Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate The Geography of MFW-Land and the Limits of Controlling Shareholder Ratification Itai Fiegenbaum Table of Contents I. Introduction 2 II. Related Party Transactions with a Controlling Shareholders 5 A. Controlling Shareholders - General 5 B. Controlling Shareholders under Delaware Law 8 C. Controlling Shareholders – A Complicated Taxonomy 9 D. Controlling Shareholders and Related Party Transactions 12 III.Standards of Review in Delaware Law 14 A. Introduction 14 B. Business Judgment Rule 15 C. Enhanced Scrutiny 17 D. Entire Fairness 19 E. Downgrading from Enhanced Fairness 22 IV. Questioning MFW's Reach – Doctrine 27 a. Introduction 27 b. MFW and the Unification of Final Period Review 27 c. Standards of Review for Going-Concern RPTs 27 V. Questioning MFW's Reach – Policy 28 a. Independent Board Committees – A Critique 28 b. Majority of Minority Shareholder Approval – A Critique 32 VI. The Geography of MFW-LAND 35 PhD Candidate, Tel Aviv University. LL.B, Tel Aviv University, LL.M, Columbia University. 1 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate I. Introduction Judicial standards of review for board actions and inactions are a foundational element of Delaware corporate law.1 Market forces are believed to correct egregious episodes of simple mismanagement more swiftly and mercilessly than the courts. Accordingly, a shareholder complaint against decisions undertaken by the board of directors will be met with the default deferential business judgment rule standard of review.2 This standard's hallmark is a heavy presumption that the board acted in the corporation's best interests. Application of the business judgment rule usually results in a swift dismissal of the complaint. Factual situations that cast suspicion on the board's ability to champion shareholder interests result in an upgrade of the standard of review. Arrival of an outside bidder that seeks to wrest control from incumbent management is an example of such a scenario. Lingering doubts regarding the actual motivation behind the board’s response towards an unwanted suitor undermines the presumption of fidelity and justifies adoption of an intermediate 'enhanced scrutiny' level of review. Once enhanced scrutiny applies, the onus shifts to the board to prove that the defensive measures were reasonable to the recognized threat. Transactions between the corporation and its controlling shareholder provide another example of a suspect situation. Ownership of a control block of shares connotes a heavy influence over board composition and by implication corporate policy. An inherent suspicion that board approval was induced by the desire to stay on the controller's good graces justifies evocation of an even more stringent standard of review. Under the entire fairness standard, it is up to the board to prove that the challenged transaction materialized after an impeccable negotiating process that successfully safeguarded minority shareholder interests. 1 2 Robert B. Thompson, Mapping Judicial Review: Sinclair v. Levien, in THE ICONIC CASES IN CORPORATE LAW 79 (Jonathan R. Macey, ed.) (2008) ("The intensity of judicial review of corporate decisions is the central issue of corporate law"). "Distinguishing among standards of review is an important (and frequently dispositive) exercise" (In Re Molycorp, Inc. Shareholder Derivative Litigation, Consolidated C.A. No 7282-VCN, (Del. Ch. May 27, 2015) *20-21). This is because “[t]he applicable standard of judicial review often controls often controls the outcome of the litigation on the merits” Emerald Partners v. Berlin, 787 A.2d 85, 89 (Del. 2001) (citations omitted). Carsanaro v. Bloodhound Technologies, Inc., 65 A.3d 618, 637 (Del. Ch. 2013) ("The business judgment rule serves as Delaware's default standard of review and applies to the overwhelming majority of decisions that boards make"). 2 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate Court deference to independent, disinterested, and sufficiently informed decision makers is an additional feature of Delaware law.3 Under certain conditions, effective employment of a qualified decision maker results in a reduction of the standard of review.4 Recent case law and scholarly endeavors have elucidated the effect of qualified decision maker approval in certain situations.5 While helpful, these clarifications have done little to redress the scarcity of settled authority detailing the effect of qualified decision maker(s) approval in problematic scenarios involving the corporation and a controlling shareholder.6 This article attempts to fill that void. Specifically, it questions whether effective employment of a ratification procedure should ever restore the business judgment rule review for transactions with a controlling shareholder. At first glance, the answer appears obvious to faithful followers of Delaware law. In a highly celebrated decision, the Delaware Supreme Court concluded that a going private merger with a controlling shareholder will be granted deferential business judgment rule review, so long as it was approved by two procedural safeguards:7 (i) a special board committee composed of disinterested directors armed with independent counsel, advisors with actual bargaining power and (ii) conditioning the consummation of the transaction on the non-revocable acceptance by a majority of minority shareholders.8 Prior to this decision, Delaware case law declined to provide a ratification avenue that results in business judgment rule review for going private mergers.9 Contrary to the "classic" ratification doctrine, which merely calls for shareholder approval,10 the MFW guideline demands the aggregate endorsement of 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 J. Travis Laster, The Effect of Stockholder Approval on Enhanced Scrutiny, 40 WM. MITCHELL L. REV. 1443 (2013). In accordance with the terminology adopted by Vice-Chancellor Laster, this article adopts the phrase "qualified decision maker" as shorthand for the list of necessary attributes. Id., at 1444 ("A court applying Delaware law moves along the standards depending on the degree to which a qualified decision maker exists"). See fn. == infra and accompanying text. Laster, supra note 4, at 1444 ("Delaware decisions explain how the standard of review escalates from the business judgment rule to entire fairness and back again… But Delaware cases address to a far lesser degree how the standard of review can diminish from enhanced scrutiny to the business judgment rule"). This article will prove that the lack of clarity exists in the controlling shareholder context as well. Kahn v. M & F Worldwide Corp., 88 A.3d 635 (2014) [hereinafter MFW Supreme]. To be more precise, the Supreme Court affirmed the analysis and framework established by the Court of Chancery; see In re MFW Shareholders Litigation, 67 A.3d 496 (2013) [hereinafter MFW Chancery]. See fn. == infra and accompanying text. See fn. == infra and accompanying text. Conceptually, the term "shareholder ratification" has been used to describe slightly different sets of circumstances. "Classic" ratification depicts situations where shareholders are asked to approve board action that would be legally valid even without shareholder approval. Examples of this type of ratification include director compensation or a board stock option 3 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate two separate qualified decision makers. In essence, MFW creates an enhanced ratification mechanism for going private mergers. Going private transactions differ from going concern transactions in that their successful completion wipes out the minority float. This distinction accelerates shareholders' divergent incentives and raises the possibility for minority shareholder abuse. All shareholders gain in value that accrues to a publicly traded corporation. An unscrupulous controller might structure the transaction in a manner that captures all unlocked value for later private consumption.11 Additionally, going private transactions allow controlling shareholders to shed the restrictions of the public market, thereby evading future retribution by minority shareholders.12 Accordingly, policy considerations call for superior protection of minority shareholders participating in a going private transaction. Since MFW establishes a procedure for achieving narrower judicial review for going private transactions, it stands to reason that the effect of this procedure should apply to all transactions involving a controlling shareholder. After all, if the courts are willing to downgrade their involvement in the most problematic of settings for minority shareholders, what possible rationale is there for staying put with enhanced review in apparently more benign circumstances? This article shows that the borders of "MFW-Land" are not as clear-cut as they appear. Across-the-board application of business judgment rule review for all controlling shareholder transactions that employ the MFW enhanced ratification blueprint does not necessarily flow from the Supreme Court's decision. Two main arguments form the basis of this contention. The dual tenets of doctrinal clarity and cohesion underpin the first argument. MFW stems from a line of cases that deal specifically with going private transactions with a controlling shareholder. Different strands of Delaware authority seemingly govern other instances of controlling shareholder self-dealing. A careful reading of the MFW decision fails to detect any mention of competing precedent or any 11 12 plan. Ratification has also been used to describe the effect of an informed shareholder vote that was statutorily required for the transaction to have legal existence. Examples of the "organic" ratification alternative include mergers and amendments to a corporation's certificate of incorporation. See: In Re Wheelabrator Tech. Shareholders Lit., 663 A,2d 1194, 1201 fn. 4 (Del. Ch. 1995). Recent case law and a scholarly article authored by ViceChancellor Laster have clarified language in prior Supreme Court opinions that arguably question the effect of shareholder ratification on organic corporate acts. See: In Re KKR Financial Holdings LLC, 101 A.3d 980, 1001-1003 (Del. Ch. 2014) and Laster, supra note 4 at p. 1848-1491. Since no statutory authority requires shareholder approval for related party transactions with a controlling shareholder, this article's focus remains on the "classic" form of shareholder ratification. Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, Controlling Controlling Shareholders, 152 U. PA. L. REV. 785, 804 (2003). Sean J. Griffith, Deal Protection Provisions in the Last Period of Play, 71 FORDHAM L. REV. 1899, 1941-1947 (2002) (discussing the last period problem). 4 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate reference regarding its application to other types of controlling shareholder transactions. Canons of judicial interpretation counsel against an indirect reversal or modification of established precedent. The second argument derives from the policy justifications explicitly articulated by the MFW court. The doctrinal shift is grounded on the twin pillars representing the competency of independent directors and non-affiliated shareholders. Whatever the validity of these mechanisms in the freeze out context, the empirical literature does not advocate an extension to going concern transactions. Serious flaws hamper the ability of independent directors and non-affiliated shareholders to pass meaningful judgment on going concern transactions. Ultimately, the courts' own reasoning does not support the establishment of an enhanced ratification procedure for all controlling shareholder transactions. The rest of the article is structured as follows. Since this article deals specifically with related party transaction with controlling shareholders, Part II defines the pertinent terms and expands on the policy issues that these types of transactions engender. Part III describes the Delaware judiciary's use of shifting standards of review to police potentially harmful transactions. Part IV traces the doctrinal evolution of the standards applicable to going-private transactions and demonstrates that their shared ancestry with the general authority regarding going concern transactions with a controlling shareholder is tenuous at best. Part V takes a closer look at the underlying policy rationales behind the MFW decision. Critically, this part will reveal the drawbacks associated with each justification. Taken together, Parts IV and V conclude that that expansion of the MFW doctrine to other types of controlling shareholder transactions is not a compulsory outcome. II. Related Party Transactions with a Controlling Shareholder A. Controlling Shareholders - General This paper questions the effect of an enhanced ratification procedure on the standard of review used to evaluate related party transactions (RPTs) with a controlling shareholder. Brisk definitions of the pertinent terms will prove useful for the analysis. 5 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate The dominant corporate governance model entrusts the board of directors with plenary authority over the whole of the corporate enterprise.13 This authority entails the ability to hire active management, set their pay, and if need be, fire them.14 A republican theory of shareholder democracy justifies this broad vest of authority.15 If shareholders are displeased, they are entitled to attempt to galvanize the electorate in an effort to replace the board.16 By virtue of their legal capability to set board composition, ultimate indirect control over the corporation belongs to shareholders. Firm-specific shareholder ownership displays significant variance.17 An accepted taxonomy distinguishes between 'dispersed' and 'concentrated' ownership. Dispersed ownership occurs when shareholder fragmentation is so severe that no single shareholder or groups of shareholders can singlehandedly determine the shareholder vote. This scenario entertains the theoretic possibility that the next annual shareholders meeting transfers de-facto control over the corporation to a new slate of directors. Ownership of a corporation is considered 'concentrated' if either a single shareholder or a group of shareholders, working in unison, are able to unilaterally dictate the result of the shareholder vote. Ownership of over half the shares renders most shareholder votes foregone conclusions. However, actual control can be achieved by means of a much lower ownership stake. Fragmented shareholders face prohibitive collective action problems that are amplified by legal rules skewed in favor of the incumbent board.18 For this reason, the comparative corporate law 13 14 15 16 17 18 REINIER KRAAKMAN ET AL., THE ANATOMY OF CORPORATE LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND FUNCTIONAL APPROACH (2nd ed. 2009), pp. 56-60. Id. PP. 60-62. Stephen M. Bainbridge, Why a Board - Group Decisionmaking in Corporate Governance, 55 VAND. L. REV. 1, 4 (2002). See Leo E. Strine, Jr., The Story of Blasius v. Atlas Corp.: Keeping the Electoral Path to Takeovers Clear, in J. MARK RAMSEYER, CORPORATE LAW STORIES 243 (2009) (detailing how Delaware law severely limits director actions designed to impede stockholder access to the voting booth). The actual scope of stockholders' ability to displace incumbent directors is subject to some debate; compare Lucian A. Bebchuk, The Myth of the Shareholder Franchise, 93 VA. L. REV. 675 (2007) with E. Norman Veasey, The Stockholder Franchise Is Not a Myth: A Response to Professor Bebchuk, 93 VA. L. REV. 811 (2007) and Martin Lipton & William Savitt, The Many Myths of Lucian Bebchuk, 93 VA. L. REV. 733 (2007). Since this article's analysis of enhanced ratification procedure premises the existence of a controlling shareholder, I sidestep the debate regarding the actual efficacy of stockholder democracy in corporations characterized with disperse ownership. Beyond simple serendipity, this variance may also result from the relative costs associated with jointly owning different types of enterprises; see ZOHAR GOSHEN & RICHARD SQUIRE, PRINCIPAL COSTS, http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2571739 (last visited Aug 3, 2015). Two examples come readily into mind. The first is the general case law that permits the corporation to reimburse incumbent directors for election and proxy solicitation expenses while denying unsuccessful insurgents the same benefit; see Rosenfeld v. Fairchild Engine & Airplane Corp., 309 NY 168 (N.Y. 1955), Steinberg v. Adams, 90 F. SUPP. 604 (S.D.N.Y 1950). The second is the Delaware courts' validation of a shareholder right plan (colloquially referred to as a poison pill), which allows the corporation to heavily dilute a shareholder that 6 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate literature has settled on the 20% ownership threshold as evidence of control.19 Beyond this point, the largest shareholder usually has a clear ability to influence the shareholder vote and is accordingly identified as the controlling shareholder. The traditional narrative of American public corporation ownership posits extreme stockholder fragmentation.20 This is unfortunate, since the absence of controlling shareholders would relegate an article pondering the legal rules that govern controlling shareholder self-dealing into a work of fiction. Luckily, recent scholarship has documented significant nuance in the actual levels of shareholder ownership. Dominant shareholders, while not unheard of, are indeed a rare occurrence in the largest publicly traded corporations.21 However, expanding the universe of surveyed corporations to include both mid-size and even relatively small publicly traded corporations reveals an increase in the average size of the largest shareholder.22 The continued survival of large shareholders in publicly traded corporations assures that this article's motivating question generates practical applications.23 19 20 21 22 23 passes a pre-determined ownership threshold without board permission; see Moran v. Household Intern., Inc., 500 A.2d 1346 (Del. 1985) and Versata Enterprises v. Selectica, Inc., 5 A.3d 586 (Del. 2010). The aggregate effect of these rules is to hamper shareholders' ability to marshal a voting coalition aimed at displacing the incumbent board. Coincidentally, this means that a relatively small shareholder support base in necessary to help the incumbent board retain control. Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes & Andrei Shleifer, Corporate Ownership Around the World, 54 J. FIN. 471, 476-477 (1999), Mara Faccio & Larry H. P Lang, The Ultimate Ownership of Western European corporations, 65 J. FIN. ECON. 365, 369 (2002). The narrative stems from a highly influential depiction of American corporate ownership coauthored by two depression-era scholars; see Adolph Berle and Gardner Means, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932). The prevalence of the Berle-Means ownership model as the go-to depiction of American shareholder ownership probably stems from the disproportionate amount of research devoted to the largest corporations. Since ownership fragmentation is more severe in larger corporations, ignorance of smaller corporations leads to a failure to recognize the actual frequency of controlled corporations in American stock markets; see Brian Cheffins & Steven Bank, Is Berle and Means Really a Myth?, 83 BUS. HIST. REV. 443, 464 (2009) ("[E]vidence concerning ownership patters in very large companies has perpetuated the idea that a split between ownership and control characterizes U.S. corporate governance"). Id., Appendix 5 (summarizing studies of ownership dispersion that focus predominantly on very large U.S. companies, c. 1980-2005). Mining a database composed of a random sample of 375 corporations traded on NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ, Holderness provides evidence that 96% of the sampled firms had a blockholder owning more than 5% of the shares. Moreover, the average aggregate stock ownership of all blockholders was 39%. For firms with a blockholder, the largest blockholder owned on average 26% of the voting shares; see Clifford G. Holderness, The Myth of Diffuse Ownership in the United States, 22 REV. FIN. STUD. 1377 (2009). Other studies, which focused primarily on larger corporations, found lower levels of shareholder ownership. For a useful overview and synthesis of the data regarding small and mid-sized publicly trade corporations, see Cheffins and Bank, supra note 20, at 463-466. Another recent trend that undermines the validity of the Berle-Means model of corporate ownership is the growing ownership shares of intermediary financial institutions; see Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Agency Costs of Agency Capitalism: Activist Investors and the Revaluation of Governance Rights, 113 COLUM. L. REV. 863 (2013). Taking the ownership 7 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate B. Controlling Shareholders under Delaware Law Delaware law recognizes two sets of circumstance that implicate the existence of a controlling shareholder. Ownership of at least 50% of the voting rights provides evidence of control.24 Alternatively, domination over the board's decision-making process can transform a substantial stockholder owning less than a majority of the voting rights into a controlling stockholder25 with regards to a challenged board action.26 The second option requires further clarification. The Delaware General Corporate Law's (DGCL) broad grant of authority to the board of directors is predicated on the grounds of efficiency. 27 Empowering a select group of motivated individuals28 to manage the business and affairs of the corporation facilitates decisionmaking.29 The next chapter details the courts' well thought-out use of standards of review to police board actions. Suffice it for now, the default standard of review includes a heavy presumption against judicial intrusion in the challenged business decision. While not outcome-definitive, the existence of a controlling shareholder is more likely to invoke a more exacting standard of review. However, a higher standard come at a price. Overcoming procedural and transactional hurdles requires meticulous and costly planning. Even then, the realities of representative stockholder litigation all but assure that nearly all large transactions will be challenged in court.30 While this might deter blatant over-reaching, higher transaction costs and the risk of being forced to run a judicial gauntlet could just as easily dissuade the corporation from advancing 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 stake of these financial institutions into account produces large blockholders in almost all publicly traded corporations. Weinstein Enterprises, Inc. v. Orloff, 870 A.2d 499, 507 (Del. 2005) ("In the context of imposing fiduciary responsibilities, it is well established in the corporate jurisprudence of Delaware that control exists when a stockholder owns, directly or indirectly, more than half of the corporation's voting power") (footnotes omitted). Citron v. Fairchild Camera & Instrument, 569 A.2d 53, 70 (Del. 1989) ("For a dominating relationship to exist in the absence of controlling stock ownership, a plaintiff must allege domination by a minority shareholder through actual control of corporate conduct"). IN RE KKR FINANCIAL HOLDINGS LLC, supra note 7, at 991 ("To survive a motion to dismiss under this theory, plaintiffs must allege facts demonstrating actual control with regard to the particular action that is being challenged") (internal quotations omitted), Williamson v. Cox Commc'ns, Inc., 2006 WL 1586375, at *4 (Del. Ch. June 5, 2006). 8 DEL. CODE ANN. tit 8, § 141(a). For a provocative argument advocating that specialized firms be allowed to take up the directorship mantle, see: Stephen M. Bainbridge & M. Todd Henderson, Boards-R-Us: Reconceptualizing Corporate Boards, 66 STAN. L. REV. 1051 (2014). Stephen M. Bainbridge, The Business Judgment Rule as Abstention Doctrine, 57 VAND. L. REV. 83, 104-109 (2004) (applying Kenneth Arrow's authority vs. accountability framework as a normative justification for the board's large grant of authority). Matthew D. Cain & Steven Davidoff Solomon, A Great Game: The Dynamics of State Competition and Litigation, 100 IOWA L. REV. 465, 475 (2014) ("[I]n the past ten years [takeover litigation] has experienced a significant uptick as almost every transaction is challenged"). 8 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate value-enhancing transactions. An overly-cavalier attitude when contemplating the status of a large shareholder is ultimately detrimental to stockholders' interests.31 These overarching rationales are ingrained in the "actual domination" test endorsed by the Delaware courts. Ownership of a large bundle of stock carries with it legitimate rights, such as the ability to effectively veto transactions that require approval by the general stockholder assembly.32 However, ownership of even a large block of stock does not impinge on the board's mandate to manage the company.33 Bullying the board to plot a course of action is an illegitimate abuse of power. The test's fact-intensive inquiry is designed to reveal instances where board discretion was usurped by a non-majority shareholder.34 Absent evidence of this type of abuse, efficiency gains realized by deference to board authority advocate against classifying every large shareholder a controller.35 C. Controlling Shareholders – A Complicated Taxonomy Realization of one of the alternative sets of circumstances set out in Delaware case law verifies the existence of a controlling shareholder. The controller's concomitant potential to distort elements of effective corporate governance is 31 32 33 34 35 In addition to measurable expenditures, such as legal and financial counsel, a comprehensive tally must include immeasurable costs as well. Examples of immeasurable costs include management resources spent on the lawsuit that would otherwise be devoted to corporate needs as well as the chilling effect that subsequent litigation poses for the consummation of value-enhancing transactions. Mendel v. Carroll, 651 A.2d 297, 306 (Del. Ch. 1994) ("No part of their duty as controlling shareholders requires them to sell their interest"). WEINSTEIN ENTERPRISES, INC. V. ORLOFF, supra note 24, at 508-509 ("For publicly held corporations, the Delaware General Corporate Law contemplates a separation of control and ownership. The board of directors has the legal responsibility to manage the business of the corporation for the benefit of its stockholders. This Court has consistently held that the fact the directors of a corporation are elected by the majority stockholder does not relieve those directors of their fiduciary duties to the corporation and its minority stockholder) (footnotes omitted). Superior Vision Services, Inc. v. ReliaStar Life Insurance Co., 2006 WL 2403999, at *4 (Del. Ch. Aug. 18, 2006) ("[T]he focus of the inquiry has been on the de fact power of a significant (but less than majority) shareholder, which, when coupled with other factors, gives that shareholder the ability to dominate the corporate decision-making process. The concern is that the significant shareholder will use its power to obtain (or compel) favorable actions by the board to the ultimate detriment of other shareholders"). In Re Crimson Exploration Inc. Stockholder Litigation, at *29-30 (Del. Ch. Oct. 24, 2014) ("These [surveyed] cases show that a large blockholder will not be considered a controlling stockholder unless they actually control the board's decisions about the challenged transaction... Absent a significant showing such as was made in these prior cases, the courts have been reluctant to apply the label of controlling stockholder - potentially triggering fiduciary duties - to large, but minority, blockholders"). See also Bainbridge, supra note 28, at 104 ("Given the significant virtues of [board] discretion, however, one should not lightly interfere with management or the board's decision-making authority in the name of accountability. Preservation of managerial discretion should always be the null hypothesis"). 9 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate noteworthy. The lack of a credible hostile takeover threat impairs the market for corporate control's ability to function as a natural policing mechanism against board malfeasance.36 An additional complication stems from the controller's substantial sway over board composition. In Delaware, like most jurisdictions, the default rule is that director elections take place via simple shareholder vote.37 Even in our era of increased board independence,38 a directorial candidate's chances of success hinge on at least tacit endorsement by a controlling shareholder.39 Once elected, incumbent directors enjoy ample motivation to stay on the controller's good graces. Assuming a director wishes to maintain her post, a rebuked controlling shareholder might affect retribution by withholding support in a subsequent director election.40 Although wielding no formal power under most corporate law statutes, the nomenclature of "controlling shareholder" recognizes the harsh reality that a control block of shares allows a shareholder to exert indirect and informal influence over corporate policy.41 36 37 38 39 40 41 Lucian A. Bebchuk & Assaf Hamdani, The Elusive Quest for Global Governance Standards, 157 U. PA. L. REV. 1263, 1282 (2009). For the positive impact that control contestability has on share value, see: Lucian A. Bebchuk & Alma Cohen, The Costs of Entrenched Boards, 78 J. FIN. ECON. 409 (2005) and Alma Cohen & Charles C. Y. Wang, How do Staggered Boards Affect Shareholder Value? Evidence from a Natural Experiment, 110 J. FIN. ECON. 627 (2013). 8 DEL. CODE ANN. tit 8, § 211(b). Initiatives aimed at changing the default rule include the requirement that a majority of voting rights in the corporation vote in favor of the directorial candidate, instead of a plurality of votes rendered; see: LISA M. FAIRFAX, SHAREHOLDER DEMOCRACY: A PRIMER ON SHAREHOLDER ACTIVISM AND PARTICIPATION (2011), pp. 90-91. Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Rise of Independent Directors in the United States, 1950-2005: Of Shareholder Value and Stock Market Prices, 59 STAN. L. REV. 1465 (2007) (detailing and explaining the shift from boards comprised of approximately 20% independent directors in the 1950s to boards comprised of approximately 75% independent directors in the mid2000s) . For an enlightening analysis of the legal issues relating to director nominations, see: Lawrence A. Hamermesh, Director Nominations, 39 DEL. J. CORP. LAW 117 (2014). In an earlier academic article, current Delaware Chief Justice Leo Strine candidly depicted a judge's dueling concerns when adjudicating shareholder claims in a controlled corporation: "Nagging at the judge will be a concern that the [subsidiary] board is going to be unduly responsive to [the controlling shareholder], and that even the independent directors will be subtly influenced by the fact that [the controlling shareholder] has the voting power to unseat them the next time around. On the other hand, the judge will consider that the independent directors were only making a modest director's fee and were persons of some means and reputation. Would such persons approve an unfair transaction if they did not believe in good faith that it was beneficial to [the subsidiary]?"; Leo E. Strine, Jr., The Inescapably Empirical Foundation of the Common Law of Corporations, 27 DEL. J. CORP. LAW 499, 504 (2002). Assaf Hamdani & Ehud Kamar, Hidden Government Influence over Privatized Banks, 13 THEOR. INQ. LAW 567, 580 (2012). 10 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate For these reasons, the infirmaries associated with so-called 'structural bias' are arguably at their most severe in corporations with a controlling shareholder.42 A director's ability to curb and if need be defy the controlling shareholder's wishes is weakened by the fear of relinquishing her post. The preceding analysis does not lead to a conclusion that minority shareholders in controlled corporations are necessarily in worse shape than shareholders in a corporation devoid of a controller. A comprehensive analysis of the benefits and drawbacks associated with controlling shareholders must take into account agency costs that fail to materialize because of the controller’s presence. While long considered a bane in 'bad law' jurisdictions,43 controlling shareholders can prove quite useful for Delaware corporations. The alternative to a controlled corporation is a corporation bereft of a controlling shareholder. In this highly frequent scenario, management of the corporation is entrusted with the board and senior officers. Opportunities for abuse arise when a course of action that is beneficial to management but detrimental to shareholders presents itself.44 Shareholder fragmentation undermines the effectiveness of capital market disciple. Collective action costs facilitate managerial malfeasance, contributing to the suppressed stock price. The counter-factual scenario highlights the benefits associated with controlling shareholders. Unlike dispersed shareholders, a controlling shareholder's considerable equity position provides sufficient financial motivation to actively monitor her investment and initiate corrective action when necessary.45 Monetary incentive is backed by implicit legal power, as ownership of a large share block brings with it the ability to 42 43 44 45 See: Claire A. Hill & Brett H. McDonnell, Disney, Good Faith, and Structural Bias, 32 J. CORP. L. 833, 853 (2006) ("No definitive or consensus definition of structural bias exists. In our view, the strongest case is where a director makes a decision that she knows or ought to know may favor her own interests or those of another director, officer, or controlling stockholder to whom she is beholden over those of the corporation"). While acknowledging the potential infirmaries that potentially rise in these types of situations, recent case law requires shareholder plaintiffs to successfully plead a non-exculpated claim against disinterested, independent directors that approved a suspect transaction with a controlling shareholder; see: In Re Cornerstone Theraputics Inc, Stockholder Litigation, Nos. 564, 706 (Del. 2015). Ronald J. Gilson, Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1641, 1653-1657 (2005). In economic terms, this scenario is referred to as the agency problem; see: Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305 (1976). Stijn Claessens et al., Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings, 57 J. FIN. 2741 (2002) (finding a positive correlation between an increase in the holdings of the largest shareholder and corporate value in eight East Asian economies), Lucian A. Bebchuk & Robert J. Jr Jackson, The Law and Economics of Blockholder Disclosure, 2 HARV. BUS. L. REV. 39, 47-49 (2012) (summarizing empirical evidence of the value of large blockholders on corporate value). But cf. Kobi Kastiel, Executive Compensation in Controlled Companies, 90 IND. L. J. 1131 (2015) (arguing that some controllers might overpay corporate officers in exchange for tacit support of controllers' consumption of private benefits). 11 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate effectuate change in board composition. Efficient controlling shareholders therefore bear monitoring costs that would otherwise be borne (or not) by all shareholders.46 In the same vein, while transactions between the corporation and its controller should make shareholders wary, valid arguments support this common practice. Often, an insider will be the one to offer the best terms to the corporation. This is obvious in situations where the corporation's dire financial situation discourages third parties seeking out a prolonged commercial relationship.47 However, this scenario can also take place in financially viable corporations where informational asymmetries create unbridgeable valuation gaps between the corporation and outsiders.48 A weak bargaining position or an inability to bridge information asymmetries often means that the controlling shareholder's offer is the best available for the corporation.49 Ultimately, this more nuanced calculus informs our position regarding controlling shareholders. As long as the benefits accrued from the duties performed by the controller at least offset the negative aspects, dispersed shareholders are better off. Indeed, since many controllers sacrifice the liquidity benefits enjoyed by other shareholders, a case can be made that minority shareholders tolerate low-level expropriation by controlling shareholders as reparation for their loss of liquidity and compensation for provided services.50 D. Controlling Shareholders and Related Party Transactions The above analysis informs our conclusion that the presence of a controller is not inherently harmful to minority shareholders. Normally, it is safe to assume that corporate agents endeavor to maximize corporate value. However, this assumption is questioned when the controlling shareholder is either a direct or indirect counterparty to the transaction. Even a peripheral awareness of the controller's influence over board composition might erode the agent’s motivation to bargain for the best deal possible for the corporation, or even worse, covertly champion the counterparty’s position.51 46 47 48 49 50 51 Gilson, supra note 44. Ronald J. Gilson, Controlling Family Shareholders in Developing Countries: Anchoring Relational Exchange, 60 STAN. L. REV. 633, 640-641 (2007). STEPHEN M. BAINBRIDGE, CORPORATION LAW AND ECONOMICS 308 (2002). Id. Gilson, supra note 44, at 1652. This does not imply that the corporate agent necessarily acts in bad faith. Unconscious processes unknowingly undermine the effectiveness of even the most subjectively earnest agent; see: Antony Page, Unconscious Bias and the Limits of Director Independence, 2009 U. ILL. L REV. 237, 259-276 (2009) (detailing the unconscious processes that bias the decisionmaking process). 12 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate Different terms have been used to describe the same basic state of affairs.52 The distinguishing attribute of a controlling shareholder related party transaction is a divergence of interests between the controller and the rest of the shareholder base.53 Myriad methods exist though which unscrupulous controllers can extract a disproportionate level of corporate value. A particularly useful dichotomy distinguishes between asset tunneling, cash flow tunneling, and equity tunneling.54 Asset tunneling involves the transfer of productive corporate assets between the corporation and its controlling shareholder.55 Since the corporation's value derives from assets under control, unfair asset pricing directly harms the value of minority shares. In a related party scenario, minority shareholders should be wary that the corporation will overpay to buy assets from the controller and accept low-ball offers to sell assets. Cash flow tunneling differs from asset tunneling in that the corporation's longterm productive assets remain unharmed.56 Obviously, employees and agents should be expected to be compensated for their endeavors on behalf of the corporation. However, owing to the uneven playing field, cash flow tunneling with controlling shareholders diverts what would otherwise be operating cash flow from the firm to the coffers of the controller or affiliated entities.57 By contrast, equity tunneling does not directly affect a corporation's operations. However, equity tunneling allows the controller to increase her ownership share over the corporation's assets, at the expense of minority shareholders.58 Freeze out transactions and dilutive equity issuances, are examples of possible equity tunneling. 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 See, e.g.,: Simon Johnson, et al., Tunneling, 90 AM. ECON. REV. 22, 22 (2000) (tunneling), Simeon Djankov et al., The Law and Economics of Self-Dealing, 88 J. FIN. ECON. 430, 430 (2008) (self-dealing), Claire Hill & Brett McDonnell, Sanitizing Interested Transactions, 36 DEL. J. CORP. L. 903, 904 (2011) (interested transactions) and Lewis H. Lazarus & Brett M. McCartney, Standards of Review in Conflict Transactions on Motions to Dismiss: Lessons Learned in the Past Decade, 36 DEL. J. CORP. L. 967, 972 (2011) (conflict transactions). Most often, the divergence of interests stems from a corporate insider's ability to extract private pecuniary benefits not available to the broad shareholder base; see: ZOHAR GOSHEN & ASSAF HAMDANI, CONCENTRATED OWNERSHIP REVISITED: THE IDIOSYNCRATIC VALUE OF CORPORATE CONTROL (2013), http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2228194 (last visited Sep 21, 2015). This taxonomy is established in Vladimir Atanasov, Bernard Black & Conrad S. Ciccotello, Law and Tunneling, 37 J. CORP. L. 1 (2011). Id, at p.7. Id, at p.6. Excess executive compensation is the emblematic example of cash flow tunneling. See: LUCIAN A. BEBCHUK & JESSE FRIED, PAY WITHOUT PERFORMANCE: THE UNFULFILLED PROMISE OF EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION (2009). Atanasov, Black, and Ciccotello, supra note 55, at p. 8-9. 13 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate This chapter's purpose is to introduce the terms and concepts necessary for the forthcoming analysis. Delaware law recognizes two distinct tests used to unveil the presence of a controlling shareholder: (i) ownership of at least a majority of shares; or (ii) actual domination of the board that resulted in a specific course of action, albeit with ownership of less than a majority of shares. Without more, the existence of a controlling shareholder reveals little about the predicament that minority shareholders find themselves in. While controllers have the capacity to harm minority share value, they can also provide a valuable service. Lawmakers and the courts are expected to craft solutions that balance two competing principles. On one hand, the solution should provide effective protection and redress for minority shareholders that find themselves faced with a potentially dire situation; on the other hand, the solution should minimize unnecessary transaction costs that ultimately harm minority shareholders. The next chapter will focus on Delaware's resourceful use of shifting standards of review to achieve these dual goals. III. Standards of Review in Delaware Law A. Introduction Delaware law has long endeavored to enhance the protection afforded to minority shareholders. Judicial standards of review serve as a crucial component of this effort. Technically, a standard of review is a "test that a court should apply when it reviews an actor's conduct whether to impose liability or grant injunctive relief."59 This modest definition understates the significance that the choice of standard entails. Standards of review in Delaware corporate law differ amongst themselves in the level of judicial scrutiny applied to the challenged board action. Put differently, the selected standard determines the relative deference granted to the corporate defendants.60 Sound policy justifications dictate the types of factual patterns that call for greater or lesser judicial interference.61 Heightened judicial oversight is warranted in situations that question the board's devotion to shareholders' interests. Precise application of the appropriate standard allows the courts to strike a delicate balance between board authority and board accountability. 59 60 61 Melvin Aron Eisenberg, The Divergence of Standards of Conduct and Standards of Review in Corporate Law, 62 FORDHAM L. REV. 437, 437 (1993). William T. Allen, Jack B. Jacobs & Leo E. Strine Jr., Function over Form: A Reassessment of Standards of Review in Delaware Corporation Law, 26 DEL. J. CORP. L. 859, 867 (2001). Id. at 869. 14 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate The most frequently used standard of review involves a relatively lax judicial inquiry over the challenged transaction.62 As long as no discernible divergence of interests with the shareholders exists and the board was reasonably diligent in fulfilling its role, the standard will normally hold.63 Suspect motivations support an upgrade in the applied standard of review and consequent intensity of judicial evaluation. Importantly, employment of self-cleansing mechanisms in the form of qualified decisionmakers allow for a relaxation of the intensity of judicial review. The following sections will more fully describe the three main standards of review under Delaware law64 as well as the settled law regarding shareholder ratification. B. Business Judgment Rule The business judgment rule (BJR) is the default standard of review utilized by Delaware courts to adjudicate a shareholder claim against the board of directors.65 The rule’s animating principal is a judicial attitude of deference towards real-world 62 63 64 65 Laster, supra note 5, at p. 1445 (“At the bottom of the pyramid [of standards of review] is the business judgment rule, which gives the pyramid a capaciously broad foundation”). Two residual doctrines serve as safety valves that allow the court to intervene in apparently non-conflicted situations. The waste standard permits a court to set aside a transfer of assets where the consideration is "so inadequate in value that no person of ordinary, sound business judgment would deem it worth what the corporation has paid"; Saxe v. Brady, 184 A.2d 602, 610 (Del. 1962). The duty to act in good faith is violated when, for instance, "a fiduciary intentionally acts with a purpose other than that of advancing the best interests of the corporation, where the fiduciary acts with the intent to violate applicable positive law, or where the fiduciary intentionally fails to act in the face of a known duty to act, demonstrating a conscious disregard for his duties;" In re Walt Disney Co. Derivative Litigation, 906 A.2d 27, 67 (Del. 2006) (citations omitted). Both of these exceptions are extremely difficult for a plaintiff to meet; see In re Lear Corp. Shareholder Litigation, 967 A.2d 640, 657 (Del. Ch. 2008) (describing the waste standard as a "rigorous test designed to smoke out shady, bad faith deals) and Lyondell Chem. Co. v. Ryan, 970 A.2d 235, 243 (Del. 2009) ("[T]here is a vast difference between an inadequate or flawed effort to carry out fiduciary duties and a conscious disregard for those duties"). “When shareholder litigation challenges actions by boards of directors, generally one of three standards of judicial review is applied” Emerald Partners v. Berlin, 787 A.2d 85, 89 (Del. 2001), reversed on other grounds In Re Cornerstone Theraputics Inc, Stockholder Litigation, (Del. 2015). For slightly differing categorizations of the other standards of review in Delaware, compare Julian Velasco, How Many Fiduciary Duties are There in Corporate Law, 83 S. CAL. L. REV. 1231, 1237-1256 (2009) with Mary Siegel, The Illusion of Enhanced Review of Board Actions, 15 U. PA. J. BUS. L. 599, 602-616 (2012). CITRON V. FAIRCHILD CAMERA & INSTRUMENT, supra note 28, at 64 ("The presumption initially attaches to a director-approved transaction within a board's conferred or apparent authority in the absence of any evidence of fraud, bad faith, or self-dealing in the usual sense of personal profit or betterment" (internal quotations omitted) and Reis v. Hazelett StripCasting Corp., 28 A.3d 442, 457 (Del. Ch. 2011) ("The business judgment rule is the default standard of review"). 15 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate decisions carried out by unconflicted directors.66 Absent well-plead allegations necessary to rebut the rule’s initial presumption, the substantial merits of the business decision are essentially immune from judicial second-guessing.67 Perhaps the most famous formulation68 of the business judgment rule depicts it as "a presumption that in making a business decision, the directors of a corporation acted on an informed basis, in good faith and in the honest belief that the action taken was in the best interests of the company."69 The respect afforded to well thought-out business decisions is grounded in more than judicial humility. Adoption of the rule facilitates shareholder value maximization. Rational and diversified shareholders would prefer that their elected directors advance investment projects with the highest risk adjusted rate of return.70 The rule's de-facto prohibition against second-guessing failed business decisions empowers directors to overcome understandable risk-aversion and fear of being sued.71 Competitive markets police simple mismanagement ruthlessly and 66 67 68 69 70 71 D. GORDON SMITH, THE MODERN BUSINESS JUDGMENT RULE, http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2620536 (last visited Jun 19, 2015), at *5 ("[T]he crucial feature of the business judgment rule.. is not a presumption that the directors have acted well, but rather a commitment not to question the substance of director action when there is no proof that the directors have acted badly"). While one prominent scholar characterizes the business judgment rule as an abstention doctrine, litigation realities lead to court oversight over the process adopted by the directors at the outset of the litigation; cf. Bainbridge, supra note 32 with SMITH, supra at *7 and E. Norman Veasey & Christine T. Di Guglielmo, What Happened in Delaware Corporate Law and Governance from 1992-2004? A Retrospective on Some Key Developments, 153 U. PA. L. REV. 1399, 1421 (2005) ("[T]he focus of the business judgment rule remains on the process that directors use in reaching their decisions"). CITRON V. FAIRCHILD CAMERA & INSTRUMENT, supra note 28, at 64 ("The burden falls upon the proponent of a claim to rebut the presumption by introducing evidence either of director self-interest, if not self-dealing, or that the directors either lacked good faith or failed to exercise due care"). In order to rebut the business judgment rule's presumption of care, a plaintiff must plead and later prove gross negligence; see Brehm v. Eisner, 746 A.2d 244, 264 (Del. 2000). Siegel, supra note 68, at p. 602 ("Perhaps the most often quoted description of the business judgment rule is found in Aronson v. Lewis") and SMITH, supra note 71 at *5 ("Over the years, the presumption [of good faith] expanded and contracted in various ways before achieving its modern form in Aronson v. Lewis"). Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d 805, 812 (Del. 1984), overruled on other grounds by Brehm v. Eisner, 746 A.2d 244 (Del. 2000). Gagliardi v. TriFoods Intern., Inc., 683 A.2d 1049, 1052 (Del. Ch. 1996). Roberta Romano, Corporate Governance in the Aftermath of the Insurance Crisis, 39 EMORY L. J. 1155, 1160 (1990) (detailing how 42 states reacted to a perceived insurance crisis by amending their corporation statutes to reduce directors' liability exposure). The question of optimal liability exposure is an open debate in corporate law. It is entirely possible that an overly lax corporate law might be detrimental to shareholders' interests; see Michal Barzuza & David C. Smith, What Happens in Nevada? Self-Selecting into Lax Law, REV. FINANC. STUD. (forthcoming 2014) (finding that firms prone to financial reporting failures are more likely to reincorporate in a state with lax corporate law). 16 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate efficiently.72 Insulation from shareholder intervention in a regular business setting has the added value of preserving board authority.73 The business judgment rule is the starting off point in a judicial inquiry of a challenged board action. Judicial respect towards outcomes produced by rational business procedures usually results in a loss for the plaintiff.74 The next sections will depict less defendant-friendly standards of review. C. Enhanced Scrutiny The educated belief that non-conflicted directors are innately motivated to maximize shareholder value heavily influences the business judgment rule's deferential attitude. Creeping suspicions about the board's true motivations therefore chip away at the rule's basic assumption and invite heightened judicial involvement. Delaware courts carry out this involvement through the medium of more exacting standards of review. Enhanced scrutiny is Delaware's intermediate standard of review.75 The standard applies in factual situations that call into question a director's ability to impartially advance shareholders' best interests.76 Two main transactional archetypes lead to application of this standard.77 Board defensive responses in the face of a hostile takeover attempt epitomize the first factual pattern that warrants application of enhanced scrutiny. A successful hostile takeover results in removal of incumbent board members. The "omnipresent specter" surrounding the board's self-serving motivation justifies subjecting the selected reaction to a more stringent judicial examination.78 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 REIS V. HAZELETT STRIP-CASTING CORP., supra note 66, at p. 458. STEPHEN M. BAINBRIDGE, CORPORATION LAW AND ECONOMICS 268 (2002). Nixon v. Blackwell, 626 A.2d 1366, 1376 (Del. 1993) ("It is sometimes thought that the decision to apply the business judgment rule or the entire fairness test can be outcomedeterminative"). REIS V. HAZELETT STRIP-CASTING CORP., supra note 69 at p. 457. Id. ("Enhanced scrutiny applies when the realities of the decision-making context can subtly undermine the decisions of even independent and disinterested directors"). Enhanced scrutiny is also applied to adjudicate board postponement of a shareholder meeting that does not deal with director elections; see Mercier v. Inter-Tel (Delaware), Inc., 929 A.2d 786 (Del. Ch. 2007) (applying enhanced scrutiny instead of the more demanding Blasius standard to a board decision to postpone a shareholder vote on an impending merger so as to provide more information and not jeopardize what the board believes to be an irrevocable loss of a pending offer). Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d 946, 954 (Del. 1985). 17 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate In this context, enhanced scrutiny consists of a two-part analysis conducted by the courts. The first part of the test requires corporate defendants to prove reasonable grounds for believing that a danger to corporate policy existed.79 After proving that, the directors must then prove that their response was reasonable relative to the threat posed.80 The second main fact-pattern that engenders enhanced scrutiny is colloquially referenced by the seminal case that introduced the analysis.81 In what would become a cornerstone of Delaware jurisprudence, the Supreme Court held that the broad deference usually afforded to the board of directors no longer applies in the face of an impending sale or break-up of the corporation. When finding itself in this situation, the board's raison d'etre focuses on "maximization of the company's value at a sale for the stockholder's benefit."82 While subsequent cases have attempted to clarify what a "sale or break-up" of the corporation entails,83 recent scholarship still grapples with this seemingly unsettled issue.84 Since even a self-initiated sale of the corporation results in broad personnel changes amongst the corporate hierarchy, enhanced judicial scrutiny attempts to weed out subtle manipulation of the sales process. In a Revlon setting, the burden shifts to the board to prove that they have taken reasonable steps to ensure shareholders receive the best price possible for their shares. Although the term "auctioneer" was originally used to describe the board's new function,85 subsequent decisions clarified that there is no single blueprint for the board to follow.86 In sum, the policy justifications that counsel against judicial interference hold considerably less sway when directors are faced with the tangible prospect of 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 Id., at 955. Id. Significant refinement of the Unocal doctrine occurred in Unitrin, Inc. v. American General Corp., 651 A.2d 1361, 1387-1390 (Del. 1995) (a reasonable response by the board must be neither coercive nor preclusive, and should not impinge on the shareholder's ability to vote directors out of office). See for example, Lyman Johnson & Robert Ricca, The Dwindling of Revlon, 71 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 167 (2014), and Stephen M. Bainbridge, The Geography of Revlon-Land, 81 FORDHAM L. REV. 3277 (2012), which obviously inspired this article's title. Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, 506 A.2d 173, 182 (Del. 1986). Most famously, Paramount Communications v. QVC Network, 637 A.2d 34, 47-48 (Del. 1994) (for the purpose of the Revlon test, a "sale" occurs when the consummation of a transaction introduces a new controlling shareholder to an entity previously has none). Cf. Bainbridge, supra note 82. (arguing that the Revlon standard of review is motivated by a conflicts of interest) with Mohsen Manesh, Defined by Dictum: The Geography of RevlonLand in Cash and Mixed Consideration Transactions, 59 VILL. L. REV. 1 (2014) (refuting Bainbridge's claim). A recent article authored by Vice-Chancellor Laster professes his personal views that the Revlon standard should apply in all final-period transactions, regardless of choice of consideration; see J. Travis Laster, Revlon Is a Standard of Review: Why It’s True and What It Means, 19 FORD. J. CORP. FIN. L. 5 (2013). REVLON, INC. V. MACANDREWS & FORBES HOLDINGS, supra note 83 at p. 184. Johnson and Ricca, supra note 85, at p. 189-193 (summarizing subsequent holdings detailing the board's proper conduct in the sales process). 18 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate relinquishing their post. Unocal and Revlon situations place the onus on the board to prove the reasonableness of their actions. While not an extremely difficult test to pass,87 the enhanced scrutiny standard of review allows a certain degree of judicial oversight in inherently problematic settings. The next section will detail the most extracting standard of review in a transactional setting. D. Entire Fairness An inverse correlation exists between the severity of the impediments that possibly undermine corporate decisionmaker's ability to advance shareholder interests and the applicable standard of review. The differential default standard transforms into enhanced scrutiny when the challenged board action implicates the director's continued incumbency. Full-fledged conflicts of interest between the corporation and members of the corporate hierarchy necessitate a further upgrade in the intensity of judicial oversight. Immediate realization of profit in a related party transaction usually more than offsets the prospect of market discipline.88 Delaware law accordingly requires that these transactions pass through the filter of entire fairness review. A helpful preliminary taxonomy of related party transactions distinguishes between director self-dealing and controlling shareholder self-dealing. As long as the director's conflict is sufficiently disclosed and approved by an otherwise independent and disinterested board, even a direct transaction with a corporate director will enjoy the presumptions afforded by the business judgment rule.89 In order to rebut the business judgment rule's application regarding director self-dealing, a shareholder has 87 88 89 MERCIER V. INTER-TEL (DELAWARE), INC., supra note 81 at p. 810 ("I recognize.. that some of the prior Unocal case law gave reason to fear that that standard, and the related Revlon standard, were being denuded into simply another name for business judgment review" (footnotes omitted). Mary Siegal provides data that defendants are able to pass Unocal and Revlon scrutiny almost 80% of the time the standards are evoked; see Siegel, supra note 68, at p. 621, 629. FRANK H. EASTERBROOK & DANIEL R. FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPORATE LAW (1996),at p. 103 ("Duty-of-loyalty problems often involve spectacular, one-shot appropriations, of the "take the money and run" sort, in which subsequent penalties through markets are inadequate"); see also Claire Hill & Brett McDonnell, Sanitizing Interested Transactions, 36 DEL. J. CORP. L. 903, 908-909 (2011) ("[T]he law has long treated self-dealing with suspicion. The reasons for the suspicion are obvious: If the leading decisionmakers, or those with strong influence over such decisionmakers, can gain personally by making a decision that hurts the corporation, they may make decisions that benefit them at the corporation's expense"). Telxon Corp. v. Meyerson, 802 A.2d 257, 264 (Del. 2002) ("Where only one director has an interest in a transaction, however, a plaintiff seeking to rebut the presumption of the business judgment rule under the duty of loyalty must show that the interested director controls or dominates the board as a whole") (internal quotations omitted). 19 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate to plead facts demonstrating that a majority of the board either had a financial interest in the transaction or was otherwise dominated by a materially interested director.90 In this context, the Delaware Supreme Court has identified independence to exist in situations where "a director's decision is based on the corporate merits of the subject before the board rather than extraneous considerations or influences."91 Overcoming the presumption of director independence relies on "pleading facts that support a reasonable inference that the director is beholden to a controlling person or so under their influence that their discretion would be sterilized."92 The Aronson court additionally articulated what would be recognized as the canonical definition for director self-interest.93 In order to be considered disinterested, a director "can neither appear on both sides of a transaction nor expect to derive any personal financial benefit from it in the sense of self-dealing, as opposed to a benefit which devolves upon the corporation or all stockholders generally."94 Subsequent cases have clarified that director self-interest is not limited to direct personal dealings with a corporation, and further manifests in situations where the director has a stake in or serves as an executive at the corporation's counterparty.95 The pecuniary benefit creates a disqualifying interest, regardless of whether or not the benefit was in fact material for the director.96 Even more nuances affect the applied standard of review for transactions with a controlling shareholder. The relationship between the strands of authority that 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 The pleading requirement stems from Chancery Court Rule 23.1, which requires a shareholder plaintiff prosecuting a derivative action to "allege with peculiarity" reasons for not making a demand on the board of directs. ARONSON V. LEWIS, supra note 73, at 812 ("[I]f such director interest is present, and the transaction is not approved by a majority consisting of the disinterested directors, then the business judgment rule has no application whatever in determining demand futility"). See also Laster, supra note 5, at p. 1455 ("To change the standard of review from the business judgment rule to entire fairness, a plaintiff must show that there were not enough independent, disinterested, and sufficiently informed individuals who acted in good faith when making the challenged decision to constitute a board majority"). ARONSON V. LEWIS, supra note 73, at p. 816. IN RE KKR FINANCIAL HOLDINGS LLC, supra note 7, at *25 (internal quotations omitted). For examples of a paralyzing interest, see Harbor Finance Partners v. Huizenga, 751 A.2d 879, 889 (Del. Ch. 1999) (familial relationship casts doubt on a director's ability to impartially consider a board demand), and New Jersey Carpenters Pension Fund v. Infogroup, Inc., C.A. No. 5334-VCN (Del. Ch. Oct. 6, 2011) (ostensibly independent directors were actually the control of a dominant and bullying blockholder and member of the board). IN RE CRIMSON EXPLORATION INC. STOCKHOLDER LITIGATION, supra note 38, at *51 ("Aronson v. Lewis set forth the now-standard definitions for the terms "interested" and "independent") (footnote omitted). ARONSON V. LEWIS, supra note 73, at p. 812 (citations omitted). Cinerama, Inc. v. Technicolor, Inc., 663 A.2d 1156, 1169 (Del. 1995) (subsequent history omitted) (citing 8 Del. § 144(a)). See also Rales v. Blasband, 634 A.2d 927, 936 (Del. 1993) ("Directorial interest also exists where a corporate decision will have a materially detrimental impact on the director, but not on the corporation and the stockholders"). Cambridge Retirement System v. Bosnjak, C.A. No. 9178-CB (Del. Ch. June 26, 2014), at *9. 20 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate govern going private and non-going private transactions with a controlling shareholder will be dealt with at length in Chapter IV. Regardless of whether or not the transaction consummates with the elimination of minority shareholders, the authorities seem to be in agreement that entire fairness applies in situations where the controlling shareholder engages in a conflicted transaction.97 A direct transaction between the controller and the corporation is the essence of a conflicted transaction.98 Under certain conditions, going-private transaction with a bona fide third party can also lead to application of entire fairness review. Although Delaware law imposes minimal restrictions on the controller's ability to sell her shares at a premium,99 receipt of unequal consideration in a going-private transaction will invite entire fairness review. Unequal consideration may manifest in either a tangible or non-tangible form. Higher prices for the same class of shares or a continuing equity stake in the surviving entity are examples of a tangible unequal consideration.100 Unavoidable competition for a larger proportion of the deal consideration necessitates heightened court involvement. Extinguishment of a derivative claim or immediate realization of much-needed liquidity are examples of a non-tangible unique benefit.101 Although receipt of prorata treatment should usually assuage minority shareholder' fears of misappropriation,102 the controller's acceptance of a unique benefit might detract from the price ultimately offered for all shares. The definitive formulation of the entire fairness test has remained virtually the same for three decades: "The concept of fairness has two basic aspects: fair dealing 97 98 99 100 101 102 IN RE CRIMSON EXPLORATION INC. STOCKHOLDER LITIGATION, supra note 38, at p. 30. Kahn v. Lynch Communication Systems, 638 A.2d 1110, 1115 (Del. 1994) ("A controlling or dominating shareholder standing on both sides of a transaction, as in a parent-subsidiary context, bears the burden of proving its entire fairness"). The main competitor for the primary doctrine regarding controlling shareholder self-dealing includes an additional wrinkle that the controlling shareholder is able to extract from the corporation a benefit to the exclusion of, and detriment to, the minority stockholders of the corporation; see: Sinclair Oil Corporation v. Levien, 280 A.2d 717, 720 (Del. 1971). Abraham v. Emerson Radio Corp., 901 A.2d 751, 753 (Del. Ch. 2006) ("Under Delaware law, a controller remains free to sell its stock for a premium not shared with other stockholders except in very narrow circumstances"). Examples of these very narrow circumstances exist when the controller has entered into a contractual commitment not to receive a premium or she knows that the buyer is a looter or was aware of circumstances that would alert a reasonably prudent person to a risk that the buyer was dishonest in a material aspect; see In re Delphi Fin. Gp. S'holder Litig., 2012 WL 729323 (Del. Ch. Mar. 6, 2012) and Harris v. Carter, 582 A.2d 222, 235 (Del.1990). IN RE CRIMSON EXPLORATION INC. STOCKHOLDER LITIGATION, supra note 38, *31-33 (analyzing and generating a rule from In re Tel-Communications, Inc. S'holder Litig., 2005 WL 3642727 (Del. Ch. Jan. 10, 2006), In re Delphi Fin. Gp. S'holder Litig., 2012 WL 729232 (Del. Ch. Mar. 6, 2012), In re John Q. Hammons Hotels Inc. S'holder Litig., 2009 WL 3165613 (Del. Ch. Oct. 2, 2009), and In re LNR Prop. Corp. S'holder Litig., 896 A.2d 169 (Del. Ch. 2005)). In re Primedia, Inc. Shareholders Litig., 67 A.3d 455 (Del. Ch. 2013) and In re Synthes, Inc. Shareholder Litigation, 50 A.3d 1022 (Del. Ch. 2012). IN RE SYNTHES, INC. SHAREHOLDER LITIGATION, supra note 105, at p. 1039-1040. 21 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate and fair price. The former embraces questions of when the transaction was timed, how it was initiated, structured, negotiated, disclosed to the directors, and how the approvals of the directors and the stockholders were obtained. The latter aspect of fairness relates to the economic and financial considerations of the proposed merger, including all relevant factors: assets, market value, earnings, future prospects, and any other elements that affect the intrinsic or inherent value of a company's stock. However, the test for fairness is not a bifurcated one as between fair dealing and price. All aspects of the issue must be examined as a whole since the question is one of entire fairness."103 Special attention is called to the relationship between a motion to dismiss and the standard of review.104 A successful motion results in the immediate dismissal of the shareholder complaint. A failed motion adds discovery and trial costs to the already substantial transaction bill.105 Importantly, application of the entire fairness standard proves a near-insurmountable obstacle for a defendant's motion to dismiss.106 The chosen standard's influence on the litigation dynamic guarantees that it remains one of the most heavily debated aspects in corporate litigation.107 Onerous standards of review invite some of the more unscrupulous and entrepreneurial members of the plaintiffs' bar to file hastily crafted complaints in an effort to secure settlements that offer no discernible advantage to the remaining shareholders.108 The next section will detail how careful implementation of corporate self-cleansing mechanisms allows for a downgrade in the severity of the standard of review. E. Downgrading from Entire Fairness 103 104 105 106 107 108 Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 711 (Del. 1983) (internal citations omitted). Court of Chancery Rule 12 governs the motion for judgment at the pleadings stage. Importantly, Rule 12(b)(6) allows defendants to file a motion to dismiss for "failure to state a claim upon which relief can be granted". To be sure, it is still possible for the defendant to prevail in proving the entire fairness of the transaction. For examples of defendant success in proving entire fairness, see: CINERAMA, INC. V. TECHNICOLOR, INC., supra note 99, NIXON V. BLACKWELL, supra note 78, and Kahn v. Lynch Communication Systems, 669 A.2d 79 (Del. 1995). Even when entire fairness undoubtedly applies, the complaint must contain well-plead allegations disputing either the fair price or fair process of the transaction. See: Monroe Cnty. Emps. Ret. Sys. V. Carlson, 2010 WL 2376890, at *2 (Del. Ch. June 7, 2010) ("Delaware law is clear that even where a transaction between the controlling shareholder and the company is involved – such that entire fairness review is in play – plaintiff must make factual allegations about the transaction in the complaint that demonstrate the absence of fairness") and Ravenswood Investment Company, L.P. v. Winmill, C.A. No. 3730-VCN (Del. Ch. May 31, 2011). Lewis H. Lazarus, Standards of Review in Conflict Transactions: An Examination of Decisions Rendered on Motions to Dismiss, 26 DEL. J. CORP. L. 911, 926 (2001). Johnson and Ricca, supra note 85, at p. 168. 22 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate Higher standards of review all but ascertain that a shareholder complaint survives a motion to dismiss. The credible threat of a prolonged and costly trial is arguably at the root of what some consider a non-meritorious litigation epidemic.109 Conditioning the transaction on the approval of qualified decisionmakers offers transactional planners a way to downgrade the standard of review and thus recover from a tactical litigation disadvantage.110 The collective wisdom of qualified decisionmakers is considered a suitable substitute for court oversight. A clarifying note on terminology is warranted at the outset. Although frequently used, "ratification" is not the most precise legal term to describe the selfcleansing mechanism. In agency law, ratification consists of "the affirmance of a prior act done by another, whereby the act is given effect as if done by an agent acting with actual authority."111 Most shareholder challenges against corporate acts focus on potential breaches of fiduciary duties, not a lack of actual authority. The selfcleansing mechanisms are not intended to confer actual authority upon the corporate actors, but to de-escalate the standard of review.112 Two equally competent corporate organs form the core of the Delaware selfcleansing framework:113 a committee of independent and disinterested directors and a disinterested shareholder vote.114 109 110 111 112 113 Cain & Davidoff Solomon, footnote 30 supra. One recent study found that plaintiff attorneys filed lawsuits in 93% of all mergers and acquisition deals announced in 2014 and valued at over $100 million. For Delaware-incorporated firms, plaintiffs filed lawsuits either exclusively in Delaware or in conjunction with litigation in other courts on 88% of the deals. Merger and acquisition oriented lawsuits obviously implicate either the enhanced scrutiny or entire fairness standard of review, thus considerably raising the complaint's probability of surviving a motion to dismiss. Cornerstone Research, Shareholder Litigation Involving Acquisitions of Public Companies – Review of 2014 M&A Litigation, at 2-3. Scott V. Simpson & Katherine Brody, The Evolving Role of Special Committees in M&A Transactions: Seeking Business Judgment Rule Protection in the Context of Controlling Shareholder Transactions and Other Corporate Transactions Involving Conflicts of Interest, 69 BUS. LAW. 1117, 1120 (2014) ("[T]he ability to structure a board's process in connection with its consideration of a transaction such that its decisions will benefit from the protection of the business judgment rule provides significant practical comfort that its decisions will not be overturned by a court"). Restatement (3rd) of Agency §4.01 (2006). SMITH, supra note 67, at *3 ("The modern business judgment rule is applied not only in cases without procedural infirmities, but in cases where procedural infirmities at the board level have been mitigated by a special committee, stockholder approval, or partial substantive review by the courts. In these new contexts, a court must satisfy itself that a board decision is worthy of respect, not because the decision was substantively correct, but because the effect of the procedural infirmities was sufficiently muted"). The corporation, as an artificial entity, requires actors to act on its behalf. A corporate organ is one such actor. An organ, such as the board of directors or a stockholder general assembly, acts on the corporation's behalf but is not subject to its control; Amitai Aviram, Officers’ Fiduciary Duties and the Nature of Corporate Organs, 2013 U. ILL. L. REV. 763, 768 (2013). See also Arnold v. Soc'y for Sav. Bancorp, Inc., 678 A.2d 533, 539-540 (Del. 1996) ("Directors, in the ordinary course of their service as directors, do not act as agents of the corporation… An 23 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate Reliance on independent director committees is a natural extension to the respect Delaware law affords the board of directors. Absent a disabling conflict for a majority of the board, the courts are reluctant to intrude into the realm of business judgment. Deference to the wisdom of the board is no longer justifiable when a majority of the board is conflicted. Importantly, the DGCL permits the board to cede a portion of its authority to a board committee.115 The logic behind the refusal to impinge on the authority of a non-conflicted board equally applies to a non-conflicted and duly authorized board committee.116 By itself, this legislative interpretation would have a hard time justifying the deference afforded to a committee of qualified directors. Even legally independent and disinterested directors cannot erase a joint history of mutual service. Unchecked camaraderie can potentially undermine the committee's ability to carry out its function. Adherence to court-mandated guidelines designed to weed out lingering biases or structural dependencies is therefore an essential component of this selfcleansing avenue. Insulation from even the hint of undue influence substantially reinforces the committee's resolve to impartially review the merits of the proposed transaction. An independent stockholder vote is the second independent element of Delaware's self-cleansing mechanism.117 Subjecting key events in the corporation's life to stockholder approval is supported by several complimentary justifications. Even in the cradle of director primacy, the stockholder vote remains the "ideological 114 115 116 117 agent acts under the control of the principal. The board of directors of a corporation is charged with the ultimate responsibility to manage or direct the management of the business and affairs of the corporation. A board of directors, in fulfilling its fiduciary duty, controls the corporation, not vice versa" (citations omitted)). The resemblance between the two organs comprising the Delaware ratification process and Section 144 of the DGCL is easily discernable. An apparent resemblance does not mean that Section 144 governs the ratification procedure. Section 144 was enacted in order to counteract the old common law principle that voided related party transactions and provide transaction planners a road map to avoid such a fate; see: Blake Rohrbacher et. al., Finding Safe Harbor: Clarifying the Limited Application of Section 144, 33 DEL. J. CORP. L. 719, 719720 (2008). Determination of "when an interested transaction might give rise to a claim for breach of fiduciary duty … was left to the common law of corporations to answer;" In re Cox Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d 604, 615 (Del. Ch. 2005). DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, Sect. 141(c). Laster, supra note 4, at 1456. Previous case law can be read to create an analytical distinction between "classic" shareholder ratification and instances where a stockholder vote was a necessary step in authorizing the transaction, such as a statutory merger or amendment to the certificate of incorporation. A recent Chancery Court opinion clarified that the stockholder self-cleansing doctrine applies with equal force to both types of stockholder votes; see: IN RE KKR FINANCIAL HOLDINGS LLC, supra note 11, at 1002 ("Although the language from the Supreme Court's decision quoted above could be interpreted to imply that the legal effect of a fully informed stockholder vote would be different when the vote was voluntary as opposed to statutorily required, I do not read it that way"). 24 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate underpinning upon which the legitimacy of directorial powers rests".118 Under this view, the voting mechanism aggregates the preferences of the stockholder constituency and thus legitimizes the chosen course of action.119 A slightly different rationalization focuses on the accountability aspect of the stockholder vote. Conflicts of interest are an unavoidable consequence of publicly traded corporations. Subjecting a contentious course of action to stockholder approval serves to align the interests of the corporate directors with those of the entire stockholder base. The stockholder vote thus functions as a means to reduce the likelihood of a self-serving error by the original corporate actors.120 Implicit in both of these views is the fact that rational stockholders vote for their own interests.121 Manipulation of the process invalidates the cleansing effect of the stockholder vote. Courts therefore police the voting mechanism in order to prevent substantive coercion and ensure that stockholders are given enough information from which to arrive at an informed decision. After detailing the independent components of the self-cleansing mechanism, I will now explain their effect on the entire fairness standard of review.122 A starting dichotomy distinguishes between the entire fairness standard that stems from a majority-conflicted board and entire fairness resulting from a related party transaction with a controlling shareholder. The effect of a competent approval by either a qualified director committee or a qualified stockholder vote when no controlling shareholder is involved is relatively straightforward. Valid approval by either one of the corporate organs reaffirms the presumptions of the business judgment rule to the transaction.123 Once the business 118 119 120 121 122 123 Blasius Industries, Inc. v. Atlas Corp., 564 A.2d 651, 659 (Del. 1988). FAIRFAX, supra note 38, at p. 29. Robert B. Thompson & Paul H. Edelman, Corporate Voting, 62 VAND. L. REV. 127, 132-133 (2009). Laster, supra note 4, at p. 1457 ("[S]tockholders are collectively well-positioned to decide whether to endorse what the board did, and that for purposes of determining how easy it should be for a stockholder plaintiff to challenge the action taken by the board (i.e., to determine the standard of review), a court should take into account and defer to an uncoerced endorsement from fully informed, disinterested stockholders"). Vice-Chancellor Laster recently professed his scholarly view that a qualified stockholder vote lower the standard of review from enhanced scrutiny to the business judgment rule; see: Laster, supra note 4, p. 1463-1470. See Valeant Pharmaceuticals Intern. v. Jerney, 921 A.2d 732, 745-746 (Del. Ch. 2007) (Approval by a well-functioning independent director compensation committee reaffirms the presumptions of the business judgment rule to the interested transaction) and IN RE KKR FINANCIAL HOLDINGS LLC, supra note 11, at p. 1001 (Approval by a fully-informed stockholder vote of a transaction with a non-controlling stockholder reaffirms the presumptions of the business judgment rule to the transaction). 25 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate judgment rule applies, judicial review is presumably limited to issues of gift or waste with the burden of proof upon the plaintiffs.124 Introduction of a controlling shareholder adds some uncertainty to the analysis. Until fairly recently, it was seemingly well-settled that a self-dealing transaction with a controlling shareholder would without fail evoke the entire fairness standard of review.125 The controlling shareholder's superior bargaining position and ability to extract revenge should the corporate agents refuse to bow down to her demand necessitated continuous court oversight.126 The Delaware Supreme Court clarified that at most, defendants can receive a shift in the burden of proof properly employing one of the self-cleansing mechanisms.127 Critically, the above holding was rendered in connection with a going-private merger with a controlling shareholder. Confusion exists regarding the degree of overlap between the line of holdings governing going-private mergers and those applicable to controlling shareholder related party transaction that do not constitute a going-private merger.128 Since both strands arrived at the same result of heightened judicial scrutiny, this confusion had little practical effect and did not engender a torrent of judicial or scholarly commentary. All this changed once the Delaware courts accepted the notion that effective employment of both self-cleansing mechanisms prior to effectuating a going-private merger with a controlling shareholder will subject the transaction to business judgment rule review. Suddenly, the relationship between the holdings applicable to going-private transactions and those applicable to going-concern transactions has 124 125 126 127 128 IN RE WHEELABRATOR TECH. SHAREHOLDERS LIT., supra note 11, at 1200 (the effect of the informed stockholder vote is to invoke the business judgment standard, which limits review to issues of gift or waste with the burden of proof upon the plaintiffs). KAHN V. LYNCH COMMUNICATION SYSTEMS, supra note 99, at 1116. This determination would not change even if the majority of the board was independent from the controlling shareholder; see EMERALD PARTNERS V. BERLIN, supra note 2, at 96-97 (overturned on other grounds in IN RE CORNERSTONE THERAPUTICS INC, STOCKHOLDER LITIGATION, supra note 43). Id, at 1116-1117 (quoting Citron v. EI Du Pont de Nemours & Co., 584 A.2d 490, 502 (Del. 1990). KAHN V. LYNCH COMMUNICATION SYSTEMS, supra note 99, at 1117. The practical effect of the burden shift is subject to debate; for Chief Justice Strine's view (as Vice-Chancellor), see In re Cysive, Inc. Shareholders Litigation, 836 A.2d 531, 548 (Del. Ch. 2003) ("The practical effect of the Lynch doctrine's burden shift is slight. One reason why this is so is that shifting the burden of persuasion under a preponderance standard is not a major move, if one assumes, as I do, that the outcome of very few cases hinges on what happens if in the evidence is in equipoise"). Hill and McDonnell, supra note 53, at 923-924 ("[I]t is somewhat unclear whether the Weinberger entire fairness framework applies only to freezeout acquisitions, or whether it applies to all transactions in which a shareholder has a controlling interest… The applicability of Weinberger outside of the freezeout context is an open and important question"). Professors Gilson, Gordon, and Khanna seem to believe that going concern related party transactions are governed by different authority than freeze out mergers. See Gilson and Gordon, supra note 12 and Vikramaditya Khanna, The Growth of the Fiduciary Duty Class Actions for Freeze Out Mergers: Weinberger v. UOP, Inc. in MACEY, supra note 2. 26 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate gained practical import. Accordingly, the next section will trace the doctrinal evolution applicable to each type of transaction. IV. Questioning MFW's Reach – Doctrine a. Introduction At the heart of the MFW decision,129 the Delaware Supreme Court overturned long-standing precedent and decreed that defendants orchestrating a going-private merger with a controlling shareholder are entitled to a deferential judicial standard of review, so long as they effectively employ two procedural safeguards: (i) a special board committee composed of disinterested and duly authorized directors equipped with independent counsel and advisors and (ii) conditioning the consummation of the transaction on a non-revocable acceptance by a majority of minority shareholders. This latest ruling invites further analysis and review. The decision makes it clear that the holding applies to going-private transactions with a controlling shareholder. Moreover, the decision provides an admirable articulation of the underlying policy rationales responsible for the doctrinal shift. Unfortunately, the decision lacks any reference to the multitude of other factual situations that would otherwise compel entire fairness review of a transaction undertaken with a controlling shareholder. Thus, business planners are left with an unanswered question following the MFW decision: what effect, if any, does proper employment of both of the selfcleansing mechanisms have in those scenarios? b. MFW and the Unification of Final Period Review [depicting the coherent evolution of the standard of review applicable to going private transactions – ed.] c. Standards of Review for Going-Concern RPTs 129 Kahn v. M & F Worldwide Corp., 88 A.3d 635 (Del. 2014) (affirming In re MFW S'holders Litig., 67 A.3d 496 (Del. Ch. 2013)). 27 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate [depicting the standards of review applicable to RPTs with a controlling shareholder that do not conclude with the elimination of minority shareholders. In contrast with the coherent evolution found in going private transactions, diverging strands of authority govern this type of transaction. There are no compelling textual justifications found in the cases to conclude that the MFW standard applies to going-concern transactions as well – ed.] V. Questioning MFW's Reach – Policy a. Independent Board Committees – A Critique One does not have to be overly cynical in order to question the utility of allowing committees composed of nominally independent directors to serve as the first line of defense against potentially abusive RPTs. While bereft of noticeable material connections to the corporation, the controlling shareholder or the transaction at hand, this does not ensure that independent directors obtain optimal results for shareholders. Opponents of the 'director independence movement' focus their criticism along two main fronts: (1) the overarching presumption that director independence leads to director objectivity similar to which is found in a bona fide arm's-length counterparty; and, even assuming that such objectivity exists, (2) the utility that independent directors add to the corporation. We begin by taking a closer look at the argument questioning the independent director's actual objectivity. Corporate governance reforms promoting director independence rely on the assumption that independent directors add much needed objectivity to the board. This objectivity is crucial to combating complacent tendencies that undermine the board's effectiveness. However, numerous studies have shown that formal independence by itself does not lead to an ability to overcome the psychological factors that damper actual objectivity. Independent directors are generally pre-approved by the controlling shareholder and the incumbent board. At least tacit support and an affirmative vote by the controller are essential in elevating the director to his esteemed position.130 Gratitude towards the controller and the other board members contributes to the wideheld notion that "none of the outside directors are likely to bite the hand that feeds them."131 130 Lucien Bebchuk, The Myth of the Shareholder Franchise, 93 VA. L. REV. 675, 677 ("[F]or directors of public companies, the incidence of replacement by a rival slate seeking to manage the company better as a stand-alone entity is negligible"). 131 Stephen M. Bainbridge CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AFTER THE FINANCIL CRISIS 88. See also Claire A. Hill, Brett McDonnell, Disney, Good Faith and Structural Bias, 32 J. CORP. L. 834, 853 (2007) 28 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate Following the appointment, additional phenomena identified in the social psychology literature further weakens the ability of an independent director to replicate the bargaining dynamic such as that found with an objective counterparty. While the courts definition of independence ostensibly encompasses more than just financial relationships, commentators versed in the intricacies of Delaware law conclude that in practice a director's designation of independence is rarely invalidated by anything but financial ties.132 Maintaining the focus on financial ties neglects objectivity-hampering norms and biases that emanate from repeated interactions between members of a close-knit and highly-esteemed group such as a board of directors. In-group bias arises from human beings' natural tendency to categorize people around them.133 The basic partition distinguishes between individuals that belong to one's in-group from those that do not.134 An innate affinity subsequently flows towards other members of the ingroup.135 This affinity translates into a placating disposition toward members of the in-group that does not extend to members of the out-group. Application of this phenomenon in the board context has led commentators to question the ability of technically independent directors to achieve true objectivity.136 ("[P]otentially touching every director's decision is her desire to keep her director position. Doing so depends on whether she stays in management's good graces") and Lucien Bebchuk, Jesse Fried, PAY WITHOUT PERFORMANCE: THE UNFULFILLED PROMISE OF EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION pp. 25-27 (2006). 132 Lisa M. Fairfax, The Elusive Quest for the Inside Director, (in RESEARCH HANDBOOK OF THE ECONOMICS OF CORPORATE LAW), 174; see also J. Robert Brown, Disloyalty Without Limits: "Independent" Directors and the Elimination of the Duty of Loyalty, 95 KY. L. J. 53 (2006). One of the most famous or notorious examples, depending on one's point of view, for a court finding that sustained social connections do not create a disabling conflict is found In re Martha Stewart 845 A.2d 1040, 1051-52. (Del. 2004). 133 C. Neil Macrae, Galen V. Bodenhausen, Social Cognition: Thinking Categorically About Others, 51 ANNU. REV. PSYCHOL. 93 (2000). This categorization is a heuristic shortcut used to help arrange the overflow of information the mind is constantly forced to decipher; D. H. J. Wigboldus, et al., Capacity and Comprehension: Spontaneous Stereotyping Under Cognitive Load, 22 SOCIAL COGNITION 292 (2004). Henri Tajfel, et al., Social Categorization and Inter-group Behavior, 1 EUR. J. SOC. PSYCHOL. 149, 172177 (1971) and Michael Billig & Henri Tajfel, Social Categorization and Similarity in Intergroup Behavior, 3 EUR. J. SOC. PSYCHOL. 27, 37-48 (1973) ; for a more updated study, see: Jerry M. Burger et al., What a Coincidence! The Effects of Incidental Similarity on Compliance, 30 PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. BULL. 35 (2004). 134 135 In the ground-breaking research that depicted this phenomena, Muzafar Sharif and colleagues examined the behavior of pre-adolescent boys in a setting with no parental guidance. Campers were randomly assigned to one of two insular groups. Following introduction of the two groups, the subsequent camp athletic competitions were characterized by excessive violence between members of the two groups; Muzafer Sherif, et al., INTERGROUP CONFLICT AND COOPERATION: THE ROBBERS CAVE EXPERIMENT, ch. 5 (1961) available at http://psychclassics.yorku.ca/Sherif/chap5.html. 136 Lisa Fairfax, The Elusive Quest for the Inside Director p 176; Julian Velasco, Structural Bias and the Need for Substantive Review, 82 WASH. U. L. Q. 821 (2004); James D. Cox & Harry L. Musinger, Bias in the Boardroom: Psychological Foundations and Legal Implications of Corporate Cohesion, 48 LAW & CONTEMPORARY PROBLEMS 83 (1985). 29 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate At best, the legal rules foster "cosmetic independence" that result in a poor facsimile of an arm's-length counterparty.137 Arguably, judicial oversight of procedural best practices empowers independent directors to overcome structural biases and fulfill their role in an objective manner. The MFW opinion stresses that independent committee adherence to procedural guidelines is essential for a downgrade of the standard of review. Assuming this view to be correct does not detract from the second main argument lobbed against increased authority to independent board members and committees. Substantial literature has failed to detect the undeniable benefits that increased board independence supposedly adds to the corporation. On the contrary, a claim can be made that in certain situations, increased board independence actually harms performance. Whatever evidence supports the usefulness of properly empowered independent committees in the freeze out context does not easily extrapolate to going concern transactions as well. The rest of this section will describe the benefits and pitfalls associated with independent directors and independent committees. Proponents of independent directors rely on the notion that distance from the powers that run the corporation leads to increased objectivity. The argument further equates objectivity with more efficient fulfillment of their duties. This account, however, ignores the fact that increased objectivity comes at a price. Independent directors often have no first-hand knowledge of the corporation or its' business and must rely on second-hand accounts.138 Arguably, corporate law rules – like those found in the MFW guidelines – minimize the information gap by facilitating and even mandating the supply of information to independent directors. However, a caveat applies. "Information" does not necessarily equate with "knowledge." While independence and objectivity might be beneficial to satisfying the board's monitoring functions, this is but one aspect of the board's role.139 A dearth of firm-specific or industry-specific knowledge hampers 137 Nicola F. Sharpe, The Cosmetic Independence of Corporate Boards, 34 SEA. L. REV. 1435 (2011) (arguing that cosmetic independence only takes into account a corporate director's relationship with the corporation and not the tools a director needs to achieve substantive independence). 138 Arnoud W. A. Boot & Jonathan Macey, Monitoring Corporate Performance: The Role of Objectivity, Proximity and Adaptability in Corporate Governance, 89 CORN. L. REV. 356 (2003) (objectivity and proximity of monitors is tradeoff that cannot co-exist); Jill Fisch, Taking Boards Seriously, 19 CARD. L. REV. 265, 267 (1998) (director independence comes at the expense of a decline in the board's management capacity). For a taxonomy of board functions, see: Stephen Bainbridge, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AFTER THE FINANCIAL CRISIS 49-50, 61 (2012) (monitoring and disciplining management, providing advice and guidance for management and providing a network of useful business contacts), Lynne L. Dallas, The Multiple Roles of Corporate Boards of Directors, 40 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 781, 782-783 (2003) (characterizing the functions of the board as monitoring, relational and strategic). 139 30 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate the independent director's ability to observe and assess a corporation's strategic direction.140 The empirical research that attempts to identify causation or at least correlation between the incidence of independent directors on boards and corporate performance supports the above hypothesis. To date, the studies have not been able to find an undeniable link between board independence and improved performance.141 Studies that purport to uncover economic benefits of increased board independence cabin their conclusion to a specific context. The important variable is the relative cost associated with acquiring knowledge about the firm and the industry. Increased director independence in a corporation operating in a straightforward industry is followed by performance growth. Conversely, for corporations that operate in a niche industry where expertise is hard to gain, appointment of independent directors actually leads to a decrease in performance parameters.142 The above research analyzes the connection between board independence and corporate performance. Studies that focus on the impact of independent directors on board committees have also been unable to verify an irrefutable correlation between committee independence and committee performance. As in the case of board independence, the committee's function is an important variable on the effect that enhanced independence has on committee performance.143 140 Fisch, Taking Boards Seriously, 282-286; Nicola F. Sharpe, Rethinking Board Function in the Wake of the 2008 Financial Crisis, 5 J. BUS. & TECH. L. 99, 108-110 (2010). 141 Sanjai Bhagat & Bernard Black, The Non-Correlation Between Board Independence and Long-Term Firm Performance, 27 J. CORP. L. 231 (2002) (Taken as a whole, the empirical evidence does not convincingly prove that independent directors necessarily lead to more effective and efficient monitoring); David Larcker & Brian Tayan, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MATTERS, 144 (2011) ("Most 142 studies fail to find a significant relationship between formal board independence and improved corporate outcomes… In aggregate, they tend to demonstrate either a modest relationship or no relationship between independence and long-term performance") Ran Duchin, et. al., When Are Outside Directors Effective? 96 J. FIN. ECO. 195 (2010). For studies casting further doubt about the utility of independent directors in the banks and financial holding sector, see: David. H. Erkens, et al., Corporate Governance in the 2007-2008 Financial Crisis: Evidence from Financial Institutions Worldwide (January, 2012) Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=139768 ("[W]e find that firms with higher institutional ownership and more independent boards had worse stock returns than other firms during the crisis") and Renee B. Adams & Hamid Mehran Bank Board Structure and Performance: Evidence for Large Bank Holding Companies, (October, 2011) Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1945548 ("As in many studies of nonfinancial firms, we find that the proportion of independent outsiders on the board [of bank holding companies] is not significantly related to performance"). 143 Cf. April Klein, Firm Performance and Board Composition Structure, 41 J. L. & ECO. 275 (1998) (little evidence that additional independence on the nominating, audit or compensation committees positively impact firm performance) with Robert A. Prentice & David B. Spence, Sarbanes-Oxley as Quack Corporate Governance: How Wise is the Perceived Wisdom? 95 GEO. L. J. 1843 (2007) (greater independence on the auditing committee improves financial reporting) 31 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate An important study by Davidoff and Cain underscores this point.144 Focusing solely on end game transactions in which incumbent management are part of the buyout team (MBOs), the authors find that the existence of special committees is associated with higher offer premiums.145 A closer look at their findings, however, does support the proposition that independent committees necessarily bring value to shareholders in other types of RPTs.146 This is because independent committees analyzing a going concern RPT fulfill a different role than those pondering a going private offer. Independent committees examining a going-concern RPT fulfill more than one function. While it is expected that they monitor the transaction for potential abuses, many going-concern RPTs are an integral part of long-term corporate strategy. The collected data does not support the conclusion that increased independence assists board committees to accomplish this task.147 MFW provides guidelines that allow a controlling shareholder to receive deferential BJR review while orchestrating a going-private transaction. These guidelines emphasize the role of independent board committees and an affirmative vote of a majority of the minority shareholders. This section focused on the two main criticisms lobbied against independent directors and committees. First, that deeprooted structural bias prevents the independent director from achieving similar objectivity to that which is found in an arm's-length counterparty; and second, available data is incapable of proving a causal link between increased independence and increased performance. The next sections will take a closer look at shareholder voting and ponder whether the supreme court's confidence in the minority vote is misplaced. b. Majority of Minority Shareholder Approval – A Critique Shareholder voting is predicated on the twin principals of corporate legitimacy and error-correction. However, systemic impediments hamper achievement of those goals. Ultimately, conditioning the course of action on shareholder approval cannot 144 145 146 147 Steven M. Davidoff & Matthew D. Cain Form Over Substance? The Value of Corporate Process and Management Buy-Outs, 36 DEL. J. CORP. L. 849 (2011). Id., p 889-890. Critically, the study finds that independent directors committees are not associated with higher takeover premiums in controlling shareholder freeze-outs subject to the WeinbergerLynch standard; id p. 892. This could be because of the cognitive limitations on the type of decision they are asked to make. A going-private decision has one main variable – the adequacy of the share price offer. A decision regarding a going concern RPT contemplates many input-based metrics can properly be calculated by a director with some proximity to the corporation; Bainbridge, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AFTER THE FINANCIAL CRISIS 99. 32 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate guarantee efficient results. A majority of the minority condition does not change the basic calculus, and in fact has the potential to engender even more harm. In order for the voting mechanism to achieve the desired result, the voting constituency must be suitably informed and educated regarding the contents of the ballot. However, a rational voter's effort to inform himself about the intricacies of the voted-upon subject is linked to the benefit that will personally accrue from the anticipated result. Implementation of both axioms in the corporate sphere leads to dire conclusions. Monitoring a publicly-held corporation is a costly endeavor; forming an educated opinion about business intricacies requires the shareholder to collect and process a vast amount of information. Owing to the minute share ownership of most minority shareholders, chances are that most shareholders do not play a pivotal role in the vote. In addition, any benefits that a value-producing vote accrues to the corporation will be distributed among all shareholders. As a result, the expected benefits of an informed vote are microscopic and at the very best marginally related to the incurred costs. The above analysis leads to a phenomenon labeled by the finance literature as 'rational apathy': a typical shareholder has no incentive to inform himself and participate in the vote, and therefore will not.148 Arguably, a majority of the minority condition works to dissipate the rational apathy associated with the shareholder vote. Exclusion of the controlling shareholder from the voting constituency increases the relative voting power attached to a minority shareholder's holdings; the possibility that a minority shareholder's vote will prove pivotal rises. Increased voting power provides a greater incentive to acquire adequate information on the voted-upon issues. In theory, the minority of the majority condition facilitates an informed and efficient vote by the shareholder constituency. Unfortunately, the realities of shareholder voting cast serious doubt on achievement of this goal. Conditioning a going concern RPT on the approval of a majority of minority shareholders has the potential to unleash harmful unintended consequences. First, although minority shareholders subject to this condition ostensibly have a greater incentive to collect information on the issues on the ballot box, there is no guarantee that this incentive is enough to overcome rational apathy; the high costs associated with becoming informed and the division of potential benefits conspire to preclude minority shareholders from actually carrying out this endeavor. In all likelihood, minority shareholders that wish to make their vote count – but not enough to actually 148 Stephen M. Bainbridge, The Case for Limited Shareholder Voting Rights, 53 UCLA L. REV. 601, 607. 33 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate incur the costs necessary to become informed – will blindly vote in accordance with the recommendation of proxy advisory services.149 A second unintended consequence regards the effect that conditioning the transaction on minority shareholder approval has on the motivations and actions of members of the independent director committee. Recall that prior to MFW, although they were not enough to cause a downgrade of the standard of review, corporate best practices dictated the creation of independent director committees. Indeed, the actions of the committee were heavily scrutinized under the exhaustive entire fairness standard. In the post-MFW landscape, independent shareholder approval of independent committee recommendation has become the norm. However, buttressing the independent committee's actions on the approval of minority shareholders weakens the committee's ex ante incentive to act in the interests of minority shareholders. Under the MFW guidelines, independent directors bear joint responsibility with minority shareholders. The independent committee's incentive to properly fulfill its' task is further undermined by the lax standard of review that MFW affords. The net result is that the addition of minority shareholders approval might result in the dismantling of incentives that compel effective independent director oversight.150 Increasing the power given to minority shareholders is a potentially misguided strategy for a different reason. Minority shareholders, even relatively substantial ones, are not all cut from the same cloth. In fact, minority shareholders are motivated by widely divergent interests.151 Recall that for the error-correcting role of the shareholder vote to function correctly, shareholders must share a common goal. Raising the relative voting power of minority shareholders transforms formerly disenfranchised shareholders into potential swing-votes. Under these conditions, it is perfectly rational for a minority shareholder to utilize his new-found voting power to engage in 'rent-seeking' behavior; i.e. to condition his agreement on the promotion of private interests that have the potential to be detrimental to the rest of the shareholders.152 Before moving on to explore the geography of MFW-Land, another distinction between shareholder voting on freeze-out transactions and going-concern RPTs needs to be made. In both scenarios, public shareholders generally suffer from information 149 150 151 152 Larcker & Tayan, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MATTERS 403. Another pitfall associated with proxy advisory firms are the proliferation of "one size fits all" recommendations based upon purported corporate best practices that are not supported by the literature; see Asaf Ekstein, Great Expectations: The Perils of Proxy Advisor Regulation, forthcoming DEL. J. CORP. L. Minor Myers, The Perils of Shareholder Voting on Executive Compensation, 36 DEL. J. CORP. L. 417 (2011). Iman Anabtawi, Some Skepticism About Increasing Shareholder Power, 53 UCLA L. REV. 561 (2006) (depicting the divergent interests of minority shareholders along the following axis: investment horizon (short vs. long termism), risk preference (diversified vs. non-diversified), and degree of "social" considerations (union-affiliated shareholders vs. financial institutions). Bainbridge, The Case for Limited Shareholder Voting Rights, p. 634. 34 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate deficits regarding the intrinsic value of the corporation or the transaction at hand. Incentivizing shareholders to carry out an informed vote is an essential component of a well-operating voting regime. Shareholders in a going-private scenario have higher motivation to inform themselves about the value of the transaction as well as a much cheaper way to do so. A successful undertaking of a going-private transaction results in the elimination of the public float. Shareholders are in fact voting on whether to cash in on the future revenue stream associated with their shares. A 'wrong' decision cannot be easily rectified; shareholders that successfully defeat a value-enhancing deal will be left owning something of worse value. Conversely, agreeing to sell means that the shareholder will not participate in future gains. The incentive to make an informed decision will never be higher. In addition, the capital market's ability to aggregate available information into a single stock price offers the shareholders a clear benchmark of the value of their shares.153 In contrast, shareholders asked to approve a going-concern RPT have neither the incentive nor the informational shortcut that attach to a going-private transaction. Regardless of the final tally, their shares will still be in their possession. Continued share ownership allows them to enjoy future gains if the transaction is valueproducing or punish the corporation if the transaction is value-reducing. Regardless, shareholders can defer passing judgment on the transaction to a later period. There is no unique incentive to accrue costs designed to inform themselves about the efficacy of the transaction. Not only is there no incentive, in contrast to a going-private decision the deliberating shareholders cannot readily rely on the market price of the shares. Considerable evidence casts doubt on the market's ability to disentangle the and accurately price discrete portions of the corporate enterprise.154 VI. The Geography of MFW-LAND We now return to ponder the impact of the MFW decision in other factual situations involving a controlling shareholder that would otherwise require heightened judicial review. Specifically, does utilization of both approval mechanisms mandate application of lax judicial review? At first glance, the answer appears obvious. MFW was rendered in connection with a going-private transaction with a controlling shareholder. Going private 153 154 Bainbridge, The Case for Limited Shareholder Voting Rights, p. 624. Sudha Krishnaswami, Venkat Subramanium, Information Asymmetry, Valuation and the Corporate Spin-off Decision, 53 J. FIN. ECON. 73 (1999) (providing evidence that information asymmetries prevent the market from correctly pricing independent firm units and that the actual value is recognized following a spin-off). 35 Draft for Corporate & Securities Litigation Workshop – Do not cite or circulate transactions differ from going-concern transactions in that their successful completion wipes out the minority float. With regards to enterprise transactions, abusive actions undertaken by the controlling shareholder will be embedded in the collective memory of the public market. When the opportunity arises, minority shareholders will most assuredly punish the controlling shareholder for past transgressions. Conventional wisdom holds that the equilibrium established by this balance of power works to curb overly-aggressive actions contemplated for the betterment of the controlling shareholder. Following a going-private transaction, minority shareholders are wiped out and can no longer threaten future retribution. Accordingly, policy considerations call for superior protection of minority shareholders participating in a going-private transaction as a substitute for relinquishment of their side of the balance of power equilibrium. Since MFW establishes narrower judicial review following a doublebarreled self-cleansing mechanism for going private transactions, it stands to reason that this standard should apply to all transactions involving a controlling shareholder. After all, if the courts are willing to downgrade their involvement in the most problematic of settings for minority shareholders, what possible rationale is there for staying put with enhanced review in apparently more benign circumstances? Another avenue, predicated on canons of judicial interpretation, distinguishes MFW as stemming from a line of cases dealing specifically with going private transactions. Accordingly, MFW does not change the judicial standard of review for all other transactions with a controlling shareholder, as those are governed by different Supreme Court authority. Still another avenue of development emerges from careful reading of the Chancery Court decision. Dealing with an issue of first impression, then-Chancellor Strine adopted the novel argument that effective double-barreled approval lowers the applicable standard of review. In his careful analysis of the situation, the former Chancellor gave great weight to the prevalence of non-meritorious "strike-suits" and the inefficiencies stemming from mandatory entire fairness review for all going private transactions. While this portion of the analysis was not replicated by the Supreme Court, the underlying rationale holds persuasive analytical force and should not be ignored. Should the doctrine advance in this direction, the borders of "MFWLand" will extend only to those factual situations that nearly always give rise to shareholder claims while leaving out all seldom-litigated scenarios that currently invite intrusive judicial review. 36