Annexure : “AG” IN THE HIGH COURT OF SOUTH AFRICA (TRANSVAAL PROVINCIAL DIVISION) Case no: 4183/98 In the matter between: PHARMACEUTICAL MANUFACTURERS’ ASSOCIATION OF SOUTH AFRICA AND OTHERS Applicants and THE PRESIDENT OF THE REPUBLIC OF SOUTH AFRICA AND OTHERS Respondents and TREATMENT ACTION CAMPAIGN (TAC) Amicus Curiae AFFIDAVIT I, the undersigned: ANDREW GRAY Do hereby make oath and say: 1. I am a lecturer in the School of Pharmacy and Pharmacology (Division of Pharmacy Practice) at the University of Durban-Westville. I have held this position since 1994. 2. I am a fully qualified pharmacist and member of the South African Pharmacy Council. I have published extensively on issues of pharmacology as well as the role and regulation of medicines in public health. My Curriculum Vitae (CV) is attached hereto and I submit that I am fully qualified to make this expert submission on the promotion of generic medicines as a policy instrument. 3. My submissions below are based to a large extent on the chapter of the 2000 SA Health Review entitled “Drug pricing – a policy conundrum”, written by myself and T Matsebula, and published by the Health Systems Trust. Electronic copies of the full chapter may be obtained from <http://www.hst.org.za/sahr>. 4. In this affidavit I make reference to sources of some of my conclusions. These documents will be made available for this Honorable Court should they be requested. 5. In this affidavit the following issues will be addressed: 5.1. Justification for government intervention in the use and provision of medicines; 2- - 5.2. Use of generic medicines as a cost-saving measure; 5.3. Patient rights and generic policies. JUSTIFICATION FOR GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION 6. Any government wishing to pursue equity as a policy goal will commit itself to improving access to quality health care. Access may be constrained by many factors, both geographic and economic. If economic factors predominate, these are usually related to the costs of services. Out-ofpocket expenditure on drugs is high in many countries, and has been quoted at being as much as 65% of total drug expenditure in sub-Saharan Africa, 81% in Asia and less than 40% in established market economies. “Out-of-pocket” expenses refer to those made by patients themselves, rather than by the health system (e.g. the State, by providing free medicine) or paid by medical insurance (e.g. reimbursed by a medical scheme). (Velásquez G, Madrid Y, Quick JD. Health reform and drug financing. WHO/DAP/98.3. World Health Organization, Geneva, 1998). 7. Growth in drug expenditure has been shown to have exceeded that for other components of the health care system, particularly in Europe. (Rosian I, Habl C, Vogler S. Pharmaceuticals: Market control in nine European countries. Austrian Health Institute, Vienna, 1998; European Federation of Pharmaceutical Industries and Associations. The pharmaceutical industry in figures. EFPIA, Brussels, 2000 (available at www.efpia.org/6_publ/document/In figures 2000.new.pdf) 3- - 8. Drug prices may be considered a crucial element in determining access. Drug costs also impact directly on many policy choices, not least choices on whether or not to offer AIDS-related drug care in the public sector. The Panos Institute, an international global development think-tank, has stated that “the main reason why anti-retrovirals are not widely available in the developing world is the price of the drugs themselves”. (Panos Institute, Beyond Our Means? The Cost of Treating HIV/AIDS in the Developing World. Panos Institute, London, 2000.) 9. The costs of drugs is a prime consideration in whether or not they are included in Essential Drugs Lists, both internationally and in South Africa. (World Health Organization 11th Model Essential Drugs List (available at www.who.int/medicines); Gray A. An “essential” response to the issue of access to drugs? AIDS Bulletin 2000; 9(1): 4-6; Pérez-Casas C, Berman D, Kasper T. HIV/AIDS medicine pricing report. Setting objectives: is there a political will? Médecins Sans Frontières, Geneva, 2000 (available at www.msf.org/) 10. It should be stated clearly though that expenditure is a result of both unit price and volume of consumption. Countries with recognised low prices may not be able to keep prescribing levels under control. (e.g. Italy, France). (Tarabusi CC, Vickery G. Globalization in the pharmaceutical industry: Part I. Int J Health Serv 1998; 28(1): 67-105.; Tarabusi CC, Vickery G. Globalization in the pharmaceutical industry: Part II. Int J Health 4- - Serv 1998; 28(2): 281-303. Bloor K, Maynard A, Freemantle N. Lessons from international experience in controlling pharmaceutical expenditure III: regulating industry. Br Med J 1996; 313: 33-35.) 11. The United Kingdom, with the highest prices in Europe, manages to keep drug expenditure to about 10% of total health care costs. Australia is recognised as the exception, which has managed to both curtail prices and improve on the rationality of drug use. 12. However, in addition to the fact that drug prices are one of the key issues determining access, government intervention is also warranted on the basis that medicines are not ordinary articles of trade. Specifically, their demand and supply characteristics do not follow classic market principles. 12.1. Firstly, there is a three-tiered demand structure – with the prescribers (medical practitioners and others) as the actual demanders, the patients as the consumers and the health care system frequently the payer. There is often limited competition between suppliers, especially in the case of patented products, which are more characteristic of oligopolistic markets ie., market power is in the hands of a small group. 12.2. Drugs also have both positive and negative externalities (for example, through the prevention or non-prevention of infectious diseases). Information available to prescribers and consumers is often 5- - selective, unbalanced or incomplete, further demonstrating the supplydriven nature of trade in medicines. 12.3. Finally, market forces rarely reflect true social costs and benefits, and cannot meet social objectives such as equity. 13. The factors mentioned above, together with the apparent inability of the industry to develop and provide needed drugs for tropical diseases in poor countries have been called “market failure”. Attached as annexure “AG1” is an article from the International Journal of Infectious Diseases addressing this issue. Drugs can therefore be considered to be “meritorious” goods, worthy of government intervention. 14. One of the key areas addressed by the new government in 1994 was therefore to convene a Drug Policy Committee to advise on the component parts of a new policy. Local policy is encapsulated in the 1996 National Drug Policy. (Department of Health. National Drug Policy for South Africa. Pretoria, 1996. (available at www.sadap.org.za) 15. The drug policy sought to “ensure the availability and accessibility of essential drugs to all citizens”. While it sought, as a purely economic objective, to “lower the cost of drugs in both the private and public sectors”, it also aimed to “promote the rational use of drugs”, thus targeting both parts of the expenditure equation. As a national development 6- - objective, it aimed to “support the development of the local pharmaceutical industry and the local production of essential drugs”. 16. Specific cost containment measures that were signaled in 1996 were: 16.1. a pricing committee, to “monitor and regulate drug prices”; 16.2. total transparency in the pricing structure (at all points of the distribution chain); 16.3. a non-discriminatory pricing system; 16.4. replacing the wholesale and retail mark-up system with one based on a fixed professional fee; 16.5. a database to monitor costs compared with other developing and developed countries; 16.6. the regulation of price increases; 16.7. provision, in certain circumstances, of public sector stock to the private sector (e.g. supplying lower cost drugs bought by the State to private sector clinics in order to address a priority disease); 7- - 16.8. promotion of generics (multi-source pharmaceutical products, generally cheaper than the originator’s branded products), including generic substitution, while maintaining a negative list (a list of drugs that could not be substituted by the pharmacist at the patient’s request, but where the original brand would have to be supplied); 16.9. measures to improve rational drug use, including establishing Pharmacy and Therapeutics Committees (PTCs) in all hospitals; 16.10. 17. control of pharmaceutical marketing practices. In essence therefore: 17.1. a policy to promote the use of generic medicines has a basis in government’s obligation to intervene in an area of public life where pure market forces are not sufficient to ensure maximal public welfare; 17.2. where such policies are being pursued by the SA Government, they form part of a comprehensive approach to all aspects of drug use, targeting both price and rationality of drug use and are therefore not arbitrary or unjustified. USE OF GENERIC MEDICINES AS A COST-SAVING MEASURE 18. The options open to governments that do choose to intervene can be characterised in a number of ways. They can be either direct (primarily 8- - legal measures that have an immediate effect on suppliers or consumers) or indirect (usually market-related measures, which entail financial implications for the various actors). 19. They may either target prices themselves (supply-side measures such as price controls, positive or negative lists, promotion of generics) or consumption (demand-side measures such as exclusion from positive lists, reclassification to “Over the Counter” (OTC) status, introduction of patient co-payments, caps on pharmaceutical budgets). A positive list includes those items that will be supplied or reimbursed, a negative list in contrast indicates those items that will not be available to the patient. 20. Policy options have been described as resulting in either a total control situation (as in Ecuador and Honduras), a mixed system (as in Canada), a situation of monitored freedom (as in Brazil) or total freedom (as in the US). (Sarmiento AZ. Alternative pricing policies in the Americas. WHO/DAP/95.6. World Health Organization, Geneva, 1995). 21. Significantly, resorts to price control are more common in developed than in developing countries, even though price sensitivity might be greater in countries with poorer social security systems. 22. The promotion of generics has long been supported by the World Health Organisation (WHO), and is mentioned in every policy analysis or model policy document produced by that body. While always contested by those 9- - with vested interests, it cannot be said to be peculiar to South Africa’s approach. 23. Attached as annexure “AG2” is a pricing comparison of a range of offpatent medicines, based on information drawn from the Ethical Pricing List. For a range of medicines, some of which are used in the treatment of HIV-related opportunistic differences between infections, off-patent it indicates significant price name medicines and brand interchangeable multi-source generic alternatives. 24. Thus the policy of generic substitution cannot be said to be an arbitrary choice of this government. 25. In essence, generic promotion policies seek to: 25.1. improve the rationality of drug prescribing, by limiting the use of confusing trade names in both education and practice (preferring instead to use internationally recognised non-proprietary or generic names); 25.2. limit the impact of marketing activities by manufacturers, without necessarily totally denying them the use of the trademark concerned; 25.3. increase the potential for competition between manufacturers of products considered equivalent. 10- - 26. The policy option may take a number of forms, depending on the degree to which the legislating authority wishes to intervene. These can be considered to be a continuum, with varying degrees of acceptability to each party: 27. in the most restrictive form, which still pertains in South Africa under current law, substitution of a product by a pharmacist is proscribed unless the prescriber has chosen to use a generic or non-proprietary name in prescribing that item (e.g. writing a prescription for paracetamol, without stating the trade name). In essence therefore, all power resides in the hands of the prescriber. Any change requires that a new prescription be issued, even if verbally by the prescriber (e.g. on request of the pharmacist or patient). Having such a system is really a “non-policy”. That it should change has long been recognised, not only by the current government. 27.1. In 1986, the Browne Commission report on Health Services went even further, suggesting that substitution of “therapeutically equivalent medicines” on a positive list to be identified by the MCC, be introduced. (Final Report of the Commission of Inquiry into Health Services (Browne Commission). March 1986) 27.2. To an extent this area of practice is also governed by the so- called “Ethical Rules” to which pharmacists are subject. An attempt to 11- - change the rule in question was also made in 1989, but failed in the face of opposition. 28. An intermediate form would be to allow substitution within limits set by the legislation, but to continue to allow prescriptions to be legally written using trade names and products to be labelled as such. It is a form of this option that is included in Act 90 of 1997, and which was clearly signalled by the 1996 National Drug Policy. Again, two broad variations are possible. 29. A less interventionist option would entail optional substitution by the pharmacist. A more interventionist approach would be to mandate substitution were this approved by the regulatory authority for that product. The SA option is a mid-point, where mandatory offer of substitution is well guarded by rights accorded the prescriber (to mark the item “do not substitute”), the regulatory authority (to publish a “non-substitutable list”) and the patient (to refuse the offer), with the additional caveat that any substitution must result in a cost saving. 30. To do less is again almost tantamount to a non-policy, as it can hardly be construed as “promoting” the use of generics. In addition, as trade names continue to be recognised and are valid for prescribing, they retain some force in the market. 31. The most interventionist options have been used in a number of countries, albeit with vehement opposition from manufacturers of branded products. 12- - This can take one or both of two forms. On the one hand, restrictions may be placed on the legality of trade names in prescribing (mandatory generic prescribing). On the other, the use of trade names in labelling products and promoting their sale is proscribed. It is these options that can be seen as severely limiting the trademark rights of manufacturers. However, they are not being used in the Act in question. 32. In essence therefore: 32.1. Generic policies are widely promoted by the World Health Organisation, and have been adopted in many countries, including in the United States of America. Attached as annexure “AG 3” is a report of the United States Congressional Budget Office, that indicates that in one year alone, 1994, substituting generic for brand-name drugs saved consumers “roughly $8 billion to $10 billion (at retail prices).” 32.2. As included in the Medicines and Related Substances Control Amendment Act of 1997 (as was intended in legislation passed by the previous government but never implemented), they are neither arbitrary nor excessive but represent a mid-point in the policy continuum, one which gives adequate recognition to manufacturer’s commercial rights while nonetheless being sufficient for government to fulfill its obligation to intervene in an area of legitimate concern. 13- - 32.3. Generic competition per se is one of the few areas in which classic market forces can be brought to bear on drug prices. PATIENT RIGHTS AND GENERIC POLICIES 33. One of the defining characteristics of modern medical practice has been a gradual movement away from paternalistic practices (“your doctor knows best”) to practices that more fully acknowledged and protected the right of patient autonomy. This movement has informed not only medical practice, but also that of other related professions, notably pharmacists. As encapsulated in the practice philosophy of “Pharmaceutical Care”, it has been codified in the amended Pharmacy Act. 34. It is therefore worthwhile considering to what extent current legal restrictions on generic substitution reflect out-moded paternalistic practices, and conversely, to what extent the proposed measures indicate an intention to advance patient rights. 35. The current practice places all rights in the hands of the prescriber. This has in the past been justified by the need for technical knowledge, the ability to choose an appropriate drug but also an acceptable manufacturer, in order to maximise the chance of reaching the desired therapeutic outcome. It is clear that the patient is given very little say in the matter, based on a paternalistic assumption of the patient’s ability to contribute to the decision in a meaningful way. 14- - 36. However, this also presupposes that no other party to the therapeutic process has the ability to add value. In particular, it ignores the potential role of the pharmacist, who by virtue of her/his training is better positioned than the prescriber to assess the technical quality of alternative sources of the desired active drug. 37. The measure, as included in the Act, instead involves all three parties in the decision. Crucially, for the first time it acknowledges the right of the patient to have a say in the matter. 38. The right to participate in decisions about one’s own health and health care is a human right. This right has been increasingly recognised in South African law, not least in the Choice on Termination of Pregnancy Act. 39. However, the right is also not without balance – the section recognises the right of the prescriber to refuse substitution (which would, preferably, have been discussed with the patient), and adds the weight of the Medicines Control Council in assessing the technical merits of substitution. It also, in accordance with modern practice and in line with the NDP, recognises the ability of the pharmacist to provide appropriate technical advice to the patient. 15- - 40. In essence, therefore the mandatory offer of generic substitution ensures the maximal involvement of all parties in making a drug choice, and implicitly recognises patients’ rights to choice. CONCLUSION 41. Generic policies have long been regarded as appropriate interventions for governments to contemplate, despite often vehement opposition from vested interests. The options available to governments run the gamut from total rejection of commercial rights to graduated intervention. 42. Those instruments chosen by the South African government are reasonable, indicate a balanced appreciation of the rights of all parties and are not excessive when viewed in the context of the full continuum of options that have been used. In addition, they significantly advance individual patient rights. In this regard they also contribute to the National Drug Policy’s objective of greater patient involvement in rational drug use. ________________________ DEPONENT SIGNED AND SWORN TO BEFORE _____________________________________________ 16- - ME AT ON THIS THE 9TH DAY OF APRIL 2001, THE DEPONENT HAVING ACKNOWLEDGED THAT HE KNOWS AND UNDERSTANDS THE CONTENTS OF THIS AFFIDAVIT, THAT HE HAS NO OBJECTION TO TAKING THE PRESCRIBED OATH AND THAT HE CONSIDERS THE SAME AS BINDING ON HIS CONSCIENCE. ________________________ COMMISSIONER OF OATHS 17- - Annexure “AG 2” PRICE COMPARISON OF OFF-PATENT MEDICINES The table below compares the prices of competing off-patent medicines. The table shows that for many important medicines, the formerly patented drug is significantly more expensive than its generic competitors. All prices have been obtained from the electronic format of the Ethical Pricing List (Blue Book) as of 28 March 2001 published by Pharmaceutical Printers and Publishers. Not all generic competitors are compared with the formerly patented medicine. The cheapest generic medicine under each category is not necessarily the cheapest generic available. This version of the Blue Book used to obtain this data can be made available to the Court.. Explanation of Columns: 1. Name of Medicine: The scientific name for a medicine is written in bold, followed by the brand-names. The formerly patented medicine (or medicines) is italicised and is the first brand-name listed under each scientific name. The name of the manufacturer appears in parenthesis along side the brand-name, unless the brand-name is prefixed with the manufacturer’s name. 2. Dosage: This refers to the dosage of the active ingredient in one unit, usually a capsule or tablet, but other measurements are used for ointments, creams, syrups, suspensions, aerosols and inhalants. 18- - 3. Package Size: This is usually the number of capsules or tablets sold per package, but also the weight of medicines sold as ointments or creams. For Beclometasone, refill packets of the same size are compared. Similar package sizes are compared so that bulk discounted packages are not unfairly compared against small packages. 4. Trade Price: This is the price at which the medicine is sold by pharmaceutical companies to dispensers. This does not take into account discounts or other incentives, perverse or otherwise. 5. Retail Price: This is the maximum price at which a dispenser should sell the medicine to a customer. It includes VAT. The Blue Book calculates this as the Trade Price multiplied by 1.5 (dispensing mark-up) multiplied by 1.14 (VAT). 6. Price Per Unit: This is usually the Trade Price divided by the Package Size. It represents the cost of one capsule or tablet. In the case of ointments, creams, syrups, suspensions, aerosols and inhalants this has been set equal to the trade price, because only equivalent size packages are considered. 19- - Name of Medicine Dosage Zovirax (GSK) Lovire (Ranbaxy) Cyclivex (Aspen) 400mg 400mg 400mg Package Size Trade Price Retail Price Price Per Unit Acyclovir 56 56 70 827.29 306.84 304.12 1414.67 524.7 520.05 14.77 5.48 4.34 92.31 49.7 157.86 84.99 92.31 49.7 525.96 75.60 899.39 129.28 5.26 0.76 Beclometasone Becotide (Sekmed – prev. GSK) Clenil (Rolab) 50mcg 50mcg Refill Refill Cotrimoxazole (Double Strength package size between 100 and 250) Bactrim (Roche) 960mg 100 Rolab Co-trimoxazole 960mg 100 Cotrimoxazole (Double Strength package size = 10) Bactrim (Roche) 960mg Septran (GSK) 960mg Purbac (Aspen) 960mg 10 10 10 55.3 33.01 8.5 94.56 56.45 14.54 5.53 3.30 0.85 Cotrimoxazole (Single Strength package size = 20) Bactrim (Roche) 480mg Septran (GSK) 480mg Rolab Co-trimoxazole 480mg Purbac (Aspen) 480mg 20 20 20 20 55.64 34.94 9.61 8.89 95.14 59.75 16.43 15.2 2.78 1.75 0.48 0.44 50ml 50ml 50ml Syrup Suspension Suspension 29.05 18.02 6.31 49.68 30.81 10.79 29.05 18.02 6.31 20mg 20mg 20mg 20mg 20mg 30 30 30 28 30 261.36 189.54 128.87 98.8 99.43 446.93 324.11 220.37 168.95 170.03 8.71 6.32 4.3 3.53 3.31 Cotrimoxazole (Suspension/Syrup) Bactrim (Roche) Septran (GSK) Purbac (Aspen) Fluoxetine Prozac (Lilly) (tab) Prozac (Lilly) (cap) Apo-Fluoxetine (cap) (Aspen) Lilly-Fluoxetine (cap) Rolab-Fluoxetine (cap) Loperamide 2mg 6 14.02 23.97 2.34 Betaperamide (Restan) 2mg 10 18.9 32.32 1.89 Maxolon (Pharmaco) Metalon (Caps Pharm) (cap) 10mg 10mg 100 100 69.99 23.05 119.68 39.42 0.70 0.23 Nystatin (cream) Mycostatin (BMS) Nystacid (Aspen) 100.000u/g 100.000u/g 15g 15g 32.29 19.82 55.22 33.89 32.29 19.82 Imodium (Janssen-Con) Metoclopramide 20- - Paracetamol Panado (Restan) Painamol (Be-tabs) 500mg 500mg 100 100 21- - 30.26 9.28 51.74 15.87 0.30 0.09