European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 Long-term growth and short-term economic instability Philippe Martin!,#,*, Carol Ann Rogers" ! CERAS-ENPC, 28 rue des Saints Pe% res, 75007 Paris, France " Department of Economics, Georgetown University, Washington, DC 20057, USA # CEPR, London, UK Received 1 August 1997; accepted 1 May 1998 Abstract When learning by doing is at the origin of growth the long-run growth rate should be negatively related to the amplitude of the business cycle if human capital accumulation is increasing and concave in the cyclical component of production. Empirical evidence strongly supports this "nding for industrialized countries and European regions. Using the standard control variables, we "nd that countries and regions that have a higher standard deviation of growth and of unemployment have lower growth rates. The result does not come from an e!ect of instability on investment. The negative relation, however, does not hold for non-industrialized countries, for which learning by doing may not to be the main engine of growth. ( 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classixcation: O40; E32 Keywords: Growth; Business cycle; Learning by doing; Short-term economic instability 1. Introduction A strong tradition among macroeconomists has been to study the business cycle and long-term growth as two separate phenomena. Business cycle theorists * Corresponding author. Tel.: 33 1 44 58 28 76; fax: 33 1 44 58 28 80; e-mail: martin-p@paris. enpc.fr. 0014-2921/00/$ - see front matter ( 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 0 1 4 - 2 9 2 1 ( 9 8 ) 0 0 0 7 3 - 7 360 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 have considered long-term growth as an exogenous trend and growth theorists have typically worked with models where short-term shocks have no impact on the long-run growth rate of the economy. A recent strand of literature has put together the two phenomena in a common theoretical framework. From a theoretical point of view, the relation between short-term economic instability and long-run growth can be positive or negative, depending on the mechanism at the origin of growth. As shown by Aghion and Saint-Paul (1993), the sign of the relation depends on whether the activity that generates growth in productivity is a complement or a substitute to production. In the case where they are substitutes, since the opportunity cost of productivity improving activities falls in recessions, a larger amplitude and frequency of business-cycle #uctuations may have a positive e!ect on long-run productivity and growth (Aghion and Saint-Paul, 1991). In the case of complementarity, they show, as does Stadler (1990), that a positive (negative) shock will have a positive (negative) long-term impact on productivity. Two recent papers of ours (Martin and Rogers, 1995, 1997), in which growth is generated by learning by doing, belong to this class of models in which production and productivity increasing activities are complements. We have shown how stabilization policies could have a positive impact on human capital accumulation and, through this channel, on growth. A counter cyclical policy that smooths the impact of shocks on employment was needed for growth maximization (Martin and Rogers, 1997) or welfare maximization (Martin and Rogers, 1995). One natural implication from these models, that we did not directly address, was that short-term economic instability is detrimental for human capital accumulation and growth. As theoretical models can predict a negative or a positive relation between the amplitude of the business cycle and growth, the next natural step should be to attempt to settle the question at the empirical level. One way to do this is to use time-series methods to determine the long-run e!ect of macroeconomic shocks. Bean (1990) and Saint-Paul (1993) have found results that are mildly supportive of a negative long-run e!ect of demand shocks on productivity. These timeseries results may not be easy, however, to interpret in terms of the relation between long-term growth and the business cycle. The question of whether a positive shock has a positive or negative impact on the level of long-term productivity is not the same as the question of whether the amplitude of the business cycle is a determinant of the long-term growth rate. Even though the answer to the "rst question is important from a positive point of view, it is not certain what the policy implications are. On the other hand, if the amplitude of the business cycle has a negative impact on long-run growth, this has important policy implications because it gives counter cyclical stabilization policies a new strong role. A more direct way to test the relation is to use cross-country regressions. This paper does so for OECD countries as well as for a sample of 90 European P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 361 regions. Our empirical "ndings are the following. There is a strongly signi"cant and negative relation between growth and the standard deviation of growth, both for OECD countries and for European regions. This is true with di!erent sets of control variables and this is robust to di!erent speci"cations. In particular, the relation is robust to the inclusion in the regressions of the investment share in GDP for industrialized countries. We also "nd that European regions and industrialized countries with high standard deviation of unemployment have had lower growth which points to the key role of employment and presumably learning by doing in this relation. However, we do not "nd that such a relation holds for developing countries. This is consistent with Young's (1993) theoretical "nding that growth will be driven by learning by doing only at relatively high levels of development. Ramey and Ramey (1995) have found, in a sample of 92 countries as well as in a sample of OECD countries, that countries with higher volatility of growth have lower growth. Their work focuses on the possible link between short-term uncertainty and long-run growth.1 In our work (Martin and Rogers, 1995, 1997), we posit that learning by doing could generate a relation between growth and instability. The link between #uctuations and growth then would rely neither on uncertainty nor on an investment channel but on a labour channel so that in our tests of this relationship in this paper, we will not di!erentiate between predictable and unpredictable shocks. The next section of the paper describes the relation between instability and growth that we want to test, the methodology and the data. Section 3 reports the empirical results for European regions and OECD countries. Section 4 does it for developing countries. An appendix outlines the simple theoretical model that informs our empirical tests. 2. Instability and growth In an economy in which learning by doing is at the origin of growth, business cycle #uctuations may reduce the growth rate. Recessions are periods in which opportunities to learn by doing are foregone, so adverse business cycle shocks negatively a!ect human capital accumulation. As long as employment and therefore human capital accumulation is increasing and concave in the business cycle disturbance, the &lost' learning is not fully regained when the cycle turns upwards again. This is precisely the channel through which business cycle #uctuations can negatively a!ect long-term growth rates. 1 They are interested in testing theories for which the negative relation between volatility and growth relies on uncertainty through the link of investment, see Bernanke (1983), Pindyck (1991) and Ramey and Ramey (1991). 362 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 The appendix outlines a growth model with stochastic short-term productivity shocks. It shows that the amplitude of the business cycle a!ects negatively the growth rate if employment is concave in the output disturbances. The source of the disturbances (demand or supply) is not important for the conclusions, since all that matters is that employment is increasing and concave in the disturbances. We do not test directly this concavity condition, but note that one of the stylized facts reported in the empirical literature on business cycles (see, for example, Danthine and Donaldson, 1993) is that labour productivity is pro-cyclical in all industrialized countries. The positive correlation between labour productivity (output over employment) and output itself implies that employment increases with output but at a decreasing rate. Evidence also exists at the micro-level that, for di!erent product lines, learning rates are initially high, declining over time as production cumulates. Lucas (1993) insists both on &how impressive the evidence on the productivity e!ects of learning by doing can be' and on the shape of the learning curve.2 This evidence of the learning curve suggests that learning increases more rapidly when production is high (as it accumulates more rapidly) than when it is low but that this increase takes place at an decreasing rate. We test the relation between growth and instability for three samples. The "rst sample consists of 90 European regions for which we have data between 1979 and 1992. The second sample consists of the 24 industrialized countries for which we have complete data between 1960 and 1988. We test the relation both for the entire period and also for three sub-periods (1960}1969, 1970}1979 and 1980}1988) that we pool together. The third sample consists of the 72 nonindustrialized and non-oil-producing countries for which again we use data both for the entire period and the three sub-periods already mentioned. The data for the European regions are taken from Eurostat and the data for the 96 countries are from the World Bank and Barro and Lee (1993). As in Easterly, 1994, the growth rates are computed by running a least-squares regression of the logarithm of per capita GDP on time.3 The annual standard deviation of growth rates (SDGW) are taken as the measure of the amplitude of the business cycle. Alternatively, we could have chosen the variance of the growth rate. The results are very similar but in most cases produced a slightly better "t when using the standard deviation. In addition, because the volatility of employment is a key element driving the theoretical results, we also use the standard deviation of the unemployment rate as an alternative measure of the amplitude of the business cycle when using data for the European regions and the industrialized countries. The list of countries and European regions and their respective growth rates and standard deviation of the growth rates are given in Tables 1 and 2. 2 See the evidence on both of these aspects in the studies by Searle (1945), Rapping (1965) and Bahk and Gort (1993). 3 Watson (1992) shows that the least-squares growth rate is more robust to di!erences in the serial correlation properties of the data than the geometric rate of growth. P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 363 Table 1 Per capita growth rates and standard deviations of the growth rates for 97 countries Countries Least-squares growth rates (1960}1988) SDGW Africa 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 Algeria Chad Egypt Morocco Botswana Cameroon Central Africa Congo Gabon Gambia (The) Ghana Cote d'Ivoire Kenya Lesotho Liberia Madagascar Malawi Mali Mauritania Mauritius Mozambique Niger Nigeria Rwanda Senegal Sierra Leone Somalia Sudan Swaziland Tanzania Togo Tunisia Uganda Zambia Zimbabwe 4.23 !2.00 5.15 0.87 8.06 3.77 0.56 2.07 4.88 3.86 !0.77 1.75 1.11 5.60 !0.50 !1.64 16.24 1.23 0.91 0.69 !2.99 0.73 !0.60 2.90 !0.71 0.41 1.28 !0.17 0.24 2.52 2.75 0.81 0.86 !1.81 2.88 11.67 8.16 6.21 4.55 7.92 5.45 3.88 6.89 16.13 9.34 4.82 5.29 5.83 8.93 7.27 3.46 5.28 5.14 7.88 5.62 7.73 7.82 8.34 9.31 4.35 6.25 13.36 7.21 8.73 5.30 6.07 3.44 14.15 6.72 6.23 Latin America 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 Barbados Costa Rica Dominican Rep. El Salvador Guatemala Haiti Honduras Jamaica Mexico 0.98 0.53 1.53 !0.04 1.83 0.77 1.67 0.19 1.73 5.39 3.58 6.61 4.95 2.86 4.25 3.73 5.72 4.16 364 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 Table 1 (Continued) Countries Least-squares growth rates (1960}1988) SDGW !0.46 3.12 1.70 1.09 1.40 3.29 0.09 2.20 3.16 2.83 0.71 0.93 1.54 12.44 3.83 9.15 4.26 4.57 8.86 5.95 2.64 4.97 4.78 5.72 5.04 6.76 Latin America 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 Nicaragua Panama Trinidad Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Ecuador Paraguay Peru Uruguay Venezuela Asia 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 Myanamar India Israel Jordan Pakistan Syria Korea Malaysia Philippines Singapore Taiwan Thailand Fiji Cyprus Malta 2.19 1.16 2.74 2.98 1.86 4.41 8.50 3.41 2.19 4.77 5.60 3.66 1.39 3.79 4.84 5.60 3.78 4.54 8.06 3.68 10.38 4.55 4.72 3.91 4.34 2.99 3.15 5.42 9.49 4.61 Western 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden 3.27 2.38 1.70 2.99 2.70 2.42 4.23 2.20 2.45 3.52 2.19 2.04 2.63 3.34 3.09 1.64 2.41 2.59 2.80 2.89 2.12 2.58 4.07 4.06 3.21 2.84 3.43 2.41 1.62 3.94 4.03 1.78 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 365 Table 1 (Continued) Western 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 Countries Least-squares growth rates (1960}1988) SDGW Switzerland Turkey United Kingdom Canada U.S.A. Japan Australia New Zealand 1.43 3.45 1.85 1.36 1.11 4.99 1.58 0.37 2.93 3.72 2.17 2.98 2.54 3.30 2.59 3.39 The other variables are the usual control variables that are used in growth regressions (see Barro, 1991; Levine and Renelt, 1992; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995). For all samples, the regression contains the initial GDP of the period (GDPI). The reason is twofold. First, the literature on conditional convergence has shown that initial income is a determinant of growth. Second, if transitional dynamics exist and resemble those of the Solow model they would give rise to a convergence result4 in the sense of a decline over time in per capita growth rates. This creates a bias in the relation between growth rates and the standard deviation of growth rates. Suppose we look at two countries identical in all dimensions (in particular, in the underlying temporary shocks that hit the economy) except in their position with respect to the (common) steady state (de"ned as a situation where its growth rate is constant). The country further away from the steady state will have a higher growth rate because of the transitional dynamics. Its growth rate will also be decreasing faster than the country close to the steady state so that mechanically the variance of its growth rate will also be higher. This implies that the presence of transitional dynamics in itself creates a positive relation between growth rates and the standard deviation of the growth rates. It will therefore be especially important in our growth regressions to account for the transitional dynamics so as to avert a positive bias on the coe$cient of the standard deviation of growth. In the cross-country regressions, we also have the average investment share in GDP (INV), the average share of government expenditures in GDP (SGOV), and the primary schooling (PRIM) from Barro (1991) which refers to the initial human capital. For European regions, secondary education (SEC) is also 4 Even though we need to take into account of transitional dynamics in the empirical tests performed in the next section, we do not conduct &convergence' tests so that our tests are not marred by Galton's fallacy as described by Quah (1993). 16 17 18 19 20 21 14 15 13 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Deutschland Denmark Belgium Countries Baden Wuerttemberg Bayern Berlin Bremen Hamburg Hessen Sjvlland-Lolland Falster-Bornholm Fyn Jylland Vlaams Gewest Region Vallone Bruxelles Regions Antwerpen Brabant Hainaut Liege Limburg Luxembourg Namur Oost-Vlaandern West-Vlaanderen Subregions Table 2 Per capita growth rates and standard deviations of the growth rates for 90 European regions 4.08 4.58 2.03 4.00 4.10 4.70 0.61 1.32 1.22 1.67 1.05 1.64 1.37 1.32 0.93 1.06 2.30 1.86 1.19 1.91 1.54 Least-square SDGWgrowth rates (1978}1992)(%) 2.24 2.44 6.79 2.29 4.33 2.84 3.73 3.77 3.18 2.58 2.41 3.16 3.08 2.66 2.56 2.61 3.40 2.15 2.75 2.96 2.86 SDGW (%) 366 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 46 47 44 45 41 42 43 38 39 40 35 36 37 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 27 22 23 24 25 26 France Mediterranee Centre Est Sud Ouest Ouest Nord Pas de Calais Est Ile de France Bassin Parisien Niedersachsen Nordrhein Westfalen Rheinland Pfalz Saarland Schleswig Holstein Languedoc Roussillon Provence Alpes Cote d'Azur Rhones Alpes Auvergne Aquitaine Midi Pyrenees Limousin Pays de la Loire Bretagne Poitou Charentes Lorraine Alsace Franche Comte Champage Ardenne Picardie Haute Normandie Centre Basse Normandie Bourgogne 0.18 !0.32 0.20 0.20 0.15 0.70 0.34 0.16 0.18 0.19 !0.52 0.24 !0.08 0.00 !0.65 !0.29 0.23 0.21 0.19 !0.32 0.73 3.96 3.49 3.62 1.68 3.71 3.79 3.52 3.13 2.96 3.75 3.45 3.35 3.20 3.29 3.18 3.88 3.37 2.56 3.59 3.35 4.61 3.39 2.93 3.17 3.39 2.68 2.26 2.14 2.74 1.81 2.48 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 367 64 65 66 62 63 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 49 50 51 52 48 Italia Ireland Countries Table 2 (Continued) Sud Lazio Campania Abruzzi Molise Emilia Romagna Lombardia Nord Est Nord Ovest Regions Puglia Basilicata Calabria Abruzzi Molise Toscana Umbria Marche Trentino alto adige Veneto Friuli Venezia Giulia Piemonte Valle d'Aosta Liguria Subregions 0.51 !0.65 0.11 0.79 0.83 0.52 0.90 0.75 !0.09 !0.14 !0.15 0.32 0.86 0.27 !0.15 !0.44 !0.22 0.12 1.06 Least-square SDGWgrowth rates (1978}1992)(%) 5.61 6.10 6.69 5.84 6.08 5.93 6.15 4.93 5.87 4.76 5.92 7.24 4.82 4.76 3.90 4.04 3.75 4.62 5.09 SDGW (%) 368 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 78 79 74 75 76 77 70 71 72 73 69 67 68 United Kingdom Nederland Luxembourg North Yorkshire East Midlands East Anglia South East South West West Midlands North West Wales Scotland Northern Ireland Zuid Oost West Sicilia Sardegna Noord Brabant Limburg Utrecht Noord Holland Zuid Holland Zeeland Groningen Friesland Drenthe 0.24 0.45 0.64 1.15 0.80 0.91 0.43 0.11 0.69 0.52 0.60 3.54 3.86 3.06 2.90 2.77 3.68 !0.88 3.08 2.22 2.86 3.48 0.03 0.07 9.48 8.47 9.42 9.34 9.47 9.48 8.16 8.94 8.78 9.09 8.78 3.12 2.66 4.49 2.34 3.30 4.09 10.75 3.76 4.91 2.75 6.11 4.86 4.19 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 369 370 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 included. For the developing countries, we include variables for political instability. These are the average number of revolutions and coups (REVC) over the period and the number of political assassinations per million inhabitants (ASSP). The shocks we consider in our theoretical model could be thought of, as in Barro and Sala-i-Martin, as supply shocks and equivalent to temporary declines in the security of property rights. We include political variables in the regressions because we want to distinguish between economic and political instability.5 3. Empirical evidence for European regions and industrialized countries We now report results of the tests of the link between the amplitude of the business cycle and the growth rate. Table 3 shows the results for the regressions for European regions between 1979 and 1992.6 We also include country dummies. The "rst and second column report regressions without and with sectoral shares: the share of agriculture in production (AGRI) and the share of industry in production (IND). In both cases, SDGW has the right sign and is very signi"cant. We have checked that these results are not due to the presence of outliers. Table 4 reports the results for the sample of 24 industrialized countries. The "rst two columns have the results for pooled data set whereas the next two columns report the growth rate between 1960 and 1988 as the dependent variable. In all speci"cations, the coe$cient on SDGW is negative and signi"cant at the 5% level or less. We have checked that the coe$cient on SDGW remains negative and signi"cant even when, in the pooled data set, we control for "xed time e!ects. The coe$cient becomes more negative and signi"cant when the investment ratio (INV) is included in the regression7 (see columns 2 and 4). This shows that the impact of short-term instability does not go through an e!ect on investment which could be a natural alternative explanation to our empirical "ndings. This con"rms the results of Ramey and Ramey (1995). In their cross-country regressions, they "nd no relation between the investment share in GDP and the standard deviation of growth rates. A further implication of our theoretical framework is that employment instability has a negative impact on long-term growth. To test this, we used, as 5 On the impact of political instability on growth see Alesina et al. (1992). 6 The standard errors in all the regressions reported in the paper are computed using White's heteroskedacity-robust procedure. 7 Note that the coe$cient on the investment ratio has the wrong sign and is not signi"cant. In the di!erent regressions we have performed the coe$cient on the investment ratio in the industrialized countries is signi"cant and positive only when SGOV and PRIM are excluded from the regression. P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 371 an alternative measure of the amplitude of the business cycle, the standard deviation of the unemployment rate (SDUN). The two columns M3N and M4N in Table 3 report for European regions the same regressions as in M1N and M2N except that SDGW is replaced by SDUN. Because of lack of data on unemployment, the growth rate for these regressions is computed on the period 1983}1992. The coe$cient on SDUN is negative and signi"cant at the 5% level. We also tried as a measure of the e!ect of the business cycle on employment the standard deviation of the unemployment rate of workers under 25 (SDUN25). We thought that young workers should have the steepest learning curve so that the e!ect of employment instability on growth should be stronger in this case. The results are given in columns M5N and M6N. The coe$cient has the right sign in both regressions but is not very signi"cant whether sectoral shares are included or not in the regression. We also tested this implication of the model for OECD countries. In columns M5N}M8N, the measure of the amplitude of the business cycle, the standard deviation of growth, SDGW, is replaced by the standard deviation of the unemployment rate, SDUN. Again, as for the European regions the coe$cient has the expected sign but is signi"cant at the 5% level only in the pooled data set. Another implication of the channel we identify in the theoretical model is that average e!ective employment should have a positive impact on human capital accumulation and growth. Average unemployment rates are imperfect measures of this e!ect but we nonetheless include them in our growth regressions to see if they have a negative impact on average growth. In all samples, the coe$cient (not reported) for the average unemployment rate is negative and very signi"cant. There is, however, an obvious problem of reverse causality as average growth rates are also a determinant of unemployment. To tackle this problem, we used two-stage least-squares regressions.8 We report these regressions in columns M7N and M8N of Table 3 and columns M9N and M10N of Table 4. In regression M7N of Table 3, where the instability measure is not included, the average unemployment rate (AVUN) has a strong negative and signi"cant impact on growth in European regions. For industrialized countries (see regression M9N in Table 4) this is also the case. When we include both the instability measure and the average unemployment rate in our regressions, the later becomes insigni"cant in the European regions sample and even though the coe$cient on instability remains verysigni"cant, it decreases in both samples. This suggests that short-term instability and unemployment a!ect long-term growth in similar ways. 8 For European regions, the instruments for the unemployment are a constant, the share of industry in regional output, the initial GDP and SDGW. For industrialized countries (pooled data), the instruments are a constant, the initial unemployment rate of the period, a dummy for the "rst decade and the initial GDP. These instruments are unlikely to be caused by average growth rates. SDUN25 SDUN SDGW IND AGRI SEC PRIM GDPI Constant No of obs. !0.4255 [0.00] 90 0.0278 [0.31] !0.00023 [0.70] 0.65315 [0.97] !0.0199 [0.14] M1N 87 0.0479 [0.04] !0.00019 [0.78] !0.0115 [0.58] !0.0259 [0.07] !0.0197 [0.41] !0.0117 [0.11] !0.4169 [0.00] M2N !0.00218 [0.33] 90 0.00493 [0.84] !0.991 [0.205] 0.0158 [0.43] !0.00218 [0.51] M3N !0.00212 [0.04] 87 0.0292 [0.22] !1.02]10~6 [0.22] 0.00279 [0.90] !0.0182 [0.17] !0.0321 [0.25] !0.0152 [0.07] M4N M6N M7N M8N !0.000635 [0.19] !0.000821 [0.075] TSLS TSLS 87 90 90 90 0.023 0.000358 0.0312 0.0203 [0.34] [0.99] [0.10] [0.20] !9.94]10~7 !9.28]10~7 !2.13]10~6 !9.17]10~7 [0.25] [0.25] [0.00] [0.07] 0.00448 0.0136 0.025 0.0184 [0.85] [0.49] [0.20] [0.25] !0.0151 !0.00377 !0.0189 !0.0162 [0.27] [0.82] [0.10] [0.12] !0.005 [0.13] !0.0135 [0.09] !0.274 [0.005] M5N Table 3 European regions dependent variable: growth rate 1979}1972 (regression M1N and M2N), growth rate 1983}1992 (regressions M3N to M8N) 372 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 0.84 !0.0208 [0.005] 0.0401 [0.00] 0.00355 [0.62] 0.00628 [0.37] 0.0335 [0.00] 0.0191 [0.01] 0.85 0.0206 [0.00] 0.0410 [0.00] 0.00374 [0.57] 0.00701 [0.31] 0.0325 [0.00] 0.0192 [0.00] Note: The signi"cance level is in brackets. R2 Uki Ned Ita Fra Ger Bedlux AVUN 0.81 0.0155 [0.00] 0.0405 [0.00] 0.00131 [0.78] 0.00342 [0.45] 0.0293 [0.00] 0.0065 [0.15] 0.81 0.0152 [0.00] 0.04 [0.00] 0.00191 [0.66] 0.00444 [0.31] 0.0287 [0.00] 0.00706 [0.07] 0.81 0.0153 [0.00] 0.042 [0.00] 0.00359 [0.49] 0.00615 [0.23] 0.0293 [0.00] 0.00735 [0.12] 0.80 0.0161 [0.00] 0.0413 [0.00] 0.00278 [0.62] 0.00449 [0.39] 0.0293 [0.00] 0.00673 [0.20] 0.84 !0.230 [0.00] 0.0137 [0.00] 0.0399 [0.00] 0.00189 [0.30] 0.0061 [0.09] 0.0308 [0.00] 0.0082 [0.04] 0.86 !0.084 [0.20] 0.0165 [0.00] 0.0393 [0.00] 0.00220 [0.30] 0.0057 [0.09] 0.0319 [0.00] 0.0136 [0.00] P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 373 0.53 } 0.296 [0.00] !0.0282 [0.00] !0.074 [0.041] 0.0002 [0.37] !0.3768 [0.00] } 70 0.60 !0.0266 [0.25] 0.307 [0.00] !0.0287 [0.00] 0.0898 [0.02] 0.0003 [0.20] !0.4630 [0.00] } 68 M2N 0.67 } 0.210 [0.00] !0.019 [0.00] !0.0404 [0.22] 0.00015 [0.36] !0.5334 [0.03] } 24 M3N Note: The signi"cance level is in brackets. R2 AVUN INV SDUN SDGW PRIM SGOV GDPI No. of obs. Const. M1N 0.73 !0.0322 [0.31] 0.244 [0.00] !0.023 [0.00] !0.0587 [0.10] 0.0003 [0.01] !0.7231 [0.00] } 23 M4N 0.59 !0.0069 [0.00] } 0.265 [0.00] !0.026 [0.00] !0.0121 [0.76] 0.00031 [0.28] } 60 M5N 0.6 !0.0071 [0.00] !0.0405 [0.24] 0.284 [0.00] !0.0264 [0.00] !0.039 [0.45] 0.00019 [0.64] } 57 M6N 0.74 !0.0008 [0.12] } 0.1845 [0.00] !0.0192 [0.00] !0.0437 [0.11] 0.00028 [0.00] } 24 M7N 0.73 !0.00055 [0.29] !0.001 [0.97] 0.1826 [0.00] !0.0199 [0.00] !0.0415 [0.13] 0.0004 [0.00] } 23 M8N Table 4 Industrialized countries dependent variable: growth rates 1960}1969; 1970}1979; 1980}1988 and growth rate 1960}1988 !0.004 [0.10] !0.001 [0.02] 0.58 } 68 TSLS 0.278 [0.00] !0.026 [0.00] !0.0518 [0.10] 0.0002 [0.25] } M9N !0.036 [0.15] !0.001 [0.025] 0.62 68 TSLS 0.310 [0.00] !0.028 [0.00] !0.0781 [0.02] 0.0002 [0.25] !0.413 [0.01] } M10N 374 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 375 In both the European regions sample and the industrialized countries sample, the impact of short-term instability is quantitatively important. Lowering the instability measure (SDGW) across European regions by one standard deviation is associated with an increase in the average growth rate of around half a percentage point of annual per capita growth. For industrialized countries this number is around 0.4 percentage point. Reducing the instability of the unemployment rate by one standard deviation has even a larger impact as it increases the average growth rate by 0.8}0.9 percentage point of annual per capita growth in European regions and around 0.6 percentage point for industrialized countries. 4. Empirical evidence for developing countries Table 5 reports results for non-industrialized countries. The "rst two columns report the regression results for the three decades pooled together without and with the investment ratio. The next two columns report the same regressions for the period 1960}1988. Except in one regression, the coe$cient on the instability measure is positive and insigni"cant. We "rst note that these results contradict those of Ramey and Ramey whereas our results for the developed countries do not.9 We conclude that the negative relation between short-term instability and growth is robust only for the developed countries.10 There are several possible reasons for the di!erence in the relation between growth and the standard deviation of growth in developed countries (European regions and industrialized countries) and in developing countries. (i) The lack of relation between the two variables in the developing countries could be due to measurement error. To see whether our results are due to measurement errors, we reestimated our regression for the non-industrialized countries sample using instrumental variables. The instruments for the standard deviation of the growth rate are the standard deviation of the growth rate of the preceding decade, the initial in#ation rate of the decade, the initial GDP per capita level and the number of revolutions and coups. This implied that we could not use the observations of the "rst decade (1950}1960) when we used these instruments in the regression. The results did not change much. For this 9 This may be due to di!erent factors: our growth rates are calculated over the period 1960}1988 rather than 1962}1985, using least square growth rates rather than geometric growth rates and with a slightly larger set of developing countries (72 in our sample, 68 in their sample, the di!erence being mostly in African countries). A natural candidate explanation would also be that political instability variables are included in our regressions but not theirs. However, we have checked that their exclusion does not alter the results. 10 We have also performed the same type of regressions with all countries, both developed and developing. The coe$cient on the instability measure is positive and insigni"cant. 376 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 Table 5 Developing countires dependent variable: growth rates 1960}1969; 1970}1979; 1980}1988 and growth rate 1960}1988 No of obs. Const. GDPI SGOV PRIM REVC ASSP SDGW M1N M2N M3N M4N M5N 224 0.1643 [0.0000] !0.0154 [0.0001] !0.0763 [0.0022] 0.0001 [0.2822] !0.0117 [0.0543] !4.7523 [0.6585] 0.097 [0.2112] 205 0.1706 [0.00000] !0.0204 [0.0000] !0.0683 [0.0043] 0.0001 [0.681] !0.0012 [0.8142] !6.835 [0.53078] 0.1516 [0.0494] 0.148 [0.0000] 72 0.01763 [0.0012] !0.0198 [0.0012] !0.0268 [0.325] 0.0004 [0.0109] !0.021 [0.0436] 7.2319 [0.07061] 0.0967 [0.2902] 67 0.168 [0.0003] !0.0218 [0.00058] !0.0331 [0.2168] 0.0003 [0.0268] !0.0134 [0.1952] 8.4874 [0.6392] 0.03962 [0.7021] 0.1207 [0.0018] 70 0.12 [0.006] !0.0156 [0.0123] !0.0507 [0.1774] 0.0001 [0.2489] !0.0031 [0.5989] !14.3062 [0.5987] 0.0807 [0.4115] 0.1268 [0.0016] INV DAGL SUBAFRICA LAAM R2 !0.0244 [0.0000] !0.0134 [0.0101] !0.0253 [0.0000] !0.0044 [0.4116] !0.0186 [0.0263] !0.0143 [0.0143] !0.01315 [0.1366] !0.0069 [0.2855] !0.0017 [0.0034] !0.0184 [0.0209] !0.0086 [0.1797] 0.17 0.26 0.29 0.30 0.28 Note: The signi"cance level is in brackets. limited sample, the coe$cient became negative but only signi"cant at the 30% level so that this does not make a very convincing case that measurement error is at the origin of our results for these countries. (ii) Transitional dynamics should create a positive mechanical bias between growth and the standard deviation of growth. We have checked that there is indeed a negative correlation between the initial level of GDP and the standard deviation of growth rates. This bias will be more important the more important the role of transitional dynamics in explaining growth. It should therefore be stronger for developing countries. We have accounted for transitional dynamics through the insertion in the regression of the initial level of GDP per capita and for proxies for the steady-state levels of growth rates. Our results may re#ect that not all the e!ect of transitional dynamics has been eliminated. P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 377 A related argument is that some of the high growth countries in our sample of developing countries may have been hit by important permanent shocks. This will be the case for countries where industrialization has played an important role in growth. This would induce a positive bias between the standard deviation of growth and the growth rate. We have tested this hypothesis by adding in the regression the di!erence in the initial and "nal shares of agriculture in GDP (DAGL) in column M5N of Table 5. Unfortunately, we lose a lot of observations because we do not have this data for all the countries of our sample. Introducing this variable (which non-surprisingly is very signi"cant and negative) reduces the positive coe$cient on the SDGW and also its signi"cance compared to regression M2N. This may constitute weak evidence that developing countries have been hit by important permanent shocks which obscure the relation between growth and the standard deviation of growth. (iii) Our theoretical prediction should only hold in countries for which growth is driven by learning by doing. In developing countries where the economy is dominated by traditional economic activities such as agriculture, the learning curve can be thought as almost #at. In this case, our model predicts no relation between growth and the standard deviation of growth. Our empirical results are also consistent with Young's (1993) theoretical "nding that growth will be driven by learning by doing only at relatively high levels of development that is when the market size is large relative to the cost of invention. (iv) If growth is driven by learning by doing then the level of employment is key to our results. In particular, it is important that employment is procyclical. It is quite likely that in developing countries employment responds di!erently to shocks than in developed countries. In particular, contrarily to industrialized countries, we have no stylized facts about the procyclical nature of employment in developing countries. More generally, our results may simply re#ect the fact that the business cycle is an industrialized countries phenomenon. It is di$cult at this stage to discriminate between these di!erent explanations which may all play a role. Our theoretical model coupled with Young's (1993) "nding that the learning by doing model should apply only at high development stages would predict that (iii) is enough to explain the empirical di!erences between developed and developing countries. 5. Conclusion We have studied the impact of learning by doing on the relation between growth and short-term instability at the aggregate level. For developed countries, our empirical results show a signi"cant and quantitatively important negative relation between growth and the amplitude of the business cycle whether measured by the standard deviation of growth or the standard deviation of unemployment. We have seen that this relation does not work through 378 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 an impact of short-term instability on the level of investment in industrialized countries which could be a natural explanation of the empirical results. Furthermore, if investment played an important role in this relation it would be di$cult to explain the di!erence in results between developed and developing countries. If short-term instability is detrimental to investment it should be so in both sets of countries. Instead, our results are consistent with a model where human capital accumulation is increasing and concave in production and Young's (1993) "nding that growth is driven by learning by doing only at high levels of development. Our conclusions have interesting policy implications. They give a clear and novel rationale in favour of short-term stabilization policies, be they monetary or "scal policies. Two recent papers of ours (Martin and Rogers, 1995, 1997) study in similar models under which conditions a "scal counter-cyclical policy can improve growth prospects. An interesting characteristic of this policy implication is that it does not come out of a Keynesian-type model. In particular, markets clear, and the origin of the shocks, supply or demand, does not matter for the results. Acknowledgements We gratefully acknowledge the "nancial support of the Swiss Fonds National de la Recherche Scienti"que. We thank an anonymous referee, Gilles Dowek, Hans Genberg, Pierre-Yves Geo!ard, Claire Lefevbre, Danny Quah and Pierre Villa as well as seminar participants at CEPII for helpful comments and Marco Fugazza for excellent research assistance. Appendix: A model of growth with learning by doing with stochastic shocks A representative household chooses consumption c and labour l over an t t in"nite horizon to maximize the expected utility function: A B t ac1~1@p#(1!a)[h (1!l )]1~1@p = 1 t t t E ;"E + . (A.1) 0 0 1!1/p 1#o t/0 There is only one factor of production, labour, and goods and factor markets are perfectly competitive so that the income of the household is given by the level of production and the household faces the budget constraints: w l "c , t"0, 12, (A.2) tt t where w is the wage rate. There is no saving. The maximum amount of labour t the consumer can supply in any date t equals unity: 04 l 41. t P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 379 Output is produced using e!ective labour, which equals hours worked (l) times human capital (h): y "/ l h . The parameter / is an exogenous stochast t t t t tic productivity disturbance. The wage rate per unit of time worked is: w "/ h . t t t Human capital accumulates via learning by doing: h "(1!d#bl ) h , (A.3) t`1 t t where d is the rate of depreciation of human capital, b is a parameter that tells how much is learned through experience. According to Eq. (A.3), returns to learning are not bounded and the rate of learning depends upon the #ow of e!ective labour. All bene"ts of human capital accumulation are &external' that is, that individual workers do not internalize the fact that experience a!ects future wages in the economy. The business cycle is characterized by a two-state stationary Markov process. In good states the productivity level, / , takes the value G. In bad states, it takes t the value B(G. We thus assume that all disturbances are transitory. The two-state Markov chain is de"ned by the following probabilities: PrM/ "G; / "GN"P , PrM/ "B; / "BN"P , t`1 t G t`1 t B PrM/ "G; / "BN"1!P , PrM/ "B; / "GN"1!P . t`1 t B t`1 t G The long-term expected value of productivity is therefore: G(1!P )#B(1!P ) B G, E/ " t 1!j (A.4) where j"P #P !1. We also assume that agents observe the state of the G B economy at the beginning of the period. The optimal private choice of labour supply is then derived from the "rstorder conditions of the maximization problem of the consumer: 1 l" , (A.5) t 1#k/1~p t where k"[(1!a)/a]p.11 The labour supply is increasing in the cyclical component of the wage rate } the productivity level } and will be procyclical if p is more than 1. There are two levels of labour supply: l and l . G B The expected growth rate of output between date 0 and date ¹ is E (y /y ). 0 T 0 The average annual growth rate between those dates then equals C A BD y T E 0 y 0 1@T . 11 For utility to be "nite, a su$cient condition is that l ((o#d)/b for all t. t (A.6) 380 P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 If the economy is the same states in dates 0 and ¹, then as ¹PR, the long-run expected growth rate can be rewritten as C A BD 1@T C A BD C A BD 1@T 1@T / l h h TT T T " E " E 0 / l h 0 h 00 0 0 (A.7) "(1!d#bl )(1~PB)@(1~j) (1!d#bl )(1~PG)@(1~j). B G In Eq. (A.7), (1!P )/(1!j) is the expected long-run proportion of good B states (when the growth rate equals (1!d#b1 )) and (1!P )/(1!j) is the B G expected long-run proportion of bad states (when the growth rate equals (1!d#bl )). To determine the e!ect of the amplitude of the business cycle on G the expected long-run growth rate, we di!erentiate Eq. (A.7) with respect to the productivity levels B and G. For the exercise to be meaningful, the change in the amplitude of the business cycle must leave the long-run expected level of productivity / unchanged. This requires that the changes in B and G satisfy the t condition y T E 0 y 0 1!P B dG. dB"! 1!P G In this case, we obtain C A BD C A BD d E y T 0 y 0 (A.8) 1@T C D 1@T 1!P Ll y 1 1 Ll T G B ! B . (A.9) "b E 0 y 1!j LG 1!d#bl LB 1!d#bl G B 0 As long as the labour supply is increasing and concave in the productivity level, this expression is negative so that the expected long-run growth rate decreases with the amplitude of the business cycle. References Aghion, P., Saint-Paul, G., 1991. On the virtues of bad times. Working Paper no. 578. CEPR, London. Aghion, P., Saint-Paul, G., 1993. Uncovering some causal relationships between productivity growth and the structure of economic #uctuations: A tentative survey. Working Paper d 4603. NBER, Cambridge, MA. Alesina, A., Sule, O., Nouriel, R., Philip, S. 1992. Political instability and economic growth. Working Paper 4173, September, NBER, Cambridge, MA. Bahk, B.H., Gort, M., 1993. Decomposing learning by doing in new plants. Journal of Political Economy 101, 4. Barro, R., 1991. Economic growth in a cross-section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2), 407}444. P. Martin, C.A. Rogers / European Economic Review 44 (2000) 359}381 381 Barro, R., Lee J.-W., 1993. International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, December 32 (3), 363}394. Barro, R., Sala-I-Martin, X., 1995. Economic Growth. McGraw-Hill, New York. Bean, C., 1990. Endogenous growth and the pro-cyclical behaviour of productivity. European Economic Review 34, 355}363. Bernanke, B.S., 1983. Irreversibility, uncertainty, and cyclical investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (1), 85}106. Danthine, J.P., Donaldson, J., 1993. Methodological and empirical issues in real business cycle theory. European Economic Review 33, 31}50. Easterly, W., Rebelo, S., 1994. Fiscal policy and economic growth: An empirical investigation, Discussion Paper Series No. 885. CEPR, London. Levine, R., Renelt, D., 1992. A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. American Economic Review 82 (4), 942}963. Lucas, R., 1993. Making a miracle, Econometrica 61, 2. Martin, P., Rogers, C.A., 1997. Stabilization policy, learning by doing, and economic growth. Oxford Economic Papers 49 (2), 152}166. Martin, P., Rogers, C.A., 1995. Optimal stabilization policy, in the presence of learning by doing, Discussion Paper No. 1129. CEPR, London. Pindyck, R.S., 1991. Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment. Journal of Economic Literature 29 (3), 1110}1148. Quah, D., 1993. Galton's fallacy and tests of the convergence hypothesis. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95 (4), 427}443. Ramey, G., Ramey, V.A., 1991. Technology commitment and the cost of economic #uctuations, Working Paper No. 3755, June. NBER, Cambridge, MA. Ramey, G., Ramey, V.A., 1995. Cross-country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review 85 (5), 1138}1159. Rapping, L., 1965. Learning and World War II production functions. Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 81}86. Saint-Paul, G., 1993. Productivity growth and the structure of the business cycle. European Economic Review 37, 861}890. Searle, A., 1945. Productivity changes in selected wartime shipbuilding programs, Monthly Labor Review 61. Stadler, G.W., 1990. Business cycle models with endogenous technology. American Economic Review 80 (4), 763}778. Watson, M., 1992, A note on estimating deterministic trends in the presence of serially correlated errors, Working paper, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL. Young, A., 1993. Invention and bounded learning by doing. Journal of Political Economy 101 (3), 443}472.