THE PRACTICE OF CONTRACTING IN PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS: TRANSACTION COSTS AND RELATIONAL CONTRACTING IN THE IRISH SCHOOLS SECTOR Eoin Reeves Department of Economics University of Limerick Limerick Ireland Abstract This paper explores the practice of contracting in public private partnerships. Focusing on the first Irish PPP to provide secondary schools, it draws on perspectives from transaction cost economics and socio-legal theory. It finds that the ex ante contractual setting was undermined by pushing forward with the PPP before conducting an adequate level of project appraisal. It explores the experiences of key stakeholders in the ex post contracting stage and concludes that the conduct of contracting practice was not characterized by the shift to relational contracting expected under PPP. Whereas, this approach to contractual governance did not hinder the development of broadly trusting relations between the client and contractor, this was not manifest in terms of relations between the contractor and schools. A significant degree of conflict was evident in some schools-contractor relations, which can be attributed to sources of transaction costs including incomplete information, bounded rationality and uncertainty. Forthcoming in Public Administration Key Words: Public Private Partnerships, Contracting, Schools, Ireland. THE PRACTICE OF CONTRACTING IN PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS: TRANSACTION COSTS AND RELATIONAL CONTRACTING IN THE IRISH SCHOOLS SECTOR INTRODUCTION In 1999 the Irish government launched a pilot programme of Public Private Partnerships (PPPs) as part of the effort to address the country’s severe deficit of physical infrastructure. In simplest terms the case for PPP over traditional forms of public procurement was articulated in terms of speedier delivery of projects and better value for money (VFM) (Department of Finance 2001). These arguments proved persuasive and the proposed PPP programme expanded rapidly. This was recognised in a review of worldwide PPP activity by global consultancy firm Deloitte (2007) that categorised Ireland along with Australia and the UK as the countries with the most mature PPP markets. Against the claims in favour of PPP there is a growing body of critical literature, which provides grounds for questioning the rationale for adopting this procurement model (for example, Quiggin 2001; Ball et al 2001). The basic VFM case has been questioned on the basis that it can only be achieved if financial savings under PPP outweigh the relatively higher borrowing costs faced by the private sector. Also, there is increased recognition that new institutional arrangements such as PPP involve significant transaction costs, which are in addition to those costs that are measurable in financial terms. As the PPP model of procuring infrastructure and services typically involves features such as lengthy procurement processes and the management of relations over periods as long as 30 years, the resultant demands on 1 the resources of both buyers and sellers must be considered when assessing the appropriateness, or otherwise, of institutional arrangements such as PPP. The focus of this paper is on the practice of contracting under PPP. The research explores whether or not PPP involves relational contracting? Such a practice of contracting would involve high levels of co-operation and trust and reduced transaction costs thereby improving the prospects for economic efficiency. The paper is structured as follows. It begins with a general discussion on the case for PPPs and the development of the PPP programme in Ireland. It proceeds to develop a theoretical framework for analysing PPP projects. The framework is based on transaction cost economics, supplemented by socio-legal theory and perspectives on contractual governance. The framework is then applied for the purpose of analysing the first PPP project in Ireland to reach the stage of operation. As the procurement of the contract to design, build, operate and finance five secondary schools was completed in 2003 the analysis in this paper covers both the ex ante and ex post stages of this PPP. PPPs IN IRELAND In June 1999 the Irish Minister for Finance, Mr. Charlie McCreevy announced the decision to experiment with PPPs as a method for procuring public infrastructure and services. Initially eight pilot PPP projects were announced in the roads (4), schools (2) environment (1) and public transport (1) sectors and the number of PPP projects has subsequently increased on a steady basis. By the end of 2005 PPP projects were 2 under procurement in sectors including roads, environment (waste and water), health (nursing homes), schools, prisons, courts services and social housing. Despite this expansion, the implementation of the PPP programme has encountered difficulties. By mid-2003, four years after the announcement of the pilot projects, the procurement process had been completed in just three cases, two of which were in the schools sector (Reeves, 2003). At this point the PPP programme was the subject of strong criticism from the private sector with respect to aspects such as the extent of deal flow, the level of public sector skills in the context of procuring PPPs and the costs involved in bidding for PPP contracts. The fiscal treatment of PPP expenditures presented a significant obstacle in terms of mobilising the PPP programme. The potential for PPP as a means of keeping capital expenditures off-balance sheet had undoubted appeal for the Irish government which was committed to keeping within the fiscal constraints imposed by membership of the single European currency. Uncertainty in relation to this issue was exemplified in the case of the PPP to build the Cork Music School. Although a preferred bidder had been selected, the Department of Finance would not recommend approval of the project on the grounds that the full capital cost would be counted in the General Government Balance (GGB) figures and treated as Gross Fixed Capital Formation of general government spread across the period of construction. Approval for the project was only granted after Eurostat issued a clarification about the accounting treatment of PPP expenditures in February 2004. In its clarification Eurostat recommended that “the assets involved in a public-private partnership should be classified as nongovernment assets, and therefore recorded off balance sheet for government, if both of 3 the following conditions are met: (1) the private partner bears the construction risk, and (2) the private partner bears at least one of either availability or demand risk” (Eurostat 2004, p.1). Despite these problems the government has demonstrated continued faith in the PPP model. Buoyed by the fact that two PPP roads projects in addition to the PPP to build five secondary schools were completed ahead of schedule, the government announced a number of significant PPP projects in late 2005. These include an expansion of the PPP programme in the education (buildings at primary, secondary and University levels) and health (national radiotherapy network) sectors and the announcement of the PPP to provide a national conference centre. In November 2005 the government unveiled a transport plan, which commits to invest over €34 billion by 2015 with €8 billion coming from the private sector. A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSING PPPs From the outset, the case for adopting PPPs in Ireland has been largely predicated on the basis that PPPs would deliver better VFM compared to traditional procurement. This has been explained in terms of features of PPP including: competition for contracts; bundling the elements of the project life-cycle; risk transfer and superior private sector innovation (Department of Finance 2001). In theoretical terms, the proposition of better VFM under PPP is broadly in accordance with the neo-classical view of markets where firms are assumed to maximize profits, individuals are assumed to be self-seeking and rational, and there is perfect information. Although the neo-classical view of markets provides theoretical support for market-based 4 reforms such as PPP it is open to criticism on the basis that it focuses entirely on production costs. Such costs however constitute just one element of economic efficiency. A wider perspective on economic efficiency embraces transaction costs. These are the costs that arise in organising a competitive tendering process as well as writing, monitoring and enforcing contracts. As the central plank of ‘new institutional economics’ transaction cost economics represents an important contribution to understanding issues such as contracting practice and choices concerning the coordination of economic activity (e.g. market, hierarchy, outsourcing, strategic alliances). Nevertheless, the limitations of adopting a purely economic perspective need to be recognized. Investigations of how economic activity is organized have engaged the attention of those across a host of disciplines including law, psychology and sociology. With this in mind, the analysis of PPP presented in this paper goes beyond the transaction cost framework and is primarily supplemented by aspects of socio-legal theory. This approach facilitates an analysis of aspects of contracting practice such as the quality of contractual relations under PPP. It also addresses questions such as the degree to which the contracting process is co-operative or conflictual and the role of contract and other mechanisms in co-ordinating economic activity in a PPP context. Economic and socio-legal perspectives of contracting As PPPs entail contracting between the private sector and government under conditions of imperfect information, the literature on the ‘economics of contracting’ provides useful insights into the practice of contracting under PPP. The theory of transaction costs, initially developed by Ronald Coase (1937) and built upon and 5 popularized by Oliver Williamson (1975; 1985; 1996), is fundamental to the ‘economics of contracting’. Transaction costs are essentially the costs of using the market and include “costs of negotiation and writing contingent contracts; costs of monitoring contractual performance; costs of enforcing contractual promises; and costs associated with breaches of contractual promises” (Rahman and Kumaraswamy, 2002:46). Consideration of transaction costs sheds light on issues including the choice of procurement method (for example, PPP) and the practice of contracting after contracts are signed. Central to the theory of transaction costs is imperfect information. The theory of transaction costs recognizes that agreement and exchange frequently occurs in the context of parties possessing imperfect information about all aspects of the exchange. Moreover, in some cases, exchange is characterized by information asymmetries with one party to the transaction possessing knowledge that other parties do not. The concept of bounded rationality recognizes the limits on human foresight and cognition and how these limits give rise to transaction costs, especially in the context of imperfect information and uncertainty. Opportunism refers to ‘the incomplete or distorted disclosure of information, especially to calculated efforts to mislead, distort, disguise, obfuscate or otherwise confuse’ (Williamson 1985, pp. 47-48). Taken together, bounded rationality and opportunism give rise to the possibility that one or other of the parties to exchange will exploit their information advantage at either the pre- or post-contractual stages. 6 The danger of opportunism is increased where there is asset specificity. This refers to the degree to which investments associated with the transaction are specific to the parties involved. Specific investments have little or no use outside the transaction in question and can lead to a situation of bilateral monopoly where both parties are confined to exchange with each other (Walsh 1995). In other words, both parties are ‘locked-in’ to the exchange. Asymmetric lock-in occurs where one party has made the majority of specific investments. Any resultant shift in the balance of power creates scope for opportunistic behaviour or ‘hold-up’ whereby one party attempts to exploit the dependency of the other party which has been brought about by the latter’s specific investment. The danger of hold-up is increased where there are few alternative parties with whom to contract (i.e. small numbers exchange). As uncertainty and asset specificity together with repeat trading become more significant features of the exchange, transaction cost analysis predicts the emergence of ‘relational contracting’. Williamson (1985) describes relational contracting as a means of displacing neo-classical contracting due to progressively increasing duration and complexity of contract. The reference point for effecting adaptations is not the original agreement. Instead the reference point under a relational agreement is the ‘entire relation as it has developed [through] time. This may or may not include an original agreement and if it does, may or may not result in great deference being given it’ (Williamson 1985, p.72). Relational contracting is closely associated with partnerships and strategic alliances and involves long-term social exchange between parties, mutual trust, interpersonal attachment, and commitment to specific partners, altruism and problem solving (Darwin et al 2000). 7 The relational contracting context, which characterizes arrangements expected under PPP, leads parties to supplement formal contractual clauses with more informal mechanisms. Insights into these dimensions of the practice of contracting have been illuminated by socio-legal theorists (for example, Vincent-Jones and Harries 1995a; 1995b; Deakin and Wilkinson 1995, Campbell, 2001, Vincent-Jones 2006) who have drawn on perspectives including transaction cost analysis to explore the quality of transaction processes considered with reference to how conflict and co-operation in the management and adjustment of various kinds of exchange are related to the uses made of different forms of governance structure, both contractual and extracontractual. This approach owes much to Macaulay (1963) who found that the contractual process in business relationships has relatively little connection with traditional contract law. His empirical studies confirmed Weber’s observations on the importance of the noncontractual elements of business relationships including loyalty, co-operation and trust (Deakin and Michie 1997, pp.19-20). Frankel (1977) describes trust as the 'binding cement of all relationships' (Quoted in Davis and Walker 1997, p.3). It provides the basis for confidence that the obligations and commitments undertaken in incomplete contracts will be met. Its presence can promote co-operation and reduce transaction costs in relationships based on long term or repeated exchange. The great benefit of trust is that it is efficient; the more there is trust the less necessary it is to engage in detailed and expensive monitoring of performance (Walsh 1995). As the threat of opportunism increases there are strong incentives for cementing relations. Co-operative utility maximisation is viewed as the basis for efficient long 8 term contracting (Campbell and Harris 1993). It should be noted however that the concept of efficiency referred to here is ‘dynamic’ rather than static (technical or allocative). Dynamic efficiency is enhanced by innovation and the introduction of new goods and new processes and takes time to accrue. The concept of dynamic efficiency is of particular relevance to PPPs, which are typically promoted on the basis of features such as output-specification and risk transfer which are viewed as drivers of superior private sector innovation. PPPs constitute a significant change in public procurement practice and proponents commonly make claims for the PPP model on the basis of the benefits derived from establishing collaborative relationships based on ‘shared vision, authority, information, planning, decision making, financial risk, responsibility and accountability’ (Langford 2001, p.3). The framework described in this paper is designed to examine the quality of the transaction processes in the case of PPP. Its particular focus is on the transaction cost features of the relationship. The starting point of the analysis is the recognition that whilst the high costs of managing and adjusting conflictual transactions might be outweighed by financial savings in some cases, there is likely to be a strong association between co-operation and dynamic efficiency (Deakin and Wilkinson 1995). Moreover this analysis is mindful of the distinctive challenges that arise in the case of PPPs as illuminated by Vincent-Jones (2006) who argues in his extensive socio-legal analysis of ‘new public contracting’ that economic contracting regimes such PPP ‘Tend to be particularly cumbersome, complex, and convoluted in operation. The question is whether these regimes are capable of succeeding where bureaucracies and 9 markets have failed; or rather, given all governance arrangements are imperfect, whether in any particular case this mode of economic coordination is better that the next best alternative’ (2006, pp.357-358). With these views in mind, this paper examines the practice of contracting in the case of a PPP to build and operate five secondary schools. First, the ex ante contractual setting is examined in terms of factors that present potential obstacles to co-operative contracting. These are identified with reference to the theoretical considerations discussed above as well as literature on public procurement practice. This is followed by analysis of the conduct of exchange after the schools were constructed and in operation. Factors affecting the quality of contractual exchange A number of writers (e.g. Parker and Hartley 2003; Vincent-Jones and Harries 1995a; and Lonsdale 2005) have examined the practice of public-private sector contracting in the context of market-based reforms such as contracting-out and PPPs. These writers have drawn attention to the following factors, which potentially hinder the achievement of co-operative exchange and dynamic efficiency: Un-developed and unstable markets resulting in insufficient competition for contracts; Over-emphasis on price and insufficient regard to quality at the stage of contract award; 10 Loss-leading behaviour and lack of contracting experience on the part of clients; The nature of the pre-contractual power relations; The relative commercial resources of the two parties to the transaction; The relative importance of the transaction to the two parties and The relative switching costs faced by the two parties to the transaction. Uncompetitive markets, loss-leading and over-emphasis on contract price A fundamental requirement for successful procurement is effective competition for contracts and the benefits of competitive tendering in terms of improvements in productive efficiency (cost reduction) are well documented (see Domberger and Jensen 1997 for a review). A number of factors can however condition the degree of competition required to meet contracting objectives. These include the problem of small numbers exchange at the initial tendering or re-tendering stage and loss-leading behaviour by bidders. Vincent-Jones and Harries (1995a) draw attention to the strong possibility of ‘transaction problems due to underbidding, whether deliberate or inadvertent, and the “winners curse” according to which a winning bidder is likely to have over-estimated the value of the object and hence be unable to perform to the specification without cutting corners’ (1995a, p.6). The probability of such outcomes is increased where public sector clients attach disproportionate weighting to contract price. 11 Asymmetric power relations and the importance of the transaction to both parties Lonsdale (2005) examines the issue of asymmetric lock-in whereby one party becomes dependent on the other thereby empowering the latter to engage in the relationship on the terms of its own choosing. He emphasizes the case where the buyer is the party in a position of dependency. In a PPP context this can result in the supplier passing back the risk transferred in the original agreement. Contrary to the thrust of orthodox (Williamsonian) transaction cost analysis which sees the protection of contractor’s reputation as a safeguard against exploiting contractual power, Lonsdale views any imbalance of power relations at the pre-contractual stage, as a threat to efficient exchange. In such circumstances the supplier may wish to ‘perpetuate its dominance’ at later stages of the relationship (Lonsdale 2005 p.74). In addition, asymmetric lock-in is possible when the importance of the transaction to a buyer is greater than it is to the supplier. If the supplier recognizes that the public sector is constrained by its statutory obligations to provide for key services they can exploit this knowledge as leverage when negotiating at the post-contractual stage. Unequal resources Grimshaw et al (2002) and Lonsdale (2005) draw attention to the lack of expertise, experience, or resources on the part of public sector clients as an obstacle to cooperative exchange. It is widely recognized that the procurement process under PPP is longer and significantly more complex compared to traditional procurement. In cases where “the purchasing function of the buying organization possesses inferior resources, in terms of capacities and capabilities, to the sales team of the supplier…. 12 [T]his can lead to the purchasing organisation signing an inappropriate contract – through sheer pressure of time as much as anything else” (Lonsdale 2005, p.74). A similar outcome can occur where a procurement model is imposed on the public sector client by government. The Institute for Public Policy Research (IPPR) (2001) warn of the inappropriateness of adopting the PPP model of procurement as the ‘only game in town’ or where there is political pressure to urgently complete the project subject to tight deadlines. Switching costs Failed business relationships, particularly under long-term contractual arrangements for the delivery of important public services, impose significant costs on all parties. One set of costs involves switching an organisation’s resources from one contract to another. The potential of high switching costs (including the political embarrassment of failing to secure satisfactory service delivery) is higher in cases where one party has made most of the required specific investments. Consequent asymmetric lock-in can become manifest in terms of failure to impose penalties or negotiate hard when the need arises. The factors discussed above create the wider setting for contracting under PPP. Moreover, they influence the conduct of exchange once contracts are signed and services are being provided. Among the main factors that have a direct bearing on the quality of exchange is the balance between strict adherence to the terms of the contract and reliance on non-contractual mechanisms such as flexibility, goodwill and trust. The socio-legal and relational contracting literature suggests that over-referral 13 to the precise terms of the contract by either party, particularly with respect to factors such as mechanisms for dealing with poor performance (e.g. penalty points and deductions in payment) can damage the conduct of exchange and impact negatively on dynamic efficiency. On the other hand, it must be noted that loose, informal contracting may lead to a business relationship that is ‘too cosy’ and may not prove acceptable when ‘set against accepted and expected standards for the conduct of public life’ (Davis and Walker 1997, p.52). The following sections seek to bear these considerations in mind when examining the nature of contracting practice in the case of Ireland’s first PPP. ANALYSING THE FIVE SCHOOLS PPP Ex ante analysis: the contractual setting and procurement process The contract for a group of five schools was announced as one of the original group of pilot projects in June 1999. In 2001, the private sector consortium led by Jarvis Projects Limited (Jarvis) was contracted to design, build, operate and finance the five schools over a 25-year period. Construction of the five schools was completed in approximately one year, which compares favourably with an average of two years for schools constructed using conventional procurement (Dail Eireann, Committee of Public Accounts 2005). All five schools were opened in January 2003. A number of factors relevant to dimensions of the pre-contractual setting discussed above served to shape the procurement process for this PPP. The experience with this pilot project suggests a robust degree of competition for contracts in the schools 14 sector. Following the issue of initial notice in the Official Journal of the European Community in June 2000, a total of twelve expressions of interest were received. Six pre-qualification bids were invited and a final shortlist of three detailed tenders was completed. The preferred bidder, Jarvis, was selected in February 2001 and the contract documents were signed in November 2001. When interviewed in February 2006, the official in the PPP unit at the Department of Education and Science (DoES) with chief responsibility for the PPP expressed satisfaction with the degree of competition for the contract and stressed that the pitfalls associated with overemphasis on the criterion of contract price (i.e. winners curse) were avoided as the lowest bid was rejected on the basis of inferior design. The question of risk allocation, which is a key feature of the PPP model, was negotiated between the client and contractor on the basis of a risk transfer matrix used by the DoES. The private sector takes full responsibility for risk in relation to school design, construction, and operation of the contract whereas the public sector assumes demand risk and residual value risk. Risks in relation to project finance, planning and business regulation risks are shared. Normal business regulation risk is mainly carried by the private sector whereas industry specific regulation is solely carried by the public sector. It is worth noting that in its assessment of the procurement process the Comptroller and Auditor General (C&AG) concluded that risks were appropriately retained by the public sector but that the level of risk transferred to Jarvis was ‘limited’ (2004: 52) accounting for 6.9% of the overall estimated cost of procuring the schools by conventional means. 15 The C&AG’s report also highlighted a number of relevant shortcomings in the procurement process. Whereas the DoES estimated that the PPP would yield cost savings of 6%, the C&AG found that this estimate was subject to error and that the PPP would be between 8% and 13% more expensive than under traditional procurement. In addition the C&AG was critical of the decision to appoint the preferred bidder prior to conducting the VFM test and the failure to establish an affordability cap. As this project was the first of eight pilot projects announced in 1999 there was a significant degree of prestige attached to this PPP. This raised the relative importance of the project to the public sector and provides a plausible explanation for the push to complete the procurement process and build the five schools. The resources provided for procuring this PPP also deserve mention. The dedicated PPP Unit within the DoES, which handled the procurement process, consists of just two civil servants. As a consequence the DoES relied heavily on external advisers to carry out project evaluation and management functions necessary to develop the project. According to the C&AG, fees paid to these external advisers amounted to €401,200. The evident inexperience of the public sector client can be viewed in contrast to knowledge accumulated by the private contractor, Jarvis, which had been successful in a number of PFI schools projects in the UK. Ex post analysis: the practice of contracting The principal objective of the analysis of ex-post contractual exchange in this paper is to determine whether it possesses the features required for the achievement of 16 dynamic efficiency. It therefore probes whether high levels of trust and co-operation characterize the PPP relationship. For this purpose the study adopts a framework developed by Macneil (1978; 1985), which conceptualizes contractual relationships in terms of two extreme types. The first, a transactional approach to governance, ‘involves a formal adversarial relationship between brokers and participants characterized by economic exchange, short-termism and zero conflict of interest in which integration and control are achieved through the implementation of contractual specifications and the discipline of (quasi-) market forces’ (Darwin et al 2000, p.40). At the other extreme is relational contracting which is associated with forms of contracting such as partnerships and alliances and is characterized by features such as informality, shared problem solving, co-operation and mutual trust. The data used for this stage of the research was gathered during interviews with the private contractor, the official in the DoES with chief responsibility for the PPP and each of the five school principals. As part of the semi-structured interviews (which were conducted over the period January-March 2006), interviewees were also asked to complete a pro forma questionnaire concerning dimensions of the client-contractor relationship. The questionnaire was based on the contractual governance framework developed by Macneil. Interviewees were asked, where feasible and appropriate, to apply scores to ten dimensions of the client-contractor relationship that are intended to distinguish between those relationships that are mainly transactional and those that are more relational in nature. For example, one of the dimensions drawn from Macneil’s framework concerns the extent to which the written contract binds the parties. This 17 dimension of the relationship is considered transactional if the contract agreement binds the parties totally. Alternatively, this dimension is considered to be relational if the agreement is tentative. A scale of 1-10 was adopted with 1 representing the transactional pole and 10 representing the relational pole. This follows the approach adopted in studies of competitive tendering in the UK public sector by Walker and Davis (1999) and Darwin et al (2000). It should be noted that prominent socio-legal scholars (Campbell, 2001, VincentJones, 2001) have been critical of analysis based on the transactional-relational spectrum. For example Vincent-Jones (2001) argues that these studies demonstrate the ‘importance of trust and co-operation in exchange relationships, and have contributed to our overall understanding of relational contracting. However, in comparison with the potential scope of relational theory as set out in Macneil’s recent clarification, the analyses appear unduly limited by an ideal-type methodology based on the polar opposition of discrete and relational contracts’ (2001, p.78). While recognizing the wider debate that covers these limitations as well as exploring how Macneil’s ideas might be applied more productively, it should be noted that the ex post analysis of contractual relations in this paper recognizes that the contract is unlikely to be entirely relational or entirely transactional. Rather it is likely to have elements of both. In this context the transactional-relational spectrum is adopted on the grounds that it serves as a useful basis for describing the differing relationships, 18 which have developed in this PPP, and proceeding to explore why they have developed in these ways. Details of the ten aspects of contractual governance examined are provided in table 1. The respondents were also asked to provide an overall assessment of the relationship in terms of the degree to which it was characterized by co-operation, flexibility and trust. These were also presented in terms of extremes (e.g. low-trust to high-trust) and respondents were requested to score these aspects on a scale of 1-10. Whereas this subjective scaling helped identify the differing relationships developing under PPP, the research also sought to identify the key factors shaping the development of relationships by posing open-ended questions concerning important issues and events which arose in the course of the contract, how they arose, how they were resolved and the approaches of relevant stakeholders. Findings PPP contracts are characterized by complexity in relation to aspects such as the number of parties involved (e.g. contractors, sub-contractors, financiers and service users) and the extensive documentation in PPP contracts. These complexities must be taken into account when seeking to examine the quality of the contracting relationship under PPP. In this case study it is recognised that while the formal contractual arrangement is between the DoES and the private contractor, a full analysis of contractual governance also requires an assessment of the relationship between the contractor and the schools. As a consequence this examination of the public-private 19 sector relationship under PPP focuses specifically on the relationship between (1) the DoES and Jarvis and (2) the schools and Jarvis. TABLE 1: THE POLES OF TRANSACTIONAL AND RELATIONAL CONTRACT RELATIONSHIPS Transactional Pole Relational Pole Communication Communication is limited and formal. Communication Communication is extensive and both formal and informal Contract The contract document plays little or no role in terms of dealing with issues as they arise. Contract The contract document is referred to extensively for the purpose of dealing with issues as they arise. Planning Initial planning is complete and specific – only remote contingencies are not covered. Bargaining There is little or no bargaining as the contract proceeds. Binding The contract agreement binds the parties totally. Cooperation Almost no cooperation is required after the start of the contract. Planning There is limited specific planning at the beginning. Bargaining The contract involves extended mutual planning – a ‘joint creative effort’. Binding The agreement is tentative. Cooperation The success of the contract is entirely dependent on further cooperation in both performance and planning. Benefits and Burdens There is unspecified sharing of both benefits and burdens. Rules and Rights Rules and benefits are non-specific and nonmeasurable. Altruism There is significant expectation of altruistic behaviour. Problems The possibility of trouble is anticipated and dealt with by co-operation. Benefits and Burdens Each particular benefit and burden is specifically assigned to one party. Rules and Rights Specific rules and rights are applicable, usually measured in monetary terms. Altruism No altruistic behaviour is expected or occurs. Problems Unplanned problems in performance or among participants are not expected. If they occur, they are covered by specific rules. Source: Adapted from Walker and Davis (1999), Darwin et al (2000). DoES and contractor relations 20 The results in table 2 indicate that both the DoES and Jarvis see the current exchange as distinctly transactional. It is particularly noteworthy that this view was held more strongly by the public sector client. The only aspect of the relationship that was viewed as strongly relational by both parties was the role of co-operation as a basis for ensuring successful exchange. There was a significant difference in the views regarding the use of the contract when contingencies arose. Whereas the client expressed the view that the contract played a strong role in dealing with contingencies, the contractor asserted that they frequently handled contingencies by working flexibly outside the terms of the contract. This assessment was reflected in the contractor’s view that the relationship was characterized by an appreciable degree of altruism on their part. TABLE 2: CLIENT’S (DOES) AND CONTRACTOR’S VIEWS OF CURRENT CONTRACT RELATIONSHIPS Dimensions of Current Relationship Communication Role of Contract Planning Bargaining Binding Co-operation Benefits and Burdens Rules and Rights Altruism Problems Client Contractor 2 2 1 1 1 6 1 1 2 3 5 8 3 4 1 8 3 3 5 3 Table 3 presents the data on actual and preferred aspects of the relationship. The data indicates a salient preference for a mainly transactional relationship on the parts of both client and contractor. While similar preferences were found in comparable studies (e.g. Walker and Davis 1999; Darwin et al 2000) these were confined to aspects such as complete initial planning, specification of rules and rights and the binding character of the contract. It is striking that respondents in the case of this 21 study expressed a preference for a transactional approach to aspects such as communication and the degree to which the contract document should be used to regulate the exchange. This was notably true of the public sector client who revealed a marked preference for referring to the contract document when problems arose – a preference that is consistent with his initial expectation that the contract would cover most contingencies. TABLE 3: CLIENT’S (DOES) AND CONTRACTOR’S VIEWS OF CURRENT AND PREFERRED CONTRACT RELATIONSHIPS Dimensions of Relationship Communication Role of Contract Planning Bargaining Binding Co-operation Benefits and Burdens Rules and Rights Altruism Problems Average Client Current 2 2 1 1 1 6 1 1 2 3 2 Client Preferred 3 2 2 8 1 8 2 2 8 2 3.8 Contractor Current 5 8 3 4 1 8 3 3 5 3 4.3 Contractor Preferred 3 5 3 3 3 10 3 3 1 8 4.2 TABLE 4: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE QUALITY OF PPP RELATIONSHIP Client Contractor Un-Cooperative (1) – Cooperative (10) 8 6 Inflexible (1) – Flexible (10) 5.5 6 Low Trust (1) – High Trust (10) 8 8 Despite these views of the relationship as largely transactional it is important to note that both client and contractor consider their relationship to be characterized by high levels of cooperation and trust (see table 4). While a number of issues have proved difficult to resolve, both parties consider the PPP contract to be working well and expressed satisfaction with the approach adopted by their partners. The broadly cooperative nature of the relationship has been evident in terms of the mutually satisfactory handling of contingencies and variations arising in the course of the 22 contract and the non-application of formal sanctions in the case of poor performance (i.e. default points or deductions). Overall, the responses from both the public and private sector parties indicate an approach to contractual governance that is neither strictly transactional nor strictly relational. This is to be expected. ‘No real life co-operation will be found entirely transactional; it will involve at least some whole personal relations, some diffuse communication and some non-economic personal satisfaction. Nor will contractual relations be found entirely lacking in transactional discreteness, if such lack of discreteness is indeed humanly possible’ (Rahman and Kumaraswamy 2002, p.47). A question that naturally arises concerns the factors explaining the transactional and relational aspects of the relationship. With respect to the former, it must be recognized that the responses in terms of aspects derived from Macneil’s framework present a picture that is at odds with the expectation that partnerships are associated with a relational approach to contractual governance. However, it can be noted that empirical studies of business practice (for example, Macaulay 1963; Beale and Dugdale 1975; and Darwin et al 2000) generally find a transactional approach to aspects such as planning the contract and its basic parameters (e.g. price, specification, assignment of rules and rights and an expectation that the contract is binding to a large degree). In addition, there are other factors specific to this PPP that have shaped a transactional approach. First, the contract in question is a pilot project and the first such arrangement in the Irish schools sector. Hence, the largely 23 transactional approach observed in the first three years of this contract is consistent with the proposition advanced by Sako (1992) who proposed that new contracting arrangements will engender a transactional approach, particularly in the early stages of the relationship. Second, the belief expressed by the public sector that the contract would deal with all eventualities offers a possible explanation for a preferred transactional approach to the use of the contract document to deal with issues. In addition, the expressed preference for a formal approach to communication (with a particular emphasis on the helpdesk system of providing information) can, to a degree, be attributed to public sector resource constraints (there are two civil servants working in PPP Unit in the DoES) and a set of schools that is geographically dispersed. The factors lending to the view of a mainly transactional relationship must however be set beside other aspects that have governed the relationship to date. These include the long-term (25 year) nature of the PPP contract, which has provided incentives for fostering a cooperative approach in the interest of sustaining the relationship. For example, both parties provided examples of cooperative behaviour on the part of the private contractor. These include the replacement of equipment and the provision of some small-scale facilities outside the terms of the contract. In some cases these issues arose due to incomplete specifications provided by the DoES. Whereas incomplete specifications can provide scope for disagreement and conflict the responses in this case suggest that the contractor was willing to demonstrate the flexibility and goodwill expected in the context of relational contracting. In addition, it has been noted that aspects associated with a low trust environment have not characterized this public-private exchange. There was no evidence presented of 24 excessive monitoring such as extensive inspection. Moreover, problems that have arisen to date have largely been resolved on the basis of negotiation and a degree of reciprocity rather than immediate imposition of financial penalties. Although the nonimposition of financial penalties is consistent with a more relational approach to contractual governance it does raise questions about the de facto extent of risk transfer, which is an important feature of contracting under PPP. This issue is addressed in the next section. Schools and contractor relations Although this PPP contract is formally agreed between the DoES and Jarvis, a complete analysis of contractual governance in this context requires a focus on the relationship between the private contractor and the service user (i.e. the schools). To examine these contractual relationships, structured interviews were conducted with each of the five school principals. These interviews (which were conducted over the period January-March 2006) were structured along the same lines as those conducted with the DoES and Jarvis. Interviewees were asked to complete the pro forma questionnaire concerning dimensions of the client-contractor relationship in terms of transactional and relational aspects as well as discussing issues concerning their degree of satisfaction with the new school building and standard of service supplied by the private contractor. The scores attributed to different aspects of the current relationship are detailed in table 5. It can be seen that, on average, the five schools indicated a view of the relationship that is largely transactional with average scores of less than five recorded 25 for seven of the ten aspects covered. Of particular note is the widely held view that communication between the schools and contractor is transactional in nature. This is explained by significant reliance on the helpdesk as a means of communicating issues and the fact that face-to-face contact is mainly confined to scheduled meetings. In this context one school principal described the relationship between the schools and the contractor as “businesslike”. TABLE 5: SCHOOL’S VIEWS OF CURRENT CONTRACT RELATIONSHIPS Dimension of Contract Relationship / School Communication Role of Contract Planning Bargaining Binding Co-operation Benefits and Burdens Rules and Rights Altruism Problems A 3 5 7 3 3 7 4 3 5 4 B 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 C 3 3 1 2 5 3 1 4 D 2 2 2 1 3 8 2 9 9 E 8 9 2 2 2 9 2 2 9 9 Av. 3.40 4.20 2.80 2.00 2.50 6.20 2.60 2.33 5.20 5.60 Table 6 compares the school’s views of the current contractual relationship with how they would prefer to see the relationship governed. The responses reveal a desire for a more relational approach across all dimensions of the contractual relationship. It is noteworthy that this consensus contrasts strongly with that of the DoES, which expressed a preference for a mainly transactional approach (see table 3). With regard to their overall assessment of the relationship, the data in table 7 shows significant diversity of opinion across schools. For example, whereas schools D and E see the relationship as characterized by high levels of trust, cooperation and flexibility, the other three schools (in particular, school B) hold relatively negative views. In this regard it is significant that the latter three schools view their 26 relationships with the contractor as characterized by relatively low levels of trust in particular. TABLE 6: SCHOOL’S VIEWS OF CURRENT VERSUS PREFERRED CONTRACT RELATIONSHIP Dimension of Contract Relationship Communication Role of Contract Planning Bargaining Binding Co-operation Benefits and Burdens Rules and Rights Altruism Problems Actual Preferred 3.4 4.2 2.8 2 2.5 6.2 2.6 2.33 5.2 5.6 6 6.2 6.4 4.6 5.25 9 6 5.5 7.25 7.8 TABLE 7: OVERALL ASSESSMENT OF THE QUALITY OF PPP RELATIONSHIP: SCHOOLS AND DOES School Characteristic Relationship Cooperation Flexibility Trust A B C D E AV DoES 6 8 5 1 1 1 8 5 4 9 8 9 10 8 7 6.8 6.0 5.2 8.0 5.5 8.0 of The striking differences in views expressed by schools was explored in follow-up questions which shed light on a number of issues that shape the conduct of contractual relations under PPP. First, the different views expressed highlight how the disposition of school principals towards the question of private sector involvement in schools can impact on the quality of exchange. For example, in the two schools with the most negative views of PPP, both principals expressed fundamental problems with private sector involvement in the provision of school services. To illustrate, the principal in school C remarked that he “does not believe that a partnership can occur as public and private sectors have different and irreconcilable objectives”. The principal in 27 school B expressed similar views. Moreover he asserted that PPP has failed to deliver promised, “state of the art facilities and services”. In this case the school principal is particularly dissatisfied with the standard of the school building in terms of features such as structure and materials, remarking that “everything is driven by cost…they couldn’t have done it cheaper”. As a consequence the contractual relationship between school B and the private contractor has been characterized by a high degree of conflict. This was illustrated in terms of examples such as (a) the principal’s decision to install fixtures and fittings regardless of whether this was in accordance with the contract or not and (b) alleged opportunistic behaviour by the contractor with regard to quoting exorbitant rates for requested variations. In contrast to this conflictual relationship, the principal in School E depicted a relationship characterized by high levels of trust and cooperation. In this case the principal expressed a strong degree of satisfaction with both the standard of the school building (physical structure and architectural features) and the service provided by the contractor. In his view the establishment of co-operative relations can be attributed to high degrees of flexibility and reciprocity. He has always been positively disposed to the PPP pilot project and has sought to establish good relations with the private contractor from the outset. An illustrative example concerns the delivery of equipment prior to the school opening. As in other schools, some of the equipment was either unnecessary or failed to meet expected standards. Whereas this caused a significant degree of tension in other schools, the principal in this case dealt with the problem by securing credit notes from the main supplier and giving teachers the discretion to purchase necessary items as they deemed fit. 28 The principal in School E has operated on the basis of managing most issues locally. Whereas another school principal expressed frustration with the formality of the helpdesk system and consequent delays in resolving straightforward issues, the principal in school E asserted that he uses the system on his own terms. For example if a replacement window is required he will work to deal with the issue promptly and may log the issue with the helpdesk after the issue is resolved. A number of factors shaping the conduct of contractual relations between the schools and Jarvis, derive from the functioning of the DoES. A significant grievance on the part of schools concerns uncertainty regarding the content of the contract. As the schools have been provided with just excerpts of the contract, three of the five schools referred to problems in dealing with the contractor in the light of this imperfect information. To illustrate, one school principal referred to the problem of discerning between items that were to be ‘supplied’ and items that were to be ‘supplied and maintained’ by Jarvis. Due to this uncertainty, schools are in a weak bargaining position if requests for replacement equipment are refused on the grounds that “they are not provided for in the contract”. While there was scope for dealing with these issues at scheduled monthly meetings between the schools, Jarvis and the DoEs, these meetings were phased out. One school principal remarked, “that the DoES should pay more visits to schools or have more contact”. Moreover, three principals expressed concerns about the DoES’s reliance on the contractor for information concerning the status of issues logged with the helpdesk, “how can it work when the profit seeker is in effect the provider of information and the public sector is not monitoring adequately?”. Three schools indicated that insufficient monitoring by the DoES undermined the enforcement of risk transfer. One principal remarked, “in 29 effect the contract is not being monitored and so the private sector is not effectively taking risks. As a consequence there has not been one payment deduction”. Three schools expressed the opinion that the contract was poorly negotiated and was poorly specified. These concerns were expressed in remarks including “most areas are covered by the contract but they are not covered adequately…too many issues are not bolted down” and “We would prefer more flexibility to deal with things outside the contract. A number of issues are messy and there was a lack of clarity about who should take care of them. We would like to control these rather than refer to the contract”. Another factor impacting negatively on the quality of contractual relations is the quality of the interface between the contractor and the schools. The five schools are widely dispersed around the country whereas the contractor is based in Dublin. Although the contractor’s facilities manager visits the schools on a monthly basis, four of the five schools indicated that this arrangement was inadequate: “We would prefer more contact with Jarvis, or a person on the ground between the school and Jarvis. Having them located in Dublin is a problem” and “I am happy with the caretaker and the facilities manager who visits once a month…it works on that level but the weaknesses in the contract prevents it working at higher levels… There is also a problem of having a geographical spread of schools under one contract”. With regard to the overall question of quality of relationships between schools and the private contractor the evidence presents a picture of mixed experiences across schools. It appears that the degree of cooperation or conflict depends to some degree on the personalities involved. The evidence also indicates that schools are broadly 30 dissatisfied with the transactional nature of contractual governance and would prefer a more relational approach that affords them greater discretion. Interestingly, four of the five principals expressed the opinion that contrary to expectations, PPP has not provided principals with more time to focus on educational matters rather than administrative or facilities management duties. The evidence indicates that where transaction cost issues arise, these relate to uncertainty in the context of imperfect information. There appears to be scope for significantly improved communication between the schools and the DoES, particularly in terms of clarification of rights and responsibilities as specified in the contract. CONCLUSIONS The PPP model of procuring public infrastructure and services is growing in terms of its adoption by policy makers worldwide. However the model is still in its infancy and much of the evidence concerning its use concentrates on the procurement process and ex-ante estimates of VFM (for example, Gaffney et al 1999; Shaoul 2002; 2003). This paper seeks to add to the evidence on PPP by analysing the ex ante and ex post stages of the PPP procurement process in the case of the contract to design, build, operate and finance five secondary schools in Ireland. The examination of this PPP project in terms of transactional/relational poles of contractual governance indicates that the client-contractor relationship is largely transactional in nature, a finding that is at odds with commonly accepted notions of partnership. Moreover, the high level of satisfaction with these transactional aspects, on the part of both client and contractor, highlights the complex nature of contractual 31 governance under PPP. It appears that a largely transactional approach does not prevent the development of trusting and cooperative relations. In this case, mutual satisfaction with the quality of the contractual relationship can be attributed to factors such as the long-term nature of the PPP agreement, the constructive use of the contract as a channel for cooperative dealing with problems that arise during performance and a broad displacement of the contract with regard to monitoring and sanctioning poor performance. The findings in this paper indicate that the existence of trusting relations between client and contractor is not necessarily mirrored in relations between schools and the contractor. Whereas schools see the relationship as mainly transactional they express a clear preference for a more relational approach. The relationship between some schools and the contractor has been characterized by conflict. Where this has occurred it has been attributable to factors including the dispositions of key players towards PPP and the relationship between the schools and the DoES. The latter factor has had a particularly important bearing on the operation of this PPP. Most schools have faced difficulties due to incomplete information regarding contractual provisions and have expressed concerns that the contract is not sufficiently monitored and enforced. The findings presented in this paper indicate that the practice of contracting in the case of this PPP has, in some respects, been at odds with expectation of relational contracting in the context of partnership arrangements. For example, Grimshaw et al (2002) describe the adoption of partnerships in terms of a 32 ‘shift from a system of atomistic, short-term market-based contracts, which are designed to maximize the gain of each bounded entity, to the development of medium-to-long ‘relational contracts’ where the emphasis is upon permeable organising practices that are intended to yield mutually beneficial outcomes. According to this view, notions of market structure and the organising principles of the quasi-market are less important than the form of contractual relationships and the nature of organisational form’ (2002, p.482). In this particular case, any expected shift towards relational contracting has encountered a number of fundamental obstacles. These include the practical reality of procuring the project in the context of political pressure to get the schools up and running. This led to sub-optimal decisions at the pre-contractual stage, in particular the appointment of a preferred bidder prior to testing the scope for VFM under PPP. In addition the ex post conduct of exchange has been impeded by fundamental problems in communication between the DoES and the ultimate users of the contracted service i.e. the schools. As a result, this PPP has been characterized by a higher level of transaction costs than might be expected under relational forms of contracting. While it is recognised that this analysis is based on the first three years of a 25-year contract and that contractual relations may change over time, it is concluded that the use of PPPs in the education sector will not necessarily lead to improved economic efficiency unless considerable care is taken to quantify the costs and benefits of PPP at the ex ante stage. In addition it is necessary to improve the flow of information to all key stakeholders thereby securing a level of ‘buy in’ which can underpin the development of long-term cooperation and mutual benefit. 33 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT The author is grateful to the University of Limerick Foundation for funding the research costs associated with this paper. The author also wishes to acknowledge the helpful comments made by Jim Gleeson, Sarah Moore, Donal Palcic, Eoin O’Sullivan, Sean O’Riain and the anonymous referees on earlier drafts of this paper. The usual disclaimer applies. REFERENCES Ball. R., M. Heafey and D. King. 2001. ‘Private finance initiative – a good deal for the public or a drain on future generations?’ Policy and Politics, 29, 1, 95-108. Beale, H. and T. Dugdale. 1975. ‘Contracts between businessmen: planning and the use of contractual remedies’, British Journal of Law and Society 2, 45-60. Campbell, D. 2001. ‘Ian Macneil and the relational theory of contract’ in D. Campbell (ed) The relational theory of contract, London: Sweet and Maxwell, 3-58. Campbell, D. and D. Harris. 1993. ‘Flexibility in long-term contractual relationships: the role of co-operation’, Journal of Law and Society, 20, 2, 166-191. Coase, R.H. 1937. ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica, 4, 16, 386-405. Comptroller and Auditor General. 2004 The grouped schools pilot partnership project. Dublin, Stationery Office. Dail Eireann, Committee of Public Accounts. 2005. Fifth interim report on the 2002 report of the comptroller and auditor general. Dublin: Stationery Office. Darwin, J., J. Duberley and P. Johnson. 2000 ‘Contracting out in ten english local authorities: preferences and practices’, International Journal of Public Sector Management, 13, 1, 38-57. Davis, H. and B. Walker. 1997. ‘Trust based relationships in local government contracting’, Public Money and Management, 7, 4, 47-44. Deakin, S. and J. Michie. 1997. ‘The theory and practice of contracting” in S. Deakin and J. Michie. (eds), Contracts, co-operation and competition - studies in economics, management and law, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1-39. Deakin, S. and F. Wilkinson. 1995. ‘Contracts, co-operation and trust: the role of the institutional framework”, in D. Campbell and P. Vincent-Jones (eds), Contract and economic organisation: socio-legal initiatives, Aldershot: Dartmouth Press, 95-115. 34 Deloitte. 2007. Closing the infrastructure gap – the role of public private partnerships, London; Deloitte Research. Department of Finance. 2001. Framework for public private partnerships, Dublin: Stationery Office. Domberger, S. and P. Jensen. 1997. ‘Contracting out in the public sector: theory, evidence and prospects’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 13, 4, 67-79. Eurostat. 2004. “New decision of Eurostat on deficit and debt treatment of publicprivate partnerships” Eurostat News Release, Luxembourg. Gaffney, D. M. Pollock, D. Price and J. Shaoul. 1999. ‘NHS capital expenditure and the private finance initiative: expansion or contraction?’, British Medical Journal, 319, 48-51. Grimshaw, D. S. Vincent and H. Wilmott. 2002. ‘Going privately: partnership and outsourcing in UK public services’, Public Administration, 80, 3, 475-502. Institute for Public Policy Research. 2001. Building better partnerships, London: Institute for Public Policy Research. Langford, J. 2001 ‘Managing Public-Private Partnerships in Canada’, presented at conference on New players and processes: a public sector without boundaries Canberra, April. Lonsdale, C. 2005. ‘Post-contractual lock-in and the UK private finance initiative (PFI): the cases of the national savings and investments and the lord chancellor’s department’, Public Administration, 83, 1, 67-88. Macaulay, S. 1963. ‘Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study’, American Sociological Review, 28, 55-67. Macneil, I.R. 1978. ‘Contracts: adjustment of long-term economic relations under classical, neoclassical and relational contract law’, Northwestern University Law Review, 854-905. Macneil, I.R. 1985. ‘Relational contract: what we do and do not know’, Wisconsin Law Review, 483-525. Parker, D. and K. Hartley. 2003. ‘Transaction costs, relational contracting and public private partnerships: a case study of UK defence’ Journal of Purchasing & Supply Management 9, 3, 97-198. Quiggin, J. 2001. ‘Risk, PPPs and the public sector comparator’ Australian Accounting Review, 14, 2, 51-61. 35 Rahman, M.M., and M.M. Kumaraswamy. 2002. ‘Joint risk management through transactionally efficient relational contracting’, Construction Management & Economics, 20, 1, 45-54. Reeves, E. 2003. ‘Public private partnerships in Ireland: policy and practice’, Public Money and Management, 23, 3, 63-170. Sako, M. 1992. Prices, quality and trust, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Shaoul, J. 2003. ‘A financial analysis of the national air traffic services public private partnership’, Public Money and Management, 3, 23, 185-194. Shaoul, J. 2002. ‘A financial appraisal of London underground public private partnership’, Public Money and Management, 22, 2, 53-60. Vincent-Jones, P. 2006. The new public contracting – regulation, responsiveness, relationality, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Vincent-Jones, P. 2001. ‘The reception of Ian Macneil’s work on contract in the U.K. in D. Campbell (ed) The relational theory of contract, London: Sweet and Maxwell, 59-86. Vincent-Jones, P. 1997. 'Hybrid organization, contractual governance, and compulsory competitive tendering in the provision of local authority services' S. Deakin and J. Michie. (eds), Contracts, co-operation and competition - studies in economics, management and law, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 143-174. Vincent-Jones, P. and A. Harries. 1995a. 'Co-operation in local authority CCT transactions: 'contracting-in' and 'contracting-out' refuse collection services', presented at Socio-legal studies annual conference, University of Leeds. Vincent-Jones, P. and A. Harries. 1995b. 'Conflict and co-operation in local authority quasi-markets: the hybrid organisation of internal contracting under CCT', presented at Fourth ESRC quasi-markets seminar, London School of Economics. Walker, B. and H. Davis. 1999. ‘Perspectives on contractual relationships and the move to best value in local authorities’, Local Government Studies, 25, 22, 16-37. Walsh, K. 1995. Public services and market mechanism - competition, contracting and the new public management, Hampshire: MacMillan. Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antritrust implications, New York: Free Press. Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism, New York: Free Press. Williamson, O.E. 1996. The mechanisms of governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press. 36