International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Preliminary Draft Notes on the Pure Theory of International Trade Houston H. Stokes Note: These "preliminary notes" are geared to the books 1. International Economics 6th edition by Robert Dunn and John Mutti, Routledge (2004) 2. Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence by Robert Feenstra Princeton (2004). 3. International Economics by Robert Mundell (1968) Columbia University as well as various key articles in the Handbook of International Economics series. The goal of these notes is to provide a "living" editable document so that students can add material to the basic outline that hopefully will focus the discussion. These notes should be treated as preliminary. Key math setups are given. Please report any errors. Notes on the Pure Theory of International Trade ............................ 1 1. Introduction .................................................. 2 2. Why Nations Trade - Gains from Trade .............................. 10 3. Modern Theory of Trade. ........................................ 21 4. Basis for Trade: The Ricardian Model vs the Hechscher-Ohlin Models ........ 25 Math Treatment of Two Factor Model ............................... 33 Magnification Effect. How do changes in product prices impact factor prices? ... 34 Effect of changes in Endowments on Industry outputs .................... 36 5. Effect on Wages of Outsourcing Intermediate Inputs; Developing an Empirical Model ............................................................ 39 Simple Model of Trade in Intermediate Inputs ......................... 41 Estimation setup .............................................. 43 Example Code and results from B34S, Rats and Stata: .................... 44 Note e ' e values reported for B34S and Rats agree. Stata made an "adjustment."Code for Leverage Plots with OLS, GAM and Marspline ......................... 54 Code for Leverage Plots with OLS, GAM and Marspline ................... 55 Edited output from Leverage Plots ................................. 56 Selected Leverage Plots. ......................................... 59 6. Extensions to H-O model suggested by Vanek .......................... 63 7. H-O Theory, increasing returns and the Gravity Model.................... 71 8. Alternative approaches to trade theory contrasted to Original HO Model. ...... 80 9. The Theory of Protection ........................................ 85 10. Arguments for Protection ....................................... 90 11. Mundell Policy Equation ........................................ 95 1 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 12. Regional Blocks => Discriminatory Trade Liberalization ................. 99 13. Commercial Policy ........................................... 100 14 Trade of Less Developed Countries ................................ 103 15 International Mobility of Labor and Capital ......................... 104 16. Balance of Payments Accounting ................................. 106 17. Market for Foreign Exchange ................................... 107 18. Impact of trade on determination of National Income ................... 113 19. Alternative Models of Balance of Payments or Exchange Rate Determination .. 114 20. Balance of Payments adjustment with fixed exchange rates ............... 116 21. Balance of Payments Adjustment through exchange rate changes .......... 119 22. The theory of flexible exchange rates .............................. 120 23. International Monetary Experience 1880-1940 ....................... 121 24 The International Monetary System 1945-1973 ........................ 125 25 International Monetary Relations 1973 - Present ...................... 127 1. Introduction International Trade is concerned with exchange. Important topics include the mechanisms by which trade causes: Welfare changes in both countries. Who gains and by how much? Large and small country assumptions impact the analysis. Can growth actually lower a countries welfare? The distribution of income changes in both countries. Who owns the factors? Are the factors mobile both into and out of the country? Factor prices change in both countries. Will factor prices adjust so as to be equalized? Why is factor price equalization so important? How does persistent wage differentials drive immigration? Under what assumptions does immigration of workers lead to PL / PK , to PL / PK constant, to PL / PK ? The range of goods produced changes in both countries. What is the consumption gain from trade? the production gain from trade? Under what conditions will countries with same tastes and same production conditions trade? Who gains from trade inside the country? Who loses? Under what assumptions will the relative prices of goods to change after trade, the relative price of factors change? Key aspects of trade policy include: 2 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - The effect of tariff on international trade. - The effect of free trade areas (NAFTA), customs unions and economic unions on welfare. Why do we need a theory of international trade? Macroeconomics assumes: 1. economic agents maximize their self interest, 2. such agents are rational. In trade theory more assumptions are needed. Within a nation state it is assumed that labor and capital are free to move among regions. This may not be the case across countries. What does this “restriction” cost? Within a nation state there are normally no government-imposed barriers to shipment of goods (tariff). Between countries there are many barriers including tariffs, regulations (steering wheel construction laws forced Rolls Royce to buy parts from GM in the 1960’s. Cars had to be crash tested, even if they were high priced and hand made.) The state of the economy within a nation state is usually the same for all regions. Across countries, differences in a countries position in the business cycle can have major ramifications. (In the EU zone Germany and Greece are in different “phases”.) Within a country there is only one currency. Exchange rate changes complicate the analysis. (In world of fixed exchange rate and perfect capital mobility there is only one interest rate. In a world of flexible exchange rates, different interest rates across countries are possible.) In period 1970-2000 share of exports + imports as a % of GNP (See Table 1.1 Dunn Mutti 2004) - US - Canada -Mexico - UK - Japan - Germany - France - Italy 1970 10.8 42.5 17.4 43.8 20.3 43.2 31.1 30.5 1975 15.8 46.8 16.5 52.5 25.6 49.5 36.9 39.1 1980 20.5 54.7 23.7 52.0 27.9 55.1 43.2 44.1 1985 17.1 54.0 25.9 56.6 25.0 63.8 46.8 45.4 1990 20.4 50.8 40.7 50.6 19.8 61.6 43.6 39.4 3 1995 23.3 71.3 58.1 57.1 16.8 48.2 43.6 50.0 2000 26.0 85.8 64.0 58.1 20.1 67.1 55.8 55.7 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 US share is low but has increased substantially. Compared to most all other countries, US share is low. US is now being impacted by the world to an increased degree. In the period 1970-2000 the total capital outflows of the US increased from 10.88 to 580.65. Inflows from 6.24 to 1024.23 (See table 1.2). These numbers are greater for UK (3.16 to 777.68 and 1.64 to 801.58). This data is nominal, not real! US faces increased vulnerability to foreign shocks (such as 1974 oil price shock). As of 2012, the EU and the China slow-down are the biggest risks. Changes is exchange rates under the flexible exchange rate system provides a damper of shocks to the US economy. (In early 80's high US interest rates attracted capital from abroad causing the dollar to appreciate and making sales overseas more difficult.) Recent experience in the fall of 2008 indicates how vulnerable the world economy is to the financial system. The degree of leverage in many parts of the world has caused a general loss of confidence in financial institutions. The real side is being impacted by the monetary side to a degree not seen for a long time. Euro now gives Europe one currency like the US. The EEC is like what was setup in the US in 1796. US now faces a potential economic rival. "Pure Theory" of International Trade provides a framework by which all kinds of exchanges can be analyzed, both graphically and using statistical (econometric) methods. "Monetary Theory" of International trade is concerned with balance of payments adjustment. Increasingly it appears that the monetary side can have substantial real side effects. It remains to be seen if the crisis of the fall of 2008 will result in higher tariffs such as were enacted in the US and other countries in 1932 and which proved so damaging. Positive Economics - Develops a framework of analysis - Constructs various alternative hypothesis - Tests hypothesis Normative Economics - Determines what ought to be 4 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Can lay out costs and benefits (defense vs welfare) - Want to look at gains from exchange. - Want to look at the costs and benefits of differing policies. Trade can be shown from supply and demand analysis. Figure 1 Def: An indifference curve drawn on the X and Y diagram contains the locus of points showing different bundles of X and Y to which the consumer (country) is indifferent. Assume barter ratio is fixed. Country at f producing and consuming oc of steel and od of food. The domestic relative P P price line is a a'. The world relative price line is a a'' . World steel domestic steel causing Pfood Pfood producers to stop producing food and go 100% to steel (o a). At position g the country consumes ob of steel and gives up ab of steel to get oe of food. Trade moved the country from U1 to U2. Trade is caused by the relative price differing between regions. 5 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Figure 2 For complements the indifference curve approaches a 900 angle. For substitutes the indifference curve approaches a 1800 angle. The above analysis assumes we have a community indifference curve. A major unsolved problem in economics is how to construct the community indifference curve. Key idea: Normative economics is in the indifference curve and changes: - Over time - Due to advertising - Due to consumption itself Trade theory assumes exchange in the presence of some fixed factor. The fixed factor does not have to be location related. Examples are land, tastes, skills, climate. Gains from trade can arise: Due to changing consumption patterns as a result of changes in relative prices. Changes in the degree by which a country specializes. Both changes in consumption patterns and specialization. 6 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Key idea: "Under what conditions can trade gain one country more than another? Who gains in the country? Changes is specialization imply changes in the returns to factors and thus possible dislocation. This can cause political problems. Wheat farmers in Mass lost out to Iowa when US Constitution outlawed internal tariffs. Historic international trade models assumed perfect competition and constant returns to scale. Assuming increasing returns was not studied sufficiently. Growth. Sources of growth in the United States include: Population (immigration) Education (increases in technology) Resources Will of People (WWII increased productivity) Some assumptions used to simplify analysis. (How sensitive are results to these assumptions?) Neutrality of Money: Real variables determined independently of monetary variables. Each sector looks at relative prices not absolute prices (which are a function of money supply). All prices are flexible (determined by competition) Assume initially the amount of factors of production are fixed. Assume initially that factors are immobile between countries. Assume initially that same technology is available to all consumers. Assume that initial income patterns are known. Assume initially no barriers to trade in form of transportation, information, communication. 7 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Key questions: Direction of trade Volume of trade and prices of traded goods Effects of trade restrictions Effect of free trade and restricted trade on welfare Approaches: - Partial equilibrium approach uses supply and demand. The problem is that as you move on the supply and demand curve, the assumptions underlying these curves are not met resulting in the curves shifting. (See Above figure) - General Equilibrium Approach. Uses production possibility curve (PPP), Community indifference curves, and relative price line to determine trade welfare. This approach will be the main focus of the course. 8 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Technical problems is Trade Analysis: Time period of analysis. If the period is too short, then substitutes cannot be developed and analysis leads to misleading results. Example. Gas crisis in 1974. Gas prices increased and in the short run people drove old cars. In the longer run more fuel efficient cars were produced and demand for gas fell. => Negative balance of payments effects of an increase in import prices are most severe in the short run. Simultaneity Both supply and demand may be shifting. Need to identify the supply and demand curves using 2SLS or 3SLS methods. Errors of Measurement. Trade data may be poor. Example: US used value of disks and manuals to measure software sales. Aggregate elasticity. Aggregate elasticity measures biased toward zero since greatest price fluctuation is observed in goods with inelastic response => goods with inelastic S & D are likely to be given too much weight in the calculation of the aggregate price index. Adjustment. During the time path of adjustment we may see points not on the true curve. Elasticity measurement is critical. Assume two countries initially in equilibrium. The home country (A) imports X and exports Y. Define the income elasticity of demand in A as: aI (X / X ) /(I / I ) If BI AI then as A and B grow the balance of payments will move against B. It will be in B's interest to have growth in A increase. => Economic stagnation in the foreign country implies balance of payments problems in the home country. The lower the income elasticity of demand, the faster a country can grow and still maintain balance of payments equilibrium. 9 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 2. Why Nations Trade - Gains from Trade - Nations trade because they benefit from it. - Adam Smith stressed that nations traded due to absolute advantage. Absolute cost advantage => the real cost (labor ) was less in one country than another. Smith was thinking in terms of labor theory of value. Modern economics (not Marxism) discards this approach and looks at other costs of production such as land and capital. - Assuming labor is mobile, labor is the only input and competition within a single country => goods will trade at prices that are a direct proportion of their labor costs. This further assumes away retraining problems. But between countries labor may not be mobile due to a number of reasons. - Ricardo stated that absolute advantage was not a necessary condition for trade. Trade could occur due to comparative advantage. Ricardo's example involved the number of hours to produce two goods: Cloth Wine Portugal 90 80 England 100 120 Portugal has absolute advantage in both goods since it takes less labor to produce cloth and wine than England. This does not mean that England cannot benefit from trade In Portugal 90 hours of labor get you 9/8 of a wine barrel or 1C = (9/8)W. In England 100 hours of labor get you 5/6 of a wine barrel or 1C = (5/6)W. => Portugal sell wine, England sell cloth which suggests that it would be desirable for labor in Portugal (England) to move into production of wine (cloth). Define ai and ai* as the # of hours for the ith good in the home (Portugal) and foreign country (England). a1 a2 90 80 * * a1 a2 100 120 2 2 i 1 i 1 Assume L and L* are the labor in the home and foreign country. L Li and L* L*i 10 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 MPPLi 1/ ai and MPPL* 1/ ai* Assume cloth is on the x axis and pi and pi* are the prices of i the ith good in home and foreign country, The slope of the budget lines that are tangent to the indifference curves imply that in the absence of trade a1 / a2 p1 / p2 90 / 80 1.125 and a1* / a2* p1* / p2* 100 /120 .8333 . This suggests that cloth is relative expensive in the home country Portugal and wine is relative expensive in the foreign country England. => England sell cloth and Portugal sell wine. Define the world price in terms of the relative price of good 1 (here cloth). If P a1 / a2 ( P a1* / a2* ) then the home (foreign) country will produce both cloth and wine. If a1 / a2 P a1* / a2* then the home country will specialize in cloth and the foreign country in wine. Note: comparative advantage determines the wages in each country. Absolute advantage determines the level of wages across countries. Can setup example in terms of 1 unit of labor. England Germany Broadcloth 10 10 Linen 15 20 -=> in England 10 broadcloth = 15 Linen in Germany 10 broadcloth = 20 Linen - English broadcloth producers should exchange broadcloth for linen in Germany. Broadcloth produces will benefit if they can obtain more than 15 linen for 10 broadcloth. German liner producers note that to get broadcloth in Germans they have to trade 20 linen but if they trade with England they can only give up 15 linen for 10 broadcloth. Mill introduced demand to allows us to determine how much each country would trade. Specie Flow Mechanism. Assume national money is determined by gold stocks. Assume a two country world where trade is initially in balance. Here prices in each country are stable. Assume next that increased demand for A's goods causes gold to flow in. PA / PB causes demand for A's goods to fall and demand for B's goods to rise. Specie Flow mechanism implies that | A | | B | 1 (Marshall Lerner Condition). If this condition is not met, all gold will flow from B to A. This classical adjustment mechanism relied on change in gold flows to change national money to change prices and costs. This theory did not deal with output and unemployment effects. 11 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Managed Adjustment. Keynes suggested that a change in demand could change the demand for imports (exports) without a change in prices. Taussig noted that before WWI the system appeared to adjust faster that the level of gold flows would suggest. Neuburger-Stokes (1979) presented time series evidence that suggested that central banks were using interest rate policy to speed the adjustment without having to resort to the level of gold flows that would other wise occur. Historical notes: Earl Hamilton studied gold flows from the new world to Spain and hence to France and England. During wars (such as the Bullionist Controversy) many countries suspended the gold standard. In this century the gold standard was suspended during WWI. After the war the UK went back on gold at the prewar rate. The return was protracted and slow. In the late 20's the world moved into depression and countries moved off gold. After WWII the world moved to the gold exchange standard. Here countries pegged to either the pound or the dollar which in turn pegged to gold. Major problems included adjustment, confidence, and liquidity. In the fall of 1967 at the Rio Conference the SDR was setup. The SDR paid interest. No country was required to accept more that 2 times its quota. The SDR was designed to solve the liquidity problem. It did not address the confidence or adjustment problem. In Nov 1967 the pound was devalued from $2.80 to $2.40. In the 20's exchange rates moved in part as a result of changes in prices. This led to purchasing power parity theory or the "law of one price." The problem is that this theory is not general. It does not look at changes in demand, at changes in capital flows and at technological changes, all of which impact on exchange rates. Define as the dollar price of one unit of the foreign currency. Theory suggests that: ( Pf / Pd ) Technological changes (lower domestic prices) Capital inflow In 30's moved away from PPP since there were other causes of exchange rate movements. These included large scale speculative capital flows, competitive devaluations by both deficit and surplus countries and problems of exchange stability due to fears. Expectations can alter 's in countries. - Before trade the relative prices of goods in A and B differ. After trade they adjust to be the same. Assume ( PXA / PYX ) ( PXB / PYB ) . This implies that A is willing to sell Y to B and import X from B. The gains from trade include a consumption effect and a possible production effect. Assuming no changes in production in each country, trade can still result in a gain for both countries. If as a result of trade production changes in both countries there can be a still further production effect. To accurately measure the gains from trade we need: 12 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Community indifference curves in each country. Production functions in each country (Production possibility curves) Offer Curves (derived from community indifference curves and production possibility curves to determine the world trade price). It is important to know how to derive these curves. Partial equilibrium analysis such as figure 1 can be used to attempt to measure the gains from trade but there are serious problems in moving along country supply and demand curves without the curves themselves shifting. This course will use general equilibrium approach. Basic diagram is given in figure 3. We assume diminishing returns to scale which is seen by the country having a production possibility curve which is bowed outward. The country starts at k with oc of food and oi of steel. After trade with no production change the country is on higher indifference curve and consuming oe of food and on of steel. If production changes, country produces at g. Here food is ob and steel is of. After trade country gives up bd to food to get fp of steel. Country now on highest in difference curve. We assume here that the world trade price does not change as a result of trade (small country assumption). Figure 3 13 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 14 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Figure 4 shows equilibrium in a closed economy assuming constant returns to scale production. Here in contrast to figure 3 we have a straight line production possibility curve. Figure 4 Country reaches U2 by producing oa food and ob steel. Country is at point C on the production possibility curve. Without trade country cannot get to U3. Figure 5 shows effect of trade. Country was consuming and producing at k. After Trade county reached higher indifference curve at g. Steel consumption increased from ob to om and food consumption did not change much. Country production point was now on Food and no steel. Na of food was sold for om of steel. Figure 5 15 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Historical Development of Trade Theory - Trade theory developed in four areas: I. II. III. IV. Balance of payments and theory of employment Fluctuating Exchange rates Price Theory and International trade Commercial Policy and The Theory of International Trade I. Balance of payments and Theory of Employment - Prior to Keynes - Monetary theory (specie flow mechanism) suggested that system adjusted automatically. Gold out => P d , P f and trade adjusts. The classical theory did have a role for interest rates. The mechanism was Gold M P, costs not output, employment - Keynes attacked theory suggesting could have unemployment and over production. - New theory. An external event which causes exports => imports without Pd. The mechanism was exports => level of aggregate demand => imports . This theory covered the balance of payments effects being either or depending on Ia and Ib where Ii is the income elasticity of the i th country. - Taussig before WWI noted that the system appeared to adjust faster that gold flows would suggest. He had no theory to explain what was happening. Neuburger and Stokes in "The Relationship between Interest Rates and Gold Flows Under the Gold Standard: A New Empirical Approach," , Economica, Vol. 46, August 1979, pp. 261-279. presented evidence that governments were using a variety of policies to force adjustment without a gold flow. - After WWI elasticity measurements appeared to be low. Why did trade adjust? The Keynesian approach provided a missing link. - Keynesian theory independent of banking policy and implied that banks cannot influence the system. The Keynesian theory did have antecedents in Ricardo and others. 16 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Capital flow effects. Keynesian theory => unless a disturbance (such as a capital flow) disturbs the circular flow of income (via a change in investment), it will have no effect on the system. The classical theory treated all flows as the same. In classical theory the gold flow => M and M => changes in prices and the balance of payments etc. II. Fluctuating Exchange Rates - During WWI gold standard suspended. After war world's return to the gold standard was protracted and slow. Next the world moved into depression => a period of fluctuating rates. - In 20's exchange rate moved as a result of war causing prices to increase. This led to purchasing power parity theory (see contributions of Officer) that codified the "law of one price." PPP => exchange rates had to move. Problems with PPP included 1. not looking at effects of shifts in international demand on exchange rates, 2. not looking at effects of capital flows on exchange rates, 3. difficulty on selecting just what price should be used in the index. - In 30's many countries found depression caused changes in the exchange rate. There was a move away from PPP since here changes in the price level was not the cause of exchange rate movements. The income of all countries fell in the depression but not all countries balance of payments were effected the same. Keynesian theory on the effect of induced income changes implied: Balance of payments deficit => Y down => imports down => balance of payments improves. This line of reasoning suggested that changes in the exchange rate would not adjust the balance of payments. The situation was complicated by: - large scale speculative capital flows. - Competitive devaluation by both deficit and surplus countries. - Problems with exchange stability due to fear => . III. Price Theory and International Trade - Classical theory measured gain from trade as difference between international rate of exchange on commodities and the rate that would prevail in the absence of international trade. Gain = the savings in resources from trade. This theory rested on the labor theory of value. - Haberler postulated production possibility curve. Leontief added indifference curves which allowed measurement of the gains from trade. The new approach got away from real costs theories and depended on the ratio of the marginal costs of the two products. - Viner attacked the new approach on the grounds that the PPC (or production substitution curve) assumed fixed quantities of factors. In Viner's view, P changes caused 17 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 changes in factor prices. Since as we move along the PPC curve relative prices of factors changes (except in constant returns to scale case) => supply of factors must change. Viner wanted to look at the "real cost" of supplying factors. Viner further noted that the country indifference curves depend on the distribution of goods. Since international trade changes the distribution of goods => Country indifference curves shift as a result of trade. This important point is moot if we assume homogenous tastes for all consumers in the country. - Samuelson (in 1939 Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science) showed that after trade, each country if it wants can obtain more of every good while performing less of every production service. => cannot measure the gain but it is a gain never the less. Samuelson showed that some degree of trade can make the country better. This leaves open the possibility of an optimum tariff. - The more modern H-O Theory shows how trade based on factor endowments alters the distribution of income. H-O Theory argues that in many cases trade originates from the fact that one country had a large supply of one factor. This is contrast to the Ricardian Theory that focused on technology differences in the countries. Using the basic H-O assumptions of two goods, two factors and the same technology in each country and constant returns to scale, the H-O model argues that assuming trade in a good that uses one factor intensively => returns to owners of that factor relative to other factor owners. H-O Theory showed that assuming constant returns to scale, except for some cases involving complete specialization, trade tended to equalize relative factor returns in the two trading countries. Ohlin showed how changes in relative factor prices might change factor supplies in the longer run. H-O theory can assume fixed factors supplies or variable factor supplies. Recent advances in theory have extended the analysis to the increasing returns case (Krugman, Helpman) that refine the arguments for trade and for protection. Use of the H-O-V Model allows adding more inputs and setting up tests of the Leontief hypothesis using econometric methods. Looking only at one country producing goods yi i 1, , N where there are N goods. If there are two factors of production yi fi ( Li Ki ) L1 L2 L and K1 K2 K . Assuming the "even case" which implies an equal number of goods and factors and maximizing the production of good 2 conditional on good 1 we note that y2 h( y1 , L, K ) which defines the production possibility curve. If y 2 is a concave function of y1 then 2h( y1 , L, K ) / y12 0 which indicates that as we increase production of good 1 the rate of increase in good 2 is reduced, giving the concave shape of the production possibility curve. (See figure 3 of these notes). Mill introduced demand which allows us to determine how much each country would trade. IV Theory of Tariffs 18 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Tariffs and terms of trade. Between WWI and WWII shaky foundation for free trade. In 30's US raised tariffs as did other countries. Samuelson showed that using the optimum tariff (to be defined later) that assumes the elasticity of supply of the foreign country is not => country putting up tariff could gain at expense of the other country. Scitovsky showed how such a tariff increased gains from retaliation. => all countries try to gain = all countries lose. Such a result might lead to tariff bargaining. A tariff is like a monopoly. Some gain, some lose. In a tariff war the bigger countries are at an advantage. - Tariffs and the distribution of income. Tariff => certain groups gain. StolperSamuelson (RES Nov 41) showed that regardless of tariff effects on the terms of trade and real income as a whole, protection increases return and relative share of factor of production most important in protected industry. Proved for 2 good, 2 factor case. In more than 2 good world cannot tell for sure what will happen since can have complementary relationships. In the 19th century agriculture was governed by land. A tariff on manufacturing made labor scarce => raised return of the working class. This became the "pauper labor" argument for tariffs. 'Pauper Labor" theory not the whole story!! V Commercial policy - Mercantilists thought trade was an outlet for a countries surplus production and a way to get gold. - Classical theory argued against mercantilism. In their view trade was to satisfy wants. A shift in emphasis from exports to imports. In classical view, exports to obtain gold not necessarily the right thing to do since P . The goal was not a surplus but balance. In an N country world only N-1 countries can be successful multilateral mercantilists. Only one can be a successful bilateral mercantilist! - Keynes attached the classical view that export surplus was not a good thing. Keynes argues exports => gold =>Yd => increased welfare country. This argument assumes that initially you had unemployment. In Keynes view mercantilists were OK when they argued that exports should be a vent for over production. Keynes noted that not all countries could run a balance of payments surplus. Keynes felt that a policy of trade restriction is a treacherous policy, even in the short run. Summary. - Meade integrated income (multiplier) and price theory of balance of payments. He argued looking at two policy targets(internal balance, external balance). To obtain these goals 19 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 required two instruments. => # of targets = # of instruments. - Mundell principle of effective market classification => use instrument where it is most effective. - Meade argued that there is no one rate of exchange. There is one equilibrium rate corresponding to each level of interest rates and income. As interest rates increase, with a fixed level of income, capital will be attracted in. This will appreciate the exchange rate. Give interest rates, if income were to increase => demand for exports would increase implying a depreciation of the exchange rate. - Alexander looked at income effects on the balance of payments. A balance of payments surplus => total production > total absorption (C + I in real terms). If a devaluation is to improve trade balance it must reduce absorption. This argument is irrespective of elasticities. Absorption theory => balance of payments only if hoarding goes up since only in this way can we forestall imports as a result of income increasing due to exports . This theory has a Keynesian flavor. - If at full employment and have a devaluation due to a prior deficit, then absorption theory suggests balance of payments will not improve because Y cannot increase. The devaluation has converted demand for the import good to demand for the domestic good. => cannot rely only on to help external balance without policies to reduce absorption. Unless absorption then country will have nothing to sell! Key idea: Demand is not the only thing to look at. Supply is also important. - Problems with absorption theory. The theory as stated implicitly assumes a neutral monetary policy or one that maintains the interest rate by changes in M. If this is not done: deficit => devaluation => demand of domestic consumers for foreign goods , domestic demand => balance of payments gets worse since absorption had to have increased. If were at less than full employment could have domestic income > absorption and get an improvement in the balance of payments. If drop neutral monetary policy assumption the increased domestic demand => id => capital comes in and balance of payments improves. Metzler Case. Stolper-Samuelson showed how a large factor could gain absolutely as well as relatively from a tariff. Logic: tariff=> internal price of protected good => value of scarce factor goes . As a counter example, Metzler showed protection may not increase price of the importable good since it may improve the terms of trade sufficiently to shift not only the external terms of trade (price ratio of exports relative to imports without tariff) but also the internal terms of trade in favor of exportables => buy more of the foreign good. 20 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 3. Modern Theory of Trade. - Moved away from theory based only on labor theory of value. - Initial Assumptions (to be relaxed later): - Perfect Competition in both commodity and factor markets. - Given quantities of the factors of production (assume population and capital growth are zero) - Technology is given. - Zero transport costs and no barriers to trade. - Given tastes and preferences. -Factors of production are perfectly mobile among industries within each country but are immobile between countries. - Opportunity cost of one unit of X is the amount of Y that you have to give to produce one more unit of X. From opportunity cost you get the production possibility curve which defines the maximum amount of X given Y or conversely the maximum amount of Y given X. - Production possibility curves show constant returns to scale if they are straight lines from the upper left to the lower right. (See figure 2-1). - Production possibility curves show decreasing returns to scale if they are convex to the origin. (See figure 2.6). - Production possibility curves show increasing returns to scale if they are concave to the origin. - Community Indifference Curves shows the locus of points showing the consumption of X and Y to which the community is indifferent. To derive these curves requires assumptions be made on the distribution of income within a country. => all policy implications have to be somewhat qualified. - With constant returns to scale, trade drives country to complete specialization (See figure 2-4) 21 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - With decreasing returns to scale trade does not in general drive a country to complete specialization. (See figure 2-6). - With increasing returns to scale there can be specialization in the wrong direction. Figure 5B Specialization in right/wrong direction assuming increasing returns. - The Offer Curve plots the quantities that countries will be willing to export at different prices. Intersection of the offer curves sets the international trade price. - Draw Increasing, constant and decreasing returns to scale production possibility curves. Recent research by Krugman and others have discussed the implications of product differentiation (monopolistic competition and economies of scale) on the results obtained using the 2 by 2 case and constant returns to scale. - Draw Gains from trade in case of increasing returns, constant returns and decreasing returns in two cases: 1. where there is no change in production (only Consumption gain) and 2. when there is consumption and production gains. (See book figure 2-9 as a basis upon which to draw). Show specialization in the right and wrong direction. - Draw the derivation of the offer curve in the case of constant returns to scale (see book figure 2-9) and decreasing returns to scale. 22 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Draw determination of the equilibrium terms of trade. (see book figure 210 - Define the coefficient elasticity of the offer curve => e = % change in quantity demanded / % change in the terms of trade. In figure 2-11 we see e= in segment Oa, e > 1 in segment ab and at b e = 1 since for small movements the % change in the terms of trade % change in the quantity demanded. In the segment bc e< 1. The elasticity of demand the foreign countries offer curves determines whether the optimum tariff is 0 (if e= ). In trade the small country assumption => that e < for the domestic country but that e = for the foreign country. - Define the coefficient of elasticity of demand as e = % change in Q demanded / % change in terms of trade - For a straight line offer curve e = - For a curved (yet positively sloped) offer curve e>0 - For a negatively sloped offer curve e < 0 (See figure 2-11). - If the offer curve is not a straight line => can have the possibility of an optimum tariff. Complications will occur if the other country "fights back. - Distribution of the gains from trade. The lower e for the foreign country the more the gains from trade accrue to the home country. Take of a small county trading with the United States. The small country sees the US offer curve as having e = . Here no matter what the small country does, the US price is always the same. This will be shown to be true in the case when the small country places a tariff on the US. If e < , then as the tariff reduces quantity, the foreign country lowers price. Hence the price net of the tariff falls. - Effects of trade. If there are production changes due to trade opening, resources will be reallocated. Mechanism: Assume country A exports X and imports Y. After trade, production of X will increase and production of Y will fall. Inputs used more intensively in the production of X will increase in value relative to prices of inputs used intensively in the production of Y. This is will cause changes in income and may have an impact on demand within the country. Those gaining from trade should be able to compensate those hurt by trade. After trade a country tends to specialize in the direction of the good in which it has a comparative advantage. Changes in the production mix are checked by increasing costs. 23 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Figure 2.10 shows general equilibrium determination of world relative price. Figure 2.9 can be modified to show total gain consumption gain and production gain. Figure 2-8 shows partial equilibrium approach to same problem. - Unless the country is driven to complete specialization after trade (PXA/PYA) = (PXB/PYB). At a later date we will show that the prices of inputs are related to the prices of final products. - A movement along the production possibility curve may take a great deal of time and involve much retraining and human cost. There may be political pressures against such moves. The 2008 US election showed that even within a state there are winners and losers of opening trade. - In the real world with many countries, transport costs and many products analysis can proceed if for each country goods are ranked by their relative comparative advantage. Usually a country exports the good for which it has the greatest comparative advantage and imports goods for which it has the least comparative advantage. The heavier (or more perishable) a good the more likely it will not be traded. - It is hoped that through trade there can be a reduction of tensions (war). This was an important motivation for the development of the European Common Market and in recent times NAFTA. - Free Trade Area. No tariffs between country A and B. A and B maintain separate tariffs for the rest of the world. - Customs Union. No tariffs between country A and B. A and B maintain a common tariff for the rest of the world. - Economic Union. => Customs union with labor mobility. 24 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 4. Basis for Trade: The Ricardian Model vs the Hechscher-Ohlin Models -The Ricardian Model stresses that trade is due to technological differences across countries. The Hechscher-Ohlin model stress that trade is due to differences in factor endowments. After first looking at the Ricardian Model using math (See Feenstra Chapter 1), the Heckscher-Ohlin Model is discussed. - Let ai labor needed for production of good i in the home country. ai* labor needed for production of good i in the foreign country L and L* are the labor in the homer and foreign country. The marginal product of labor in each industry is 1 / ai . If pi the price of the product in industry i and workers are paid their marginal product, then in equilibrium p1 / a1 p2 / a2 . The slopes of the production possibility curve in each country is a1 / a2 and a1* / a2* . If the home country has a comparative advantage in good 1, then a1 / a2 a1* / a2* . Define p as the relative price of good 1 or p p1 / p2 . Figure 4.1 Ricardian Model 25 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Define A p a* a1* / a2* and C =p a a1 / a2 If p is below A and C, then both countries produce good 2. For C<p<A then the home country produces good 1 and the foreign country produces good 2. Point D ( L / a1 ) / L* / a2* ) . - Heckscher-Ohlin theory, which assumes two countries, two goods and two factor of production, is one explanation of why relative prices of goods differ before trade. Basic idea: Countries differ in the amounts of various factors of production (land, labor, capital) that they possess. Relative scarcity impacts relative factor prices and hence production patterns. - Theory predicts that a nation's export (import) list will include commodities whose production requires factors that are relatively abundant (scarce) in relation to other nations. (Exception is case there tastes out weight production conditions.) - => Comparative Advantage determined by supply side. Later we will show a situation where by "tastes outweigh production conditions." Here demand conditions are overwhelming supply conditions. - H-O theory predicts that trade will increase the price of the abundant factor and decrease the price of the scarce factor. Assuming two factors L and K, then in equilibrium (PLA/PKA) = (PLB/PKB). This condition holds unless one or both countries are driven to complete specialization. - If we assume indifference curves are the same in all countries (same tastes) => supply conditions will drive trade. - Because a nation's comparative advantage is based on relative factor endowment, over time it could change. Physical capital could be accumulated. Human capital could change (more education, trained workers come into country). (After WWII Germany had ruined physical capital but there was still human capital in the population.) - Formal assumptions - Perfect competition in both commodity and factor markets. (=> price = MC and full employment in both countries) - Factors of production immobile internationally but mobile nationally. - Same tastes in both countries. 26 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Transport costs are zero, no tariffs. - State of technology given and the same in both countries. - Constant returns to scale exist in both industries. (Note in the Cobb-Douglas case Q L K . The production function shows decreasing returns to scale, constant returns to scale of increasing returns to scale as ( ) is < 1, = 1 or > 1. - Commodities can be unambiguously ranked in terms of factor intensity. - Discussion of assumptions. Constant returns to scale => that is all inputs go up by a factor then output goes up by . Proof: Q ' ( L) ( K ) L K Q Isoquants are shown in figure 3-4 - The assumption of identical production functions does not mean that all countries operate using the same mix of labor and capital. Figure 3-5 shows isoquants for wheat (W1 W2) and cloth (C1 C2). Initial budget line is MN. (Can buy OM of land or ON of labor. At these relative prices, country will maximize wheat production at E or cloth production at J. Note that the country cannot do both at the same time. Given this budget line, cloth in labor intensive and wheat is land intensive at E. Next assume that the price of land becomes relatively cheaper relative to labor. The budget line rotates clockwise to RS. Given the setup the same amount of cloth is produced (C1) but in a more land intensive way at K. Substantially more wheat is produced (at W2) in a more land intensive way. Note that the slope of MN represents the factorprice ratio. In this case, even with a shift in relative factor prices, wheat is still more land intensive than cloth. If isoquants are drawn where the wheat isoquant shows a high degree of substitution between land and labor while the cloth isoquant shows that land and labor are more complementary, then a reversal in factor intensity is possible. - Derivation of the production possibility curve - Place two figure 3.1's back to back to form Edgeworth Box. In figure 3-6 line OO' is the contract curve. It is always more efficient to move from a position such as Z off the contract curve to a position such as Q on the contract curve. Points P, Q and R trace out the 27 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 production possibility curve. Point Z becomes a point inside the production possibility curve. - Along the contract curve the marginal rate of substitution between labor and land in the production of wheat is the same as the marginal rate of substitution of labor and land in the production of cloth. - Define MPP i j as the increase in the production of j for one more input of i. In equilibrium MPP 1 j / P1 = MPP 2 j / P2 where 1 and 2 are inputs. - Slope of the isoquant = MPP 1 j / MPP 2 j - Slope of isocost = P1 / P2 - Note: We assume that input 2 is on the vertical axis. (As you get close to vertical axis MPP of that input 0 => slope . As you get to horizontal axis slope of isocqant 0 => MPP of that input goes to 0.) - Along the contract curve slopes of isoquants are the same. => (MPP 1 j / MPP 2 j) = (MPP 1 i / MPP 2 i ) and are equal to the ratios of the input prices P1 / P2 - Figure 3-7 shows effect on production possibility curve of increasing inputs land and labor. - Slope of PPC = marginal rate of transformation MRT. In equilibrium MRT = ratio of good prices. - In consumption theory we have [MUx / Px] = [MUy / Py] - Slope of indifference curve = MUx / MUy - In equilibrium ratios of MU, prices and MRT are the same in both countries. => If the assumptions of the analysis are true you will get factor price equalization. For further detail see classic papers by Stolper-Samuelson in 1941 and 1948. - As the economy moves to equilibrium there are income effects. Owners of factors of production having price increases (decreases) will have their relative incomes increase (decrease). Because it is impossible to make interpersonal comparisons of utility, cannot tell if national welfare went up. If all persons have the same utility functions and because income went up => winners get more than losers lose. If all persons do not have same utility functions, then 28 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 compensation principle can be used. - Compensation principle. Can winners pay losers to accept the change? Will they? In practice owners of scarce factors of production favor protection since free trade will lower their rent. In the United States free trade usually impacts unskilled labor negatively. => labor often favors higher tariffs. - The predictions of H-O theory require that adjustment is complete. In the short run all factors of production in the import competing industry may be hurt. Since these industries are in specific regions, may have negative regional effects. - Trade is a substitute for factor mobility. H-O theory => can either have factor mobility or international trade. Factor mobility alters the relative prices of factor prices. Rybczynski Theorem show conditions under which relative factor prices do not have to move when one input increases. European economic community allows labor to be mobile but when times get tough in one region labor can go home. EEC found cultural effects of labor mobility. NAFTA allows Mexican workers not to come to the US to produce but to produce in Mexico and send goods here. - Rybczynski Theorem shows conditions under which an increase in one factor of production does not lead to the relative price of this factor going down. (See figure 3.9). Assume the economy is on the contract curve and that on the axis of the Edgeworth box is Labor and Capital. Assume that labor is on the horizontal axis. Given the production of X and Y does not change and K is labor intensive, then if L => [PL/PK] . If on the other hand the production of the capital intensive good Y goes down and the production of the labor intensive good X goes up, then the capital released from the production of Y will combine with the new labor such that it is possible that [PL/PK] remains unchanged. This theorem shows that immigration of labor does not necessarily result in a decrease in the wage rate. There are three possible cases. The Rybczynski line can be drawn on the production possibility diagram. In order for [PL/Pk] to stay constant, when the input used most intensively in the production of C goes up, the output of food must decrease to release the other input to now combine with the more plentiful input. See figure 3.9 -Leontief Paradox. Leontief expected that the United States would export goods that were capital intensive and import goods that were labor intensive. We found the converse. Why? (Later using the H-O-V theory we will discuss whether in fact Leontief setup the econometric model correctly. - US labor may have more (human) capital attached than labor in other countries. => cannot just measure labor. - H-O theory assumes same tariff on all goods. US tariffs are relatively higher on 29 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 labor intensive good than capital intensive goods. - Leontief may have statistical error such that the there may not be a significant difference between the two capital/labor ratios. - Reversal. The H-O theory assumes that all goods can be ranked in terms of their capital intensity and that the ranking is the same for all price ratios of capital and labor. The usual case is: Figure 4.2 Non Reversal Case Figure 4.2 shows the usual case. For relative price # 1 X=Y=1. If (Pk/PL) => than x=1 is less expensive than y=1. Hence (PX/PY) and (PK/PL) are positively related. 30 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Figure 4.3 shows a factor intensity reversal. Assume two goods X and Y. X has low substitutability of capital and labor while Y has high substitutability of capital and labor. In figure 4.3 for isocost line BB [PL/PK] > than [PL/PK] for AA. For BB good Y is relatively more capital intensive than X, for AA good Y is relatively more labor intensive than X. => H-O assumption of ranking goods in terms of their capital intensive does not hold and the prediction of H-O on the intensive of the exports of the United States will not necessarily hold. The importance of a reversal is that some for one P X / PY value there are two values of P L / PK. 31 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Scale induced factor intensity reversal. Analysis to date has assumed that ( PK / PL ) 0 and showed under what conditions it was possible for a reversal to take place. Now assume ( PK / PL ) 0 and look at figure 8. Here as the isocost shifts out, X continues to be capital intensive and Y continues to be labor intensive. This is the usual case. Figure 9 shows what happens when there is a factor intensity reversal even without a change in relative factor prices. Here due to scale effects at relatively low level of output X is relative capital intensive and Y is relatively labor intensive. At higher levels of output the situation reverses. Example: A small garden may be labor intensive. As the scale of operation increases, the production process becomes more capital intensive. Figure 4.4 Reversal due to scale - Since Leontief looked only at labor and capital, all natural resources were lumped into capital. This may have biased the results. 32 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Math Treatment of Two Factor Model (See Chapter 1 of Feenstra) yi fi ( Li , Ki ), i 1, 2 L1 L2 L (M1) K1 K 2 K G ( p1 , p2 , L, K ) max y1 , y2 p1 y1 p2 y2 s.t. y2 h( y1, L, K ) We assume perfect competition in product and factor markets. This assumption implies that each industry is producing to maximize GDP. By substituting the constraint into the GDP objective function and choosing y1 to maximize p1 y1 p2h( y1, L, K ) (M2) gives the first order condition p1 p2 (h / y1 ) 0 or p p1 h y 2 p2 y1 y1 (M3) or in words the economy will produce where the relative price of good 1 equals the slope of the production possibility curve. Differentiation of the GDP function (M1)produces y G y yi p1 1 p2 2 , pi pi pi (M4) Due to the "envelope theorem" the terms inside sum to 0 resulting in G / pi yi . In words the derivative of the GDP function with respect to the price of good i is the output of good i. The envelope theorem can be seen once we note that p1y1 p2y2 . Moving all terms to the left hand side and dividing by pi shows that 0 for small movements of yi induced by changes in pi . The unit cost function ci (w, r ) min Li ,Ki 0 wLi rKi | fi ( Li , Ki ) 1 (M5) is the dual of the production function fi ( Li , Ki ) . The solution of the maximization of the unit cost function is 33 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 ci (w, r ) waiL raiK (M6) where aiL yi Li and aiK yi Ki at the equilibrium ci a a aiL w iL r iK w w w ci a a aiK w iL r iK r r r (M7) ci c aiL , i aiK since the terms inside =0. In words, at equilibrium, aiL and aiK are w r the derivatives of the unit cost function with respect to the wage and interest rate, The assumption that profits equal zero (perfect competition) and full employment produces four nonlinear equations that solve w, r , y1, y2 . Gives p1 c1 ( w, r ) p2 c2 ( w, r ) (M7 & M8) a1L y1 a2 L y2 L a1K y1 a2 K y2 K The first two equations indicate that provided there are no reversals and both goods are produced, each price vector p ( p1, p2 ) corresponds to a unique wage and interest rate independent of factor endowments. Using the Ricardian model, however, this would not be the case, since any increase in L / K would lower wages. The Samuelson factor price equalization theorem (1949) requires the two sector model. The reason trade can equalize factor prices is that a labor intensive country can keep exporting the labor intensive product so that the wages of labor are kept high. Magnification Effect. How do changes in product prices impact factor prices? First differentiate the zero profit equations (M7). dpi aiL dw aik dr (M9) Which can be transformed to 34 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 dpi waiL dw raiK dr (M10) pi ci w ci r dw wa ra Note d ln w . Define iL iL and iK iK or in words the cost share of labor and w ci ci dp dw dr , rˆ capital in industry i. Given ci waiL raiK iL iK 1 . Define pˆ i i , wˆ pi w r which implies pˆ i iL wˆ iK rˆ, i 1, 2 (M11) which can be solved as pˆ1 1L 1K wˆ ˆ p2 2 L 2 K rˆ 1 wˆ 1L 1K pˆ1 1 2 K 1K pˆ1 ˆ r 2 L 2 K pˆ 2 | | 2 L 1L pˆ 2 | | (1L 2 K 1K 2 L ) (M12) 1L (1 2 L ) (1 1L ) 2 L 1L 2 L 2 K 1K If industry 1 is labor intensive => 1L 2 L | | 0 . Assume the price of good 1 increases so pˆ ( pˆ1 pˆ 2 ) 1 2 K pˆ1 1K pˆ 2 ( 2 K 1K ) pˆ1 1K ( pˆ1 pˆ 2 ) ( pˆ pˆ 2 ) pˆ1 1K 1 pˆ1 | | ( 2 K 1K ) ( 2 K 1K ) (M13) 1L pˆ 2 2 L pˆ1 (1L 2 L ) pˆ 2 2 L ( pˆ1 pˆ 2 ) ( pˆ pˆ 2 ) pˆ 2 2 L 1 pˆ 2 | | (1L 2 L ) (1L 2 L ) (M14) wˆ rˆ Wages increases more than price of good 1 since wˆ pˆ1 pˆ 2 . Since both w / p1 and w / p2 workers can buy more of both good 1 and good 2 (real wage up). Since r / p1 and r / p2 the real return to capital has fallen. 35 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Stopler-Samuelson 1941 theorem "An increase in the relative price of a good will increase the real return to the factor used intensively in that good and reduce the real return to the other factor." wˆ pˆ1 pˆ 2 rˆ (M15) Which is called the "magnification effect" by Jones (1965). Effect of changes in Endowments on Industry outputs Holding product prices fixed implies that aiL and aiK do not change. From (M8) a1L dy1 a2 L dy2 dL (E1) a1L dy1 a2 K dy2 dK Which can be rewritten as y1a1L dy1 y2 a2 L dy2 dL L y1 L y2 L (E2) y1a1K dy1 y2a2 K dy2 dK K y1 K y2 K Define dyi / yi yˆi , iL ( yi aiL / L) Li / L and iK ( yi aiK / K ) Ki / K where 1 j 2 j 1 . And rewrite (E2) as 1L yˆ1 2 L yˆ 2 Lˆ (E3) 1K yˆ1 2 K yˆ 2 Kˆ And solve 1L 2 L yˆ1 Lˆ yˆ ˆ 1K 2 K 2 K (E4) 36 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 yˆ1 1 2 K 2 L Lˆ ˆ y2 | | 1K 1L Kˆ (E5) | | 1L2 K 2 L1L 1L (1 1K ) (1 1L )1K (E6) 1L 1K 2 K 2 L Since industry 1 is labor intensive (1L 1K ) 0 | | 0 . Given that labor is increasing (immigration) and with a fixed capital stock => Lˆ 0 and Kˆ 0 since factor prices and product prices are fixed, then 2 K Lˆ Lˆ 0 (2 K 2 L ) 1K yˆ 2 Lˆ 0 (2 K 2 L ) yˆ1 (E7) Which proves the Rybczynski theorem that the labor intensive industry, 1, increases production (using up the new labor) and the capital intensive industry, 2, decreases production thus releasing capital to combine with this newly more abundant labor force. When oil was discovered off the Dutch coast. Industries using oil expanded while other industries not using oil contracted. This was called the "Dutch disease." Remark: The Rybczynski theorem assumes that both goods are produced (in the zone of diversification) and there are no reversals (either relative price reversals or scale reversals). For any endowment vector (L, K), there is a unique y1 , y2 such that when (a1L a1K ) and (a2 L a2 K ) are multiplied by this vector all endowments will be used. See (M8). Under what conditions will all outputs be > 0? Consult Feenstra Figure 1.9. The (L' K) must lie inside the vectors (a1L a1K ) and (a2 L a2 K ) . For example if too much labor is added, even if industry 2 completely stops, not enough capital can be released to hold relative factor prices constant. Proof that the Rybczynski line is straight. From (E1) assume dK 0 which implies dy a a1L dy1 a2 K dy2 0 . The slope of the Rybczynski line is 2 1K and fixed since dy1 a2 K 37 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 a1K and a2 K are fixed by assumption. 38 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 5. Effect on Wages of Outsourcing Intermediate Inputs; Developing an Empirical Model The goal of this section is to present the key ideas in Feenstra (2004) chapter 4 regarding modeling outsourcing. Preliminary empirical results will also be presented that extend his models reported in his Tables 4.4 and 4.5. The paper "The Impact of Outsourcing and High-Technology Capital on Wages: Estimates for the United States 1979-1990" by Robert Feenstra and Gorden Hanson Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol 114 # 3 (August 1999) pp 907-940 should also be consulted. Feenstra has provided his data and Stata programs which helps in the replication. B34S data files are also distributed to aid in the replication and extension of this important work. - Since the 1980's the wage of skilled workers has increased relative to unskilled workers. We want to look at the effect of outsourcing to try to explain what has occurred. - Assume an input is outsourced and is thus lower cost. - Option 1 is to use the Stopler-Samuelson 1941 Theorem, to show how if a traded good price increases the price of the input used most intensively will increase relative to the other input. - Option 2 use Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanek approach and compute the change in factor content of trade and the associated changes in factor prices. Assume w t is the equilibrium wage in a county in year t and F t is the factor content of exports where endowments are given. Deardoff-Staiger (1988) show that ( w2 w1 )( F 2 F 1 ) 0 (5.1) Which implies that a higher content of imports for some factor k , or Fk2 Fk1 0 or ( Fk2 Fk1 ) 0 will be associated with a falling wage for that factor or ( wk2 w1k ) 0. The same effect as immigration on labor wage. Borjas, Freeman and Katz (1997) find that immigration into the US during 1980-1995 explains 25% to 50% of the relative wage of high school dropouts. The increasing factor content of imports from less-developed countries also reduces the wage of high school drop outs but less than immigration. -Option 3 is to directly model the presence of traded intermediate inputs caused by firms splitting their production across several countries. Key idea Trade in intermediate inputs can have an effect on production and factor prices that is different from trade in final goods. - A fall in the price of imported intermediate inputs decreases the relative wage of the factor used intensively in those imports in the home country. (See Stopler-Samuelson). (Note in this setup the intermediate input is produced in the foreign and domestic 39 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 country.) - Since the US outsources production of labor intensive intermediate goods, this suggests a fall in the wage of unskilled labor in the United States since there is now less demand for the domestically produced intermediate input. Feenstra (page 117) argues what while unskilled labor in the home country (US) are the most disadvantaged, their real wages may in fact increase never the less due to possible lower prices of the final product. - Assuming a continuum of inputs and the 1980 Dornbusch-Fisher-Samuelson model. The US is more abundant in skilled labor than abroad. Their model predicts that the growth of capital or technology abroad will lead to increased outsourcing of labor intensive inputs from the US and increase the relative wage of skilled labor in both countries. Reason. capital and or technology implies the marginal product of foreign labor (both skilled and unskilled) goes up leading to more outsourcing. In the US unskilled labor wages fall relative to skilled wages. - In period 1979-1995 real wages of those with HS fell 13.4%, those with less that 12 years of school fell 20.2% and those with 16 or more years of school increased by 3.4%. - See Figures 4.1 & 4.2. There has been both an increase in the relative wage of nonproduction to production (manufacturing) workers and an increase in the relative employment of nonproduction to production workers. The only explanation is that there has been a movement outward of the demand curve for more skilled workers. The bulk of the increase in relative demand has occurred within the manufacturing industries. - This suggests that trade cannot be a dominant explanation of the wage and employment shifts because the movements between industries are smaller than the movements within industries. - Stopler-Samuelson suggests that if the price of skill intensive products (computers) increases then the relative wages of skilled workers will increase but the prices of computers fell and the relative wages of skilled workers increased. Data from Lawrence and Slaughter (1993) showed that the relative prices of goods produced in low skilled (production) worker intensive industries increased. => Price movements due to international competition could not explain the wage movements. - Trade however can shift the structure of production within an industry and thus on factor demand within an industry. 40 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Simple Model of Trade in Intermediate Inputs y1 unskilled labor intensive input y2 skilled labor intensive input Li Unskilled labor H i skilled labor Ki Capital pi price of input i xi 0 ( 0) import (export) of input i. yi fi ( Li , H i , Ki ), i 1, 2 (5.1) Given the price of traded inputs p ( p1 p2 ) and holding capital fixed the production of the final good yn in terms of inputs 1 and 2 is yn f n ( y1 x1 , y2 x2 ) (5.2) Ignoring additional labor and capital used in the final "bundling" stage for production of the final product, L1 L2 Ln , H1 H 2 H n , K1 K2 K n (5.3) Optimal output assuming perfect competition maximizes Gn ( Ln , H n , K n pn , p ) max xi , Li , Hi , Ki pn f n ( y1 x1, y2 x2 ) p1x1 p2 x2 (5.4) subject to the resource constraints (5.3) and the production technology (5.2) - The question becomes how will a drop in the relative price of imported inputs affect factor prices? For locally produced inputs to be competitive to those produced abroad, assume zero profit condition for producing inputs yi for i 1, 2 pi ci (w, q, r ) (5.5) 41 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Totally differencing (5.5) following Jones (1965) express the percent change in prices pˆ i and as a function of the percent change in input prices wˆ , qˆ , rˆ where ij = cost share of factor j in the production of input i. ij 1. j pˆ1 1L wˆ 1H qˆ 1K rˆ pˆ 2 2 L wˆ 2 H qˆ 2 K rˆ (5.6) With two equations and three unknowns ( wˆ , qˆ , rˆ) no solution is possible unless we assume capital has equal shares in the two industries (1K 2 K ) and subtract pˆ1 pˆ 2 (1L 2 L ) wˆ (1H 2 H )qˆ (1L 2 L )( wˆ qˆ ) (5.7) Note that (1K 2 K ) (1L 1H ) (2 L 2 H ) or (1L 2 L ) (1H 2 H ) since ij 1. j Activity 1 involves unskilled labor => (1L 2 L ) 0 . The importance of this is that it shows that a decrease in the relative price of the unskilled labor intensive import 1 ( pˆ1 pˆ 2 ) 0 leads to a decrease in the relative wage of unskilled labor in the domestic country ( wˆ qˆ ) 0 ( wˆ qˆ ) ( pˆ1 pˆ 2 ) (1L 2 L ) (5.8) In summary, a drop in the price of the imported unskilled labor intensive input 1 leads to a fall in the relative wage of unskilled labor or ( w / q) . What happens to the price of the final product pn ? Define pn cn ( p1, p2 ) = unit cost that is the dual of the production function yn f n ( y1, y2 ) . The change in the final good price is a weighted average of the input prices pˆ n n1 pˆ1 n 2 pˆ 2 (5.9) 42 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 ( pˆ1 pˆ 2 ) 0 pˆ1 pˆ n pˆ 2 or ( pˆ n pˆ1 ) 0 . We have shown that the relative price of the final product rises relative to the price of the imported input. In the US in the 1980's domestic prices rose faster than import prices. Note we are comparing import and domestic prices within an industry. While the relative wage of unskilled workers falls in both countries, their real wages need not fall. Estimation setup Since (5.4) is linear homogeneous it can be written as (5.10) pnGn ( Ln , H n , Kn , 1, p / pn ) A measure of real value-added including real net exports becomes Yn Gn ( Ln , H n , Kn , 1, p / pn ) (5.11) Given that the capital stock and output are fixed in the short run, we define a short-run cost function Cn ( w, q, K n , Yn , p / pn ) min Ln , H n wLn qH n s.t.(5.11) (5.12) Note than any structural variables that shift the production function and affect costs should be included. In the empirical implementation imported intermediate inputs will be measured by expenditure on imported inputs for each industry. Structural variables in industry n will be denoted as zn . Feenstra uses the translog production function M ln C 0 i ln wi i 1 K k 1 k ln xk 1 K K k l ln xk ln xl 2 k 1 l 1 M 1 M M ij ln wi ln w j 2 i1 j 1 (5.13) K i 1 k 1 ik ln wi ln xk k 1, , K = inputs/shift parameters. wi = optimally chosen inputs for i 1, , M , xk There are two optimally chosen inputs, skilled and unskilled labor. The objective is to calculate the effect on the percent change in costs if the price of one labor input changes. ln C C wi ln wi wi C (5.14) 43 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Differentiating (5.13) with respect to ln wi produces a short run model which was estimated in Feenstra 4.4 M K j 1 k 1 si i i j ln w j i k ln xk i 1, (5.15) ,M Feenstra imposed symmetry i j j i and the requirement that (5.13) was homogenious of degree one in wages which implied M M M i 1 i 1 i 1 i 1, i j i k 0 . Assume a cross section of countries. Equation (5.15) can be estimated over time, for a single year or for the change between two years. Feenstra used this latter approach for the years 1979 and 1990. This approach assumed the same cost function applied across the industries. Feenstra also made the usual assumption of dropping the wage terms to estimate a wage share of skilled labor SnH 0 k ln Kn ln Yn z 'zn n 1, ,N (5.16) in table 4.4. Note the relatively low R 2 terms. This model was estimated with Stata which uses the weighted regression coefficients on the raw data in a manner that is not used in Rats. In Table 4.4 Feenstra For more details see the assignment sheet. Example Code and results from B34S, Rats and Stata: /; /; Uses Align to insure 447 obs /; b34sexec options ginclude('Feenstra_ch4.mac') member(table4_4A); b34srun; /; b34sexec data set dropmiss; b34srun; b34sexec matrix; /; call loaddata; call get(chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh dofsh1 htsh_exp htsh_exa ci dhtsh ); big= 'chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh dofsh1 htsh_exp htsh_exa ci dhtsh'; call align(argument(big)); mod4_42=' chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp'; mod4_42=' chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp'; 44 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 mod4_43=' chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh1 htsh_exa'; mod4_44=' chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a ci dhtsh'; n=namelist(argument(big)); do i=1,10; call describe(argument(n(i)) :print); enddo; /; call tabulate(argument(mod4_42)); /; call tabulate(argument(mod4_43)); /; call tabulate(argument(mod4_44)); call olsq( argument(mod4_42) call gamfit( argument(mod4_42) call marspline(argument(mod4_42) call ppreg(argument(mod4_42) :print :white); :print ); :print); :print); call olsq( argument(mod4_43) call gamfit( argument(mod4_43) call marspline(argument(mod4_43) call ppreg(argument(mod4_43) :print :white); :print ); :print); :print); call olsq( argument(mod4_44) call gamfit( argument(mod4_44) call marspline(argument(mod4_44) call ppreg(argument(mod4_44) :print :white); :print ); :print); :print); b34srun; Note: If Feenstra_ch4.mac is on your computer, unless it is in c:\b34slm, do not use ginclude. Note: The Stata code [aw=share] weights the regression including the constant by multiplying buy sharei . What effect does this transformation have if the variables are not appropriate? Note that Rats and B34S and other software divide the right and left hand sides by 45 sharei . International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Example code from Problem _4_2.do set mem 300m log using log_4_2.log,replace use d:\feenstra_course\chap4\data_Chp4,clear * use /usr/local/lib/hhsfiles/data_Chp4,clear drop if year==1972|year==1987 drop if sic72==2067|sic72==2794|sic72==3483 egen wagebill=sum(pay), by(year) gen share=pay/wagebill sort sic72 year by sic72: gen lagshare=share[_n-1] gen ashare=(share+lagshare)/2 by sic72: gen lagnwsh=nwsh[_n-1] gen chanwsh=(nwsh-lagnwsh)*100/11 gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen gen wchanwsh=chanwsh*ashare wdlky=dlky*ashare wdly=dly*ashare wdsimat1a=dsimat1a*ashare wdsimat1b=dsimat1a*ashare diffout=dsimat1a-dsimat1b wdiffout=(dsimat1a-dsimat1b)*ashare wcosh_exp=dofsh*ashare htsh_exp=dhtsh-dofsh whtsh_exp=(dhtsh-dofsh)*ashare wcosh_exa=dofsh1*ashare htsh_exa=dhtsh1-dofsh1 whtsh_exa=(dhtsh1-dofsh1)*ashare wcosh=ci*ashare whtsh=dhtsh*ashare * Check with the first column of Table 4.4 * tabstat wchanwsh wdlky wdly wdsimat1a wcosh_exp whtsh_exp wcosh_exa whtsh_exa wcosh whtsh, stats(mean) tabstat chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp dofsh1 htsh_exa ci dhtsh, stats(mean) * Reproduce the rest of the columns in Table 4.4 * * replicates table 4.4 col 2 regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp [aw=ashare], cluster (sic2) * test ols regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh1 htsh_exa [aw=ashare], cluster (sic2) * test ols regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh1 htsh_exa regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a ci dhtsh [aw=ashare], cluster (sic2) * test ols regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a ci dhtsh * To instead distinguish narrow and other outsourcing, we can reproduce column (1) of table III in Feenstra and Hanson, 1999 * tabstat wchanwsh wdlky wdly wdsimat1b wdiffout wcosh_exp whtsh_exp wcosh_exa whtsh_exa wcosh whtsh, stats(sum) * Reproduce the rest of the columns in Table III * regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1b diffout dofsh htsh_exp [aw=ashare], cluster (sic2) 46 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1b diffout dofsh1 htsh_exa [aw=ashare], cluster (sic2) regress chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1b diffout ci dhtsh [aw=ashare], cluster (sic2) log close * clear exit Example Code to Test WLS with "junk" data. Test case shows how WLS can give "significant" but misleading answers. WLS is shown with Rats and Stata. Note that Stata uses a non standard weighting system. B34S first build a random left hands side varuiable and a randon right hand sicde variable and a random vector of "weights" to forma "junk" model. Next OLS and weignted least squares are run in three software systems. The results speak for themselves. /; /; B34S-Stata-Rats /; b34sexec matrix; * tests weighted regression ; * illustrates how weighted least squares can give "significance"; n=10000; k=4; y=rn(array(n:)); w=abs(rn(array(n:))); x=rn(array(n,k:)); /; /; OLS Model /; /; quick way to go to weighted least squares assuming /; vector or matrix input call olsq(y x :print :savex); ww=1./afam(sqrt(w)); %xnew=transpose(transpose(afam(%x))*ww); %ynew=afam(%y)*ww; call print('Weighted Least Squares':); call olsq(%ynew %xnew :noint :print); /; pass data to test WLS with Stata and Rats call dmfput(y,w :file 'file_1.dmf' :member file1 :comment 'y and w for weighted regression test' ); call dmfput(x :file 'file_2.dmf' :member file2 ); b34srun; /; /; test reading the save /; b34sexec data file('file_1.dmf') filef=fdmf dmfmember(file1) ; b34srun; b34sexec data file('file_2.dmf') filef=fdmf dmfmember(file2) ; b34srun; 47 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 /; /; Merge the two DMF files /; b34sexec merge file1('file_1.dmf') file2('file_2.dmf') file3('file_3.dmf') member1(file1) member2(file2) member3(file3) outfmt=formatted /; comment('Test of effect of Weighted Regression') ; b34srun; /; /; illustrate a read of a DMF into the matrix Command /; b34sexec matrix; call dmfget(:file 'file_3.dmf' :member file3 :print); b34srun; /; b34sexec data file('file_3.dmf') filef=fdmf; b34srun; /; /; This is the best way to go /; b34sexec options open('statdata.do') unit(28) disp=unknown$ b34srun$ b34sexec options clean(28)$ b34srun$ b34sexec options open('stata.do') unit(29) disp=unknown$ b34srun$ b34sexec options clean(29)$ b34srun$ b34sexec pgmcall idata=28 icntrl=29$ stata$ pgmcards$ // uncomment if do not use /e // log using stata.log, text // describe regress y m1* regress y m1* [aw=1/w] b34sreturn$ b34seend$ b34sexec options close(28); b34srun; b34sexec options close(29); b34srun; b34sexec options dodos('stata /e stata.do'); b34srun; b34sexec options npageout writeout('output from stata',' ',' ') copyfout('stata.log') dodos('erase stata.do','erase stata.log','erase statdata.do') $ b34srun$ /$ user places RATS commands between /$ PGMCARDS$ /$ note: user RATS commands here /$ B34SRETURN$ /$ b34sexec b34sexec b34sexec b34sexec options options options options open('rats.dat') unit(28) disp=unknown$ b34srun$ open('rats.in') unit(29) disp=unknown$ b34srun$ clean(28)$ b34srun$ clean(29)$ b34srun$ b34sexec pgmcall$ rats pcomments('* ', '* Data passed from B34S(r) system to RATS', '* ', "display @1 %dateandtime() @33 ' Rats Version ' %ratsversion()" '* ') $ PGMCARDS$ * 48 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 linreg y # constant m1col__1 m1col__2 m1col__3 m1col__4 linreg(spread=w) y # constant m1col__1 m1col__2 m1col__3 m1col__4 b34sreturn$ b34srun $ b34sexec options close(28)$ b34srun$ b34sexec options close(29)$ b34srun$ b34sexec options /$ dodos(' rats386 rats.in rats.out ') dodos('start /w /r rats32s rats.in /run') dounix('rats rats.in rats.out')$ B34SRUN$ b34sexec options npageout WRITEOUT('Output from RATS',' ',' ') COPYFOUT('rats.out') dodos('ERASE rats.in','ERASE rats.out','ERASE dounix('rm rats.in','rm rats.out','rm $ rats.dat') rats.dat') Results B34SI Matrix Command. d/m/y 15/ 8/10. h:m:s 21:18:32. => * TESTS WEIGHTED REGRESSION $ => * ILLUSTRATES HOW WEIGHTED LEAST SQUARES CAN GIVE "SIGNIFICANCE"$ => N=10000$ => K=4$ => Y=RN(ARRAY(N:))$ => W=ABS(RN(ARRAY(N:)))$ => X=RN(ARRAY(N,K:))$ => CALL OLSQ(Y X :PRINT :SAVEX)$ Results for the OLS Model of 10,000 observations on "junk" data. Ordinary Least Squares Estimation Dependent variable Centered R**2 Adjusted R**2 Residual Sum of Squares Residual Variance Standard Error Total Sum of Squares Log Likelihood Mean of the Dependent Variable Std. Error of Dependent Variable Sum Absolute Residuals F( 4, 9995) F Significance 1/Condition XPX Maximum Absolute Residual Number of Observations Variable Col____1 Col____2 Col____3 Col____4 CONSTANT => Lag 0 0 0 0 0 Coefficient -0.21613705E-01 0.99455008E-02 -0.25503089E-01 -0.83857056E-02 -0.11056801E-01 Y 1.283800318883199E-003 8.841139958492355E-004 10083.5816512905 1.00886259642727 1.00442152327958 10096.5435971802 -14231.0024774754 -1.106035532484140E-002 1.00486582947752 8006.64281307591 3.21201963864575 0.987921184267561 0.945609242214882 4.03166296169811 10000 SE 0.10089154E-01 0.10155609E-01 0.99336699E-02 0.10068969E-01 0.10044510E-01 t -2.1422713 0.97931108 -2.5673381 -0.83282667 -1.1007806 WW=1./AFAM(SQRT(W))$ 49 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 => %XNEW=TRANSPOSE(TRANSPOSE(AFAM(%X))*WW)$ => %YNEW=AFAM(%Y)*WW$ => CALL PRINT('Weighted Least Squares':)$ Weighted Least Squares Weighted Least Squares of above model that will be validated with Rats and Stata below. => CALL OLSQ(%YNEW %XNEW :NOINT :PRINT)$ Ordinary Least Squares Estimation Dependent variable Centered R**2 Adjusted R**2 Residual Sum of Squares Residual Variance Standard Error Total Sum of Squares Log Likelihood Mean of the Dependent Variable Std. Error of Dependent Variable Sum Absolute Residuals F( 4, 9995) F Significance 1/Condition XPX Maximum Absolute Residual Number of Observations Variable Col____1 Col____2 Col____3 Col____4 Col____5 Lag 0 0 0 0 0 Coefficient 0.13243375 0.32195210 0.31666619E-01 -0.15003716 0.60455770E-01 %YNEW 0.125430978105311 0.125080975495248 104592.075351771 10.4644397550546 3.23487863065287 119592.705359240 -25926.7988036037 -1.522589703452888E-002 3.45839075041880 14772.8577916210 358.371550665769 0.999999999999874 0.255815512089038 110.962446369039 10000 SE 0.98266760E-02 0.11437311E-01 0.95544411E-02 0.11766487E-01 0.97906901E-02 => => => => CALL DMFPUT(Y,W :FILE 'file_1.dmf' :MEMBER FILE1 :COMMENT 'y and w for weighted regression test' )$ => => => CALL DMFPUT(X :FILE 'file_2.dmf' :MEMBER FILE2 )$ t 13.476963 28.149282 3.3143350 -12.751228 6.1748221 B34S Matrix Command Ending. Last Command reached. Space available in allocator Number variables used Number temp variables used B34SI 8.11E Variable Y W CONSTANT (D:M:Y) # Cases 1 2 3 14856808, peak space used 49, peak number used 45, # user temp clean 15/ 8/10 (H:M:S) 21:18:32 Mean 10000 -0.1106035532E-01 10000 0.7897850809 10000 1.000000000 581397 51 0 DATA STEP Std Deviation 1.004865829 0.5970220007 0.000000000 Variable M1COL__1 M1COL__2 M1COL__3 M1COL__4 CONSTANT (D:M:Y) # Cases 1 2 3 4 5 15/ 8/10 (H:M:S) 21:18:33 Mean 10000 0.4888179470E-02 10000 0.2011437524E-03 10000 -0.2136661813E-02 10000 -0.5438502297E-02 10000 1.000000000 3.460313180 3.646702144 1.000000000 Std Deviation 0.9956528401 0.9891161269 1.011215800 0.9976399892 0.000000000 Maximum 0.9913245780 0.9783507125 1.022557394 0.9952855480 0.000000000 CALL DMFGET(:FILE 'file_3.dmf' :MEMBER FILE3 :PRINT)$ 50 1 PAGE 2 -4.001602802 0.3183224533E-04 1.000000000 Data from Matrix Command Variance B34SI Matrix Command. d/m/y 15/ 8/10. h:m:s 21:18:33. PAGE Minimum 1 DATA STEP Number of observations in data file 10000 Current missing variable code 1.000000000000000E+031 Data begins on (D:M:Y) 2: 1:1960 ends 2: 1:****. Frequency is => Maximum 1.009755335 0.3564352694 0.000000000 Number of observations in data file 10000 Current missing variable code 1.000000000000000E+031 Data begins on (D:M:Y) 2: 1:1960 ends 2: 1:****. Frequency is B34SI 8.11E Data from Matrix Command Variance 3.689869729 3.785540146 3.964659396 3.611193295 1.000000000 1 Minimum -3.764639466 -4.161275084 -3.849832359 -3.935043696 1.000000000 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 DMF File Name Member Created on date Time Number of series Number of observations Frequency File format is FORMATTED Base Date d/m/y Header Number of comments file_3.dmf FILE3 15/ 8/10 21:18:32 6 10000 1.00000000000000 2/ 1/1960 Data from Matrix Command 1 Comments: Series: Y W M1COL__1 M1COL__2 M1COL__3 M1COL__4 Type 0 0 0 0 0 0 Label: B34S Matrix Command Ending. Last Command reached. Space available in allocator Number variables used Number temp variables used B34SI 8.11E Variable Y W M1COL__1 M1COL__2 M1COL__3 M1COL__4 CONSTANT (D:M:Y) # Cases 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 14856979, peak space used 14, peak number used 7, # user temp clean 15/ 8/10 (H:M:S) 21:18:34 Mean DATA STEP Std Deviation 10000 -0.1106035532E-01 10000 0.7897850809 10000 0.4888179470E-02 10000 0.2011437524E-03 10000 -0.2136661813E-02 10000 -0.5438502297E-02 10000 1.000000000 100370 14 0 1.004865829 0.5970220007 0.9956528401 0.9891161269 1.011215800 0.9976399892 0.000000000 Data from Matrix Command Variance 1.009755335 0.3564352694 0.9913245780 0.9783507125 1.022557394 0.9952855480 0.000000000 Number of observations in data file 10000 Current missing variable code 1.000000000000000E+031 Data begins on (D:M:Y) 2: 1:1960 ends 2: 1:****. Frequency is output from stata ___ ____ ____ ____ ____ (R) /__ / ____/ / ____/ ___/ / /___/ / /___/ 11.1 Statistics/Data Analysis Maximum 3.460313180 3.646702144 3.689869729 3.785540146 3.964659396 3.611193295 1.000000000 1 Copyright 2009 StataCorp LP StataCorp 4905 Lakeway Drive College Station, Texas 77845 USA 800-STATA-PC http://www.stata.com 979-696-4600 stata@stata.com 979-696-4601 (fax) Single-user Stata perpetual license: Serial number: 30110535901 Licensed to: Houston H. Stokes University of Illinois at Chicago Notes: 1. 2. (/m# option or -set memory-) 120.00 MB allocated to data Stata running in batch mode . do stata.do . * File built by B34S . run statdata.do on 15/ 8/10 at 21:18:34 Stata validates the B34S results. Note command setup. . regress y m1* Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 12.9619459 4 3.24048647 Residual | 10083.5817 9995 1.0088626 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 10096.5436 9999 1.00975534 Number of obs F( 4, 9995) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 10000 3.21 0.0121 0.0013 0.0009 1.0044 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------y | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------m1col__1 | -.0216137 .0100892 -2.14 0.032 -.0413905 -.0018369 51 Minimum -4.001602802 0.3183224533E-04 -3.764639466 -4.161275084 -3.849832359 -3.935043696 1.000000000 PAGE 3 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 m1col__2 | .0099455 .0101556 0.98 0.327 -.0099615 .0298525 m1col__3 | -.0255031 .0099337 -2.57 0.010 -.0449751 -.0060311 m1col__4 | -.0083857 .010069 -0.83 0.405 -.0281229 .0113515 _cons | -.0110568 .0100445 -1.10 0.271 -.0307461 .0086325 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------. regress y m1* [aw=1/w] (sum of wgt is 1.3529e+05) Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 866.267364 4 216.566841 Residual | 7730.9091 9995 .773477649 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 8597.17646 9999 .859803627 Number of obs F( 4, 9995) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared = = = = = 10000 279.99 0.0000 0.1008 0.1004 Root MSE = .87948 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------y | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------m1col__1 | .1324338 .0098267 13.48 0.000 .1131715 .151696 m1col__2 | .3219521 .0114373 28.15 0.000 .2995327 .3443715 m1col__3 | .0316666 .0095544 3.31 0.001 .012938 .0503952 m1col__4 | -.1500372 .0117665 -12.75 0.000 -.1731018 -.1269725 _cons | .0604558 .0097907 6.17 0.000 .041264 .0796475 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------. end of do-file 52 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Output from RATS Rats used to validate B34S and Stata results. * * Data passed from B34S(r) system to RATS * display @1 %dateandtime() @33 ' Rats Version ' %ratsversion() 08/15/2010 21:18 Rats Version 7.30000 * CALENDAR(IRREGULAR) ALLOCATE 10000 OPEN DATA rats.dat DATA(FORMAT=FREE,ORG=OBS, $ MISSING= 0.1000000000000000E+32 ) / $ Y $ W $ M1COL__1 $ M1COL__2 $ M1COL__3 $ M1COL__4 $ CONSTANT SET TREND = T TABLE Series Obs Mean Std Error Minimum Y 10000 -0.011060 1.004866 -4.001603 W 10000 0.789785 0.597022 0.000032 M1COL__1 10000 0.004888 0.995653 -3.764639 M1COL__2 10000 0.000201 0.989116 -4.161275 M1COL__3 10000 -0.002137 1.011216 -3.849832 M1COL__4 10000 -0.005439 0.997640 -3.935044 TREND 10000 5000.500000 2886.895680 1.000000 Maximum 3.460313 3.646702 3.689870 3.785540 3.964659 3.611193 10000.000000 * linreg y # constant m1col__1 m1col__2 m1col__3 m1col__4 Linear Regression - Estimation by Least Squares Dependent Variable Y Usable Observations 10000 Degrees of Freedom 9995 Centered R**2 0.001284 R Bar **2 0.000884 Uncentered R**2 0.001405 T x R**2 14.048 Mean of Dependent Variable -0.011060355 Std Error of Dependent Variable 1.004865829 Standard Error of Estimate 1.004421523 Sum of Squared Residuals 10083.581651 Regression F(4,9995) 3.2120 Significance Level of F 0.01207882 Log Likelihood -14231.00248 Durbin-Watson Statistic 1.980979 Variable Coeff Std Error T-Stat Signif ******************************************************************************** 1. Constant -0.011056801 0.010044510 -1.10078 0.27101868 2. M1COL__1 -0.021613705 0.010089154 -2.14227 0.03219575 3. M1COL__2 0.009945501 0.010155609 0.97931 0.32745000 4. M1COL__3 -0.025503089 0.009933670 -2.56734 0.01026268 5. M1COL__4 -0.008385706 0.010068969 -0.83283 0.40496239 linreg(spread=w) y # constant m1col__1 m1col__2 m1col__3 m1col__4 Linear Regression - Estimation by Weighted Least Squares Dependent Variable Y Usable Observations 10000 Degrees of Freedom 9995 Centered R**2 0.125431 R Bar **2 0.125081 Uncentered R**2 0.125448 T x R**2 1254.479 Mean of Dependent Variable -0.015225897 Std Error of Dependent Variable 3.458390750 Standard Error of Estimate 3.234878631 Sum of Squared Residuals 104592.07535 Log Likelihood -22690.72492 Durbin-Watson Statistic 1.952328 Variable Coeff Std Error T-Stat Signif ******************************************************************************** 1. Constant 0.060455770 0.009790690 6.17482 0.00000000 2. M1COL__1 0.132433752 0.009826676 13.47696 0.00000000 3. M1COL__2 0.321952098 0.011437311 28.14928 0.00000000 4. M1COL__3 0.031666619 0.009554441 3.31434 0.00092188 5. M1COL__4 -0.150037162 0.011766487 -12.75123 0.00000000 B34S normal exit on Date (D:M:Y) 15/ 8/10 at Time (H:M:S) 21:18:40Results: 53 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Note e ' e values reported for B34S and Rats agree. Stata made an "adjustment." 54 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Code for Leverage Plots with OLS, GAM and Marspline /; /; Uses Align to insure 447 obs /; b34sexec options include('d:\feenstra_course\chap4\Feenstra_ch4.mac') member(table4_4A); b34srun; b34sexec matrix; call echooff; call get(chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh dofsh1 htsh_exp htsh_exa ci dhtsh ); big= 'chanwsh dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh dofsh1 htsh_exp htsh_exa ci dhtsh'; call align(argument(big)); mod4_42=' mod4_42=' mod4_43=' mod4_44=' chanwsh chanwsh chanwsh chanwsh dlky dlky dlky dlky dly dly dly dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp'; dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp'; dsimat1a dofsh1 htsh_exa'; dsimat1a ci dhtsh'; n=namelist(argument(big)); datamean=1; dopass1=1; dopass2=0; if(datamean.ne.0)then; do i=1,10; call describe(argument(n(i)) :print); enddo; endif; if(dopass1.ne.0)then; call load(contrib); call contribi; /; /; specific settings /; do_ppexp=0; _m=8; iols=2; /; _mi=1; _mi=2; _nk=40; /; ppreg code _m=30; iols=2; /; iols=4; isave=1; /; rf code _mtry=2; _mtree=200; call call call call call character(fsv_info,'1. Model 1'); character(l_hand_s,'chanwsh'); character(_args, 'dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp'); character(_argsg,'dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp'); contribl; 55 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 call contribd; endif; /; call tabulate(argument(mod4_42)); /; call tabulate(argument(mod4_43)); /; call tabulate(argument(mod4_44)); if(dopass2.ne.0)then; call olsq( chanwsh call gamfit( chanwsh call marspline(chanwsh call ppreg(chanwsh argument(mod4_42) argument(mod4_42) argument(mod4_42) argument(mod4_42) :print :white); :print ); :print :mi 3 :nk 20); :print); call olsq( chanwsh call gamfit( chanwsh call marspline(chanwsh call ppreg(chanwsh argument(mod4_43) argument(mod4_43) argument(mod4_43) argument(mod4_43) :print :white); :print ); :print :mi 3 :nk 20); :print); call olsq( chanwsh call gamfit( chanwsh call marspline(chanwsh call ppreg(chanwsh endif; argument(mod4_44) argument(mod4_44) argument(mod4_44) argument(mod4_44) :print :white); :print ); :print :mi 3 :nk 20); :print); b34srun; Edited output from Leverage Plots Settings for Leverage plots Mars Models Number of knots for MARS (_knots) Number of interactions (_mi) Max span between each knot (_ms=0) C_rows / r_rows print setting Plot setting 16 2 0 0 2 GAM Models Degree of Polynomial for forecasts (degmod) Default degree of GAM model (_gdf) 6 2.000000000000000 PPREG Models Number of trees 30 (_m) Exploratory Projection Pursuit turned off OLS, GAM and MARS plotted Plots produced in WMF form Data saved in SCA fsv format (do_ppexp=0) (iols=2) (ihp=0) (isave=1) Leverage effect of target variable (iversion=1) Grids placed on graphs (igrid=1) Show graphs (ishow=1) Data to write in fsv file (fsv_info) 1. Model 1 Left hand side variable Right hand side variables _ARGS = dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp _ARGSG = dlky dly dsimat1a dofsh htsh_exp GAM right hand side variables (l_hand_s) chanwsh (_args) (_argsg) Ordinary Least Squares Estimation using QR Method Dependent variable CHANWSH Centered R**2 4.663004197990550E-02 Adjusted R**2 3.582085878239876E-02 Residual Sum of Squares 99.69274477778127 Residual Variance 0.2260606457546060 Standard Error 0.4754583533335028 Total Sum of Squares 104.5687919355227 Log Likelihood -298.9114424425495 Mean of the Dependent Variable 0.3772410371879195 Std. Error of Dependent Variable 0.4842098457728058 Sum Absolute Residuals 154.2697623492203 F( 5, 441) 4.313928363306974 F Significance 0.9992344947238444 56 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 QR Rank Check variable (eps) set as Maximum Absolute Residual Number of Observations 2.220446049250313E-16 2.423346113505557 447 -2 * ln(Maximum of Likelihood Function) Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) Scwartz Information Criterion (SIC) Akaike (1970) Finite Prediction Error Generalized Cross Validation Hannan & Quinn (1979) HQ Shibata (1981) Rice (1984) Variable DLKY DLY DSIMAT1A DOFSH HTSH_EXP CONSTANT Lag 0 0 0 0 0 0 Coefficient 0.19461621E-01 0.16346747E-02 0.85486338E-01 0.17738186 -0.63894988E-02 0.30441686 597.8228848850989 611.8228848850989 640.5407950473939 0.2290950168385605 0.2291363007988864 0.2341227407534938 0.2290135572121456 0.2291787236270834 SE 0.10929047E-01 0.87081211E-02 0.40337870E-01 0.78035999E-01 0.10346851 0.34539594E-01 t 1.7807244 0.18771841 2.1192576 2.2730773 -0.61753074E-01 8.8135623 Using MARS note the number of time any knot figures. Also compare e ' e values/ Multivariate Autoregressive Splines Analysis Model Estimated using Hastie-Tibshirani GPL routines in CRAN General Public License (GPL) Library. Version - 1 March 2006. Left Hand Side Variable Penalty cost per degree of freedom Threshold for Forward stepwise Stopping Rank Test Tolerance Max # of Knots (nk) Max interaction (mi) Number of Observations Number of right hand Variables tolbx set as stopfac gcv/gcvnull > stopfac => stop prevcrit set as CHANWSH 3.000 0.1000E-03 0.1000E-12 16 2 447 5 1.000000000000000E-09 10.00000000000000 10000000000.00000 Series Lag DLKY 0 DLY 0 DSIMAT1A 0 DOFSH 0 HTSH_EXP 0 Min -13.03 -13.96 -3.900 -0.3634 -0.8415E-01 Mean 0.5129 0.3948 0.3653 0.1801 0.1540 Max 14.73 22.53 2.970 0.8314 0.9744 GCV with only the constant Total sum of squares Final gcv Variance of Y Variable R**2 (1 - (var(res)/var(y))) Residual Sum of Squares Residual Variance Residual Standard Error Sum Absolute Residuals Max Absolute Residual # of coefficients after last fwd step 0.2349848679602379 104.5687919355228 0.2243541985438403 0.2344591747433244 9.800778114759146E-02 94.32023666063806 0.2114803512570358 0.4598699286287763 151.8419819292555 2.356771963985708 6 MARS Model Coefficients CHANWSH = + 0.11234242 + 0.33196963 + 0.16270845 -0.70342093 + 0.19893933 SE 0.22430248 * max( DLKY{ 0} * max( DOFSH{ 0} * max(DSIMAT1A{ 0} * max( DLKY{ 0} * max( -0.47806446E-01 * max( 5.1820626 * max( -0.47806446E-01 - 5.1592455 , -0.47806446E-01, 0.20999895 , -0.38131475E-01, DOFSH{ 0} , DLY{ 0} , DOFSH{ 0} , 0.0) 0.0) 0.0) 0.0) 0.0) 0.0) 0.0) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 _GCV 0.2308 0.2306 0.2320 0.2345 0.2355 0.2373 0.2394 _RSS 100.4 98.08 96.41 95.22 93.38 91.87 90.47 _KNOT _VAR 5.159 DLKY -0.4781E-01 DOFSH 0.2100 DSIMAT1A -0.3813E-01 DLKY 5.182 DLY -7.413 DLY 3.993 DLY Importance # 100.000 5.145 74.273 64.206 8.725 99.886 100.000 74.278 82.687 1 2 3 4 5 0.64517991E-01 3.08 87 19.463 80.530 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Generalized Additive Models (GAM) Analysis Reference: Generalized Additive Models by Hastie and Tibshirani. Chapman (1990) Model estimated using CRAN General Public License (GPL) routines. 57 % 447 23 332 287 39 _LAG Gaussian additive model assumed Identity link - yhat = x*b + sum(splines) Non Zero 6.18 3.82 3.82 2.84 -3.16 Analysis of GCV, RSS and KNOT by Variable before prune step Obs t 0.36260299E-01 0.29373323E-01 0.86699033E-01 0.57208979E-01 0.22217457 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Response variable .... Number of observations: Residual Sum of Squares # iterations # smooths/variable Mean Squared Residual df of deviance Scale Estimate Primary tolerence Secondary tolerance R square Total sum of Squares Model df -----------1. 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 ----11.0 coef ---0.307945 0.182242E-01 0.759133E-03 0.742341E-01 0.195753 -.177332E-01 CHANWSH 447 96.78912935189766 1 12 0.2165304907201290 435.9990210388421 0.2219939143929292 1.000000000000000E-09 1.000000000000000E-09 7.439755628449879E-02 104.5687919355228 st err z score -----------0.3423E-01 8.997 0.1083E-01 1.683 0.8629E-02 0.8797E-01 0.3997E-01 1.857 0.7733E-01 2.531 0.1025 -.1729 nl pval ------- lin_res ------- 0.7998 0.5792 0.7106 0.6579 0.7457 97.50 97.17 97.34 97.27 97.40 Name ---intcpt DLKY DLY DSIMAT1A DOFSH HTSH_EXP Lag --0 0 0 0 0 Projection Pursuit Regression Number of Observations Number of right hand side variables Maximum number of trees Minimum number of trees Number of left hand side variables Level of fit Max number of Primary Iterations (maxit) Max number of Secondary Iterations (mitone) Number of cj Iterations (mitcj) Smoother tone control (alpha) Span Convergence (CONV) set as Left Hand Side Variable Series CHANWSH Mean 0.3772 Max 2.972 447 6 30 30 1 2 200 200 10 0.000000000000000E+00 0.000000000000000E+00 5.000000000000000E-03 CHANWSH Min -1.184 Right Hand Side Variables # 1 2 3 4 5 6 Series DLKY DLY DSIMAT1A DOFSH HTSH_EXP CONSTANT Lag 0 0 0 0 0 0 Mean 0.5129 0.3948 0.3653 0.1801 0.1540 1.000 Max 14.73 22.53 2.970 0.8314 0.9744 1.000 Min -13.03 -13.96 -3.900 -0.3634 -0.8415E-01 1.000 Given # of trees # primary iterations used # secondary iterations used # cj iterations used Residual sum of squares Total sum of squares Mean of the Dependent Variable Std. Error of Dependent Variable Sum Absolute Residuals Maximum Absolute Residual Residual Variance 30 2 3 2 45.74746740785981 104.5687919355227 0.3772410371879195 0.4842098457728058 102.4741977233084 1.592191521771080 0.1037357537593193 Variable Importance for Model with # Trees Series Number Importance 1 1.00000 2 0.582809 3 0.547460 5 0.397385 4 0.343518 6 0.00000 30 For Random Forest method note effect on e ' e of bagging and averaging. Note mtry was set as 2! Random Forest Analysis Ver. 3.1 - 30 May 2009 build Regression option selected. Number of Observations 447 Number of right hand side variables 5 Maximum number of trees (maxtree) 200 Maximum number of nodes (nrnodes) 179 Number of Variables to select at each node (mtry) 2 Minimum node size (ndsize) 5 Left Hand Side Variable CHANWSH Series Mean Max Min 58 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 CHANWSH 0.3772 2.972 -1.184 Right Hand Side Variables # 1 2 3 4 5 Series Lag DLKY 0 DLY 0 DSIMAT1A 0 DOFSH 0 HTSH_EXP 0 Mean 0.5129 0.3948 0.3653 0.1801 0.1540 Max 14.73 22.53 2.970 0.8314 0.9744 Total Sum of Squares Sum of Squared Residuals for last bagged model Sum of Squared Residuals for averaged OOB model Sum of Squared Residuals for averaged model Centered R**2 for %YHAT Centered R**2 for %YHAT2 Centered R**2 for %YHAT3 Min -13.03 -13.96 -3.900 -0.3634 -0.8415E-01 104.5687919355227 85.36903992005276 111.6020632996678 39.00181645337509 0.1836088154036296 -6.725975536259265E-02 0.6270224057152378 Importance Analysis For details see Hastie-Tibshirani-Friedman (2009, 594) Variable importance based on Randomization 1 0.0000000 2 0.0000000 3 0.0000000 4 0.0000000 5 0.0000000 Variable importance based on Gini 1 4268.8911 2 3955.2716 3 4179.0395 4 1710.9527 5 1407.7635 Selected Leverage Plots. It appears that there are thresholds. Only select graphs are shown. 59 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Prediction L everage of D L K Y [ lag= 0 , i nt= 2, o=M edians] 1.4 1.2 Contribution 1 M A R S Y H A T .8 .6 .4 .2 -10 -5 0 DLK Y 60 5 10 15 O L S _ Y H A T G A M _ Y H A T International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Prediction L everage of D L Y [ lag= 0 , int= 2, o=M edians] .44 .42 Contribution .40 M A R S Y H A T .38 .36 .34 O L S _ Y H A T G A M _ Y H A T .32 .30 -15 -10 -5 0 5 DLY 10 15 20 Table 4.5 represents another approach that assumes a long run cost function where both types of labor and capital are jointly solved from Cn ( wn , qn , rn , Yn , p / pn ) min Ln , H n , K n wn Ln qn H n rn K n s.t. (5.11) (5.17) Here factor prices differ across industries. (5.17) is linearly homogeneous in inputs and can be written as Cn (wn , qn , rn , Yn , zn ) Yn cn ( wn , qn , rn , zn ) (5.18) Where we replaced ( p / pn ) by zn that includes other structural variables. Note that cn ( wn , qn , rn , zn ) is the unit cost function and pn cn (wn , qn , rn , zn ), n 1, ,N (5.19) 61 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 (5.19) shows that both product prices and structural change ( zn ) can affect factor prices. Taking the difference between the log change in factor and product prices and noting that the cost shares sum to 1.0, total factor productivity is TFPn (nL ln wn nH ln qn nK ln rn ) ln pn (5.20) Which can be used to form the estimating equation ln pn TFPn nL ln wn nH ln qn nK ln rn n 1, ,N (5.21) If the data are factor shares nj then the implied change in factor prices L , H , K can be estimated from ln pn TFPn nL L nH H nK K n 1, ,N (5.22) Which has been used in Table 4.5. L , H , K can be interpreted as the change in factor prices that are mandated by the change in product prices. A code template for further investigation of this issue is Code Template for Estimation of a Long Run Model b34sexec options include('Feenstra_ch4.mac') member(ch4_3_a); b34srun; b34sexec matrix; call loaddata; call olsq( dlp34 ptfp apsh ansh aksh :print :white); call gamfit( dlp34 ptfp apsh ansh aksh :print ); call marspline(dlp34 ptfp apsh ansh aksh :print); call ppreg(dlp34 ptfp apsh ansh aksh :print); b34srun; 62 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 6. Extensions to H-O model suggested by Vanek (Math treatment by Feenstra) Assume C countries ( i 1, , C ) , N industries ( j 1, , N ) and M factors indexed by (k 1, , M ) or l 1, , M ) . Define A [a j k ]' the requirements of labor and capital to produce one unit of good j using input k. Assuming the 2 by 2 case with Labor L and capital K a1L a2 L A Matrix A includes both direct primary factors A used in production and indirect a1K a2 K factors used through intermediate production. Remark: [In input-output analysis: Define B as the N by N input-output matrix. Define d j = final demand in industry j and x j = production of good j. Total production needs to take into account N final demand and intermediate demand. x j a ji xi d j or i 1 d j (1 a jj ) x j N a i 1 i j x . (6.1) ji i Define B such that ( I B ) x d . Final production of goods x ( I B) 1 d . In terms of the primary and indirect factors, A A( I B)1 ] Define Y i = outputs of the N industries in country i, Di = demands for N industries in country i and T i Y i Di net exports. (Can think of Di as absorption). Remark: [ S. Alexander (See Dunn-Mutti page 400) argued that if Y i Di it was not possible to export. Other writers have stressed the fact that it was important to determine if the economy was at full employment or not. If an economy is at full employment then the only way to increase exports is to reduce absorption.] Factor content of trade is F i AT i . Define an individual component of F i as Fki . where >0 (<0) determines if the k factor is exported (imported). Goal of HOV theory is to relate factor content of trade in country i to the underlying factor endowments. 63 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 AY i V i = demand for factors in country i. ADi demand for factors in country i that are consumed domestically. Assuming product prices are equalized across countries => consumption vectors are proportional => can simplify the analysis. Define s i =share of country i. D i s i D w , AD i si AD w . If trade is balanced, s i = country i's share of world GDP. Given world consumption = world production, AD i s i AD w s i AY w s iV w . (6.2) This proves the HOV theorem relating to the factor content of trade F i . Recall V i = total demand for factors in country i. If F i 0 this implies that factor content of trade greater than countries consumption share times total world factor demand. F i AT i V i s iV w (6.3) for the kth factor. Equation (6.3) is the basic HOV theorem. Equations (6.19) and (6.25) extend the HOV model by allowing for factor productivity differences in the A matrix across countries. Fki Vki ski Vkw (6.4) A country i is abundant in factor k if Vki si Vkw (6.5) Looking at two elements of the factor content of trade vector Fki K i si K w (6.6) FLi Li si LW K w ( K i Fki ) / si (6.7) Lw ( Li Fl i ) / s i which can be transformed to 64 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Ki si K i K w ( K i Fki ) Li s i Li Lk ( Li Fl i ) Ki Li K w Lw (6.8) Ki Li ( K i Fki ) ( Li Fl i ) Define capital to be abundant relative to labor if ( K i / K w ) ( Li / Lw ) (6.9) which simplifies to the Leamer (1980) Theorem "If capital is abundant relative to labor in country i then the HOV theorem for all inputs is F i AT i V i siV w (6.10) and for the k th input Fki Vki ski Vkw (6.11) Leamer's 1980 theorem states that if capital is abundant relative to labor in country i, then Ki Li K w Lw (6.12) or Ki Kw w Li L (6.13) From (6.7) and (6.13) we have proved that the capital/labor ratio embodied in production for country i exceeds the capital/labor ratio embodied in consumption" if country i is capital abundant. ( K i / Li ) [( K i Fki ) / ( Li FLi )] (6.14) Strict equality holds if there is no trade and FKi FLi 0 . Feenstra page 40 reports that (6.14) 65 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 holds for the US in 1947. => No Leontief paradox! The Leamer theorem does not require balanced trade! To fully test the Leontief paradox requires data on T i , A, V i and V w . If the number of factors equals the number of goods we can estimate net exports as T i A1 (V i s iV w ) (6.15) taking A1 from (6.3) as data. The estimated coefficients should estimate the relative abundance of each factor (V i s iV w ) . (Note: This is the usual OLS model Y=XB where X A1 ) If the number of goods is greater than the number of factors, we can estimate T i (adjusted net exports of each industry) as a function of A' (their labor and capital requirements). T i A' (6.16) ˆ ( AA ') 1 AT i ( AA ') 1 (V i s iV w ) (6.17) Feenstra (2004, 43) and others have argued that this less than optimum formulation gives a "contaminated estimate" of the vector of relative factor endowments that could be less than zero. Leamer using an alternative approach treated (V i s iV w ) as data and using data for all C countries estimated M T ji jk (Vki s iVkw ) i 1, C (6.18) k 1 which is not a test of Leontief. For details on this and other possible approaches, see Freenstra (2004, 44-60). In an important extension Trefler (1993) assumed different productivity of factors across countries. Let ki represent the relative productivity of i th country for the k th factor relative to the US. Looking at all countries, equation (6.4) becomes 66 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 C Fki kiVki si kjVk j , i 1, , C; k 1, , M (6.19) j 1 which restates the HOV theory in equation (6.3). There are MC equations but since both sides sum to 0.0, we drop one country and solve for M(C-1) parameters using an inverse. Equation (6.19) holds as an identity. Given the assumptions of the model, it is thus not testable. Of interest is whether the assumptions are warranted. One way to proceed is to see if the solutions generated by the inverse are all greater than 0.0. Any value < 0.0 is not reasonable. Another way to proceed is to assume factor price equalization and see if the estimated relative labor productivity ki follows relative wage differences across countries. The empirical results for this hypothesis for the factor labor are given in figure 2.4 on page 51 of Feenstra and tend to support Trefler (1993). Research Ideas: It would be interesting to generate figure 2.4 for other factors and see what countries are off the line. Figure 2.4 suggests that relative wages in Canada are above what Canadian labor productivity would imply. Hong Kong, Finland, France etc being below the line are more productive in labor than their relative wages. Another research question might be to look at trends over time. Trefler (1995) approached the same general problem using a method involving differences in the factor requirements matrix Ai across countries. One simplifying assumption is to assume a uniform amount change across countries defined as i . In his 1993 paper defined ki to resent the relative productivity of i th country for the k th factor relative to the US. In the 1995 papew if i 1 then the i th country is less technologically advanced than the US. In terms of the US technology matrix i Ai AUS (6.20) Starting from the factor requirement equation for total production in country i AiY i V i (6.21) we define factors needed for trade. C AiT i AiY i Ai Di V i Ai ( si D w ) V i Ai si Y j j 1 67 (6.22) International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Using (6.20) we multiply both sides of (6.22) by i to express the factor content of trade of the i th country in terms of US factor requirements matrix. C i AiT i AUST i F iUS iV i i Ai si Y j (6.23) j 1 Looking at all countries we note C A US j 1 C C j 1 j 1 Y j j A jY j jV j (6.24) which allows simplification of the last term in (6.23). Equation (6.23) can now be written as C i AiT i AUST i F iUS iV i si jV j . (6.25). j 1 Equation (6.25) is a restatement of the HOV theorem when we allow for uniform technological differences across countries. Equation (6.25) needs to be estimated to get the best i values. Trefler's results are given in Table 2.5. Significance can be measured for each estimate. The estimates i themselves are of interest. Summary of Selected Factor Content Research: Equation (6.3) is the HOV Model assuming no productivity parameters Equation (6.19) allows individual country individual factor productivity adjustments. Equation (6.25) imposes a country-wide adjustment to all the elements of the A matrix for a specific country. Trefler (1998) looked at bilateral trade. He assumed that output of every good is exported to each country in proportion to the purchasing country's GDP. Define X i j as gross exports of goods from country i to country j . This is related to net exports Ti 68 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 T i X i j X ji i j (6.26) i j The bilaterial export assumption ( s j GDP j / GDP w Y j / Y w ) implies X i j s jY i (6.27) Define F i j as the factor content of exports from country i to country j . F i j Ai X i j (6.28) Using (6.21) equation (6.27) becomes F i j s j AiY i s jV i (6.29) which can be transformed to relative endowments of country i V i si V j (1 si )V i si V j V i s j si V j j i j j i (6.30) j i From equation (6.31) we prove the Trefler (1998) theorem that is an identity if the assumptions of the derivation are correct. V i si V j F i j F ji j j i (6.31) j i The left term is the relative factor endowments. On the right the first term is the factor content for trade from country i to all countries. The second term on the right is the factor content from country of imports for all countries to country i . Feenstra contains a number of other tests on trade which are not treated here due to time limitations. It appears although the data fails the rigid assumptions of same tastes and same production 69 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 conditions of the H-O model, that with adjustments the theory can be made to work. If the number of goods equals the number of factors, it is possible to have factor price equalization. If the number of factors is > number of goods factor price equalization does not hold! If the number of factors is < number of goods "there is a wide range of possible factor endowments across countries such that factor prices equalization continues to hold, provided that technologies are the same across countries. However the amount of production occurring in each country is indeterminate when factor prices are equalized." Many concerns remain. One key issue is that the H-O theory was developed to explain trade in final goods not intermediate goods. With "outsourcing" increasing, this assumption is not realistic. Outsourcing is usually implemented as a means by which labor intensive intensive can be produced. Econometrically a drop in the price of imported intermediate goods implies effects that are observationally equivalent to the effect of skill-based technological change. 70 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 7. H-O Theory, increasing returns and the Gravity Model. Figure 5B shows specialization in right and wrong direction with increasing returns. While the H-O theory suggested that factor endowments drove trade between countries, the majority of trade currently is between similar countries. Krugman attempted to explain this finding by investigating the effects of assuming monopolistic competition and increasing returns. - Monopolistic competition assumes that each firm sets MC=MR where the MR curve is downwardly sloped and firms enter an industry if profits are positive. It is assumed that at equilibrium P=AR=AC. Following Feenstra (2004 139) Assume labor is the only input, w is the equilibrium wage, w is the marginal cost and ci is the consumption of the i th good. Assume there are L consumers. We initially assume an additive symmetric utility function N v(ci ) v ' 0, v " 0 or U v (ci ) . Dropping subscripts, at equilibrium the supply of each good i 1 equals the demand or y Lc For the ith good y Lc Li yi (7.0) (7.1) AC wL / y w / y w TC w w y MC w (7.2) (7.3) (7.4) p AC p / w [a / ( Lc )] (7.5) 1 MR MC pi 1 w (7.6) p w ( 1) (7.7) Solving (7.5) and (7.7) for p / w and c c ( a a ) / ( L ) p/w ( ) / ( 1) (7.8) (7.9) Remark: (7.8) and (7.9) solve for the intersection point of the ZZ and PP curves. Equation (7.7) plots as the PP curve in Feenstra figure 5.2 or the figure below. PP is upward sloped and indicates that as demand increases resulting in c , then equilibrium ( p / w) from (7.9).Note that we have a downward sloped AC curve. In a graph with p on the y axis and q on the x axis an 71 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 p as we w move up the curve. Assume two identical countries start trading. This is like L* 2 L . From (7.8) we see that Equation (7.5) plots on the graphs as ZZ and is the firms average cost curve. outward shift in the demand curve implies everything else equal resulting in The next task is to determine the equilibrium number of firms N. N N i 1 i 1 L Li ( yi ) N ( y ) N ( Lc) N 1 [( / L) c) (7.10) (7.11) which is a function of the equilibrium consumption c which in turn depends on and . Graphical analysis of the model that shows how p/w and c are determined is shown below. Assume that di / dci 0 or that reduced consumption implies a movement up the demand curve and thus an increase in in most cases. This insures that the PP curve showing the locus of points that solves p / w ( / ( 1)) is upward sloped. Remember that 0 . If 1 then as it increases from 1.1 to 1.2 to 1.3 assuming = 1, p / w ( / ( 1)) decreases from (1.1/.1)=11, to (1.2/.2) =6 to (1.3/.3) = 4.333. The ZZ curve which is the firm's average cost curve is downward sloped and solves (6.5) or p / w / Lc . Increased consumption with increasing returns to scale implies that average cost will fall. Increasing the population L will shift ZZ to Z' Z' and result in a decrease in both p / w and c . In words, consumption of the ith good falls due to individuals spreading their expenditure over more goods. This lowers p / w . Equations (7.8) and (7.9) can provide insight into dynamics. Looking at (7.8) assume there is an increase in L. The initial effect is to lower p / w , but this is not an equilibrium value. The solution will involve a move down the PP curve and a fall in which from (7.9) will lower c, Notes for a future setup: In a later setup we will use a CES utility curve that makes a flat PP curve. Here as L we find that ci but p / w does not change. Using the Krugman assumptions the result of assuming two identical countries with increasing returns that are trading finds: 72 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 L implies ci . Number of firms N since for each country full employment requires L N ( y ) and economies of scale allow y to increase more than proportionally than the increase in L. This can be seen when we note that p / w implies that y as increased returns to scale kick in. In summary the increase in y as firms exploit economies of scale necessarily implies a reduction in the number of firms in each country. Think of it as the firms are capitalizing on the increased profits obtainable from the increasing returns to scale. It pays for them to specialize due to increased demand. => opening trade between countries indeed implies that firms must exit in each, while the remaining firms expand their output and take advantage of scale economies. Krugman's model makes two predictions concerning the impact of trade productivity of firms: The scale effect as surviving firms expand their outputs and the selection effect as some firms are forced to exit. The evidence is that the scale effect is not all that large. Increased USCanada trade had only a small effect on scale. It appears that the gains to scale were not all that big in the first place. The selection effect suggests that if the least efficient firms exit this will result in an increase in average industry productivity. (This is outside Krugman's model that did not allow for differences in productivity among firms to simplify the analysis.) The evidence is that productivity in Canada increased but that there was a small scale effect. Models have been suggested by Head-Reis (see Feenstra (2004 143)) to impose a model with no scale effect. Note "If the elasticity of demand for product varieties is constant then firm scale will not change at all due to tariffs or trade liberalization." To impose this restriction use a CES utility function: N U ci(( 1)/ ) . (7.12) i 1 The elasticity of substitution between products is equal to 1 which when N is large equals the elasticity of demand . In this model di / dci 0 which implies a flat PP curve and no scale effect. Another implication is that the markup of prices over marginal costs is fixed or pi w ( 1) (7.13) since limn . Equation (7.13) comes directly from a simple transformation of (7.7). This 73 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 can be seen by looking at the implications of a flat PP curve. In such a world the profit equation is y . 1 py w( y ) w (7.14) Equation (7.14) can be derived if we note: w py w(a y ) y w(a y ) 1 y w wa w y 1 y y ( 1) w a 1 (7.15) y w a 1 Assuming no extra normal profits in the long run for monopolistic competition => output will be fixed y ( 1) / . (7.16) Equation (7.16) insures the term on the right of (7.14) in [ ]) = 0. (Note that the w can be normalized to 1.0.) The number of products N produced can be solved from the identity L N ( y ) as N L / ( y ) (7.17) and does not change because of the CES assumption. (7.11) can be derived from (7.17) is we use (7.0). (7.17) illustrates there is no selection effect on the production side. But more varieties are consumed due to imports. Melitz and Yeaple allow for heterogeneous firms and thus allow for the selection effect even with a CES utility function. Summary: The theory is attempting to explain trade between similar countries but is still short of explaining most of what is happening. More work needs to be done in developing the theory and then performing tests. In the last 20 years a major effort has been made to test pure theory trade models. Key articles on the reading list will point to how to proceed with research in this area. The goal of future research might be to explain what has happened and to make predictions on 74 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 what might occur in the future. Why does all this matter? In the past 20 years the ratio of skilled wages to unskilled wages has increased in many countries in addition to the US. This has led to political ramifications. How is this to be explained? What is to be done about it? An argument made by Feenstra and others is that "movements in product prices (combined with growth in productivity) are fully consistent with the increase in the relative wage of skilled labor in the United States." A number of authors "have argued that the variables most highly correlated with the movement in wages over the 1980s and 1990s are neither trade prices nor outsourcing nor high-technology capital, but rather, a sharp increase in the price of skill-intensive nontraded goods in the United States as well as a decrease in the price of unskilled-intensive nontradables. This finding poses a challenge to those who believe that either trade of technology is responsible for the change in wages and will no doubt be an important area for further research." Feenstra (134). Gravity Equation Research Assume two countries that have simular production conditions and tastes operating under monopolistic competition : - Gravity equation => bilaterial trade between two countries is directly proportional to the product of the countries' GDP. => larger countries trade more. => more similar countries 75 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 trade more. Assume production of two countries sums to 10. Case one assumes the sizes were equal. 5*5 = 25. Case 2 assumes sizes were 1 and 9. 1*9=9. Case 1 implies more trade. Define X i j as trade from i to j . It can be proved, given all countries have the same price, that Xij X ji 2 w Y iY Y j (7.18) N Proof: Assume N products and C countries. Total GDP in each country is Y i yki and k 1 Yj world GDP is Y Y . Define s as country j's share of world expenditure so that s w . Y i 1 Assume all countries producing different products and demand are identical and homothetic. C w i j j Remark: [A homothetic utility function states that the point at which a ray from the origin of an indifference map intersects each indifference curve will find a constant rate of transformation (slope). In words MU y / MU x constant .] Exports from country i to country j of product k is X kij s j yki . (7.19) For all products N N k 1 k 1 X ij X kij s j yki s jY i Y jY i s j siY w X ji w Y (7.20) - An important question is if the assumptions needed for this result are too binding to be of use in empirical models. Focusing on size, X ij X ji 2 s i s jY w (7.21) or two countries of unequal size will not trade as much as two countries of the same size. 76 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Assume a region "A" such as OECD with two countries. Y A Y i Y j . (7.22) Their relative shares are siA Y i / Y A , s jA Y i / Y A , s A Y A / Y w . (7.23) The size equation can be expressed as X ij X ji 2 siAs jAs A YA (7.24) Squaring the identity s iA s jA 1 (7.25) implies that 2siAs jA [1 ( siA )2 ( s jA )2 ]. (7.26) Substituting back into (7.24) proves the Helpman 1987 theorem that states that if countries are completely specialized in their outputs, tastes are identical and homothetic and there is free trade then the volume of trade is: Volume of Trade in A s A 1 ( siA ) 2 A GDP iA (7.27) The term 1 ( s iA ) 2 is a "size dispersion index" that shows how trade is related to the iA relative size of countries. In the more than two country case look at pairs of countries and define A [i, j ]. The above equation is usually expressed in logs (Feenstra 2004, 147) or 2 X ij X ji Yi Y j i j ln i ln( s s ) ln[1 i i j j j Y Y Y Y Y Y For empirical work using fixed effect models the form 77 2 (7.28) International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 2 X tij X t ji Yt i Yt j i j ln i ij ln( st st ) ln[1 i i j j j Yt Yt Yt Yt Yt Yt 2 (7.29) has been used. The second term, if present assumes country shares are not constant, while if this term is not present the implicit assumption is that the shares are constant and are in the ij term. Helpman' model assumes 1 which is tested by the above form. Results for this and other related models are shown in Feenstra (2004 148-). - Summary: The Monopolistic Competition model assumes each country will be exporting varieties of the differentiated product to another. It is assumed that such countries are completely specialized in that product but could costlessly move to another product => intraindustry trade. Remark: [(H-O model only in an extreme case has complete specialization and never has intraindustry trade. When there is a continuum of goods H-O can result in complete specialization. Feenstra asserts that factor prices will not be equal. Johnson shows a special case where they might be). Common assumption of Monopolistic competition model and H-O Continuum of goods model is that # of goods exceeds # factors.] - Simple Heckscher-Ohlin Model does not allow for intraindustry trade unless there is a continum of goods produced. -H-O models with a continuum of goods => more goods than factors. - Using the gains from trade. A country can gain from trade in the following cases: - Same production conditions, different tastes. - Different production conditions, same tastes - Different production conditions, different tastes where tastes do not outweigh production conditions . - Different production conditions, different tastes where tastes do outweigh production conditions. - Same production conditions and same tastes implies no gains from trade are possible. (Does this work for marriages?) 78 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Figure 2.7 is the basic diagram. Form this base the above cases can be drawn. - The gains from trade can be broken down into the production gain and the consumption gain. The consumption gain refers to the gain that occurs when the production of all goods in a country stays the same after trade opens but the consumption pattern changes. If production does not change, then there are usually fewer political repercussions of trade. Note that politicians never complain about the consumption gain, only the costs of obtaining the production gain. The production gain arises as the mix of goods produced changes as a result of trade opening. Figure 9 below shows these gains Figure 9. Initially the country is at a for consumption and production. After trade opens the country moves to a higher indifference curve at b but still produces at a. When production of X relative to y increases the country gets to c. The diagram makes the small country assumption. If this is not the case, the terms of trade may deteriorate as production of X increases. 79 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 8. Alternative approaches to trade theory contrasted to Original HO Model. - Product cycle of a new good - Vernon. - 1. Product development and sale in the US - 2. Growth in US exports as foreign demand increases. - 3. Decline in US exports as foreign firms begin to produce for their home markets. - 4. US becomes a new importer as foreign prices fall. - Examples Radios, television, synthetic fibers, transistors, pocket calculators. Product cycle theory is short run and dynamic. - Multinationals. If the product is developed by a multinational, the production may move overseas at once. Note that the product cycle theory is not in conflict with comparative advantage since the US may have a comparative advantage in science and research technology. Continuing product improvements may allow the US to maintain its role as a producer. Since technology and capital are mobile the US may lose its production role. Technology may be stolen!! - Economies of Scale Considerations - Krugman. - Products such as aircraft may require large fixed cost to get going. Firms in these industries may require larger markets (and not proceed unless such markets are available). The large startup costs insulate such firms from stages 3-4 of the product cycle. - Economists have argued that anti trust laws should not be used to prevent US firms from cooperating on major research efforts. - Preference Similarity Hypothesis - Linder. - => Countries will export good which has a large domestic market. => countries will find that the most promising markets are those which have preference similarities to their home market. This analysis explains gains from trade in the same tastes different production conditions case but in addition considers the case where a country both imports and exports the same product class, but different models. (US imports cars but also exports cars of different 80 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 design. Linder model does not explain why production originates in one country. - Border Trade. - Trade based on similarities in consumer preferences implies that similar products may cross a border in both directions. Often the product is not quite the same. Shipping costs for bulk products may explain this circumstance. - Changes in Factor Supplies. - Figure 10-1 in Dunn and Mutti shows neutral growth. Here the same % increase in factor supplies cause PPC to move out. Exports increase. Relative prices of food and cloth remain the same. This analysis assumes a number of things: - Income elasticity of demand for all goods is unity. - Constant returns to scale. (If one good had increasing returns, then the same % increase in both factors would not increase the production of both good the same percentage. - Analysis assumes that world trade prices do not change (small country assumption.) - Figure 10-2 in Dunn and Mutti shows same conditions except that demand does not go up by the same percentage as factors of production increased. If final consumption point is along GQ' = > then we have trade biased growth. If final consumption is along Q'K then trade is anti-trade biased growth. - The production expansion path OPP' assumes that the terms of trade remain the same. If the terms of trade move against the country, then the expansion path will be steeper than OPP'. Immiserizing growth (see figure 10-4 is an extreme case. Here welfare of the country actually falls. This can cause substantial political problems! - Immiserizing growth can occur due to: - The country increasing production. - World trade prices moving against the country which by increasing production tries to stay ahead. - Increases of one factor of production. 81 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Figure 10-2 shows effect on PPC of increasing one factor of production. Cloth is relative labor intensive in comparison to wheat. An increase in labor (immigration went up) causes the PPC to move out. The increase in the potential cloth output (C1C2/OC1 is proportionately greater that the increase in potential food output F2F1/OF1. The effect of this change is that at the same world trade price the expansion path can no longer be a straight line. - A complete analysis looks at both production and consumption effects. Increased supply may cause world trade prices to change. Changes in income inside the home country may have effects on consumption patterns. From figure 10-3 we add indifference curves and generate the new offer curves shown on figure 10.3 These are drawn on figure 10 below. 82 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Figure 10 - Offer curve analysis. Initial offer curve for home country was OA. The offer curve of the rest of the world is ORest of World. The world trade relative price is OT and the home country exports OC1 of cloth for OF1 of food. As a result of the production possibility curve moving out, the home country offer curve moves to OA'. If the small country assumption was in effect, the rest of the world offer curve would be OT and the home country would sell OC3 of cloth and be at point E2. Since the rest of the world offer curve is not completely elastic, then the terms of trade move against the home country ( Pc / Pf ) and the equilibrium point becomes the new terms of trade line OT'. Immiserizing growth (see figure 10-4) is the extreme situation. Prebisch argued that this occurred for less developed countries in the 60's. This fact has been controversial. - Changes in technology shift the PPC and can be handled like changes in factor supplies. - Changes in demand can shift community indifference curve and cause changes in relative prices. - Transport Costs. Have assumed that transport costs are zero. This assumption implies that trade will equalize commodity prices at home and abroad for traded goods and assuming do not have complete specialization. Transport costs imply that price of good in foreign exporting country is less that price in domestic country. => transport costs lower gains from trade. In some cases transport costs preclude trade. IMF data suggests that transport costs have fallen from about 9% of the value to trade to 6% of the value of trade in the last 40 years. Time to deliver a product also makes some products not able to be exported. 83 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Dumping. Defined as selling a good in one market below the cost charged in another market. For a consumer in a given market, dumping is a gain. For the domestic producer of the domestic good being imported, dumping is seen as "unfair." For the i t h good MR i (1 (1/ i )) AR If | i | , then MRi ARi Pi . If id and i f are domestic and foreign elasticities of demand for the ith good, then | i f | | id | implies that Pi f Pi d Different elasticities of demand suggest market segmentation. Dumping => a gain to importing consumers but is usually protested by competing domestic firms. - Cartels. Cartels attempt to reduce supply and raise price. This action will tend to be more successful if: - The price elasticity of demand for the product is low (=> no close substitutes). In the case of oil initially people were "stuck" with cars that had low mileage. Over time as energy efficient cars were built demand elasticity changed. - The elasticity of supply for products from outside the cartel is low (new firms cannot enter easily). In the long run firms may be more likely to be able to enter. - A few members of the cartel must be willing to reduce production. Some way must be found to monitor production and assign quotas This has been a problem within OPEC. - The cartel must be congenial and small enough to work together. 84 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 9. The Theory of Protection - National money supplies were historically linked with gold. With increasing population and growth outstripping increases in the gold stock, governments were anxious to increase gold reserves. Arguments were been made for bilateral mercantilism where a country ran a surplus with each and every other country. Since in an N country world, at most there can be 1 successful bilateral mercantilism, argument shifted to multilateral mercantilism. where on balance a country ran a surplus but not necessarily with all countries. Tariffs have been used to restrict imports. Retaliation often negates first round effects. Import "regulations" or "standards" have been used to achieve the same goals. - Partial Equilibrium Analysis - Small country assumption (Small country assumption assumes that country has no effect on the world trade price) See figure 5-1. We assume area under demand curve = consumer welfare. - Initially free trade at world price = Pw. Country produces 0Q1. Country consumes OQ4. Imports Q1Q4. - Tariff increases such that (1 ) Pw Pt . Domestic producers able to produce Q2Q1 more. Domestic consumers consume Q3Q4 less. As result of tariff imports now Q2Q3. Tariff proceeds [Q2Q3] * [PT-Pw]. b = producer surplus gain. d = consumer surplus loss. c = gov gain due to tariff. After tariff consumer surplus loss = a+b+c+d . But other sectors gain. a = producers gain, c= government gain b+d = consumers loss. Deadweight loss = reduction in imports * tariff * .5 = (Q3Q4 + Q1Q2)*(PT-PW)* .5 + b+c. Assumes straight line demand and supply curves. => total consumer loss = a+b+c+d. If consumers get benefit of tariff from government then a+b+d is the loss. Producers gain b. => consumers and producers are often on different sides of the politics of tariffs. - Non Trade Barriers. Regulations regarding packaging may hinder foreign firms. In late 50's size of headlights limited high priced Italian cars from being sold in the US. Crash testing limited low volume cars. RR had to import steering columns from GM. When the requirement is not in the home market => costs of compliance cannot be shifted/shared. - Quotas. Although GATT outlawed quotas have "Voluntary Export Restraints" (VERs). 85 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 VER can be used to convince Congress not to place tariff on good. See figure 5-2. In the absence of a quota would import Q1Q4 = 40. VER limits imports to Q2Q3 = 25. Producer surplus = a. Deadweight loss = b + d. c goes to foreign country exporter who has the right to ship to domestic country. In 1950s and 1960s oil companies were given limited rights to ship oil to the US and earn area c. If treasury auctioned quota right, could recapture the monopoly rent. Same holds for NBC's right to channel 5!! Producers can upgrade products to sell a limited number of top of the line products. Producers can send parts to the US and put them together on US soil. - Subsidies. US producers are given a subsidy of S per unit. In figure 5-3 => supply curve shifts from S to S'. => Domestic producers can sell Q1Q2 more. Imports now Q2Q4 not Q1Q4. Total subsidy = S * OQ2 (paid for by taxes) of which producers get a. b is the deadweight loss since it represents an inefficiency in resource use. The subsidy is less inefficient than a tariff since the level of consumption was the same as before the subsidy. (There is no area d that occurs with the tariff since the tariff implies an increase in price. Subsidies are deemed less politically defensible. - Lerner "The Symmetry Between Import and Export Taxes" (Caves and Johnson # 11. A tax or subsidy on trade involves a divergence between foreign and domestic price ratios. Equal taxes on exports and imports create the same divergence between foreign and domestic price ratios (if trade is in balance) so the real effect of import and export taxes are symmetrical. [tariff] + [import subsidy] = 0 effect on price [tariff] = [consumption tax] + [production subsidy] [export tax] = [production tax] + [devaluation] + [import subsidy] = 0 effect on imports [devaluation] = [tariff] + [export subsidy] [consumption subsidy] = [consumption tax] + [production subsidy] [tariff] + [export subsidy] + [appreciation] = 0 [export tax] = [tariff] + [appreciation] [appreciation] = [consumption subsidy] + [production tax] 86 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 [import subsidy] = [consumption subsidy] + [production tax] - Large Country Case - Here tariff => foreign price -Figure 5-4 shows partial equilibrium analysis. Assume A is the home country and B is the foreign country. If there was no trade between A and B, the price of oats would be higher in A than B. With free trade are initially at price PW. B sells q1q4 ) to A. Assume next that country A places a tariff of T on imports from B. Price is not PW+T since B's price falls as tariff drives B down its supply curve. B's price is now P0. In A this is P0 + T. The effect is that A imports Q2Q3. Area c = tariff collected. d+b = deadweight loss and a = production subsidy. In A domestic production goes up by Q1Q2 and consumption goes down by Q3Q4. - Elastic supply. If B had a perfectly elastic supply curve, then the price in A after the tariff would rise the full amount of the tariff. A would not be able to drive the price lower in B. A has no power over the price it pays! - Inelastic supply. If B had a perfectly inelastic supply curve and none of the product was sold in B, then the effect of a tariff is to lower the price B gets. A sees the same price. Tariff collections rise but producers in A do not see any increase in sales. This may be the case in some primary product producing countries. Here foreign country pays the tariff. - Inelastic supply - export tax. In 1973 oil producing countries imposed an export tax and collected more money from the developed countries who need the oil and initially imported what they had in the past, but at a higher cost. - General Equilibrium Analysis. (See figure 5-5) - Small Country Case. Country initially at P1 for production and C1 for consumption. The world relative price line is TT. Tariff on the imported good (food) raises the relative price of food. Hence as [PF / PC] the relative price line gets flatter and moves to EE. Tariff has driven a wedge between domestic and world price. The new domestic price => food production in country as move along PPC to P2. Consumption is now at C2 on indifference curve i1. - Large Country Case. See figure 5-6. Initially at P1 for production and C1 for consumption. As a result of tariff domestically [PF/PC] but due to large country assumption and assuming that the foreign country has supply elasticity < => that the world [PF/PC] . Due to the domestic price [PF/PC] production shifts to P3 but foreign imports are made at the new world price. Final consumption point C3 is where indifference curve i3 is tangent to the new 87 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 domestic price ratio. - Offer Curve Analysis. Figure 6-2 shows the initial position E. Here A supplied OC of cloth for OF of food. The terms of trade are represented by OE. Country A now places a tariff on B => A's offer curve shifts to OA'. Without retaliation, A hopes to obtain the new relative price OE'. Point E' is selected such that A's indifference curve (not drawn) is tangent to B's offer curve. If B retaliates to get back to the original price we move to E"(not shown in ed # 6). Here trade will fall. If B has elasticity of supply of , then the effect of A's tariff in would be no change in the terms of trade and equilibrium since A cannot change prices. - Dynamics of Offer Curve Adjustment. Usually assume Walrusian adjustment => Excess demand causes price to rise. Can have Marshallian adjustment where excess demand => supply to increase. - Effective rate of Protection for industry j, ej t j (ai j ti ) i 1 ai j i e j effective rate of protection in industry j ti nominal tariff in industry i ai j share of inputs from industry i in industry j Case 1. Value added 50%. Tariff = 33% => effective rate of protection = .33/(1-.50) = 66% Case 2. tariff on motor cycle tariff imported steel tariff on imported chrome share of steel = 40% = 60% = 50% = .2 88 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 share of chrome % value added = .22 = 10% 1 ai j i effective rate of protection on value added = [.4 - [(.2*.6) + (.22 * .5)]]/.1 = 1.7 => 170% without tariffs on imported steel and chrome would be .4/.1 =400% - Export Subsidies. Governments have various means by which they can stimulate exports. In the 60's JFK gave "tied aid" that required that the foreign country buy American goods (usually military hardware). Other schemes include direct payments to export firms which is illustrated in figure 5-7 for a country facing world demand elasticity = | | . Here the world price is P0. In the absence of any intervention the country would export c. As a result of the subsidy the export firms have a price of P1 . The higher price increases exports by d + b ( and reduces domestic consumption by b. Note that the subsidy is not available for domestic sales so the firm raises the domestic price which cuts off b of domestic sales. The deadweight loss is b (loss of domestic consumer surplus) and d (the loss of productive efficiency which results from producing goods at a cost (the area under the supply curve) which is higher than the revenue received from foreign firms. If the small country assumption was not in effect, the effect of the subsidy might be to reduce the world price. 89 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 10. Arguments for Protection - Protectionism and free trade have always been in conflict in the United States. Labor used to be pro free trade but in recent years labor has tried to secure tariffs to "save jobs." In the 25 years after WWII, there was a consensus to reduce tariffs. In this era the United States was economically dominant. JFK made major progress in pushing for free trade. Now protectionism has become far more popular since the world trade market is much more competitive. A number of arguments are made for tariffs. - Protection of a way of life. The scissors statement in the book on page 142 was a plea to protect an industry from becoming extinct. The statement did not make any attempt to measure the costs of the tariff against the benefits. No attempt was made to make a security argument. - Increase Output and Employment. These arguments assume that the country will have a net increase of jobs = the protected jobs. What will happen is that there will be less jobs due to the reduction in real income. In the tariff analysis we showed the deadweight loss (d+b) in figure 6-1. There is no way to get around this cost. In a country with flexible exchange rates, a tariff will initially make the balance of payments go more into surplus but, exchange rate changes will nullify this gain. Mechanism: Tariff reduces demand for foreign currency which will fall in value making imports cheaper for a range of goods. The fall in the exchange rate nullifies the effect of the tariff. - Closing a Trade Deficit. In the short run tariffs on non essential items are sometimes used. In the long run these policies are usually not effective. - Pauper Labor. The argument is made that foreign labor is less expensive => US labor need protection. Argument assumes that 1. labor is the only input and 2. there are no differences in labor productivity 3. that wages rates have not adjusted for differences in productivity. Argument also ignores that exchange rates adjust to compensate for differences in unit labor costs across countries. Key factor is not wage rates but unit labor costs. - Heckscher-Ohlin - Factor price Adjustment. H-O theory shows how trade tends to equalize good prices and factor prices (in the absence of complete specialization.) Figure 11A & 11B shows the conditions under which factor prices adjust (11A) and do not adjust (11B). In 11A The initial endowments of the countries (RI and RII) are more similar than in figure 11B. AI => complete specialization of X in country I AII => complete specialization of X in country II BI => complete specialization of Y in country I BII => complete specialization of Y in country II 90 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 In figure 11A BII < BI < AII < AI while in figure 11B BII < AII < BI < AI Because of complete specialization in figure 11B you never can get to the zone between AII - BI => need factor mobility. Obstacles to factor price equalization from trade - Many countries - will only cause problems if all productions functions are not the same. - Many products and factors - to equalize all factors need an equal number of traded products. - Imperfect competition - To get equalization need MC = price of product and factors being paid the value of their marginal product. 91 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Increasing returns to scale breaks down perfect competition since one producer dominates. - Different production functions in different countries ruins equalization since one country will have an edge. - Increasing marginal productivity of factors of production => the price of factors =/ VMP of factor. - Factor intensity reversals cause problems due to: 1. lack of homogeneity since will not get straight line expansion paths and 2. due to one good's isoquant curve being positioned inside another good's isoquant curve. If a country expands and there is a reversal there will be a switch in the good having comparative advantage. If trade does not equalize factor prices, factors can move! Even if factor prices adjust, the formerly scare factor owners will lose relative to the formerly abundant factor owners. This change in the relative position of factor owners sets the stage for political pressure for tariffs. Since the welfare of the country goes up with free trade => gainers should be able to compensate losers. Problem: it may take time to adjust. Terms of trade argument. Figure 6-2 shows initially the world is at E. Country A seeing that the elasticity of B's offer curve is not perfectly elastic, decides to impose an "optimum" tariff and move to E'. B does not let this pass and itself passes a tariff moving the world to E". If B did not react, then from A's nationalistic perspective the move to E' is in its interest. OPEC's oil price increases are similar to export taxes. Here OPEC wanted to get the tariff gains. The primary product producing countries have been interested in raising the value of their products. They have suspected that demand for their products has not been growing worldwide as fast as the demand for the products of the developed countries. What is the optimum tariff? If the other countries offer curve has an elasticity | | , => optimum tariff = 0. If the elasticity = 1, then there is no limit to the amount of tariff that can be applied by one country since no matter what the tariff, the other country supplies the same amount. For an example see figure 6-2. The optimum point is where country A's trade indifference curve is tangent to country B's offer curve. The analysis assumes no retaliation. Infant Industry Argument. Argues that start up industries or infant industries need special protection. Over time the learning curve will => that the PPC curve will shift out and the firm will be competitive. Firms fear that attempts to develop an industry will be defeated by vigorous price competition from existing firms. Argument can be traced to Alexander Hamilton's "Report on Manufactures" (1791). While argument appears to have appeal: 92 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - How do we tell in advance if an industry will ever grow up and have the PPC shift out? - Will the eventual gains outweigh the costs of protection? - Why does the market not finance the startup? Why is the government needed? - If the wrong industry is selected the country will be saddled with a continuing burden. Many infant industries remain dependent. Industrial Strategy. Krugman has developed an argument that is an extension of infant industry and product cycle argument. Protectionism is advocated for new or emerging industries while extensive research is carried out or until sufficient economies of scale are realized. Protection of such industries may discourage foreign firms from entering the field. It is suggested that the United States may thus be able to gain permanent dominance of the market. Krugman looked an Japan and detected that this was their strategy. - Why does the market not finance such an industry? - How is Washington going to "beat the market" and pick a winner? How has Japan been doing recently in picking winners? Secondary Arguments for Protectionism. - National Defense. This argument was recognized by Adam Smith "defense is more important than opulence." If the product is storable a better strategy might be to buy on the world market at a low price and store the product. It is costly for a country to become self sufficient. International dependence may be a means by which to avoid war. An argument can be made to protect an industry to maintain skills in the work force. - Cultural or Social Values. Country may want to protect a way of life. What is the cost? - Protection to Correct Distortions in the Domestic Market. Figure 6-5 illustrates the situation. D SP Pw = domestic demand. = domestic supply curve. = world price. With no tariff the domestic production = OA, domestic consumption = OF and domestic imports = AF. We assume that SP does not include external economies in the production of the good that, if present, would make the supply curve SS. Solution is to impost a tariff raising the price to PT such that domestic production = OB, domestic consumption = OC and domestic imports = BC. Problem is that tariff induces a deadweight loss of shaded area. A better policy might be to 93 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 provide a domestic production subsidy of GE. Here domestic consumption = OF, domestic imports = BF and domestic production = OB. The domestic distortion argument has been suggested by economists that think that wages in manufacturing in some developing countries are > that wages for the same labor in agriculture. If true this would imply that the social cost of labor is < than the private cost and suggest a tariff to protect manufacturing. Others suggest that the market is paying a higher wage in the city due to differences in skills of to pay people for the disutility of working in that location. - Anti-dumping tariffs. Can place a tariff to correct an artificially low price due to dumping. If dumping is long run, the country as a while gains while the industry facing the dumped product is hurt. If dumping is short run (goal to drive domestic competing firm out of business) can have a case to use a tariff to counter dumping. - Scientific Tariff. Arguments have been made to apply a tariff to "equalize the costs of production at home and abroad." This would cancel the gains from trade. These arguments are usually made in political campaigns. - Revenues. Tariffs have been used as a source of revenues. (US in late 1700's) and in many developing countries having no income tax. The problem is that the export sector is hurt. In Nigeria farmers in Palm Oil, Ground nuts and Coca were required to sell their produce to marketing boards at a low price which in turn were the only one that could legally export. The result was that agricultural, output was below that which could be realized if the world trade price was used. Since the marketing boards price paid to farmers never changed. Farmers did not get a higher price in lean years and a lower price in good years. => farmer faced the full effect of changes in the crop. HHS argued that the government go into the palm oil business and gradually raise the price that farmers obtained. 94 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 11. Mundell Policy Equation The Mundell policy equation listed on page 41 of his International Economics (1968) provides a way to unify a great deal of the pure trade theory that was first introduced as graphs. The policy equation can be simplified by assuming some effects to be zero. The basic equation is (1 ma mb )T I (a b 1)P Ia' ta Ib' tb ma X a* mbX b* ' ' ya ya tca xb xb' tcb Ya ya t pa X b xb' t pb B (11.1) which shows how changes in transfers (T), changes in the terms of trade (P), changes in tariffs in countries a and b (ta , tb ) , changes in consumption taxes in a and b (tca , tcb ) , changes in production taxes in a and b (t pa , t pb ) , changes in the balance of payments (B), and changes in productivity in countries a and b ( X i* ) are related. Define T > (<0) as a lending of funds from country a to country b in terms of X goods. P is the price of Y in terms of X. If we define Da domestic expenditure in a, then Da xa Pya X a PYa T Db xb X T yb b Yb P P P where demand in a (b) is defined in X (Y) goods. Small letters define consumption ( xa , ya ) while capital letters ( X a , Ya ) denote production Country a (b) exports good X (Y). i and i' are the elasticity and Hicks real income constant elasticities respectively. These are in absolute value form. We note that mi is the marginal propensity to spend on imports in the ith country. i i' mi (11.2) ya' compensated elasticity of supply of y in a. The elasticity of supply in b is defined as b b 1 (11.3) 95 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Since country a imports y then y Y a ya a ya a I I (11.4) which leads to ya Y ( ya ma ) a I I ya ' Ya ya I I a' a ma ( ya ma ) ' ya (11.5) The policy equation provides a way to apply the theory used in the graphs since the parameters of the equation can be estimated. In terms of the Mundell equation, the Marshall-Lerner exchange rate stability relationships is just I ( a b 1) P B (11.6) Define the terms of trade P as the foreign price / the domestic price. B implies an increased surplus or reduced deficit. I = amount of imports. Assume exchange stability or a b 1 where we assume i is the absolute value of the elasticity of demand for imports of the ith country. The above equation suggests that if the terms of trade move against the country ( P ) the balance of payments improves B . Assume a is Germany and b is the UK. After WW I Germany was required to make a payment to the UK, One way to do this would be to place a tariff on UK goods or T a' I ta (1 ma mb ) (11.7) or have the UK grow and Germany not grow T mb * X b (1 ma mb ) (11.8) If the terms of trade are to remain fixed, the only way for country A to grow faster than country B is for the marginal propensity to import in A to be less than in B because ma X a* mb X b* . Suppose country a wishes to know the rate at which it must tax import goods to relieve disequilibrium caused by an increase in productivity in the foreign country b then 96 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 ' ya ya tca mbX b* 0 (11.9) or tca mb * ' X b ya ya (11.10) If China is country b who has mb 0 then no tax change is needed. However if Chinese buy more from the US (country a) then the consumption tax in the US must be lowered to stimulate demand for Chinese goods. The effect on the terms of trade of a tariff is P a' ta (a b 1) (11.11) Unless b the effect of a tariff increase in country a is to improve the terms of trade for country a which implies that P or in words the price of the foreign good/domestic good falls. The effect on the domestic price ratio ( Pta ) of a tariff change is ( Pta ) P a' ( ma 1) P ta 1 b ta ta (a b 1) (a b 1) (11.12) if we assume P and t a initially were 1. A tariff raises the domestic price of imports if the sum of the foreign demand for imports, b plus the domestic marginal propensity to import, ma is greater than one. Other interesting related items are U a / X a* 1 I (P / X a* ) , (11.13) which relates changes in utility in country A to the growth of productivity in country A. Multiply out to get U a X a* I P (11.14) 97 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 which highlights the result that the gain in productivity comes at the cost of a loss in the terms of trade. If X a* I P we have immeriserizing growth! The effect of a production tax in country a on the imported good y, increases demand for the foreign good and worsens the terms of trade. ya P Ya t py I (a b 1) ' (11.15) The effect of a consumption tax in country a on the imported good has the reverse effect ' ya ya P tca I (a b 1) (11.16) The policy equation allows us to net out the effect of a number of policy instruments being applied. The basic idea is that any policy will cause either excess demand or excess supply which requires some other variable to change. The advantage of the policy equation is that more than one policy can be changed at the same time. For further details and extensions see Mundell (1968) Application: Since WW II the US has tried to promote growth of first Europe and later other sectors of the world. Assuming the US is country A and that there is US growth X a* 0 , the policy equation suggests that unless we can get growth going in the rest of the world (B), the terms of trade are going to move against the US. A country can grow faster than the rest of the world if its marginal; propensity to import is lower. 98 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 12. Regional Blocks => Discriminatory Trade Liberalization - United States has the following trading classes: - Free trade (NAFTA) - Most favored nation status - tariff not at MFN level - embargo - Free Trade Area. Easiest to setup since do not have to agree on a common tariff but there is always the problem of reshipment of goods. Usually setup when the countries are quite different and a common tariff makes little sense and/or when the countries are quite far apart and the reshipment problem is less. - Customs Union. (free trade area with a common tariff) avoids the reshipment problem. Customs union has trade creation and trade diversion. Trade diversion arises from the higher costs of trading from the new partner country rather than a third lower cost country outside the customs union. Trade creation is the added trade with the partner country that was not possible in the past. - Economic Union. (Customs union with capital and labor freely mobile). An economic union is a large step toward one economy. The United States became an economic union when the constitution was passed since tariffs between the states were outlawed and capital and labor were freely mobile. Figure 7-1 shows trade creation and diversion due to a customs union. Before the customs union was formed between France and Germany, France had a tariff T which was added to the US supply curve SUS. At that time imports were Q2Q3 from the US. After the formation of the customs union, there was trade diversion from the US which was the low cost producer to Germany. Imports are now Q1Q4 from Germany. Total consumer surplus increases by a + b + c + d. The French government loses c + e of tariff revenue. The efficiency gains for the expansion of trade = b + d. The result of the customs union was that local producers lost sales but customers gained. Since e = the loss and b + d = the gain, if e > (<) (b + d) then on balance the customs union hurt (helped) country. - Dynamic Effects. Europe noted that in many cases the complete output from an industry in one country was less than the output from one firm. => Form the EEC to allow bigger firms since the market would be bigger. Another gain from the common market was that national firms faced increased competition. New changes in the works include: - Removal of border controls. - Standardization of industrial standards (TV). - Removal of limitations on movement of professional people (common licensing 99 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 standards for doctors etc) - Standardization of legal systems. - Removal of capital controls. - Removal of restrictions on trade in services such as banking, insurance and air transport. - All cross country government procurement. Major problem with economic unification - Distribution of the seignorage. How do we coordinate monetary policy? What happens if different parts of Europe want a different rate of monetary growth? 13. Commercial Policy - The rise of nationalism in the Western world (1500-1800) associated with mercantilism and close and detailed regulation of trade. The objective was to amass gold to increase the national money supply. The classical economists fought against these theories. They argued that imports were desirable. To get imports you had to export. In the UK the Corn Laws were repealed in 1846. UK was a leader in the free trade movement which reached a peak in 1870 when Germany, France and Italy wanted tariff protection for their new industries against the established UK industries. - Period 1875 - 1914 European countries developed preferential relationships with their colonies. - Protectionist tide swelled until middle of depression. Tariffs over the history of the United States. In the period 1789-1934 tariffs set by Congress and were in general relatively quite high. Tariff of 1789 was designed to generate revenue. After 1812 Southern and Western interests who exported agricultural good and imported manufacturing goods, wanted low tariffs. Eastern and Mid Atlantic States wanted higher tariffs to protect their industry. In 1828 Southerners added high tariffs on manufacturing goods usually imported into the East in the hopes the tariff would fail. The south wanted low tariffs while the North wanted high tariffs to protect their industry. Much to their surprise the "Tariff of the Abominations" passed. In 1833 some of the worst tariff abominations were removed. After the civil war Southerners had little political power. Tariffs were raised since the North was in power and remained high until the Underwood tariff of the 1920's. In 1930 SmootHawley tariff passed. Trade soon fell. In 1934 President Roosevelt was given the authority to negotiate bilateral tariff agreements (Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act). In the period 1934-1947 agreements with 29 nations were made. All agreements stressed the unconditional most-favored 100 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 nation clause and the chief supplier rule where the US only negotiated with the countries who were the chief supplier of the product. By many agreements the US was able to lower world tariffs. After WWII there was a move toward multilateralism. The International Trade Organization, International Monetary Fund and the World Bank were setup. The Reciprocal Trade Agreement provided the authorization for the United States to participate under the GATT agreement which was established in 1947. The main principle of GATT is nondiscrimination. However if all countries get the same tariff on a product but not all products get the same tariff, and all countries do not produce the same range of products, there is a possibility that what appears nondiscriminatory is in fact discriminatory. In the period 1933 - 1960's tariffs fell from ~ 53% to 10%. 1962 Trade Expansion Act authorized Kennedy Round. Eventually in 1967 tariffs were cut about 35%. While most reductions were across the board, there were special cases for individual countries. Trade Expansion Act provided "adjustment assistance" to workers impacted. This good idea did not work out too well in practice due to administrative problems. Workers may have problems learning new skills. How do we tell it is foreign competition that was the problem? An escape clause in the act allowing firms to partition for relief provided a warning to foreign firms that a tariff was possible. Many foreign firms a voluntary limits on exports to the United States. In the negotiations many countries questioned whether tariffs contained water and as a result tariff reductions were not meaningful. The Tokyo Round began in 1973 and was completed in 1979. The President was authorized to reduce tariffs up to 60% and eliminate "nuisance tariffs." After the Tokyo round the European Community reduced tariffs 29%, Japan reduced tariffs 49%, the United States reduced rates 31% and all industrial countries reduced 34%. The US participated in the Tokyo Round under the 1974 Trade Reform Act which again contained an "escape clause" and "adjustment" help and gave the President's hand in dealing with certain unfair trading practices. The President was authorized to give special treatment to developing countries in the form of a Generalized System of Preferences. Only some commodities qualified to be on the GSP list. The Uruguay Round began in 1986 and as concerned with trade in services, intellectual property rights, and Voluntary Export Restraints. GATT passed in late 1995. The 1988 Omnibus Trade Act included provisions allowing retaliation against the exports of countries whose governments do not make reasonable efforts to enforce U. S. patents and copyrights within their borders (Super 301). During the Clinton years NAFTA open trade with Canada and Mexico. So far this legislation has been a success. Bush II wants fast track authority to extend trade with other South 101 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 American Countries. 102 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 14 Trade of Less Developed Countries Issues: In the 60's primary product producers felt that the terms of trade were moving against them. That the prices of primary products were low and that production in the developed countries prevented industry from developing in the developing countries. In recent period many of same countries have experienced rapid growth. Two types of countries: - Those that have partially or totally broken away from the past trading pattern and now export manufactured goods. - Those that still export primary products (OPEC). Price instability of primary product producing countries: Competitive markets more volatile than oligopolies. Elasticities of demand and supply are lower for primary products than manufactured products (use Mundell equation to determine the effect on growth. Possible policies: - Marketing boards => Government gets the profits. Farmer's earnings fluctuate as yield changes. - Buffer stock system. (Clinton released oil from US reserve in May 1996). - Figure 10-3 Shows decline in concentration of merchandise for least developed countries. Many countries tried to reduce impact of foreign trade by a policy of import substitution. A costly way to proceed. Infant industry argument a temporary import substitution policy. - "Four tigers" (Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore, South Korea) were countries that pursued an export-led growth policy. Indonesia, Thailand, Malaysia and China also were successful. Countries exported labor intensive goods. 103 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 15 International Mobility of Labor and Capital Without mobility of labor => high wages can persist is a labor scarce region. If a country is driven to complete specialization BEFORE factor prices are equalized => need labor mobility to equalize relative factor prices. Trade and factor mobility are close substitutes. AFL-CIO supports immigration restrictions to raise wages. Also support protectionism. If production patterns stay the same more labor immigrating => PL/PK . If the production of the capital intensive good goes down, it is possible to release enough capital to combine with the now more abundant labor to keep PL/PK fixed. Assume Y = F(K, LABOR, LAND, TECHNOLOGY) K includes education and training LABOR = a(population) where a = labor force participation rate Y/C = output per capita Y/C = F(K/LABOR, LAND/LABOR, TECHNOLOGY (Y/C) / (K/LABOR) > 0 (Y/C) / (LAND/LABOR) > 0 (Y/C) / (TECHNOLOGY) > 0 It is in the interest of the US to let in highly educated and talented immigrants. Reverse brain drain. Most of the world's largest firms are multinationals. Direct investment of capital by Multi National Corporations) MNC improves the world's allocation of capital. Owners of capital in capital scare countries may not want foreign capital to come in since relative return on capital will fall. Their position in society may change!! 104 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 MNC adjust prices and move money to reduce taxes. Source Country Issues: - Return to labor goes down in country exporting capital. - For tax reduction reasons, MNC may "over" export capital to reduce tax. - Home country labor force feels export of capital => export of jobs. - Source country may feel that in many cases host country pressures MNC to distort trade flows. Host country issues: - Host country gains BUT does it get a fair deal? How controls this capital? - MNC may improve host countries ability to export by developing a capability to produce certain products. - Host country may not get its "share" of research. - Host countries often complain that MNC's change prices in order of avoid taxes. Money can be moved from one country to another in "payment" of input goods. - Host countries try to impose their laws on MNC that are under different laws. - Developing countries, increasingly find it difficult to borrow funds. Have turned to MNCs as a source of capital. 105 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 16. Balance of Payments Accounting CA = current account KA = capital account d(FXR) = change in country's foreign exchange reserves CA + KA = d(FXR) Under fixed exchange rates d(FXR) =/ 0 Under flexible exchange rates d(FXR) ~ 0. Y = C + I + G +(X-M) Y = C + Sp + T I + (X-M) = Sp + (T-G) I -(Sp + (T - G)) = M - X T - G = Sg St = Sp + Sg => I - St = M - X => Excess of investment over total savings = imports - exports Assume a sharp decline in US total savings caused by large government budget deficits and lower personal savings. => I > St implies that M > X System will come into equilibrium at a higher interest rate. US investing more than it saves, a capital inflow. Rest of world is the mirror image. 106 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 17. Market for Foreign Exchange XRr = real effective exchange rate XRn = nominal effective exchange rate Pd = domestic price level Prow = price level for rest of world XRr = (XRn * Pd) / Prow Purchasing power parity (PPP) => nominal exchange rates should move to just offset changes in inflation. Change notation to be specific St = dollar price of one unit of the foreign currency for delivery today F dollar price of one unit of the foreign currency for delivery in t+n t+n t = e expected spot rate in period t for period t+n t + nS t = itd = 90 day interest rate in domestic county it f = 90 day interest rate in foreign country Be careful how the exchange rate is defined!! Equilibrium Interest parity condition t St (1 itd ) t n Ft (1 it f ) Interest Parity Diagram shows parity condition graphically along diagonal line. 107 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Positions 1, 2 and 3 are outflows while positions 4, 5 and 6 are inflows. Along the parity line are no flow points. 1 => 2 => 3 => 4 => 5 => 6 => Define making it on exchange > loss on interest making it on both exchange and interest making it on interest > loss on exchange making it on exchange > loss on interest making it on both interest and exchange making it on interest > loss on exchange t n Ft * t St (1 itd ) /(1 it f ) Inflow condition t St (1 itd ) t n Ft (1 it f ) or t n Ft * t n Ft Outflow condition 108 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 t St (1 itd ) t n Ft (1 it f ) or t n Ft * t n Ft Outflow: 1. Buy foreign currency spot. 2. Buy foreign security. 3. Sell enough of foreign currency forward to bring back principle and interest in period t+n. 4. In 90 days unwind forward contract. Equilibrium spot speculation condition t St (1 itd ) t n Ste (1 it f ) Which can be written as t n Ft * t n Ste Inflow condition t St (1 itd ) t n Ste (1 it f ) or t n Ft * t n Ste Outflow condition t St (1 itd ) t n Ste (1 it f ) or t n Ft * t n Ste 109 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Outflow: 1. Buy foreign currency spot. 2. Buy foreign security. 3. In 90 days bring funds home hopefully at a rate t n St n t n Ste Forward speculation Do nothing if t n Ft t n Ste Sell forward if t n Ft e t n t Buy forward if t n Ft e t n t S S Define: Ca t = desired stock of forward contracts held by arbitragers in period t. Cs t = desired stock of forward contracts held by forward speculators in period t. Cŝ t = desired stock of domestic currency held by spot speculators in period t. Cat (t n Ft t n Ft * ) where 0 Cs t (t n Ft t n Ste ) where 0 Csˆ t Z (t n Ste t n Ft * ) where Z < 0 With no intervention | Cat | | Cs t | and Ca t Cs t |t n Ste t n Ft * | = return to spot speculation |t n Ste t n Ft | = return to forward speculation 110 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 |t n Ft t n Ft * | = return to arbitrage Return to spot speculation = return to arbitrage plus return to forward speculation. |t n Ste t n Ft * | = |t n Ft t n Ft * | + |t n Ste t n Ft | Non intervention cases t n Ft * t n Ste t n Ft t n Ft t n Ste t n Ft * Intervention cases t n Ft* t n Ste t n Ft t n Ft* t n t n Ft t n Ste t n t n Ste t n t n Ft Ste Ft * Ft*t n Ft See Stokes (1973 figures 1 and 2) Define dMd = new flow of money to the domestic country due to forward intervention, then (dropping subscripts) dMd = dF[( Se/ F)Z + ] where dMd = dI[( Se/ F)Z + 1] where and I = the dollar amount of forward contracts of the foreign currency sold by the central bank. The key problem is the sign of Se/ F. If Se/ F < 0 => central bank causes F to fall but the market believes that the attempt will fail and as a result Se rises. 111 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 Tension index based on hypothesis that not all values for tn Ft tn Ft* imply the same degree of tension in the market. Weighing each market as wi for n countries the weighted tension index t is defined as t i 1 wi [[(iti itd ) /(1 iti )]2 [(Fi t Si t ) / Si t ]2 ].5 / n n 112 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 18. Impact of trade on determination of National Income Under assumptions of fixed exchange rate the business cycles of major trading partners tend to be linked. => Recession in UK causes less demand for US goods which in turn shows US production. => Small countries do not export business cycles. => During Vietnam war US inflation caused an outflow of money from the US. causing world wide inflation. => If Canada knows the US is moving into recession, it can adopt an expansionary fiscal policy. 113 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 19. Alternative Models of Balance of Payments or Exchange Rate Determination - Under fixed exchange rates a balance of payments deficit => loss of reserves. - If M > X => a recessionary factor. Loss of competitiveness. - Balance of payments deficit for US => stock of US dollars builds up outside country. US central bank forced to sell foreign currency for US dollars. => reduction is US money supply. - Trade surplus => expansionary effects. - In the 60' and 70' the US sterilized US deficits. => no domestic effects of the deficit. => caused the world to bear burden of adjustment. Keynesian View of balance of payments BOT = Px* Qx - Pm* Qm Q m = F(Yd, XR r) Qm/ Yd > 0, Q m / (XR r ) > 0 XR r = foreign price of domestic money. UK def Qx = F(Yf, XRr) Q f / Yf > 0, Q f / (XR f ) < 0 BOT = Px * F(Yf, XR r) - Pm* F(Yd, XR r) + - - + BOT = F(Px, Pm,Yd, Yf, XRr) KA = capital account + - - + = F(rd, rf, riskd, riskf) + - - + - + - - + BOP = F(Px, Pm, Yd, Yf, XRr, rd, rf, risk d, risk f) Monetarist Approach to balance of payments - Excess money creation drives down domestic interest rate => BOP deficit => 114 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 money flows out to adjust system. - In recent years velocity has been changing up, then down. => hard to determine the appropriate increase in money supply. - Figure 13-2 shows US dollar appreciation in period 80-85 due to tight US monetary policy. The exchange rate also appreciated in the period 95-2000, After 2000 US growth and government deficits together with lower foreign growth causes the effective exchange rate to depreciate. In a world of flexible exchange rates speculative flows of money have a large impact. Economists have not been able to effectively model these flows. 115 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 20. Balance of Payments adjustment with fixed exchange rates Hume "Specie flow mechanism" => Money linked to gold. Deficit => money flows out increasing domestic interest rate, and lowering domestic prices, reduces domestic income. =>Sets into motion corrective forces that will adjust system. Need IS/LM/BB analysis to under stand what happens. IS Curve => locus of points where S=I LM Curve => locus of points where Money Demand = money supply BB Curve => locus of points where BOP=0 IS curve goes from upper left to lower right. See fig 16-1. Assumptions: I/ r < 0, S/ Y > 0 Points to right (left) or IS are points of excess supply or S > I. (excess demand or S < I). Assume any point on r, Y axis. Move right. Here Y up => S up. Since r = fixed then S > I. In order to increase I, need to move down. As r falls I increases. The more sensitive investment is to interest rates, the flatter the IS. IS curve drawn on Y r axis where r is real interest rate. LM curve goes from lower left to upper right. Figure 16-2. Points to right (left) are points of excess demand (supply). Assumptions Ms = m1 + m2 where m1 = transactions demand for money, m2 = speculative demand for money 116 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 m1 / Y > 0, m2 / r < 0 The more sensitive the speculative demand for money is to interest rates the flatter the LM. The less sensitive the transactions demand to income the flatter the LM. Ms up => LM to right. P up => LM to left. BB curve goes from lower left to upper right. See figure 16-6. Assert a point. Move right. => Y up causes BOP < 0. r must increase to attract capital into country. The more sensitive capital flows are to changes in r the flatter the BB. The less sensitive the BOP to changes in Y the flatter the BB. If the dollar price of the foreign currency goes up => BB moves right. Figures 16-3 shows closed economy equilibrium where IS=LM. We assume away problem that IS a function of real interest rate r and LM is function of nominal interest rate i. If we were to assume r (P)e / P i then Mundell draws GG such that difference between IS and GG is (P)e / P . If this world equilibrium is where LM = GG. Figure 16-4 shows effect of fiscal policy. Figure 16-5 shows effect of monetary policy. Both curves assume Y is below full employment. If Y is at full employment fiscal policy will move IS right. Prices will increase and LM will move left resulting is same level of income but higher interest rates. Figure 16-7 shows open economy equilibrium where BB, IS and LM intersect. Figure 16-8 shows domestic equilibrium at A but at a BOP deficit since are to right of 117 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 BB. Figure 16-9 shows money flowing out of country causing LM to move left to equilibrium. Figure 16-10 shows Brenton Woods adjustment. Here central bank moves LM by reducing money supply. After adjustment Y down , r up. Figure 16-11 shows fiscal policy being used to adjust system. Here after adjustment Y down and r down. Mundell "Principle of Effective Market Classification" => use the instrument that is most effective in adjusting the system. Figure 16-12 shows that if LM is flatter than BB = > use monetary policy rather than fiscal policy since there will be less of a loss of income. A steep BB curve => BOP not sensitive to changes in interest rates. Figure 16-13 shows that if LM is steeper than BB => use fiscal policy to adjust a deficit since here need to move IS right not left as in case of figure 16-12. A flat BB => the BOP payments sensitive to interest rate changes! Figure 16-14 shows Mundell diagram. y axis is government surplus. On horizontal axis is interest rate. - Along FF have balance of payments equilibrium. To left (right) have deficit (surplus). - Along DD have domestic equilibrium. To left (right) of DD have recession (inflation). Slopes of FF and DD represent relative impacts of monetary and fiscal policy on equilibrium. Note that fiscal policy is relatively strong at achieving domestic balance and monetary policy is relatively effective at achieving BOP equilibrium. Figure 16-15 Shows how if fiscal policy (monetary policy) is used on the BOP (domestic balance), system moves away from equilibrium. Figure 16-16 shows Reagan policy. Tight money to help BOP, expansionary fiscal policy to help obtain domestic balance. 118 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 21. Balance of Payments Adjustment through exchange rate changes Marshall-Lerner Case. We have assumed that if the domestic price of one unit of the foreign currency goes up, then exports up, imports go down and the BOP improves. This is exchange stability and forms the basis of the Mundell Equation. If the demand for imports and exports is inelastic => as foreign prices go up will buy less but spend more. On export side as price fall exports increase but prices fall faster. Figure 17-3 shows a small country facing a horizontal supply curve. Devaluation shifts up supply curve. On import side elasticity = │1│. Demand curve for exports is vertical. Devaluation has no effect. Figure 17-4 shows case where D for exports is not completely inelastic. Here devaluation helps since demand for imports is │1│ and demand for exports is not 0. Figure 17-5 same as figure 17-3 except on import side elasticity < │1│. Figure 17-6 shows small country case. Devaluation will improve BOP. Figure 17-7 shows country with no power as an importer but some power as an exported. Devaluation will help. Figure 17-8 shows that a devaluation moves BB right and IS up. IS moves up since because prices of imports have risen, demand for domestic production will increase. 119 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 22. The theory of flexible exchange rates Figure 18-10 shows a monetary expansion with fixed exchange rates. The resulting initial fall in interest rates causes money to flow out of the country. LM shifts back. Monetary policy will not work with fixed exchange rates if there is capital mobility. Figure 18-11 shows effect of fiscal policy expansion with perfect capital mobility and fixed exchange rates. Here IS shifts and increases interest rates. The capital inflow increases the money supply and the LM drops. Figure 18-12 shows effect of not complete capital mobility (BB is still flatter that LM).. Here BB has a positive slope. Fiscal policy is still strong but interest rates have risen. In Figure 18-13 still less capital mobility. Here BB steeper than LM. Here if IS shifts right there is a balance of payments deficit since we are to the right of the BB. This causes money to leave the country and the LM curve shifts up. Fiscal policy is not powerful here. 120 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 23. International Monetary Experience 1880-1940 - Reasons that gold flows were not large under the gold standard were: - The mint par exchange rate was $4.866 = L-1.00. The cost of shipping was $.026 per pound sterling equivalent. This implies that the gold points were $4.866 + .026. When the spot exchange moved toward gold export point for UK of $4.84 = -l 1, US traders regarded the pound as cheap and bought pounds. Since the market knew that the dollar price of the pound could only stay the same or go up, they made capital flows into the UK in the hope that the exchange rate would rise. These flows bid of the rate and did not require gold flows to adjust the system. - Central banks moved interest rates to limit flows. - Capital flows were sensitive and moved in a equilibrating direction as discussed above. - The gold standard required flexibility of wages and prices and tolerance for swings income and employment. - World merchandise exports tripled from 1876-1880 to 1911-1913. - Gold standard discipline. Any nations ability to expand its money supply is limited by its balance of payments position. If M increases too much, the country will lose gold and cause a internal deflation. The total money stock of the world is linked to gold discoveries. => a tendency for world wide deflation. Gold discoveries (California 1949 and South Africa 1890) were unrelated to need. This is the main weakness of the Gold Standard. - Some concerns: - Relatively satisfactory performance of the world economy in the pre 1914 period may be due to factors other than the gold standard. In a period of high growth a country with a balance of payments problem might just grow a little slower. In a static world such an adjustment would me much harder. - The gold standard worked much better in the central countries of Europe than in the developing countries where the gold standard tended to exaggerate the swings in the economy. In a boom the UK made capital exports to developing countries and bought raw materials. Developing countries gained by both. In less good times, capital flows fell and in addition the price of the export goods fell. This hurt the developing country on two fronts. 121 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - The large capital flows did lessen the need to make adjustments in wages and prices since the capital flows were in the equilibrating direction. - Many of the central bank "did not play by the rules." They intervened in blocking gold shipments and did not always let the gold flows influence central bank discount rates. - While the supply of gold was linked to money supplies, many countries had paper currency. Triffin estimated that 90% of the increase in the money supplies in the period 18731913 were from paper money. - During WWI the gold standard ceased to exist. This implied that the linkage of the economies was no longer there. The debtor nation (US) came out of the war a creditor nation. These changes made starting over again in 1918 difficult. - The period 1919 to 1926 was a period of fluctuating exchange rates as many countries delayed their return to the discipline of the gold standard. Key question what parity rates should be set? - When the war time pound peg was removed in 1919, the pound fell to $3.81. In 1920 inflation drove is still further down to $3.38. The UK government decided to reduce wages and prices in the UK. => tight money (high interest rates) high taxes. BUT wages and prices were not as flexible as anticipated. The UK fought is way back to the prewar parity but at a high cost in terms of lost growth and high unemployment. Unions resisted wage cuts. The UK faced growing competition in its basic export industries and needed to develop new export goods. - The United States in the 20's had a balance of payments surplus. Under the rules this would => US prices would increase but the Federal Reserve attempted to sterilize these flows by selling bonds. This action shifted the burden of adjustment on the UK. The United States showed that it was unable to allow foreign determination of domestic economic variables. - In April 1925 Churchill, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, returned the UK to the prewar parity rate and announced that the UK would again redeem its notes in gold and allow gold to freely flow. Speculators anticipating this even had been moving funds in to the UK. After the announcement, these funds moved out of the country. The UK still had to maintain deflationary pressure to hold the rate. Keynes attached this policy arguing that the UK not allow "the tides of gold to play what tricks they like with the internal price level." Keynes wanted a managed paper standard. "The gold standard is already a barbarous relic... advocates of the ancient standard do not observe how remote it is from the spirit and requirement of the age. A well regulated nonmetallic standard has slipped in unnoticed..." 122 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - France was more economically hurt by WWI than the UK. In 1919 the Franc was floating and lost 50% of its value going from $.183 to $.092 in the period March to December, well below its prewar rate of $.193. The French government did not have sufficient taxes and hoped German reparations would pay. As French prices increased due to the deficit, the Franc fell still further. Changes in the exchange rate fed expectations and the domestic price level was driven up. The Franc fell to $0.035 in March 1924. A conservative government led by Poincare borrowed from J. P. Morgan and bit up the Franc to $0.065 in April 1994, but was driven from office in May 1924. In the next 2 years there were 6 changes in the government. In 1926 a wave of selling hit the Franc as it fell to $0.0205 partially in response the German problems with hyperinflation. Poincare came back into power and stabilized the Franc at $0.0392 as France offered to buy and sell Francs to maintain that rate. France was effectively no longer on a flexible exchange rate system. As a result of the stabilization policy confidence was restored and capital flowed back to France. - The UK which chose to maintain their fixed exchange rate system suffered recession and hardship, while in France there was full employment. => UK citizens saw the costs in maintaining a fixed exchange rate system. France, Belgium and Italy saw the costs on inflation. Figure 19-3 shows the exchange rate in the UK while figure 19-5 shows what happened in France. Figure 19-7 shows countries struggling back on to then off the gold standard. - Problems of going back on the gold standard: - Countries had difficulty setting the appropriate exchange rate. It was too high => needed recession to maintain it. If it was too low = surplus. - There was concern regarding whether there was enough gold being discovered. To save on gold countries encouraged to hold L- and $ which in turn were pegged to gold. - Many countries were reluctant to play by the rules of the gold standard. Surplus countries fearing inflation neutralized gold inflows so prices would not increase. Deficit countries attempted to avoid the deflation consequences of gold outflows. Changes in social attitudes made the price system less flexible. - In 1928 France prohibited the central bank from issuing the Franc backed by anything but gold. This action caused problems for the gold exchange standard since whenever France had a surplus, it demanded gold. French gold reserves rose in 1929, 1930 and 1931. - In 1931 growing depression led to "hot" money flows. In September 1931 after a near naval mutiny, the UK went off gold. The UK government had no stomach for another dose 123 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 of classical medicine. The restored gold standard failed because nations were never able to reestablish the closely knit, highly integrated world economy that had evolved in the prewar period. Countries rejected interdependence and sough in various ways to go it alone. - In the 30's countries attempted to manage the float. Some countries tried to peg their currencies to the pound (Sterling Area) others resorted to various exchange controls. In the US wholesale prices fell 30% and 23% of the work force was out of work as national income fell 45% and exports fell 38%. In the US FDR wanted to raise prices. This was done by raising the price of gold from $20.67 to $35.00. FDR imposed an embargo on gold exports (taking the US off gold) and required all private gold to be turned in (prior to the price of gold being raised). (This was repealed in 1974). This action abrogated "gold clauses" in contracts. The effect was a huge gold inflow in to the US and miners found and sold gold to the US treasury. Figure 19-9 shows how this caused the gold price of the pound to increase helping US exports and limiting US imports. 124 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 24 The International Monetary System 1945-1973 - At the 1944 Bretton Woods conference the IMF was setup to help maintain an exchange rate system (1945-1973). Goals of the IMF were to 1. Provide an orderly method of regulation of exchange rates, 2. Provide a supplementary supply of international reserves, 3. Provide a mechanism for the adjustment of balance of payments disturbances. All these goals impacted on national sovereignty and autonomy. - Each member pegs its currency to the US dollar. - Each member agreed to keep its spot rate within + _ 1% of par. => the countries central bank had to stand ready to intervene. - The IMF provided a mechanism by which exchange rates could be changed. Wanted the advantages of both flexible and fixed exchange rate syste did not have to be put in the situation of having to deflate internally as the UK had to do when it went back on gold. - While exchange controls were outlawed under article VIII, article XIV allowed a "transition period" that has expended for many years. - Adjustment problems In the prewar period deficit countries had to take action at once while surplus countries could wait. Under the IMF scarce currency provision a currency can be declared scarce (from a surplus country) giving other countries the right to adopt discriminatory provisions. => force adjustment costs on both surplus and deficit countries. - In period 1945-1958 there was a dollar shortage as the US ran balance of payments surplus. The US gave $30 billion to Europe alone under the Marshall plan. By 1958 the US was running a deficit. In 1949 the Pound was depreciated 30% from $4.03 to $2.80. - After 1958 there was a dollar surplus. Figure 20-1 shows Japanese yen, French franc, Italian lira and Swiss franc. - The need for an international money led to the rise of the Eurocurrency market. This was essentially unregulated banking since there was no formal reserve requirement. The only thing stopping the expansion is if Eurodollars are placed in an American bank which would trade them into the US currency, the "reserve" base of the Eurodollar. 125 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 - Reasons for Eurodollar Market - Until the mid 60's regulation Q limited the amount American banks could pay on time deposits to 4%. Eurobanks not subject to this law could pay more than 4%. - In the 60' LBJ imposed a tax on foreign bond issues in New York and placed restrictions on loans to foreigners by U. S. banks. => US firms needing money in Europe borrowed from the Eurodollar market. - Nations with exchange controls and legal restrictions on their citizens moved into the Eurodollar market. - US banks were required to maintain reserves in the US which they did not get interest on. => US banks had an incentive to move to Eurodollar market. - The Eurocurrency market played a major role in financing the Oil shock of the 70's. Many countries made a major mistake in borrowing long term for oil => a large buildup of debt. 126 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 25 International Monetary Relations 1973 - Present - US dollar float was relative stable in the period 75-76. In 1977 a new US secretary of the treasury stated that he thought the dollar was too strong and that it should float down. This statement led to the US dollar floating down. Higher US inflation in 1978 made matters worse. Paul Volcker became the newly appointed chairman of the Federal Reserve Board and started tightening US monetary policy. Starting in 1981, capital began to flow into the United States and the dollar appreciated 40%. => a disastrous decline in the cost and price competitiveness of US firms operating in international markets. - The US dollar appreciated because of tight money and high US interest rates due to sales of government bonds to finance the tax cut. During Don Reagan the dollar floated relatively cleanly while under Baker there was more US intervention to lower the value of the dollar. - The historical record under the flexible exchange rate period shows more volatility than was initially expected. Large "hot" capital flows are certainly part of the problem. The possibility of a "dual rate system" where trade had one exchange rate and capital had a freely floating rate would be easily circumvented since invoicing could be adjusted to move capital. - A return to the gold standard puts the world at the mercy of gold production in South African and Russia. - Key lesson. Open economies cannot escape some degree of vulnerability to macroeconomic shocks that originate abroad and policy independence will always be partially constrained by balance of payments or exchange rate considerations. Economic isolation has great costs!! - Europe has attempted to limit the degree of fluctuation across countries. i:j = i price of one unit of j's currency. [A:B] = [A:C]*[C:B] [$:M] = [$:L-][L-:K][K:E][E:M] - European Monetary system has a new currency (European Currency Unit or ECU) made up of a basket of currencies. Goal is for the ECU to replace national currencies. Problems might occur if one section of the European Monetary system wanted more inflation than another 127 International Trade Notes: 27 August 2012 section. Mundell argued for optimum currency areas. - In 1976 the SDR which was once linked to the gold content of the US dollar became equal to a basket of currencies. .5720 US dollar, .4530 Deutsche mark, .8000 French franc, 31.8000 4. Japanese yen, .0812 Pound sterling. - The Latin American debt crisis continues to be a problem. While most debtor countries were able to make interest payments in the 70'2, this was not the case in the 80's when defaults threatened US banks. - The disintegration of the Soviet bloc remains a problem. How are these countries to be integrated into the world financial system? Will the US continue to play a major international role or will it retreat into isolationism? How interested will the US be in the third world countries now the cold war is over? Can we explain exchange rate movements? See page 469. No one theory will explain everything. Purchasing Power Parity clearly works for hyper inflations but is not the whole story. Interest Rate Parity almost never holds. This suggests the AA curve is not flat! If the SS curve was flat is would suggest that S e F or that the forward rate is an unbiased predictor of the spot rate. A flat SS curve and flat AA curve is not possible at one time. Monetarist Models argue that the exchange rates depreciate if the domestic money supply increases and appreciates in response to an increase in total output. Dornbusch in the 80's argued that this is not a complete answer either. Changes in exchange rates can impact certain sectors more than other sectors. The EU tries to correct for this. See page 489-491 for a list of pressing problems. 128