MSWord Version of Topics Related to Decision Making

advertisement
Table of Contents
Chapter 1 – What is Decision making?
2
Chapter 2 – Decision theory
8
Chapter 3 – Emotions in Decision Making
13
Chapter 4 – Risk
18
Chapter 5 – Risk management
31
Chapter 6 – Responsible decision making
42
Chapter 7 – Behavioral Decision Making
47
Webliography
56
Chapter 1
What is
Decision
making?
Decision making can be regarded as an outcome of mental processes (cognitive process) leading to the
selection of a course of action among several alternatives. Every decision making process produces a
final choice.[1] The output can be an action or an opinion of choice.
Contents
* 1 Overview
* 2 Decision making processes topics
o 2.1 Cognitive and personal biases
o 2.2 Neuroscience perspective
* 3 Styles and methods of decision making
* 4 See also
* 5 References
* 6 Further reading
* 7 External links
Overview
Human performance in decision making terms has been subject of active research from several
perspectives. From a psychological perspective, it is necessary to examine individual decisions in the
context of a set of needs, preferences an individual has and values he/she seeks. From a cognitive
perspective, the decision making process must be regarded as a continuous process integrated in the
interaction with the environment. From a normative perspective, the analysis of individual decisions is
concerned with the logic of decision making and rationality and the invariant choice it leads to.[2]
Yet, at another level, it might be regarded as a problem solving activity which is terminated when a
satisfactory solution is found. Therefore, decision making is a reasoning or emotional process which can
be rational or irrational, can be based on explicit assumptions or tacit assumptions.
Logical decision making is an important part of all science-based professions, where specialists apply
their knowledge in a given area to making informed decisions. For example, medical decision making
often involves making a diagnosis and selecting an appropriate treatment. Some research using
naturalistic methods shows, however, that in situations with higher time pressure, higher stakes, or
increased ambiguities, experts use intuitive decision making rather than structured approaches,
following a recognition primed decision approach to fit a set of indicators into the expert's experience
and immediately arrive at a satisfactory course of action without weighing alternatives. Also, recent
robust decision efforts have formally integrated uncertainty into the decision making process.
Decision making processes topics
According to behavioralist Isabel Briggs Myers, a person's decision making process depends on a
significant degree on their cognitive style.[3] Myers developed a set of four bi-polar dimensions, called
the Myers-Briggs Type Indicator (MBTI). The terminal points on these dimensions are: thinking and
feeling; extroversion and introversion; judgment and perception; and sensing and intuition. She claimed
that a person's decision making style is based largely on how they score on these four dimensions. For
example, someone who scored near the thinking, extroversion, sensing, and judgment ends of the
dimensions would tend to have a logical, analytical, objective, critical, and empirical decision making
style.
Other studies suggest that these national or cross-cultural differences exist across entire societies. For
example, Maris Martinsons has found that American, Japanese and Chinese business leaders each
exhibit a distinctive national style of decision making.[4]
Cognitive and personal biases
Some of the decision making techniques that we use in everyday life include:
* listing the advantages and disadvantages of each option, popularized by Plato and Benjamin Franklin
* flipping a coin, cutting a deck of playing cards, and other random or coincidence methods
* accepting the first option that seems like it might achieve the desired result
* prayer, tarot cards, astrology, augurs, revelation, or other forms of divination
* acquiesce to a person in authority or an "expert"
* calculating the expected value or utility for each option.
For example, a person is considering two jobs. At the first job option the person has a 60% chance of
getting a 30% raise in the first year. And at the second job option the person has an 80% chance of
getting a 10% raise in the first year. The decision maker would calculate the expected value of each
option, calculating the probability multiplied by the increase of value. (0.60*0.30=0.18 [option a]
0.80*0.10=0.08 [option b]) The person deciding on the job would chose the option with the highest
expected value, in this example option number one. An alternative may be to apply one of the processes
described below, in particular in the Business and Management section.
Biases can creep into our decision making processes. Many different people have made a decision about
the same question (e.g. "Should I have a doctor look at this troubling breast cancer symptom I've
discovered?" "Why did I ignore the evidence that the project was going over budget?") and then craft
potential cognitive interventions aimed at improving decision making outcomes.
Below is a list of some of the more commonly debated cognitive biases.
* Selective search for evidence (a.k.a. Confirmation bias in psychology) (Scott Plous, 1993) - We tend
to be willing to gather facts that support certain conclusions but disregard other facts that support
different conclusions.
* Premature termination of search for evidence - We tend to accept the first alternative that looks like
it might work.
* Inertia - Unwillingness to change thought patterns that we have used in the past in the face of new
circumstances.
* Selective perception - We actively screen-out information that we do not think is salient. (See
prejudice.)
* Wishful thinking or optimism bias - We tend to want to see things in a positive light and this can
distort our perception and thinking.
* Choice-supportive bias occurs when we distort our memories of chosen and rejected options to
make the chosen options seem relatively more attractive.
* Recency - We tend to place more attention on more recent information and either ignore or forget
more distant information. (See semantic priming.) The opposite effect in the first set of data or other
information is termed Primacy effect (Plous, 1993).
* Repetition bias - A willingness to believe what we have been told most often and by the greatest
number of different of sources.
* Anchoring and adjustment - Decisions are unduly influenced by initial information that shapes our
view of subsequent information.
* Group think - Peer pressure to conform to the opinions held by the group.
* Source credibility bias - We reject something if we have a bias against the person, organization, or
group to which the person belongs: We are inclined to accept a statement by someone we like. (See
prejudice.)
* Incremental decision making and escalating commitment - We look at a decision as a small step in a
process and this tends to perpetuate a series of similar decisions. This can be contrasted with zerobased decision making. (See slippery slope.)
* Attribution asymmetry - We tend to attribute our success to our abilities and talents, but we
attribute our failures to bad luck and external factors. We attribute other's success to good luck, and
their failures to their mistakes.
* Role fulfillment (Self Fulfilling Prophecy) - We conform to the decision making expectations that
others have of someone in our position.
* Underestimating uncertainty and the illusion of control - We tend to underestimate future
uncertainty because we tend to believe we have more control over events than we really do. We believe
we have control to minimize potential problems in our decisions.
] Neuroscience perspective
The anterior cingulate cortex (ACC) and orbitofrontal cortex are brain regions involved in decision
making processes. A recent neuroimaging study, Interactions between decision making and
performance monitoring within prefrontal cortex, found distinctive patterns of neural activation in these
regions depending on whether decisions were made on the basis of personal volition or following
directions from someone else.
Another recent study by Kennerly, et al. (2006) found that lesions to the ACC in the macaque resulted in
impaired decision making in the long run of reinforcement guided tasks suggesting that the ACC is
responsible for evaluating past reinforcement information and guiding future action.
Emotion appears to aid the decision making process:
* Decision making often occurs in the face of uncertainty about whether one's choices will lead to
benefit or harm (see also Risk). The somatic-marker hypothesis is a neurobiological theory of how
decisions are made in the face of uncertain outcome. This theory holds that such decisions are aided by
emotions, in the form of bodily states, that are elicited during the deliberation of future consequences
and that mark different options for behavior as being advantageous or disadvantageous. This process
involves an interplay between neural systems that elicit emotional/bodily states and neural systems that
map these emotional/bodily states. [http://www.blackwell-synergy.com/doi/abs/10.1111/j.14678721.2006.00448.x?cookieSet=1&journalCode=cdir
Styles and methods of decision making
Styles and methods of decision making were elaborated by the founder of Predispositioning Theory,
Aron Katsenelinboigen. In his analysis on styles and methods Katsenelinboigen referred to the game of
chess, saying that “chess does disclose various methods of operation, notably the creation of
predisposition—methods which may be applicable to other, more complex systems.”[5]
In his book Katsenelinboigen states that apart from the methods (reactive and selective) and submethods (randomization, predispositioning, programming), there are two major styles – positional and
combinational. Both styles are utilized in the game of chess. According to Katsenelinboigen, the two
styles reflect two basic approaches to the uncertainty: deterministic (combinational style) and
indeterministic (positional style). Katsenelinboigen’s definition of the two styles are the following.
The combinational style is characterized by


a very narrow, clearly defined, primarily material goal, and
a program that links the initial position with the final outcome.
In defining the combinational style in chess, Katsenelinboigen writes:
The combinational style features a clearly formulated limited objective, namely the capture of
material (the main constituent element of a chess position). The objective is implemented via a
well defined and in some cases in a unique sequence of moves aimed at reaching the set goal.
As a rule, this sequence leaves no options for the opponent. Finding a combinational objective
allows the player to focus all his energies on efficient execution, that is, the player’s analysis
may be limited to the pieces directly partaking in the combination. This approach is the crux of
the combination and the combinational style of play.[5]
The positional style is distinguished by


a positional goal and
a formation of semi-complete linkages between the initial step and final outcome.
“Unlike the combinational player, the positional player is occupied, first and foremost, with the
elaboration of the position that will allow him to develop in the unknown future. In playing the
positional style, the player must evaluate relational and material parameters as independent
variables. ( … ) The positional style gives the player the opportunity to develop a position until it
becomes pregnant with a combination. However, the combination is not the final goal of the
positional player—it helps him to achieve the desirable, keeping in mind a predisposition for
the future development. The Pyrrhic victory is the best example of one’s inability to think
positionally.”[6]
The positional style serves to
a) create a predisposition to the future development of the position;
b) induce the environment in a certain way;
c) absorb an unexpected outcome in one’s favor;
d) avoid the negative aspects of unexpected outcomes.
The positional style gives the player the opportunity to develop a position until it becomes
pregnant with a combination. Katsenelinboigen writes:
“As the game progressed and defense became more sophisticated the combinational style of
play declined. . . . The positional style of chess does not eliminate the combinational one with
its attempt to see the entire program of action in advance. The positional style merely prepares
the transformation to a combination when the latter becomes feasible.”
Chapter 2
Decision theory
Normative and descriptive decision theory
Most of decision theory is normative or prescriptive, i.e. it is concerned with identifying the
best decision to take, assuming an ideal decision maker who is fully informed, able to compute
with perfect accuracy, and fully rational. The practical application of this prescriptive approach
(how people should make decisions) is called decision analysis, and aimed at finding tools,
methodologies and software to help people make better decisions. The most systematic and
comprehensive software tools developed in this way are called decision support systems.
Since it is obvious that people do not typically behave in optimal ways, there is also a related
area of study, which is a positive or descriptive discipline, attempting to describe what people
will actually do. Since the normative, optimal decision often creates hypotheses for testing
against actual behaviour, the two fields are closely linked. Furthermore it is possible to relax the
assumptions of perfect information, rationality and so forth in various ways, and produce a
series of different prescriptions or predictions about behaviour, allowing for further tests of the
kind of decision-making that occurs in practice.
What kinds of decisions need a theory?
Choice between incommensurable commodities
Choice under uncertainty
This area represents the heart of decision theory. The procedure now referred to as expected
value was known from the 17th century. Blaise Pascal invoked it in his famous wager (see
below), which is contained in his Pensées, published in 1670. The idea of expected value is that,
when faced with a number of actions, each of which could give rise to more than one possible
outcome with different probabilities, the rational procedure is to identify all possible outcomes,
determine their values (positive or negative) and the probabilities that will result from each
course of action, and multiply the two to give an expected value. The action to be chosen
should be the one that gives rise to the highest total expected value. In 1738, Daniel Bernoulli
published an influential paper entitled Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk,
in which he uses the St. Petersburg paradox to show that expected value theory must be
normatively wrong. He also gives an example in which a Dutch merchant is trying to decide
whether to insure a cargo being sent from Amsterdam to St Petersburg in winter, when it is
known that there is a 5% chance that the ship and cargo will be lost. In his solution, he defines a
utility function and computes expected utility rather than expected financial value.
In the 20th century, interest was reignited by Abraham Wald's 1939 paper[1] pointing out that
the two central concerns of orthodox statistical theory at that time, namely statistical
hypothesis testing and statistical estimation theory, could both be regarded as particular special
cases of the more general decision problem. This paper introduced much of the mental
landscape of modern decision theory, including loss functions, risk functions, admissible
decision rules, a priori distributions, Bayes decision rules, and minimax decision rules. The
phrase "decision theory" itself was first used in 1950 by E. L. Lehmann.[citation needed]
The rise of subjective probability theory, from the work of Frank Ramsey, Bruno de Finetti,
Leonard Savage and others, extended the scope of expected utility theory to situations where
only subjective probabilities are available. At this time it was generally assumed in economics
that people behave as rational agents and thus expected utility theory also provided a theory of
actual human decision-making behaviour under risk. The work of Maurice Allais and Daniel
Ellsberg showed that this was clearly not so. The prospect theory of Daniel Kahneman and
Amos Tversky placed behavioural economics on a more evidence-based footing. It emphasized
that in actual human (as opposed to normatively correct) decision-making "losses loom larger
than gains", people are more focused on changes in their utility states than the states
themselves and estimation of subjective probabilities is severely biased by anchoring.
Castagnoli and LiCalzi (1996),[citation needed] Bordley and LiCalzi (2000)[citation needed] recently showed
that maximizing expected utility is mathematically equivalent to maximizing the probability that
the uncertain consequences of a decision are preferable to an uncertain benchmark (e.g., the
probability that a mutual fund strategy outperforms the S&P 500 or that a firm outperforms the
uncertain future performance of a major competitor.). This reinterpretation relates to
psychological work suggesting that individuals have fuzzy aspiration levels (Lopes &
Oden),[citation needed] which may vary from choice context to choice context. Hence it shifts the
focus from utility to the individual's uncertain reference point.
Pascal's Wager is a classic example of a choice under uncertainty. The uncertainty, according to
Pascal, is whether or not God exists. Belief or non-belief in God is the choice to be made.
However, the reward for belief in God if God actually does exist is infinite. Therefore, however
small the probability of God's existence, the expected value of belief exceeds that of non-belief,
so it is better to believe in God. (There are several criticisms of the argument.)
Intertemporal choice
This area is concerned with the kind of choice where different actions lead to outcomes that
are realised at different points in time. If someone received a windfall of several thousand
dollars, they could spend it on an expensive holiday, giving them immediate pleasure, or they
could invest it in a pension scheme, giving them an income at some time in the future. What is
the optimal thing to do? The answer depends partly on factors such as the expected rates of
interest and inflation, the person's life expectancy, and their confidence in the pensions
industry. However even with all those factors taken into account, human behavior again
deviates greatly from the predictions of prescriptive decision theory, leading to alternative
models in which, for example, objective interest rates are replaced by subjective discount rates.
Competing decision makers
Some decisions are difficult because of the need to take into account how other people in the
situation will respond to the decision that is taken. The analysis of such social decisions is the
business of game theory, and is not normally considered part of decision theory, though it is
closely related. In the emerging socio-cognitive engineering the research is especially focused
on the different types of distributed decision-making in human organizations, in normal and
abnormal/emergency/crisis situations. The signal detection theory is based on the Decision
theory.
Complex decisions
Other areas of decision theory are concerned with decisions that are difficult simply because of
their complexity, or the complexity of the organization that has to make them. In such cases the
issue is not the deviation between real and optimal behaviour, but the difficulty of determining
the optimal behaviour in the first place. The Club of Rome, for example, developed a model of
economic growth and resource usage that helps politicians make real-life decisions in complex
situations.
Paradox of choice
Observed in many cases is the paradox that more choices may lead to a poorer decision or a
failure to make a decision at all. It is sometimes theorized to be caused by analysis paralysis,
real or perceived, or perhaps from rational ignorance. A number of researchers including
Sheena S. Iyengar and Mark R. Lepper have published studies on this phenomenon.[2] A
popularization of this analysis was done by Barry Schwartz in his 2004 book, The Paradox of
Choice.
Statistical decision theory
Several statistical tools and methods are available to organize evidence, evaluate risks, and aid
in decision making. The risks of Type I and type II errors can be quantified (estimated
probability, cost, expected value, etc) and rational decision making is improved.
Alternatives to probability theory
A highly controversial issue is whether one can replace the use of probability in decision theory
by other alternatives. The proponents of fuzzy logic, possibility theory, Dempster-Shafer theory
and info-gap decision theory maintain that probability is only one of many alternatives and
point to many examples where non-standard alternatives have been implemented with
apparent success. Work by Yousef and others advocate exotic probability theories using
complex-valued functions based on the probability amplitudes developed and validated by
Birkhoff and Von Neumann in quantum physics.
Advocates of probability theory point to:

the work of Richard Threlkeld Cox for justification of the probability axioms,

the Dutch book paradoxes of Bruno de Finetti as illustrative of the theoretical difficulties that
can arise from departures from the probability axioms, and

the complete class theorems which show that all admissible decision rules are equivalent to a
Bayesian decision rule with some prior distribution (possibly improper) and some utility
function. Thus, for any decision rule generated by non-probabilistic methods, either there is an
equivalent rule derivable by Bayesian means, or there is a rule derivable by Bayesian means
which is never worse and (at least) sometimes better.
Chapter 3
Emotions in
Decision
Making
One of the most common theories in the field of decision making is the expected utility theory
(EU). According to this theory, people usually make their decisions by weighing the severity and
likelihood of the possible outcomes of different alternatives. The integration of this information
is made through some type of expectation, based calculus (cognitive activity) which enables us
to make a decision. In this theory, psychological processes and the decision maker’s emotional
state were ignored and not taken into account as inputs to the expectation based calculus.
Emotions as an information source
In “Risk as Feelings”, Loewenstein, Weber and Hsee [1] argue that these processes of decision
making include ‘anticipatory emotions’ and ‘anticipated emotions’: “anticipatory emotions are
immediate visceral reactions (fear, anxiety, dread) to risk and uncertainties”; “anticipated
emotions are typically not experienced in the immediate present but are expected to be
experienced in the future” (disappointment or regret). Both types of emotions serve as
additional source of information.
For example, research shows that happy decision-makers are reluctant to gamble. The fact that
a person is happy would make him or her decide against gambling, since he or she would not
want to undermine his or her happy feeling. This can be looked upon as "mood maintenance"
[2].
According to the information hypothesis, feelings during the decision process affects people's
choices, in cases where feelings are experienced as reactions to the imminent decision. If
feelings are attributed to an irrelevant source to the decision at hand, their impact is reduced or
eliminated.
Zajonc [3] argues that emotions are meant to help people take or avoid taking a stand, versus
cognitive calculus that helps people make a true/false decision.
Anticipated Pleasure
Mellers and McGraw (2001) [4] proposed that anticipated pleasure is an emotion that is
generated during the decision making process and is taken into account as an additional
information source. They argued that the decision maker estimates how he or she will feel
when he or she is right or wrong as a result of choosing one of the alternatives. These
estimated feelings are “averaged” and compared between the different alternatives. It seems
that this theory is the same as the expected utility theory (EU) but both can result in different
choices.
Implications to decision making processes
In a research from 2001, Isen suggests that tasks which are meaningful, interesting, or
important to the decision maker; and if he or she is in a good mood, the decision making
process will be more efficient and thorough. People will usually integrate material for decision
making and be less confused by a large set of variables, if the conditions are of positive affect.
This allows the decision makers to work faster and they will either finish the task at hand
quicker, or will turn attention to other important tasks. Positive affect generally leads people to
be gracious, generous, and kind to others; to be socially responsible and to take other’s
perspective better in interaction.
Emotional bias
An emotional bias is a distortion in cognition and decision making due to emotional factors.
That is, a person will be usually inclined


to believe something that has a positive emotional effect, that gives a pleasant feeling, even if
there is evidence to the contrary.
to be reluctant to accept hard facts that are unpleasant and gives mental suffering.
Those factors can be either individual and self-centered, or linked to interpersonal relationship
or to group influence.
The effects of emotional biases
Its effects can be similar to those of a cognitive bias, it can even be considered as a subcategory
of such biases. The specificity is that the cause lies in one's desires or fears, which divert the
attention of the person, more than in one's reasoning.
Neuroscience experiments have shown how emotions and cognition, which are present in
different areas of the human brain, interfere between each other in the decision making
process, resulting often on a primacy of emotions over reasoning [1]
This might explain some irrational and damaging reactions and moves that might take place
when those emotions are biased (in case of over-optimism or over-pessimism for example).
Greed and fear
Greed and fear are supposed, together with herd instinct, to be the three main emotional
motivators of stock markets and business behavior, and one of the cause of bull markets, bear
markets and business cycles.[citation needed]
From a market saying to an academic research topic
The phrase, traditionally used by traders and market commentators, has become a topic of
economic research about investor irrationalities (cognitive and emotional biases). Its effects on
market prices and returns contradict, or at least moderate, the efficient market hypothesis.
Here are two examples of approaches:


How those two alterning emotions work for traders, and how they can distort their decision
process, has been the subject of neuroeconomics studies (1). More generally, those researches
show some primacy of emotion over cognition in decision making.
According to Hersh Shefrin, one of the key researchers in Behavioral economics, the phrase
hope and fear, although less colloquially used, would describe better those alterning excessive
expectations by market players
Wishful thinking
Wishful thinking is the formation of beliefs and making decisions according to what might be
pleasing to imagine instead of by appealing to evidence or rationality.
Studies have consistently shown that holding all else equal, subjects will predict positive
outcomes to be more likely than negative outcomes. See positive outcome bias.
Prominent examples of wishful thinking include:


Economist Irving Fisher said that "stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high
plateau" a few weeks before Stock Market Crash of 1929, which was followed by the Great
Depression.
President John F. Kennedy believed that, if overpowered by Cuban forces, the CIA-backed rebels
could "escape destruction by melting into the countryside" in the Bay of Pigs Invasion.
As a logical fallacy
In addition to being a cognitive bias and a poor way of making decisions, wishful thinking is
commonly held to be a specific logical fallacy in an argument when it is assumed that because
we wish something to be true or false that it is actually true or false. This fallacy has the form "I
wish that P is true/false, therefore P is true/false."[1] Wishful thinking, if this were true, would
underlie appeals to emotion, and would also be a red herring.
Some atheists argue that much of theology, particularly arguments for the existence of God, is
based on wishful thinking because it takes the desired outcome (that a god or gods exist) and
tries to prove it on the basis of a premise through reasoning which can be analysed as
fallacious, but which may nevertheless be wished "true" in the mind of the believer. Some
theologians argue that it is actually atheism which is the product of wishful thinking, in that
atheists may not want to believe in any gods or may not want there to be any gods. Both of
these arguments would better be described as confirmation bias. Since one rarely, if ever, finds
an argument written or spoken as described above ("I wish it to be true, therefore it is true"),
the charge of "wishful thinking" itself can be a form of circumstantial ad hominem argument,
even a Bulverism.
Wishful thinking may cause blindness to unintended consequences.
Related fallacies are the Negative proof and Argument from ignorance fallacies ("It hasn't been proven
false, so it must be true." and vice versa). For instance, a believer in UFOs may accept that most UFO
photos are faked, but claim that the ones that haven't been debunked must be considered genuine.
Chapter 4
Risk
Risk is a concept that denotes the precise probability of specific eventualities. Technically, the notion of
risk is independent from the notion of value, and as such, eventualities may have both beneficial and
adverse consequences. However in general usage the convention is to focus only on potential negative
impact to some characteristic of value that may arise from a future event. Definitions of risk
There are many definitions of risk that vary by specific application and situational context. One is that
risk is an issue, which can be avoided or mitigated (wherein an issue is a potential problem that has to
be fixed now.) Risk is described both qualitatively and quantitatively. In some texts risk is described as a
situation which would lead to negative consequences.
Qualitatively, risk is proportional to both the expected losses which may be caused by an event and to
the probability of this event. Greater loss and greater event likelihood result in a greater overall risk.
Frequently in the subject matter literature, risk is defined in pseudo-formal forms where the
components of the definition are vague and ill-defined, for example, risk is considered as an indicator of
threat, or depends on threats, vulnerability, impact and uncertainty.[citation needed]
In engineering, the definition risk often simply is:
\text{Risk} = (\text{probability of an accident}) \times (\text{losses per accident}).\,
Or in more general terms:
\text{Risk} = (\text{probability of risk occurring}) \times (\text{impact of risk occuring}).\,
There are more sophisticated definitions, however. Measuring engineering risk is often difficult,
especially in potentially dangerous industries such as nuclear energy. Often, the probability of a negative
event is estimated by using the frequency of past similar events or by event-tree methods, but
probabilities for rare failures may be difficult to estimate if an event tree cannot be formulated.
Methods to calculate the cost of the loss of human life vary depending on the purpose of the
calculation. Specific methods include what people are willing to pay to insure against death,[1] and
radiological release (e.g., GBq of radio-iodine).[citation needed] There are many formal methods used to
assess or to "measure" risk, considered as one of the critical indicators important for human decision
making.
Financial risk is often defined as the unexpected variability or volatility of returns and thus includes both
potential worse-than-expected as well as better-than-expected returns. References to negative risk
below should be read as applying to positive impacts or opportunity (e.g., for "loss" read "loss or gain")
unless the context precludes.
In statistics, risk is often mapped to the probability of some event which is seen as undesirable. Usually,
the probability of that event and some assessment of its expected harm must be combined into a
believable scenario (an outcome), which combines the set of risk, regret and reward probabilities into an
expected value for that outcome. (See also Expected utility.)
Thus, in statistical decision theory, the risk function of an estimator δ(x) for a parameter θ, calculated
from some observables x, is defined as the expectation value of the loss function L,
R(\theta,\delta(x)) = \int L(\theta,\delta(x)) f(x|\theta)\,dx
In information security[citation needed], a risk is defined as a function of three variables:
1. the probability that there is a threat
2. the probability that there are any vulnerabilities
3. the potential impact.
If any of these variables approaches zero, the overall risk approaches zero.
The management of actuarial risk is called risk management.
Historical background
Scenario analysis matured during Cold War confrontations between major powers, notably the U.S. and
the USSR. It became widespread in insurance circles in the 1970s when major oil tanker disasters forced
a more comprehensive foresight.[citation needed] The scientific approach to risk entered finance in the
1980s when financial derivatives proliferated. It reached general professions in the 1990s when the
power of personal computing allowed for widespread data collection and numbers crunching.
Governments are apparently only now learning to use sophisticated risk methods, most obviously to set
standards for environmental regulation, e.g. "pathway analysis" as practiced by the United States
Environmental Protection Agency.
Risk versus uncertainty
In his seminal work Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Frank Knight (1921) established the distinction
between risk and uncertainty.
“
... Uncertainty must be taken in a sense radically distinct from the familiar notion of Risk, from
which it has never been properly separated. The term "risk," as loosely used in everyday speech and in
economic discussion, really covers two things which, functionally at least, in their causal relations to the
phenomena of economic organization, are categorically different. ... The essential fact is that "risk"
means in some cases a quantity susceptible of measurement, while at other times it is something
distinctly not of this character; and there are far-reaching and crucial differences in the bearings of the
phenomenon depending on which of the two is really present and operating. ... It will appear that a
measurable uncertainty, or "risk" proper, as we shall use the term, is so far different from an
unmeasurable one that it is not in effect an uncertainty at all. We ... accordingly restrict the term
"uncertainty" to cases of the non-quantitive type.
”
A solution to this ambiguity is proposed in "How to Measure Anything: Finding the Value of Intangibles
in Business" by Doug Hubbard:[2]
Uncertainty: The lack of complete certainty, that is, the existence of more than one possibility. The
"true" outcome/state/result/value is not known.
Measurement of uncertainty: A set of probabilities assigned to a set of possibilities. Example:
"There is a 60% chance this market will double in five years"
Risk: A state of uncertainty where some of the possibilities involve a loss, catastrophe, or other
undesirable outcome.
Measurement of risk: A set of possibilities each with quantified probabilities and quantified losses.
Example: "There is a 40% chance the proposed oil well will be dry with a loss of $12 million in
exploratory drilling costs".
In this sense, Hubbard uses the terms so that one may have uncertainty without risk but not risk without
uncertainty. We can be uncertain about the winner of a contest, but unless we have some personal
stake in it, we have no risk. If we bet money on the outcome of the contest, then we have a risk. In both
cases there are more than one outcome. The measure of uncertainty refers only to the probabilities
assigned to outcomes, while the measure of risk requires both probabilities for outcomes and losses
quantified for outcomes.
Insurance and health risk
Insurance is a risk-reducing investment in which the buyer pays a small fixed amount to be protected
from a potential large loss. Gambling is a risk-increasing investment, wherein money on hand is risked
for a possible large return, but with the possibility of losing it all. Purchasing a lottery ticket is a very
risky investment with a high chance of no return and a small chance of a very high return. In contrast,
putting money in a bank at a defined rate of interest is a risk-averse action that gives a guaranteed
return of a small gain and precludes other investments with possibly higher gain.
Risks in personal health may be reduced by primary prevention actions that decrease early causes of
illness or by secondary prevention actions after a person has clearly measured clinical signs or symptoms
recognized as risk factors. Tertiary prevention (medical) reduces the negative impact of an already
established disease by restoring function and reducing disease-related complications. Ethical medical
practice requires careful discussion of risk factors with individual patients to obtain informed consent for
secondary and tertiary prevention efforts, whereas public health efforts in primary prevention require
education of the entire population at risk. In each case, careful communication about risk factors, likely
outcomes and certainty must distinguish between causal events that must be decreased and associated
events that may be merely consequences rather than causes.
Economic risk
Insight
The central insight in the methodology for incorporating economic risks arise from the realization of the
fact that however manifold and diverse might be the causes, or factors, of risks around a specific project
or business (for instance, the hike in the price for raw materials, the lapsing of deadlines for construction
of a new operating facility, disruptions in a production process, emergence of a serious competitor on
the market, the loss of key personnel, the change of a political regime, natural contingencies, etc.), all of
these are ultimately manifested under only two guises. According to CCF Conception the economic risk
consists in that: "Actual positive conventional cash flows (income, inflows) turn out to be less than
expected AND / OR Actual negative conventional cash flows (expenditures, outflows) turn out to be
larger than expected (in absolute terms)".
Such lucid and unambiguous conceptual treatment of such a complex and multi-faceted notion as the
economic risk emphasizes the very core of the question. The "economic risk is not an abstract
‘uncertainty’ or ‘possibility of failure’ or changeableness (variability) of the outcome… The economic risk
– is a monetary amount which might be under-collected and/or over-paid." Just as in music, one must
use musical notes and staves—not alphabet letters or colors—to render a melody, in describing
economic risk, we must ultimately operate with monetary units and not with the percentages of
discount rates, magnitudes of volatility or anything else. (See [1].)
In business
Means of assessing risk vary widely between professions. Indeed, they may define these professions; for
example, a doctor manages medical risk, while a civil engineer manages risk of structural failure. A
professional code of ethics is usually focused on risk assessment and mitigation (by the professional on
behalf of client, public, society or life in general).
In the workplace, incidental and inherent risks exist. Incidental risks are those which occur naturally in
the business but are not part of the core of the business. Inherent risks have a negative effect on the
operating profit of the business.
Criticism
Criticism has been leveled at the amoral ("rational") application of quantitative risk assessment.[citation
needed]
Risk-sensitive industries
Some industries manage risk in a highly quantified and numerate way. These include the nuclear power
and aircraft industries, where the possible failure of a complex series of engineered systems could result
in highly undesirable outcomes. The usual measure of risk for a class of events is then:
R = probability of the event × C
The total risk is then the sum of the individual class-risks.
In the nuclear industry, consequence is often measured in terms of off-site radiological release, and this
is often banded into five or six decade-wide bands.
The risks are evaluated using fault tree/event tree techniques (see safety engineering). Where these
risks are low, they are normally considered to be "Broadly Acceptable". A higher level of risk (typically up
to 10 to 100 times what is considered Broadly Acceptable) has to be justified against the costs of
reducing it further and the possible benefits that make it tolerable—these risks are described as
"Tolerable if ALARP". Risks beyond this level are classified as "Intolerable".
The level of risk deemed Broadly Acceptable has been considered by regulatory bodies in various
countries—an early attempt by UK government regulator and academic F. R. Farmer used the example
of hill-walking and similar activities which have definable risks that people appear to find acceptable.
This resulted in the so-called Farmer Curve of acceptable probability of an event versus its consequence.
The technique as a whole is usually referred to as Probabilistic Risk Assessment (PRA) (or Probabilistic
Safety Assessment, PSA). See WASH-1400 for an example of this approach.
In finance
In finance, risk is the probability that an investment's actual return will be different than expected. This
includes the possibility of losing some or all of the original investment. It is usually measured by
calculating the standard deviation of the historical returns or average returns of a specific
investment.[citation needed]
In finance, risk has no one definition, but some theorists, notably Ron Dembo, have defined quite
general methods to assess risk as an expected after-the-fact level of regret. Such methods have been
uniquely successful in limiting interest rate risk in financial markets. Financial markets are considered to
be a proving ground for general methods of risk assessment.
However, these methods are also hard to understand. The mathematical difficulties interfere with other
social goods such as disclosure, valuation and transparency. In particular, it is often difficult to tell if such
financial instruments are "hedging" (purchasing/selling a financial instrument specifically to reduce or
cancel out the risk in another investment) or "gambling" (increasing measurable risk and exposing the
investor to catastrophic loss in pursuit of very high windfalls that increase expected value).
As regret measures rarely reflect actual human risk-aversion, it is difficult to determine if the outcomes
of such transactions will be satisfactory. Risk seeking describes an individual whose utility function's
second derivative is positive. Such an individual would willingly (actually pay a premium to) assume all
risk in the economy and is hence not likely to exist.
In financial markets, one may need to measure credit risk, information timing and source risk,
probability model risk, and legal risk if there are regulatory or civil actions taken as a result of some
"investor's regret".
"A fundamental idea in finance is the relationship between risk and return. The greater the amount of
risk that an investor is willing to take on, the greater the potential return. The reason for this is that
investors need to be compensated for taking on additional risk."
"For example, a US Treasury bond is considered to be one of the safest investments and, when
compared to a corporate bond, provides a lower rate of return. The reason for this is that a corporation
is much more likely to go bankrupt than the U.S. government. Because the risk of investing in a
corporate bond is higher, investors are offered a higher rate of return."
In public works
In a peer reviewed study of risk in public works projects located in twenty nations on five continents,
Flyvbjerg, Holm, and Buhl (2002, 2005) documented high risks for such ventures for both costs [2] and
demand [3]. Actual costs of projects were typically higher than estimated costs; cost overruns of 50%
were common, overruns above 100% not uncommon. Actual demand was often lower than estimated;
demand shortfalls of 25% were common, of 50% not uncommon.
Due to such cost and demand risks, cost-benefit analyses of public works projects have proved to be
highly uncertain.
The main causes of cost and demand risks were found to be optimism bias and strategic
misrepresentation. Measures identified to mitigate this type of risk are better governance through
incentive alignment and the use of reference class forecasting. [4]
In human services
Huge ethical and political issues arise when human beings themselves are seen or treated as 'risks', or
when the risk decision making of people who use human services might have an impact on that service.
The experience of many people who rely on human services for support is that 'risk' is often used as a
reason to prevent them from gaining further independence or fully accessing the community, and that
these services are often unnecessarily risk averse.[3]
Regret
In decision theory, regret (and anticipation of regret) can play a significant part in decision-making,
distinct from risk aversion (preferring the status quo in case one becomes worse off).
Framing
Framing (Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman, 1981. "The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of
Choice.") is a fundamental problem with all forms of risk assessment. In particular, because of bounded
rationality (our brains get overloaded, so we take mental shortcuts), the risk of extreme events is
discounted because the probability is too low to evaluate intuitively. As an example, one of the leading
causes of death is road accidents caused by drunk driving—partly because any given driver frames the
problem by largely or totally ignoring the risk of a serious or fatal accident.
For instance, an extremely disturbing event (an attack by hijacking, or moral hazards) may be ignored in
analysis despite the fact it has occurred and has a nonzero probability. Or, an event that everyone
agrees is inevitable may be ruled out of analysis due to greed or an unwillingness to admit that it is
believed to be inevitable. These human tendencies to error and wishful thinking often affect even the
most rigorous applications of the scientific method and are a major concern of the philosophy of
science.
All decision-making under uncertainty must consider cognitive bias, cultural bias, and notational bias: No
group of people assessing risk is immune to "groupthink": acceptance of obviously wrong answers
simply because it is socially painful to disagree, where there are conflicts of interest. One effective way
to solve framing problems in risk assessment or measurement (although some argue that risk cannot be
measured, only assessed) is to raise others' fears or personal ideals by way of completeness.
Fear as intuitive risk assessment
For the time being, people rely on their fear and hesitation to keep them out of the most profoundly
unknown circumstances.
In The Gift of Fear, Gavin de Becker argues that "True fear is a gift. It is a survival signal that sounds only
in the presence of danger. Yet unwarranted fear has assumed a power over us that it holds over no
other creature on Earth. It need not be this way."
Risk could be said to be the way we collectively measure and share this "true fear"—a fusion of rational
doubt, irrational fear, and a set of unquantified biases from our own experience.
The field of behavioral finance focuses on human risk-aversion, asymmetric regret, and other ways that
human financial behavior varies from what analysts call "rational". Risk in that case is the degree of
uncertainty associated with a return on an asset.
Recognizing and respecting the irrational influences on human decision making may do much to reduce
disasters caused by naive risk assessments that pretend to rationality but in fact merely fuse many
shared biases together.
Root causes of risk
Optimism bias and strategic misrepresentation have been found to be root causes of risk.[citation
needed]
Risk assessment and management
Because planned actions are subject to large cost and benefit risks, proper risk assessment and risk
management for such actions are crucial to making them successful (Flyvbjerg 2006).
Since Risk assessment and management is essential in security management, both are tightly related.
Security assessment methodologies like BEATO or CRAMM contain risk assessment modules as an
important part of the first steps of the methodology. On the other hand, Risk Assessment
methodologies, like Mehari evolved to become Security Assessment methodologies. A ISO standard on
risk management (Principles and guidelines on implementation) is currently being draft under code
ISO/DIS 31000. Target publication date 30 May 2009.
Risk in auditing
The audit risk model expresses the risk of an auditor providing an inappropriate opinion of a commercial
entity's financial statements. It can be analytically expressed as:
AR = IR x CR x DR
Where AR is audit risk, IR is inherent risk, CR is control risk and DR is detection risk.
Categories of risks
* Political: Change of government, cross cutting policy decisions (e.g., the Euro).
* Regulatory: Change of policy by state, national or multinational regulatory bodies
* Market: Fundamental change in supply and demand functions or global prices for commodities
* Professional: Associated with the nature of each profession.
* Economic: Ability to attract and retain staff in the labour market; exchange rates affect costs of
international transactions; effect of global economy on UK economy.
* Socio-cultural: Demographic change affects demand for services; stakeholder expectations change.
* Health and Safety: Buildings, vehicles, equipment, fire, noise, vibration, asbestos, chemical and
biological hazards, food safety, traffic management, stress, lone working, etc.
* Technological: Obsolescence of current systems; cost of procuring best technology available,
opportunity arising from technological development.
* Contractual: Associated with the failure of contractors to deliver devices or products to the agreed
cost and specification.
* Environmental: Buildings need to comply with changing standards; disposal of rubbish and surplus
equipment needs to comply with changing standards.
* Physical: Theft, vandalism, arson, building related risks, Storm, flood, other related weather, damage
to vehicles, mobile plant and equipment.
* Operational: Relating to existing operations – both current delivery and building and maintaining.
Chapter 5
Risk
management
Risk management is a structured approach to managing uncertainty related to a threat, a sequence of
human activities including: risk assessment, strategies development to manage it, and mitigation of risk
using managerial resources.
The strategies include transferring the risk to another party, avoiding the risk, reducing the negative
effect of the risk, and accepting some or all of the consequences of a particular risk.
Some traditional risk managements are focused on risks stemming from physical or legal causes (e.g.
natural disasters or fires, accidents, ergonomics, death and lawsuits). Financial risk management, on the
other hand, focuses on risks that can be managed using traded financial instruments.
The objective of risk management is to reduce different risks related to a preselected domain to the
level accepted by society. It may refer to numerous types of threats caused by environment, technology,
humans, organizations and politics. On the other hand it involves all means available for humans, or in
particular, for a risk management entity (person, staff, organization). Some explanations
In ideal risk management, a prioritization process is followed whereby the risks with the greatest loss
and the greatest probability of occurring are handled first, and risks with lower probability of occurrence
and lower loss are handled in descending order. In practice the process can be very difficult, and
balancing between risks with a high probability of occurrence but lower loss versus a risk with high loss
but lower probability of occurrence can often be mishandled.
Intangible risk management identifies a new type of risk - a risk that has a 100% probability of occurring
but is ignored by the organization due to a lack of identification ability. For example, when deficient
knowledge is applied to a situation, a knowledge risk materialises. Relationship risk appears when
ineffective collaboration occurs. Process-engagement risk may be an issue when ineffective operational
procedures are applied. These risks directly reduce the productivity of knowledge workers, decrease
cost effectiveness, profitability, service, quality, reputation, brand value, and earnings quality. Intangible
risk management allows risk management to create immediate value from the identification and
reduction of risks that reduce productivity.
Risk management also faces difficulties allocating resources. This is the idea of opportunity cost.
Resources spent on risk management could have been spent on more profitable activities. Again, ideal
risk management minimizes spending while maximizing the reduction of the negative effects of risks.
Steps in the risk management process
Establish the context
Establishing the context involves
1. Identification of risk in a selected domain of interest
2. Planning the remainder of the process.
3. Mapping out the following:
* the social scope of risk management
* the identity and objectives of stakeholders
* the basis upon which risks will be evaluated, constraints.
4. Defining a framework for the activity and an agenda for identification.
5. Developing an analysis of risks involved in the process.
6. Mitigation of risks using available technological, human and organizational resources.
Identification
After establishing the context, the next step in the process of managing risk is to identify potential risks.
Risks are about events that, when triggered, cause problems. Hence, risk identification can start with the
source of problems, or with the problem itself.
* Source analysis Risk sources may be internal or external to the system that is the target of risk
management. Examples of risk sources are: stakeholders of a project, employees of a company or the
weather over an airport.
* Problem analysis Risks are related to identified threats. For example: the threat of losing money, the
threat of abuse of privacy information or the threat of accidents and casualties. The threats may exist
with various entities, most important with shareholders, customers and legislative bodies such as the
government.
When either source or problem is known, the events that a source may trigger or the events that can
lead to a problem can be investigated. For example: stakeholders withdrawing during a project may
endanger funding of the project; privacy information may be stolen by employees even within a closed
network; lightning striking a Boeing 747 during takeoff may make all people onboard immediate
casualties.
The chosen method of identifying risks may depend on culture, industry practice and compliance. The
identification methods are formed by templates or the development of templates for identifying source,
problem or event. Common risk identification methods are:
* Objectives-based risk identification Organizations and project teams have objectives. Any event that
may endanger achieving an objective partly or completely is identified as risk.
* Scenario-based risk identification In scenario analysis different scenarios are created. The scenarios
may be the alternative ways to achieve an objective, or an analysis of the interaction of forces in, for
example, a market or battle. Any event that triggers an undesired scenario alternative is identified as
risk - see Futures Studies for methodology used by Futurists.
* Taxonomy-based risk identification The taxonomy in taxonomy-based risk identification is a
breakdown of possible risk sources. Based on the taxonomy and knowledge of best practices, a
questionnaire is compiled. The answers to the questions reveal risks. Taxonomy-based risk identification
in software industry can be found in CMU/SEI-93-TR-6.
* Common-risk Checking In several industries lists with known risks are available. Each risk in the list
can be checked for application to a particular situation. An example of known risks in the software
industry is the Common Vulnerability and Exposures list found at http://cve.mitre.org.
* Risk Charting This method combines the above approaches by listing Resources at risk, Threats to
those resources Modifying Factors which may increase or decrease the risk and Consequences it is
wished to avoid. Creating a matrix under these headings enables a variety of approaches. One can begin
with resources and consider the threats they are exposed to and the consequences of each.
Alternatively one can start with the threats and examine which resources they would affect, or one can
begin with the consequences and determine which combination of threats and resources would be
involved to bring them about.
Assessment
Once risks have been identified, they must then be assessed as to their potential severity of loss and to
the probability of occurrence. These quantities can be either simple to measure, in the case of the value
of a lost building, or impossible to know for sure in the case of the probability of an unlikely event
occurring. Therefore, in the assessment process it is critical to make the best educated guesses possible
in order to properly prioritize the implementation of the risk management plan.
The fundamental difficulty in risk assessment is determining the rate of occurrence since statistical
information is not available on all kinds of past incidents. Furthermore, evaluating the severity of the
consequences (impact) is often quite difficult for immaterial assets. Asset valuation is another question
that needs to be addressed. Thus, best educated opinions and available statistics are the primary
sources of information. Nevertheless, risk assessment should produce such information for the
management of the organization that the primary risks are easy to understand and that the risk
management decisions may be prioritized. Thus, there have been several theories and attempts to
quantify risks. Numerous different risk formulae exist, but perhaps the most widely accepted formula
for risk quantification is:
Rate of occurrence multiplied by the impact of the event equals risk
Later research has shown that the financial benefits of risk management are less dependent on the
formula used but are more dependent on the frequency and how risk assessment is performed.
In business it is imperative to be able to present the findings of risk assessments in financial terms.
Robert Courtney Jr. (IBM, 1970) proposed a formula for presenting risks in financial terms. The Courtney
formula was accepted as the official risk analysis method for the US governmental agencies. The formula
proposes calculation of ALE (annualised loss expectancy) and compares the expected loss value to the
security control implementation costs (cost-benefit analysis).
Potential risk treatments
Once risks have been identified and assessed, all techniques to manage the risk fall into one or more of
these four major categories:[1]
* Avoidance (eliminate)
* Reduction (mitigate)
* Transference (outsource or insure)
* Retention (accept and budget)
Ideal use of these strategies may not be possible. Some of them may involve trade-offs that are not
acceptable to the organization or person making the risk management decisions. Another source, from
the US Department of Defense, Defense Acquisition University, calls these categories ACAT, for Avoid,
Control, Accept, or Transfer. This use of the ACAT acronym is reminiscent of another ACAT (for
Acquisition Category) used in US Defense industry procurements, in which Risk Management figures
prominently in decision making and planning.
Risk avoidance
Includes not performing an activity that could carry risk. An example would be not buying a property or
business in order to not take on the liability that comes with it. Another would be not flying in order to
not take the risk that the airplane were to be hijacked. Avoidance may seem the answer to all risks, but
avoiding risks also means losing out on the potential gain that accepting (retaining) the risk may have
allowed. Not entering a business to avoid the risk of loss also avoids the possibility of earning profits.
Risk reduction
Involves methods that reduce the severity of the loss or the likelihood of the loss from occurring.
Examples include sprinklers designed to put out a fire to reduce the risk of loss by fire. This method may
cause a greater loss by water damage and therefore may not be suitable. Halon fire suppression systems
may mitigate that risk, but the cost may be prohibitive as a strategy.
Modern software development methodologies reduce risk by developing and delivering software
incrementally. Early methodologies suffered from the fact that they only delivered software in the final
phase of development; any problems encountered in earlier phases meant costly rework and often
jeopardized the whole project. By developing in iterations, software projects can limit effort wasted to a
single iteration.
Outsourcing could be an example of risk reduction if the outsourcer can demonstrate higher capability
at managing or reducing risks. [2] In this case companies outsource only some of their departmental
needs. For example, a company may outsource only its software development, the manufacturing of
hard goods, or customer support needs to another company, while handling the business management
itself. This way, the company can concentrate more on business development without having to worry
as much about the manufacturing process, managing the development team, or finding a physical
location for a call center.
Risk retention
Involves accepting the loss when it occurs. True self insurance falls in this category. Risk retention is a
viable strategy for small risks where the cost of insuring against the risk would be greater over time than
the total losses sustained. All risks that are not avoided or transferred are retained by default. This
includes risks that are so large or catastrophic that they either cannot be insured against or the
premiums would be infeasible. War is an example since most property and risks are not insured against
war, so the loss attributed by war is retained by the insured. Also any amounts of potential loss (risk)
over the amount insured is retained risk. This may also be acceptable if the chance of a very large loss is
small or if the cost to insure for greater coverage amounts is so great it would hinder the goals of the
organization too much.
Risk Transference
Many sectors have for a long time regarded insurance as a transfer of risk. This is not correct. Insurance
is a post event compensatory mechanism. That is, even if an insurance policy has been effected this
does not mean that the risk has been transferred. For example, a personal injuries insurance policy does
not transfer the risk of a car accident to the insurance company. The risk still lies with the policy holder
namely the person who has been in the accident. The insurance policy simply provides that if an
accident (the event) occurs involving the policy holder then some compensation may be payable to the
policy holder that is commensurate to the suffering/damage.
{the rest needs to be substantially altered] Means causing another party to accept the risk, typically by
contract or by hedging. Insurance is one type of risk transfer that uses contracts. Other times it may
involve contract language that transfers a risk to another party without the payment of an insurance
premium. Liability among construction or other contractors is very often transferred this way. On the
other hand, taking offsetting positions in derivatives is typically how firms use hedging to financially
manage risk.
Some ways of managing risk fall into multiple categories. Risk retention pools are technically retaining
the risk for the group, but spreading it over the whole group involves transfer among individual
members of the group. This is different from traditional insurance, in that no premium is exchanged
between members of the group up front, but instead losses are assessed to all members of the group.
Create a risk management plan
Select appropriate controls or countermeasures to measure each risk. Risk mitigation needs to be
approved by the appropriate level of management. For example, a risk concerning the image of the
organization should have top management decision behind it whereas IT management would have the
authority to decide on computer virus risks.
The risk management plan should propose applicable and effective security controls for managing the
risks. For example, an observed high risk of computer viruses could be mitigated by acquiring and
implementing antivirus software. A good risk management plan should contain a schedule for control
implementation and responsible persons for those actions.
According to ISO/IEC 27001, the stage immediately after completion of the Risk Assessment phase
consists of preparing a Risk Treatment Plan, which should document the decisions about how each of
the identified risks should be handled. Mitigation of risks often means selection of Security Controls,
which should be documented in a Statement of Applicability, which identifies which particular control
objectives and controls from the standard have been selected, and why.
Implementation
Follow all of the planned methods for mitigating the effect of the risks. Purchase insurance policies for
the risks that have been decided to be transferred to an insurer, avoid all risks that can be avoided
without sacrificing the entity's goals, reduce others, and retain the rest.
Review and evaluation of the plan
Initial risk management plans will never be perfect. Practice, experience, and actual loss results will
necessitate changes in the plan and contribute information to allow possible different decisions to be
made in dealing with the risks being faced.
Risk analysis results and management plans should be updated periodically. There are two primary
reasons for this:
1. to evaluate whether the previously selected security controls are still applicable and effective, and
2. to evaluate the possible risk level changes in the business environment. For example, information
risks are a good example of rapidly changing business environment.
Limitations
If risks are improperly assessed and prioritized, time can be wasted in dealing with risk of losses that are
not likely to occur. Spending too much time assessing and managing unlikely risks can divert resources
that could be used more profitably. Unlikely events do occur but if the risk is unlikely enough to occur it
may be better to simply retain the risk and deal with the result if the loss does in fact occur.
Prioritizing too highly the risk management processes could keep an organization from ever completing
a project or even getting started. This is especially true if other work is suspended until the risk
management process is considered complete.
It is also important to keep in mind the distinction between risk and uncertainty. Risk can be measured
by impacts x probability.
Areas of risk management
As applied to corporate finance, risk management is the technique for measuring, monitoring and
controlling the financial or operational risk on a firm's balance sheet. See value at risk.
The Basel II framework breaks risks into market risk (price risk), credit risk and operational risk and also
specifies methods for calculating capital requirements for each of these components.
Enterprise risk management
In enterprise risk management, a risk is defined as a possible event or circumstance that can have
negative influences on the enterprise in question. Its impact can be on the very existence, the resources
(human and capital), the products and services, or the customers of the enterprise, as well as external
impacts on society, markets, or the environment. In a financial institution, enterprise risk management
is normally thought of as the combination of credit risk, interest rate risk or asset liability management,
market risk, and operational risk.
In the more general case, every probable risk can have a pre-formulated plan to deal with its possible
consequences (to ensure contingency if the risk becomes a liability).
From the information above and the average cost per employee over time, or cost accrual ratio, a
project manager can estimate:
* the cost associated with the risk if it arises, estimated by multiplying employee costs per unit time
by the estimated time lost (cost impact, C where C = cost accrual ratio * S).
* the probable increase in time associated with a risk (schedule variance due to risk, Rs where Rs = P *
S):
o Sorting on this value puts the highest risks to the schedule first. This is intended to cause the
greatest risks to the project to be attempted first so that risk is minimized as quickly as possible.
o This is slightly misleading as schedule variances with a large P and small S and vice versa are not
equivalent. (The risk of the RMS Titanic sinking vs. the passengers' meals being served at slightly the
wrong time).
* the probable increase in cost associated with a risk (cost variance due to risk, Rc where Rc = P*C =
P*CAR*S = P*S*CAR)
o sorting on this value puts the highest risks to the budget first.
o see concerns about schedule variance as this is a function of it, as illustrated in the equation
above.
Risk in a project or process can be due either to Special Cause Variation or Common Cause Variation and
requires appropriate treatment. That is to re-iterate the concern about extremal cases not being
equivalent in the list immediately above.
Risk management activities as applied to project management
In project management, risk management includes the following activities:
* Planning how risk management will be held in the particular project. Plan should include risk
management tasks, responsibilities, activities and budget.
* Assigning a risk officer - a team member other than a project manager who is responsible for
foreseeing potential project problems. Typical characteristic of risk officer is a healthy skepticism.
* Maintaining live project risk database. Each risk should have the following attributes: opening date,
title, short description, probability and importance. Optionally a risk may have an assigned person
responsible for its resolution and a date by which the risk must be resolved.
* Creating anonymous risk reporting channel. Each team member should have possibility to report risk
that he foresees in the project.
* Preparing mitigation plans for risks that are chosen to be mitigated. The purpose of the mitigation
plan is to describe how this particular risk will be handled – what, when, by who and how will it be done
to avoid it or minimize consequences if it becomes a liability.
* Summarizing planned and faced risks, effectiveness of mitigation activities, and effort spent for the
risk management.
Risk management and business continuity
Risk management is simply a practice of systematically selecting cost effective approaches for
minimising the effect of threat realization to the organization. All risks can never be fully avoided or
mitigated simply because of financial and practical limitations. Therefore all organizations have to
accept some level of residual risks.
Whereas risk management tends to be preemptive, business continuity planning (BCP) was invented to
deal with the consequences of realised residual risks. The necessity to have BCP in place arises because
even very unlikely events will occur if given enough time. Risk management and BCP are often
mistakenly seen as rivals or overlapping practices. In fact these processes are so tightly tied together
that such separation seems artificial. For example, the risk management process creates important
inputs for the BCP (assets, impact assessments, cost estimates etc). Risk management also proposes
applicable controls for the observed risks. Therefore, risk management covers several areas that are
vital for the BCP process. However, the BCP process goes beyond risk management's preemptive
approach and moves on from the assumption that the disaster will realize at some point.
Chapter 6
Responsible
decision
making
People have different ways of making decisions. Inactive decision making is delaying a decision in the
hope that the situation will resolve itself. Reactive decision making is allowing the views and opinions of
others to determine your decision. Proactive decision making, on the other hand, is looking at a decision
that must be made, considering the options, choosing a plan of action, and taking responsibility for the
outcome. Proactive decision making gives a person a greater degree of control over the problem
situation being addressed.
In order to make proactive, responsible decisions, follow these seven steps:
1. State the problem.
2. List the options.
3. Think about the possible benefits and consequences of each option.
4. Consider your own value and beliefs.
5. Weigh the option and then decide which one to take. If possible, share your list with a friend or adult.
6. Act.
7. Evalauate the results.
Inactive decision making
Inactive decision making is when the decider does nothing consequential to make a definite choice. In
effect, the choice is to let the problem resolve itself. This approach is quite common in everyday human
decision making due to the peculiarities of human nature. However, it is not a rational approach to
making decisions, for little or no reasoning is actually done. From a strategic viewpoint, the decider is
forgoing opportunities to influence the outcome.
Reactive decision making
Reactive decision making is when the decider opts for a course of action by reacting to the choices made
by other stakeholders in the problem. This approach is rather common in everyday human decision
making. Deciding reactively may at times give the impression of being a rational act in a given set of
circumstances, but beware: simply reacting to the actions of others can easily expose the decider to
unforeseen risks. Strategically, it is neither a rational nor advisable approach.
Making good decisions under pressure by Kellie Fowler
People tend to make decisions reactively when confronted with emergency situations or when a disaster
unfolds. In these circumstances, the best decisions tend to be those that have been thought-through
and rehearsed ahead of time, a good example being use of a pre-prepared evacuation plan when the
office catches on fire.
The normal decision-making process generally involves:
1. Defining the problem,
2. Collecting necessary information,
3. Developing options,
4. Devising a plan,
5. Executing and
6. Following-up.
However reactive decision-making is. reactive. Because of this, there is not usually time to execute this
full decision-making process, meaning that it's all-too-easy to make a bad decision when under pressure.
What this means is that actions to be taken in an emergency should be carefully planned for beforehand
so that you can act appropriately when an event occurs. This may include, for example, devising
contingency plans for what to do when a supplier ships poor quality goods when you are on a very tight
deadline, or planning how to get essential systems back online if your office premises are burgled and
computers are stolen.
Chapter 7
Behavioral
Decision
Making
Physical sciences are in general based on the cause-and-effect logic. Human’s behaviors are, however
based on motives. There is always a motivation force generated by some causes and purposes that can
tell why a person makes a particular decision, i.e., the Emotivisim School of thought.
Managers wish to motivate workers to exert effort. For example, there is large literature on the use of
wages and monetary incentives for this purpose, but in practice the "honor" or "prestige" of an award
can be a significant motivator as well, unless the award is given so often that its prestige is diluted. The
main focus must be on management of the reputation of an award that may or may not have a fixed
monetary component but how to manage the award over time.
The cardinal aim of modeling human behavior is to model a business process that increases workforce
enthusiasm considering all aspects of human behavior including group dynamics, project work climate,
and organizational culture.
A Behavioral Decision Making Classification: Decision making types may allows for only three unique
systems of making decisions:
1. Individualism -- which access inequity, relishes competition and identifies with the rights and power
of the individual.
2. Collaboration -- which treats all men as equally important, exalts collaborative efforts and identifies
with unlimited democracy.
3. Power and authority -- which respects power and identifies with controlling authority.
An organizational system based upon the "nature of man" blends the three possible systems into a
harmonious unity, accepting that any one of the systems standing alone is both unstable and ineffective.
The universality of the three decision-making processes seems obvious. Everyone wants to be free to
make his or her own decisions. At the same time, everyone needs the companionship and the sense of
belonging that comes with being part of a group, and everyone fears the absolute solitude of
unrestricted freedom. Finally, everyone wants to believe in something or someone, to conform his or
her behavior to some kind of authority, whether that authority comes internally from religious, political,
or cultural values or externally from a leader in a hierarchy.
While it may seem obvious that everyone relies upon these three types of decision making, our political
conversations often polarize into conflicts of two decision-making types, a battle of group consensus
versus individual freedom. We have dogmas of the "left" and "right" or of "liberals" and "conservatives."
Conforming to these dogmas is a serious blunder. Dogmas of the left or right fail to recognize the role
that authority plays in balancing the interests of the group and the individual. Without a balance of all
three types, organizations can quickly become unstable and ineffective.
Organizations use decision-making processes that vary from elaborate designs with numerous decision
points to relatively simple procedures. In each case, the process relies on a mix of the three types of
decision making inherent in human thinking:
* Individual decision making based upon self interest,
* Group decision making based upon consensus, and
* Authoritative decision making based upon values, rules and hierarchies. The organizations that
succeed during both good times and bad times are those that maintain an effective balance between
these three ways of choosing a course of action. In fact, what we regard as a "civil" society is one that
balances the three decision-making methods in a constant tug of war. As a result, modern "civil"
societies facilitate the creation of balanced organizations.
There have been two extreme approaches to modeling human behavior. The simple models emphasis
on "rational persons," while other's emphasis is on the fact that people have much more complex
motivations, both individually and collectively, especially in herd-instinct, or malicious-intent situations.
An integrative descriptive model for human behavior must consider all aspects of decision-making
factors including use the economic, sociology, law, and social psychology. This might be achieved at
three levels: the individual, the organization, and the society, with interactions among the three. The
interactions among these three levels include flows of information, and resources, and within each
system of values and decision structures. These two kinds of flows shape the interactions between these
three levels.
Facing Unfavorable Outcome of a Good Decision: Often an unfavorable outcome of a good decision
leads individuals to switch away from that decision due to negative emotional responses to the
outcome. Negative emotional reactions led many to abandon the option that they recalled as having
been more successful in the past and which they expected to perform better in the future. They focus
on their affective reactions rather than beliefs about the earlier disappointing outcome. Those
individuals with a general tendency to focus on their needed cognition are less likely to switch away
from the better option following a disappointing outcome. It is also likely that an emotional reaction to a
negative outcome lead people to switch away from the options that they believe might be successful on
the next occasion.
Feeling versus Being: Feeling is different form being. Feeling is the mind response while being is the
bodily manifestation of the same thing. For example, feeling of being sad is an emotion, which is not
measurable, however, being sad, is a bodily response and therefore, the degree of being sadness is
measurable on numerical scales by the appropriate psychometric instruments.
Conflict Is a Part of Life: People and businesses suffer when conflict is ignored and not managed
properly. Relationships are strained, productivity diminishes, and destruction can be the ultimate result.
Many of us are so averse to conflict that we practice appeasement at any price, while others cling to
adversarial approaches, which can escalate all the costs of settling differences. These behaviors are
often the spawning ground for further conflict. They occur because we do not know about how to
effectively use the array of possibilities that exist for successful conflict management. The OR/MS/DS/SS
use of conflict modelling is in model-based decision support systems, i.e., the use of flexible, userfriendly software to build up systems of decision makers, set of options, and preferences. This facilitates
rapid change in one's assumptions, and conditions among the participants.
Behavioral decision-making is to understand how people make decisions and how they can make the
decision-making process more effective and efficient. A person could be very conservative, or perpetual
in making any decision. The behavior sciences are applicable to decision processes from both
quantitative and qualitative viewpoints to improve a stronger foundation for making better decisions.
The decision-maker's style and characteristics can be classified as: the thinker, the cowboy (snap and
uncompromising), Machiavellian (ends justifies the means), the historian (how others did it), the
cautious (even nervous), etc.
Decision-Making versus Habits: Decision-making involves reaching a conclusion, which implies
deliberation and thought and suggests a conscious act. While a natural reaction or unconscious act
would be labeled as habit, reflex act, or impulsive act, or habit which is, unfortunately the center of
gravity when we want to start the decision-making process.
The Manager versus the Leader: A manager is defined, as a person who decides on "how to do the
things right" while a leader is concerned with "how to do the right things
Power and the Leadership: Strategy implementation is a political process that involves bargaining,
persuasion, and confrontation among actors who divide power.
People in power usually want to stay there. And one way they think they can do this is by enforcing rigid
adherence to a set of principles that they believe are responsible for their organization's success. By
requiring employees to abide by these superstitions -- better known as company policies -- rather than
examining the facts, they build organizations that appear streamlined. In fact, they are doomed.
There is no such thing as "organizational behavior;" it is the behavior of the people in the organization. It
is impossible to understand the decision-maker's behavior in organizational situations where conflict
exists without considering the role of power. Power has a major impact on information, uncertainty, and
resource dependency since there is competition among organization's members for scarce resources.
There is a big difference between management and leadership: while management works in the system,
leadership works on the system. If one is able enough to accurately define all three of these parameters;
Task, Time, and Resources, then one is able to deal with the decision-making modeling process. The very
essence of leadership is that you have to have vision for these parameters. You can't blow an uncertain
trumpet.
Leadership is defined as, "the quality of a leader, and the capacity to lead." It can also be defined as
setting the example. Whether they realize it or not, a given staff will look to the leader to set the trend
in the workplace. So what trend are you setting? There is a reason the CEO of a multi-billion dollar
international soft drink company spends one day a month delivering cases of soda via delivery truck and
wheeled dolly. Because he's smart and successful, and his staff is watching him like a hawk. They can't
help but copy and respect the CEO's sense of enthusiasm and commitment to what the business is really
all about--getting product into customer's hands.
The Challenge of Leadership is mainly its human-side. The leader is to be strong, but not rude; kind, but
not weak; bold, but not a bully; thoughtful, but not lazy; humble, but not timid; proud, but not arrogant;
and have a sense of humor, without folly.
Before the leaders can inspire with emotion, they must be swamped with it themselves. Before they can
move the tears of others, their own must flow. To convince others, they must themselves believe.
Evil and Unethical Decisions: One must certainly be aware of the big difference between unethical and
evil decisions. The CEO for an internationally known tire company signs off on the production of tires
that he knows are likely to disintegrate under certain conditions. Even with such knowledge, he makes it
clear that this information is not to be publicized and approves production and sales of the tires. Decide
whether such a decision is an evil or unethical one? What about this scenario? An administrator in a
fascist country followed the orders of his superior and signed off on the death of thousands of innocent
men, women and children. He never personally killed any of those people himself nor would he.
Without integrity, no company can have positive word of mouth.
Reason Is Not the Supreme Judge: The critical and postmodern organization theorists have already built
their case against Reason. They see reason as "disciplinary knowledge" in modern organizations because
it constrains the natural autonomy of the individual. This view, all of the social sciences are seen as
knowledge structures used in domination. Sociology, social work, law, psychology, and most certainly
management and organization theory are implicated. Just as psychology is used to persuade the
individual to adjust to (thus accept) the external world, theories of leadership and organization are used
to develop discourses and classification schemes that reproduce systems of power. By rejecting Western
cultural history, positioning the "naturalness" of the individual, and assuming all discipline is oppressive
power generated by knowledge, critical organization theory and postmodern organization theory
elevate individualism, although only implicitly, to the role of their supreme value.
Instrumental reasoning has been used successfully in science to make our world manageable. For its
utilitarian characteristic, the instrumental reasoning is the supreme judge in any scientific field.
It is possible to use reason to describe everything scientifically, but it would make no sense; it would be
without meaning, as if you described a Beethoven ninth symphony as a variation of wave pressure.
Dealing with People: While senior management formulate clear strategies to achieve the essential fit
between internal strengths and weaknesses and external threats and opportunities. However, strategy
implementation is a social process rooted in culture, involving common interest and integration. People
react and adapt to environmental changes and constraints.
There are two ways to persuade people. The first is by using conventional rhetoric, which is what most
managers are trained in. The other way to persuade people and ultimately a much more powerful way is
by uniting an idea with an emotional appeal.
There are two different types of relationships among people namely the Frequent and Infrequent
relationships. Negotiation is an effective tool for dealing with infrequent relationships. To have an
effective negotiation one must separate the people from the problem, focus on interest (not taking
positions), generate a variety of possibilities, and insist that the results be based on some objective
numerable and measurable scales. For the ongoing relationships the strategies vary. The classical tactics
are: carrots and sticks, tit-for-tat, and live-and-let-live.
Human abuse does not stem from a wanton exercise of power, rather, hurting people is a sign that we
are still lacking power. Or it shows a sense of frustration in the face of this poverty. The blockage of selfdevelopments is what lie behind abusive behavior. Since whoever is dissatisfied with himself is
continually ready for revenge and we others will be his victims. An eye for an eye will make the whole
world go blind.
Progressive Approach to Modeling: Modeling for decision making involves two distinct parties, one is
the decision-maker and the other is the model-builder known as the analyst. The analyst is to assist the
decision-maker in his/her decision-making process. Therefore, the analyst must be equipped with more
than a set of analytical methods.
Specialists in model building are often tempted to study a problem, and then go off in isolation to
develop an elaborate mathematical model for use by the manager (i.e., the decision-maker).
Unfortunately the manager may not understand this model and may either use it blindly or reject it
entirely. The specialist may feel that the manager is too ignorant and unsophisticated to appreciate the
model, while the manager may feel that the specialist lives in a dream world of unrealistic assumptions
and irrelevant mathematical language.
Such miscommunication can be avoided if the manager works with the specialist to develop first a
simple model that provides a crude but understandable analysis. After the manager has built up
confidence in this model, additional detail and sophistication can be added, perhaps progressively only a
bit at a time. This process requires an investment of time on the part of the manager and sincere
interest on the part of the specialist in solving the manager's real problem, rather than in creating and
trying to explain sophisticated models. This progressive model building is often referred to as the
bootstrapping approach and is the most important factor in determining successful implementation of a
decision model. Moreover the bootstrapping approach simplifies otherwise the difficult task of model
validating and verification processes.
Resistance to Decisions: Progress is a nice word. But change is its motivator and change has its enemies.
It is not so much that we are afraid of change or so in love with the old ways, but it is that place in
between that we fear. It's like being between trapezes, there's nothing to hold on to.
Any change, even a change for the better, is always accompanied by drawbacks and discomforts.
Change is not made without inconvenience, even from worse to better. The most universal difficulties
arise from people's fear of planned change. People often oppose a proposed model merely because
they have participated in planning it, or because it may have been planned by those whom they dislike.
People resist changes. More accurately, they resist being changed by other people. Resistance can take
the form of either open hostility or covert sabotage of decision-makers' efforts. Even the best designed
strategy always fails if those who must carry it out refuse to do so. As Machiavelli wrote in The Prince "It
must be remembered that there is nothing more difficult to plan, more uncertain of success, nor more
dangerous to manage than the creation of a new order of things. For the initiator has the enmity of all
who would profit by the preservation of the old institutions, and merely lukewarm defenders in those
who would gain by the new ones."
Incremental versus Optimal Changes: Optimal (i.e., the best) decisions are often used to justify sweeping
organizational changes that may disrupt individual routines. One important value is the cooperation and
morale that can develop when the members of the organization know that they are respected members
of a productive organization. Noting this human-side of decision-making, many organizations use the
goal-seeking approach rather than optimal decisions. This suggests that changes at any time be limited
to a goal, which needs minor deviations from the current situation. This approach to decision-making is
known as incrementalism, or the goal-seeking approach. For example, instead of maximizing profit, one
may set the goal of achieving 10% increase in profit.
Copping with the Major Changes: A Transitional Process : The responses of individuals will vary
considerably not only from person to person, but also over time. By this we mean that a person will
respond negatively to a change at one point, but perhaps have a different attitude to it at a later stage.
However, there is a pattern in the response of an individual to change over a period of time. Obviously
the more traumatic the change, the more pronounced will be the effect.
The major changes at work can resemble other major changes, such as bereavement or marriage, in
their effect on individuals. Often people going through such change progress through the following
process, stage-by-stage:
* Immobilization
* Denial of change
* Incompetence
* Acceptance of reality
* Testing possibilities
* Search for meaning
* Integration
The time taken to accept major changes fully can be as much as say, 18 months or even longer.
However, an understanding of what is happening can often reduce the time needed to come to terms
with change, and to fully adopt new ways of behaving. A leader’s support and concern through the
stages will also be critical for the individual team member faced with major change. Understanding of
the process will also help the leader to deal with the individual in a way appropriate to the stage they
are at.
Webliography
References
1. ^ James Reason (1990). Human Error. Ashgate. ISBN 1840141042.
2. ^ Daniel Kahneman, Amos Tversky (2000). Choice, Values, Frames. The Cambridge
University Press. ISBN 0521621720.
3. ^ Isabel Briggs Myers|Myers, I. (1962) Introduction to Type: A description of the theory and
applications of the Myers-Briggs type indicator, Consulting Psychologists Press, Palo Alto Ca.,
1962.
4. ^ Martinsons, Maris G., Comparing the Decision Styles of American, Chinese and Japanese
Business Leaders. Best Paper Proceedings of Academy of Management Meetings, Washington,
DC, August 2001 [1]
5. ^ a b Katsenelinboigen, Aron. The Concept of Indeterminism and Its Applications:
Economics, Social Systems, Ethics, Artificial Intelligence, and Aesthetics Praeger: Westport,
Connecticut, 1997, p.6)
6. ^ V. Ulea, The Concept of Dramatic Genre and The Comedy of A New Type. Chess,
Literature, and Film. Southern Illinois University Press, 2002, p.p.17-18])
7. ^ Selected Topics in Indeterministic Systems Intersystems Publications: California, 1989, p.
21
1. ^ "A new formula for the index of cost of living", 1939, in Econometrica
2. ^ Goode, Erica. (2001) In Weird Math of Choices, 6 Choices Can Beat 600. The New York Times.
Retrieved May 16, 2005.
http://home.ubalt.edu/ntsbarsh/opre640/partXIII.htm
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Decision_making
Download