and 7), the federal government payment transaction is neutralized, with the net amount of settlement balances in the system being brought back to zero. In all likelihood, the actual overnight rate will be close to the target. Footnote 2: In reality, the Bank of Canada will auction an amount of government deposits that is smaller than the amount maturing on that day (and hence returning to the government account at the Bank of Canada, formally called the Receiver General balances). Table 6 The Impact of Federal Government Expenditures on Intraday Changes in Balance Sheets Bank of Montreal (BMO) Assets Liabilities LVTS Deposits of LVTS Assets Liabilities Balances of Bank of Canada (BofC) Assets Liabilities Deposits of balances +$60,000 economist +$60,000 BMO $+60,000 Balances of BofC $-60,000 Canadian government -$60,000 LVTS balances -$60,000 Table 7 The Impact of Shifting Government Deposits from Banks to the Central Bank on Intraday Changes in Balance Sheets Bank of Montreal (BMO) Assets Liabilities LVTS Deposits of balances government -$60,000 -$60,000 LVTS Assets Liabilities Balances of BMO -$60,000 Balances of BofC +$60,000 Bank of Canada (BofC) Assets Liabilities Deposits of Canadian government +$60,000 LVTS balances +$60,000 Table 8 The Neutralizing impact of a Shift of Government Deposits into the Account at the Central Bank Following a Federal Government Expenditure Outflow Bank of Montreal (BMO) Assets Liabilities LVTS Deposits of balances economist $0 + $60,000 Deposits of government -$60,000 LVTS Assets Liabilities Balances of BMO $0 Balances of BofC $0 Bank of Canada (BofC) Assets Liabilities Deposits of Canadian government $0 LVTS balances $0 {In RED} When the federal government receives a payment (taxes), the banking system as a whole is put in a negative settlement balance position; when the federal government makes a payment (expenditures), the banking system as a whole is put in a positive settlement balance position. To neutralize the effects of financial payments received by the federal government, the Bank of Canada shifts government deposits from the central bank to banks; to neutralize the effects of financial payments made by the federal government, the Bank of Canada shifts government deposits from banks to the central bank. {END of RED} The Bank of Canada transfers government deposits twice a day. It does so first in the early morning, when most of the bank payments through the LVTS are made. It does it again late in the afternoon, after all bank payments involving the federal government have been made. When this second adjustment is being carried, the Bank of Canada knows with certainty how much settlement balances there are in the system. The Bank of Canada is thus able to calculate the exact amount of government deposits that need to be shifted to achieve a zero amount of net settlement balances, as occurred in our examples of Tables 5 and 8. Unless there are some unusual circumstances, the amount of government deposits being auctioned will be such that the amount of settlement balances is indeed zero by the end of the day. In other words, the Bank of Canada normally targets a zero amount of settlement balances. {IN RED} Under normal circumstances, the net amount of settlement balances in the system is zero at the end of the day. The amounts of positive LVTS balances held by some banks are exactly equal to the amounts of negative LVTS balances held by the other banks. {END of RED} Thus, despite the existence of government payment transactions, the situation by the end of the day is exactly the one that was described in Chapter 12, in Table 11. Thus any bank with a net debit LVTS position that needs to borrow funds to settle its position is aware that there is at least one other bank with an offsetting net credit LVTS position, which is a potential lender of LVTS balances. These banks will meet on the overnight market and the rate of interest on which they will agree to borrow or lend will be the overnight interest rate. All bank payments involving a client come to a close at 6:00 pm, with banks being given an additional half hour to interact one last time on the overnight market, lending their remaining positive balances or borrowing from other banks when they are in a debit LVTS position. Hence each individual bank is able to bring its LVTS balances to zero, thus avoiding having to take overnight advances from the central bank at the Bank rate or avoiding depositing its positive LVTS balances for the night at the Bank of Canada, as was described in the example of Table 13 of Chapter 12. It follows that, whatever the size of GDP or the size of daily transactions, under normal circumstances, bank deposits at the Bank of Canada are zero or very close to zero, while advances by the Bank of Canada are also zero or next to zero. This can be verified with a look at Figures 3 and 4, which show the evolution of overnight bank deposits at the central bank and overnight advances taken by banks at the Bank of Canada. The magnitude of these deposits and advances, a few dozen million dollars on average with a few spikes in the hundreds of millions, is dwarfed by the size of daily transactions through the LVTS – more than $165 billions, and the size of monetary aggregates such as M2 – over $750 billions! These few dozen millions are peanuts when measured by the scale of the Canadian monetary system, and hence can be considered as being virtually equal to zero. Actually, to “grease” the wheels of the payment system, the Bank of Canada purposefully targets an amount of $25 million in positive settlement balances as of 2007. A banking officer that lets this amount as an overnight deposit at the Bank of Canada, instead of lending it in the interbank market, foregoes about $175 in interest! Figure 3: Bank Deposits at the Bank of Canada Source: Statistics Canada, series v36629, weekly series Figure 4: Bank of Canada Advances to Banks Source: Statistics Canada, series v36634, weekly series What would be abnormal or unusual circumstances? A well-known instance occurred when the World Trade Centre in the financial centre of New York was subjected to two airplane attacks on September 11, 2001. The Bank of Canada, along with other central banks, made it clear that it would alleviate any fear of financial disruption by providing the monetary system with the additional liquidity that was being demanded by the banks and other financial institutions. For more than a week, the Bank of Canada set settlement balances at levels of several hundreds of million dollars. This was done with appropriate government deposit shifting actions. These settlement balances were then gradually brought back to zero. Technical factors have also forced occasionally the Bank of Canada to set settlement balances at negative levels in 2006 and 2007. In other words, the Canadian monetary system is such that the overall demand for settlement balances is usually zero, so that the Bank of Canada sets the supply of settlement balances to zero in normal circumstances. In the case of 9/11, there was a temporary large demand for settlement balances, which induced the Bank of Canada to set the supply of settlement balances much above zero, equal to this overall demand, so as to keep the overnight interest rate on target. In addition, we have already pointed out that currency is provided to the banks on demand. Thus, if we designate the sum of currency and bank deposits at the central bank by the term base money, we can say that there is a horizontal supply of base money, at the target overnight interest rate. Whenever the demand for base money increases, so does the supply of base money. This is illustrated in Figure 5, under the standard assumption that the demand for base money is downward sloping (the interest rate being a measure of the opportunity cost of holding coins or banknotes – the higher the interest rate, the less base money one wishes to hold). If there is a shift in the demand for base money, from D0D0 to D1D1, the supply of base money will accommodate at the target overnight interest rate. Sidebar: Base money is made up of two components of the liability side of the balance sheet of the central bank: currency and deposits at the central bank (which used to be called bank reserves). Figure 5 The Demand for and the Supply of Base Money Box The Evolution of the Canadian Monetary System The Canadian monetary system that we describe in this chapter is relatively new. It was fully implemented only in February 1999, when the Large Value Transfer System became operational. As pointed out in Chapter 12, page 238, prior to 1994, Canadian banks were under a legal requirement to hold deposits at the Bank of Canada that were not remunerated, called reserves. These reserves had to be a certain percentage of the deposits held by the public in banks. Reserves had a dual role: in theory they provided banks with the means to face a bank run; in practice they were said to help the control of monetary aggregates. Discussions on the possibility of implementing Canadian monetary policy with highly reduced reserves and even no reserves at all started in September 1987. A first step towards this process was implemented in 1991, when restrictions on the frequency and size of Bank of Canada advances to banks (with the appropriate collateral) were lifted. Compulsory reserve requirements were also progressively phased out over a three year period, until they were completely eliminated in mid-1994. The focus of monetary policy moved away from the Treasury bill rate – the interest rate on short-term (mainly 90-day) government securities – towards the overnight rate. The 50 basis points operating band for the overnight rate of Figure 1 was put in place in 1994, and in 1996 the Bank rate was disconnected from the Treasury bill rate, and set instead at the upper end of the operating band, to provide more clarity as to the intentions of the Bank. A second round of discussions took place in 1995, when the present system, dealing with electronic large-value payments, was designed. As noted above, the LVTS was implemented in 1999. An official target overnight rate was put in place, as the rate to be found at the midpoint of the operating band, thus completing the corridor system that had been started in 1994. And finally, in late 2000, the Bank of Canada moved to a system whereby possible changes in the target overnight rate are announced at eight annual preset dates, the so-called fixed announcement dates. Nearly identical corridor systems with no reserve requirements exist in New Zealand, Australia, England and Sweden, but not yet in the United States or in the European Monetary System with its European Central Bank. {End of Box} Box What Happens to our Cheques? Both the description of the clearing and settlement system and the discussion about monetary policy implementation were conducted as if all payments went through the LVTS. But what about the cheques for $100 or $200 that we make to other individuals or to various merchants, the payments that we make with our debit cards, and the direct deposits that we receive when we are on the payroll of some firm or of the university? What happens to these small value payments? These payments go through another clearing and settlement system, called the Automated Clearing Settlement System (ACSS), the participants of which are nearly the same as those of the LVTS. But although most transactions occur through the ACSS, the value of these transactions now only represents about 10 percent of total clearing aggregates. The ACSS functions under rules that are similar to, but yet different from, those of the LVTS. Banks in a negative ACSS position at the end of the day are charged the target overnight rate, and those in a positive ACSS position receive the target overnight rate. Settlement occurs on the day following clearing, with banks in a debit ACSS position making a LVTS payment that incorporates the interest cost being charged. However, ACSS transactions involving the federal government must be presented before 3 p.m. each afternoon, so that their settlement occurs on the same day, also by a LVTS payment. Thus all net public sector payment flows end up as residual balances in the LVTS. As a result, the Bank of Canada has full information on its own overall net balance position when it proceeds to its final cash setting operation, in the late afternoon, and can thus bring to zero the amount of settlement balances. For this reason, the LVTS remains the sole focus of monetary policy operations. The Canadian Payments Association plans to introduce electronic images of cheques in 2008, with paper cheques being scanned and cleared on an electronic support, in an effort to improve efficiency of the payment system. Yellow Square Open Market Operations and Buyback Operations The Bank of Canada can make use of another operational instrument when unusual circumstances arise. This instrument is called open-market operations. In contrast to the American monetary system, in the Canadian monetary system open market operations never played a key role, being mainly a supporting instrument, most of the adjustment being carried by government deposit shifting. SIDEBAR: Open market operations refer to the sale or purchase of government securities by the Bank of Canada through transactions in the open market. Open-market operations traditionally involve the sale or the purchase of government securities by the central bank. The counterparty to this transaction could be a bank or a nonfinancial firm, but most often it involves a government securities distributor, called a primary dealer. When the central bank purchases securities on the open market it adds settlement balances to the monetary system. When the central bank sells securities it drains settlement balances out of the system. The bookkeeping of such open market operations is shown in Tables 9 and 10, where for simplicity it is assumed that a bank is the counterparty. Table 9 illustrates the central bank purchase of securities. The Bank of Montreal receives a payment inflow when it sells the securities to the central bank, thus obtaining LVTS balances. The Bank of Canada thus adds $100,000 worth of settlement balances to the system. Reciprocally, Table 10 shows what happens when the central bank sells some of its securities to the Bank of Montreal. This bank makes a payment outflow to purchase the securities, thus losing $100,000 in LVTS balances. The net amount of LVTS balances held by banks is thus reduced by this same amount, meaning that the Bank of Canada has reduced settlement balances to the tune of $100,000. Table 9 Effects of a Central Bank Open Market Purchase of Securities on the Intraday Balance Sheet of Banks and that of the Bank of Canada Bank of Montreal Assets Liabilities Canadian Government Securities -$100,000 Bank of Canada Assets Canadian Government Securities Liabilities +$100,000 LVTS balances -$100,000 LVTS balances +$100,000 Table 10 Effects of a Central Bank Open Market Sale of Securities on the Intraday Balance Sheet of Banks and that of the Bank of Canada Bank of Montreal Assets Canadian Government Securities +$100,000 LVTS balances -$100,000 Liabilities Bank of Canada Assets Canadian Government Securities -$100,000 LVTS balances +$100,000 Liabilities What is the impact of such operations on the overnight interest rate? When the central bank purchases securities on the open market, it increases the net amount of settlement balances in the system. This will tend to push down the overnight interest rate since some banks will wind up with positive LVTS balances that they will be unable to lend on the overnight market, being forced to deposit them at the end of the day on their account at the Bank of Canada. In symmetry, central bank sales on the open market decrease the net amount of settlement balances and hence pushes up the overnight interest rate, as some banks will be forced to take advances from the Bank of Canada at the Bank rate. Since 1995, the Bank of Canada no longer pursues outright open market operations. Instead it only pursues buyback operations, which were introduced in 1985. The Bank of Canada sells or purchases government securities, but with the promise to reverse the transaction on the next day, at a predetermined price. In Canada, when the central bank purchases securities for one day, this is called a Special Purchase and Resale Agreement (SPRA), or specials. This instrument gives much more flexibility to the Bank of Canada because the settlement balances which are added to the system are removed automatically the next day, when the resale provision kicks in. Similarly, when the Bank of Canada sells securities for one day – an operation designated as a Sale and Repurchase Agreement (SRA), or reverses – settlement balances are removed from the system for one day, being added back automatically on the next day when the repurchase provision takes effect. The buyback operations, because they are repurchase operations, are called repos. This gives rise to the repo market, which is the third component (besides the interbank and the wholesale deposit markets) of the overnight market, since the purchase operations are usually reversed on the very next day. SIDEBAR: Buyback operations are sales of securities that are accompanied by promises to repurchase the securities at a predetermined price, on a specific day, usually the next day. They occur on a segment of the overnight market, called the repo market. Nowadays the Bank of Canada uses buyback operations when it is unhappy with the evolution of the overnight interest rate, as determined in the repo market, relative to the target overnight rate. Banks transact with each other and with other financial entities on the overnight market all day long, on the basis of their current LVTS balance positions, and not only when they know for certain what their final LVTS balance position will be. When the overnight rate (more precisely the repo rate) is trading above the target rate, the Bank of Canada might intervene on the repo market, typically a bit before noon, conducting SPRAs at the target overnight rate, thus inducing banks and other repo market participants to bring the overnight rate back to its target. By contrast, when the overnight rate is trading below the target rate, the Bank of Canada can intervene with SRAs at the target overnight rate, thus inducing banks to negotiate the overnight rate around the target overnight rate. The effects of these operations are usually quite immediate. {In red} Central bank open-market purchases of securities and SPRA interventions on the repo market increase the amount of settlement balances and tend to decrease the overnight interest rate. Central bank open-market sales of securities and SRA interventions on the repo market decrease the amount of settlement balances and tend to increase the overnight interest rate. {END of RED} In late afternoon, when the bank decides on the amount of government deposits to be shifted, the buyback operations will be taken into account and neutralized. For instance, if liquidity has been inserted into the system through SPRA operations, more liquidity will be removed than otherwise would have been the case, as more government deposits will be shifted back to the central bank, unless the Bank of Canada is still unsatisfied about the actual overnight rate relative to its target. Yellow Square Standing Facilities and the Role of Lender of Last Resort Standing facilities are now a key element of all monetary systems that rely on a corridor framework, as is the case in Canada. Standing facilities are defined as monetary operations involving the central bank that banks can use at their discretion at any moment. Standing facilities are divided into borrowing facilities and deposit facilities. We have already encountered several instances of standing facilities within the Canadian monetary system in this chapter. First, during the day, a net debit LVTS position constitutes a form of borrowing facilities, although it only involves the Bank of Canada indirectly, as the holder of the pledged collateral. SIDEBAR: Standing facilities are routine monetary operations involving the central bank that banks can use at their discretion at any moment. Standing facilities include borrowing facilities and deposit facilities. Secondly, as we have also seen, at the end of the day, when the overnight market closes at 6:30 pm and settlement occurs, any remaining negative LVTS balances gets transformed into an overnight loan – an advance – by the Bank of Canada. This is done without restrictions, at the Bank rate, as long as the borrowing bank has adequate collateral. By contrast, in some countries, taking advances from the central bank is highly discouraged, as it was in Canada until 1991. Thirdly, also at the end of the day, banks that still have positive LVTS balances can deposit them on their account at the Bank of Canada, earning the interest rate on deposits at the central bank. This thus constitutes a classic example of deposit facility. Banks that, for any reason and at their discretion, do not wish to lend to other banks or to a specific bank on the overnight market, can still earn interest on the LVTS balances that they have left over. Standing facilities are the oldest of the central bank instruments. Open market operations were introduced much later, with most central banks in the world relying on standing facilities rather than on open market operations. At the beginning of central banking, banks brought commercial bills, that is, promises by a company to pay a given amount, say $10,000 in three months, to the central bank. The banks would then get an amount smaller than the nominal value of the bill from the central bank, say $9,900, immediately, with the central bank getting the full $10,000 three months later. The bill was thus being discounted, with the discount rate here being 1 percent ($100/$10,000) for three months, or 4 percent per annum. As a result, advances by central banks came to be known as discount facilities, or the discount window. This is why the interest rate on central bank advances to banks – the Bank rate – is still known in many countries as the discount rate. In addition to its standing facilities, the Bank of Canada offers an additional access to borrowing, which is tied to its role of lender of last resort. One of the roles of the Bank of Canada is to prevent financial panics and to avoid the spread of bank defaults, where the failure of one bank would generate the failure of another bank, with a domino effect. As we saw in Chapter 12, various rules and controls have been put in place in the LVTS, so that a defaulting or a failing bank should not jeopardize the health of the rest of the banking industry. In that event, the Bank of Canada would seize the collateral pledged by the failing bank, and would provide the funds needed for settlement. In the unlikely event that two large banks would fail simultaneously, the Bank of Canada might be obliged to supply more funds to the LVTS system than the value of the collateral, thus acting as the lender of last resort. The Bank of Canada may also act as a lender of last resort in another situation. An otherwise solvent bank may be subjected to a bank run, where depositors all wish to turn their deposits into cash or wish to transfer their deposits to another institution. In such a case it may difficult for the bank to respond to such a change of mind without selling some of its assets, many of which may be non-marketable and difficult to sell without enduring large losses. To prevent a liquidity problem from turning into a solvency problem, the Bank of Canada may decide to grant loans to this bank at the Bank rate, for a maximum term to maturity of six months, and this would be called an Emergency Lending Assistance (ELA) loan. Box The Timetable of Monetary Policy Implementation All Eastern times 7:00am Banks set their bilateral credit limits and pledge their collateral. 8:00am LVTS opens for transactions. 9:00am On fixed dates, the Bank of Canada announces new target overnight rate. 9:15am Morning auction of government deposits (early cash setting). 11:45am Open-market buyback operations by the Bank of Canada, if required. 3:00pm Last ACSS transaction involving the public sector. 4:00pm Last LVTS transaction involving the public sector. 4:15pm Afternoon auction of government deposits (final cash setting). 6:00pm Last LVTS transaction involving clearing of payment. 6:30pm End of pre-settlement period; closing of the overnight market. 8:00pm Calculations of LVTS balances are final and banks are advised of their settlement position (deposits at, and advances from, the Bank of Canada). {END OF BOX}