Economic ncentives for Farm-Leve Resource Conservation Resource conservation at the farm level has posed a management problem since systems of husbandry began. Economic agents are guided in their choices and behaviour by the incentives made available to them. Natural resource economists have examined a range of policy options to encourage the conservation of agroecological resources at the farm level. Some incentives have been used with more success than others and some promise to be effective tools, even though they have not yet been well tried. Some incentives have had unfortunate and unforeseen outcomes. DIANA J BEAL Faculty of Commerce, Universiry of Southern Queensland Introduction The problem of resource conservation at the farm level has been apparent in various civilisations since systems of animal and crop husbandry began. Historical examples of degradation are available from most parts of the globe. In Australia, cases of resource depletion can be cited from the first few years of European .occupation. Indeed, the exhaustion of seemingly lush pastures which inexplicably did not regenerate in the same way as European pastures forced pioneer pastoralists to push beyond the New South Wales government's restrictive "Nineteen Counties", despite the passing of four Acts of the British Parliament to restrain them.' Where economic agents such as the pioneer pastoralists were able to exhaust resources and move on, resource depletion was of little consequence to them personally because there was little cost, with the exception perhaps of some physical discomfort. Until the 1970s, the economics profession in the main appeared to take the same view that natural resources were virtually unlimited, and that depletion in one location merely implied relocation to start the process again. A more sophisticated view (the Julian Simon school) was that technological improvement and substitution of other types of resources would compensate for depletion with the market mechanism chipping in to assist the process. Unfortunately, the farm sector in developed countries usually does not enjoy the luxury of being able to deplete resources and move on.' Additionally, whilst technological improvement unquestionably has occurred and will, no doubt, continue to happen, the infinite substitution of other resources or inputs for degraded land, water supplies and biodiversity appears highly unlikely. These Acts were 4 Will IV 10 of 1833,7 Will IV 4 of 1836, 2 Vic 19 of 1838 and 2 Vic 27 of 1839. 2 In some lesser developed economies, this still occurs. In parts of Africa, for example, the chitimene, or slash and bum, system causes short-tenn environmental damage. In Australia some horticultural producers are still able to grow high-value crops on land until nematode populations increase to an uneconomic level, then move their operations to fresh earth. Where land tenure and social systems allow shifting agriculture, it may be an optid system- However, it is not generally an option in developed counVies it may be argued, ag*cultura~ lands am fully settled. I Ecologists and the environmental movement have raised awareness of the need to protect ecosystems to ensure that the earth may continue to support humankind at a reasonably sophisticated level. he concept of .scalugic~~3y .,ustinif8rc &velo*~;g6fiEbk&uce@1372~gi - the;- Uriiied Natioi!s conference in S t o c ~ o l m ' ~given d greater promiience subsequently in the Bruntland Report in 1987. was * e; BEAE - " ----- __ ________--_ _ _ --- , LY- . ...--- During the last decade or two, the construct of "sustainability" has migrated from reports and scientific journals to the more popular press, and during that time it has come to mean many things to a variety of people. An ecologist may see sustainability as the ability of a system to maintain productivity, to withstand collapse under stress and to recover once the stress is removed. Putting an economist's viewpoint, Rose defined an economically sustainable agricultural system as one where the A social costs of all the resources used in the system are fully re~ognised.~ Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO) (1989) definition is that sustainable agriculture "enhances'the environmental quality and resource base on which agriculture depends; provides for basic human food and fibre needs; is economically viable and enhances the quality of life for farmers and society as a ~ h o l e " . ~ Izac and Swift argued cogently for the need to bring the sustainability debate to a more pragmatic level so that it could be put into operation by land managers.' Using the region of sub-Saharan Africa as a case study, they adopted the village ecosystem as the unit of analysis and proposed that a sustainable agroecosystem is one which retains the capacity to respond to exogenous change as well as to internal disruptions by maintaining non-declining trends in its resources and amenities over a period of at least one decade. Sustainability is viewed as a desirable goal of agricultural ecosystems. Conservation of resources, on the other hand, may be considered as a necessary condition to attain sustainable systems. Sustainability is not necessarily achieved by being somewhat conservative, but a conservative attitude by agricultural operators is more likely to assist in developing sustainable systems than short-term profit maximisation coupled with an absolute neglect of longer term social needs and aspirations. The objectives of this article are, first, to analyse the economic forces which have induced the generally recognised depletion of agroecological resources, both in Australia and internationally and, secondly, to review the literature to ascertain just how successful various economic incentives have been found to be in practice in promoting resource conservation. This article is structured so that in the next section an economic rationale underlying resource depletion on farms is examined and in the following section economic incentives are introduced. The remainder of the article reviews some of the published farm-level findings involving the application of incentives and the fortune of many resources, including biodiversity."he final section draws together the findings from the earlier discussion. 3 R Rose, Economics of a Sustainable Agriculture" in Natural Resource Management: An Economic Perspective (ABARE. Canberra, 1992). p 127. FAO, Sustuinable Agricultural Production: Implications for International Agricultural Research (Technical Advisory Committee, CGIAR, FA0 Research and Technical Papers No 4. Rome, 1989). A-M N Izac and M J Swift, "On Agricultural Sustainability and its Measurement in Small-Scale Farming in Sub-Saharan Africa" (1 994) 11 Ecological Economics 105- 125. Biodiversity is defined as the variety of all life forms and their life processes. It includes the whole spectrum of biological variety, from the genetic level through species and communities to systems and landscapes. An economic rationale for depletion of natural resources on farms Economic Incentives for Farm-Level Resource Conservation Degradation of natural resources at the farm level has occurred through information deficiencies, economic pressure. faulty market signals and inappropriate government policy. Unwise government policies, to a large degree, were the culmination in the public policy sector of the same forces of information deficiencies and economic pressures, together with political pressures. For many years, for example, wholesale clearing of land was government policy spurred by dreams of rapid economic development and encouraged by taxation incentives. It has been since shown, however, to be an inappropriate policy which took no account of other values. For nature conservation, it was a perverse incentive. Historically, the first generations of pastoralists and farmers in Australia did not understand the ecosystems they were using and did not appreciate the long-term effects of their management practices. Pastoralists overestimated the ability of perennial grasses which had drawn them to such places as Mitchell's "Australia Felix", the Liverpool Plains and the Darling Downs to regenerate after heavy stocking. Early farmers found Australia's climate of uncertain rainfall was a difficult companion resource to her "unfruitful" soils, as a brief scan of contemporary diaries and newspapers shows. Politicians and bureaucrats generally endorsed similar over-optimistic views, and together put in place policies which promoted resource degradation. Reeve7 in his A Squandered Land noted the celebrated case of the 1930s Victorian politician who came back from a trip to the mallee, the soil of which was by then blowing away in huge dust-storms, and told reporters: ' 'I saw no erosion." More recently (at least since the 1950s), declining terns of trade have reduced primary producers' margins significantly on each unit of produce. Consequently, many producers have sought to make their land produce more so that a minimum net income and standard of living may be maintained. Sometimes, the extra output has been produced without permanent damage to the natural resource base. More often, however, degradation of the resource base has occurred, because more than sustainable use has been made of resources. In many lesser developed countries (LDCs), food shortages as well as low prices exacerbate resource degradation. The supply of agricultural resource inputs is inextricably linked to agricultural land. Hence, it might be expected that the quantity and quality of those resources would be reflected in land prices, and that management which encouraged resource conservation or enhancement would be rewarded with a market premium. Unfortunately, this has generally not been the case, as many authors have shown, As prices in agricultural land markets can act as an economic incentive to conservation, this factor will be discussed further later in the article. Economists use the concept of efficiency as one criterion against which dge whether an economic system or, indeed, a part thereof is working The nub of the concept of efficiency, at the highest possible level, stemming from the concept as understood by mechanics science. is that there should be an equality between what is produced ?nd the volume - of resources used tg praduce it. T& iiirpii@iaIioioni$3Bat allEi@e soyrciq of-. , +7&,*--.q,c-; --- --+.>----- . - - _,- . - .~=--,, ':. .... . . , -" g;k-z - L - * + - - * * * mber 1997 - -Ree;*=, A - ~ (um,~ d d a 3 e ) .-. - . -7.1 ~ J , a ~ . ~, ., ----'c----= 213 , +. , d -- _.-, ' .-..-..~-...-.~ ._*_ ~ value or benefits from a given output should be matched against all the costs of that production, so that a valid analysis may be undertaken. BEAL population of the whole world is potentially involved as in the case of ozone-depleting production. Because the efficiency notion, to be valid, must comprise all benefits, all costs and all people potentially involved, economists use the concepts of social benefits and social costs, meaning benefits and costs to the whole of engaged society. Socially efficient output will thus occur when marginal social benefit equals marginal social cost. However, where potential benefits and costs to parties not directly involved in a transaction must be identified, there are likely to be identification and valuation problems. If benefits and costs are consequently underestimated, production is not likely to be at optimal levels. If benefits are underestimated, production will be less than optimal. If costs are underestimated, production is likely to be greater than optimal. These are the classic cases of market failure. In a market economy, the benefits derived from production of market goods are relatively easy to measure. The market in which goods are sold sets their value to society at that time. Hence, a monetary value for production is established. In addition, there may be some other benefits in the form of positive externalities. Costs comprise the cash costs of production, plus any negative externalities of production. Estimation of the value of externalities is likely to prove somewhat difficult. In relation to agriculture, negative externalities rather than positive externalities of production immediately spring to mind. Negative externalities include soil erosion, reduction of soil fertility, degradation of soil structure, depletion of soil organic matter and water-holding capacity, decrease in soil micro-flora and fauna, chemical pollution of waterways, water turbidity, algal blooms in waterways, depletion of water resources, loss of vegetation, salinity, acidification, loss of biodiversity and so on. The list is long. Positive externalities of agriculture exist, but the list is surely somewhat shorter. Agriculture contributes managed open space as a recreational resource for city dwellers. In addition, it keeps alive the rural heritage, albeit in a modified contemporary form, which non-farm dwellers of many developed countries appear to value.qn Australia, it might be argued that primary producers provide uncompensated benefits to the nation in being a resident population in rural and remote areas. As such, producers are able to assist defence and customs personnel in stemming illegal landings. Additionally, producers are able to assist unprepared tourists who get bogged, stranded or lost. On balance, it is likely that negative externalities far outweigh positive externalities. Economic theory indicates that output in these circumstances will be greater than the long-run optimum. The historical record of agricultural production in Australia certainly suggests that output has been consistently greater than it would have been if all costs and benefits had been accounted for. a M Lockwood, P Tracey and N Klomp, "Analysing Conflict between Cultural Heritage and Nature Conservation in the Australian Alps" (1996) 39 Journul of Environmentul Planning cmd Mtinugement 357-370. These authors used the contingent valuation method to analyse conflict between cultural heritage in the form of seasonal grazing and nature conservation in the Australian Alps and found a positive preference for retention of grazing. + ,. Economic Incentives for Farm-Leve! Resource Conservation People as economic agents make decisions on production (and conmption) within the confines of the economic and social institutions of eir community. "Institutions" include the agents, structures and ractices that make up the business and social environment, such as ivate and public organisations, the legal system and generally-accepted ectations. These institutions provide the bases or es that lead people to make decisions one way or 1 An incentive is something that provokes people to modify their behaviour in some way. Thus an economic incentive encourages producers or consumers to behave in a certain fashion. Ideally, incentives are put in place by society as a framework to encourage the community to behave in uch a fashion that social objectives are achieved. Equally ideally, the policies that are instituted should not contain incentives which inadvertently encourage private choice behaviour which militates against the achievement of society's goals. Communities have a range of policies to consider when attempting to change private choice. These policies include prohibition of an activity, setting maximum limits to the activity, regulation, voluntary payments, taxes, subsidies, and tradeable property rights. Prohibition, maximum tion are not economic incentives in the sense that they set lawful individual choice? Some of the remaining options itability than others to the farm-level choice .problem. ents, for example, may have only limited applicability, leaving taxes, subsidies and tradeable property rights as apparently appropriate incentives. Apart from these largely institutional-framework incentives, prices and costs which stem from market conditions and debtlevels act as incentives. I 1 I I Incentives for farm-level conservation Taxation, subsidies and tradeable property rights at the farm level are considered in this section, together with prices for produce, prices for farm land and debt levels. Taxation and subsidies Regulatory taxes are taxes imposed as an incentive to limit or dampen down some economic behaviour. Subsidies, on the other hand, may be viewed as negative taxes which act as an incentive to promote the production of desirable outcomes. Regulatory taxes operate as a cost allocation system, which attempts to ensure that the resource user pays for his or her use. Additionally, such taxes are a method of cost internalisation which implies higher cost in line with true social cost, greater economic efficiency, higher market prices and reduced output. Theoretically managers will choose to limit private cost (and social cost), and thus limit resource depletion or degradation. , The Polluter Pays Principle (PPP) embodies the regulatory tax philosThey could be said to be economic ophy, and includes a provision that polluters should not be granted any incentives if an individual up government assistance in any form whatever. It was adopted by the 12 the expected value of the fine against the European Union (EU) member states under the Maastricht Treaty in 1992. benefit for transgression. - - -_ .-----.--- - - - - -- L'..-- -..--- -. . . --. _ _ -'"-.. --.I-...- -*_ _ =__ -- _ - - f , ----c -ST.- J 7 _ -" -, ----,s . : . d - & -C- -j.-- I.u . -+ c.l.L -"'r 'i.-:L~-'= C , -i r-c ?--I. " ,'/." -I__ December 1997 * =, - - A *I--. _ & _ 215 ' * - I _.,._ -- I -- . r ,.. ,_ .l BEAL apply to primary industries. Tobey and Smets examined the operation of PPP in relation to agriculture and found the complexity of non-point pollution coupled with institutional arrangements in industrial countries endows agricultural managers with comprehensive "rights to p~llute".~~' Consequently, the . incentive for cost internalisation on farms in industrial countries is insignificant. Despite the principles of PPP, the agricultural agreement resulting from the Uruguay Round of General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and measures adopted by the EU under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) allow subsidy of producers up to the full cost of compliance with environmental measures. Tobey and Smets further found that the use of subsidy schemes to reduce non-point pollution is widespread and increasing so that such payments could replace production subsidies. In common with other authors, they concluded that consideration for the survival of the family fa&, the principal business organisational arrangement in agriculture in many countries, has inhibited the implementation of more stringent and costly resource degradation control measures. Hilgard wrote perspicaciously that irrigators were foolish "to hope that natural laws would be waived in favour of [them and their unwise irrigation practices]"." Following Hilgard's predictions, Caswell and Zilberman12 have been keenly interested in investigating the choice of irrigatiqn technologies in California, given the scarcity of water and the likelihood of water pollution. The misuse of groundwater and the exhaustion of its quality attributes have become major issues in California where saltwater, seepage of solvents, toxic wastes and agricultural 'O J A Tobey and H Smetss "The chemicals have contaminated some groundwater basins to the extent that water is suspected to be the cause of chronic health problems in some ~ f ~ , " f ~ ~ ~~ ~i y~ s ~ i n , " , communities. ( 1996) 19 World Economy 65. l1 Hilgard*Irrigation andA1kuli Caswell, Lichtenberg and Zilberman l3 showed that a tax on tailwater, a in India, Report to the President of the pollution tax, would encourage the adoption by competitive farm firms of University of (Bulletin drip technology in place of furrow or flood irrigation. This measure would NO 86, Berkeley, 18861, 34. conserve water and minimise pollution, even though the drainage tax 12 M F CasweIl and D Zilberman, would be difficult to administer. Additionally, they argued that the optimal "The Choices of irrigation Technologies solution may not be politically feasible, because the charge would impact most on heavily-indebted farmers, most of whom run family farms. 224-234; M F Caswell and Just and Zilberman l4 examined the equity implications of both taxes on D Zilberman, "The Effects of Well pollution and imposing a pollution. standard by regulation of agricultural Depth and Land Quality on the Choice of Irrigation Technology" (1986) 68 operations which impose environmental risk such as pesticide contami- American Journarcfl Agricultural Econnation of water resources. They were especially interested in the omics 798-8 11. 13 M F Caswell, E Lichtenberg and distributional effects among small family farms and larger farms. Incorporating consideration of risk and credit availability, they found D Zilberman, "The Effects of Pricing Policies on Water Conservation and equity effects to be variable. Absolute equity was improved by the Drainage" (1990) 70 American Journal imposition of taxes and standards on activities of high pollution intensity, of Agriculturcrl Economics 883-890. but pollution standards alone improved relative equity in low pollution 14 R E Just and D Zilberman, "A Methodology for Evaluating Equity Imindustries. plications of Environmental Policy ConBiological diversity is important for maintaining the resilience of siderations in Agriculture" (1988) 64 ecosystems to changing environments and as a source of genetic patterns Land Economics 37-52. ' ~ u ~ ~ f O m , " ' ~~~~~~ ~,~?~~ for improvements in food, fibre and other species used by humankind. To depart from the utilitarian viewpoint, there is growing acceptance that it has value in its own right. Declining biodiversity at the farm level may be manifest, for example, by increasing dryland salinity caused by the lack of deep-rooted vegetation species ro pu111p groundwater in conjunction with appropriate geology, loss of species locally, larger pest insect populations due to declining numbers of natural predators, and inadequate nutrient absorption by crops, due to declining soil microflora and microfauna. Whilst incentives to ameliorate irrigation-induced salinity appear to have been a pre-occupation of American resource economists, the examination of dryland salinity appears to be a particular Australian interest. Just as turbidity of watercourses is an externality and consequence of soil erosion and non-point groundwater pollution an external cost of poor irrigation practices, dryland salinity is predominantly an artefact of inappropriate clearing of vegetation. Often the clearing has taken place in recharge zones many kilometres distant from the eventual saline outbreak. Wholesale clearing of vegetation was actively encouraged by government in Australia until 1983 by the incentive of tax deductibility of expenditure on clearing, even though initial clearing of land is clearly a capital expense. Growing concern over this land management issue is understandable, given that the estimated area in Australia affected by dryland salinity has tripled in the decade to 1993 to 1.2 million hectares, and the area at risk is very large." Initial indications of salinity include poor germination of crops, altered soil structure of cropping lands and changed mix of species in pastures. As the problem worsens, production may drop to zero, except, ironically, in the very driest seasons when the water table drops significantly to allow some useful vegetative growth. Biodiversity suffers in grasslands which suffer saline outbreaks as the vegetative mix declines to salt-tolerant species or the earth becomes totally bare. In common with many other conservation issues, dryland salinity is an example of market failure, in that private and social costs are not equal. Farmers clear land for private gain, and inflict costs on other members of the community. As outbreaks of dryland salinity spread, costs are imposed on an ever widening circle of community members. Currently in Australia, that circle has been seen to include other farmers through lost production, townspeople through degrading foundations of buildings, local authorities through disintegrating roads, and future generations. Future generations may lose through many routes, including lost production, more expensive services, lost amenity and lost biodiversity. Greig and Devonshire argued for a tax on clearing whilst Hodge countered that farm-level transferable rights to clear land would provide a more efficient and useful economic incentive to reduce clearing in catchments which were not already overcleared. In a substantial review of the Australian state of rural land management, Cameron and Elix l7 conceded that taxation incentives (in effect, subsidies delivered through the taxation system) can reduce the divergence between '" Economic Incentives for Farm-Level Resource Conservation "5 R Greiner, "On-Farm Costs of Soil Salinisation: a Case Study for the Liverpool Plains in New South Wales" (1996) 64 Review of Murketing cmd Agriculturcll Economics 60-74. '6 P J Greig and P G Devonshire, "Tree Removals and Saline Seepage in Victorian Catchments: Some Hydro1og;ic and Economic Results" (1481) 35 Allrtruliun ufAEriculrurul E~(),,.mi,, 134-148; I Hodge. "Rights to Cleared Land and the ~ o n i o l of Salinity" (1982) 26 1 rf Agriculturul Econ- . December 1997 . benefit from tax deductions and may indeed see no benefit in carryforward tax credits. Despite endorsement by the community in many nations that soil erosion is an undesirable effect of agricultural production, and despite awareness-raising projects and technical and financial assistance to farmers, soil erosion world-wide has not been significantly mitigated. Various reasons have been advanced for the lack of adoption of land conservation measures. One such reason is the inability of many farmers to observe insidious losses of productivity. Whilst an insidious loss might be inconceivable to non-farmers, it is more understandable when one considers that farmers must examine the effects of numerous inputs to production on an achieved yield to trace a shortfall to expectations. Those inputs include rainfall distribution and total amount received, stored soil moisture at planting, seed variety, planting rate, planting time, germination rate (a result of seed quality, seedbed preparation and planting technology), inherent soil fertility, added nutrients, pest and disease management, as well as harvesting time and-harvesting techniquekkill. Which of these contributed to the lower yield? Was it the reduced soil depth, fertility and waterholding capacity which stem from soil erosion? Nevertheless, numerous authors lR have estimated the annual costs of soil degradation in specific areas. Some nations have resorted to coupling farm assistance programs with adoption of either soil conservation strategies or indicators of conscientious land management such as farm plansin order to achieve a desirable balance. Linking the two has been called "cross-compliance" (CC). In the United States of America, farmers in receipt of some government loans are required to have a farm plan endorsed by the Soil Conservation Service." This policy was extended by the Food Security Act 1985, which expanded publicly-financed soil conservation incentives. Similarly, in Australia, l farmers applying for government assistance under the ~ u r a Adjustment Scheme have been required to show that farm development planning has taken place. Ervin, Heffernan and Green examined the anticipated efficiency and distributive impacts of such CC programs. The guiding principle of CC is that only land managers who achieve stipulated soil conservation standards or management requirements receive benefits under aid programs. The specification of the land management standard is obviously an important variable, as is the identification of the aid program to which to link the goal. Using a theoretical model incorporating private costs and benefits as well as public on-site and off-site benefits of erosion control on increasingly erosive lands, Ervin et a1 found a CC program may have unintended and unwanted effects. Specifically, these authors concluded that owners of land with least soil erosion potential and thus least cost remediation would be able to meet the conservation standard more easily and thus earn the greatest rent."' In regions where larger and more profitable farm units occupy less sloping lands and smaller farms lie on surrounding slopes and foothill country, the program would not operate as intended. Data from a random sample of BEAL l8 See, for example, B S Alcock, The Costs of Soil Erosion (Economic Services Branch, QDPI. Toowoomba, 1980); M Blyth and A McCallum, "Onsite Costs of Land Degradation in Agriculture and Forestry" in A Chisholm and R Dumsday (eds), Environmentul Studies (ANU, Canberra, 1987). l9D E Ervin, W D Heffernan and G P Green. Cross-Compliance for Erosion Control: Anticipating Efficiency and Distributive Impacts" (1984) 66 Americun Journttl cf Agriculturul Econ0mic1273-27820 In economics, rent is defined as a pa,,ment emed by a fador in excess of ,he minimum required to bring it into production. Missouri farm managers provided empirical evidence for this conclusion. Older and higher-equity land managers ownecfthe least erosive large farm units, whilst younger lower-equity farmers occupied sloping, more erosive lands. Hence, whilst CC appears both efficient and equitable in principle, it may prove difficult to target precisely in practice. Economic for Farm-Level Resource Conservation Tradeable property rights -- - -- - .. Johnson" reviewed extensively the nature of property rights in land and examined options to redistribute those rights so that incentives to improve land management would be provided. He argued that the Torrens system of title registration in Australia and New Zealand has been too successful in achieving security of title, in that it assures holders of title that they can do what they like with their freehold land and there is no incentive to manage externalities properly. This belief is characterised as a state of LLunattenuated"rights, a concept discussed by Q~iggin.'~ The attenuation of a bundle of rights will usually reduce their aggregate value to the owner,23 but rights are attenuated to prevent costs being imposed by proprietors on others and society as a whole. Johnson argued that the existing property rights systems do not protect the rights of others, especially in relation to the natural environment, and that administrative solutions incorporating transferable rights must be devised so that farm managers come to regard themselves first as responsible land managers. Zilberman, MacDougall and Shahz4examined water allocation mechanisms in California, in the light of growing water scarcity and increasing awareness of environmental issues. They concluded that transition from water rights to water markets through transferable rights systems would induce farmers to adopt water conservation technologies and may not disadvantage holders of historic rights to water for farm use. Moreover, they contended that a net transfer of water away from agriculture coupled with improved irrigation technologies may not leave individual Californian farmers worse off and would have considerable social benefits. At farm level in Australia, the development of tradeable rights to resource use appears to be an area where government is actively developing policy, especially in relation to water rights. The theory behind the development of a transferable water market is that allocation efficiency will improve over time as water is directed to enterprises with the highest rates of return (highest marginal revenue product). At the farm level, the opportunity cost of water will encourage farmers to improve distributional efficiency and conservation. James2' identified Victoria as the most advanced with a water market in operation since December 1990. The experience with this incentive in that State is that it has not lived up to its promise. Most trades have been for temporary rather than permanent transfers, and prices generally have fallen rather than risen. Whilst the general malaise in Australian agriculture due to continual decline of the terms of trade, seemingly continuous drought in some areas, ageing farm population and so on may well be involved in this result, some reforms such as widening the market to encompass all States involved with a large water system would probably allow the system to work better. Other States are investigating -- the fqejlitstion ofwater-m,prkets,. In Qlreensland, for example; the author '-+--c~~~personaHy cttcsttk* the Department of Natural-Resbbices-is currently December 1997 I I I I I 2' R W M Johnson, "Resource Management, Sustainability and Property Rights in New Zealand" (1992) 36 Ausrruliun Journul of Agriculturul Economics 1 67- 1 8 5. 22 J Quiggin, "Common Property, Private Property and Regulation: The Case of Dryland Salinity" (1986) 30 Austruliun Journul rfAgriculturu1 Economics 103- 1 17. 23 So long as a proprietor has not extinguished or used up completely his or her right (to clear or to pollute, for example) then, like any other asset, each bundle of rights will have positive value where a system of transferable rights is instituted. 24 D Zilberman, N MacDougall and F Shah, "Changes in Water Allocation Mechanisms for California Agriculture"(1994) XI1 Contemporury Economic Policy 122- 133. 25 D James, Environmentul Incentives (Environment' -~ustralla,' -Canberra, .*..: 1937). <... r. " * " % - --* . - . - . a . -1-'- r: . 2 -- . - - _- _ _ c -<. -. I + Apart from the incentives imposed by policy prescription in order to encourage socially desirable outcomes, there are market-determined incentives such as prices of output, costs of inputs and the final "golden handshake" when the farm is sold, and other factors such as debt levels which may influence farm decision-making. Whilst it might appear at first consideration that the effects of these incentives on decisions regarding resource conservation is unambiguous, the literature does not reveal clear direction. ~ u r t ~ v o u nthat d relatively high grain prices were an incentive which exacerbated soil erosion in eastern Washington and western Idaho. Choosing to ignore the issue of externalities and social costs caused by sedimentation and pollution of streams caused by agricultural soil ingress, he used depth of topsoil and percentage of organic matter in the top 15 centimetres of soil as two variables which captured the most essential information in a dynamic optimisation problem set in the Palouse area. He concluded resource degradation was generally within "economic limits" but that localised Severe degradation required specialised management techniques. In Australia, a lively debate developed between LaFrance and clarke2' whether increased commodity prices and subsidies acted as incentives to more or less soil degradation. LaFrance initially maintained in agreement with Burt that soil conservation efforts are negatively related to increased revenue. Clarke, on the other hand, held that increasing profitability from favourabre product prices or changes in input factor prices provide an incentive for profit-maximising farmers to increase their investment in the conservation of soil quality when appropriate technologies exist. LaFrance countered with a more sophisticated dynamic model to conclude that higher profits do not increase the incentive to farmers to take better care of the soil. Further, he argued that whilst subsidising conservation expenditure may increase soil conservation, subsidising other farm inputs, such as irrigation water of the Murray-Darling Basin, is likely to promote soil degradation through overuse. Subsidisation of commodity prices is likely to increase degradation, whilst a tax on soil loss is likely to promote soil improvements. Research by Barbier developed and adapted McConnell's basic farrnlevel soil conservation model to the situation in an LDC.2HThe location is the highly-populated uplands of Java in Indonesia, where holdings average less than 0.4 hectares, and subsistence households use cropping systems which result in severe erosion. Erosion is increasing at the rate of 1-2 per cent per annum. Barbier considered economic incentives and other factors which influence farmers' decisions to undertake soil erosion control measures including soil types, prices and profitability of current crops, input subsidies, availability of finance, off-farm employment and land tenure. He concluded that upland subsistence farmers will not modify their land management practices without appropriate economic incentives, and that many government programs such as maintaining relatively high prices for cassava and vegetables and subsidies for fertilisers are antagonistic to the social goal of soil conservation. 26 0 R Burt, "Farm Level Economics of Soil Conservation in the Palouse Area , of the Northwest" (1981) 63 American Journal elf Agricultural Economics 83-92. 27 J T LaFrance, "Supply Response and Soil Conservation are Negatively Related" (1990) Mimeo, Montana State , University; J T Lsrance, "A Dynamic Model of Soil Conservation and Prices", Paper presented to the Workshop on Land Degradation and Sustainable Agriculture, AAES Annual Conference, ' Armidale, (1991); I T LaFrance, "Do Increased Commodity Prices L e d to More or Less Soil Degradation? (1992) ' 36 Australian Journul of Agriculturul Economics 57-82; H R Clarke, "Land Degradation and Prices", Paper presented to the Workshop on Land Degradation and Sustainable Agriculture, AAES Annual Conference, Armidale, (1991); H R Clarke, "The Supply of Non-Degraded Agricultural Land" (1992) 36 Austruliun Journal of Agricultural Economics 3 1-56. 28 K E McConnell, "An Economic Model of Soil Conservation" (1983) 65 Americun Journul elf Agriculturul Econontics 83-89; E B Barbier. "The F m Level Economics of Soil Conservation: The Uplands of Java" (1990) 66 htno Economics 199-2 1 1. Land prices as ml irtcerztive Economic Incentives for arm-L~V~I Resource Conservation Generally the condition or quality of a traded good will have a bearing on the price it can command in the market. Thus it is to be expected that a well-kept or high quality good will command a higher price than a degraded, ill-maintained or poor quality good. Agricultural land theoretically should not be an exception, because the quality of the land (soil depth and structure, inherent fertility and organic matter content) has a direct bearing on the quality and yield of produce grown on it. Even so, the findings of published studies have not been unequivocal. United States studies by Ervin and Mill and Gardner and ~arrows,"for example, of farm land- prices in Iowa and Wisconsin respectively conciuded that a link could not be found between the use of conservation practices and structures and the prices of the land, when eventually sold. In contrast, King and sinden"' analysed the farm land market in Manilla Shire in central New South Wales and concluded that the market clearly recognised the condition of the land and accorded a premium to land of higher quality. In the first of two studies of the formation of price in the rural land market, King and Sinden employed the hedonic approach, which uses the relationship between attributes of a good and observed prices to explain differenced in market prices. Several variables which were theorised as significant attributes of rural land were defined, measured and tested in two model specifications. Among these variables were several which related to land productivity, cost of recommended remedial action, slope, soil loss and priority for receipt of government soil conservation funding. These authors found that land condition influenced price more profoundly than immediate expectations of higher yields. Other influences may well have been the desire to acquire productive and better managed soils (the stewardship ethic) and a wish to avoid future costs of rectification of symptoms of land degradation. In the course of completing this research task, King and Sinden realised the land market was more complex than they had initially envisaged. Some other issues which had to be considered and incorporated into models, if possible, were the relative influence or market power of buyers and sellers, characteristics of the market, the differential values placed on land characteristics by buyers and sellers, and the influence of the bargaining or sale process. Four models were specified and estimated. 'Among other findings not relevant to this article, King and Sinden concluded land in better condition sold for higher prices and buyers valued soil conservation more highly than did the sellers. In terms of the usefulness of economic incentives, it appears sellers generally did not incorporate a land price premium into their consideration of soil conservation activities. Insights gained from this research spurred Sinden and ~ i n g ) 'to consider the usefulness of education of buyers and the provision of information on the erosion status and environmental quality of sale I 29 1, E Ervin and J w Mill, "Agricultural Land Markets and Soil Erosion: Policy Relevance and Concep- ~ ~ ~ ~~ ~~ ~ ' ~ , " r A ~ n~ ~ $ ~u r f ~ 938-942: K Gardner and R Barrows, "The of Soil Conservation ~ n : vestments on Land prices" (1985) 67 American (?fAgricufturaLEconomics 943-947. I, A King and A Sinden, "Influence of Soil Conservation 'on Farm Land Values" (1988) 64 Land A King and Economics 242-255; J A sinden. "Price Formation in Farm Land ~ a r k & " (1994) 70 lrutd Econ- mia act , - - - - , - for a scheme based on this incentive December 1997 22 1 i I Debt-levels as an incentive High levels of farm debt have been implicated, together with small farm size, with increasing resource degradation. These factors, it has been argued, are especially relevant when coupled with declining terms of farm trade. Biological degradation of arid rangelands is of concern in most continents. Focusing on the over-grazing and consequent degradation of the 19 million hectares of the mulga (Acacia aneura) zone in south-west Queensland, Passmore and ~rown'' developed a dynamic optimisation model incorporating the initial state of the pastures, the financial position of the operator, expectations of market prices and rainfall, attitude to risk, planning horizon and business objective. They concluded that high stocking rates were positively related to small property size, the fine wool effect?4 debt levels and current financial needs, a lesser degree of risk aversion, and short planning period. The dominant constraint on more optimal stocking rates was found to be small property size. Policy-makers may promote property build-up with the incentives of subsidies and taxation concessions but, in the absence of appropriate ecological information and a change in attitude of individual operators, these incentives may merely prolong the financial survival of smaller properties, an outcome which may not be consistent with the longterm health of the agroecosystem. Small property size in many regions of Australia is a legacy of a past policy which is no longer appropriate. Historically, Australian governments were committed to "closer settlement", a policy which placed settlers on the land with minimum "living areas" at the time. Because agricultural terms of trade have declined virtually in a steeply linear fashion since the 1950s, properties subdivided with a minimal allowance for declining financial margins have become too small to support a family without degrading the natural resources. Small property size and over-use of resources are related. Sinden and Jones3' considered the problem of eucalypt dieback in the southern New England district of northern New South Wales. The immediate effect of death of the trees and reduction of the tree biomass was an increase in pasture production, a consequent increase in canying capacity and an increase in farm income. There was thus an observable short run gain at the expense of biodiversity. At that time, scientists had no explanation for the dieback phenomenon, although it was suspected that biological simplification was implicated. ow ever, it had been observed that eucalypts were least affected by dieback in patches which retained a wide variety of species including trees, shrubs and herbs. Thus, although graziers were not able to pinpoint the exact management practice which would maintain their mature trees, they could manage their properties to retain their mature eucalypts by cutting stocking rates and fencing off remnant forest patches. s2 That is, prices unE&stic in of productive potential. There may well be a future subdivision premium. G Passmore and C Brown, "Analysis of Rangeland Degradation using Stochastic Dynamic prop-- ~ ~ ~ ~ c ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ Of w~ i stocfing ~ h tend ~ to~lead less well fed sheep which may produce finer wool- Fier wool is of higher to 2 ~ ~ g , " ' e ~ n ~ ~ V ~ g ~~ vressure to underfeed sheep to produce and likely to produce costly sheep deaths and l&d degradation, as well & being unethical. ~~~~~~k aiiA$t E: Stc!)gJgs in New England, New wales" (1985) 29 Australian joum1 of Agricultural Economics 149- 156. I Conclusion Agricultural producers decide on the crops to grow and the animal species to husband, and these decisions are accompanied by decisions on the types and levels of inputs necessary to their production. A further complication of primary production is that the inputs of natural capital, soil, water and biological resources, may be used up and, unlike in many other productive processes using man-made capital, exhausted without the scope for easy replacement. Economic incentives are part of the framework within which primary producers operate. The imposition of tax and subsidy regimes by governments to try to change community behaviour has generally found considerable support among economists. The evidence from the literature suggests that, whilst subsidies have been used, seldom have taxes been imposed on activities causing degradation at the farm level. One of the most important reasons for this is the lack of political will of governments to impose additional cost burdens on the often financially-faltering family farm. Some incentives have worked as intended and channelled industry towards resource conserving practices. Other incentives have had unintended effects and many have been difficult to administer at the practical level. Specification of land management standards and focusing programs towards the regions and landscapes which would yield the most efficient results have been offered as policies. However, research results have suggested that such transfer payments may be earned inequitably by those most able to afford unaided conservation efforts. 1n the final analysis, it appears that the extent of conservation activities depends on the degree of altruism in managers' outlooks, rather than on economic incentives currently available. - Economic Incentives for Farm-Level Resource Conservation