Solutions to the Review Questions at the End of Chapter 4 y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t 4 y t 1 u t 1. y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t 4 y t 1 vt . Note that we have not changed anything substantial between these models in the sense that the second model is just a re-parameterisation (rearrangement) of the first, where we have subtracted yt-1 from both sides of the equation. (i) Remember that the residual sum of squares is the sum of each of the squared residuals. So lets consider what the residuals will be in each case. For the first model in the level of y uˆ t yt yˆ t yt ˆ1 ˆ 2 x2t ˆ 3 X 3t ˆ 4 yt 1 Now for the second model, the dependent variable is now the change in y: vˆt y t yˆ t y t ˆ1 ˆ 2 x 2t ˆ 3 x3t ˆ 4 y t 1 where y is the fitted value in each case (note that we do not need at this stage to assume they are the same). Rearranging this second model would give uˆ t y t y t 1 ˆ1 ˆ 2 x 2t ˆ 3 x3t ˆ 4 y t 1 y t ˆ1 ˆ 2 x 2t ˆ 3 x 3t (ˆ 4 1) y t 1 If we compare this formulation with the one we calculated for the first model, we can see that the residuals are exactly the same for the two models, with ˆ 4 ˆ 4 1 and ˆ ˆ (i = 1, 2, 3). Hence if the residuals are the same, the residual sum of squares i i must also be the same. In fact the two models are really identical, since one is just a rearrangement of the other. (ii) As for R2, recall how we calculate R2: RSS for the first model and R2 1 ( yi y ) 2 R2 1 RSS in the second case. Therefore since the total sum of squares (yi y ) 2 (the denominator) has changed, then the value of R2 must have also changed as a consequence of changing the dependent variable. (iii) By the same logic, since the value of the adjusted R2 is just an algebraic modification of R2 itself, the value of the adjusted R2 must also change. 2. A researcher estimates the following two econometric models y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t u t (1) y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t 4 x 4t vt (2) 2 (i) The value of R will almost always be higher for the second model since it has another variable added to the regression. The value of R2 would only be identical for the two models in the very, very unlikely event that the estimated coefficient on the x4t 1/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002 variable was exactly zero. Otherwise, the R2 must be higher for the second model than the first. (ii) The value of the adjusted R2 could fall as we add another variable. The reason for this is that the adjusted version of R2 has a correction for the loss of degrees of freedom associated with adding another regressor into a regression. This implies a penalty term, so that the value of the adjusted R2 will only rise if the increase in this penalty is more than outweighed by the rise in the value of R2. 3. In the same way as we make assumptions about the true value of beta and not the estimated values, we make assumptions about the true unobservable disturbance terms rather than their estimated counterparts, the residuals. We know the exact value of the residuals, since they are defined by uˆ t y t yˆ t . So we do not need to make any assumptions about the residuals since we already know their value. We make assumptions about the unobservable error terms since it is always the true value of the population disturbances that we are really interested in, although we never actually know what these are. 4. We would like to see no pattern in the residual plot! If there is a pattern in the residual plot, this is an indication that there is still some “action” or variability left in yt that has not been explained by our model. This indicates that potentially it may be possible to form a better model, perhaps using additional or completely different explanatory variables, or by using lags of either the dependent or of one or more of the explanatory variables. Recall that the two plots shown on pages 157 and 159, where the residuals followed a cyclical pattern, and when they followed an alternating pattern are used as indications that the residuals are positively and negatively autocorrelated respectively. Another problem if there is a “pattern” in the residuals is that, if it does indicate the presence of autocorrelation, then this may suggest that our standard error estimates for the coefficients could be wrong and hence any inferences we make about the coefficients could be misleading. 5. The t-ratios for the coefficients in this model are given in the third row after the standard errors. They are calculated by dividing the individual coefficients by their standard errors. ŷt = 0.638 + 0.402 x2t - 0.891 x3t (0.436) (0.291) (0.763) t-ratios 1.46 1.38 1.17 R 2 0.96,R 2 0.89 The problem appears to be that the regression parameters are all individually insignificant (i.e. not significantly different from zero), although the value of R2 and its adjusted version are both very high, so that the regression taken as a whole seems to indicate a good fit. This looks like a classic example of what we term near multicollinearity. This is where the individual regressors are very closely related, so 2/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002 that it becomes difficult to disentangle the effect of each individual variable upon the dependent variable. The solution to near multicollinearity that is usually suggested is that since the problem is really one of insufficient information in the sample to determine each of the coefficients, then one should go out and get more data. In other words, we should switch to a higher frequency of data for analysis (e.g. weekly instead of monthly, monthly instead of quarterly etc.). An alternative is also to get more data by using a longer sample period (i.e. one going further back in time), or to combine the two independent variables in a ratio (e.g. x2t / x3t ). Other, more ad hoc methods for dealing with the possible existence of near multicollinearity were discussed in Chapter 4: - Ignore it: if the model is otherwise adequate, i.e. statistically and in terms of each coefficient being of a plausible magnitude and having an appropriate sign. Sometimes, the existence of multicollinearity does not reduce the t-ratios on variables that would have been significant without the multicollinearity sufficiently to make them insignificant. It is worth stating that the presence of near multicollinearity does not affect the BLUE properties of the OLS estimator – i.e. it will still be consistent, unbiased and efficient since the presence of near multicollinearity does not violate any of the CLRM assumptions 1-4. However, in the presence of near multicollinearity, it will be hard to obtain small standard errors. This will not matter if the aim of the model-building exercise is to produce forecasts from the estimated model, since the forecasts will be unaffected by the presence of near multicollinearity so long as this relationship between the explanatory variables continues to hold over the forecasted sample. - Drop one of the collinear variables - so that the problem disappears. However, this may be unacceptable to the researcher if there were strong a priori theoretical reasons for including both variables in the model. Also, if the removed variable was relevant in the data generating process for y, an omitted variable bias would result (see Section 4.12). - Transform the highly correlated variables into a ratio and include only the ratio and not the individual variables in the regression. Again, this may be unacceptable if financial theory suggests that changes in the dependent variable should occur following changes in the individual explanatory variables, and not a ratio of them. 6. (i) The assumption of homoscedasticity is that the variance of the errors is constant and finite over time. Technically, we write Var (u t ) u2 . (ii) The coefficient estimates would still be the “correct” ones (assuming that the other assumptions required to demonstrate OLS optimality are satisfied), but the problem would be that the standard errors could be wrong. Hence if we were trying to test hypotheses about the true parameter values, we could end up drawing the wrong conclusions. In fact, for all of the variables except the constant, the standard errors would typically be too small, so that we would end up rejecting the null hypothesis too many times. (iii) There are a number of ways to proceed in practice, including 3/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002 - Using heteroscedasticity robust standard errors which correct for the problem by enlarging the standard errors relative to what they would have been for the situation where the error variance is positively related to one of the explanatory variables. - Transforming the data into logs, which has the effect of reducing the effect of large errors relative to small ones. 7. (i) This is where there is a relationship between the ith and jth residuals. Recall that one of the assumptions of the CLRM was that such a relationship did not exist. We want our residuals to be random, and if there is evidence of autocorrelation in the residuals, then it implies that we could predict the sign of the next residual and get the right answer more than half the time on average! (ii) The Durbin Watson test is a test for first order autocorrelation. The test is calculated as follows. You would run whatever regression you were interested in, and obtain the residuals. Then calculate the statistic T uˆ DW t 2 uˆt 1 2 t T uˆ t 2 2 t You would then need to look up the two critical values from the Durbin Watson tables, and these would depend on how many variables and how many observations and how many regressors (excluding the constant this time) you had in the model. The rejection / non-rejection rule would be given by selecting the appropriate region from the following diagram: (iii) We have 60 observations, and the number of regressors excluding the constant term is 3. The appropriate lower and upper limits are 1.48 and 1.69 respectively, so the Durbin Watson is lower than the lower limit. It is thus clear that we reject the null hypothesis of no autocorrelation. So it looks like the residuals are positively autocorrelated. (iv) y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t 4 x 4t u t The problem with a model entirely in first differences, is that once we calculate the long run solution, all the first difference terms drop out (as in the long run we assume that the values of all variables have converged on their own long run values so that yt = yt-1 etc.) Thus when we try to calculate the long run solution to this model, we cannot do it because there isn’t a long run solution to this model! (v) y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t 4 x 4t 5 x 2t 1 6 X 3t 1 7 X 4t 1 vt The answer is yes, there is no reason why we cannot use Durbin Watson in this case. You may have said no here because there are lagged values of the regressors (the x 4/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002 variables) variables in the regression. In fact this would be wrong since there are no lags of the DEPENDENT (y) variable and hence DW can still be used. 8. y t 1 2 x 2t 3 x3t 4 y t 1 5 x 2t 1 6 x3t 1 7 x rt 4 u t The major steps involved in calculating the long run solution are to - set the disturbance term equal to its expected value of zero - drop the time subscripts - remove all difference terms altogether since these will all be zero by the definition of the long run in this context. Following these steps, we obtain 0 1 4 y 5 x 2 6 x3 7 x3 We now want to rearrange this to have all the terms in x2 together and so that y is the subject of the formula: 4 y 1 5 x 2 6 x3 7 x3 4 y 1 5 x 2 ( 6 7 ) x3 ( 4 ) y 1 5 x2 6 x3 4 4 4 The last equation above is the long run solution. 9. Ramsey’s RESET test is a test of whether the functional form of the regression is appropriate. In other words, we test whether the relationship between the dependent variable and the independent variables really should be linear or whether a non-linear form would be more appropriate. The test works by adding powers of the fitted values from the regression into a second regression. If the appropriate model was a linear one, then the powers of the fitted values would not be significant in this second regression. If we fail Ramsey’s RESET test, then the easiest “solution” is probably to transform all of the variables into logarithms. This has the effect of turning a multiplicative model into an additive one. If this still fails, then we really have to admit that the relationship between the dependent variable and the independent variables was probably not linear after all so that we have to either estimate a non-linear model for the data (which is beyond the scope of this course) or we have to go back to the drawing board and run a different regression containing different variables. 10. (i) It is important to note that we did not need to assume normality in order to derive the sample estimates of and or in calculating their standard errors. We needed the normality assumption at the later stage when we come to test hypotheses about the regression coefficients, either singly or jointly, so that the test statistics we calculate would indeed have the distribution (t or F) that we said they would. (ii) One solution would be to use a technique for estimation and inference which did not require normality. But these techniques are often highly complex and 5/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002 also their properties are not so well understood, so we do not know with such certainty how well the methods will perform in different circumstances. One pragmatic approach to failing the normality test is to plot the estimated residuals of the model, and look for one or more very extreme outliers. These would be residuals that are much “bigger” (either very big and positive, or very big and negative) than the rest. It is, fortunately for us, often the case that one or two very extreme outliers will cause a violation of the normality assumption. The reason that one or two extreme outliers can cause a violation of the normality assumption is that they would lead the (absolute value of the) skewness and / or kurtosis estimates to be very large. Once we spot a few extreme residuals, we should look at the dates when these outliers occurred. If we have a good theoretical reason for doing so, we can add in separate dummy variables for big outliers caused by, for example, wars, changes of government, stock market crashes, changes in market microstructure (e.g. the “big bang” of 1986). The effect of the dummy variable is exactly the same as if we had removed the observation from the sample altogether and estimated the regression on the remainder. If we only remove observations in this way, then we make sure that we do not lose any useful pieces of information represented by sample points. 11. (a) Parameter structural stability refers to whether the coefficient estimates for a regression equation are stable over time. If the regression is not structurally stable, it implies that the coefficient estimates would be different for some sub-samples of the data compared to others. This is clearly not what we want to find since when we estimate a regression, we are implicitly assuming that the regression parameters are constant over the entire sample period under consideration. (b) 1981M1-1995M12 rt = 0.0215 + 1.491 rmt RSS=0.189 T=180 1981M1-1987M10 rt = 0.0163 + 1.308 rmt RSS=0.079 T=82 1987M11-1995M12 rt = 0.0360 + 1.613 rmt RSS=0.082 T=98 (i) If we define the coefficient estimates for the first and second halves of the sample as 1 and 1, and 2 and 2 respectively, then the null and alternative hypotheses are H0 : 1 = 2 and 1 = 2 and H1 : 1 2 or 1 2 (ii) The test statistic is calculated as Test stat. = RSS ( RSS 1 RSS 2 ) (T 2k ) 0.189 (0.079 0.082) 180 4 * * 15.304 RSS 1 RSS 2 k 0.079 0.082 2 This follows an F distribution with (k,T-2k) degrees of freedom. F(2,176) = 3.05 at the 5% level. Clearly we reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients are equal in the two sub-periods. 6/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002 12.The data we have are 1981M1-1995M12 rt = 0.0215 + 1.491 Rmt RSS=0.189 T=180 1981M1-1994M12 rt = 0.0212 + 1.478 Rmt RSS=0.148 T=168 1982M1-1995M12 rt = 0.0217 + 1.523 Rmt RSS=0.182 T=168 First, the forward predictive failure test - i.e. we are trying to see if the model for 1981M1-1994M12 can predict 1995M1-1995M12. The test statistic is given by RSS RSS 1 T1 k 0.189 0.148 168 2 * * 3.832 RSS 1 T2 0.148 12 Where T1 is the number of observations in the first period (i.e. the period that we actually estimate the model over), and T2 is the number of observations we are trying to “predict”. The test statistic follows an F-distribution with (T2, T1-k) degrees of freedom. F(12, 166) = 1.81 at the 5% level. So we reject the null hypothesis that the model can predict the observations for 1995. We would conclude that our model is no use for predicting this period, and from a practical point of view, we would have to consider whether this failure is a result of a-typical behaviour of the series out-ofsample (i.e. during 1995), or whether it results from a genuine deficiency in the model. The backward predictive failure test is a little more difficult to understand, although no more difficult to implement. The test statistic is given by RSS RSS 1 T1 k 0.189 0.182 168 2 * * 0.532 RSS 1 T2 0.182 12 Now we need to be a little careful in our interpretation of what exactly are the “first” and “second” sample periods. It would be possible to define T1 as always being the first sample period. But I think it easier to say that T1 is always the sample over which we estimate the model (even though it now comes after the hold-out-sample). Thus T2 is still the sample that we are trying to predict, even though it comes first. You can use either notation, but you need to be clear and consistent. If you wanted to choose the other way to the one I suggest, then you would need to change the subscript 1 everywhere in the formula above so that it was 2, and change every 2 so that it was a 1. Either way, we conclude that there is little evidence against the null hypothesis. Thus our model is able to adequately back-cast the first 12 observations of the sample. 7/7 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2002