International Transfer Pricing and Income Shifting: Implications for the Multinational Manufacturing Enterprise and Research Robert Hutchinson University of Toledo Toledo, OH 43606, USA 419.530.4004 roberthutchinson@alumni.duq.edu ABSTRACT Implications of globalization on accounting and tax functions have largely remained an afterthought of corporate strategy until recently. This is changing; however, as more multinational manufacturing firms recognize the potential to arbitrage the various market imperfections arising from exchange process differentials across borders. Commonly known as transfer pricing, and viewed as a legitimate business opportunity by transnational corporations, internal pricing between subsidiaries is often manipulated in order to misrepresent financial performance and evade taxation. This paper provides a review of existing research on international intra-firm pricing and discusses its implications for research at the interface of other research areas. Keywords: international manufacturing, transfer pricing, income shifting, intra-firm trade, arm’s length standard INTRODUCTION Transfer pricing is an accounting convention that concerns the terms that connected parties use when they conduct business with each other, trading both goods and services. The issue of internal transfer pricing is of particular importance for multinational manufacturing enterprises that conduct business across international boundaries, selling raw materials, intermediary products, and finished goods between business units and affiliates. The transfer pricing policy of such firms will often have a significant effect on the amount of profit or loss that is recognized in each of the countries in which they do business. As globalization continues to extend to encompass almost every country and every industry, so too has the importance of intra-firm trade and international transfer pricing policy. The Economist (2004) estimates that a full 60% of the world’s trade takes place within multinational firms, i.e. through the transfer of goods and services among their subsidiaries, making intra-firm trade by far the single largest component of global business. Many firms today have global brands, research and development, and manufacturing, and, quite simply, the only reason for maintaining regional profit centers and accounts is that governmental tax authorities require it. Even so, it becomes exceedingly difficult to say quite where global firms’ profits are truly generated. High levels of cost transfers within corporations not only create significant opportunities for tax minimization and financial management, but also create potential problems with the overall management of company resources. Balancing these considerations is of primary importance to management, and presents a unique opportunity for academic researchers in the areas of strategy, organizational behavior, supply chain management, and international business to better understand the impact of transfer pricing policy on firm performance. Beyond the tax and accounting implications of internal transfer pricing, this paper will also address the significant managerial implications that a particular system for internal transfer pricing can have on firm performance. Although they do not usually rank high in organizational hierarchies or in academic research models, the fact is that the firm’s accounting systems provide the ultimate scorecard used in all aspects of the business management and strategy. As summarized by Zimmerman (2003), managerial accounting system should exhibit the following characteristics: 1. Provide the information necessary to identify the most profitable products and the pricing and marketing strategies to achieve desired volume levels. 2. Provide information to detect production inefficiencies to ensure that the proposed products and volumes are produced at minimum cost. 246 3. 4. 5. When combined with the performance evaluation and reward systems, create incentives for managers to maximize firm value. Support the financial accounting and tax accounting reporting functions. Contribute more to firm value than it costs. The objectives of management accounting are to assist managers and to influence their behavior in a way that results in goal congruent actions. (Anthony, 1989) Figure 1 presents a framework for organizational change and management accounting’s roll in driving the action that leads to firm value. Changes in business environment should lead to new strategies and ultimately to changes in the firm’s organizational architecture, including changes in the accounting system, in order to better align the interests of the employees and create incentive structures congruent to the objectives of the organization. (Zimmerman, 2003) Figure 1: Framework for Organizational Change and Management Accounting (Anthony 1989) Business Environment Business Strategy Organizational Architecture > Decision - Right Assignment > Performance Evaluation > Reward System Incentives and Action Firm Value Information provided by the managerial accounting system should assist the firm’s management in setting profit goals, establishing departmental targets in the form of budget plans, evaluating the effectiveness resource usage against those plans, investigating successes and failures in terms of specific manufacturing processes and support tasks, and taking action on adjustments and improvements necessary to keep the entire manufacturing enterprise moving towards the established corporate objectives. When a firm manipulates its accounting income via international transfer pricing, it also reduces the usefulness of accounting information for strategic decision making. Although many senior executives feel that transfer pricing issues are simply problems for the tax accounts, this is a great misconception. The methodology used for transfer pricing does not simply shift income among the various subsidiaries, strategic business units, groups, and countries, with little effect other than on performance evaluations; rather it has a great effect on the primary operations and the overall profits of the firm. Although much of the attention focuses on how multinational firms employ transfer pricing to avoid paying income taxes, it is increasingly apparent that attempting to minimize the tax burden is only one of the objectives of an international transfer pricing strategy. (Cravens, 1997) Transfer pricing is increasingly becoming strategic rather than simply procedural. (Cravens, 1997; Spicer, 1988; Eccles, 1985) INTRA-FIRM TRADE AND TRANSFER PRICING SCOPE The significance of intra-firm transfer pricing continues to increase with the continued intensification of globalization. According to the UNCTAD in the early 1990s there were approximately 37,000 international companies with 175,000 foreign subsidiaries. By 2003 this number had risen to 64,000 international companies with 870,000 foreign subsidiaries. The international significance of transfer pricing can be gauged from the sheer amount of global intra-firm trade estimated the Economist (2004) at roughly 60% of all international trade, and one third of total world trade, valued in the ballpark of $1.6 trillion, according to estimates by the International Monetary Fund, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, the United Nations Conference on Trade And Development, and the World Trade Organization. 247 These current estimates support past empirical research on cross-border intra-firm trade. In 1986, approximately 36% of the United States’ imports and exports were transactions between US firms and their foreign subsidiaries. (Cho, 1990) This is consistent with more recent estimates that 40% of all US international trade is intra-firm trade. (Clausing, 2003) Approximately 55% of trade between the European Union and Japan, 40% of the trade between the EU and the US, and 80% of the trade between Japan and the US is between parent companies and foreign subsidiaries. (Stewart, 1993) EXPLOITING MULTINATIONALITY Through its multinationality, the manufacturing enterprise may maximize its objectives by exploiting the market imperfections that arise from exchange process differentials. (Cravens, 1997; Leitch & Barret, 1992) There is a long-held belief that international transfer pricing is used by multinational firms to minimize global tax liability, which would be a rational economic response to market imperfections created by national governments. Global market imperfections are created by host government policies to attract and retain multinational company investments. (Emmanuel, 1999; Leitch & Barrett, 1992) Multinational firms are therefore provided with strong incentives to adjust their international transfer pricing policies to secure the benefits offered by host governments and would not be acting rationally, in economic terms, and would fail to create wealth for their shareholders if their transfer pricing policies did not recognize the opportunities created by market imperfections. (Emmanuel, 1999; Borkowski, 1996) Following a similar methodology employed by Clausing (2003), Kant (1995), and Horst (1971), a simple mathematical model can be developed that supports the prediction that intra-firm trade prices will be affected by tax minimization strategies of the multinational firm. Consider the case of a multinational manufacturing firm, with a large degree of market power, which is operating in two countries. It produces and sells in each country, and also exports part of its production from the home country (H) to the fully-owned foreign affiliate abroad (F). Profit functions are thus: πH = RH (sH) – CH (sH + m) + pm (1) πF = RF (sF) – CF (sF + m) + pm (2) Where πH is the profit in the home country, which depends on revenues (RH) that are a function of sales (sH), and costs (CH ) that are a function of production. Production includes both those goods sold at home and those exported to the foreign affiliate m at a transfer price p. Considering the case where the tax rates at home are greater than the tax rates abroad (tH > tF) and deferral is allowed, let f represent the fraction of profits that are repatriated. The effective tax rate on income earned in the affiliate country is then; teF = tF + (tH – tF) f (3) Thus the net profit function for the firm’s global operations is; π = (1-tH) πH + (1- teF) πF (4) To illustrate how the firm would likely choose a transfer price in order to maximize these net profits, take the derivative of equation (4) with respect to the transfer price p. πp = (1-tH) m - (1- teF) m (5) A simple substitution of teF using equation (3) and rearranging the terms: πp = - (tH –tF) (1- f) m (6) 248 Therefore if tH > tF, the above expression is negative, and the firm’s global net profits decrease with the transfer price. Thus, firms have an incentive to under price goods sold to low tax countries in order to shift profits to low tax locations or, conversely, to overprice goods sold to high tax affiliates when tF > tH. In order to better illustrate the tax implications of transfer pricing methodologies on a firm, it may be helpful to look at a simple fictional case study of a multinational manufacturing firm, Robert Hutchinson International (RHI), maker of widgets. In this scenario model, RHI manufactures widgets at its plant in the Netherlands, and ships them to its Australian subsidiary, which sells the widgets for 85 Australian Dollars. The variable cost of manufacturing the widgets is 50 Euros, while the exchange rate we assume to be fixed at 0.70 Australian Dollars to 1 Euro. Let us further assume that the Dutch corporate tax rate is 30% compared with an effective tax rate is 40% in Australia. Now suppose that the transfer price of widgets is variable, and that RHI is allowed to set the transfer price anywhere between 80 and 110 Euros. The following table demonstrates that international transfer pricing methodologies do not only determine profit allocations between business units, but also may greatly affect the overall profits to be divided. Figure 2 shows the net tax affects to RHI based on two possible transfer pricing methods: Figure 2: Scenario Model of Transfer Pricing Between Netherlands and Australia for RHI 80 Euros Transfer Price Taxes Paid in the Netherlands: Revenue (transfer price) Variable Cost Taxable Income Tax Rate Dutch Taxes 110 Euros 80.00 (50.00) 30.00 0.30 9.00 Taxes Paid in Australia: Revenue Transfer price in Euros X Exchange rate 0.70 A$/Euro Transfer price as A$ Taxable Income Tax Rate Australian Taxes Converted to Euro (÷0.70) 110.00 (50.00) 60.00 0.30 18.00 85.00 80.00 0.70 Sum of Dutch and Australian Taxes (Euros) 85.00 110.00 0.70 (56.00) 29.00 0.40 11.60 16.57 (77.00) 8.00 0.40 3.20 4.57 25.57 22.57 Both the mathematical model and the RHI case study are rather simplistic; however, they serve the purpose of demonstrating the possibility for the firm to exploit its multinationality to mitigate its overall global tax burden. Of course, in the arcane world of international taxation, nothing is quite as simple as these two previous examples. For instance, under the Subpart F provisions of the US tax code, US firms are not eligible to defer taxation on foreign income not repatriated that is derived from passive investments or foreign base company income, including foreign income derived from sales of goods between related parties where the goods are manufactured and sold for use outside the base country. And, woe to the company that faces a tax audit for pushing the envelope too far. Kant (1990) reminds us that managers must balance potential penalties, if manipulation of transfer prices becomes too flagrant, and consider minority interests, as foreign affiliates may not be wholly owned. Governments are cracking down on income manipulation according to the Economist (2004), recognizing the impact of such practice on government revenues. A report by the United States Senate in 2001 claimed that multinationals evaded up to $45 billion in taxes in 2000. Although it is hard to substantiate this number, some of the more flagrant offenses do further fan the flames, as one firm sold toothbrushes between subsidiaries valued at $5,655 each. Complexity of international organizations and of tax codes is a double edged sword for both governmental taxing authorities and the multinational manufacturing firm alike. For just as difficult for the multinational manufacturing 249 firm to determine where profits are actually made is it for governmental taxing authorities to prove otherwise. Mehafdi (2000) demonstrates that international tax litigation cases involving multinational manufacturing firms become exponentially complex as a function of the number of divisions and subsidiaries across the number of countries. Even a relatively simple example (figure 3) of a multinational firm with only three subsidiaries becomes complex in terms of sourcing and pricing decisions. Figure 3: Transfer Pricing Linkages in a Hypothetical 3-Division Decentralized Multinational Manufacturing Enterprise (Adapted from Mehafdi 2000) Key: Flow of intra-firm trade of intermediate products ( 2 to 3 and 4; 3 to 4) 1. Multinational Manufacturing Firm (Headquarters in Home Country) Trading in intermediate product markets (selling to/buying from is permitted, restricted, or prohibited: 2 & 3 to 5; 3 & 4 from 5) Trading in the final product market (4 to 6) Internal Pricing Decision Interest charges, royalties, management fees ( 1 to 2, 3 & 4) 2. Division X (Transferor) International intra-firm trade @ $ transfer price 3. Division Y (Transferee & Transferor) Domestic intra-firm trade @ $ transfer price 4. Division Z (Transferee) International intra-firm trade @ $ transfer price Sourcing Decsion 5. Intermediate Product Markets 6. Final Product Market Despite organizational complexities and tax regulations ad infinitum, empirical research supports the mathematical proofs that firms do in fact shift income to avoid taxation. Hines and Rice (1994) find that a 1% difference in tax rates between countries are associated with a 2.3% difference in reported pretax profitability. This finding is consistent with the Clausing (2003) that found a tax rate 1% lower in the country of destination/origin is associated with intra-firm export prices that are 1.8% lower and intra-firm import prices that are 2.0% higher relative to nonintra-firm goods. This evidence is particularly noteworthy in the context of large empirical literature on taxmotivated transfer pricing that has relied almost entirely on indirect evidence. (Clausing, 2003) Tax incentives are certainly not the only motivation for multinational manufacturing firms, and the trend towards diversifying the manufacturing base of the will continue to grow exponentially as managers try to take advantage of the combination of factors relating to ownership, location, and internationalization. According to Leitch and Barrett (1992) these ownership advantages include (1) capital assets that give an organization a competitive edge, (2) economies of scale, (3) access to markets, (4) products to distribute, and (5) diversity of products. With the advantages relating to location including (1) material sourcing, (2) good labor market, (3) cooperative governmental policies -including tax policies, (4) governmental service and infrastructure, and (5) access to local markets. And the advantages relating to internationalization including (1) stable supplies, (2) control of markets, (3) exploitation of technology, (4) vertical integration economies, and (5) larger markets. As transfer pricing continues to play an ever larger role in the overall operations of the multinational manufacturing firm, it becomes increasingly important to better understand the scope of its impact on corporate strategy not just on tax compliance. Increasingly firms become aware of the potential of transfer pricing policy to impact the overall strategic direction of the firm. In a domestic environment, issues related to management evaluation and performance is generally the major concern with transfer pricing. However the multinational firm is faced with numerous complicating factors within the global marketplace such as taxation, competitive advantage, foreign exchange, cash controls, and inflation. (Cravens, 1997) 250 TRANSFER PRICING METHODOLOGIES The discussion thus far may seem very interesting to the accountant or tax manager, but to the average high-level executive, the tax profits are not really useful to the overall corporate strategy and direction of the company. What is most useful to the executive manager is information for decision making. Because firms are organized into responsibility centers, whether it be by group, strategic business unit, or individual projects, each is center is measured on its individual performance. Ensuring a fair and useful measurement means that meaningful transfer prices must be established, which reflects the economic reality of the firm and give the executive a basis for rationalizing resources within the firm. When we consider that executive managers must make investment, purchasing, and production decisions based on this performance, it becomes clear how meaningful transfer pricing is to the overall economic profits of the firm. Establishing transfer prices that simply attempts to minimize overall global tax liability may in fact cause managers to make inappropriate decisions, thus reducing the value to the overall firm. There is also evidence that managers’ perceptions on the interests of local partners and maintenance of good relations with the host government play a role in the selection of an international transfer pricing methodology. (Chan & Lo, 2004) The three most commonly discussed methodologies for transfer pricing are discussed in the following: Separate and Unequal One potential solution to the problem of balancing tax issues with managerial issues that has often been suggested, and practiced by many firms, is to maintain two separate transfer pricing systems, one to be used for tax purposes and another to be used simply for managerial decision making. While this appears to be an ideal solution of giving the top executives a clear view of ‘real’ profitability, while minimizing tax profitability, Michael Patton, a Senior Partner at Ernst & Young disagrees: An essential problem with separated reporting is that transfer prices already reflect the profitability of a division or project. If you are trying to make decisions about new activities or facilities, and trying to judge the return on invested capital, you need good benchmarks to judge these by, and good transfer prices provide that. Basically, then, the question is whether your current transfer prices reflect economic reality or not. If they do, there’s little need for a new system. If not, the tax authorities may have a question or two for you on audit in a few years’ time. (Springsteed, 1999) So the response to this all too often used solution is to maintain two sets of records at your own risk of audit, not to mention the significant cost of duplication caused by maintaining two separate sets of books for this purpose. Other important considerations from the managerial perspective when establishing transfer pricing may include balancing the marketing and financial management strategies of the corporation. Besides taxation and investment decision making, internal pricing may have a great effect on the competitive position of the company in a particular market. One strategy, for which the United States had often accused the Japanese automakers, is to subsidized product dumping in foreign markets with the high prices charged in protected domestic markets. The World Trade Organization is one of the global organizations charged with reducing this practice worldwide. High transfer prices might be used to circumvent or significantly lessen the impact of national controls. Many governments have restrictions on the amount of profits which a firm can remove at any one point, thereby creating difficulties for profitable subsidiaries to transfer funds back to the corporate office. However, overpricing the goods shipped to a subsidiary in such a country would make it possible to for the funds to be taken out. This method will then circumvent any government regulations, penalties, or restrictions. (Gray et al., 2001) On the other hand, the more important management perceives foreign exchange controls in transfer pricing, the more likely the firm will chose a cost-based method. (Chan & Lo, 2004) Opportunity Cost The importance given to the issue of transfer pricing is evident. From the managerial perspective, one rule exists for transfer pricing. The transfer pricing rule is quite simple to state: the optimal transfer price for a product or service is its opportunity cost – it is the value forgone by not using the transferred product in its next best alternative use. 251 (Zimmerman, 2003) Unfortunately, the simple solution is not as simple as it may first appear. If perfect information were available to the executive, transfer prices would simply be set to opportunity cost. The manufacturing plant of RHI, from the example above, would produce widgets to the point where the variable cost of production is equal to the transfer price, and the Australian subsidiary would continue to purchase as long as its revenues cover the transfer cost. In this ideal situation, both divisions will be maximizing their economic profits. Economists will argue that this is the optimal solution for setting transfer prices; however, as we all know, economic reality is that perfect information is extremely difficult, if not impossible, to obtain. The high cost of obtaining such symmetrical information from executives who have incentives to see their own responsibility center maximize its profits can most often greatly outweigh the benefits. As a practical matter, marginal cost information is rarely known to anybody in the firm, because it depends on the opportunity costs that vary with capacity use. And, even if marginal cost information were available, there is no guarantee that it would be revealed in a truthful fashion for the purpose of determining an optimal transfer price. (Holstrom & Tirole, 1991) Therefore, the firm must often rely on the least difficult method for setting transfer costs, and the most common are based on market price, variable costs, full costs, or other variations. Market Pricing – Arm’s Length Standard The examples in the previous clearly shows what governments wish to circumvent in their efforts through the OECD to establish international guidelines for transfer pricing. Transfer pricing methods can deprive governments of their fair share of taxes from global corporations and expose multinationals to possible double taxation. No country – poor, emerging or wealthy – wants its tax base to suffer because of transfer pricing. The arm’s length principle can help. (Neighbour, 2002) In an effort to minimize the potential problems caused by the various methodologies for internal transfer pricing, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) released a new set of guidelines in 1999 revising its original guidelines publish in 1995. These guidelines are based on the ‘arm’s length’ principle (ALP) – that a transfer price should be developed as if the two associated enterprises involved were completely independent of one another. The details of this principle can be found in Article 9 of the OECD Model Tax Convention, and is used as a framework for bilateral treaties between OECD and non-OECD governments alike. The following is the definition of ‘Associated Enterprises’ according to Article 9: Where: a) an enterprise of a Contracting State participates directly or indirectly in the management, control or capital of an enterprise of the other Contracting State, or b) the same persons participate directly or indirectly in the management, control or capital of an enterprise of a Contracting State and an enterprise of the other Contracting State, Though the arm’s length principle is an agreeable one, and inherently just to both governmental tax authorities and to multinational enterprises, the actual application and adherence to this policy becomes increasingly fastidious. This is particularly true today when multinational firms become more service oriented and products become more intangible in nature. Even for traditional manufacturing firms it often becomes difficult to separate out the goods from the services, which become bundled into hard-to-price intangible products. Market pricing is often the easiest internal pricing method to implement, and most authorities agree, that given a highly competitive market for the product outside the firm, this method comes closest to representing full opportunity cost. It often works best in commodity-type products, where markets set the price without much variation. However, if no external market for the intermediate products exists, or when large synergies exist between the various subsidiaries, market pricing becomes less accurate. Under such conditions variable cost transfers, or some form of this method, may be the most effective alternative. Empirical evidence suggests that the market method is most likely to be used where managers perceive a high level of importance at maintaining good relations with the host government. (Chan & Lo, 2004) However, variable cost transfers are often unpopular with manufacturing divisions, and there are many cases in which internal fighting among the marketing and manufacturing divisions have led to either full cost transferring methods, or variable costs plus some additional fixed distribution fee. 252 SELECTED LITERATURE Despite its evident impact for both researchers and practitioners, little empirical research has been done in this area. This is largely due to the sensitivity of the issue and potential for penalties. In 1992 the United States Treasury introduced extensive transfer pricing documentation requirements coupled with non-negotiable penalties and aggressive enforcement of regulations of section 482 of the Tax Code. Other countries, such as Australia, Canada, France, Korea, and Mexico have already developed or are in the process of developing their own formal transfer pricing requirements along with corresponding penalties. In the face of draconian regulation, it is understandable that many companies are hesitant to offer much data in the form of case studies. Thus, academic research to discover evidence of income shifting by international transfer pricing tends to be indirect, survey-based, and with a general focus rather than investigating specific cross border trades. (Emmanuel, 1999) Utilizing a scenario experimentation methodology, Lin and others (1993) investigated the ability of multinational firms operating in Asian-Pacific countries, given tax and other economic factors, to maximize cash flows through arbitrary transfer pricing schemes. The potential differences are so great that they conclude that multinational firms would, quite rationally, use international transfer pricing to arbitrage the government-induced market imperfections in order to improve cash flows. Emmanuel (1999), following a similar methodology to Lin and others, finds major variations in after-tax income of subsidiaries operating under different combinations of fiscal regimes and international transfer pricing policies. While differential rates between the three countries used in the study (USA, Greece, and Taiwan) have minor significance on the parent company’s total global after-tax income, the absence of any one particular form of tax, such as withholding tax, can provide substantial opportunities to maximize global after-tax income through the choice of transfer price methodology. Utilizing a unique data monthly set from 1997 through 1999, made available by the US Bureau of Labor Statistics, Clausing (2003) finds important differences in the behavior of intra-firm trade prices when compared with true arms-length trade, indicating the influence of tax-motivated income shifting on US intra-firm trade. The paper finds evidence that tax-motivated income shifting is consistent with theoretical expectation and robust to different approaches and specifications, i.e. using both statutory and effective tax rates as explanatory variables and controlling for other influences that may affect trade prices. One of the noted limitations; however, was the fact that this study was unable to detect other methods of tax-motivated income shifting, such as altering manufacturing overhead cost allocations or manipulating the terms of financial transactions within the firm. Using a sample of all non-financial and non-utility firms listed on the Tokyo Stock Exchange from 1977 through 1997, from the PACAP-Japan database TM, Gramlich and others (2004) found that the pre-tax return and marginal tax rate status of listed firms is significantly moderated by membership in a major Keiretsu. This was a very interesting study for international business in that it identified another benefit to the Keiretsu business model in Japan. The evidence suggests that all keiretsu members shift income to work towards a collective lower tax rate, despite any localized incentives not to undertake this shifting. In a survey of 82 of the 500 largest multinational firms from The World Directory of Multinationals, Cravens (1997) found in contrast to a purely tax-driven mechanism, international transfer pricing can be considered as a means to accomplish corporate objectives and thus create strategic consequences. In general executives perceive that transfer pricing does influence measures of corporate performance and contributes towards achieving corporate objectives. Kaplan and others (1992) give an example of a firm that found it necessary to modify its variable cost transfer pricing structure was Teva Pharmaceutical Industries, Ltd. based in Israel. Because of the stringency of employment law in Israel, where it is difficult to layoff workers, labor is considered to be a fixed cost, at least in the mediumterm. Senior management originally decided on variable cost transfers for its products to the various marketing divisions worldwide. This worked well for the marketing divisions, which were free to purchase pharmaceuticals from competitors as well, but this left the manufacturing division with little incentive to control labor or capital costs. While this proved to be an easier method than allowing the divisions to negotiate a free-market price, the cost of manufacturing began to spin out of control. Teva would later replace its variable cost transfer system with full cost system. However, Kaplan and others (1992) reiterate that full cost transfer systems are not without their own inherent problems. Even though it often solves the problem of wasteful disputes between divisions and ensures that 253 each division is at a minimum covering all its costs, as was the case in Teva, full cost transfer pricing can often cause distribution to purchase too few units. A case of the absurd is presented by Kovac and Troy (1989) as it had occurred at Bellcore, one of AT&T’s research labs. Bellcore attempted to establish a full cost charge for secretarial services, used by the research engineers and scientists. The transfer price established for typing included not only the direct secretarial labor and administrative costs, but also a share of overhead including utilities, rent, and taxes. This pool was then divided by the number of typing hours and charged to various projects. With an increase in charges, the highly-paid researchers began to do their own typing in an attempt to control costs over various projects. As the number of typing hours shrank, the full cost charge per page rose to a point where it cost as much as $50 per page to have a secretary type a memo. Bellcore solved the problem by subtracting some of the fixed costs. CONCLUSION & IMPLICATIONS FOR RESEARCH Internal transfer pricing will continue to be at the forefront of concerns for the multinational firm, governmental taxing authorities and regulatory agencies, and researchers as globalization continues into the next decade. The implications not only affect the firm and other stakeholders in the form of taxes, but also have great implications in terms of investments the firm will make in the future. While those in government and political circles are most concerned with the effects of transfer pricing decisions on their revenue base, and tax managers with overall global tax liabilities of the firm, the top executives at the multinational firms have many other issues to consider. First and foremost on the executive’s mind is the need for clear and objective information, which clearly reflects the economic realities of the business, and on which rational decisions can be made for capital appropriations. It is clear from the cases presented above, that the choice for transfer pricing methodology can have a great impact not only on the way the profits will be distributed, but also on the overall profits of the firm. In choosing a methodology, the executive manager must balance the costs and the benefits of the system, and attempt to choose the one which most appropriately reflects the true economic opportunity cost. For the academic researcher attempting to study the impact of international transfer pricing and income shifting in terms of strategy, organizational behavior, or supply chain management, the extremely sensitive nature of this controversial subject makes it almost impossible to conduct survey research with any meaning. A major defect in the survey approach, despite the guarantees of confidentiality afforded participants, is a suspicion that respondents would be unlikely to admit to an arbitrary international transfer pricing [policy] which circumvents tax laws or suggests unethical behavior. An attempt to apply meta-analysis to the findings of twenty-one surveys was at best marginally successful and failed to reveal any underlying associations or trends. (Borkowski, 1996) That is not to say that opportunities do not exist for academic research; quite to the contrary, they are as plentiful as the quasi-experimental methodologies needed to leverage them. At a macro level there exists a wealth of secondary data on pricing and international trade, which given even a general knowledge of accounting and tax regulations can be used effectively in an event study. At the firm level, researchers in this area can utilize scenario experimentation or simulation to determine the opportunities for the multinational manufacturing firm to maximize after-tax income. At a micro level, the organizational behavior academician can utilize mathematical modeling or game theoretic methods to determine a manager’s rational response to given economic conditions. A particularly interesting potential research project for international business would be to repeat the methodology employed by Gramlich and others (2004) in other countries such as Korea, with its Chaebol business model, and Finanz Kapital in Germany, where a similar system of common ownership exists with large industrial banks at the center. Any findings of higher levels of income shifting in these countries might indicate a cultural collectiveness, supporting Geert Hofstede’s cultural dimensions. The growth in opportunities for research in this area is great, as this field has largely remained within the realms of accounting and economics literature and has remained woefully underdeveloped. How international transfer pricing decisions interact with other areas such as strategy, organizational behavior, and supply chain management presents a fertile field in which the academician can sow the seeds of knowledge. 254 REFERENCES Anthony, R. (1989) ‘Reminiscences About Management Accounting’, Journal of Management Accounting Research, 1(1): 1-20 Borkowski, C. (1996) ‘An Analysis (Meta and Otherwise) of Multinational Transfer Pricing Research’, The International Journal of Accounting, 31(1): 39-53 Chan, K. H. & Lo, A. W. Y. (2004) ‘The Influence of Management Perception of Environmental Variables on the Choice of International Transfer Pricing Methods’, The International Journal of Accounting, 39(2): 93-110 Cho, K. R. (1990) ‘The Role of Product Specific Factors in Intra-Firm Trade of US Manufacturing Multinational Corporations’, Journal of International Business Studies, Q2: 319-330 Clausing, K. A. (2003) ‘Tax-Motivated Transfer Pricing and US Intrafirm Trade Prices’, Journal of Public Economics, 87: 2207-2223 Cravens, K. S. (1997) ‘Examining the Role of Transfer Pricing as a Strategy for Multinational Firms’, International Business Review, 6(2): 127-145 Economist (2004) ‘A taxing battle’, January 29: 71-72 Eccles, R. G. (1985) The Transfer Pricing Problem: A Theory for Practice, Lexington Books, Lexington, Mass. Emmanuel, C. R. (1999) ‘Income Shifting and International Transfer Pricing: A Three Country Example’, ABACUS, 35(3): 252-267 Gramlich, J. D., Limpaphayom, P., & Rhee, S. G. (2004) ‘Taxes, Keiretsu Affiliation, and Income Shifting’, Journal of Accounting & Economics, 37: 203-228 Gray, S., Salter, S., and Radebaugh, L. (2001) Global Accounting and Control: A Managerial Emphasis, Wiley, New York Hines, J. R. and Rice, E. M. (1994) ‘Fiscal Paradise: Foreign Tax Havens and American Business’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(1): 149-182 Holmstrom, B. and Tirole, J. (1991) Transfer Pricing and Organizational Form, Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 7: 201-228 Horst, T. (1971) ‘The Theory of the Multinational Firm: Optimal Behavior Under Different Tariff and Tax Rates’, Journal of Political Economy, 79(5): 1059-1072 Kant, C. (1990) ‘Multinational Firms and Government Revenue’, Journal of Public Economics, 42(2): 135-147 Kant, C. (1995) ‘Minority Ownership, Deferral, Perverse Intrafirm Trade and Tariffs’, International Economic Journal, 9(1): 19-37 Kaplan, R., Weiss, D., and Desheh, E. (1997) ‘Transfer Pricing with ABC’, Management Accounting, (May): 21-28 Kovac, E. and Troy, H. (1989) ‘Getting Transfer Prices Right’, Harvard Business Review, (SeptemberOctober):146-154 Leitch, R. A. and Barrett, K. S. (1992) ‘Multinational Transfer Pricing: Objectives and Constraints’, Journal of Accounting Literature, 11: 47-92 Lin, L., Lefebvre, C., and Kantor, J. (1993) ‘Economic Determinants of International Transfer Pricing and the Related Accounting Issues, with Particular Reference to Asian Pacific Countries’, International Journal of Accounting Literature, 28: 40-70 Mehafdi, M. (2000) ‘The Ethics of International Transfer Pricing’, Journal of Business Ethics, Vol. 28(4): 365-381 Neighbour, J. (2002) ‘Transfer Pricing: Keeping it Arm’s Length’, OECD, April Spicer, B. H. (1988) ‘Towards an organizational theory of the transfer pricing process, Accounting’, Organizations and Society, 13(3): 303-324 Springsteed, (1999) ‘Separate But Unequal’, CFO Magazine, August Stewart, T. A. (1993) ‘The New Face of American Power’, Fortune, July 26: 72 Umapathy, S. (1987) Current Budgeting Practices in US Industry, Quorum Books, New York Zimmerman, J. (2003) Accounting for Decision Making and Control, 4th Edition, McGraw-Hill Irwin, New York 255