Willingness to Pay as a Range: Theoretical Foundations

advertisement
Willingness to Pay as a Range:
Theoretical Foundations, Measurement,
and Implications for Marketing Mix Decisions
Inauguraldissertation
to attain the academic degree
doctor rerum politicarum
(Doktor der Wirtschaftswissenschaften)
at the
ESCP Europe Business School Berlin
by
Dipl.-Ing. Florian Dost
Berlin
2012
Doctoral examination committee
Head:
Prof. Dr. Frank Jacob
Examiner:
Prof. Dr. Robert Wilken
Examiner:
Prof. Dr. Bernd Skiera
Day of disputation: 29.03.2012
Table of Contents
Table of Contents
Table of Contents....................................................................................................................... i
List of Figures .......................................................................................................................... iii
List of Tables .............................................................................................................................iv
List of Abbreviations ............................................................................................................... v
I.
Preamble .............................................................................................................................. 1
1
Introduction ........................................................................................................................ 2
1.1 Willingness to Pay (WTP) as a Range ......................................................................................... 2
1.2 Thesis Objectives and Structure ................................................................................................... 5
2 A Framework for the Role of WTP as a Range in Marketing Mix
Decisions ...................................................................................................................................... 7
3
Introduction to the Manuscripts ................................................................................ 9
II. Manuscripts...................................................................................................................... 11
4 Measuring Willingness to Pay as a Range, Revisited: When Should We
Care? ........................................................................................................................................... 12
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’
Willingness-to-Pay Ranges................................................................................................ 13
5.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................................................... 13
5.2 Theoretical Foundations .............................................................................................................. 15
5.2.1
Willingness to pay as a range ........................................................................................................ 15
5.2.2
WTP range–based targeting approach...................................................................................... 16
5.3 Empirical Studies............................................................................................................................. 18
5.3.1
Study 1: Price promotions in the FMCG category ................................................................. 18
5.3.2
Study 2: Different marketing mix activities in a high-involvement category ........... 20
5.3.3
Study 3: Price promotions in the FMCG category (competitive setting)..................... 25
5.4 General Discussion.......................................................................................................................... 31
5.4.1
Key findings and implications....................................................................................................... 31
5.4.2
Limitations and further research ................................................................................................ 32
5.5 Appendix A: Results of Study 3 .................................................................................................. 33
i
6 Verhaltensorientierter Ansatz zur Erklärung von Preisreaktionen bei
Commodities ........................................................................................................................... 34
III. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................ 35
7
Overview of Results ...................................................................................................... 36
8
Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3 ............................................................ 38
8.1 The Link of WTP Ranges and Cognitive Effort in Price-Related Choice ..................... 38
8.2 Study Design ...................................................................................................................................... 38
8.3 Procedure ........................................................................................................................................... 39
8.4 Results ................................................................................................................................................. 39
8.5 Discussion .......................................................................................................................................... 41
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among WTP, Range, and
Uncertainty .............................................................................................................................. 43
9.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................................................... 43
9.2 Study Design ...................................................................................................................................... 44
9.3 Results ................................................................................................................................................. 45
9.4 Discussion .......................................................................................................................................... 47
10 Implications of the Findings ..................................................................................... 48
10.1
WTP-as-a-Range Model ........................................................................................................ 48
10.2
WTP Range Measurement ................................................................................................... 50
10.3
WTP Range Management..................................................................................................... 51
10.4
A Call for Dynamics in WTP as a Range Research ...................................................... 53
References ................................................................................................................................ 55
ii
List of Figures
List of Figures
Figure 1.1: WTP as a range (adapted from Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterjee, 2007) .......... 3
Figure 2.1: Willingness to pay as a range in marketing mix decisions ....................................... 7
Figure 2.2: Overview of research questions ......................................................................................... 8
Figure 3.1: Overview on the manuscripts .............................................................................................. 9
Figure 5.1: Willingness to Pay as a Range ........................................................................................... 16
Figure 5.2: Differences in Choice Rate by Consumer Group ........................................................ 24
Figure 5.3: Retailer Gains in Choice Rate by Consumer Group ................................................... 28
Figure 7.1: Overview of findings in the manuscripts...................................................................... 36
Figure 8.1: Results of extension study ................................................................................................. 40
iii
List of Tables
List of Tables
Table 5.1: Results of Study 1 .................................................................................................................... 20
Table 5.2: Results of Study 2 .................................................................................................................... 23
Table 5.3: Predictive Validity in Study 2 ............................................................................................. 25
Table 5.4: Comparison of Retail Targeting Approaches ................................................................ 30
Table 5.5: Choice Rate Means and Comparisons of Study 3 ........................................................ 33
Table 9.1: Secondary analysis regression results ............................................................................ 46
iv
List of Abbreviations
List of Abbreviations
CP
ceiling reservation price
ed.
editor
eds.
editors
et al.
et alii (and others)
EUR
Euro (currency)
e.g.
exempli gratia (for example)
FMCG
fast moving consumer good
FP
floor reservation price
Hrsg.
Herausgeber
i.e.
id est (that means)
ICERANGE incentive-compatible elicitation of the range in a consumer’s reservation prices
IP
indifference reservation price
BDM
lottery mechanism by Becker, DeGroot, and Marschak (1964)
MANOVA
multivariate analysis of variance
OLS
ordinary least squares
pp.
pages
PWOM
positive word of mouth
sec.
second
SCL
shift-in-choice likelihood
SD
standard deviation
SE
standard error
vs.
versus
Vol.
volume
WTP
willingness to pay
WOM
word of mouth
z.B.
zum Beispiel
v
I. Preamble
1
1 Introduction
1 Introduction
1.1 Willingness to Pay (WTP) as a Range
In the wake of global economic turmoil and increasing pressures from global competition,
marketers seek salvation in the individualization of their marketing mixes. The individuallevel customization of product, price, promotion, and (with the advent of customizable online
shopping portals) even place thus appears on the agendas of most marketing practitioners and
researchers. Yet these efforts to enhance individual value propositions must first ensure
knowledge about consumers’ valuations and choice behavior. For example, individual
willingness to pay (WTP), or a person’s reservation price, is a fundamental concept for
individual choice, in both marketing and other fields such as micro-economics. Researchers,
marketing managers, and policy makers all see WTP as a monetized individual value (or
utility) for a good or service.
Thus optimal individual pricing decisions and predictions of individual consumer choice often
rely on measured WTP values. Pricing decisions might apply to whole segments or
populations of people, based on demand functions. In theory, aggregated individual WTP
values form demand. To estimate unbiased aggregate-level demand functions, together with
unbiased individual-level valuations, researchers need a valid method to measure WTP (e.g.,
Cameron & James 1987; Gijsbrechts 1993; Jedidi, Jagpal, & Manchanda 2003; Miller,
Hofstetter, Krohmer, & Zhang 2010; Voelckner 2006). Once they know demand or WTP,
marketing managers, as well as policy makers, might want to determine how they can
influence WTP, generally to enhance revenues or adoption of a good or service (e.g. Ajzen &
Driver 1992; Homburg, Koschate, & Hoyer 2005; Kalra & Goodstein 1998; Prelec &
Simester 2001). Thus, we are interested in the “measurement” and the “management” of
WTP, and both aspects depend on a model that links WTP to individual choice behavior and
ultimately to aggregate-level choice behavior. Therefore, this thesis considers all three
aspects: model, measurement, and management.
To find a valid measurement method, recent research has proposed measuring WTP as a range
rather than a single point. Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterjee (2007) argue that common
definitions of a reservation price, such as “the price at or below which a consumer will
demand one unit of the good” (Varian 1992, p. 152), “the price at which a consumer is
2
1 Introduction
indifferent between buying and not buying” (Moorthy, Ratchford, & Talukdar 1997, p. 265),
or “the minimum price at which a consumer would no longer purchase” (Hauser & Urban
1986, p. 449), are equivalent only if consumers make rational choices and are certain about
their preferences and product performance. However, value perceptions and actual behavior
are subject to limited rationality in individual behavior. Consumers suffer from bounded
rationality (Simon 1955) and construct their preferences during the course of their decision
making (Bettman, Luce, & Payne 1998). Thus choice is subject to uncertainty.
To account for bounded rationality, preference uncertainty, and product performance
uncertainty, WTP should be conceptualized and measured as a range of prices.1 Wang et al.
(2007) propose ICERANGE, a method focused on the floor, indifference, and ceiling
reservation prices. Each reservation price corresponds to one of the WTP definitions and is
linked to choice probabilities of 1, .5, and 0, respectively. The difference between the ceiling
and floor reservation price is the WTP range. A representation of Wang and colleagues’
conceptualization of a WTP range (hereafter, simply “range”) and the respective choice
probabilities appear in Figure 1.1.
Figure 1.1: WTP as a range (adapted from Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterjee, 2007)
1
WTP as a range is a unique concept compared with other purchase behavior–related concepts that feature price
ranges, such as the range-frequency theory for reference prices (Parducci 1965). The WTP range features
reservation prices; range-frequency theory is about reference prices. A (point-based) reservation price constitutes
the upper boundary of reference price ranges. For an individual consumer, WTP range and reference price ranges
refer to different price levels. See Chapter 3 for a detailed comparison.
3
1 Introduction
However, literature about WTP as a range and its uses is scarce, and knowledge remains
incomplete. Three major areas of inquiry correspond to the model, measurement, and
management categories. Each area exhibits research gaps at several levels, from aggregate
demand down to individual consumers’ internal decision making.
First, Wang et al. (2007) assume that WTP as a range is a novel conceptualization of
individual WTP, but they do not explain how their conceptualization influences individual
buying decisions or, ultimately, the marketing mix and pricing decisions. More generally,
they do not discuss potential changes to the model that might induce changes in pricing
decisions, too. Nor has any research determined how range-based WTP estimates relate to
traditional point-based estimates at the individual consumer level. This part of the model is
important to evaluate what past research has explained using point-based methods. Consumer
uncertainty appears to be the sole driver of WTP ranges, but empirical results are inconclusive
about the uncertainty–range link (Wang, Venkatesh, & Chatterjee 2007). Thus far, alternative
antecedents, or different modes of consumer decision making, have been neglected.
Second, the measurement benefits of range-based methods are unclear when considering the
relationship between point- and range-based methods. To put it simply: Why should
marketers care about WTP as a range from an empirical perspective? And when should they
apply range-based elicitation methods? The existing methodology, such as ICERANGE
procedure (Wang et al., 2007) may be complex for many respondents, because it implicitly
assumes that respondents can state their reservation prices for any purchase probability within
their individual WTP range. Strictly speaking, this assumption contradicts the general finding
of consumers’ preference uncertainty.
Third, adding the dimension of a WTP range should broaden the possibilities by which
marketing mix activities influence consumer behavior and ultimately profit. Because WTP
ranges have never been considered in previous studies of WTP antecedents or marketing mix–
related choice behavior, extant results may have been misinterpreted in light of the new WTP
conceptualization.
In summary, the conceptualization of WTP as a range generates various questions about the
measurement and management of WTP ranges, as well as the relevant theoretical foundations,
as manifested in the model that explains the link among antecedents, WTP, choice behavior,
and optimal marketing mix decisions. Therefore, all three aspects—model, measurement, and
management—constitute part of my inquiries.
4
1 Introduction
1.2 Thesis Objectives and Structure
In a series of manuscripts, I propose a modified model to substantiate the theoretical
foundations of the WTP-as-a-range concept and consider its relations to extant point-based
WTP concepts. The modified model and resulting consequences for the link between WTP
and choice will be tested empirically. To improve the practical applicability of the concept
and the related measurement methods, a modified variant of a range-based WTP method will
be developed and empirically compared and examined. A comparison with traditional (pointbased) methods should reveal the conditions in which the new range-based methods are more
useful or even superior in the context of individual-level and aggregate demand–level pricing
decisions. Finally, because conceptualizing WTP as a range extends the toolset for managerial
actions targeted at individual consumer profitability, the concept shall be applied further to
marketing mix decision problems including empirical validation of the findings. Taken
together, these contributions offer important recommendations for the measurement and
management of WTP as a range, as well as a sound theoretical foundation for the model.
In pursuing these aims, this thesis starts with a perspective on the nature of rationality and
uncertainty in choice that is similar to the assumptions delineated by Wang and colleagues:
Consumers have a bounded rationality and construct their preferences in the decision-making
process (Wang, Venkatesh, & Chatterjee 2007; see also: Bettman, Luce, & Payne 1998). Still,
consumers can engage in rational processing, at a restricted and uncertainty-prone level. This
perspective is useful for two reasons. First, readers already familiar with WTP as a range will
have an easy access to the research in this thesis. Second, by slowly broadening the view to
related research dealing with behavioral choice models, which uses reference prices and
decision heuristics, this thesis aims to establish findings for future consolidations of
descriptive research on behavioral choice and normative (bounded) rational choice.
Therefore I present a framework that centers on the WTP-as-a-range concept and that is
embedded in marketing mix decision making in Chapter 2. After I introduce and position the
three focal manuscripts in Chapter 3, the second part of this thesis is dedicated to those three
manuscripts, which constitute Chapters 4–6.2 Each manuscript constitutes a distinct, selfcontained piece of research. Finally, the last part of this thesis is dedicated to a synthesis of
the various findings according to its overarching framework, as well as an extension of their
2
The manuscripts have been adapted to match the overall structure of this thesis, so the enumerations of the
headlines, layout of text and tables, and citation styles may differ from those in the original publications.
5
1 Introduction
distinct findings. Chapter 8 empirically substantiates the conceptual results related to
cognitive efforts in WTP ranges from the third manuscript (Chapter 6); Chapter 9 integrates
the data sets of all manuscripts using secondary and meta-analyses, which review links
between uncertainty and WTP ranges that were inconclusively demonstrated by Wang and
colleagues (2007). Chapter 10 provides a synthesis of the major results and proposes avenues
for further research.
6
2 A Framework for the Role of WTP as a Range in Marketing Mix Decisions
2 A Framework for the Role of WTP as a Range in
Marketing Mix Decisions
The optimal allocation of scarce resources to the marketing mix requires particular attention
of marketing academia. For example, the current Marketing Science Institute (MSI) research
priorities ask: “What are effective pricing strategies, tactics, and practices for complex
products in a multi-media, multi-channel environment that allow for increasingly customized
pricing decisions? How should firms determine the absolute level of marketing spending and
how should spending be allocated at the strategic level—that is, across products, customer
groups, and geographies?” (MSI 2011, p. 9). These questions provide the boundaries for the
research framework of this thesis, depicted in Figure 2.1.
Figure 2.1: Willingness to pay as a range in marketing mix decisions
First, an optimal marketing mix decision requires a model that links marketing variables to
marketers’ goals (e.g. Little 2004). This model constitutes the central pillar of the framework.
At the highest level, the variables refer to aggregate consumer behavior, such as market
7
2 A Framework for the Role of WTP as a Range in Marketing Mix Decisions
reaction or demand. Relevant at the individual level is observable, individual-level consumer
behavior, such as individual choice behavior. Individual behavior then is linked to
unobservable variables at the organism level, such as willingness to pay, or in this case WTP
as a range. The WTP ranges can be driven by other unobservable variables that are subjacent
in the organism, such as preferences or uncertainty (Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterjee, 2007),
or they may be the result of a heuristic that combines past experiences with conjectures
derived from observed information, such as current prices (e.g. Wathieu & Bertini 2007; Park,
McLachlan, & Love 2011).
Second, a marketing manager needs valid information about the key variables in the model.
Consequently, valid and reliable measurement methods must retrieve the variable states at the
desired level of information. Measurement constitutes the second pillar of the framework.
Third, an optimal marketing mix not only adapts to the current state but also seeks to alter it.
The marketer uses elements of the marketing mix to manage and manipulate the value states
in the model, such as by setting an optimal price, setting the right amount of advertising
spending for the right communication channel to increase WTP levels or manipulate levels of
uncertainty, or targeting the right group of consumers. Management is thus the third pillar of
the framework.
The research questions identified in Chapter 1.1 and their links to the framework are depicted
in Figure 2.2.
Figure 2.2: Overview of research questions
8
3 Introduction to the Manuscripts
3 Introduction to the Manuscripts
To cover this broad area of inquiry, each research project in this thesis focuses on a different
pillar, such as model, measurement, or management, or a different level of information, or
both. The three main manuscripts constitute distinct contributions to research; they also are
closely related though and cover important research gaps in the overarching framework.
Furthermore, each manuscript covers a different level of aggregation, to present an array of
novel findings. Figure 3.1 provide an overview of their position within the framework.
Figure 3.1: Overview on the manuscripts
The first manuscript, “Willingness to Pay as a Range, Revisited: When Should We Care?”
deals with the central construct of WTP as a range. It covers valid “measurements” of the
range, while also reviewing the “model” at the levels of individual and aggregate choice
behavior, in the context of the “management” of optimal pricing decisions. I theoretically
propose and empirically show that traditional point-based methods reveal the midpoint of
WTP ranges. Furthermore, a method to measure WTP as a range that is simpler and less
restricted than ICERANGE, but still achieves comparable performance, is introduced in
Chapter 4. A Monte Carlo simulation reveals that except in very artificial conditions, point-
9
3 Introduction to the Manuscripts
based methods fail to reproduce the revenue maximizing prices identified by range-based
methods, even on an aggregate consumer choice level.
In “On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay
Ranges,” I propose an in-store targeting approach based on WTP ranges. It covers the higher
aggregation levels of the framework, consumer choice behavior and aggregate choice, and it
focuses on the management dimension for the marketing mix. By adopting a retailers’
perspective, Chapter 5 shows analytically and empirically that only the so called “uncertain”
consumers, whose range includes the current price, are affected by marketing mix activities
and therefore should be targeted. Specifically, this uncertain segment indicates significantly
different choice behavior due to marketing mix manipulations and subsequent changes in
price, WTP, or WTP ranges.
Finally, the third manuscript, entitled “Verhaltensorientierter Ansatz zur Erklärung von
Preisreaktionen bei Commodities und Empfehlungen für die Preissetzung auf CommodityMärkten,”3 theoretically conceptualizes potential behavioral links between WTP as a range
and reference price reaction models, using the two mental decision modes of dual process
theory (e.g., Epstein 1991; Godek & Murray 2008; Sloman 1996). The manuscript thus covers
the organism level for WTP range formation and choice behavior.
To complement these three manuscripts, the concluding chapters also offer two extensions:
(1) empirical evidence for the link between WTP ranges and a dual process of decision
making, as conceptualized in Chapter 6, and (2) an empirical assessment of the link between
WTP ranges and uncertainty as an antecedent.
3
This manuscript is the only part of the thesis written in German.
10
II. Manuscripts
4 Measuring Willingness to Pay as a Range, Revisited: When Should We Care?
4 Measuring Willingness to Pay as a Range,
Revisited: When Should We Care?
Manuscript No. 1
This manuscript is forthcoming as: Dost, Florian & Wilken, Robert (2012). Measuring
Willingness to Pay as a Range, Revisited: When Should We Care?. International Journal of
Research in Marketing, forthcoming in Vol. 29 (2).
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2011.09.003
12
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach
Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay
Ranges
Manuscript No. 2
Authors: Florian Dost and Robert Wilken.
Publication status: Under review in Journal of Retailing.
5.1 Introduction
Shopper marketing attracts ever increasing attention, largely because more than 50% of
consumption choices occur while the consumer shops in the store (Inman, Winer, & Ferraro
2009). Investments in marketing mix activities at the point of purchase (e.g., sales
promotions, advertising) thus have grown more than 20% per year (e.g., Shankar et al. 2011).
Many of these activities remain unprofitable though; Ailawadi et al. (2006) report failure rates
of 50% across all promotions. To improve the effectiveness of shopper marketing activities,
retailers try to customize their activities. Rather than targeting the mass market in an
undifferentiated way, they focus on consumer groups or even individual consumers who
appear likely change their choice behavior, for example in response to a price discount for a
specific product.
Academic insights into these targeting strategies are limited though. For example, the current
MSI Research Priorities call for “new ways to leverage information about customer
preferences … to enhance or supplant conventional … market segmentation, and targeting
approaches … to allocate … resources more effectively to influence a shopper along the
entire ‘path to purchase’” (MSI 2011, p. 4). Shankar and colleagues (2011, p. S40) similarly
ask: “How can shopper segmentation be improved and the results be better interpreted and
utilized?”
Unfortunately, related literature offers only incomplete or inconclusive answers. For example,
retailing research on targeted marketing mix activities has mostly centered on the retailer’s
effort to bring customers into the store; few studies adopt an in-store perspective to
13
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
investigate the effectiveness of in-store promotions (Ailawadi et al. 2006; Srinivasan et al.
2004). Those that do, however, provide mixed results (for an overview, see Ailawadi et al.
2009). Furthermore, in-store targeting research tends to ignore the retailer perspective and
investigate instead topics such as brand switching, taking the manufacturer’s point of view.
But retailers do not benefit from brand switching unless the manufacturer chooses to align its
interests with those of the retailer (Ailawadi et al. 2009). Another stream considers the
optimal granularity for targeting (e.g., mass market, segments, individuals). Analytically,
greater granularity should be more profitable (Grewal et al. 2011; Zhang & Krishnamurthi
2004), but empirical evidence remains inconsistent: Rossi, McCulloch, and Allenby (1996)
confirm this result, Zhang and Wedel (2009) cannot.
Noting this lack of insight into in-store targeting approaches that benefit a retailer, we propose
a novel targeting approach based on recent developments that suggest conceptualizing
consumers’ willingness to pay (WTP) as a range (Wang, Venkatesh, & Chatterjee 2007; Dost
& Wilken 2012). For a retailer, WTP is obviously crucial information: Its relation with the
price of a specific product or service determines the consumer’s purchase choice. Moreover,
WTP ranges can reveal not only if a consumer is willing to purchase at a given price, but also
if he or she might be uncertain about purchasing at that price. We argue that information
about consumers’ uncertainty may enhance targeting, because uncertain consumers can be
influenced more easily than those who are certain about their preferences. In turn, marketing
mix activities, such as price promotions, might be more effective (i.e., modify choice behavior
more) when targeted at uncertain consumers. In contrast, targeting other consumers would be
a waste of resources, because they certainly would or certainly would not have purchased
anyway.
In three studies, we establish the usefulness of a targeting approach based on WTP ranges.
Study 1 tests whether uncertain customers are more reactive to price promotions than certain
buyers or certain non-buyers. Study 2 generalizes the findings of Study 1 by (a) featuring a
different product category (higher price level, durable instead of fast moving consumer good),
(b) extending the analysis to marketing mix activities beyond price promotions, and (c)
establishing the predictive validity of choice behavior. Then we extend Study 1 further to a
competitive setting with two products in Study 3, to generalize the approach and compare our
approach with prevailing targeting practices. Compared with (a) brand customer promotions
(e.g., loyalty promotions), (b) competitive brand customer promotions (e.g., competitive
14
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
promotions), or (c) a combination, the WTP range–based targeting approach leads to a greater
increase in total choice rates per targeted consumer across both products we study.
5.2 Theoretical Foundations
5.2.1 Willingness to pay as a range
According to Wang, Venkatesh, & Chatterjee (2007), consumers do not know their true
willingness to pay (WTP), because they suffer from uncertainty. Instead they conceptualize
WTP as a range of reservation prices, each with a corresponding choice probability. We
modify and advance this conceptualization and define a WTP distribution that represents the
distribution of choice probability around a true, yet latent, individual WTP (Dost & Wilken
2012; see also Park, MacLachlan, & Love 2011; Schlereth, Eckert, & Skiera 2011).
The individual WTP distribution can be specified by an expected individual WTP value,
which corresponds with a traditional definition of WTP, and variance in the individual WTP,
which corresponds to the “range” introduced by Wang et al. (2007). Individual choice (or
buying) probability is therefore a function of preference (expected WTP) and uncertainty
(WTP range or simply range). Figure 5.1 illustrates the range-based WTP concept, as well as
a corresponding function of individual purchase probability. For clarity, we use the linearly
decreasing probability function introduced by Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterjee (2007).
This novel conceptualization of individual WTP distributions offers a new dimension,
relevant for individual consumer choice. However, other than measurement issues, we know
little about the usefulness of the WTP range conceptualization, including how the marketing
mix activities that aim to influence WTP also might influence WTP range, or vice versa. How
might WTP ranges affect a firm’s or a retailer’s sales and profitability? Should WTP ranges
be increased or reduced? In their more general approach, Dost and Wilken (2012) show that
failing to control for WTP ranges can lead to misspecifications of the respective demand
function.
15
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
Figure 5.1: Willingness to Pay as a Range
5.2.2 WTP range–based targeting approach
Most targeting studies investigate price promotions (e.g., Grewal & Levy, 2007), because
price is the one marketing mix element that can be directly influenced by a retailer. But
retailers also can affect consumers’ preferences and attain the same market response
indirectly. The range-based WTP concept offers three alternatives: change the price, influence
a consumer’s WTP, or influence a consumer’s WTP range. All these options only affect the
consumer’s purchase probability if the retail price is within his or her WTP range or moves
into that range through the application of one of the alternatives. We thus offer the following:
Proposition 1: Only choice behavior by uncertain consumers (i.e., whose ranges include the
current retail price) are affected by a change in (a) price, (b) consumers’ WTP, or (c)
consumers’ WTP range.
Proof: We assume a linear decrease in purchase probability within the WTP range (Wang,
Venkatesh, & Chatterjee, 2007), such that it equals 1 for any price below the floor reservation
price (FP); 0 for any price beyond ceiling reservation price (CP); and a value between 1 and 0
for any price between FP and CP (WTP range), with a linear decrease between FP and CP.
That is,
16
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
Pr(
0
−
⎧
| ) = ⎨
⎩
; ≥
1
+
2
;
1
<
<
;
>
; ≤
Partial derivatives reveal sensitivities in purchase probabilities to changes in price, individual
WTP, and individual WTP range, respectively:
∂Pr(
∂Pr(
∂Pr(
| )
| )
| )
0
1
⎧
; ≥
= −
⎨
⎩
0
⎧
=
⎨
⎩
;
<
; ≥
0
; ≤
= −
⎨
⎩
;
>
; ≤
0
1
⎧
<
;
<
0
;
>
; ≥
−
0
<
;
<
<
;
>
; ≤
These equations demonstrate that changes in purchase probability due to changes in price,
individual WTP, or individual WTP range only occur if the current price appears in the
individual range. Therefore, purchase probability declines as price increases, increases as
individual WTP increases, and can decrease or increase when range increases, depending on
whether the current price p is lower or higher, respectively, than WTP. Analytically, when
targeting is based on consumers’ WTP ranges, a retailer should focus on the segment of
uncertain consumers. Is this prediction consistent with empirical observations? We conduct
three studies to answer this question.
17
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
5.3 Empirical Studies
5.3.1 Study 1: Price promotions in the FMCG category
5.3.1.1 Design
With this first study, we empirically test Proposition 1 by examining the effect of a price
promotion on choices by three consumer groups: certain non-buyers, uncertain, and certain
buyers. We designed a quasi-experiment in an online store setting, which holds appeal for
targeting studies. Because it does not rely on coupons, it achieves 100% redemption rates
(Zhang & Wedel 2009), and redemption rates strongly affect targeting results.
The stimuli were fake online offers, illustrated by a picture and complemented with a textual
description, for a 100 fl. oz. bottle of Ultra Purex Coldwater liquid detergent, a medium
priced liquid detergent developed for use with energy-saving washing at low temperatures.
For this fast moving consumer good (FMCG), we expected a considerable portion of
uncertain consumers, because it was only recently introduced to the market. At the time of the
study, the online price asked by Walmart was $5.97. After participants provided their floor
and ceiling reference prices (Dost & Wilken 2012), they were assigned to one of the three
consumer groups, with the online retail price of $5.97 as a differentiator. For example, a
participant with a ceiling reservation price of $4.00 entered the certain non-buyers group,
whereas another participant with a floor price of $6.00 belonged to the certain buyers. Lastly,
a participant with a floor reservation price of $5.00 and a ceiling reservation price of $7.00
was labeled “uncertain.” The $5.97 price falls approximately in the middle of all available
prices for comparable detergents, so we expected consumers to be relatively equally
distributed across the three groups. In addition, we directly manipulated the price for the
stimulus (regular vs. discounted): Independent of their membership in one of the consumer
groups, participants were randomly assigned to a stimulus with either the current price of
$5.97 or a discounted price of $4.97. Altogether, this approach yielded a 3 (consumer group)
 2 (price level) study design.
Choice was the dependent variable, because it should not be very prone to biases, even in a
hypothetical setting without the obligation to purchase (Miller et al. 2011). More important,
choice reflects the ultimate goal of in-store targeting activities, that is, to influence
consumers’ purchase decisions at the point of purchase.
18
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
As control variables and to confirm well-balanced samples, we used one-item measures of
category knowledge and category involvement before showing the stimulus to participants.
We also collected demographic information at the end of the survey. A one-item measure of
deal attractiveness served as the manipulation check for the price promotion. All items used
seven-point Likert scales. Finally, we asked for participants’ predictions of the study’s
purpose.
5.3.1.2 Procedure
We recruited 198 respondents through Amazon Mechanical Turk, a crowdsourcing platform
for human tasks. We followed Mason and Suri’s (2011) guidelines for research on this
platform to ensure reliable and valid results. The pool of potential respondents was restricted
to U.S. residents. Each respondent received a payment between $.30 and $.40. The study
design required them to open a link for the survey, hosted on another survey platform, and
then transfer a unique code back onto Mechanical Turk. The average survey duration was
approximately five minutes; we excluded respondents who spent less than three minutes (i.e.,
the click-through benchmark) on the task. Two fail-check items helped us ensure attentive
reading. First, we asked respondents to check the third box displayed from the left. Second,
we asked if the study was about cars, and respondents answered on an agree–disagree array.
We excluded respondents who did not answer both questions correctly. Finally, we excluded
two participants who stated a ceiling price of more than $50 (one later indicated that he forgot
the decimal). After eliminating 30 respondents (15.1%), 168 data sets remained for the
analysis.
5.3.1.3 Results
A MANOVA (Pillai’s Trace p = .731 for the model; ps > .26 for the model parameters) on
age, gender, income, education, pre-stimulus knowledge about the detergent category, attitude
toward the detergent category, category involvement, and distribution of self-selected
certainty–uncertainty groups showed no significant differences across experimental groups.
There was no effect on the balance of the samples of either the random assignment or the failcheck based elimination. None of the participants guessed the actual purpose of the study.
The manipulation check revealed that the promoted price had a significant effect on deal
attractiveness (Mregular = 5.19, SE = 1.67; Mdiscount = 5.84, SE = 1.45; F(1, 166) = 7.07; p <
.01). Across all experimental groups, the average WTP was $5.55 (SE = $2.24), calculated as
the mean between the floor and ceiling reservation prices. The average WTP range, calculated
19
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
as the difference between floor and ceiling reservation prices, was $2.38 (SE = $1.75). The
distribution of respondents across the three consumer groups was reasonably similar, with 56
certain non-buyers, 73 uncertain consumers, and 39 certain buyers. Table 5.1 displays the
resulting choice behavior for each group, divided by the stimulus.
Table 5.1: Results of Study 1
N
CHOICE EFFECTS OF PRICE PROMOTION BY CONSUMER GROUPS
Certain non-buyersa
Uncertain buyersb
Certain buyersc
Regular Discounted
Regular Discounted
Regular Discounted
price
price
price
price
price
price
($5.97)
($4.97)
($5.97)
($4.97)
($5.97)
($4.97)
28
28
43
30
17
22
Choice
rate
(Standard
Error)
.32
.43
.67
.90
.88
.77
(.09)
(.10)
(.07)
(.06)
(.08)
(.09)
Δ Choiced
Te
p
+.11
.818
.417
+.23
2.293
.025
–.11
–.870
.390
a
All participants with ceiling reservation price < $5.97.
All participants with floor reservation price < $5.97 ≤ ceiling reservation price.
c
All participants with floor reservation price ≥ $5.97.
d
Change rate from regular to discounted price, expressed as a percentage, with significant differences in bold.
e
Two-tailed t-test.
b
Pairwise t-tests of differences in choice rate reveal significant differences only in the
uncertain group. It is not surprising that a small (not significant) share of non-buyers chose
the detergent, because the price reduction of 17% is more than marginal, which likely moved
the group criterion from non-buyer to uncertain. Overall, Study 1 thus provides empirical
support for the analytical suggestion that in-store targeting based on consumers’ WTP ranges
should focus on the uncertain segment.
5.3.2 Study 2: Different marketing mix activities in a high-involvement
category
Although Study 1 supports our proposition, it has several limitations. First, it pertains only to
a reduction in price. To broaden retailers’ alternatives, it also is interesting to investigate
whether other marketing mix activities overwhelmingly affect the uncertain. Second, the
stimulus belonged to a FMCG category (detergents), which generally demands little cognitive
20
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
effort to purchase. This factor might limit the results to more impulse-driven purchase
decisions. We believe this test enhances support for our proposition, because an impulse
buyer is generally more likely to change choice behavior in response to a price promotion;
however, the matter still demands empirical validation. Study 2 aims to address these
limitations and generalize the results.
5.3.2.1 Design
We designed another quasi-experiment in an online store setting. The durable product used
was the Amazon Kindle Touch, a new variant of a medium-priced e-reader. Although the
purchase of such a product likely invokes intense thought, we expect a considerable
proportion of uncertain consumers, because of the product’s newness. Furthermore, the
Kindle is for sale only online, so it enhances the realism of the research setting. To measure
WTP range according to reservation prices, after the display of the stimulus, we revised the
identification of the three groups of non-buyers, uncertain, and buyers. Specifically, we asked
participants whether they would certainly buy, certainly not buy, or were uncertain about
buying the product for $100. This self-selection variable directly identified the uncertain
segment and generated the three consumer groups for our subsequent analysis. Furthermore,
the self-selection mechanism increases the generalizability of our findings, because the use of
alternate methods reduces common method bias, and generates an even stricter test of our
proposition. The uncertain group in this case might include respondents who are simply too
lazy to decide, those who always opt for the “middle,” or any others who exhibit behavior that
leads to measurement biases. Thus the group of “truly uncertain” consumers might overlap
with those of certain buyers and certain non-buyers, which reduces discrimination between
groups and ultimately might partially hide the choice behavior effect in the uncertain group.
We used manipulated, fake online store product pages for the Kindle as stimuli. Respondents
were randomly assigned to one of five different stimuli in a between-subjects design. The first
stimulus showed a headline description and picture of the product, at the retail price of $99.
This stimulus represented the control group. Then the price promotion stimulus changed the
displayed price to $79, with no reference to the previous normal price. The word of mouth
stimulus included four short, positive user comments, taken from the actual product site on
Amazon. With the information stimulus, we included a bulleted list of the features and
advantages of the product, also taken from the actual product site. Finally, the visual stimulus
advertised the e-reader with a picture of a young, attractive woman using the product while on
a beach vacation. Choice again served as the dependent variable for all stimuli conditions.
21
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
For control variables, we again used three-point, single-item measures for knowledge about
and attitude toward the Kindle before the stimulus, and we collected demographic information
at the end of the survey. Knowledge and attitude provided a manipulation check for the selfselected groups. A single-item, seven-point Likert scale measure of offer attractiveness served
as the manipulation check for the four marketing mix stimuli (which were intended to
enhance offer attractiveness, compared with the control group). Finally, we asked for the
participants’ suspicions about the study’s purpose.
5.3.2.2 Procedure
We recruited 645 respondents through Amazon Mechanical Turk, restricted to U.S. residents.
Each respondent received a reward between $.30 and $.90. The actual survey was again
hosted on another survey platform and required the transfer of a unique code back to
Mechanical Turk. The average survey duration was approximately seven minutes, and we
excluded respondents who spent less than three minutes (click-through duration). We also
excluded respondents who guessed that the usual price for a Kindle in a store would be $0 or
more than 200% the actual market price. In two fail-check items, to ensure attentive reading,
we asked respondents to check the second box from the left and whether the study was about
a false product variant of the same brand (a Kindle Fire Tablet). These checks required the
elimination of 98 respondents (15.2%), which left 547 data sets for analysis.
5.3.2.3 Results
A MANOVA (Pillai’s Trace p = .357 for the model; ps > .24 for the model parameters) on
age, gender, income, education, pre-stimulus knowledge about the Kindle, attitude toward the
Kindle, e-reader category involvement, and distribution of the self-selected certainty–
uncertainty groups showed no significant differences across stimuli groups. The random
assignment and the fail-check elimination thus had no effect on the balance of the samples for
the marketing mix manipulation. Nor did any of the participants guess the actual purpose of
the study. Four participants suggested that the study’s purpose was to find out how people
react to positive customer reviews, which is close to the true purpose, but we decided not to
exclude them.
An analysis of the two manipulation check items for the group selection revealed that attitude
toward the Kindle was significantly better among the uncertain consumers compared with
non-buyers (Muncertain = 2.55; Mnon-buyer = 2.09; T = 8.130; p < .001). In contrast, buyers
showed a significantly better attitude than the uncertain (Mbuyer = 2.86; T = 6.062; p < .001).
22
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
Knowledge about the Kindle was only marginally higher for the uncertain compared with the
non-buyers though (Muncertain = 1.51, Mnon-buyer = 1.43; T = 1.636; p = .103), and there was no
difference between the uncertain and buyers (Mbuyer = 1.57; T = 1.122; p = .262). These results
suggest that the self-selection into the three consumer groups was driven by preference, not
by the level of information possessed, which might have confounded the subsequent results.
The offer attractiveness item revealed that the marketing mix stimuli had significant effects
on deal attractiveness. Offer attractiveness was significantly worse for the control stimulus
(Mcontrol = 4.66) compared with all four other stimuli: price promotion (M = 5.12; T = 2.344; p
< .05), information (M = 5.42; T = 3.988; p < .001), visual (M = 5.11; T = 2.309; p < .05), and
positive word of mouth (M = 5.20; T = 2.653; p < .01). The marketing mix stimuli all worked
in the intended direction; Table 5.2 displays the resulting choice behavior for each group,
divided by stimulus, as well as WTP and WTP range values.
Table 5.2: Results of Study 2
WTP, WTP RANGES, AND CHOICE RATES BY CONSUMER GROUP AND STIMULUS
Mean
Mean
WTP
(SE)
Range (SE) in Choice
Δ
Groupa
Stimulus
N in US$ in US$ in US$
US$
Rate (SE)
choiceb Tc
p
Control
Promotion
Certain nonInformation
buyers
Visual
PWOM
29
29
20
22
38
32.62
28.67
43.13
34.55
51.07
(23.84)
(26.12)
(33.35)
(33.23)
(27.99)
20.69
15.90
33.85
21.45
26.82
(21.41)
(21.90)
(49.87)
(34.41)
(29.91)
.03
.03
.05
.00
.08
(.19)
(.19)
(.22)
(.00)
(.27)
.00
+.02
-.03
+.04
.00
.264
.869
.753
Control
Promotion
Information
Visual
PWOM
55
56
57
68
49
85.96
80.16
90.25
90.31
88.37
(22.72)
(25.07)
(31.51)
(36.81)
(32.73)
63.78
51.68
53.89
65.85
48.53
(42.31)
(45.93)
(45.27)
(54.13)
(32.45)
.25
.64
.42
.43
.59
(.44)
(.48)
(.50)
(.50)
(.50)
+.39
+.17
+.17
+.34
4.425 <.001
1.873 .064
2.004 .047
3.674 <.001
Uncertain
buyers
Control
21 123.71 (30.70) 63.90 (42.60) .95
(.22)
Promotion 30 115.65 (24.66) 36.57 (36.89) 1.00 (.00)
+.05 1.200
Certain
Information 27 123.94 (28.42) 57.89 (35.08) 1.00 (.00)
+.05 1.137
buyers
Visual
21 125.71 (39.64) 46.29 (37.73) .81
(.40)
-.14 1.430
PWOM
25 120.92 (33.90) 42.00 (35.61) .92
(.28)
-.03
.434
Notes: SE = standard error. PWOM = positive word of mouth.
a
Self-selected groups.
b
Difference in choice rate between stimulus and control group, with significant differences in bold.
c
Two-tailed t-test.
1.00
.793
.389
.454
.236
.261
.160
.666
Pairwise t-tests of mean demand between the control group and respective marketing mix
stimuli revealed significant differences only for the uncertain group. Even though the certain
buyers included consumers whose WTP ranges included the price, they exhibited no
significant change in demand as a result of any of the stimuli. The certain non-buyer group
23
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
also did not adapt its choice behavior in any case. Figure 5.2 illustrates the mean differences
in demand values and significance levels from the pairwise t-tests.
Figure 5.2: Differences in Choice Rate by Consumer Group
Overall the results support our proposition that the uncertain segment should be targeted by
any marketing mix activity. The additional product information stimulus exerted no
significant impact, though its size and direction were comparable. Our subsequent analyses of
changes in WTP and WTP ranges demonstrate how the stimuli account for these results.
Similar to extant studies using WTP as a range, we adopted the shift-in-choice likelihood
(SCL) criterion to assess the predictive validity of the WTP measures for each group (Wang,
Venkatesh, & Chatterjee 2007; Dost & Wilken 2012). We applied SCL as an absolute
difference between actual choice and calculated choice probability. The mean SCL values for
each group should be generally low, to indicate predictive validity, and not differ across
groups, which would rule out the possibility that choice differences across stimuli are caused
by variables other than price, WTP, or WTP range. SCL results are shown in Table 5.3. The
SCL values were comparable to those in previous studies (absolute SCL values in Dost and
Wilken [2012] ranged between .03 and .25), and they did not differ for any marketing mix
stimuli compared with the control group. Therefore, the relationship among WTP as a range,
price, and resulting choice is unaffected by the stimulus type. However, the price promotion
stimulus indicated a significantly higher SCL than that for the control group, perhaps because
of a reference price effect, in that a different price slightly changes the relationship, compared
with the other stimuli. Reference price can influence both preference and perceived cost.
24
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
Table 5.3: Predictive Validity in Study 2
MEAN WTP, MEAN WTP RANGES, AND SCL SCORES, BY STIMULUS
Group:
Control
Promotion Information
Visual
PWOM
N:
105
115
104
111
112
Price in US$:
99
79
99
99
99
Mean WTP in US$:
78.78
76.43
89.93
85.96
82.98
(SE) in US$:
(40.39)
(40.21)
(40.96)
(46.52)
(40.72)
Mean Range in US$:
51.90
38.71
51.08
53.35
39.70
(SE) in US$:
(42.16)
(41.21)
(44.25)
(50.79)
(33.47)
Mean SCL:
.19
.33
.20
.20
.18
(Standard Error):
(.26)
(.40)
(.29)
(.27)
(.29)
Δ SCLa:
+.01
+.01
-.01
+.14
b
T:
.312
.216
.215
3.074
p:
.755
.829
.830
.002
Notes: PWOM = positive word of mouth. SCL = shift-in-choice likelihood.
a
Difference in SCL between stimulus and control group, with significant differences in bold.
b
Two-tailed t-test.
5.3.3 Study 3: Price promotions in the FMCG category (competitive setting)
5.3.3.1 Design
The two previous studies proved that increased choice caused by various marketing mix
stimuli overwhelmingly occurs among uncertain consumers. However, targeting often entails
competitive settings with more than one brand. To empirically confirm the applicability of our
novel targeting procedure to competitive settings, as well as compare our proposed approach
with extant practices (e.g., loyal customer, competitive targeting), Study 3 features a
competitive setting with two brands.
The actual WTP values for two brands might be correlated, due to income or category
preference, so for this study, we randomly assign respondents to buyer groups, independent of
the brands. We thereby manipulate the consumer group (non-buyers, uncertain, or buyers) for
both brands and on the basis of the corresponding reservation prices (floor and ceiling). We
also manipulate targeting activity (20% price discount vs. regular price) separately for each
brand. This method ultimately yielded a 3 (consumer group brand A: buyer, uncertain, nonbuyer)  3 (consumer group brand B: buyer, uncertain, non-buyer)  2 (price for brand A:
regular vs. discounted)  2 (price for brand B: regular vs. discounted) between-subjects
design. Similar to Study 1, the stimuli were fake, online FMCG offers, illustrated by a picture
and textual description. In addition to the medium-priced 100 fl. oz. bottle of Ultra Purex
Coldwater, a competitive product was represented by the higher-priced Tide brand.
25
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
The displayed prices for both products were individually calculated for each participant, on
the basis of their stated floor and ceiling reference prices (Dost & Wilken 2012) and
according to their randomly assigned consumer group. For example, a participant randomly
assigned to the non-buyers group received a regular price that was 25% above his or her
stated ceiling price, whereas a member of the uncertain group saw a regular price that
reflected the midpoint between floor and ceiling reservation prices. Finally, the certain
buyers’ regular price was 25% below their floor price. Then for each group, the discounted
price was reduced by 20% off the individual regular price. A participant assigned to the
certain non-buyers group who stated a floor (ceiling) reservation price of $4.00 ($8.00) would
consider either a regular price of $4.00 – 25% = $3.00 or a discounted price of $3.00 – 20% =
$2.40. In contrast, if this participant belonged to the certain non-buyers group, he or she
received either a regular price of $8.00 + 25% = $10.00 or a discounted price of $10.00 – 20%
= $8.00. Lastly, if this participant belonged to the uncertain group, then he or she considered a
regular price of ($4.00 + $8.00)/2 = $6.00 or a discounted price of $6.00 – 20% = $4.80.
The response options for the choice dependent variable were none, Tide, or Ultra Purex. This
single-unit choice among several brands and no choice reflected the in-store perspective of a
retailer. It also provided choice values of interest for retailers (total choice, whether Tide or
Ultra Purex), as well as for each brand manufacturer. For this case, we assume the retailer
equally benefits from each bottle of detergent sold, irrespective of the brand.
To complement our data collection, we used the controls from the previous studies (category
knowledge, category involvement, shown before the stimulus), demographic information, and
manipulation checks (deal attractiveness for both brands), measured on seven-point Likert
scales. We also asked for participants’ guesses about the study’s purpose.
5.3.3.2 Procedure
We recruited 1,568 respondents via Amazon Mechanical Turk, restricted to U.S. residents.
Each respondent received a reward between $.30 and $.82. The actual survey was again
hosted on another survey platform and required the transfer of a unique code back to
Mechanical Turk. The average survey duration was approximately six minutes. To increase
attention and time to think, we disabled the continue button for several seconds, equal to a
reading speed of 250 words per minute (Kapelner & Chandler 2010). The resulting minimum
time to complete the survey was 3:20 minutes. We excluded all respondents who guessed that
the usual price for a liquid detergent in a store would be either $0 or more than $100. For this
26
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
study, three fail-check items helped us ensure attentive reading. The first asked respondents to
check the third box from the left, the second asked them to state the number 0.12 to receive a
$.12 bonus, and the third asked whether the study was about cars. With these checks, 412
respondents (26.3%) were eliminated, which left 1,156 data sets for the analysis.
5.3.3.3 Results
A MANOVA (Pillai’s Traces p > .25) on age, gender, income, education, pre-stimulus
knowledge about the detergent category, attitude toward the detergent category, and category
involvement showed no significant difference across experimental groups, though few of the
parameters were significant (all ps > .04)—as should be expected with 36 experimental
groups. There was no or only a marginal effect on the balance of samples by random
assignment or fail-check based elimination. None of the respondents guessed the study’s
purpose correctly.
The manipulation check for the deal attractiveness items was successful (Mregular, Tide = 4.52,
Mdiscounted, Tide = 5.29; F(1, 1154) = 48.22; p < .001; Mregular, Purex = 4.36, Mdiscounted, Purex = 5.04;
F(1, 1154) = 37.10; p < .001); the price promotion stimuli worked in the intended direction.
The choice behavior with respect to Tide and/or Purex for each consumer group, divided by
the stimulus, is displayed in Appendix A (section 5.5).
Figure 5.3 reveals the resulting differences in total choice (Tide or Purex) for each
manipulated consumer group, as well as between each manipulated promotion group (Tide
promotion, Purex promotion, or both) and the control group.
Pairwise t-tests of the differences in choice rates reveal significant differences, mainly for the
uncertain groups (Tide or Purex). Thus, our central proposition is valid in a setting in which
consumers must choose between competing brands.
27
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
Figure 5.3: Retailer Gains in Choice Rate by Consumer Group
For a comparison with extant practices in retail targeting, we assume that increasing choice
rates is the retailer’s goal. Therefore, for both our targeting approach and some benchmark
approaches, we calculated the relative increase in choice rate per targeted person. This
indicator represented the choice rate for the targeted groups after the promotion, minus the
choice rate of the same groups without promotion, divided by the choice rate of the groups
without promotion. We calculated these values for the Tide and Purex promotions separately,
as well as for a joint promotion of both brands. The compared targeting approaches were:
28
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
(1) “Target the uncertain”: Only the uncertain consumer is targeted, either exclusively
for Tide or Purex, or simultaneously for both.
(2) Loyalty targeting: All consumers who at some point in time could repurchase a
brand (i.e., consumers with a purchase history of that brand) are targeted. In our
model, these are all uncertain buyers and all certain buyers.
(3) Competitive targeting: One brand is promoted to loyal customers of the
competitor’s brand.
(4) Loyalty and competitive targeting: This combination approach features loyalty
targeting to focal brand customers and competitive targeting to competitive brands
customers.
(5) Market-level targeting: All consumer groups are targeted identically.
Table 5.4 shows the targeted groups (colored boxes indicate targeted segments; white boxes
indicate untargeted ones), along with the respective relative choice rate increase for each
targeted person. The proportion of colored boxes is lowest for our proposed targeting
approach (first line); that is, this approach generates the lowest level of effort for the retailer,
which can target relatively few consumers.
In this sense, our approach is superior when it comes to the retailer’s inputs; it also generates
the highest relative increase in choice rate per targeted person. Thus, targeting uncertain
consumers, identified by their WTP ranges, is a more efficient approach than widely
employed benchmark practices. Market-level targeting generates the second highest relative
increase in choice rates. This result highlights the importance of targeting the right groups or,
if that is impossible, targeting all groups in the same way, in line with extant empirical studies
(Zhang & Wedel 2009). In contrast, competitive targeting achieves poor performance in our
results, which is not necessarily a contradiction with extant studies that have investigated the
effectiveness of competitive targeting from a manufacturer’s perspective. High gains for a
manufacturer likely cause losses for its competitors, but the retailer’s focus is the joint gain
achieved across a number of potentially competing brands.
29
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
Table 5.4: Comparison of Retail Targeting Approaches
RELATIVE INCREASE IN TOTAL CHOICE RATE PER PERSON BY TARGETING APPROACH
Approach
Promotion Tide
cnb_T
“Target the
uncertain”
Targeted groups
(red: Tide promotion,
blue Purex promotion)
uc_P
cb_P
cb_P
cb_P
+10.14%
Δ total choice rate
per targeted person
(in %)
cnb_T
uc_T
cb_T
cnb_T
cnb_P
uc_P
uc_P
uc_P
cb_P
cb_P
cb_P
+6.52%
uc_T
+2.95%
cb_T
cnb_T
uc_T
cb_T
cnb_T
cnb_P
cnb_P
uc_P
uc_P
uc_P
cb_P
cb_P
cb_P
–.32%
uc_T
+2.82%
cb_T
cnb_T
uc_T
cb_T
cnb_T
cnb_P
cnb_P
uc_P
uc_P
uc_P
cb_P
cb_P
cb_P
uc_T
+3.49%
cb_T
cnb_T
uc_T
cb_T
cnb_T
cnb_P
cnb_P
uc_P
uc_P
uc_P
cb_P
cb_P
cb_P
+9.28%
cb_T
uc_T
cb_T
uc_T
cb_T
+3.73%
cnb_P
+7.18%
uc_T
+.80%
cnb_P
+3.70%
cb_T
+6.16%
cnb_P
cnb_T
Market level
cb_T
uc_T
+9.79%
cnb_P
Δ total choice rate
per targeted person
(in %)
Targeted groups
(red: Tide promotion,
blue Purex promotion)
uc_T
+10.08%
cnb_P
cnb_T
Targeted groups
(red: Tide promotion,
blue Purex promotion)
cnb_T
cnb_P
Δ total choice rate
per targeted person
(in %)
Loyalty and
competitive
targeting
Promotion both
cb_T
uc_P
cnb_T
Competitive
targeting
uc_T
cnb_P
Δ total choice rate
per targeted person
(in %)
Targeted groups
(red: Tide promotion,
blue Purex promotion)
cnb_T
uc_P
cnb_T
Loyalty
targeting
Promotion Purex
cb_T
cnb_P
Δ total choice rate
per targeted person
(in %)
Targeted groups
(red: Tide promotion,
blue Purex promotion)
uc_T
uc_T
cb_T
+6.57%
Notes: cnb_T = “certain non-buyer for Tide”, uc_T = “uncertain buyer for Tide”, cb_T = “certain buyer for
Tide”, cnb_P = “certain non-buyer for Purex”, uc_P = “uncertain buyer for Purex”, cb_P = “certain buyer for
Purex”; Total choice rate = Tide choice rate + Purex choice rate; Δ total choice rate per targeted person = (total
choice ratepromotion, targeted – total choice rateno promotion, targeted)/ total choice rate no promotion, targeted.
30
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
5.4 General Discussion
5.4.1 Key findings and implications
Recent developments in WTP conceptualization and measurement have encouraged us to
introduce a new targeting approach for retailers. This approach classifies consumers into three
categories, depending on whether they would certainly buy, certainly not buy, or express
uncertainty about buying a particular product at a given price. With an analytic demonstration
and across three empirical studies, we substantiate the claim that our targeting approach can
benefit retailers: Compared with predominant practices (e.g., targeting loyal consumers or
consumers of competing brands), our method demands relatively little effort, by targeting
only uncertain consumers, but achieves a relatively great effect in terms of choice behavior
changes.
The result holds across different product categories (FMCGs and high-involvement electronic
devices), varied marketing mix activities, different market settings (monopolistic or
competitive), and different ways to identify consumer groups (WTP ranges, direct elicitation).
We are thus confident in the generalizability of our results.
One of our empirical studies suggested that price promotions and positive word of mouth are
particularly beneficial for the retailer. Between 30% and 40% of uncertain consumers adapted
their choice behavior (from non-purchase to purchase) for a promoted brand. Decreased WTP
ranges accounted for these effects, which indicates the usefulness of range-based WTP,
compared with traditional point-based perspectives on WTP.
Beyond these practical benefits, our study contributes to theoretical discussions about
appropriate targeting strategies. Rather than focusing on loyal customers (mostly certain
buyers), we reveal that focusing on the uncertain group can leverage purchase decisions to a
much greater extent. This result might explain why existing empirical research has been
inconclusive regarding the benefits of individual targeting. That is, the insignificant effects of
marketing activities on sales might reflect the input of certain buyers or non-buyers who,
according to our demonstration, are immune to such activities when it comes to their adapted
choice behavior.
31
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
5.4.2 Limitations and further research
We also acknowledge some limitations that additional studies could address to make further
progress in this field of inquiry. First, it would be helpful to have effective methods to identify
uncertain consumers. Ongoing research should pursue new ideas about how to use individuallevel purchase history data to measure purchase uncertainty. Irregular purchase behavior
toward a specific brand or contradictory purchase decisions at various retail prices could be
meaningful indicators of uncertainty.
Second, follow-up studies could explore in more detail how marketing mix activities should
be planned. For example, our research has shown that it is preferable to decrease consumers’
WTP ranges and leverage their WTP levels. Although the information and positive word of
mouth stimuli in Study 2 worked in these directions, only one of the effects was significant in
each case. Thus, we need more information about how to design marketing mix activities to
enhance the effectiveness of our targeting approach.
Third, further research should investigate the long-term effects of our targeting approach for
retailers. The competitive setting in Study 3 noted brand-switching effects, which
approximated the retailer’s interest (i.e., store-level instead brand-level). However, our
analysis was static, and it would be interesting to analyze the effect of targeting activities over
time. If a retailer regularly engages in price promotions for one brand in a specific category,
do these promotions lead to considerably fewer purchases of high-priced brands in that
category? What are the long-term effects on the retailer’s price image, or on the images of the
brands it sells? How permanent are the effects on targeted customers’ WTP values and
ranges? How should a retailer combine different marketing mix activities (e.g., enhanced instore visibility together with price promotions) to reduce the risk of long-term negative effects
of price discounts? Similar to our preceding discussion, we suggest that purchase history data
could provide a useful basis for answering these pertinent questions.
32
5 On the Edge of Buying: A Targeting Approach Based on Consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay Ranges
5.5 Appendix A: Results of Study 3
Table 5.5: Choice Rate Means and Comparisons of Study 3
CHOICE EFFECTS OF PRICE PROMOTION BY CONSUMER GROUP
Group
Samp
Promotion manipulation
Choice rate Tide
Choice rate Purex
Choice rate Total
manipulation
le
Tide Purex
Tide
Purex
N
Mean SE Δ
T
p
Mean SE Δ
T
p
Mean SE Δ
T
p
.09 .28
.09 .28
.17 .38
Regular Regular price 46
Certain
price Discount price 27
.04 .19 -.05 .808 .422
.15 .36 .06 .800 .426
.19 .40 .01 .120 .905
nonRegular price 29
.07 .26 -.02 .276 .783
.00 .00 -.09 1.640 .105
.07 .26 -.10 1.299 .198
Discount
buyers
price Discount price 38
.16 .37 .07 .993 .324
.08 .27 -.01 .131 .896
.24 .43 .06 .708 .481
.07 .26
.68 .48
.75 .44
Regular Regular price 28
Certain Unprice Discount price 36
.06 .23 -.02 .256 .799
.86 .35 .18 1.768 .082
.92 .28 .17 1.841 .070
non- certain
Regular price 31
.23 .43 .15 1.657 .103
.48 .51 -.19 1.515 .135
.71 .46 -.04 .342 .733
Discount
buyers buyers
price Discount price 28
.21 .42 .14 1.532 .131
.57 .50 -.11 .818 .417
.79 .42 .04 .311 .757
.07 .26
.86 .35
.93 .26
Regular Regular price 29
price Discount price 43
.07 .26 .00 .013 .990
.81 .39 -.05 .531 .597
.88 .32 -.05 .657 .513
Certain
buyers Discount Regular price 41
.15 .36 .08 .995 .323
.76 .43 -.11 1.085 .282
.90 .30 -.03 .415 .679
price Discount price 26
.19 .40 .12 1.369 .177
.65 .49 -.21 1.837 .072
.85 .37 -.08 .999 .322
.58 .50
.08 .27
.65 .49
Regular Regular price 26
Certain
price Discount price 28
.71 .46 .14 1.047 .300
.07 .26 -.01 .076 .940
.79 .42 .13 1.072 .288
nonRegular price 24
.88 .34 .30 2.436 .019
.00 .00 -.08 1.386 .172
.88 .34 .22 1.856 .070
buyers Discount
price Discount price 31
.84 .37 .26 2.249 .029
.03 .18 -.04 .743 .461
.87 .34 .22 1.978 .053
.60 .50
.26 .44
.86 .36
Regular Regular price 35
UnUnprice Discount price 31
.32 .48 -.28 2.310 .024
.65 .49 .39 3.390 .001
.97 .18 .11 1.565 .122
certain certain
Regular price 35
.89 .32 .29 2.852 .006
.06 .24 -.20 2.357 .021
.94 .24 .09 1.190 .238
buyers buyers Discount
price Discount price 25
.48 .51 -.12 .912 .365
.48 .51 .22 1.803 .077
.96 .20 .10 1.306 .197
.38 .49
.59 .50
.97 .16
Regular Regular price 39
price Discount price 32
.03 .18 -.35 3.853 .000
.91 .30 .32 3.162 .002
.94 .25 -.04 .760 .450
Certain
buyers Discount Regular price 35
.43 .50 .04 .380 .705
.54 .51 -.05 .401 .689
.97 .17 .00 .077 .939
price Discount price 29
.14 .35 -.25 2.295 .025
.86 .35 .27 2.514 .014 1.00 .00 .03 .861 .393
.88 .33
.04 .20
.92 .28
Regular Regular price 25
Certain
price Discount price 41
.88 .33 .00 .023 .982
.02 .16 -.02 .354 .725
.90 .30 -.02 .237 .813
nonRegular price 36
.97 .17 .09 1.432 .158
.03 .17 -.01 .259 .796 1.00 .00 .08 1.740 .087
buyers Discount
price Discount price 50
.94 .24 .06 .896 .373
.02 .14 -.02 .501 .618
.96 .20 .04 .720 .474
.86 .35
.05 .21
.91 .29
Regular Regular price 44
Unprice Discount price 27
.74 .45 -.12 1.297 .199
.19 .40 .14 1.941 .056
.93 .27 .02 .244 .808
Certain
certain
buyers
Regular price 32
1.00 .00 .14 2.218 .030
.00 .00 -.05 1.218 .227 1.00 .00 .09 1.765 .082
buyers Discount
price Discount price 28
.82 .39 -.04 .479 .633
.11 .31 .06 .997 .322
.93 .26 .02 .288 .774
.74 .45
.26 .45
1.00 .00
Regular Regular price 27
price Discount price 24
.38 .49 -.37 2.776 .008
.63 .49 .37 2.776 .008 1.00 .00 .00 .000 1.00
Certain
buyers Discount Regular price 22
.77 .43 .03 .254 .801
.09 .29 -.17 1.518 .136
.86 .35 -.14 2.022 .049
price Discount price 28
.71 .46 -.03 .216 .830
.21 .42 -.04 .386 .701
.93 .26 -.07 1.415 .163
33
6 Verhaltensorientierter Ansatz zur Erklärung von Preisreaktionen bei Commodities
6 Verhaltensorientierter Ansatz zur Erklärung
von Preisreaktionen bei Commodities
und Empfehlungen für die Preissetzung auf
Commodity-Märkten
Manuscript No. 3
This
manuscript
is
published
as:
Dost,
Florian
&
Wilken,
Robert
(2011).
Verhaltensorientierter Ansatz zur Erklärung von Preisreaktionen bei Commodities und
Empfehlungen für die Preissetzung auf Commodity-Märkten. In: Enke, M. & Geigenmüller,
A. (eds.). Commodity Marketing (2nd ed.). Wiesbaden: Gabler, 2011.
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-8349-6388-8_6
34
III. Conclusion
35
7 Overview of Results
7 Overview of Results
Each of the preceding chapters presents a distinct discussion of the key results, limitations,
and further research directions, though without reference to the overarching framework. That
reference is the focus of the remaining chapters. In particular, Figure 7.1 offers an overview
of the most relevant findings.
Figure 7.1: Overview of findings in the manuscripts
Without repeating the detailed results and findings from the individual manuscripts, it is
obvious that empirical results are missing in one specific area in the framework: antecedents
of WTP ranges and the modes of their construction. The WTP-as-a-range concept relies on
two important assumptions that demand empirical validation. First, though rationally
bounded, consumers will have to undertake at least some cognitive efforts to rationalize
decision making, such as retrieval of past experiences or weighing the benefits against the
36
7 Overview of Results
cost, to exhibit choice behavior that reflects WTP as a range. Chapter 6 presents support for
this premise, in that it conceptualizes choice as especially driven by a cognitive mode of
decision making at prices in the WTP range, yet it does not offer an empirical validation.
Second, the WTP-as-a-range concept relies on the assumption that uncertainty is a main
driver of WTP ranges. However, extant results have been inconclusive (Wang, Venkatesh, &
Chatterjee 2007). Thus, to synthesize a more complete and valid collection of findings, I
subject these two questions to empirical investigation.
37
8 Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3
8 Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3
8.1 The Link of WTP Ranges and Cognitive Effort in PriceRelated Choice
Chapter 6 (Verhaltensorientierter Ansatz zur Erklärung von Preisreaktionen bei Commodities)
suggested that of the two modes of processing, a cognitive processing mode is more
prominent for prices within WTP range, because it is more difficult for respondents to choose
at a price within their respective WTP range, where they cannot know with certainty whether
their WTP is truly higher than the posted price. Thus, respondents try to reduce the
uncertainty by intensive thought, or cognitive activity. In contrast, for prices lower or higher
than the floor and ceiling prices, people likely engage in rapid, experience-driven heuristic
choice behavior (Epstein 1991; Gigerenzer 2007)—the “no brainer” of choice described by
Wathieu and Bertini (2007). Thus the range defines the prices at which consumers engage in
additional thought about the exact benefits of the product, which may cause them to
reconsider their initial hunches about a current choice (Wathieu & Bertini 2007; Park,
McLachlan & Love 2011).
8.2 Study Design
The purpose of this study was to test empirically the propositions of slow, cognitively
demanding choice behavior for prices within the WTP range in contrast to a fast, cognitively
non-demanding choice behavior for prices lower or higher than the WTP range. To ensure
that the decision process is not driven by individual preference levels (i.e., levels of the WTP)
or the actual distribution of individual WTP ranges around price in a consumer group, it is
necessary to manipulate the relation of price and WTP range randomly at the individual level.
Thus in an experimental approach, respondents were assigned randomly to one of nine
experimental groups, each of which described a specific relationship between individual WTP
ranges and the price used in the decision. The groups received prices that were 50%, 30%, or
10% lower than floor reservation price; 10%, 30%, or 50% higher than ceiling reservation
price; or at the 25%, 50%, or 75% quartile of the range between floor and ceiling reservation
prices. For example, a respondent with a floor reservation price (FP) of 5 EUR and a ceiling
38
8 Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3
price (CP) of 10 EUR was assigned to one of the following prices: 2.5 EUR (FP – 50%), 3.5
EUR (FP – 30%), 4.5 EUR (FP – 10%), 11 EUR (CP + 10%), 13 EUR (CP + 30%), 15 EUR
(CP + 50%), 6.25 EUR (25% quartile), 7.5 EUR (50% quartile), or 8.75 EUR (75% quartile).
The stimulus product and control variable scales were similar to the study in section 5.3.3 (the
Tide liquid detergent offer).
After asking participants to provide their floor and ceiling reference prices, the study
procedure assigned them to one of the nine experimental groups. To distract respondents from
their posted reservation prices, most control variable scales appeared before the choice
options. The choice of the manipulated price followed on a single page; the time respondents
took to continue to the next survey page served as an objective measure of cognitive
engagement. The choice task was followed by a three-item measure of subjective cognitive
difficulty, using seven-point Likert scales. Demographic information and suspicions about the
study’s purpose were collected at the end of the survey.
8.3 Procedure
The procedure was similar to the studies in Chapter 5. That is, 297 U.S. residents were
recruited through Amazon Mechanical Turk. Each respondent received a payment between
$.20 and $.25. Respondents who spent less than 1:30 minutes on the survey or failed at either
of the three fail-check items (see section 5.3.3) were excluded. Altogether, 87 respondents
(29.3%) had to be eliminated, which left 210 data sets for the analysis.
8.4 Results
A multivariate analysis of variance (MANOVA; Pillai’s Trace p = .767 for the model; ps
>.255 for the model parameters) using age, gender, income, education, pre-stimulus
knowledge about the detergent category, attitude toward the detergent category, category
involvement, floor prices, and ceiling prices showed no significant differences across nine
experimental groups. This finding indicates no effect on the balance of the samples by
random assignment or fail-check–based elimination. None of the participants was able to
guess the actual purpose of the study.
The resulting choice rates, perceived cognitive effort, and time spent on the choice are
depicted in Figure 8.1.
39
8 Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3
Figure 8.1: Results of extension study
At face value, Figure 8.1 confirms the prediction of higher cognitive efforts for prices within
the range. However, group sample sizes per single price were small. Thus, for statistical
testing, averages over three prices were used, adapting the group classification from Chapter
5. The mean values of the three groups (certain non-buyer, uncertain buyer, and certain buyer)
were then calculated and compared. Pairwise t-tests of the differences in perceived cognitive
effort showed that perceived cognitive effort was higher at prices within the WTP range
(Mcog_eff.uncertain = 3.01, SE = 1.31) than at prices below the floor reservation price (Mcog_eff.nonbuye r=
2.13, SE = 1.06; T=4.505, p < 0.001) or above the ceiling reservation price (Mcog_eff.buyer
40
8 Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3
= 2.00, SE = 1.04; T = 4.938, p < 0.001). These results support the proposition: Cognitive
effort for choices at prices within the WTP range is higher than outside WTP range.
Furthermore, the time spent on the survey page for the choice task was longer for prices
within WTP range (Mtime.uncertain = 20.67 sec, SE = 15.19 sec) that for prices higher than the
ceiling reservation price (Mtime.nonbuyers=13.81 sec, SE = 6.51 sec; T = 3.346, p < 0.001) and
for prices below the floor reservation price, though not significantly (Mtime.buyers = 17.80 sec,
SE = 12.44 sec; T = 1.250, p = .213). The time to read the choice task information is included
as a “baseline” time in the measure, which may level out some variance caused by different
processing modes. The correlation (Pearson) was significant, at r = .178 (p <.01), in support
of the proposition of cognitively demanding, slow processing when prices fall within the
WTP range, in contrast with cognitively undemanding, rapid processing for other prices.
8.5 Discussion
These results offer empirical support for a link between WTP range and cognitive efforts by
consumers to reduce their uncertainty. Cognitive effort and perceived cognitive effort are
higher for prices within the WTP range than for prices outside it. Both results may point to the
presence of different modes of choice processing: a fast decision mode with little cognitive
effort, applicable to “certain” decisions (buy or not buy) and a slow decision mode with great
cognitive effort, applicable to “uncertain” decisions at prices within the WTP range. These
results support the propositions discussed in manuscript 3 (Chapter 6). Furthermore, they
extend findings from manuscript 2 (Chapter 5), namely, that targeting should focus on the
uncertain consumer group. Because the segment of the uncertain buyers is not only more
reactive to marketing mix activities (see manuscript 2), but also more inclined to use
cognitive processing, and thus rationalized choice (Bettman, Luce, & Payne 1998), targeted
marketing mix activities should draw on the cognitive dimension by offering cognitively
persuasive arguments.
These results have implications for extant and further research as well. First, in light of the
results in Chapter 4 (“Measuring Willingness to Pay as a Range, Revisited: When Should We
Care?”), that traditional point-based WTP refers to the midpoint of WTP ranges, it is likely
that the range of thought-provoking prices promoted by Watthieu and Bertini (2007) extends
not beyond WTP, as stated by the authors, but rather around it. Second, a potential link
between a dual process of choice and individual WTP might provide a means to measure
41
8 Empirical Extension to Manuscript No. 3
WTP ranges indirectly, according to levels of cognitive engagement in evaluating a price.
Such measures would be less prone to strategic bias. Although this study provides an
indication of links among WTP range, price, cognitive effort, and time spent on the choice as
an easy-to-use measure, this issue deserves more substantive inquiry, which in turn suggests a
fruitful route for research. Third, the theoretical considerations draw heavily on behavior that
is determined by past experiences or present stimuli, so a dual process model might be useful
to combine the behavioral, experience, and stimulus-related aspects of choice with the
(boundedly) rational aspects of choice. The merits of research in this direction ultimately
might lie in unifying extant works in a single framework for price-related decision making.
42
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among WTP, Range, and Uncertainty
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among
WTP, Range, and Uncertainty
9.1 Introduction
Although many of the original results and propositions of Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterjee
(2007) received support and extension during the course of this thesis and its related studies,
one of the most central, underlying assumptions they offer has not been addressed: Wang and
colleagues assume that individual WTP ranges are driven by individual levels of uncertainty.
Yet their empirical results are inconclusive. The authors even admit:
“Although we were able to demonstrate the existence of a positive, significant
relationship between a consumer’s reservation price range and associate levels of
uncertainty in the chocolate study, our results were inconclusive for the wine study
(probably because of a smaller sample and possibly greater measurement error due to
the survey-based elicitation). We acknowledge this limitation and encourage
additional investigation of the link.” (Wang, Venkatesh, & Chatterjee 2007, p. 211).
Because the theoretical considerations of this thesis also rely on this assumption, an additional
empirical investigation of the proposed relationship between uncertainty levels and range
levels seems necessary. However, no empirical studies focused on substantiating this link,
even as they featured covariates related to uncertainty—mostly to test the balance of the
subsamples for unwanted side effects. The covariates included knowledge, involvement,
experience, and also some certainty scales, all of which can reasonably be assumed to
correlate with consumer uncertainty. Therefore, to present more conclusive results about the
uncertainty–ranges link, a secondary analysis of all empirical subsamples seems appropriate.
Beyond the mere integration of empirical correlations between pseudo-uncertainty scales and
range levels, this secondary analysis also should account for two potentially confounding
relationships that Wang and colleagues ignore. First, range levels are based on the same
measures as WTP levels, namely, measured reservation prices. A strong correlation between
WTP and range levels is likely, because consumers tend to evaluate differences in price levels
in relative rather than absolute terms (Janiszewski & Liechtenstein 1999; Kahnemann &
Tversky 1979). For example, a range level of Range = 2.00 EUR at a WTP level of WTP =
4.00 EUR (ratio = .5) might be perceived as just as uncertain as a range level of Range = 3.00
43
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among WTP, Range, and Uncertainty
EUR at a WTP level of WTP = 6.00 EUR (again, ratio = .5). Second, the level of uncertainty
might influence WTP levels themselves, in that an existing level of uncertainty might lead to
perceptions of risk and thus shift the WTP downward for risk-averse consumers (e.g., Park,
McLachlan, & Love 2011). Such a multi-collinear relationship between WTP and uncertainty,
in relation to range levels might confound the results presented by Wang and colleagues
(2007) and in the chapters enclosed in this thesis. The latter collinear relationship needs to be
ruled out.
9.2 Study Design
This test used the existing subsamples from the previous studies to perform the regression
analyses and integration of beta and correlation coefficients. To keep the induced variance to
a minimum, each experimental stimulus or elicitation method group constituted a separate
subsample, as Table 9.1 displays, along with their various (pseudo)certainty scales. The three
variables of interest in each subsample are:
(1) WTP levels, calculated as the midpoint between floor and ceiling reservation prices;
(2) Pseudo-certainty levels, calculated as the average of all pseudo-certainty scales used in
the respective subsample. The directions of the scale levels are labeled and interpreted
as “certainty” levels instead of uncertainty levels, because of the direction of the scales
used. For example, knowledge positively correlates with certainty, not uncertainty.
Uncertainty also is multidimensional (Wang, Venkatesh, & Chatterjee 2007), so index
building by average should cover the highest possible degree of uncertainty reflected
in the various pseudo-certainty scales; and
(3) WTP ranges as dependent variables for the regression analyses, calculated as the
difference between ceiling and floor reservation prices.
The comparable nature of the range measures as dependent variables makes this selection of
subsamples appropriate for an inter-study comparison. Large differences in scales for the
independent certainty variable will add to the generalizability of the subsequent results.
44
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among WTP, Range, and Uncertainty
9.3 Results
Expected WTP and certainty served as the independent variables in a series of ordinary least
squares (OLS) regressions on WTP ranges. Standardized beta coefficients and their levels of
significance were calculated for the two independent variables in each regression model. All
resulting levels of adjusted R-square, standardized beta coefficients, p-values of the respective
two-sided t-tests, variance inflation factors, and correlations coefficients are reported in Table
9.1.
The number of significant coefficients of the same direction was then used to provide a
simple vote-count integration over subsamples (Bushman 1994). Vote counting showed that
WTP is positively and significantly (p < .05) related to the range in 20 of 21 cases, with an
average beta coefficient of +.48. The only subsample without such a strong relationship is the
ICERANGE subsample of study 1 in the first manuscript (see Chapter 4), which also was the
only regression that failed to provide a significant model fit (F = 1.776, p = .181). Altogether
these results provide strong evidence of a positive relationship between expected WTP levels
and WTP range levels. Certainty variables linked significantly and negatively to WTP range
in 12 of 19 regression models. The average coefficient was βcertainty.mean = –.17, which offers a
good indication of the existence of a theoretical relationship between uncertainty and range.
Furthermore, just one coefficient in the 19 regression models showed a non-negative sign.
Considering the importance of the relationship between uncertainty and WTP range for the
theoretic foundations of WTP as a range, further tests should corroborate this finding.
Following Shadish and Haddock’s (1994) procedure to integrate and test effect sizes from
correlation coefficients, a weighted mean correlation between certainty and ranges and a
weighted variance were calculated using respective subsample sizes as weighting factors. The
weighted mean correlation was rmean.weighted = –.1557, whereas the weighted variance was
s2weighted = .0003. The resulting Z-statistic (Eisend 2004) was Z= r/s = –8.821, indicating a
significant negative correlation. This result ultimately supports the claim that range levels are
negatively driven by levels of consumer certainty. Finally, the reported variance inflation
factors show no sign of multi-collinearity (VIF < 1.05, well below commonly used thresholds
of 4 or 10; O’Brian 2007). Uncertainty levels are not driving WTP levels, in addition to WTP
ranges.
45
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among WTP, Range, and Uncertainty
Table 9.1: Secondary analysis regression results
Dependent variable: WTP range
No.
Sub-sample
Thesis
section
N
WTP
Adj.
R2
β
p
Certainty measures
VIF
(pseudo-) certainty Items
β
p
r
.768
1
Manuscript 1, study 1,
ICERANGE
46
.03
.26
.084
Product knowledge, product usage, product
.04
expertise
.06
1.037
2
Manuscript 1, study 1,
BDM-Range
56
.16
.43
.001
Product knowledge, product usage, product
-.22 .085 -.14
expertise
1.049
3
Manuscript 1, study 2,
ICERANGE
40
.14
.40
.01
Product knowledge, product usage
-.17 .248 -.15
1.003
4
Manuscript 1, study 2,
BDM-Range
40
.27
.37
.012
Product knowledge, product usage
-.36 .016 -.36
1.000
5
Manuscript 1, study 3,
ICERANGE
44
.18
.45
.002
None
none none none
1
6
Manuscript 1, study 3,
BDM-Range
44
.44
.67 <.001
None
none none none
1
7
Manuscript 2, study 1,
control group
88
.16
.42 <.001
Category knowledge, category
involvement, purchase experience
-.10 .339 -.05
1.010
8
Manuscript 2, study 1,
price promotion
80
.16
.29
Category knowledge, category
involvement, purchase experience
-.32 .003 -.32
1.000
9
Manuscript 2, study 2,
control group
105
.32
.54 <.001
Preference certainty, price certainty, brand
choice certainty,
-.25 .002 -.20
product benefit certainty
1.008
10
Manuscript 2, study 2,
price promotion
115
.23
.49 <.001
Preference certainty, price certainty, brand
choice certainty,
-.12 .147 -.07
product benefit certainty
1.012
11
Manuscript 2, study 2,
information
104
.27
.50 <.001
Preference certainty, price certainty, brand
choice certainty,
-.13 .141 -.19
product benefit certainty
1.016
12
Manuscript 2, study 2,
visual
111
.30
.50 <.001
Preference certainty, price certainty, brand
choice certainty,
-.22 .006 -.26
product benefit certainty
1.005
13
Manuscript 2, study 2,
PWOM
112
.13
.38 <.001
Preference certainty, price certainty, brand
choice certainty,
-.01 .886
product benefit certainty
.04
1.019
14
Manuscript 2, study 3,
control; Tide
299a
.34
.57 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.24 <.001 -.17
1.015
15
Manuscript 2, study 3,
control; Purex
299a
.18
.36 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.24 <.001 -.24
1.000
16
Manuscript 2, study 3,
Tide promotion; Tide
285b
.37
.60 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.22 <.001 -.14
1.019
17
Manuscript 2, study 3,
Tide promotion; Purex
285b
.44
.64 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.19 <.001 -.16
1.002
18
Manuscript 2, study 3,
Purex promotion; Tide
289c
.36
.60 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.15 .002 -.10
1.007
19
Manuscript 2, study 3,
Purex prom.; Purex
289c
.24
.47 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.15 .004 -.15
1.000
20
Manuscript 2, study 3,
Both promotions; Tide
283d
.41
.62 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.14 .002 -.16
1.001
21
Manuscript 2, study 3,
Both promotions; Purex
283d
.38
.60 <.001
Price knowledge, category knowledge,
category involvement
-.13 .007 -.16
1.003
.006
Mean: .48
Mean: -.17
a,b,c,d
Notes:
same set of respondents. N = subsample size; β = standardized regression coefficient; p = p-value
(two sided t-test); r = Pearson correlation; VIF = variance inflation factor.
46
9 Secondary Analysis of the Interplay Among WTP, Range, and Uncertainty
9.4 Discussion
This secondary analysis established three results. First, the levels of WTP range are driven by
levels of uncertainty, as theorized by Wang and colleagues (2007). Second, levels of expected
WTP are not driven by uncertainty, which indicates that consumer uncertainty exclusively
drives the ranges. Third, WTP levels strongly drive WTP ranges. All these results have
implications for further research. Although an impact of consumer uncertainty on WTP
ranges can be assumed, the impact size is relatively small, which calls for additional inquiries
into the antecedents of WTP ranges. A previously unknown antecedent is the level of
expected WTP, a result that is especially important for attempts to model WTP as a range on
an aggregate demand level. The simulation-based approach in this thesis (see the simulation
study in manuscript 1, Chapter 4) conveniently assumes constant levels of range over all
subjects. However, a positive correlation between WTP and WTP ranges might further
increase differences between aggregated demand curves based on point-based WTP and
aggregated demand-curves based on range-based WTP, because the impact of the ranges
grows asymmetrically with higher WTP levels.
47
10 Implications of the Findings
10 Implications of the Findings
10.1 WTP-as-a-Range Model
The major contributions of this thesis to the field of marketing pertain to the model, which
links WTP ranges to behavior and to the underlying organism. The model, based on Wang
and colleagues’ (2007) proposition, asserts that WTP is a range of reservation prices and not a
single point, each with a corresponding choice probability. This thesis presents a modified
and advanced conceptualization, in which a WTP distribution that represents the distribution
of choice probability around a true, yet latent individual WTP can be defined.4 This individual
WTP distribution is specified by an expected value of individual WTP, which corresponds to
the traditional definition of WTP, and a variance of individual WTP, which corresponds to the
WTP range. Individual choice probability is therefore a function of preference (expected
WTP) and uncertainty (WTP range). This novel conceptualization provides a theoretic
foundation to explain how WTP as a range relates to extant point-based WTP literature; it
further explains why traditional point-based WTP elicitation methods measure expected WTP
(see measurement synthesis, Chapter 10.2).
Acknowledging the conceptualization, it becomes apparent why individual-level, price-related
choice behavior at prices that fall within a consumers’ WTP range differ from previously
theorized behavior. Consequently, marketing mix decisions, such as pricing decisions, are
likely to be inferior when made under the traditional point-based model of WTP, because
choice rates assumed by the marketer likely differ from actual choice rates, which prevents
optimality.
Through a simulation, this thesis has demonstrated that such a bias can translate to an
aggregate level of consumer choice, making the conceptualization relevant for demand
estimation, aggregate choice models, and marketing mix activities on a more general level. It
is further revealed that the size of the bias depends on interactions with consumer
heterogeneity in WTP levels. This finding has important consequences, such as for WTP
estimation approaches that rely on choice data: Given that both heterogeneity in aggregate
WTP levels and WTP ranges (i.e., heterogeneity in individual WTP levels) affect aggregate
4
Only recently has the idea of a WTP distribution been confirmed in independent projects that also make a case
for conceptually similar distributions (Park, MacLachlan & Love 2011; Schlereth, Eckert & Skiera 2011).
48
10 Implications of the Findings
choice behavior, any approach that relies on choice data and does not account for both types
of heterogeneity may provide biased estimates of individual ranges or the differences
(heterogeneity) between consumers.
Regarding the antecedents of WTP ranges, a secondary analysis revealed that ranges are
driven by levels of individual uncertainty, remedying the inconclusive evidence provided by
Wang and colleagues (2007). However, an additional and much stronger driver is identified in
the (expected) WTP levels: Ranges are larger for high preference consumers and for higher
priced products. This finding has implications for an understanding of ranges as an indicator
of uncertainty. Specifically, direct comparisons of ranges, without accounting for an identical
level of WTP, seem invalid. Instead, relative ranges provide a more precise indicator of the
level of underlying uncertainty and a basis for comparison. The finding has also implications
for the modeling of aggregate choice behavior: The simulation approach described in Chapter
4 uses constant ranges for the sake of convenience. However, the positive relationship
between WTP and WTP ranges would not only stretch aggregated demand curves, compared
with point-based aggregated WTP data, but also asymmetrically distort the resulting demand
functions. This effect might further increase the differences between actual aggregated
demand curves based on point-based WTP and aggregated demand-curves based on rangebased WTP. Further research should inquire into whether actual aggregated choice data reflect
this result, as well as if the estimation of demand models can be improved by accounting for
it. In a related matter, more research is needed to advance knowledge on the type and shape of
individual WTP distributions. Although a symmetric WTP distribution on the individual level
seems likely, according to the findings of this thesis, actual WTP distributions have not been
investigated empirically, an effort that remains for further research.
In this light, modeling aggregated WTP as a range through simulations seems highly
compelling. For example, agent-based models provide means to implement complex,
individual-level choice models and generate aggregate-level results. These models would be
suitable for implementing various range and WTP antecedents, pre-specified correlations
between WTP levels and range levels, different specifications of WTP distributions, and even
extensions to behavioral price reaction models. Furthermore, such models would be open to
dynamic applications (see Chapter 10.4). Only recently have guidelines for rigor been
developed to foster this new class of models (Rand & Rust 2011). They also may provide
helpful guidance in the pursuit of this particular methodological route.
49
10 Implications of the Findings
Finally, this thesis establishes that WTP ranges are linked to greater cognitive effort, in
support of the claim that a dual process choice model might better reflect consumer choice
processing. One processing mode is fast, relies on heuristics, and requires little cognitive
effort; the other one is slow, requires high cognitive efforts in sequential rational processing,
and seems more applicable to the “uncertain” decisions at prices within WTP range.
Implications for future theoretical developments of this idea are far reaching and provide
many opportunities for follow-up research. Specifically, establishing this finding provides
support for the extension of the WTP as a range conceptualization to the realm of pricerelated consumer behavior. Ultimately, WTP, uncertainty, the range of thought-provoking
prices (Park, McLachlan, & Love 2011; Watthieu & Bertini 2007), and reference price
reaction models (e.g. Helson 1964; Parducci 1965) may be integrated within a single model
that accounts for the different modes of consumer decision making.
10.2 WTP Range Measurement
Consistent with the theoretical findings from the proposed model, this thesis establishes
empirically in several studies that “traditional” point-based methods measure expected WTP
of WTP distributions. This finding is consistent over real purchase and hypothetical settings,
offline and online settings, and quantitative and qualitative modes of inquiry.
The simulation results in the first manuscript (Chapter 4) provide guidelines about when to
use range-based methods in market research, which is not just recommended but mandatory to
avoid a conceptual bias, even in aggregate-level data.
The simplified, lottery-based method, BDM-Range, is simpler by construction and less
restricted in terms of theoretical assumptions regarding the shape of the range than
ICERANGE, the method of Wang and colleagues (2007), or the BDM lottery for point-based
WTP elicitation. It is extensively compared to both other methods. Therefore, further studies
of the shape and type of WTP distribution do not need to adapt the mechanism of BDMRange. However, the method is not fully incentive-aligned, inviting further modifications, as
well as validation with real purchase choice data as a benchmark. Still, the BDM-Range
reaches comparable levels of predictive performance and internal validity and demonstrates
practical applicability at the point of purchase.
The method comparisons were restricted to direct-elicitation, lottery-based approaches. As
range-based elicitation method variants (e.g., variants of conjoint analysis) already exist
50
10 Implications of the Findings
(Schlereth & Skiera 2009; Schlereth, Eckert, & Skiera 2011), it would be interesting to
establish a comparison with methods of indirect elicitation or methods without incentive
alignment, to gain further insights on the recommended methodology. Although the second
manuscript used a non–incentive-aligned direct elicitation of WTP range, it contained no
inquiry into the size or direction of hypothetical and/or strategic bias. Such an undertaking
would be particularly important for practical use, because marketing practitioners typically
refrain from more complex applications of lottery procedures (Hofstetter & Miller 2009).
Theoretically, stating exact floor and ceiling reservation prices might be just as challenging
for respondents as is stating an exact WTP. The underlying argument—that uncertainty about
latent, true WTP prevents a person from knowing with certainty a specific preference level—
also applies to other reservation price points. However, two findings from this thesis support
the use of current range-based methods, despite this obvious theoretical shortcoming. First,
even if the size of the range is not exact, range measured as the difference of two reservation
prices still offers an indicator of variance in the WTP distribution. It thus can be compared
with other, similarly measured indicators of said variance. Further research on the empirical
relationship between “fuzzy” (Wang et al. 2007, p. 211) measures of range and the actual size
of WTP distribution variance may remedy that shortcoming. Second, it was established that
processing mode, specifically cognitive effort, changes inside the WTP range. Behavioral
research shows that humans perceive changes in perceptions as stronger than absolute levels
(Kahnemann & Tversky 1979), so the endpoints of WTP range might be easier to detect by a
respondent than the absolute level of WTP, as required in traditional point-based methods.
The establishment of cognitive effort in ranges opens another possibility, too: Measures of
cognitive effort, such as time spent, or of brain activity might be developed to offer an
indirect measurement approach for WTP ranges. Such an approach would not only be
conceptually free of strategic bias but also might provide more realistic estimates of the exact
WTP distribution.
10.3 WTP Range Management
Positioned in the framework of marketing mix decisions, several findings relate to the
peculiarities of the WTP as a range model with respect to the marketing mix. In particular,
WTP as a range should be adopted in pricing decisions, both at individual and aggregate
levels, to avoid biased pricing. Because both uncertainty and WTP levels drive this effect, the
51
10 Implications of the Findings
use of range-based methods to measure and model consumer choice is even more pressing for
the pricing of innovations. Innovative products are new and thus often unfamiliar to
consumers. Furthermore, price levels tend to be higher, because producers try to “skim” the
market to cover the upfront development cost early in the product life cycle. These higher
price levels are crucial for forming the first expected WTP levels (Park, McLachlan, & Love
2011) and further increasing WTP ranges. Therefore, pricing applications and studies remain
a fruitful avenue for research on WTP as a range.
Also, WTP ranges are profit-relevant, useful measures for the impact of other marketing mix
activities, both in practice and in subsequent research on marketing mix–related topics.
A relevant finding for aggregate-level marketing mix activities is the finding that the
“uncertain” consumers, whose range encompasses a given price, show the strongest reactions
to marketing mix activities in terms of choice behavior. Thus targeting should focus on
uncertain buyers in a given group of consumers. The theoretical delineation for this finding
(see Chapter 5) was based on the original model of Wang, Venkatesh, and Chatterje (2007).
Accordingly, it seems that certain buyer and non-buyer groups should not react to marginal
changes in the three dimensions: price, WTP, and range. However, assuming a differentiable
WTP distribution, as is likely, might result in small reactions to marginal changes in the three
dimensions for the certain buyer and non-buyer groups as well. This idea would be more in
line with the empirical results of the second manuscript. Together with the actual shape of
WTP distribution, a modified, more continuous targeting approach offers a compelling topic
for future investigations.
Marketing mix activities that target uncertain buyers find them in cognitive processing modes.
Thus targeted marketing mix activities should draw on the cognitive dimension by offering
rational, cognitively persuasive arguments. Lower prices as an objective benefit, as well as
convincing and credible information, such as that offered by other users, are examples of
marketing mix activities that theoretically should fare better. Empirical results in Chapter 5
suggest that price promotions and positive word-of-mouth are particularly beneficial for the
retailer. Between 30% and 40% of uncertain consumers adapted their choice behavior (from
non-purchase to purchase) for the promoted brand. However, these results are based on
experiments and hypothetical choice. Further evidence for range-based targeting and effective
in-range marketing mix activities requires the use of real purchase data or transaction choice
experiments.
52
10 Implications of the Findings
Finally, marketing mix activities, such as branding, word of mouth, or informative
advertisements, manipulate uncertainty and WTP ranges. In presenting the range dimension
as relevant for consumer choice, the question arises: Can a marketer actively leverage this
novel dimension? The theoretical findings indicate so. First, WTP range will have a direct
impact on consumer choice. However, this impact of decreasing the range could be either
positive or negative, depending on whether expected WTP is higher or lower than the current
price (see Chapter 5.2.2; For a similar argument, see Schlereth, Eckert, & Skiera, 2011).
Second, WTP range levels interact with changes in both price and expected WTP, such that a
smaller range increases the effect of either dimension. A combination of decreased range and
increased expected WTP should be most effective. The “information” and “positive word-ofmouth” stimuli in the second manuscript (Chapter 5.3.2) worked in these directions, though in
both cases, only one of the two effects was significant. Still, further research on effective
marketing mix activities regarding WTP range, especially on leveraging ranges for
profitability, seems fruitful.
10.4 A Call for Dynamics in WTP as a Range Research
A final suggestion for further research relates to a set of topics beyond the scope of this thesis.
The theoretical considerations of the WTP-as-a-range concept draw heavily on behavior that
is determined by either past experiences (e.g., adaption level or frequency theory; Parducci
1965), situational stimuli (Bettman, Luce, & Payne 1998), or some combination. Yet WTP as
a range thus far has been examined only in a static context. A natural and interesting route
would be to implement dynamic views. Three areas appear particularly interesting.
First, ranges are based on uncertainty, so it is highly unlikely that they remain stable over
time. Experience and learning reduce uncertainty. New pieces of conflicting information
might even increase uncertainty. Consequently, a consumer who decides to try a product or
service for the first time might feature a different expected WTP, and almost certainly a
different range, than the same customer choosing the second time. In a similar manner, WTP
elicitation studies may provide different results at different points in the product lifecycle, not
because the preference levels change, but because residual uncertainty declines as experience
in the market accumulates. Applications of such research appear promising in the area of
dynamic pricing, as well as in major marketing research areas, such as modeling product
adoption.
53
10 Implications of the Findings
Second, the impact of situational factors on the construction of preferences in the course of a
choice remains an ongoing source of insights. Extant approaches have focused on external
reference prices and point-based WTP. However, in light of uncertainty, both the potentially
moderated impact of the situational stimulus and the stimulus impact on uncertainty itself, and
thus on WTP range, provide opportunities for extensive investigation. With respect to
learning, a further opportunity arises in inquiries about the permanence of such effects.
Third, the relation between WTP as a range and consumption over time, such as through
budgeting or saving for large ticket items, has not been investigated. Yet it is an important
route for further research; in reality, demand functions, on both aggregate and individual
consumer levels, likely relate to an underlying, latent time frame: For example, a consumer
who is generally and constantly willing to pay 1 EUR for yoghurt will not necessarily do so
every time he or she is confronted with the opportunity to buy one. Therefore, studying the
relation of WTP as a range to underlying time frames may help explain consumer choice
further. The impacts of uncertainty on budget perception and purchase frequency are closely
related topics for this route of inquiry.
Considering this vast set of opportunities for research, investigating dynamics in willingness
to pay as a range provide but one of the many exciting next steps on the path of exploration
that ultimately might help practitioners and researchers make better marketing mix decisions.
54
References
Adler, J. & MacLachlan, C. (2005). Produktdifferenzierung durch Management der
Kundenwahrnehmung. In: Enke, M., Reimann, M. (Eds.), Commodity Marketing –
Grundlagen und Besonderheiten. Wiesbaden, 199-216.
Ailawadi, K., Beauchamp, J, Donthu, N., Gauri, D., & Shankar, V. (2009). Communication
and Promotion Decisions in Retailing: A Review and Directions for Future Research.
Journal of Retailing, 85 (1), 42-55.
Ailawadi, K., Harlam, B., Cesar, J. & Trounce, D. (2006). Retail Promotion Pass-Through: A
Measure, Its Magnitude, and Its Determinants. Marketing Science, 28 (4), 782-791.
Ajzen, I., & Driver, B. L. (1992). Application of the theory of planned behavior to leisure
choice. Journal of Leisure Research, 24, 207- 224.
Ariely, D., Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2003). ‘Coherent Arbitrariness’: Stable Demand
Curves Without Stable Preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 73–105.
Backhaus, K., Voeth, M., Sichtmann, C., & Wilken, R. (2005a). Conjoint-Analyse versus
Direkte Preisabfrage zur Erhebung von Zahlungsbereitschaften. Die Betriebswirtschaft,
65(5), 439-457.
Backhaus, K., Wilken, R., Voeth, M., & Sichtmann, C. (2005b). An Empirical Comparison of
Methods to Measure Willingness to Pay by Examining the Hypothetical Bias.
International Journal of Market Research, 47(5), 543-562.
Becker, G. M., DeGroot, M. H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring Utility by a SingleResponse Sequential Method. Behavioral Science, 9(3), 226-232.
Bettman, J. R., Luce, M. F., & Payne, J. W. (1998). Constructive Consumer Choice
Processes. Journal of Consumer Research, 25(4), 187-217.
Bettman, J. R., & Park, C. W. (1980). Effects of Prior Knowledge and Experience and Phase
of the Choice Process on Consumer Decision Processes: A Protocol Analysis. Journal
of Consumer Research, 7(Dec), 234-248.
55
Brown, T. C., Champ, P. A., Bishop, R.C., & McCollum, D. W (1996), Which Response
Format Reveals the Truth about Donations to a Public Good. Land Economics, 72(2),
152-166.
Bushman, B. J. (1994). Vote-Counting Procedures in Meta-Analysis. In: Cooper, H. &
Hedges, L.V. (eds.), The Handbook of Research Synthesis. New York. Russel Sage
Foundation. 193-213.
Cameron, T. A., & James, M. D. (1987). Estimating Willingness to Pay from Survey Data:
An Alternative Pre-Test-Market Evaluation Procedure. Journal of Marketing Research,
24(Nov), 389-395.
Cummings, R.G., & Taylor, L.O. (1999). Unbiased Value Estimates for Environmental
Goods: A Cheap Talk Design for the Contingent Valuation Method. American
Economic Review, 89(3), 649–665.
Ding, M. (2007). An Incentive-Aligned Mechanism for Conjoint Analysis. Journal of
Marketing Research, 44(May), 214-223.
Ding, M., Grewal, R., & Liechty, J. (2005). Incentive-Aligned Conjoint Analysis. Journal of
Marketing Research, 42(Feb), 67-82.
Dong, S., Ding, M., & Huber, J. (2010). A Simple Mechanism to Incentive-Align Conjoint
Experiments. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 27(1), 25-32.
Dost, F. & Wilken, R. (2012). Measuring Willingness to Pay as a Range, Revisited: When
Should We Care?. International Journal of Research in Marketing, forthcoming.
Dubourg, R., Jones-Lee, M., & Loomes, G. (1997). Imprecise Preferences and Survey Design
in Contingent Valuation. Economica, 64, 681–702.
Eisend, M. (2004). Metaanalyse – Einführung und kritische Diskussion. Diskussionsbeiträge
des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin, Nr. 2004/8.
Enke, Geigenmüller, & Leischnig (2011). Commodity Marketing – Eine Einführung. In:
Enke, M., Geigenmüller, A. (Eds.), Commodity Marketing – Grundlagen –
Besonderheiten und Erfahrungen, 2. Aufl.. Wiesbaden, 3-13.
56
Epstein, S. (1991). Cognitive-experiential self-theory: An integrative theory of personality. In:
Curtis, R. (Ed.), The relational self: Convergences in psychoanalysis and social
psychology, New York, 111–137.
Feinberg, F., Krishna, A., & Zhang, Z. (2002). Do We Care What Others Get? A Behaviorist
Approach to Targeted Promotions. Journal of Marketing Research, 39 (3), 277-291.
Gigerenzer, G. (2007). Bauchentscheidungen: Die Intelligenz des Unbewussten und die
Macht der Intuition, Goldmann: München.
Gijsbrechts, E. (1993). Prices and Pricing Research in Consumer Marketing: Some Recent
Developments. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 10(2), 115-151.
Godek J. & Murray, K.B. (2008). Willingness to pay for advice: The role of rational and
experiential processing. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,
106(1), S. 77-87.
Gregory, R., Liechtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (1993). Valuing Environmental Recources: A
Constructive Approach. Journal of Risk Uncertainty, 7(2), 177-197.
Grewal, D., Ailawadi, K., Gauri, D., Hall, K., Kopalle, P., & Robertson, J. (2011).
Innovations in Retail Pricing and Promotions. Journal of Retailing, 87S(1), S43-S52.
Grewal, D., & Levy, M. (2007). Retailing Research: Past, Present and Future. Journal of
Retailing, 83 (4), 447-464.
Hanemann, W. M. (1984). Welfare Evaluations in Contingent Valuation Experiments with
Discrete Responses. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66(3), 332-342.
Hauser, J. R., & Urban, G. L. (1986). The Value Priority Hypotheses for Consumer Budget
Plans. Journal of Consumer Research, 12(4), 446-462.
Helson, H. (1964). Adaption-Level Theory. New York: Harper and Row.
Hofstetter, R. & Miller, K.M. (2009). Precision Pricing: Measuring Consumers‘ Willingness
to Pay Accurately. Dissertation, Universität Bern.
57
Homburg, C. & Koschate, N. (2005 a). Behavioral Pricing-Forschung im Überblick – Teil 1.
Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft, 75(4), 383-423.
Homburg, C. & Koschate, N. (2005 b). Behavioral Pricing–Forschung im Überblick – Teil 2.
Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft, 75(5), 501-524.
Homburg, C., Koschate, N., & Hoyer, W.D. (2005). Do Satisfied Customers Really Pay
More? A Study of the Relationship Between Customer Satisfaction and Willingness to
Pay. Journal of Marketing, 69 (April), 84-96.
Inman, J. J., McAlister, L., & Hoyer, W. D. (1990). Promotion Signal: Proxy for a Price Cut?
Journal of Consumer Research, 17(1), 74-81.
Inman, J., Winer, R., & Ferraro, R. (2009). The Interplay among Category Characteristics,
Consumer Characteristics, and Customer Activities on In-Store Decision Making.
Journal of Marketing, 73 (5), 19-29.
Janiszewski, C., & Liechtenstein, D. R. (1999). A Range Theory Account of Price Perception.
Journal of Consumer Research, 25(4), 353-368.
Jedidi, K., Jagpal, S., & Manchanda, P. (2003). Measuring Heterogeneous Reservation Price
for Product Bundles. Marketing Science, 22(1), 107-130.
Kagel, J. H. (1995). Auctions: A Survey of Experimental Research. In: Kagel, J.H. & Roth,
A.E. (Eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 501-585.
Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics.
The American Economic Review, 93, 1449–1475.
Kahnemann, D. & Tverski, A. (1979). Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk.
Econometrica 47, 263-291.
Kalra, A. & Goodstein, R.C. (1998). The Impact of Advertising Positioning Strategies on
Consumer Price Sensitivity. Journal of Marketing Research (May), 210‐224.
Kalyanaram, G., & Little, J. (1994). An Empirical Analysis of Latitude of Price Acceptance in
Consumer Package Goods. Journal of Consumer Research, 21, 408–418.
58
Kalyanaram, G. & Winer, R.S. (1995). Empirical generalizations from reference price
research. Marketing Science, 14(3), 161-169.
Kapelner, A. & Chandler, D. (2010). Preventing satisficing in online surveys: A “Kapcha” to
ensure higher quality data. Proceedings of the 1st CrowdConf Conference.
Lambrecht, A. (2005). Tarifwahl bei Internetzugang: Existenz, Ursachen und Konsequenzen
von Tarifwahl-Biases. Wiesbaden.
Lambrecht, A. & Skiera, B. (2006). Paying too much and being happy about it: Existence,
causes and consequences of tariff-choice biases. Journal of Marketing Research,
18(May), 212-223.
Leeflang, P. S. H., & Wittink, D. R. (2000). Building Models for Marketing Decisions: Past,
Present and Future. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 17(2-3), 105-126.
Little, J.D. (2004). Models and Managers: The Concept of a Decision Calculus. Management
Science, 50(12), 1841-1853.
Lusk, J., & Schroeder, T. C. (2004). Are Choice Experiments Incentive Compatible? A Test
with Quality Differentiated Beef Steaks. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
86(2), 467-482.
March, J. G. (1978). Rationality, Ambiguity, and the Engineering of Choice. Bell Journal of
Economics, 9(2), 587-608.
Mason, W. & Suri, S. (2011). Conducting behavioral research on Amazon’s Mechanical Turk.
Behavior Research Methods, 1-23.
Mayring, P. (2000). Qualitative Content Analysis. Qualitative Social Research Forum, 1(2),
http://www.qualitative-research.net/fqs-texte/2-00/2-00mayring-e.htm.
Mazumdar, T., & Jun, S. (1992). Effects of Price Uncertainty on Consumer Purchase Budget
and Price Thresholds. Marketing Letters, 3, 323–329.
Menon, G., Raghubir, P., & Schwarz, N. (1995). Behavioral Frequency Judgments: An
Accessibility-Diagnosticity Framework. Journal of Consumer Research, 22(2), 212228.
59
Miles, M., & Huberman, A. (1994). Qualitative Data Analysis: An Expanded Source Book.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Miller, K., Hofstetter, R., Krohmer, H., & Zhang, J. (2011). How Should Consumers’
Willingness to Pay Be Measured? An Empirical Comparison of State-of-the-Art
Approaches. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(1), 172-184.
Moorthy, S., Ratchford, B. T., & Talukdar, D. (1997). Consumer Information Search
Revisited: Theory and Empirical Analysis. Journal of Consumer Research, 23(4), 263277.
MSI (2011). 2010-2012 Research Priorities. Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute.
Niedrich, R. W., Sharma, S., & Wedell, D. H. (2001). Reference Price and Price Perceptions:
A Comparison of Alternative Models. Journal of Consumer Research, 28(4), 339-354.
O’Brian, R.M. (2007). A Caution Regarding Rules of Thumb for Variance Inflation Factors.
Quality & Quantity 41, 673-690.
Parducci, A. (1965). Category Judgment: A Range-Frequency Model. Psychological Review,
72(6), 407-418.
Park, J. H., MacLachlan, D. L., & Love, E. (2011). New Product Pricing Strategy under
Customer Asymmetric Anchoring. International Journal of Research in Marketing,
28(4), 309-318.
Plott, C. R. (1996). Rational Individual Behavior in Markets and Social Choice Processes:
The Discovered Preference Hypothesis. In: Arrow, K. J., et al. (Eds.), The Rational
Foundations of Economic Behavior. New York: St. Martin’s. 225-250.
Prelec, D. & Simester, D. (2001). Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of
the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay. Marketing Letters, 12 (1), 5-12.
Rajendran, K. N. & Tellis, G. J. (1994). Contextual and temporal components of reference
price. Journal of Marketing, 58(1), 22-35.
Rand, W. & Rust, R.T. (2011). Agent-based Modeling in Marketing: Guidelines for Rigor.
International Journal of Research in Marketing 28 (3), 181-193.
60
Rao, A., & Sieben, W. (1992). The Effect of Prior Knowledge on Price Acceptability and the
Type of Information Examined. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 256–270.
Rossi, P., McCulloch, R., & Allenby, G. (1996). The Value of Purchase History Data Target
Marketing. Marketing Science, 15 (4), 321-340.
Schlereth, C., Eckert, C., & Skiera, B. (2011). Estimation of Willingness to Pay Intervals by
Discrete Choice Experiments. Proceedings of the 40th Conference of the European
Marketing Academy (EMAC), Ljubljana, Slovenia.
Schlereth, C. & Skiera, B. (2009). Schätzung von Zahlungsbereitschaftsintervallen mit der
Choice-Based Conjoint Analyse. Schmalenbachs Zeitschrift für betriebswirtschaftliche
Forschung (zfbf), 61(8), 838-856.
Schul, Y. & Mayo, R. (2003). Searching for certainty in an uncertain world: The difficulty of
giving up the experiential for the rational mode of thinking. Journal of Behavioral
Decision Making, 16, 93-106.
Shadish, W. R. & Haddock, C. K. (1994). Combining Estimates of Effect Sizes. In: Cooper,
H. & Hedges, L.V. (eds.), The Handbook of Research Synthesis. New York. Russel
Sage Foundation. 261-281.
Shankar, V. (2010). Shopper Marketing. Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute.
Shankar, V., Inman, J., Mantrala, M., Kelley, E., & Rizley, R. (2011). Innovations in Shopper
Marketing: Current Insights and Future Research Issues. Journal of Retailing, 87S (1),
S1-S2.
Simon, H. A. (1955). A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 69(2), 99-118.
Sloman, S. A. (1996). The empirical case for two systems of reasoning. Psychological
Bulletin, 119, 3–22.
Srinivasan, S., Pauwels, K., Hanssens, D.M., & Dekimpe, M.G. (2004). Do Promotions
Benefin Manufacturers, Retailers, or Both?. Management Science, 50(5), 617-629.
Stingel, S. (2008). Tarifwahlverhalten im Business-to-Business-Bereich. Gabler: Wiesbaden.
61
Strauss, A., & Corbin, J. (1990). Basics of Qualitative Research: Grounded Theory,
Procedures and Techniques. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
van Dijk, T. (1980). Macrostructures. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
van Westendorp, P.H. (1976) NSS Pricesensitivity-Meter (PSM) – A new approach to study
consumer perception of prices. 29th ESOMAR Congress, Venice.
Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis, 3d ed. New York: Norton.
Voelckner, F. (2006). An Empirical Comparison of Methods for Measuring Consumers’
Willingness to Pay. Marketing Letters, 17(2), 137-149.
Völckner, F. (2008). The dual role of price: decomposing consumers’ reactions to price.
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 36(3), 359-377.
Wang, T., Venkatesh, R., & Chatterjee, R. (2007). Reservation Price as a Range: An
Incentive-Compatible Measurement Approach. Journal of Marketing Research,
44(May), 200-213.
Wathieu, L. & Bertini, M. (2007). Price as a stimulus to think: The case for willful
overpricing. Marketing Science, 26(1), 118–129.
Wertenbroch, K., & Skiera, B. (2002). Measuring Consumer Willingness to Pay at the Point
of Purchase. Journal of Marketing Research, 39(May), 228-241.
Zhang, J. & Krishnamurthi, L. (2004). Customizing Promotions in Online Stores. Marketing
Science, 23 (4), 561-578.
Zhang, J. & Wedel, M. (2009). The Effectiveness of Customized Promotions in Online and
Offline Stores. Journal of Marketing Research, 46 (2), 190-206.
62
Download