GEOG7102 Geography of Foreign Investment and Trade in China (Lecture Notes – A personal property) 1 Lecture I: Introduction China: A World Focus and New Concept Underlying Mechanism for the Global Economic Transformation: Trade & FDI & MNC So, Foreign Investments and Trade in China: the Course Arrangement I. China: A World Focus and A New Concept Of Commerce, Investment and Trade – A hot place for business worldwide Of Professional Training – A popular subject in university courses across disciplines and across the world Of Academic Research – A fashionable topic in academic research in most disciplines and in most the world That matters (or is relevant to) our community, our daily life and our career Mainland China together with Hong Kong and Macau: A Growing New World Giant that will shock and re-shape the World in next 10-15 year development 2 China’s GDP, Trade and FDI in Figures 2006: Year 2006 Int’l Trade 1760.7/USD Growth Rate (%) 10.7 Almost 10% for past 10 years 23.8 Export 969.1/USD 27.2 3 Import 791.6/USD 20.0 3 69.5/USD -4.1 2 1066/USD 1333/USD by 6/07 10987billion/RMB 30 1 GDP FDI Foreign Reserve Quantity (Billion) 20940.7/RMB (2668.1/USD) Domestic 24 Investment in Fixed Assets Domestic 16158.7billion/RMB 14.6 Resident Savings Domestic Retail 7641/RMB 13.7 Volume Stock Market 8940.4/RMB 175.7 Capitalization 21898 by 8/07 Per capita GDP 2072/USD More than 10% (USD Dollar) Shanghai 8000 for past ten Beijing 5500 years Shenzhen 6000 3 Global % and Ranking 5.5% and rank No. 4 PPP No. 2 3 6 Around 70-80th China’s GDP, Trade and FDI in Figures 2007: Year 2007 Int’l Trade 2173.83/USD Growth Rate (%) 11.4 Almost 10% for past 10 years 23.5 Export 1218.02/USD 25.7 3 Import 955.82/USD 20.8 3 82.65/USD 13.8 2 43.3 24.7 1 GDP FDI Quantity (Billion) 24953/RMB (3418.2/USD) Foreign Reserve 1528.25/USD Total 13723.9/RMB Investment in Fixed Assets Domestic 17952.6/RMB Resident Savings Sales Volume of 8921/RMB Social Consumables CPI Stock Market Shanghai $36943 $17653 by 09/08 Capitalization (USD) Shenzhen $7845 $3981 by 09/08 Per capita GDP 2600/USD Shanghai $8,950 (USD Dollar) Beijing $7,680 Yuen / USD (End of 2007: 7.3) Global % and Ranking 5.5% and rank No. 4 PPP No. 2 3 11.1 16.8 Shenzhen $10,850 4 4.8 302.6 6 244.2 20 More than 10% for past ten years Around 70-80th http://wzs.mofcom.gov.cn/ http://www.fdi.gov.cn http://chinabiz.mpfinance.com/cfm/list_hg.cfm China’s International Trade: 5 US$ 100M 16000.0 14000.0 12000.0 10000.0 Export 8000.0 Im port 6000.0 4000.0 2000.0 0.0 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Total trade to GDP ratio in China: 1980: 13%, 1995: 41%, 2000: 50%, 2007: 65%, which ranked 5th in the world. International Trade contributes 30% of GDP in value-added terms. Now in China, More than 60% international trade is made by Foreign Wholly Owned or Foreign Joint Venture companies. Foreign Direct Investments China is always the second largest FDI recipient in the world, second only to the United States; and the largest amongst developing countries, about 1/3 of total FDI in the Third World Countries. In 2000, production volume arises from FDI constitutes around 35% to the total GDP output in China. In 2006, the figure is more than 50%. Annual Growth Rates of FDI: 1984-88: 38%, 1989-91: 11%, 1992-2000: 30%, 2001-2005:20% with flat growth in 2006) 6 China problems: Structural in Systems, Quality of China-made and Safety in food and health care supplies….. II. Underlying Mechanism for the Global Economic Transformation: Trade & FDI & MNC Global total trade to GDP ratio up to 35-40% Trade arise from FDI constitutes 60-70% of the total global trade volume FDI stock constitutes 20-30% of global GDP Trade made all trading partner better off and maximize the global production and consumption FDI made both the recipient and the host country better off and maximize the global production and consumption MNCs are the true vehicles promoting trade and FDI Therefore, trade, FDI &MNC are the forces behind the transformation of the global economy III. So, Foreign Investments and Trade in China: the Course Arrangement See Course Web Page: “Introduction” Reference: 7 Chapter 1: Berry B.J.L., Conkling E.C. and Ray D.M. (1997), The Global Economy in Transition (second edition), Prentice Hall Inc., New Jersey, United States. Lecture II: International trade, FDI and MNC as dynamics of global economic transaction The World Is Changing: Everything (goods and services) is tradable or nothing cannot be traded Can you name one thing that must be supplied locally? Implication: Produce (by yourself) or trade? If trade, what and from where you are going to buy, and, most importantly, what and to where you can offer – trade is a two-way journey! Open to new opportunities but new challenges too! Optimize and maximize production! Everything (goods and services) is specialized and standardized Can you name one object that cannot be found other place? Implications: Optimize and mobilize production -where you position your production base that can best secure your market Don’t produce and trade final products – processing/manufacturing in the production base and assembling in the market 8 Open to internationalization of production and firms global strategy, in a macro/corporate-level Open to business in a micro/personal-level Open to new trade perspective and theory – intra firm trade Open to demand for integrated and comprehensive skill/knowledge/ability, the specialized and standardized world is relative simple or less sophisticated. Superiority of technology, knowledge and local knowledge Can you name anything more important that this for a firm to survive, to compete, to excel? This is the winning potion and formula!!! Implication: R&D, but who can offer to finance R&D? The more money you put, the more market you need to support the larger the better” and “go to the center” and “go to global” Control and transfer of the technology the need for FDI and open a new FDI and MNC perspective and theory Needs to tap the local knowledge Needs to close to market and to set up remote subsidiaries and branches Open to new perspective and theory of geography of finance and geography of service industry. 9 Who can take most of these changes? Who can enhance and advance these changes? MNE or MNC – open a new way of business that transforms the world economy and our daily life! The Nature and Role of MNC The MNC is a company that is headquartered in one country but controls productive facilities and sales outlets in other countries. Its operations involve flows of capital, goods, services, and managerial and technical personnel among its subsidiaries. Ultimately, it leads the corporations to assume a global outlook and strategy. The world’s 14 richest nations were headquarters to 7,000 MNCs in 1969 and 24,000 in 1994. There total 37,000 MNCs in the world in 1995, accounting for more than 25% world goods production, 3% employment in world total and 10% employment in developed countries, and 50% global FDI and Int’l trade volume. The largest MNC have sales exceeding US$1000 billion annually, more than many countries’ GNP. Global sales of General Motors or Exxon are more than GNP of 25 sovereign nations. Major roles in transfers of knowledge, technology, investments, profits, and services among themselves – intra-firm trade – shipments of parts, components, subassemblies, rather than finished goods and 10 services. MNCs play dominant role in economic development, particular in int’l trade and FDI, in both developing and developed countries, including Canada, Belgium, France and Italy. New perspective to trade theory – firms rather countries are a prime agent for int’l trade, see Chapters 11 and 12 Two advantages: – Information-gathering ability or scanning capability – an immediate awareness of opportunities, problems, and new development; – Enormous store of capital, technology, and managerial skills that an MNC can draw upon Development and Structure 1. Originated from colonial operation 2. Three stages of development: A Linear Linkup to Japan (1970s); A transitional period of int’l specialisation and mesh (1980s); A final stage of global localization – the tetrapolar strategic division of the world (1990s), see Box1.2 3. Emergence of major trade blocs Role in Global Redistribution of Factors of Production 1. The most significant feature: an efficient agent for transferring capital, managerial skills, technology, product 11 design, and commodities among countries; Equalizer of factors distribution; Generator for innovation and technological change 2. Transfer of managerial skills 3. Transfer of capital – both real (machinery) and financial 4. Transfer of technology 5. Principal generator of int’l trade Theories of MNC What causes a firm to go abroad and succeed in a foreign environment? What happens to the firm during the course of internationalization? - Expectation for greater profits/returns from foreign venture by possessing four advantages that local firms don’t possess: 1. Superior knowledge – monopoly in knowledge: Leadership in innovation is the key to compete and succeed in this information age. 2. Superior size and scope of operation – oligopolistic in market competition: World-wide resources to manoeuvre for competition 3. Superior in technology protection and transfers – transfers within own firms, go with rivalry and “reverse” investment: competitors and rivalry route/locations, similar culture, legal and political system, and English-speaking environment are 12 attractive and favourable elements for MNCs to open their business. 4. Global Strategy: Move to exports Internationalization of production Internalization of organization Globalization of outlook: Worldwide recruitment of Cosmopolitan Executives who are rich in three assets: concepts – best knowledge and ideas; competence – the ability to operate at the highest standards of any place in the world anywhere; and connection – best relationships inward and outward To HK/MACS students – you should also “go to global” and “go to China”. You must equip or label with both “Global” and “China” identities and trademarks so that you can compete and survive in this increasingly competitive world/job market. 13 Global Competitive Advantage 1. Four Processes of globalisation: Mobility: Mobility of capital (both physical and financial), labour, idea, and product and service is high. Simultaneity: Introduction of a product or service in one place and its adoption at other place is required to be “instant” or “simultaneous”. By pass: New product or technological alternative can go around existing structure and barriers. Pluralism: Multiple choices These four processes have together created a globalization cascade – an efficient and mutually reinforcing feedback loops that strengthen and accelerated the globalizing forces. 2. Factors: Michael Porter’s (1990) Four Factors of Competitive Advantages (in contrast to the conventional comparative advantages): Factor conditions: conventionally called “factors of production”a) Physical resources: b) Human resources: c) Infrastructure: d) Knowledge resources: e) Capital resources: 14 The five factors can be grouped into basic factors, such as physical resources, number of peoples, and advanced factors such as educated personnel and R&D. Basic factors are endowed, limited and of diminishing necessity and impacts, while advanced factors are created (through education and research), unlimited and of increasing significance and impacts. Demand conditions: the composition of buyers needs and the size and pattern of domestic demands – a) Power comes from influence over consumption, not as traditional argument, from control over the means of production b) Japanese “light, thin, short, and small” product has international impacts The nature of supporting industries: the surrounding environment that fosters success by providing “dynamic externalities” – a) Sweden’s special steels - cutting tool industry; Swiss dye industry – pharmaceuticals; Italy’s leather – shoes and fashion; North European Envy for capital gains leads to least capital accumulation while USA is just opposite Firm strategy, structure and rivalry: Good have enemy 3. Four Stages of Economic Development: Factor-driven: Developing Countries and China (Labour), OPEC &Gulf States (Oil), Australia (Gold)/Canada (minerals) Investment-driven: Japan and South Korean, and Taiwan 15 Innovation-driven: USA Wealth-driven: UK and Western Europe Reference: Chapter 1 &11: Berry B.J.L., Conkling E.C. and Ray D.M. (1997), The Global Economy in Transition (second edition), Prentice Hall Inc., New Jersey, United States. 16 Lecture III: Old and New International trade Theories Background - The Necessity for World Trade Nowadays nations and regions are becoming increasingly interdependent, not only because of the differences of their natural and human endowment, but also because of the difference of their living tastes and choices – No country can by itself supply all ingredients for its people due to their contemporary living standard enforces them to desire for a diversified choice and therefore requires variety of goods and services A retreat to self-sufficiency would so impoverish a people that no country would find such a course politically feasible. The world need trade and the trade change the world fundamentally: A internationalized production process and development strategy of firms as well as a locational decision-making process A wholesale restructuring of industry A revolution in global communication and technology A growing dominance of MNCs in variety of aspects, including cultural and political changes 17 A shifting fortune of countries and regions and new international map of commerce and polity (political powers)…..etc A reconsideration of old theories and creation of new understanding, approaches and new outlook World Trade and the Energy Crises The Oil crises 1970s and the global recession triggered by them in the early 1980s are the most pivotal event of the last century - Henry Kissinger, former US Secretary of State OPEC (Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries) – established in 1960, but really come to power in early 1970s, then created the 2 world oil crises in 1973 and 1979 and triggered global economic recession in 1981-83; consisting of 13 countries in two groups: Iran, Algeria, Indonesia, Venezuela, Nigeria, Ecuador, and Gabon – large population and hungry for money Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emerates, Kuwait, Qatar, Libya, and Iraq – Small population and keen to preserve the oil resource 18 OPEC Oil Control - Oil Crises and Global Recession in 1970s and in the early 1980s Pre-1973 Characters World Oil Control % of the Total Oil Price $/barrel 1973 The first Oil Crisis 1979 The Second Oil Crisis 1981 1983 Global Recession 30 - 43 85 Less than 3 3 12 41 72 300 Dramatic down 31 50 - 60 Oil Revenue 7 billion $/y Oil Export million barrel Balance of Payment billion $ After 1983 Compete Control and Monoply +109 29 - 10 Less Compete Control 20 (16 1994; 3038 now) 18 27 -18 Further deficit Impacts and Consequences of the Oil Crises: Pre-crisis, $3/barrel oil encourage lavish use of oil, particularly in western countries Global inflationary spiral and economic down-turn which led to global recession Non-OPEC countries thrown into a balance-of-payments deficit – global economic downturn Enormous global transfer of fortune and wealth from nonoil counties to OPEC countries – at least $100 billion per 19 annum, creating the world new rich and new poor and creating great problems for OPEC on deciding areas of usage of their revenue Developed world benefited from recycling of OPEC wealth and developing world hit hardest with the exception of S.E. Asia Countries Global recession in the early 1980s But demand for oil drop, oil price drop and OPEC deficit rise, new alternatives and new sources (oil fields) results in and new industrial restructuring The largest losers is OPEC itself! Trade Growth and Structural Change International Labor Division Internationalization of production – highly independent and interdependent production process - 25% of finished manufactured goods made up from imports Industrial structure upgrading with manufactured goods increasingly dominant The increased interdependence did not result in greater industry specialization, as conventional theory suggested, but in greater convergence – the trade among LCs and NICs has actually become more similar, differing only in brand name, quality and reputations. 20 Regional Patterns of Global Trade See transparencies Looking for Explanation – Old and New Theories of International Trade Old Trade Theory: from Classical to Neoclassical Theory – the Principle of Comparative Advantage Basic Questions asked: Why do countries trade with each other? Is trade beneficial to all trading parties? What determines the international pattern of specialization in production and trade? From Adam Smith to David Ricardo, John Stuart Mill, Francis Edgeworth, and Alfred Marshall Mercantilism: exports exceed import – favorable balance of trade; foreign rather than domestic trade; manufacture rather than agriculture Classical Theory: Fundamental: Free trade – trade that is unencumbered by any form of governmental intervention – is beneficial to all trading partners. Why is that? To measure the effect of trade: Labor Theory of Value – all cost can be reduced ultimately to units of labor, 21 which are in turn directly related to the price of the trading products Classical + geometric technique = Neoclassical Neoclassical Theory – The Principle of Comparative Advantage Basic Rationale: To a householder: never “attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy (Never make thing unless it is cheaper to make than to buy); The same applies to a country Absolute Advantage (Adam Smith, 1776): – As long as there is a natural advantage for individual countries, it is advantageous for them to trade among them, and the trade promotes international division of labor and specialization of production, and hence maximizes the world total output and consumption But, what happen to those countries that have no single absolute advantage but all absolute disadvantage – no a single industry in which they can excel? Comparative Advantage (David Ricardo, 40 years later): Trade can indeed take place advantageously, even if one is better than others in every production, as long as they differ relatively in their capabilities. A country would not have an absolute advantage to produce everything, so as a country would not have an absolute disadvantage of producing everything. That is to say, the “rich” country’s absolute advantage over the “poor” country in one product is relatively 22 greater than its absolute advantage in another product. Similarly, the “poor” has an absolute disadvantage that is relatively less than its other absolute advantage. The principle of comparative advantage declares that countries should specialize in production and export of those things they can make more efficiently relative to other nations and should import those goods at which they are relatively less efficient Simplified assumptions: No transport cost involved; No artificial barriers to trade; Labor is homogeneous and skill labor is a multiple of nonskill labor; Production technology is identical; No labor movement 23 Example 1: Absolute Advantage in both Countries Assumption: France has absolute advantage over the production of potatoes Germany has absolute advantage over the production of wheat Production possibilities, domestic exchange ratios, and production and consumption of potatoes and wheat in France and Germany before trade 24 Production Possibilities Domestic Exchange Ratios Wheat/Potatoes Potatoes Wheat Potatoes/Wheat 90 50 140 60 100 160 1.50 0.50 France Germany Total Production and Consumption Wheat Total Potatoes 0.67 2.00 45 25 70 30 50 80 75 75 150 After trade France Germany International Exchange Possibilities Potatoes Wheat 90 100 90 100 International Exchange Ratio Potatoes/Wheat Wheat/Potatoes 0.90 1.11 0.90 1.11 Production, Trade and Consumption Potatoes France Germany Total Wheat Total Consu mptio n Production Exports Imports Consumption Production Exports Imports Consumption 90 -90 45 -45 -45 45 45 45 90 -100 100 -50 50 50 -50 50 50 100 Example 2: Absolute Advantage in One Country Only and Comparative Advantage in the Other 25 95 95 190 Production and exchange ratios of wheat and olive oil, Italy and Spain Italy has absolute advantage over Spain over the production of wheat Spain and Italy possess the same production capacity of olive oil Before Trade: Production Possibilities Wheat Olive Oil Italy Spain Total 40 20 20 20 Domestic Exchange Ratios Wheat/Oi Oil/Wheat l 2.00 0.50 1.00 1.00 26 Wheat 20 10 30 Production Olive Oil 10 10 20 After Trade: Italy Spain Total Production Wheat 40 -40 Olive Oil -20 20 International Exchange Ratios Range of Potential Ratios Ratios at Point C Wheat/Oil Oil/Wheat Wheat /Oil Oil/Wheat 2.0 Max 0.50 Min. 1.50 0.67 1.0 Min 1.00 Max 1.50 0.67 Mill’s Law of Reciprocal Demand – An Auction Process settling the real international exchange rate/price. The actual international price depends on the strength of elasticity (resposiveness to price changes) of demand for these goods in each country. The Gains from Trade - the First Gains from Trade If trade is “truly” free, all trading partners will benefit from: Exchange goods International specialization of production and division of labor Maximization of production (total output) and promotion of consumption Specialization further enhances a country’s initial comparative advantage Inadequacies of classical and neoclassical theory Unrealistic assumptions All factors of production being collapsed into a single factor, labor 27 Factor Proportions Theory and Inadequacies Effects of Supply Conditions; Land as a Factor; Labor as a Factor; Enterprise as a Factor; Capital as a Factor; Effects of Demand Conditions; Cultural Differences; Difference in Income; Domestic Consumption and Exports The emergence of the Heckscher-Ohlin model, it states that each country will export those goods whose production is relatively intensive in the country’s abundant (and therefore cheap) factor and import those that are intensive in its scarce (and therefore expensive) factors. e.g. China’s light manufacturing industry, Swiss watches, Indonesia wood products Empirical Tests: The Leontief Paradox The theoretical expectations from this model is that US exports would be capital-intensive and that its imports would be labour-intensive. But Leontief’s finding in 1953, suggested the reverse results. This empirical test raised serious doubts that factor endowments are in itself a sufficient explanation for trade. Beyond that, it identifies other elements that are known to influence trade, but that are excluded in the model. 28 A New Theory of International Trade and Transactions (Helpman and Paul Krugman 1985) Basic Fact: The Market and competition is imperfect, but the emerging and flourishing MNEs and FDI have completely transformed the worldMNEs responsible major share (up to 60-70% of the total) of world trade; The relationship between trade and industrial organization has been completely changed Increasing mobility of factors of production and firms assets The Missing Elements of Conventional Theory Reliance on Country Difference – Both absolute and comparative advantages emphasis on country difference and on country trade – an “arm’s-length” trade Intra-industry Trade Intra-firm Trade Gains from Trade – Though trade tends to increase the GDP of each participating country, it can be expected to reduce the income to those of factors of production that contribute little to its export, while increasing the income of those that contribute more. But, nowadays it founds that trade has increased the productivity of all factors of production in trading countries and it has left everyone better off. New Assumptions: 29 Individual firms possess unique competitive advantage Firm assets are mobile among branches of the enterprise Enterprises engaged in a lot of sectors/branches (“multiactivity”) and the economic functions by branches of a firm are decided in accordance with the spatial distribution of the firm assets Most transactions take placed within the same industries, between related firms and within multinational hierarchies of firms Trade is not entirely free and market competition is not perfect Firms overcome impediments to operation of a free and open market by hierarchical internalization Fundamentals of New Explanation that old Theory Left out: New Answer to Old question: Increasing Returns and Overcoming Imperfect competition (Krugman 1990)What is the Increasing Returns (to scale)? Verdoorn’s Law (1949): The greater the rate of increase of output inside a firm, the greater the increase in productivities - the core value of Increasing Returns Kaldor’s Model (1966, 1978): 30 The more a firm produces of a good, the more experience it gets as it learns by doing, and the more efficient it becomes at producing not only that good, but other like it. Productivity increases not only because of economies of scale, but also because improved techniques arise out of increased knowledge because of the specialization and concentration of production. Two factors are interrelated: Technological knowledge is acquired by experience, which is in turn a function of the specialization and concentration of production (that involves cumulative volume of gross investment). Such technological progress is internal to the firm, or endogenous, and it results in a self-propelling spiral of growth, enhanced productivity, and increasing returns – a process similar to “positive feedback” and “circular and cumulative causation”, The core of increasing returns is the view that the dynamic relationship between productivity change and output change involving economies of large-scale production and technical progress that specialization and concentration of production generates. This relationship is the key to the growth of capitalist economies, and the relationship is self-propelling and therefore endogenous. Two interrelated concepts are Dynamic Externalities and Network Organization Dynamic Externalities: Paul Romer (1986) and Robert Lucas (1988), winner of the 1995 Nobel Prize in Economics, argue that whereas how endogenous to a firm and how the interplay occurs between firms, thus external to them, it is internal to regional industrial clusters, such as Silicon Valley: The self-propelling growth mechanisms remain endogenous, but internal to the regional cluster as 31 whole – this result in extending of the principle of increasing returns from firm to region. Network Orgnization See pp. 266-268, Chapter 9, Berry B.J.L., Conkling E.C. and Ray D.M. (1997), The Global Economy in Transition (second edition), Prentice Hall Inc., New Jersey, United States. The New Explanation: Market is imperfect, however, MNEs thrive on market imperfection – Structural Imperfection and Market Insecurity, which cause a long-term and institutionalized risk for firms Structural: Government restriction, tax, subsidies, tariff, quota etc Market: Capital market insecurity: uncertain of delivery, volatility of exchange rate, difficulty for customer checking and evaluation, cost of negotiation, infringement of intellectual property rights The motivation to overcome the market imperfacction and the pressure to secure market share make MNCs/firms enter trade with FDI by entering other countries and setting up their production bases – internationalization and specialization of production. However, when MNCs/firms doing so, they find another great discovery - the opportunities for increasing returns that specialization and concentration of production makes possible by increasing its scale 32 economies and technological progress – specialization, concentration and agglomeration leads to increasing returns! Thus, MNCs/firms and even countries may enter into trade in order to enjoy the opportunities for increasing returns, initially due to the market is structurally imperfect. Thus, MNCs/firms and even countries may enter into trade so as to benefit from increasing returns that explain the proliferation of intra-industries and intra-firms trade – a two-way trade, initially due to the market is structurally imperfect. Specialization on path dependence – history matters and trying to make history by setting up a head-start, which also leads to late comer advantage The Gains from Trade again – The Second Gains from Trade: Imperfect competition make MNCs/firms enter trade and then allows them discover and enjoy the possibility for increasing returns that offers extra gains over and above those obtainable from conventional trade based on comparative advantage. Increasing returns also offer extra gains from trade for those countries having relative same factor endowments. Trade offers a way for a firm to sell to a larger market than afforded by its home country and at the same time, through scale economies, to increase its 33 productivity, efficiency and international competitiveness. That is why for the secure of market share so as to benefit from increasing returns helps to explain the proliferation of intra-industry trade, intra-firm trade, intra-region/territory trade – Global/regional economic integration – free trade block. 34 There are following effects: Own Production Effects – increasing returns reduce own cost Learning by doing and become more experiencing that reduce the Cost Concentration Effect of Production – increasing returns reduce prices worldwide Specialization Scale economy Agglomeration economy Rationalization and Internal Propelling Effect – increasing returns increase productivity and efficiency worldwide New technology New way of product Spillover effect Self-propelling Diversity Effect – increasing returns increase diversity worldwide New place --- new opportunity – new products Other alike opportunity – spill-over effects or externalities New market 35 This new theory implies that the world as a whole benefits from trade twice, or even Three-fold: Gains from comparative advantage that increases total world production and consumption – the “arm’s-length” trade Gains from increasing return resulted in scale economies agglomeration economies, new technology, new way of production that multiply productivity , production efficiency, and diversity of production. Third Gains: Give chance to catch up from absolute disadvantage to absolute advantage and give way to late comer advantage This is what we call: ‘The mechanism that transforms the world” - The mechanism of globalization and the definition of “global perspective”, globalization, and “Go Global” Grand Implications – Toward A Theory of International Transaction 36 Multi-agents for trade – Market is only one agent, others are firms and its structure, consumer groups, national government, and supranational government. Integration of Trade and Production Integration of trade and production and organization: Organizing Role of Firms, its hierarchies and networking Integration of Trade and Production and Innovation/ Technological Progress Complex of Trade – Trade includes every aspects of our lives: goods, people, capital, technology (skills), information (experience/management), knowledge (property rights), policy/regulations…. Organizing Role of National Government Organizing Role of Supranational Government – GATT and WTO The mechanism of globalization, the essence of globalization process - That is what we mean by the “Global Perspective”, and “Globalization” Reference: Chapter 9 and 11: Berry B.J.L., Conkling E.C. and Ray D.M. (1997), The Global Economy in Transition (second edition), Prentice Hall Inc., New Jersey, United States. 37 Lecture IIIa: Trade regimes (WTO), Regionalization and Global Development: Intervention, Control and Policy Trade plays a central role in economic growth, serving as a means for acquiring necessary factors of production and technology; Though trade is essential for development, it poses special problems for many LDCs. High on the list of problems affecting national growth and development are physical and political barriers to trade in addition to unfair international trade terms; However, all are emulating one another to trade and aim at an ultimate goal – free trade Thus, trade policy and intervention promoting or restricting to trade – trade conflict occurs – trade regimes occurs: regionalization, Again, MNEs make all difference – breaking through both physical and political barriers and demanding WTO Thus, needs for international cooperation – GATT and WTO overcoming physical cost and political barriers (artificial obstacles) 38 Trade and Growth Growth and the Propensity to Trade Growth through Technology The trade effects of technology Technology – Invention and Innovation; Invention – new idea and discovery; Innovation – use of new idea Two kinds of innovation – new way (efficiency) and new thing (complete different new products) Technology change every aspects of our life and is the most dynamic element in today’s world trade picture. Creation of technology: Education and R&D, Buy and Theft – Trade Trade growth and the diffusion of innovation Trade and Development Trade problems of LDCs – locked into long-term poverty Unequal trade terms with industrialized countries Trade strategies for development Trade whatever you can and the launch of the industrialization of a country and then to participate in high level trade and share the benefit of trade 39 Barriers to Trade Distance Transfer costs make goods more expensive to importers and less valuable to exporters – see Figure 12.2 The end result is that transport cost decrease international specialization – USA produces more and sell less abroad while Canada reduce output though sell more at home Bill Gates foresee ahead a world of “friction-free capitalism” in which markets come close to Adam Smith’s concept of perfect competition and in which the distance barrier will by and large be removed. However, there is still other kind of intervention – political interference 40 Political Interference Incentives for intervention Incentives for intervention – Why do governments intervene? Nationalism Balance of payment – Equal between the total export and import of goods and services including visible trade and invisible trade Visible trade – merchandise goods that is physical Invisible trade –all kinds of services – transportation, tourism, financial service (banking and insurance), investment service (international transfer of interest, dividends, profits), and professional service (consultancy), and technological service. It also includes foreign exchange from gifts, private charities, money sent by individual expatriates, governmental one-way transactions (government loans, foreign aid, pension payment), and long-term capital flows (FDI and mutual fund portfolio investment – making loans to or purchasing stock in foreign countries). Nowadays, balance of payment is very hard to measure and tends to not much important in making national trade policy Political interference includes trade exhibition fairs, government subsidies, loan guarantees, tax rebates, and other incentives to exporters Tariffs (both import and export) Two main reasons: to earn revenue and to protect domestic producers, especially industries where the countries is on the early developmental stage – the “socalled” infant industry see Figure 12.3 Imposition of tariffs has a protection effect, a consumption effect, and an income-redistribution effect. Tariff is basically a way of taxing foreigner. Tariff leads to retaliation, hence reduce trade, trade specialization, production and consumption 41 Quotas – a specific limitation on the quantity of exports or imports, particularly the latter Quota system makes domestic plants gain at expense of both domestic consumers and foreign suppliers. The effects are inflationary for the importing countries and at the same time they could possess monopoly control of production, hence the price of that good, in which it holds monopoly Quota is extremely arbitrary Quota yields no revenue to government Quota leads to uneasy feelings and retaliation, because of its inherent unfairness Other Non-tariff Measures State exchange control and distribution State monopolies in specific commodities such as alcoholic beverages, sugar, tobacco, cocoa, grains and other agricultural products Special labeling and packaging Sanitary and safety regulations (Japan and Europe in agricultural prodacts protection are using this excuse) Special measures and specifications 42 Effects of Trade on the Factors of Production Factor Prices and Quantities Factor Mobility With today’s globalisation trade, factors of production have increasingly become mobile but the degree of mobility of different factors are different – capital, asset, entrepreneurship, technology, labour (unskilled labour), local culture/tradition/habit having different mobility. In conventional theory, trade will equalize prices, but the MNEs and FDI may do the opposite – because of circular and cumulative causes giving rise to increasing returns 43 Lecture IV: China’s Foreign Trade Overview 1980 1985 1990 1991 1995 1998 China’s Foreign Trade, 1978-91 (US $ Million) Ministry Data Customs Data Total Imports Exports Total Imports Exports 37.8 19.6 18.3 38.1 20.0 18.1 60.3 34.3 25.9 69.6 42.3 27.4 84.1 32.4 51.7 111.6 53.4 62.1 99.5 38.5 60.9 115.4 63.8 71.9 N/A 280.1 132.1 148.0 N/A 324.0 141.0 184.0 China’s Foreign Trade Growth, 1980-91 Average Annual Growth Rate (%) China’s trade: Ministry Data Customs Data Memo items: China’s growth of gross national product World Trade Growth 9.2 12.3 8.8 5.5 In the pre-reform era, exports were selected without much consideration of China’s comparative advantage → As a result, expanding exports might contribute little or nothing to economic growth Development economists have long argued that countries pursuing externally-oriented development strategies achieve higher rates of economic growth, because They attain higher rates of savings and investment More efficient use of scarce resources Allow technological upgrading A source of rapid productivity growth China exports $152.3 billion yuan worth of goods and services in 1998 The most impressive export performance in China has been from the foreign-funded enterprises and Chinese firms engaged in export processing (township and village enterprises rather than state owned enterprises. 44 The output of foreign funded enterprises, along with that produced by firms with a variety of less important forms of ownership, constitutes from about 1% of output in 1985 to 7% by 1992. The contribution of foreign-funded enterprises to annual incremental exports rose from 4% in 1986 to an average of 3/5 in 1992-94. Comparatively, state owned firms, which produced 2/3 of all manufactured goods in 1985, have contributed a rapidly declining share of annual incremental exports. In 1986 and 1987 they accounted for more than 4/5 of the growth of exports, in 1991-92, they still accounted for fully half of all manufactured goods production, their contribution was only a fifth By 1994 foreign funded enterprises accounted for 15 times more exports than would have been expected on the basis of their contribution to output China began its economic reform with virtually no external debt A very large share of the exports of foreign-funded enterprises are processed products such as machinery, electronics and garments Export earnings are largely used to pay for imported components and assemblies used in the production of these goods, therefore, the imports were mostly financed by export earnings After the launching of the economic reform, China had been trading predominantly with Western market economies for almost two decades China has not borrowed significant amounts on international markets China charged a relatively high tariff, which would change after China’s accession to the WTO The state-owned industries have not participated proportionately in the growth of China’s exports, and they are heavily insulted from international competition, and are protected heavily (for example: The chemical industry receives an effective rate of protection from imports of more than 110%) They appeared to be ill-prepared to compete with foreign firms in China’s domestic market Effects on Foreign Invested firms on Trade The small amounts of foreign direct investment in the late 1970s and early 1980s initially made a negligible contribution to China’s total exports As late as 1985, six years after the passage of China’s foreign investment law and five years after the establishment of special economic zones, the exports of foreign invested enterprises were only $320 million, barely 45 over 1% of China’s total exports, → Expanded dramatically, reaching about $35 billion by 1994. Exports produced by foreign invested firms are predominantly products assembled from imported parts and components. Many Chinese firms also produce processed exports using parts and components supplied by or purchased from foreign firms Total processed exports grew to $57 billion in 1994, almost half of China’s exports They comprised about 60% of $100 billion in manufactured goods exports that year In recent years about half of these exports have been produced by foreign-funded firms Foreign Borrowing and Foreign Equity Investment It is China’s second largest source of foreign capital China’s total external debt rising from well under $1 billion in 1978, to $93 billion by the end of 1994 China is the only transition economy, except for the Czech Republic, that enjoys an investment grade rating on its sovereign debt, allowing it to sell its bonds internationally with a lower interest rate than the market would otherwise demand It was the ready access to international borrowing which made China to enjoy the luxury of running relatively large trade deficits in the first three years of economic reform China’s external debt is only modestly smaller than the two most heavily indebted upper-middle income economies, Mexico and Brazil At the end of 1993, China’s total external debt was $83.6 billion, a little over $10 billion was owed to the World Bank and other lending agencies Borrowing from private creditors on commercial terms comprised only about three-fifths of China’s total external debt B shares in China, which are priced in domestic currency but paid in hard currencies, began in 1992, in Shenzhen and in Shanghai. The listing of nine Chinese state owned companies on the Hong Kong stock exchange beginning in 1993 In 1994 gross capital inflows exceeded $53 billion, including about $17 billion in borrowing from commercial banks, international organizations, bilateral development banks and international bond markets, there is about $2.5 billion in equity investments→ These figures suggest that 46 China is heavily dependent on foreign capital to finance investment and thus to generate the rapid economic growth of the 1990s. At least to the end of 1994, foreign capital appears to have been an insignificant source of investment in China. The reasons: Capital inflows may be used to finance a current accounts deficit or may added to the foreign exchange holdings of the government, enterprises or individuals. Capital inflows must be measured on a net basis, outflows of capital must be taken into account Official holdings of foreign exchange by the People’s Bank of China more than doubled in 1994, from $21.2 billion throughout 1993 to $51.6 billion throughout 1994 Individual holdings of foreign exchange in the Bank of China and other banks authorized to accept foreign exchange deposits, which since August 1992 have not been included in China’s official foreign exchange holdings, grew by about $6 billion in 1994. Retained foreign exchange earnings of the Bank of China and other financial institutions presumably also rose. It is instructive to examine China’s current account, ignoring for the moment changes in reserve holdings, any current account deficit must be financed with a capital inflow. In short, net capital inflows must be used either to finance a current account deficit or be added to foreign exchange holdings. After adjusting for changes in holding of foreign reserves, China’s net capital inflows over time can be measured by its cumulative current account deficit On a year-by-year basis China’s current account surplus of about $13 billion in 1991 was only 3.7% per cent of GNP The average current account deficit or surplus over the 12 year period was less than half that of 1991→ China’s average current account position has been quite modest From the beginning of 1982 to the end of 1993 it was actually a positive $5.846 billion This does not mean that China experienced a net outflow of capital, for changes in China’s foreign exchange reserves have been ignored Over the same period China’s total foreign exchange reserves rose by $44.2 billion. Therefore China’s cumulative capital inflow over the period is the difference between the increase in reserves and the current account surplus or about $38.4 billion. 47 As China’s cumulative GDP from 1982 to the end of 1993 was $4,100 billion, the cumulative net foreign capital inflows would amount to less than one per cent of cumulative output Because purchasing power parity estimates Chinese output in 1990 place GDP at from 3.5 to 8 times the level calculated on the exchange rate If the same relationship holds over the entire world, China’s cumulative net capital inflow over 12 years could have been as low as one-tenth of 1% of Chinese GDP Cumulative net foreign capital inflow relative to cumulative output of the Chinese economy over the 12 years was less than 1% and may have been vanishingly small The contribution of net foreign savings to gross domestic investment varies; in some years it is positive and in others negative. Contrary to what one might believe on the huge foreign capital flowing into China, on a net basis such inflows have not contributed to domestic capital formation in China. Foreign capital has not made a major impact on China’s savingsinvestment balance, it has contributed significantly to the transfer to China of advanced technology and managerial practices in many industries, to the expansion of China’s trade; and indirectly to the supply of foreign exchange Explaining China’s Export Growth Chinese Exports of Crude Oil and Refined Petroleum Products, 197790 Millions of tons Billions of US$ 1977 11.1 1.0 1980 17.5 4.3 1985 36.24 6.7 1990 29.25 4.3 48 Questions Explaining The Growth of Exports in China Although the pace of China’s trade expansion is clear, its sources are not. Various questions have been raised to explain the growth of exports in China. The questions are: Has the growth of exports been the result of decentralized decisions by firms and/or trading companies responding to economic incentives? Or has the rapid expansion of trade occurred largely within the traditional system of central planning? Are increases exports identified primarily through export planning and managed through nationally-run monopolistic foreign trade companies? What is the role of foreign-invested firms? The sources of China’s trade growth have changed significantly over the past dozen years. The surge in the value of exports in the late 1970s and early 1980s came largely from decisions of the state at the central level. A major source was increasing exports of petroleum, one of the key things identified to “finance foreign purchases.” It is the single product ategory accounted for one-third of China’s incremental export earnings After 1985, as petroleum is no longer served as significant sources of export growth. Trade decision making was becoming more decentralized and it became increasingly sensitive to economic factors In the first-half of the 1980s, primary products (including agricultural products and minerals) regularly comprised from 45 to 50 percent of China’s exports → A little change from the period from the mid-1960s to 1980 when they accounted for just over half The Commodity Compositions of Chinese Exports, 1980-91 (%) Primary Products Manufactured Products 1980 50.2 49.8 1981 46.6 53.4 1985 45.0 55.0 1990 25.6 74.4 1991 22.5 77.5 1998 11.7 88.3 49 Due to the rapid growth of exports of textiles and other light manufactured goods, after the mid-1980s, share of primary products in China’s exports fell continuously and the share of manufactured goods rose from half in 1985 to over three-quarters by 1991 The production of textiles and other light manufactured goods tends to be much more labour-intensive than the production of primary goods, such a shift suggesting China’s underlying comparative advantage in labourintensive products There is a strong inverse correlation between the growth of exports during 1985-90 and the ratio of capital to labour used in production. Chinese exports were increasingly labour-intensive after 1985 Between 1980-1985, there appears to belittle correlation between relative capital intensity in production Capital Intensity in Production of China’s Largest Incremental Export, 1985-90 SITC Trade Category Description Changes in Assets per Exports 1985- worker 90 (yuan) (US$ billions) D84 Apparel 4.31 5,222 D65 Textile yarn and fabrics 3.49 8,621 D89 Miscellaneous manufacturers 1.47 6,832 D76 Telecommunications and sound 1.41 20,277 Recording and reproducing equipment D85 Footwear 1.36 6,178 Mean of all export categories 0.45 13,991 There is a strong inverse correlation between export performance in 1985-90 and capital intensity in production The difference in the second half of the decade shrank in relative and sometimes absolute terms Three consequent of three critical developments of the evolvement of the composition of Chinese exports: Decentralization of decision-making in foreign trade Reforms in the pricing of traded goods, The abandonment of an over-valued exchange rate 50 Decentralization of Foreign Trade Pre-reform era: The co-ordination of the flow of raw materials and intermediate goods among major state enterprises and ensured that the production of each good was sufficient to meet both inter-industry demand and final demand for consumption, investment and export Planners used imports to fill the difference between planned demand and final demand for consumption Exports sufficient to pay for these imports were then identified, starting with goods for which domestic Exports sufficient to pay for these imports were then identified, starting with goods for which domestic supplies exceeded planned demands By the mid-1950s foreign trade was a complete monopoly of the central government. A handful of specialized foreign trade corporations, some created as early as March 1950, was responsible for implementing the plan Lack of competition since each of the foreign trade corporations was responsible for carrying out trade in specified, non-overlapping product areas The continued dominant role of these firms in the early years of reform is reflected in their share of China’s exports and imports In 1981 national foreign trade companies subordinate to the Ministry of Foreign Economic Relations and Trade accounted for 91% of exports and 87% of imports. By 1984 their shares were 79% and 65% respectively Trade reforms in the mid-1980s substantially altered it. Shown by two indicators: The growing number of foreign trade corporations The declining scope of the foreign trade plan The State Council, in 1984, called for an end to the monopoly power of the specialized national foreign trade companies→ The creation of a large number of small and medium sized trading companies. Within two years the Ministry of Foreign Economic Relations and Trade had approved the creation of more than 800 separate import and export corporations Many of these were created by converting the provincial branches of the national foreign trade companies into local companies carrying out trade in the same product lines. 51 Later province and municipalities established many general trading companies authorized to handle a much broader range of goods By the late 1980s the number of companies has soared to more than 5,000 China had long enjoyed a high reputation for fulfillment of trade contracts. Some of newly-created companies, however, lacked adequate experience and funding or were not able to acquire domestically the goods they had contracted to export Non-performance of trade contracts became a matter of growing concern to China’s trade partners The State Council reassert central control over the process of approving the creation of new trading companies and, subsequently, to dissolve or merge existing companies to be unqualified or illegal in May 1988 and March and November 1989 The resulting cutback still leaves substantial room for competition among these firms By the spring of 1990 roughly 70% of all foreign trade corporations had been examined and only 800 had been either closed or forced to merge with another corporation From 1985 foreign trade plan was divided into mandatory and guidance portions. Mandatory plan imports and exports were specified in quantitative terms and were usually the responsibility of the head offices of the national foreign trade companies Guidance plan imports and exports were generally specified in value terms, giving local trading corporations more flexibility This allowed them to take economic factors into account when determining the precise mix of imported and exported products within each category Pricing of Traded Goods The pre-reform trade regime world market prices had little or no effect on the Chinese domestic prices of tradeable goods. This led the World Bank to characterize China’s traditional trade regime as an “airlock system” Foreign trade corporations purchased goods specified by the plan from domestic producers at officially established prices Producers received the same prices whether goods were sold domestically or in the international market 52 They received none of the foreign exchange income from the sale of the goods abroad nor did they have any direct claim on it to purchase goods abroad for their own use Little economic incentive either to sell on the international market or to expand production of goods for which there was strong international demand Domestic prices of imported goods also tended to be unconnected to the world market since after 1964 the prices of 80% of China’s imports were set at levels comparable to similar domestic goods. Imports were sold at prices significantly below world prices Reforms, especially in the latter half of the 1980s, transformed the pricing of traded goods Domestic sale prices of a growing share of imported goods began to be based on the world market price The State Council’s 1984 foreign trade reform document called for the widespread adoption of the “agency system” in which foreign trade corporations undertake transactions on behalf of domestic firms and charge them a commission The agency system applies to imports the importing firm pays the world market price (converted to domestic currency at the official exchange rate) plus shipping and port fees, a commission, and any tariffs that apply, this system is known as “foreign trade agent price formation” By 1986, the domestic prices of four-fifths of all imports were based on import cost with only 28 commodities continuing to be priced according to comparable domestic goods After 1988 this list was reduced even further, including, during 1989, the removal of two of the most important commodities: from January timber and plywood, and from November most imported steel and nonferrous metals By the end of 1989 the list contained only 14 commodities so that the domestic prices of 90% of all China’s imports were based on world market prices In late April 1990 there were only eight commodity categories left: chemical fertilizer, wood pulp, alkyl benzene, five sodium compounds, nonionic surface active agents, grain, phosphorous ore, and titanium dioxide and intermediates for producing agro-chemicals The domestic prices of well over 90% of al goods imported into China in 1991 were based on world market prices The old pricing regime, which provided a high degree of protection to some import competing industries or a high degree of subsidy to domestic users of some imported commodities, had largely faded away 53 The initial pace of change in the domestic pricing of export goods appears to have been somewhat slower than that for imports By the late 1980s, the state used the pre-reform pricing system for only 21 export goods These planned exports accounted for only 20% of the value of China’s total exports in 1988, and 55% of total exports in 1988 fell outside the plan in the same year The exports outside the plan are the proliferation of competing foreign trade companies sought to bargain for the most favourable prices Initially these corporations sought to exploit the producers’ lack of knowledge of world market conditions by paying them low prices for their goods The growing number of trading companies, the degree of competition increased, tending to move domestic prices closer to world market prices Producers of the 21 commodities that fell within the export plan could take advantage of this competition by producing quantities of goods above the planned level Over plan production could be sold internationally on a decentralized basis and producers bargained with foreign trade corporations for more favourable domestic prices for that portion of their output As the scope of the foreign trade plan shrank and competition among a growing number of foreign trade corporations increased, the influence of international prices on domestic prices of exports rose The Exchange Rate and Exchange Control The price of foreign exchange had little effect on the volume of either imports or exports in the pre-reform era Thus, as in other centrally-planned economies, the exchange rate was a largely passive policy instrument Chinese domestic currency was highly over-valued in the pre-reform era and the resulting excess demand for foreign exchange was handled through a rigid system of exchange control The domestic currency cost of earning foreign exchange was persistently higher than the official exchange rate, making most exports financially unprofitable The Ministry of Foreign Trade reallocated the profits that were made by some foreign trade corporations on their sale of exported goods 54 The effective exchange rate varied from corporation to corporation and sometimes even on a product-by-product basis This phenomenon, which has called the “price-equalization mechanism”, was common in centrally-planned economies Compensating for the divergences between domestic and foreign prices undermined the incentive for trading companies to exploit comparative advantage trade opportunities Reforms of the exchange rate and relaxation of exchange control were among the most dramatic changes in China during the last decade The Chinese authorities devalued the currency from a rate that averaged 1.6 RMB per US dollar in the late 1970s to an average of 5.3 RMB in 1991 The Yuan-Dollar Exchange Rate, 1978-91 Year Yuan per Dollar 1978 1.68 1980 1.50 1985 2.94 1990 4.78 1991 5.32 2001 8.80 Changes in the official exchange rate had only a modest effect on trade in the first half of the 1980s under these reasons: Since the reform of traded goods pricing was just beginning, the exchange rate had little effect either on the domestic currency earnings of most export producers or on the prices paid by most consumers of imports Changes in the official exchange rate did not really affect the foreign trade corporations which were responsible for most trade transactions In their transactions with the bank of China they cleared their accounts at exchange rates that differed from the official rate but did not necessarily change when the latter changed Foreign trade corporations frequently received financial subsidies to cover domestic currency losses from foreign trade transactions. From 1985, changes in the exchange rate had a greater effect on trade This was partly because changes in the pricing of traded goods meant that exchange rate adjustments had a direct effect on the domestic prices of an increasing number of imports and exports 55 The value of the currency fell significantly in the second half of the 1980s By the end of 1990, the official rate remained at 3.72, from the middle of 1986 to near the end of 1989, the average exchange rate received by exporters improved significantly since they could convert a rising share of their export earnings to domestic currency at a more favourable swap market rate By the end of 1990 the real value, i.e. adjusted for relative inflation in China and the rest of the world) of the Chinese currency was 61% of that in 1985 when the value is calculated on a trade weighted basis. Combined with the reform of the pricing of traded goods this devaluation reduced substantially the bias against exports and the subsidy to imports of the pre-reform foreign trade and payments regime The resulting reduction in the excess demand for foreign exchange made possible a significant reduction in the rigidity of the exchange control system The process of relaxation began as early as 1979 with a modest foreign exchange retention system that provided firms producing export goods with a claim to use a small share of the foreign exchange earnings their products generated The scheme expanded steadily in different dimensions. The average share of retained earnings grew from less than 10% of export earnings in 1979 to more than 40% by 1988 Secondly, the opportunity to trade these foreign exchange use rights, which was introduced in 1980 Formal parallel markets existed as early as 1985 By 1988, there were parallel auction markets for foreign exchange in about 40 Chinese cities The volume of trading in foreign exchange steadily expanded over the decade The volume of transactions soared from $4.2 billion in 1987 to $13.2 billion by 1990. In the first 11 months of 1991 it grew by more than 50% to reach $18.175 billion Initially there was a substantial gap between the official exchange rate and the market price of foreign exchange, reflecting the continued overvaluation of the domestic currency at the official exchange rate. But, as the volume of transactions on the parallel market for foreign exchange expanded and the State Administration of Exchange Control devalued the official exchange rate further in December 1989 and 56 November 1990, excess demand for foreign exchange at the official rate ebbed In late 1990, when the official rate was 5.2 yuan per dollar, the parallel market rate was only 5.4 yuan per dollar, the parallel market rate was only 5.4 yuan per dollar. In 1991 the State Administration Exchange Control began a policy of frequent but small adjustments in the official exchange rate These adjustments, which led to an official exchange rate of 5.4 by the end of the year, appear to be partly guided by developments in the foreign exchange market For example, by the third quarter of 1991 the parallel market rate had increased to 5.83 But because the official rate has been devalued further, this represented a premium of under 10% over the official rate at that time The role of the swap market in allocating foreign exchange grew as a result of reforms of the foreign exchange retention system introduced in 1991 Before this each province had a fixed quota of foreign exchange to be delivered to the center and was allowed to retain 80% of all foreign exchange earnings above this amount For the other 20%, they were paid in RMB at the official exchange rate. Retained foreign exchange could be used to finance imports outside the plan or could be sold on the swap market for domestic currency The 1991 reform of the foreign trade contract system abolished the distinction between quota and over-quota foreign exchange earnings, substituting instead a requirement that half of all foreign exchange must be remitted to the center This effectively raises the marginal rate of remission from 20% to 50% The centre agreed to pay for the increased flow at the swap market rate rather than the official exchange rate, that is it will buy two-fifths of remitted foreign exchange at the official exchange rate and three-fifths at the swap market rate As a result the swap market price has become even more important Before the 1991 reform, approximately half of all foreign exchange was priced, either implicitly or explicitly, at the swap market rate From 1991 this fraction rose to four-fifths According to one prediction made early in 1991, the total amount of foreign exchange priced explicitly at the swap market rate in 1991, including that which the centre would pay for at the swap rate, would 57 reach $25 billion. The net sales of the foreign exchange swap market rose from $442 million in 1988 to more than $3 billion in 1994 The net result of these reforms was to erode substantially the bias against exporting Exporters on average received a much more favourable exchange rate for that share of their earnings they were still received the remainder in the form of a use right That use right either could be sold for domestic currency in a market where the degree of official intervention appears to have diminished significantly in the past five years or could be used to buy foreign goods On the import side, the implicit subsidy available to users of planned imports shrank dramatically as more and more goods were imported on a decentralized basis and priced according to the world market price converted to yuan at a more realistic official exchange rate or at the parallel market price for foreign exchange China appears to be within striking distance of achieving internal convertibility of the RMB in trade transactions. Among the socialist and former socialist states, only Poland matches this pace of reform. Unlike Poland, China’s reform was not backed by writing off and restructuring foreign debt or standby loan agreement with the IMF Regional and Sectoral Export Trends The three reforms analysed briefly above created the conditions in which decentralized trade based on economic incentives could flourish. This is evident in the kinds of enterprises that became the most successful exporters by the late 1980s Particularly significant is the growing share of China’s exports produced by rural township and village enterprises and joint venture enterprises. This trend was most obvious in the second half of the 1980s when the three reforms really began to take hold Rural enterprise exports jumped from about four to more than 12 billion dollars between 1985 and 1990 and joint ventures exports from around a quarter of a million dollars in 1985 to 12 billion dollars in 1991 These two decentralized sectors of the Chinese economy accounted for a large share of the growth of exports in the second half of the 1980s when the opportunities for decentralized exporting clearly emerged 58 Exports of Rural and Joint Ventures Enterprises, 1985-91 (US$ billions) Rural Enterprises Joint Venture Enterprises 1985 3.9 0.3 1990 12.5 7.8 1991 N/A 12.1 1998 N/A 19.5 Additional evidence of the new conditions comes from an examination of the regional pattern of export growth within China The Guangdong province is the most notable example In 1978, Guangdong was a second-tier exporter selling 41.4 billion in world markets, about half the level of Shanghai Up to the middle of the 1980s, Guangdong’s share of China’s total exports actually fell slightly Guangdong is not a significant producer of crude oil, refined petroleum products or the capital-intensive manufactured goods that were the main sources of China’s export growth up to the mid-1980s After 1985 Guangdong’s share rose significantly. Exports more than quadrupled from just under $3 billion in 1985 to $13.69 billion in 1991 The average annual rate of growth of Guangdong’s exports over this period was 29% compared to 13% for the rest of the country Gunagdong’s share of China’s exports rose from 11% in 1985 to 21% in 1991 In the process Guangdong eclipsed Shanghai to become China’s largest exporter Exports of Shanghai-produced goods rose only 10% between 1981 and 1988 It is easy to say Guangdong’s success is entirely on its proximity to Hong Kong and its large share of China’s foreign-invested enterprises Exports of foreign-invested firms in 1990 did account for a third of the province’s earnings with processing and compensation trade bringing another 6%. But half the growth between 1985 and 1990 was due to expanded international sales by indigenous firms in the region, so other factors must be involved. Several cases can be suggested: Guangdong manufacturing firms were on average only half the size of Shanghai’s and they were much less likely to be stateowned. In 1988 the two regions produced almost identical levels of industrial output, measured by gross value, but the number of 59 firms in Guangdong was twice that in Shanghai. Guangdong firms were smaller and capable of responding more quickly to changing international market conditions The advantage of small size was reinforced by the modest role of the state in the ownership of Guangdong’s industry. Only one-quarter of firms were state-owned. Three-quarters, producing by 1988 60% of manufactured goods output, were urban collective, township and village, private or joint venture firms They were far more entrepreneurial than state owned firms, purchasing most of their inputs and selling most of their output on the market rather than working through the state’s material distribution and wholesaling systems On the contrary, in Shanghai, entrepreneurial firms in 1988 produced only one-third of industrial output Large-scale, state-run establishments dominated the municipality’s manufacturing sector The second critical difference was that Guangdong, having had a low priority in the state’s plans for economic development since the 1950s, had a more market-oriented economy than Shanghai, even before reform With fewer state-owned firms tied to the state’s system of material distribution, enterprises in the province were more likely to buy raw materials, machinery and other producer goods on the market. By 1991 this had expanded further and more than 80% of all producer goods (i.e. machinery, equipment and other capital goods) used in the province were purchased on the market, whereas nationally the figure was only about half Many of the capital goods used in Guangdong came from other provinces The development of markets and the use of marketing agents with welldeveloped extra-provincial ties were critical to the success of Guangdong’s firms In contrast, Shanghai’s industries were dependent largely on the state’s system of material distribution At this system eroded in the 1980s, some state-run industries declined as they lost their primary source of raw material supplies and were unable or unwilling to develop alternative sources through the market, especially in the textile industry As central government’s deliveries of raw cotton to the city’s factories fell sharply in the second half of the 1980s, the industry fell into a slump still not recovered 60 Coal is another commodity that signifies the differences between Shanghai and Guangdong, neither of which has any major local deposits In 1989 the central government provided three-quarters of Shanghai’s coal requirements through the system of planned allocation The municipality purchased the remainder on the open market But in Guangdong in the same year, the central government’s allocations provided only 32% of the requirements and 68% had to be purchased on the market outside the province As a result Guangdong paid substantially more for its coal, and passed on the cost to its customers in higher electricity rates While Guangdong suffered power shortages, they appeared modest given the pace of industrial development in the region Guangdong development reliable extra-provincial supplies of coal through market channels and built additional thermal-powered generating capacity financed largely by local resources, more than doubled its output of electric power between 1985 and 1990, meeting rapidly rising demand both from industry and from domestic consumers as electric appliances became common in both urban and rural areas Shanghai’s electric power output rose only 10% over the same period Guangdong was able to compensate for what initially appeared to be a disadvantage, its low priority in the state’s plan for the distribution of key industrial commodities, by increasing its reliance on the market The rapid growth of Guangdong’s trade contributed to a structural change of the province’s industry as well as an acceleration of its economic growth Between 1978 and 1990 industrial output in the province expanded by an average of 16.3% per annum in real terms, more than4% per annum over the national average But Guangdong’s light industry grew even more rapidly, on average 18.8% per year, so that its share of total industrial output rose from 57 to 69% This structural change was largely a result of the province’s rapidly growing exports and evolving export structure Guangdong’s traditional exports were predominantly live pigs, vegetables and other agricultural goods sold primarily to Hong Kong In 1985, 41% of the exports of indigenous local firms (excluding joint venture firms and firms engaged in processing and compensation trade) were agricultural and processed agricultural products By 1990 this had fallen to only 25%, mirroring a 15% point increase in the share of light and textile industry exports 61 The dramatic rise in the latter reflected huge increases in the exports of shoes (rising 41 times between 1985 and 1990), garments (up six-fold), cotton piece goods (up seven-fold), silk piece goods (quadrupling), plastic items (up 18-fold), toys (quadrupling), and tools (up five-fold) There is no evidence that trade played a similar role in transforming Shanghai’s industry over the same period Industrial output grew by only 6.9% per annum, little more than half the national average Between 1978 and 1990 light industry advanced only marginally more rapidly than heavy industry, and indeed for the period 1981-90 heavy industry slightly outperformed light industry Thus after 1981 the share of heavy industry increased almost 3% points to reach 45.3% of industrial output in 1990, proportionately half again as large in Guangdong. The Pace of Trade Reform China’s Balance of Trade, 1983-98 (US$ billions) 1983 +0.8 1984 -1.3 1985 -14.9 1986 -12.0 1987 -3.8 1988 -7.7 1989 -6.6 1990 +8.7 1991 +8.1 1998 +16.6 The reform process was slowed down or even set back in two periods, from the second quarter of 1985 until 1987, and from mid-1989 into 1991 Liberalization of foreign trade, particularly of imports, in the fourth quarter of 1984 led to a growing trade imbalance China framed the foreign trade liberalization passed by the State Council in September 1984 from a position of a trade surplus In the fourth quarter imports grew at an astounding rate of 50% and the trade balance turned sharply negative 62 The trend accelerated throughout 1985 leading to an all-time record annual trade deficit of $14.9 billion The second period of significant trade imbalance began in 1988. As previous administrative measures had brought the merchandise account closer to balance by the end of 1987, controls on imports were relaxed. An upsurge of consumer expenditure in 1988 led to rapidly rising imports Although the government moved to reduce domestic credit expansion from the fourth quarter of 1988 to cool down an overheated economy, the flow of imports was not interrupted Indeed increased imports of consumer goods, particularly durables, may have been seen as a means of mopping up excess purchasing power that was contributing to an unusually high rate of inflation in the latter half of 1988 As a result in the 12-month period ending in June 1989, the trade deficit reached $12.3 billion, almost matching the previous record 12-month deficit in 1985 In both periods the state adopted a variety of administrative measures to restrict imports and promote exports in order to reduce the trade imbalance In 1985 a major way of cutting back on decentralized imports was a freeze on the use of retained foreign exchange Localities and export-producing enterprises were subject to “quota controls on the use of retained foreign exchange” that drastically reduced their use a fraction of the foreign exchange they had earned By the end of 1986, $19.1 billion in retained foreign exchange had been “borrowed” by the central government, which used it in part to finance its own trade deficit When the system of retained foreign exchange “borrowed” by the centre was never repaid In response to the second period of a burgeoning deficit, the central authorities imposed substantially increased restrictions on imports, particularly after mid-1989 There was a ban on the import of many types of consumer goods, an expansion of the scope of import substitution restrictions on imports, and a recentralization of control of decision-making on some types of imports Imports of foreign luxury cars, cigarettes, alcohol and canned beverages were banned from the first half of 1989 The list of import substitute products, which cannot be imported without the permission of the Ministry supervising domestic production of competing goods, expanded significantly 63 That led to de facto bans on some imports even when the foreign goods were cheaper than or technologically superior to the domestic product. The state also reassert central control of imports of a broad range of products, including wool, some types of steel products, plywood, colour television components, scientific measuring devices, various types of building materials and chemical fertilizer At the same time the state stepped up efforts to provide preferred access both to raw materials and to credit to assure the continued growth of exports Assured credit supplies for exporters were particularly important in the fourth quarter of 1988 and in 1989 because the central monetary authority was pursuing an overall restrictive credit, exports would have been severely restricted The effect of these measures on the trade balance was dramatic By the third quarter of 1989 imports were falling in absolute terms, reducing the quarterly trade deficit to $700 million, less than a fifth of the deficit in the second quarter. In the final quarter of 1989, the deficit was only $100 million. In 1990 China achieved trade surpluses that grew greater in each quarter For the year as a whole, imports fell $5.8 billion, exports rose $9.5 billion, and the trade surplus was $8.74 billion By the end of 1990 Chinese foreign exchange reserves had risen to $28.6 billion, more than twice the level of mid-1989 The reduction of the deficit should have set the stage for a renewed relaxation of controls on imports Imports did begin to grow in the last quarter of 1990 and continued to do so at double-figure rates in the early months of 1991 But exports moved up even more rapidly leading to substantial monthly trade surpluses In the first half of 1991 the trade surplus grew almost 50% compared to the first half of 1990 China’s trade strategy had changed fundamentally from a genuine policy of “opening up” and “trade liberalization” towards a policy of “continued emphasis on export growth without import liberalization” Compared with the same period a year earlier, China’s balance of trade surplus fell sharply in the second half of 1991 It appears likely that this trend will accelerate in 1992 Chinese trade practices became a matter of growing concern in the US since what was a modest bilateral trade deficit with China in the mid1980s grew to 64 $6.2 billion in 1989 (the sixth largest American deficit on a worldwide basis $10.4 billion (the third largest) in 1990 $12.76 billion (the second largest) in 1991 These deficits were related to a dramatic shift in the direction of China’s trade, particularly on the export side, with the United States becoming an increasingly important market The United States share of China’s exports went from 6% in 1979 14% in 1985 26% in 1991 In contrast, the share of China’s exports going to Japan actually declined during the 1980s Japan absorbed $4 to $5 billion annually in Chinese products in 1980-82, approximately 24% of all Chinese exports By 1988-90 Japanese actually declined during the 1980s Japan absorbed $4 to 45 billion annually in Chinese products in 1980-82, approximately 24% of all Chinese exports By 1988-90 Japanese imports from China were $10-$12 billion annually, but that was only 19% of China’s then much larger export volume Japanese exports to China plunged from a peak of $12.5 billion in 1985 to only $6.1 billion in 1990 Thus from the late 1980s Japan too incurred a deficit in its trade with China China’s trade deficit with Japan is different from her trade deficit with the United States in two respects Even at its peak in 1990 of $5.9 billion Japan’s deficit was only about half that of the US Japan’s deficit narrowed to $5.6 billion in 1991 because of a 40% increase in exports combined with an 18% increase in imports (Japan’s share of China’s total exports stabilized), while the United States’ deficit continued to widen The growing bilateral trade deficit between US and China has led the US to initiate a formal bilateral discussions on market access issues in mid1991 with the expectation that the Chinese authorities would reduce the number and severity of administrative barriers they imposed on imports These included import licensing requirements; selective quantitative restrictions on imports; onerous technical barriers, mainly product testing and certification requirements; and a lack of transparency (i.e. many internal regulation not available to foreigners) in China’s trade regime Bilateral negotiations on China’s protection of intellectual property rights also began around the same time, in late May 1991 65 The US government believed that if copyright and patent protection provided by China were raised to world standards American firms would be more willing to sell computer software, chemicals, pharmaceuticals and so forth Increase American sales to China, thus reducing the deficit The first two rounds of bilateral discussions on market access took place in Beijing in June and in Washington in August 1991 President Bush (Senior) promised to initiate trade sanctions against Chinese imports into the US market if these efforts were not successful In October the US administration launched an investigation of China’s trade practices under Section 301 of the United States Trade Act of 1974 Under the provisions of the law China had until 10 October 1992 to satisfy specific American complaints or face prohibitive tariffs on some of its exports to the US Only a few weeks later the United States would impose prohibitive tariffs on specified Chinese exports This step is allowed under the special 301 provision of the US trade law dealing with foreign violations of American patents and copyrights Although many observers predicted that China would not respond to the threat of sanctions, an agreement was reached in mid January 1992, only hours before a final deadline for the imposition of punitive tariffs Under the agreement China undertook to provide stronger protection of patents and copyrights, particularly for pharmaceuticals and other chemical products, computer software and sound recordings. Conclusion China foreign trade has made stunning advances since economic reform began in the late 1970s Initially trade expansion was heavily state directed From the mid-1980s onward this was gradually displaced by a more market determined pattern of trade The proliferation of new trading companies that could compete with the handful of national foreign companies, which hold monopoly on trade before, and far-reaching reforms in the pricing of traded goods and the RMB created the economic environment in which decentralized trade decision-making based on economic incentives became increasingly important 66 The growing role of trade after 1985 in regions such as Guangdong Province, where the system of state-owned firms and their associated supply and marketing is relatively modest, highlights the character of China’s trade reforms The emergence of large trade deficits, once in the middle of the decade and once near the end, led to some retrogression as the centre increased its reliance on administrative intervention to curtail imports The main limitation on China’s trade reform is the partial nature of domestic economic reform As Lardy (1995) suggested although there is nothing wrong for relying foreign-funded enterprises to push the rapid export growth, but combined with the protection provided to state-owned industries, it has inhibited productivity growth, especially in intermediate input industries where prices are still above international levels. Export growth from foreign invested firms A large share of which is export processing Limited backward linkagesDomestic content of exports is very low Export industries appear to be enclaves and China’s state-owned industries have underparticipated in export growth by a wide margin. Periodic burgeoning trade deficits reflect the centre’s difficulty in exercising macroeconomic control of a semi-reformed domestic economy The traditional system of controlling aggregate demand has atrophied significantly and the development of market-oriented fiscal and monetary policy instruments has just begun The sources of export growth, particularly in the second half of the 1980s and early 1990s, underline the limitations of domestic reform State-owned industrial enterprises account for a disproportionately small share of China’s export growth If China can address these problems successfully there seems little doubt that the reforms of the second half of the 1980s will provide the basis for the continued growth of Chinese exports and thus of imports as well. References: Lardy, N.R., (1995). "The Role of Foreign Trade and Investment in China’s Economic Transition” The China Quarterly, No.144, December, pp10651082. Lardy, N. R., (1996) “Chinese Foreign Trade”, in Ash, R.F. and Kueh, Y.Y., (eds), (1996) The Chinese Economy Under Deng Xiaoping, Clarendon Press, Oxford, UK 67 Lecture V: Theories of FDI in the Context of China What is FDI? The Majority of foreign investment is composed of Direct Investment Portfolio Investment The motivation of the investor is the determinate feature of the type of investment FDI is the lasting interest by a foreign investor in an enterprise to obtain an effective voice in the management of the enterprise For the international harmonization of the statistics, the lasting interest is identified with a numerical guidance of at least 10% ownership by the foreign investor (as opposed to portfolio investment for which the motivation of the investor is different) The 10% rule is the basic guidance for the classification of FDI statistics. Two schools on the role of FDI: As a Dynamic force in the host country DFI makes a positive contribution to the economic growth of the host country through: An increasing capital supply, Technology Transfer, Training Productivity gains As a Tool of International Exploitation by MNCs Investment by MNCs The ultimate economic dependence by the host country on MNCs, Undermines the host country’s economic authority MNCs are to exploit the natural resources and cheap labour The benefits of FDI mostly went to the MNCs through transfer pricing for imports and exports The Newly Industrialized Economies in East Asia, using foreign investment to promote export-oriented economic development. But FDI is less influential in Latin America and Africa. 68 FDI and multi-national corporation allows economic growth and development. It is necessary to incorporate the theories of FDI and MNCs into economic development theories. The theories of FDI and MNC are essentially micro-economic growth and development theories of analyses of transnational investment enterprises. Theories of Foreign Direct Investment There are six theories of Foreign Direct Investments. Neoclassical theory of capital mobility The industrial organization approach The transaction cost or internalization theory Location theory Dunning’s eclectic theory Kojima’s macroeconomic theory Neoclassical theory of capital Characteristics: It is part of the theory of international factor movements It implies the international movements of factors of production, including foreign investment, are determined by the different proportion of the primary production inputs available in different countries. Flow of investment: Countries where capital is relatively abundant → countries where capital is relatively scarce Movement of capital: Countries with low margin of productivity → Countries with high marginal productivity of capital Such international investment (or capital movement) may benefit both the investing and host countries Host country benefit from foreign investment. The productivity of the investment, as reflected in the income created, exceeds what foreign investors take out of the host country in the form of profit and interest 69 Weakness: The neoclassical theory assumes: Perfect competition, Zero transaction costs, Perfect competition Which fails to: Fully account for investors’ motivations and behaviour The impacts of investment on a real world with imperfect markets and uncertainty. It does not distinguish FDI from other forms of capital form It fails to explain the two-way capital flows between capital abundant countries, for instance, FDI between the US and Japan or between the US and Britain. It failed to highlight the social and economic consequences of FDI. Industrial Organization Theory Movement of capital associated with FDI is not a response to higher interest rates in “host” countries but takes place in order to finance international operations. Firms move abroad are based on a theory of firm and industrial organization. It is primarily concerned with the characteristics of multinational corporations and the market structures in which they operate. Market structure and competition conditions are the determinants of the types of firms which engage in FDI. Firm-specific advantages, such as a firm’s market position, to explain the international investment of the MNC’s. These firm-specific advantage include: Patents, Superior Knowledge Product Differentiation, Expertise in Organizational and Management Skills, Access to Overseas Markets To Credit 70 Such advantages made certain firms have over competitors in the home country can be extended into foreign markets through international direct investment. Hence, FDI, in this theory, is regarded as oligopolistic MNCs seek to close out market competition by the erection of barriers to entry and firm-specific advantages Location Theory It places emphasis on country-specific characteristics. It explains FDI in terms of relative economic conditions in both the source and host countries. Two subdivisions of the approach: Input-oriented Output-oriented Input-oriented factors are associated with supply variables, such as: Labour, Raw Materials, Energy Capital Output-oriented factors are the determinants of market demand, including: Population Size, Income per capita, Openness of the Markets The country-specific factors not only determine where MNCs make direct investment, but also can account for the different types of FDI such as domestic-market-oriented investment and export-oriented investment. The Transaction Cost or Internalization Approach Characteristics: 71 The activities of MNCs are a response to market imperfection which causes increased transaction costs. It explains the better outcome of efficiency resulted from internalization Through FDI, two types of market imperfection may be internalized: Structural and the market of transaction costs. Structural: Market imperfection associated with regulatory aspects, such as: Tariffs or subsidies Foreign Exchange Controls Import Quotas Income Taxes Restrictions on profit repartriation MNCs to internalize this type of market imperfection for a rentseeking purpose. Market imperfection also relates to market transaction costs, especially for an intangible asset transaction such as technology transfer. MNCs prefer FDI rather than trade or licensing the use of their firmspecific intangible assets. The transaction cost or internalization theory is a model pf private welfare maximization. Weakness: It allows little room for social welfare considerations It fails to account for the macroeconomic impact of FDI. Dunning’s Eclectic Theory of International Production Characteristics: It combines the industrial organization approach with both the location theory and internalization theory to explain FDI and international production activities. It is also known as OLI theory 72 It applies to entry-mode selection states that firms will choose the most appropriate form of entry into a international market by considering the following Their ownership advantages The location advantages of the country under consideration The internalization advantages of the particular situation Ownership Advantages Ownership (O) advantages are firm-specific competitive advantages (Porter, 1980) that the firm may possess These ownership advantages are created through A firm’s international experience, Size, Their ability to differentiate their product or service, The adaptability of the product or service, The service intensity and the technology intensity of their offerings (Dunning, 1993) Examples of ownership advantages might include Unique products or services which cannot easily be duplicated by competitors, or The possession of financial and experiential resources which provide a method for entry into otherwise closed markets. Ownership advantages need to be both unique and sustainable in order to provide the firm with a competitive advantage in entrymode selection (Porter, 1980) Locational Advantages Locational (L) advantages are country-specific factors related to the market under consideration – market potential and market risk (Root, 1987) and are available to all firms in that particular market (Dunning, 1988). However, some firms are better able to utilize these location advantages then other firms, thus enhancing their competitive advantage either within the new market, for example through better coordination of within country activities, or internationally, for example providing lower cost labour which would result in a cost advantage in all markets where the firm’s products are sold (Dunning, 1998) 73 Measures of location advantages include sales demand and potential demand, differences or similarity in culture, economic, legal, political and trade policies, similarity of market infrastructures and the availability of lower production costs (Dunning, 1993) Finally, the internalization (I) advantages are concerned with the costs of choosing a hierarchical mode of operation over an external mode (Dunning, 1993, 1988) Internalization Advantages The internalization advantages are concerned with the costs of choosing a hierarchical mode of operation over an external mode. (Dunning, 1993, 1998) The internalizing of international operations comes at a cost. These costs must be compared with the costs of finding and maintaining an external relationship to perform the same functions in the international market. Willliamson (1981) refers to these costs must be included in consideration of entry-modes (Contractor, 1990; Hennart, 1989, Gatignon and Anderson, 1988) They unfortunately cannot be accurately calculated before the international operation has been established (Dunning, 1993) Because of this inability to calculate internalization advantage, we have excluded this factor from the present study Dunning (1993) has recently suggested that the motivation for foreign market expansion may influence the entry-mode selection process, despite perceptions of the OLI advantages. Motivations can include market-seeking, resource-seeking, technology-seeking, cost-reduction seeking, and client-following activities. Some preliminary evidence on the influence of motivational factors can be found in a few previous entry-mode studies (Kim and Hwang, 1992; Erramilli and Rao, 1990) Dunning’s motivations for engaging in FDI (Foreign Direct Investment) were not included in this study because, based on our understanding of the dynamics of the industry. For example, most US software firms appear to have the same motive for foreign entry, market-seeking. 74 Due to the US dominance in technology and resources, Resourceseeking and technology-seeking activities tended not to motivate foreign investment in the past However, technology seeking may begin to motivate foreign investment due to the continuation of the shift of the software industry to other countries, e.g. US software firm Symantec’s merger of Delrina of Canada, to inject Delrina’s technology into Symantec Due to the requirement of high skilled personnel (which is concentrated in the US) in the software industry, Cost reduction seeking motivation is of a minor concern. Client-seeking activities do not require in the software industry, as the software industry is highly mobile easily crossing national borders, and packaged software can be exported to the whole world quickly. US software firm expansion appears to be driven primarily by motivation of seeking new markets for existing products. In other words, according to this model, three conditions are indispensable for FDI: A firm must possess net ownership advantages over rival firms in the host country’s market, It must be more profitable for the firm to maintain these advantages internally, rather than to sell or lease them to foreign firms, The firm must believe that its advantages can be better exploited by using location-specific factors (such as labour and market) in the host countries than by simply exporting to foreign markets. It combines the aspects of each of the theories mentioned above. It provides a more comprehensive explanation of the nature and characteristics of FDI initiated by a MNC. The theories mentioned above are applied to a particular type of firm, that is, the multi-national companies, and provide a micro-economic analyses of the nature, causes and types of FDI and of the transnational business behaviour of the MNCs, while macroeconomic analyses are often being ignored. Therefore, the approaches mentioned above failed to explain international differences in FDI by MNCs from countries with different cultural backgrounds and macroeconomic structures. The theories, however, fails to provide a framework for analysis of the macroeconomic impact of FDI in the host country. 75 Kojima’s Macroeconomic Theory of FDI Characteristics: He has proposed a macroeconomic theory of FDI within the framework of relative factor endowments Two different types of FDI: Trade-oriented and anti-tradeoriented. Trade Oriented: FDI from a comparatively disadvanxtaged industry in the investing industry, it will harmoniously promote an upgrading of industrial structure on both sides and this will accelerate trade between the two countries. Comparative profitability in trade-oriented FDI conform to the direction of potential comparative costs and therefore complement each other. Example: Japan investments in developing countries in Asia Anti-trade oriented FDI: It can be evidenced those from the US The US investments abroad are concentrated in capita-intensive and high echnology industries in which it has comparative advantages They do not conform with the comparative profitability formula They work against the structure of comparative advantages, because these new industries Set-up foreign subsidiaries, Cutting off their own advantages, and Leading to trade-substitution effects Weakness: Although Kojima’s macroeconomic theory of FDI provides a basis for the analysis of the relationship between FDI and trade, his classification of two types of FDI makes his macroeconomic approach less valid for assessing the economic impact of FDI in an empirical sense. An investigation of the macroeconomic impacts of FDI shall be on how and on what extent FDI affects the conditions and determinants of economic growth and development. 76 Dunning (1988) argues, the scale of benefits of FDI depend on The type and nature of the investment, The economic conditions and characteristics of the host country, The macroeconomic and organizational strategies and policies pursued by host country governments. Economic Impact of FDI: Supply-side View FDI may affect the supply of productive resources including Financial Capital, Equipment and Machinery, Technology, Management Expertise, and Labour Training. It can influence the aggregate demand of the host country Both the classical and neoclassical economic theories explain economic growth and development in terms of: The stock of productive resources available for an economy, and The utilization of these resources. The productive resources include capital, labour, technology, management skills and natural resources. According to Ricardo’s classical theory of growth, an increase in capital and labour would result in growth of output. In the Harrod-Domar Model of growth, change in capital stock (investment) + incremental capital-output ratio (ICOR) determine the growth of national income. in investment in income (output); For a given amount of capital, income is determined by marginal capital productivity (the inverse of ICOR). In Solow’s neo-classical model, stock of capital and labour and the capital-labour ratio determines economic growth. 77 Capital increases faster than the increase in labour (termed capital deepening) the capital-labour ratio in a growth of labour productivity. Technology and exports shall also being included in economic growth models. The critical factors influencing economic growth are: Technological progress Capital deepening Export orientation Rational Management Development Strategies Many argued economic development is restrained by the shortage of Capital (both financial and physical) Technology Skilled labour Management Expertise Foreign Exchange The shortage of these production factors, cause the bottlenecks in economic development of developing countries. It is the key for these countries to achieve economic growth and modernization by removing such bottlenecks. FDI may positively affect the economic growth of developing countries through the following channels FDI may positively contribute to the capital formation of the host country, FDI, as a type of foreign capital inflow, represents an addition to the domestic savings of the host country, FDI may bring advanced equipment and machinery to the developing host country or finance the importation of capital goods that cannot be produced in the host country, thereby contributing to its capital formation 78 FDI improves infrastructure in the host country and creates good investment financed by domestic savings, leading to the promotion of domestically-financed investments In addition of foreign capital may also relieve pressure on the rate of interest charged in capital markets in the host country, and provide an incentive for domestic investment Weakness FDI may displace indigenous investment in the host country. If FDI is financed from the local financial market and results in a higher interest rate, it may crowd out domestic investment. The net impact of FDI on capital formation in the host country depends upon its effect on the domestically-financed investment. FDI may promote productivity of the domestic sector of the host country through technology transfer and the training of local labour, technicians and management personnel. The induction of technology progress, transfer and diffusion are the most important contributions of FDI to the economy of the host country. It is widely believed that the new forms of FDI, especially joint ventures, facilitate the transfer and diffusion of technology in the host country. Through the forward linkage effect, foreign-invested enterprises (FIEs) supply equipment, machinery and other intermediate products to domestic firms. The products made by FIEs may also substitute for imported products, helping the host country to alleviate reliance on imports reduce trade deficits. FIEs are seen to contribute to the host Government’s tax revenue. 79 However, the net contribution depends on whether the tax revenue paid by FIEs is larger than the expenditure by the host government for establishing and improving infrastructure for FDI. In this regard, transfer pricing manipulated by MNCs in order to avoid tax is an important factor affecting the host country’s tax revenue. Economic Impacts of FDI: Demand-Size View The economic growth in a country depends not only on its productive capacity, but also on the extent to which that production capacity is actually utilized, together with the strength of demand. An in any component of aggregate demand a of GDP and income level. FDI may contribute to the economic growth of the host country through positively affecting aggregate demand. Subsequent demand by foreign-invested enterprises for inputs of production is even more important after initial investment demand As the MNCs need to employ local labour and management personnel and pay them wages and salaries, this employment creation by FDI is important for many developing host countries where the rates of unemployment and underemployment are high. It provides not only income to employees and thus additional savings to the host country, but also helps improve labour productivity of traditional sectors (such as agriculture) by absorbing underemployed or surplus labour from these sectors. Another effect: Backward linkage effect. Through buying locally made materials and intermediate products, foreign-invested enterprises can create additional demand for products made by local firms. Initial FDI generated demand Multi-rounds of subsequent demand through industrial backward linkage effects Stimulation by domestic suppliers to produce more output Growth of the entire 80 economy encouraged by the increased aggregate demand initiated by FIE’s local purchases. FDI, especially export-oriented FDI, promotes the exports of the host country. Taking advantage of an abundant and cheap labour resource in the host country, together with their own marketing channels and expertise, foreign-invested enterprises are able to expand export of their products. The impacts of FDI on the demand and supply sides are amalgamated rather than separate. The impact of FDI on the host economy can be classified into macroeconomic and microeconomic impacts. Macroeconomic impacts refers the impact of FDI on the macroeconomic variables, such as: GDP growth, Total Fixed Investment Employment Exports and Imports Aggregate consumption Government expenditure Tax revenue Microeconomic impacts concerns with the impacts of FDI on the economic behaviour of individual units including firms and family, such as labour productivity and technical efficiency of a domestic firm. While some impacts of FDI can be quantitatively measured, others cannot be directly measured. Although the effects of FDI on GDP growth, capital formation, employment, exports and government tax revenue are measurable, whereas the following are difficult to quantify: Technology transfer and diffusion efficiency Environmental pollution 81 Access to foreign markets Demonstration effects Some economic variables are affected simultaneously by multiple factors, including political, cultural and economic firms, and it is difficult to separate one factor’s effect from that of others. Income distribution, industrial structure change, environmental pollution, and inter –regional economic disparity fall into the above group. With some impacts such as transfer pricing, it is difficult to acquire reliable and sufficient data although this issue is theoretically clear and quantitatively measureable. Major Concerns on FDI: National level: State sovereignty, political control and independency and cultural change/confrontation Macro-Economic level: o Economic Exploitation: resources and profit repatriation o Economic Security: Strategic sectors – resources, basic industries, agricultural, high value added financial & service, telecom & internet & IT o But, what is “strategic” is very debatable and is a changing concept Individual/Personal level: Income inequality, urban new poors, including middle class, caused by structural restructuring 82 References References Dunning, J.H., (1988) “The Eclectic Paradigm of International Production: A Restatement and Some Possible Extensions”, in Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 19:1, pp.1-31 Dunning, J.H., (1993) Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy, Addison-Wesley, New York Dunning, J.H., (1995) “Reappraising the Eclectic Paradigm, in an Age of Alliance Capitalism”, in Journal of International Business Studies, Vol.26:3, p.461-491 Dunning, J.H., (1998) “Location and the Multinational Enterprise: A Neglected Factor?”, in “Journal of International Business Studies”, Vol.29:1, pp. 45-66 Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development, (2000), “Recent Trends in Foreign Direct Investment”, in Financial Market Trend, No.76 Sun, H.S., (1998), Chapter 1, Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China 19791996, Ashgate, Aldershot 83 Lecture VI: FDI In China: Characteristics Total actual FDI inflow in China between 1979-1999 amounted to US$306 million. The amount is equivalent to 10% of direct investment worldwide 30% of the investment amount for all developing countries China is the largest recipient of FDI in the developing world China’s growth of FDI has been subject to considerable fluctuations at different times. Such fluctuations of FDI reflect adjustments in the Chinese government’s economic policies and resulting changes in the investment environment. In general, when China has evidenced a sound macroeconomic performance and economic liberalization is to the forefront, FDI tends to grow rapidly. On the contrary, poor economic performance (low growth and high inflation), has tended to dampen economic reform and halt the liberalization process foreign investment declines. The development of FDI in China has undergone three phases during the last 20 years, reflecting changes in economic conditions, investment environments and government policies. Phase One is from 1979-1985, Phase Two 1986-1999 and Phase 3 1990-1999 Phase 1 (1979-1985) The Chinese government promulgated the Joint Venture Law, it established the principles and procedures for foreign investment. Under this law, foreign investments are permitted and encouraged in selected fields. The Chinese government set up four Special Economic Zones (SEZs), where preferential economic policies were pursued to utilize foreign investment. As a result, foreign firms flocked to China to explore the new business opportunities. However, the regulatory environment is still quite restrictive, with restrictions on foreign equity share in joint venture (generally less than 50 percent), and industrial scope (FDI at that time, was not permitted in 84 Finance and banking Transportation Telecommunications & Post Retail Restrictions on FIEs’ access to the domestic markets as well as their use of local labor and land are imposed As a result, FDI in China grew sluggishly, especially during the first four days. In 1983, legal clarification of the status of the joint ventures through the Joint Venture Implementing Regulations. It also provided a great detail about China’s policy on Profit Repatriation Technology transfer Foreign Exchange In April 1984, the Chinese government announced that 14 coastal cities would open to foreign investment, expanding the open-door policy from SEZs to other coastal regions. The pledged value of FDI grew at 53 percent and 124 percent in 1984 and 1985 respectively, while the realized FDI grew at 98 percent and 32 percent respectively. Two features of the 1984-1985 boom: More hotel joint ventures were approved, “non-productive” (service) investment projects dominated FDI in China The size distribution of investment projects was highly skewed. At the one extreme, many joint ventures were of small capital size, especially those established by Hong Kong firms in service and manufacturing industries, with most of these being capitalized at less than one million dollars At the other extreme, some projects were large, with capital exceeding several million dollars. These larger projects were typically investments in hotels, oil exploration, automobile and machinery industries. A sharp decline in the growth rate of both pledged and realized FDI followed the 1984-1985 boom. (See chart on next page) The main reasons for this sharp fall is due to the high inflation and a growing trade deficit in China. This situation led the Chinese 85 government to severely curtail domestic spending of foreign exchange and to tighten approval of so called “non-productive” FDI projects. Many joint venture are exacerbated by: A limited domestic market access A low labor productivity Excessive government bureaucracy. 120000 100000 80000 60000 40000 20000 0 94 19 92 19 90 19 88 19 86 19 84 Pledeged FDI Realized FDI 19 19 82 Value Trend of FDI in China Year Growth Rate of FDI In China 400 Realized FDI Growth Pledged FDI Growth 200 100 0 -100 19 83 19 85 19 87 19 89 19 91 19 93 19 95 % 300 Year 86 Phase 2 (1986-1989) Response to the sharp fall: “Provision for the Encouragement of Foreign Investment” in October 1986. These provisions not only clarify the legal environment for FIEs, but also provided the solutions to some major problems like: Foreign exchange imbalance in FIEs was solved by establishing swap markets between enterprises. In addition, joint ventures were offered tax benefits and greater autonomy for their business management. Greater autonomy for their decision making at the local level occurred after 1986. Provinces and cities provided their own sets of investment incentives in addition to the incentives granted by the central government. These incentives included: Exemption of local tax Lower land use fees Lower charges for using public utilities. To promote foreign investment, almost all open coastal cities set up Economic and Trade Development Zones (ETDZs) designed for high technology industrial projects. In the ETDZs, extra tax breaks were offered, in addition to lower land-use fees and other incentives. Pledged FDI by 31% in 1987, and a further 43% in 1988 (see table above) Realised FDI by 24% in 1987 and 38% in 1988, (see table above) 85% of the FDI projects involved in the manufacturing industries in 1988, and many of these projects were aimed at China’s domestic market The economy got “overheated” in 1988, to reduce a twodigit inflation, the government introduced “austerity program” in late 1988. Such program made the FIEs geared towards then domestic market found it very difficult to sell their products due to the tightened local loans and the stagnant market demand. 87 The squeezed credit also limited the ability of prospective local partners in joint ventures to raise capital. Many joint ventures ran into financial and marketing difficulties. All these factors, plus the effects of the 1989 crackdown on the student and workers movement, have resulted the following: The number of joint ventures approved in 1989 decreased by 692 compared to 1988 The growth rate of the pledged FDI value also to 5.7% in 1989, while realized FDI only by 6.2% in 1989, and a even low figure of 2.8% in 1990. Phase III: 1990-Present In order to lure back FDI: Amendments to the Joint Ventures Law in April 1990. Particularly important was the elimination of the duration limit applied to some ventures, and granting of permission for foreigners to act as joint venture board chairmen. In April 1991, the Income Tax Law for Enterprises with Foreign Investment and Foreign Enterprises (the Unified Income Tax law) was passed. It standardized the income tax rates for different forms of FIEs, and eliminated the prior tax discrimination against the wholly foreign owned enterprises (WFOEs), which had previously been subject to unfavourable treatment. The improved investment environment and expansion of domestic credit facilitated the recovery and growth of foreign investment in China after 1990. Deng’s 1992 southern tour further opening the economy to foreign investment The policy of FDI became more favourable. The new policy permits foreign companies to invest in fields such as Retailing, Real Estate, Trading, Transport, Finance and Banking, 88 The establishment of stock-holding companies and secondary business to foreign affiliates are also permitted. In September 1992, the “socialist market economy” strategy is adopted, a legal framework to standardize market operations. Regulations covering Corporation Law, Bankruptcy Law, Individual Income Law, Stock Exchange Law Some other commercial regulations have been passed since 1993. Uniting the “two track” system of foreign exchange rates (officially regulated rates and market rates) Allowing the Chinese currency to be convertible for transactions in current account. Privatization of SOEs by selling their shares to the public, and lowering tariff for imports All the above are further liberalizing the Chinese economy and aiding the emergence of high economic growth and favourable business environment. As a result, foreign investment has boomed unprecedented. Since 1992, FDI inflow into China have accelerated to reach the peak level of USD 45.5 million in 1998. From 1994 to 1996, realized FDI increased by 14.6% on average per annum A Rise in the ratio of the realized value to the pledged FDI value: 1992 18.9% 1993 24.7% 1995 41.0% 1996 57.0% Average capital size of foreign investment projects: 1994 1.75 million dollars 1995 2.47 million dollars 1996 2.98 million dollars 89 Types of FDI in China Three major forms of FDI in China: Equity Joint Venture (EJV), Contractual Joint Venture (cooperative joint venture) (CJV), Wholly foreign-owned enterprises (WFOE) These three forms of FDI are referred to as “foreign-invested enterprises” (FEI) In addition, the joint exploration of oil or coal. Equity Joint Venture (EJV) EJV is the dominant form of foreign investment in China. Creation if limited liability companies with equity and management shared by foreign and Chinese sides according to their equity shares A foreigner’s capital contribution to a joint venture may be between 25% to 99% More rapid growth than CJV since 1986, as the open-door policy spread to other coastal areas From 1987-1996, pledged FDI in EJV grew by 36.9% per year on average, higher than that of CJV (26.5%) Since 1990, EJV outweighted CJV as the principal form of FDI Wholly Foreign Owned Enterprises (WFOE) Established by a company, using entirely on capital Assumes sole responsibility for its risks, gains and losses. It enjoys flexibility and autonomy Legal framework covering WFOEs Law on Enterprises Operated Exclusively with Foreign Capital (1986) and its Enforcement Regulations (1988). From the 1990s, FDI in WFOEs displayed a strong growth momentum. Pledged FDI in WFOEs increased by 56.7% per year on average from 1987 to 1996. Due to improvement in legal condition for WFOE and Taiwan’s investment surge 90 Since 1988, Taiwanese investment in the mainland has increased rapidly. As Taiwanese investment largely took the form of WFOEs, it contributed to the growth of WFOEs Contractual Joint Venture (CJV) An arrangement whereby the Chinese and foreign partners cooperate in joint projects and activities according to the terms and conditions stipulated in a venture agreement Those terms and conditions spell out the liabilities, rights and obligations of each partner Unlike EJV, a CJV is not a legally independent “entity” no need to form a separate “legal person” from the partner companies. Investing partners in a CJV do not assume the risk or share profits according to their respective capital contributions In the first stage of the open-door policy (1979-1985), CJV was the most important type of FDI, accounting for 55% of pledged FDI, But from the 1990s, its dominance has been overtaken by EJV. All forms of FIEs are subject to standardized tax rates and are eligible for a two-year tax holiday and a three-year tax reduction. Share of Different Forms of FDI Between 1979 and 1997 EJV WFOE CJV Number of Contracts 61.3% 24.7% 14.0% Contracted Amounts 46.0% 30.0% 23.2% Joint Exploration of Natural Resources Contains features of both the contractual joint venture and compensation trade The risk sharing and distribution of output according to agreed shares It enables China to access equipment and technical assistance from foreign companies in return for a portion of the resultant output. 91 Major Investors of China’s FDI Large number of countries have made direct investments in China High concentration of FDI among several large investors. These investors are in Hong Kong, Taiwan, United States, Japan, Singapore, Britain, South Korea, Germany, Canada, and Australia. Hong Kong has been the largest investor in China since 1979, and played a leading role in investment. Between 1983 and 1998,its accumulated FDI was US$140 billion, accounting for 52% of the total FDI in China. The figures for the other major players are as follows: Japan US Taiwan Singapore South Korea 22.3 billion 21.7 billion 21.0 billion 11.9 billion 7.4 billion 8.30% 8.09% 7.85% 4.42% 2.78% Although as a recent entrant of China’s FDI, Taiwan made huge contribution to China’s FDI development. Between 1983 and 1998, its accumulated FDI was US$21 billion, accounting for 7.9% of the total. Each of the major investors has distinct characteristics: Hong Kong ● Hong Kong investment was dominated by assembly and processing projects. 92 ● ● ● ● ● ● Small in capital size and concentrated in labor-intensive manufacturing sectors. During 1983-1991, average capital size of Hong Kong FDI projects was $1.12 million. As Hong Kong investments have partially shifted to some large infrastructure projects, its average capital size increased US$ 1.51 million in 1993 and US$ 1.91 million in 1994. Reasons for Hong Kong’s FDI into China: Structural transformation from labor-intensive industries to technologyintensive industries in Hong Kong , the increasing openness of China’s domestic market, and the geographic and cultural proximities to Hong Kong facilitate investment activities Shift of manufacturing in Hong Kong to southern China 36% of Hong Kong’s manufacturing industry had been moved across the border to the Pearl River Delta. Hong Kong Chamber of Commerce estimated that over 80 (85)% of Hong Kong labour-intensive manufacturing industry has been relocated to southern China by 1996 (2000). Taiwan ● ● ● Before 1987, Taiwanese investment in China was officially prohibited. The Chinese government’s promulgation of the Regulations of Encouragement of Investment by Compatriots from Taiwan in 1988 has accelerated such development. Three main characteristics of Taiwanese investment projects: 1. They are centered in labour-intensive export manufacturing industries such as, as the labor costs are only one-third of those in Taiwan ● Plastic and rubber products, ● Electronic and electrical appliances, ● Bicycles, ● Food processing and beverage, ● Footwear and toys, ● Textiles, ● Garments and small service industries 2. Due to geo-cultural proximity, Taiwan’s investment is largely located in Fujian province, 93 ● 3. Wholly-owned enterprise is the primary mode of Taiwan’s investment in China. The reasons for growth of Taiwanese investments, similar to that of Hong Kong, including: 1. The increase in labor costs and industrial transformation from labor-intensive to capital and technology-intensive production. This has forced Taiwanese and Hong Kong manufacturers to shift labor-intensive production to regions where labor costs are lower. 2. Geographical proximity and similarities in regional Chinese culture promote Hong Kong investment in Guangdong and Taiwanese investment in Fujian. South Korea ● ● ● ● An important investor in China since diplomatic relations between the two countries was officially normalized in 1991. South Korea surpassed Britain, Germany, Canada, Thailand and Australia and became the sixth largest investor in China. If the current trend continues, South Korea’s investment status will rise further in the future. The characteristics of South Korean investment appear similar to Hong Kong and Taiwan Southeast Asian Countries ● ● ● ● Investors from Southeast Asia are mainly overseas Chinese businessmen Ancestral ties and the lure of long-term profits are major forces driving them They are similar to Hong Kong and Taiwanese investments in terms of their small size of investment projects and preference for close cultural connections. Distinguish features: They are motivated not so much by China’s cheap labor cost and abundant land, but are more motivated by China’s expanding consumer demand Their investment flows mainly into China’s primary industries and infrastructure constructions 94 These businessmen tend to locate their projects in their ancestral towns and provinces, which are scattered widely in China, therefore they could advance into towns or provinces often ignored by other foreign investors Overseas Chinese are reputedly cash-rich and debt-free, and therefore able to commit to long-term investment, rather than seeking the quicker profits to be had from export processing US and other Western Countries They differed significantly from those of Hong Kong, Taiwan and Korea They invest largely in capital and technology intensive industries, and were generally of high technology content the average size of American and European investment projects are larger than those of Asian investments Most investment projects are aimed at the Chinese domestic market, as access to China’s huge consumer population is the principal motivation for many multinational corporations from the US and other industrialized countries Differs from Hong Kong and Taiwan investments, which are largely oriented to exports using cheap labour China’s economic reforms, trade liberalization and increasing openness of the domestic market to foreign investment are important reasons for US and European investments Rather than locating in the SEZs or other coastal areas, many American and European companies prefer to put their projects in major industrial and commercial centers such as Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjin, Guangzhou, Wuhan and Shenyang Between 1979-1989, only 47% of US EJV located in coastal areas, Hong Kong 67% The duration of US joint ventures is longer Average duration of US EJV is 15 years, 2 years longer than the average duration of all sampled EJVs. Japan Interested in Chinese domestic market, have placed less emphasis than US and European investors on manufacturing and more on property development 95 Their investment is diversifying into capital intensive industries such as electrical equipment, electronics, precision machinery and transportation equipment, the weight of labor-intensive and resource-based industries remains high. Japanese investment in the wholesaling, retailing and warehousing industries has increased remarkably, as the Chinese government has relaxed restrictions on the industrial scope of FDI In terms of regional distribution, Japanese investment has concentrated in northeastern China and east coast cities such as Dalian, Tianjin, Beijing, Qingdao and Shanghai As costs of labor and land have risen in these cities, Japanese investment has spread gradually to nearby areas Many Japanese investment projects have been of small or medium scale, which differs from US and European investments Regional Distribution of FDI Great disparity among regions From 1983-1998, FDI in the east region took up 87.8%, central 8.9%, west 3.3% Within the eastern region, the share of FDI are as follows, between 1989-1996: Guangdong 30.2% Jiangsu 11.3% Fujian 10.4% Shanghai 8.6% Shandong 6.7% Liaoning 4.4% Beijing 4.0% Tianjin 3.3% Two major reasons for the imbalance of the regional distribution of FDI in China. The bias of the open-door policy to the coastal region since 1979 The advantages of the coastal region over the inland regions in economic conditions and investment environment. 96 The bias of the open-door policy to the coastal region since 1979 The Chinese government initiated the open-door policy by establishing four SEZs where special policies favourable to foreign investors were implemented. In 1984, the government opened 14 coastal cities and granted them similar policies to the SEZs A significant shift of FDI from the SEZs to other open coastal areas In 1986, the Chinese government extended the “open region” to the “three deltas” including the Pearl River Delta, the Minnan Delta (the south of Fujian) and the Changjiang (Yangzi River) Delta. In 1988, Hainan Island became the fifth SEZ. In the early 1990s, Pudong New Area in Shanghai became a new focus of foreign investment, with support by government preferential policies. Local initiatives strengths the regional emphasis of the opening policy in the coastal areas The advantages of the coastal region over the inland regions According to Dunning (1977, 1981 and 1988), location-specific factors account for a particular pattern of locational distribution of foreign investment The limited extent of the spatial diffusion of foreign investment and that most of foreign investments are concentrated in major economic centers or more developed regions are common features in most developing countries, it is because economic and social infrastructures in major economic centers are more developed than other regions. According to the transaction cost theory (Williamson 1973, 1979 and 1981), the advanced facilities help the investors to reduce information and other relevant costs by improving the efficiency of production and marketing In the Chinese case, the coastal region and major economic centers such as Beijing, Shanghai, Guangzhou and Tianjin are more developed in heir industrial facilities education and communication systems than the inland regions. 97 The coastal region was more developed than the inland regions in economic structure, industrial infrastructure, public utilities and cultural facilities. In the past 18 years, the coastal-oriented opening policy and economic reforms have further improved the investment environment of the coastal region. Therefore, the gap between the coast and the inland in economic conditions and investment environment has widened. The concentration of FDI in the coastal region, especially major economic centers, can be attributed to the cost advantages associated with superior physical and social infrastructures and liberalized economic conditions. The major investing countries show different spatial patterns: Hong Kong 41.7% in Guangdong, 10.9% in Fujian, Taiwan 19.1% in Fujian, 18% in Jiangsu, 13.6% in Gunagdong, 8.2% in Shandong US Jiangsu 16%, Guangdong 13%, Shanghai 11.1%, Shandong 11.1%, Beijing 10%, Liaoning 6.2%, Tianjin 5.6% Japan Liaoning 17%, Jiangsu 13.8%, Shanghai 12%, Gunagdong 11.2%, Beijing 7% The spatial patterns of these countries’ investments can be explained by Variations in geo-cultural links, The technological nature of investment projects, Motivations for investment. Geographical and cultural proximity are the major reasons for Hong Kong investment in Guangdong, where the local people share the same language (Cantonese) and have close ethnic links with Chinese people in Hong Kong, Taiwan and Fujian province are geographically adjacent to each other and speaking the same dialect (Minnan language). Hong Kong, Taiwanese and Korean investors are taking advantage of the abundant supply of cheap labor in China to produce goods for export markets, which requires short distances from production sites to seaports for exports An additional important reason for Hong Kong, Taiwanese and 98 Korean investments’ concentration in Guangdong and Fujian provinces. Geographic proximity and historical reasons made Japanese investment went to Liaoning, Shandong and Shanghai American and other Western investors are not significantly affected by geo-cultural factors. They are affected primarily by industrial and technological factors and market orientation. American and European investments are largely in technologically advanced industries, using capital and technology intensive production methods Requires a developed industrial base and relevant linkage industries Large cities in China, especially those in the coastal region such as Beijing, Shanghai, Guangzhou, Tianjin and Nanjing, are relatively more advanced in industrial structure and technology, and therefore fit the requirements of American and European investment in technological conditions and industrial linkages As American investments target China’s domestic market, making investments in highly populated large cities is an easy way to access local consumers, and thus effectively facilitate investors; marketing strategies and promote their sales in the domestic market. FDI Dynamic Investment Paths in China: 1. Trade & Export-orientated FDI: Cultural link and geographical proximity Sea Port/Container Port OEM clusters Super Service Hub and Financial Centre This FDI mainly utilizes the country and locational specific advantages (cheap labour, land and natural resources) and engages in standardized manufacturing (low technology assembling) 2. Domestic Market-orientated FDI: Wealthy Region and Major cities and established industrial bases Industrial Clusters and Transportation node large population centre and mega cities This is technology and capital intensive FDI that can overcome the cost in large cities and require high skill labour and sophisticate infrastructure and supporting industries. 3. IT-orientated FDI: 99 Good Natural Environment and Cultural/historical cities IT clusters and enclaves This is intellectual/knowledge/brain intensive, not necessary capital intensive, FDI that will go with intelligent brains and innovation clusters, which are normally cultural and historical centres with good natural environment. 4. Grand convergence of the above 3 FDI: Diversified Clusters and Super Service Hub – Super/Mega Cities!!! Sectoral Composition of FDI ● By the end of 1998, Share of Number of Project Share of Contracted Value Manufacturing 73.01% 59.6% Real Estate 9.92% 24.6% Distribution Industry 6.23% 6.0% Construction 2.58% 3.1% Primary Sector 2.79% 1.8% ● Within the manufacturing industries, about half of the recorded FDI was directed to sectors characterized as labour intensive. Technology intensive (26.9%) and capital intensive sectors (22.7%) almost equally share the rest ● The figure for the manufacturing industry suggests a main motivation of foreign companies is to profit from China’s low unit labor costs. The technology intensity in FDI differs according to source countries, Emerging countries used to invest in labor-intensive production technologies and in the production of standard manufactured products, while mature economies are more prone to invest in high technology sectors and differentiated products. ● In the early stage of the open-door policy, FDI was concentrated in oil exploration, hotels, tourism, and assembling and processing. ● Since 1984, the government policy has changed, and FDI has diversified its sectoral composition. The industrial sector has become increasingly important as a recipient of FDI. ● Later on, FDI in real estate, tourism and the relevant service boomed. The primary focus of this sector was investment in real estate 100 ● ● (especially hotels), tourism, and associated services which the government hoped would earn foreign exchange After 1985, the government began to discourage investment in tourism and real estate in favour of high technology and export-oriented manufacturing investment by using different tax rates and approval control, and it loosened the restrictions on foreign investors’ access to the domestic market and on the requirement for foreign exchange balances in joint ventures, As a result, FDI in the industrial sector increased steadily During 1992-1993, due to the ‘real estate fever” resulted from the housing reform, FDI in real estate increased remarkably again. FDI in real estate continued to grow by 142.1% The share of FDI in real estate increased to 31.1% in 1992 and 39.3% in 1993 Industrial Composition of FDI by Country of Origin ● ● ● ● ● ● The industrial distribution of FDI vary by country of origin. According to Dunning’s eclectic theory (1977, 1981, 1988), industryspecific factors and especially firm-specific advantages in technology and production efficiency are the principal determinants of the industrial structure of investment abroad Capital and technology-intensive investment projects were less successful compared to labour-intensive and export-oriented investment projects. Market-oriented FIEs have difficulties unless they use locally made inputs. The main propositions of Dunning’s eclectic theory of international production, with location-specific, industry-specific, and firm-specific factors leading to advantages for certain types of firms in certain environments. Locational factors, especially regional economic and social environments and geographical distance, largely determine the locations of investment. References Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development (2000), Recent Trends and Main Characteristics of Foreign Direct Investment in China, in Financial Market Trend, No.77 Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development, (2000), “Recent Trends in Foreign Direct Investment”, in Financial Market Trend, No.76 101 Sun, H.S., (1998), Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China 1979-1996, Ashgate, Aldershot 102 Lecture VII: Entry Modes of Multinational Corporations into China ● ● ● ● ● ● Entry modes are defined as the forms of capital participation in international enterprises. They are modes in which MNCs enter the intended host country through investment In terms of property rights, entry mode is the ownership structure of a foreign subsidiary. There are two basic entry modes: wholly-owned subsidiary and joint venture Three kinds of joint venture sub-modes, based on the percentage ownership of equity: ● Majority JV, ● Balanced JV, and ● Minority JV The wholly-owned subsidiary and the Joint venture mode can be realized by MNCs through acquisition of an existing enterprise or setting up a new enterprise in the host country The transaction cost theory has been broadly employed to explain MNC’s international investment activities. They argue that transaction costs are major determinants of MNC’s entry modes. A MNC tends to choose an entry mode that minimizes transaction costs There are three primary factors affecting MNC’s entry: ● The sociocultural distance between MNC’s home countries and the host country ● Technological nature of investment projects, and ● The institutional and business environments and policies of the host country. Sociocultural Distance ● ● It refers to the difference in social culture between the home and host countries. Due to an unfamiliar cultural environment MNCs have little knowledge of the local market and business practice. Sociocultural distance creates enormous information needs, hence high information costs for intending MNCs. MNCs also would find it difficult to transfer home technologies and management techniques 103 ● ● ● ● ● This disadvantage may be avoided by forming joint ventures with local firms and turning management partially over to local partners. Secondly, operating in a foreign culture at a distance increases business uncertainty and unpredictability This raises MNCs’ propensity to form joint ventures with local firms. Bivens and Lovel (1966) disagrees with this proposition, they suggested that some firms react to sociocultural distance by demanding rather than avoiding ownership so they may impose their own operating methods. Such firms do not trust local management or local partners, and prefers to “do it their way”. Sociocultural links between China and other countries are highly related to geographical adjacency. Three groups based on geographical adjacency and sociocultural links. ● The investors from Hong Kong and Taiwan ● Investors from other East Asian countries ● Western investors Investors from Hong Kong and Taiwan ● ● ● ● ● Most of them are Chinese They share the same or very similar culture with people in the Mainland In contrast to true “foreigners”, these Chinese investors have advantages in language, cultural traits and ethnic links, and in access to Chinese society These advantages allow easy entry into Chinese domestic market with less reliance on local firms. Investors in this group are expected to be less dependent on local firms for local management and market information. In many cases, it is unnecessary for them to form joint ventures with local firms to reduce transaction cost associated with an unfamiliar operating environment Investors from other East Asian countries ● ● ● They include Japan, Singapore, Malaysia and South Korea These Asian neighbouring countries have close cultural ties to china due to geographic proximity and historical links In contrast to the Western investors, they have some advantages in sociocultural linkages. 104 Western Investors ● No sociocultural linkages Research and Development Intensity ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Proprietary knowledge is an important type of specialized asset. Research and development (R & D expenditure to total sales) is usually used to measure the intellectual proprietary content of a product or process Stopford & Wells (1972) and Coughlan & Flaherty (1983) find a negative correlation between R & D expenditure and the proportion of subsidiaries organized as joint ventures rather than wholly-owned affiliates. A higher degree of control is more often employed for technically unsophisticated products. This implies that firms tend to employ a completely-controlled entry vehicle in order to protect their interest in proprietary knowledge Anderson and Gatignon (1986), and Kim and Hwang (1992) argues that, entry modes offering higher degree of control are more efficient for highly proprietary or poorly-understood products and processes. Newer technology is likely to be handled by wholly-owned subsidiaries which offer high control Anderson and Gatignon (1986) argues that “the more mature the product class, the less control firms should demand of a foreign business entity”. Williamson (1979) points out, old technology is likely to be licensed or handled by a joint venture (lower control) In terms of bargaining power, foreign firms with proprietary products and high technology are in a favorable bargaining position with the host country. They may force the host government and partners to allow them to have more ownership. As the product matures, the advantage erodes, creating pressure to give up control. Therefore, a foreign investing firms if its technology is standardized The Host Country’s Conditions, Risks and Policies ● “Country risk” = The volatility (unpredictability) of the firm’s environment. 105 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Various forms, e.g. political instability, the lack of a well-defined legal systems, economic fluctuations, price and foreign exchange controls and nationalization threat. In a highly unpredictable environment, MNCs tend to limit their equity involvement by avoiding full ownership in order to diversify the business risks. At the same time, they may want to get greater control to compensate for high risks. As Anderson & Gatignon (1986) maintain, the greater the combination of country risks, the higher the appropriate degrees of control over the subsidiaries, and the lower the MNCs inclination to establish wholly-owned subsidiaries In terms of the transaction cost theory, country risk and the uncertainty of business environment may increase the information need and management cost for MNCs to operate fully-owned subsidiaries in the host country. For investments oriented to the host country, domestic market and investments based on the host country’s resources, local partners are essential for foreign entrants since they have expertise in exploring domestic markets, managing local labor and organizing local suppliers of raw materials and intermediate products. Apart from country risk and business uncertainty, the host country’s economic conditions and policies may considerably affect MNC’s capital involvement. The economic growth trend and domestic market size of the host country would strengthen its attraction for foreign investment. Empirical Investigation of MNC’s Entry Modes ● ● Wholly foreign owned enterprises is becoming more important as an entry mode of MNCs into Chinese market For instance, during the period from 1987 to 1992, the proportion of FDI in EJVs to the total FDI by Hong Kong is 47% on average, compared to 84% for Western Europe. This indicates that the larger the sociocultural distance with the host country (China), the higher the propensity for investors to use EJV as the main entry mode→ Sociocultural difference positively correlates to the frequency of equity joint venture 106 ● ● From 1987 to 1992, 42% of Taiwan’s investment and 39% of Japanese investment were in WFOEs, much higher than the Western European (10%), and US (24%) investments. This is due to the cultural similarity allows Asian investors to have an adequate knowledge of Chinese market and business practice, which facilitate their investment activities with less need for local partner There is a positive relation exists between the cultural proximity, capital involvement and the use of WFOE as MNC’s entry mode. Entry Mode by Industry ● ● ● ● The technological nature and content of a product or process are highly correlated with the ownership structure of foreign subsidiaries The higher the technological content, the higher the equity share of a MNC requires in its foreign affiliates, and also the higher a MNC’s propensity to set up wholly-owned subsidiaries. For technologically sophisticated products or services, MNCs prefer full ownership or majority ownership in order to control their subsidiaries efficiently and to protect their proprietary rights. As technology matures and standardizes, less control and protection is needed. Therefore, a joint venture become the favoured vehicle by which MNCs enters the host country market. Entry Mode by Region ● The table below shown a liberalized economic environment and lower business uncertainly and less risks in the Southeast coastal region tend to encourage foreign investors to form wholly-owned enterprises Regions % the FDI in the Regions as EJV % of FDI in the Regions as CJV % of FDI in the Regions as WFOE Southeast Coast Other Coast Inland Region National Total 39.4% 74.3% 69.7% 57.5% 30.5% 11.0% 13.5% 20.4% 30.0% 14.6% 16.0% 22.0% 107 Findings of FDI in China ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● The cultural links between investing countries (or regions) and the host country (China) positively affect the foreign equity share in FIEs This further confirms the hypothesis that cultural proximity is positively correlated with the wholly-owned foreign enterprises and the foreign equity share in FIEs The larger the cultural distance between investors and China, the lower the foreign equity involvement in FIEs Secondly, high technology positively related to the foreign equity share in FIEs Thirdly, economic environment and government policy is the most important determinant for the entry mode (i.e. the ownership of FIEs) of MNCs In the Southeast coastal region, foreign investors prefer majority joint ventures or wholly-owned subsidiaries rather than minority joint ventures. The closer the cultural backgrounds of investors in FIEs. The sociocultural distance between the home countries and the host country discourages MNCs to invest in wholly-owned subsidiaries. Therefore, joint venture is the suitable entry modes for MNCs from a country at cultural distance from the host country The technology intensity of investment projects and liberalized economic environment positively affect the foreign equity share in FIEs and MNCs capital involvement, These findings are consistent with the major theories of multinational corporations, especially the eclectic theory (Dunning 1977 and 1981). The investment behaviour and entry mode of MNCs are primarily determined by firm-specific advantages especially proprietary technologies and also location-specific factors. For foreign firms whose technology is standardized, equity joint venture is the most suitable mode to invest in China This is particularly true for those investments oriented to Chinese domestic market or natural resource-based investment projects. Joint venture mechanism will help to minimize the external business uncertainty associated with the cultural distance and the lack of knowledge of local market, and therefore facilitate foreign firms’ access to local markets. 108 ● ● ● A joint venture may diversify business risks and produces net benefits from economies of scale. A WFOE is a favoured investment vehicle by MNCs investing in high technology industries Finally, a pre-condition for running a WFOE successfully is that investors (or their managers) have a sound knowledge of the legal system, market structure, business practice and economic and policy conditions of the host country. References Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development (2000), Recent Trends and Main Characteristics of Foreign Direct Investment in China, in Financial Market Trend, No.77 Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development, (2000), “Recent Trends in Foreign Direct Investment”, in Financial Market Trend, No.76 Sun, H.S., (1998), Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China 1979-1996, Ashgate, Aldershot 109 Lecture VIII: Impacts of FDI on Capital Formation, Economic Growth and Employment ● FDI can affect the total capital formation of the host country in various ways: ● As a source of foreign capital inflow, FDI can augment total financial resources available for investment, thereby promoting capital formation in the host country. ● In addition, FDI can dynamically influence domestic investment by creating new investment opportunities for local firms in leading industries or by easing economic growth bottlenecks such as shortages of infrastructure, investment capital and foreign exchange. ● FDI may take a physical form such as equipment, machinery, instruments and technology, which cannot be made locallyessential for domestic capital formation in a developing country. ● FDI can also stimulate domestic investment through industrial linkage effects By buying locally made inputs from, and providing intermediate inputs to, local firms. ● FDI may increase the host country’s exports, which would have a positive effect on domestic savings and investment. ● FDI may have “crowd out” effects on domestic investment if foreign firms compete with local firms both for the use of scarce physical and financial resources and also for product markets. ● These factors may affect one another, with the net effect depending on their relative strengths. Several studies on the effect of FDI on domestic investment: ● ● In Canada, Lubits (1971) and Noorzoy (1979) found that FDI had a complementary effect on the domestic investment Areskoug (1976) concluded that FDI’s effect on domestic investment in most developing countries was partially substituting, 110 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Lee, Rena and Iwasaki (1986) found out that FDI had a significant positive effect on gross domestic product (GDP) growth and a positive, but not significant effect on domestic savings. Ruffin (1993) confirms that foreign investment played a positive role in the economic growth of Asian and Pacific region. In Taiwan, Tu (1990) and Schive (1990) examines the effects of FDI on macroeconomic variables such as GDP, private fixed investment, private consumption, total exports and imports, and found that FDI stimulated private fixed investment and increased exports without significantly affecting private consumption and imports. As all the above mentioned studies investigated the impact of FDI in market economies. By comparison, China has some unique characteristics, which make an investigation of the impact of FDI more complex and difficult. The reasons are as follows ● Previous studies of this issue in the context of market economies provide limited information for a study of the Chinese economy which is characterized by ● A large population, ● Unbalanced regional development, ● A long history of self-sufficiency ● Isolation from the outside world Conclusions and implications drawn from studies of small open economies have less relevance to China, which has experienced a relatively short period of opening up of FDI since 1979. The studies of the role of FDI in China are as follows: ● Kueh (1992) pioneered the study by using the rising share of FDI in the total fixed capital investment, he confirmed that the contribution of FDI to the total capital formation in the open coastal region of China was increasingly important. ● Kueh also found that foreign invested enterprises have become important players in the industrial development and export expansion of China’s coastal region. ● However, his study lack macroeconomic variables ● Chen, Chang and Zhang (1995) assessed the role of FDI in China’s post-1978 economic development. ● They discussed the effects of FDI on the growth of GDP, domestic savings, fixed capital investment and exports of China. 111 ● ● They also briefly assessed the influence of FDI on China’s transition to a market economy. They concluded that FDI has contributed to China’s post1978 economic growth by augmenting resources available for capital formation and promoting exports. A Systematic Analysis of Macroeconomic Model in the Contribution of FDI ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● A more systematic analytical model by Sun (1998), implementing the hypothesis that FDI positively influenced GDP growth and domestically-financed investment in China. The results from the analytical model indicate that Domestic savings is the main determinant of economic growth. A 1 percent increase in domestic savings would give rise to a 0.5% increase in GDP. Foreign capital plays an important role in Chinese economic growth. A 1 percent increase in FDI would lead to a 0.047% increase in GDP. Labor force also shows a positive and statistically significant impact on economic growth. A 1 % increase in the labor force tends to give rise to a 0.31% increase in GDP. With regard to domestic capital formation, a 1% increase in income per capita would result in a 0.351% increase in the domestic capital formation. FDI positively contributes to domestic investment. A 1 % increase in FDI would lead to a 0.137% increase in domestic investment. As FDI grew at 41.65% on the annual average for the period 1983-1995, it would induce a 5.71% (=0.137x 41.65) increase in domestic investment The result also indicates a complementary relationship between FDI and the domestically financed investment, which is also observed in some studies of other Asian countries. In the case of China, FDI can complement and stimulate domesticallyfinanced investment in various ways. The formation of Sino-foreign joint ventures enables domestic investors to gain financial and physical resources for investment in new projects. Without foreign capital participation, many investment projects, particularly those requiring a large capital outlays and advanced technology, would be impossible to carry out. 112 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● The joint venture mechanism offers an important channel to transfer foreign technology, management and marketing skills to local partners, with positive impacts on investment opportunities in new products FDI, especially in infrastructure projects such as airports, seaports, power stations, highways, and other transportation and telecommunication facilities, improves the investment environment, thereby enhancing the domestic investment. Recently, the proportion of FDI in these infrastructure projects has increased steadily. The bottlenecks for economic growth have been eased, and domestically-financed investment has been encouraged. FDI not only adds financial resources to the host country, but also exerts a dynamic and positive effect on domestically-financed investment. The effect of other foreign capital inflows (mainly foreign loans) on domestically financed investment is positive but statistically less significant. This can be accounted for by the fact that some foreign official loans are matched to domestic capital while some foreign private loans may replace domestically financed investment. This results in an insignificant influence of foreign loans on domestically financed investment. The share of foreign investment in the total fixed capital investment of China increased from 3.8% in 1981 to 11.5 % in 1995. In the coastal provinces the contribution of foreign investment to total capital formation is more important Foreign investment constituted 16.2% of Guangdong’s total fixed capital investment for the period from 1986 to 1992 Its share in the provincial total fixed capital investment further increased to 22.4% in 1994 In Hainan Province, foreign investment accounted for 11.9% of total fixed capital investment in 1990 and reached 13.3% in 1992. Since capital formation is the most important determinant of economic growth, as argued by development economists, FDI has promoted the economic growth of China through its contribution to domestic capital formation. FDI and Industrial Production 113 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● In terms of growth rates, FIE’s achievement is even more impressive. During1988-1995, the GOVI produced by FIEs grew at 65.8% per annum (calculated at 1988 constant prices), which is five times higher than the average growth rate of national GOVI (13.8%). Over the same period, the GOVI produced by state-owned enterprises grew only by 5.7% per annum, which is less than half of the national average growth rate. As a result, the share of stateowned enterprises in the national GOVI declined remarkably from 56.8% in 1988 to 34.0% in 1995. It clearly indicates that FIEs have become a dynamic leading force in the industry sector and play an important role in accelerating the industrial growth of China. As for the regional distribution, the industrial activities of FIEs are largely concentrated in the coastal region where they contribute markedly to the regional industrial to the regional industrial growth. FIEs in the coastal region produced 820.7 billion yuan of goods and services, contributing 25.5% in value of the total industrial output. In Guangdong and Fujian provinces, FIEs produced 50.3% and 53.7% respectively of the total industrial output in 1995. The share of SOEs in the total industrial output declined to 19.2% in Guangdong and 23.7% in Fujian In Tianjin, FIEs produced 40.4% of the total industrial output in 1995, and it has overtaken SOEs as the most important player in the industry sector Without FIE’s dynamic participation, it would be impossible for China to achieve the exceptional industrial growth of 14.9% per annum over the past 17 years The role of FDI in Chinese industrial development can also be examined by investigating the share of FIEs in the total value of output of various manufacturing industries In 1995, 21.2% of the total value of output of the manufacturing sector was produced by FIEs. In the electronic industry and the industry group of clothing, footwear and other fabric products, FIEs have become the dominant producers, producing60% and 51.5% respectively of the total output Similar figures in the precision instruments and office equipment industry (40 percent), plastic and rubber products (30.1%), transportation vehicles (24.6%) and the electrical products (24.3%) 114 ● ● ● ● ● ● Similarly, FIE’s industrial linkages especially backward linkages with local Chinese enterprises are an important element of FDI. By buying locally made intermediate inputs. FIEs provide a strong growth stimulus to Chinese domestic sectors. FDI has been concentrated in the industries with high backward linkage indices, such as electronics and electrical products, textiles, clothing, footwear, machinery and transformation vehicles. The potential linkage effects on FIEs on the domestic sectors are significant. FIEs increasingly use locally made parts and materials in their production, the potential backward linkage effects are being realized. In this process, the campaign for localization of intermediate inputs used in FIEs which is supported by the Chinese government, should further promote the potential backward linkage effects of FDI on the domestic sectors to realize. FDI and Employment Creation ● 1.35 million people were employed by FIEs in this industry, accounting for 21% of all employees in the industry. ● Total employment from sectors by FIEs: Electronics 27.5% Clothing, footwear 20.6% Plastic Products 14.9% Furniture 12.2% Office Machine 11.9% Electrical Product 11.3% ● Total employment from provinces by FIEs: Guangdong 23.8% Fujian 19.6% Shanghai 13.9% Tianjin 10.7% Beijing 10.4% Conclusion ● FDI promoted the domestically-financed investment and economic growth of China by contributing financial and physical capital and 115 ● ● ● ● ● encouraging local investment, FDI positively contributed to the capital formation in China In addition, FDI has advanced industrial production and has been an important catalyst driving Chinese industrial development FDI has also played an important role in creating new employment in China especially in the coastal region and in labour-intensive manufacturing industries The Chinese experience with the use of FDI in economic development has valuable policy implications for other developing countries. First, FDI can effectively influence the major determinants of economic development, such as domestic savings and capital formation, technology and productivity, employment FDI can significantly affect the economic growth and development of a developing country→ An indispensable factor towards its development References Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development (2000), Recent Trends and Main Characteristics of Foreign Direct Investment in China, in Financial Market Trend, No.77 Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development, (2000), “Recent Trends in Foreign Direct Investment”, in Financial Market Trend, No.76 Sun, H.S., (1998), Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China 1979-1996, Ashgate, Aldershot 116 Lecture IX: Foreign Investment and Regional Economic Growth Introduction China’s economic growth has been regionally uneven and characterized by increased inter-regional economic disparity and income inequality between the Eastern (coastal) and Western (far inland) regions The imbalance in economic growth between the two regions has been exacerbated since China further opened the coastal regions in 1984 The economic growth rate of the Eastern region was 12.1 % on average from 1984 to 1995, compared with a 9.1% for the Western region. In 1995, the GDP per capita of the Eastern region was 2.4 times that of the Western region The inter-regional economic gap has widened due to economic reforms and open-door policy in favour of the Eastern region, different economic structure and resource conditions, coast-oriented regional policy, and the differential impact of foreign trade and foreign investment Economic Dualism Economic dualism is a typical structural feature of developing countries especially for those countries at a lower level of development It refers to the coexistence of two disparate structural segments within the geographical territory of a country (Dutta, 1991) Forms of dualism include regional dualism, urban and rural dualism and industrial dualism At a less-developed stage especially during the period of transition from non-market to a market economy, a certain degree of dualism may be inevitable for many countries. As the economy passes a certain stage of development, the degree of dualism may eventually diminish, resulting in the convergence of development between regions or sectors. China’s economic development has been historically marked by regional dualism, i.e., the existence of the relatively developed Eastern (coastal) region and the less-developed Western (far inland) region. During the Maoist period (1949-1976), the inter-regional disparity transfers from the Eastern region to the Western region. It is the result of the government strategies of the Chinese government for economic development and national security. In the reform or post-Maoist period, inter-regional economic disparity and income inequality have been enlarged. Therefore, regional dualism has become a basic feature of the contemporary Chinese economy. 117 The increase in income gap demonstrates inter-regional economic disparity. During the 1978-1995 period, GDP per capita in the Eastern region grew at 9.6% per year on average (at 1978 constant prices), compared to 7.8% for the Western region, As a result, the inter-regional gap of income per capita has been further widened. The trend of income inequality between the two regions has become more evident since China further opened its eastern (coastal) region to foreign investment in 1984. As shown in the table above, GDP per capita at 1978 constant prices ↑ from 784 yuan in 1984 to 2315 yuan in 1995 in the Eastern region, with an annual growth rate of 10.9% being reached. In comparison, the GDP per capita in the Western region during the same period increased from 432 yuan to 942 yuan, growing at 7.9% per year. The remarkably differential growth rates of GDP and GDP per capita resulted in a larger income gap between the two regions. 118 In 1984, the GDP per capita ratio between the Eastern and Western region was 1.853. By 1995, this ratio increased to 2.458, indicating that the income inequality aggravated between the Eastern and Western regions. Population growth is another direct factor influencing income per capita in each region The annual average growth rates of the population---Eastern 1.54%, Western 1.46% during 1984-1995. Since the population grew slightly faster in the Eastern region that in the Western region, it did not contribute to the widening income per capita gap between the two regions. As a result, it is the regional divergence in economic growth rates that can be identified as the principal cause for the inter-regional income disparity. In fact, many factors contributed to the differential growth rates of the economy in the two regions. Apart from the government regional development strategy and policies that were favorable to the Eastern region, structural factors and differential economic openness, especially the coastal-oriented distribution of direct foreign investment has played a crucial role in the rise of the dualistic growth pattern of the Chinese economy. Structural Characteristics Various structural characteristics are connected to the dualistic growth pattern of the Eastern and Western regions Three such characteristics are industrial structure, openness of the economy, and investment structure. The different structural characteristics in the two regions shape the growth conditions and disparate growth pattern, resulting in income inequality between the two regions. The income gap in turn further reinforces the disparity of capital formation and regional dualistic growth pattern. Industrial Structure Three sectors—primary, secondary and tertiary (service) industries, Primary industry constitutes a large share of GDP and total employment when the economy is at a lower stage of development. As economic development in a country or region reaches a higher level, the secondary and tertiary industries tend to become more important an account for large shares in GDP and total employment. In the case of China, the industrial structure has experienced remarkable changes since the later 1970s. The share of primary industry in GDP declined from 28.4% in 1978 to 20.9% in 1995, while the share of secondary industry rose from 48.6% to 49.2% during the same period. 119 The tertiary industry’s share of GDO increased from 23% to 31.6%. Although structural change occurred in all regions, the pace and extent to which the economic structure changed are significantly different between the Eastern and Western regions. As shown in the table, the share of the primary industry in the GDP of the Eastern region ↓ from 27.2% in 1984 to 16% in 1995, the Western region ↓ from 37.3% to 26.8% in the Western region. Although the secondary and tertiary industries increased their importance in the Western region, their share in GDP are still lower than that of the Eastern region, By 1995, the secondary industry produced 41.5% of GDP in the Western region, compared to 49.8% in the Eastern region. Similarly, the tertiary industry contributed 31.7% of GDP in the Western region compared to 34.2% in the Eastern region. The industrial structure tends to significantly affecting the overall economic growth rate of each region reflecting the different industrial makeup. During 1984-1995, the GDP produced by the tertiary industry grew at 16.6% annually in the Eastern region, compared to 12.1% in the Western region. The GDP produced by the secondary industry grew at 11.8% in the Eastern region, compared to 9.7% in the Western region. 120 The growth rates of the primary industry were similar in the two regions (6.0% and 5.7% in the Eastern and Western regions respectively). As the secondary and tertiary industries produced over 84% of GDP in the Eastern region, their relatively higher growth rates contributed to a higher rate of GDP growth. The secondary and tertiary industries only contribute 73% of the GDP in the Western region. The Openness of the Economy The openness of the economy can be measured by the sum of exports and imports as a % of GDP in an economy. Openness increasingly being viewed as an important attribute to ensure steady economic growth in less developed countries, especially following the successful experiences of East and Southeast Asian regions. In the case of China, the openness of the economy has ↑ sharply since the ‘opening up’ and economic reform process. The sum of exports and imports as a % of GDP has risen from 10.3% in 1979 to 22% in 1996 (calculated at 1984 constant prices and the 1984 constant exchange rate). However, the government’s ‘open’ policy has been heavily biased in the Eastern region. Consequently, the openness of the Chinese economy is subject to a remarkably regional disparity. This is reflected in the table below. During 1984-1996, both the Eastern and Western regions made a considerable progress in opening their economies. However, there is still considerable disparity in the economic openness between the two regions. (e.g., 17% of the total output of the Eastern region was sold in the overseas markets in 1995, while only 3.1% of output did so in the Western region. Greater openness especially in the expansion of exports can be expected to promote economic growth in various ways. 121 Exports guide countries (or regions) to produce in which they have comparative advantage through the specialization in such industries or products, a country or region can achieve higher productivity and a lower real cost of production. Trade can also induce economic resources to flow from less productive sectors with comparative advantage, thus increasing the overall allocative efficiency of resources. In addition, trade facilitates a country or region to access new technology and overseas markets, which in turn can be expected to have positive effects on productive and management efficiencies. A greater openness and interregional into the world economy is one of the principal factors explaining the economic growth of the Eastern region in the past 20 years. 122 The impact of exports on economic growth in the Western region is less significant than in the Eastern region, due to the much smaller share of foreign trade making up its GDP. Although exports grew slightly faster in the Western region is less significantly than in the Eastern region, the exports per capita in the Eastern region were far larger. The figure was US$44.8 in the Eastern region in 1980, compared to US$1.2 in the Western region, In 1995, it reached US$284.3 in the Eastern region compared to only US$21.1 in the Western region. The different degrees of openness of the economy in the two regions are an important contributing factor in the differential economic growth rates, and thereby the resulting income gap between the regions. Foreign Investment and Capital Formation Since the early 1980s, FDI has played increasingly important role in China’s capital formation and economic growth. The arrived FDI in China grew at an annual average 33.9% between 1984-1996, with the accumulative total value increasing from US1,258 million to US$41,726 million. In 1995m FDI accounted for 11.5% of the total fixed capital investment of China FDI has thus become a dynamic part of domestic capital formation, promoting Chinese economic growth. However, the regional distribution of foreign investment is highly uneven. During the period of 1979-1995, over 90% of FDI was in the Eastern (coastal) region, with only 6% in the Central region and 4% in the Western region. The regional distribution of FDI is primarily determined by the investment environment and return on capital in different regions, The investment environment in a region is affected by a number of social and economic factors, which in terms of the theory of international investment are termed location-specific factors. The factors include infrastructure, transportation, economic structure and the development level, economic policy, legal system and resources endowment. In the case of China, location-specific factors differ considerably between the Eastern and Western regions. In general, the Eastern region is more economically developed, with considerably superior infrastructure, especially in its transportation and communication systems. China’s major economic centers including major seaports and airports have been concentrated in the eastern coastal region. 123 Better service facilities and human resources make the investment environment in the Eastern region superior than that of the Western region. In terms of economic structure, the Eastern region is also more developed than the Western region, with the manufacturing and tertiary industries having led the economic growth in this region. The existing advantages of the Eastern region over the Western region have been reinforced by coast-oriented economic reforms and open door policy since the early 1980s. The Chinese government committed a large amount of capital to the Eastern region to improve infrastructure, such as transportation, communications, public utilities and service facilities. Furthermore, the government granted a package of perferntial policies to the Eastern region, including favourable policies on taxation, foreign trade and investment, and more autonomy in economic decision making, all of which resulted in a favourable investment environment. In particular, the open-door policy has been pursued with a remarkable spatial dimension. In 1979, the Chinese government initated the open-door policy by establishing four SEZs in the southeast coastal region. These SEZs were initially designed as laboratories for the use of foreign investment, where SEZs policies were adopted, The spatial proximity to Hong Kong, the source of about 80% of the total FDI In China In the initial stage, FDI was highly concentrated in the four SEZs (Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Shantou and Xiamen) and during the period 19791983, 80% of total FDI projects was located in the four SEZs. As the government used administrative regulations to isolate the SEZs economically from the rest of the country, the SEZs in essence became foreign enclaves with few economic linkages with other regions. In 1984, 14 coastal cities were opened to foreign investment. A series of special economic policies were introduced in these open coastal cities (OCCs). This helped FDI to diffuse spatially from the SEZs to the fourteen OCCs across ten coastal provinces.→ The contracted FDI in the fourteen OCCs exceeded that in the SEZs. Since 1986 FDI has gradually spread to the other regions, including the other coastal areas and the vast inland regions. In 1990, the new emphasis of open policy shifted to the Shanghai Pudong New Area, Changjiang (Yangtse River) Delta and Minnan Delta. A rapid expansion of FDI to the inland regions after Deng Xiaoping’s ‘southern tour’ in early 1992. As a result, FDI diffused quickly to the inland regions and spread widely across the country. 124 Due to the favourable investment environment in the Eastern region, FDI has been concentrated in this region since the beginning of open-door policy. During the period of 1983-1996, 87.9% of the arrived FDI in China was located in the Eastern region, with 8.8% and 3.4 % in the Central inland and the Western inland regions respectively. Although FDI has gradually spread to the inland regions since the mid1980s, the Eastern region is still the primary location of foreign investment. E.g. the Guangdong province is the single largest recipient of FDI in 1983-1996. FDI in this province amounted to US$50.9 billion, which accounted for 30.6% of the national total. In the initial stage (1983-1985), 61% of total FDI flowed into Guangdong. The province has remained the most important location for FDI although its share in the national total has declined since the mid-1980s. Jiangsu Province is second only to Guangdong, with FDI amounting to US$19.1 billion during the 1983-1996 period and accounting for 11.5% of total FDI. This is followed by Fujian Province, whose FDI amount accounted for 10.6% of the national total. In contrast, both the Central and western regions receiv4ed a very small share of FDI. 125 These two inland regions (including 19 provinces) received less than 40% of the FDI which had flowed into Guangdong, the single province, during the 1983-1996 FDI which flowed into the Western region (9 provinces) was amounted to only 11% of FDI in Guangdong Province over the same period. The table above indicates the differing contribution of FDI to total capital formation in the two regions. In some eastern provinces, especially those in the Southeast region, by 1995 FDI had overtaken the government investment budget and become the largest capital source of total fixed capital investment. FDI, as a share of the total fixed capital investment in Fujian and Guangdong was 51% and 38.2% respectively in 1995. In other coastal provinces, the contribution of FDI to total capital formation has also been important. In Tianjin and Jiangsu, FDI as a share of total fixed capital investment was 33.1% and 25.4% respectively. As a result of the large foreign capital inflows, the investment rate (total fixed capital investment as a share of GDP) in the Eastern region has been constantly higher than in the Western region. The table below illustrate 126 this. As a result of its uneven regional distribution, the contribution of FDI to total capital formation is significantly different between the Eastern and Western regions, Foreign capital as a share of the total capital reached 22.3% in the Eastern region in 1995, which is much higher than the correspondent % in the Western region (3.9%). During 1984-1995, fixed capital investment as a share of GDP was 34.6% on average in the Eastern region, while the investment rate in the Western region was just 29.1% on average. There is no single year over this period in which the investment rate of the Western region was higher than that of the Eastern region. The Eastern region has continually headed the Western region in capital formation and this has been the most important determinant of the differential rates of economic growth in the two regions. Domestic capital flows from the Western region to the Eastern region is also a factor influencing regional capital formation. Due to preferential economic policies pursued by the Chinese government and the favourable investment environment in the Eastern region, companies and government agencies in the Western region tend to make investment in eastern provinces, especially open coastal cities or 127 provinces such as the five Special Economic Zones (Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Xiamen, Shantou and Hainan), Guangdong, Fujian and Shanghai. This results in domestic capital flows from the Western region to the Eastern region. For example, Shaanxi Province invested over 270 million yuan in eastern provinces in 1992, resulting in a net capital outflow of 225 million yuan. In the past few years, some other Western provinces have also experienced net capital outflows. Such inter-regional flows of domestic capital have a differential impact on capital formation in the two regions. They increase capital supply and stimulate capital formation in the Western region. This contributes to different investment rates in the two regions. To conclude, foreign investment, through its contribution to domestic capital investment and its positive effects on technology transfer and export growth, has accelerated the economic growth of the Eastern region. By contrast, the contribution of foreign investment to capital formation in the Western region has been slight, and hence its impact on the economic growth of the region is less significant. Rural Industry Development and Inter-Regional Economic Disparity Rural industry growth has been an important factor promoting the economic development of China in the past two decades. It has become the most dynamic part of the Chinese economy and plays an increasing role in economic growth, especially in rural development. As a principal indicator of rural industry, industrial enterprises run by townships and villages developed dramatically in the past 17 years. During the period 1978 to 1995, the total output value of township and village enterprises (TVEs) grew at annual average 24.8% (at 1978 constant prices). This growth rate is almost 10% higher than the growth rate of the gross output value of China’s industry. The development of rural industry is also subject to regional imbalance. The total output value of TVEs in the Eastern region increased from 120.4 billion yuan in 1985 to 1221.3 billion yuan (at 1984 constant prices) in 1995, with an annual growth of 23.5%. In terms of labour productivity, the value added produced by each worker in industrial TVEs was 16,046 yuan in the Eastern region, some 60.5% higher than that of the Western region (9,997 yuan). The differential growth of rural industry aggravates inter-regional economic disparity, especially the income per capita gap. This is because rural industry provides the primary source of income for the rural population, which makeup 80% of the total population of China. The table below shown the difference in the growth of rural industry 128 Due to the different growth of rural industry, the inter-regional gap of TVEs’ output value per capita in 1995 has been further widened from 250.7 yuan in 1985 to 2263.6 yuan (at 1984 constant price). In terms of value added, the TVEs’ value added per capita was 1526 yuan in the Eastern region in 1995, compared to 322 yuan in the Western region. Rural industrial growth has contributed significantly to rural economic development and income growth in the Eastern region where industrial enterprises run by townships and villages have now become dominant players in rural economic growth. Since 1987, the industrial output value produced by TVEs in this region has surpassed the gross output value of the agriculture sector (including farming, forestry, animal husbandry and fishing). By 1995, it was 3.86 times as much as the gross output value of the agriculture sector. The rapid growth of rural industry has played a leading role in rural economic development of the Eastern region. 129 In the Western region, however, the rural industry has developed relatively slower and its role in promoting the overall economic growth has been less important. By 1995, the industrial output value produced by TVEs was still less than that of the agriculture sector in the region. In terms if the income effect, the differential development of the rural industry has contributed greatly to the income gap between the Eastern and Western regions, especially in rural areas. In 1995, there were 42.85 million rural workers employed by industrial TVEs in the Eastern regions, which accounted for 26.3% of the total rural labour force. The total number of employees in all types of TVEs reached 63.72 million people, accounting for 39.1% of the total rural labour force. A massive participation of rural labour force in TVEs’ industrial and commercial activities contributed directly to the income growth of rural population in the Eastern region. For instance, the average wage income earned by each worker in TVEs in the region was 2064 yuan in 1995. On average each worker in TVEs produced a pre-tax operating profit of 2933 yuan. By comparison, the contribution of TVEs to the economic development and income growth of the Western region has been less significant. There were 9.66 million people working in industrial TVEs in 1995, accounting for only 8.4% of the total rural labour force. With the inclusion of employees in TVEs of other sectors, the total employees in the TVEs of the Western region numbered 21.17 million people, which accounted for 18.4% of the total rural labour force. In terms of income effect, the annual average wage for employees in TVEs was 831 yuan in 1995, which was only 40% of that of the Eastern region was 1101 yuan in 1995, which is also much less than the corresponding indicator for the Eastern region. This indicates that the differential development of rural industry in the two regions has further contributed to the inter-regional income inequality. Regression Analysis Using econometric modeling techniques, the section investigates fundamental factors determining the divergent economic growth of the Eastern and Western regions. The production function to be measured in this model is assumed to have the properties of the Cobb-Douglas production function, a basic and widely used form of production function. Due to the nature of data, all variables are aggregates at the provincial level. 130 Output is expressed by gross domestic product (GDP), and inputs include capital and labour. Capital input can be divided into two components: domestic and foreign capital. In this model, domestic capital input (DK) is expressed by domestically financed fixed investment. FDI represents foreign capital. It can also be regarded as an important indicator of the openness of the economy. In addition, as FDI is highly related to the transfer of foreign technology and management skills, thereby promoting technological progress in joint ventures and other firms, it can capture the impact of technology on production to some extent. Therefore, the production function can be written as: In terms of economic methodology, the model used here is a Kmenta Model (Kmenta, 1986), that is a cross-section and time-series model. This model is suitable and efficient for a regression analysis using crosssection and time-series data since it takes a cross-sectional heteroskedasticity and timewise autocorrelation into account, producing a reliable econometric output. To measure the variation in the effect of independent variables on the dependent variable (GDP) between the Eastern and Western regions, a dummy variable (D) is used. It takes the value 1 for the Eastern region and 0 for the Western region. Thus the regression formula is expressed as follows: 131 where c1 is the intercept for the Western region; c2 is the differential intercept for the Eastern region. The coefficients α1, β1 and γ1 are the estimated elasticity of GDP with respect to DK, FDI and L in the Western region. α2, β2 and γ2 are the differential coefficients of DK, FDI and L for the Eastern region. If α2, β2 and γ2 are significantly different from zero, the effects of changes in DK< FDI and L on GDP growth will be significantly different between the Eastern and Western regions, i.e. the responsiveness of GDP to changes in DK, FDI and L will be significantly different between the two regions, being stronger in the Eastern region than in the Western region, This is due to the fact that FDI has been concentrated in the Eastern region during the past 18 years. It is hypothesized that increases in domestic investment, FDI and labour will affect GDP growth positively, and therefore, the coefficients of DK, FDI and L are expected to be positive in both the regions. However, the impact of FDI on GDP growth is expected to be significantly different between the two regions, being stronger in the Eastern region than in the Western region. This is because FDI has been concentrated in the Eastern region during the past 18 years. Data and Spatial Spread The data used in this regression analysis are the provincial data of 19 provinces for the 1984-85 period. The spatial coverage is of 10 provinces in the Eastern region (Guangdong, Fujian, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Shanghai, Shandong, Hebei, Beijing, Tianjin and Liaoning) and 9 provinces in the Western region (Shaanxi, Sichuan, Qinghai, Yunnan, Guizhou, Gansu, Ningxia, Inner Mongolia and Xinjiang). The sources of data for the period 1984-1993 are from provincial statistical yearbooks for each province, with data for 1994 and 1995 being from the Statistical Yearbook of China 1995 and 1996. As the data include 19 provinces over a 12-year period, each variable has 228 observations. In order to remove the influence of inflation on the variables and their relations, GDP, DK and FDI are expressed in constant prices (1984=100). The current values of GDP and DK and FDI are expressed in constant prices (1984=100). The current values of GDP and DK are converted into real values using the 1984 constant prices for each province. 132 The value of FDI, which are originally expressed in current US dollar, are deflated using US GDP implicit price deflators. Regression Results and Implications The effects of FDI on GDP growth is positive in both the Eastern and Western regions. However, there is a significant difference in the impact of FDI between the two regions, being stronger in the Eastern region than in the Western region. This supports the hypothesis about the effect of FDI on regional economic growth. In terms of the elasticity coefficient, a 1% increase in FDI would generate a 0.0914% growth of GDP in the Eastern region, while a 1% change in FDI would lead to a 0.0356% change in the GDP of the Western region. As the elasticity coefficient reflects the percentage change in GDP in response to a 1% change in FDI, its low level implies that the % change in FDI is much larger than that of GDP. During 1984-1995, GDP grew at 12.1% per annum in the Eastern region, while FDI grew at 37.1% per annum. In the Western region GDP and FDI grew at 9.1% and 34.9% respectively. This suggests that to estimate the actual impact of FDI on GDP growth, the actual growth rate of FDO must also be considered. Domestically financed investment is the most important determinant of economic growth in both the Eastern and Western regions. The elasticity coefficients of DK are statistically significant, indicating that the responsiveness of GDP to changes in domestically financed fixed investment is positive and strong in the two regions. A 1% growth in DK will lead to a 0.394% growth of GDP in the Eastern region, and to a 0.523% growth of GDP in the Western region. A higher elasticity coefficient of DK for the Western region suggests that the economic growth in the region is more responsive to changes in domestically financed investment. This indicates that the economic growth of the Western region is more dependent on domestic investment in comparison to the Eastern region. There is a significant difference in the elasticity of GDP with respect to labor change between the two regions. A 1% increase in labour force is associated with 0.481% growth of GDP in the Western region, while the corresponding coefficient for the Eastern region is 0.377%. This implies that the economic growth of the Western region is more dependent on labour input, and the production process is more labour-intensive compared to that of the Eastern region. The differential intercept of production function for the Eastern region is significantly different from zero (0.9432), indicating that other factors such as technology, economic structure and management have played a greater part in the economic growth of the Eastern region than in the Western region. 133 A higher intercept in the production function (i.e. a higher position of the isoquant curve) suggests that technological and structural factors contributed more to economic growth in the Eastern region than in the Western region. Using the estimated elasticity coefficients of GDP with regard to DK, FDI and L, the relative contributions of these inputs to economic growth in the two regions can be identified. During 1984-1995, the average annual growth rate of GDP was 12.05% in the Eastern region, and the average growth rates of DK< FDI and L are 13.79%, 37.06% and 2.37% respectively. Over the same period, the GDP of the Western Region grew at 9.12% on the average, DK, FDI and L grew at annual rates of 10.8%, 34.9% and 2.4% respectively. Thus, the estimated GDP growth functions for the Eastern and Western regions can be expressed respectively as: (1) For the Eastern region: GDP = 2.814 + 0.394 DK + 0.091 DFI* + 0.474 L* = 2.814 + (0.394 x 13.79) + (0.091 x 37.06) + (0.377 x 2.37) = 2.814 + 5.433+ 3.634 + 0.893 = 12.774 where asterisk denotes average proportional change with respect to time. GDPr /GDP* = 12.05 / 12.774 = 0.943 where GDPr is the real GDP growth rate and GDP* is the estimated growth rate. Therefore, the relative contributions of the factors of production to GDP growth for the Eastern region are respectively: DK* / GDP* = 5.433 / 12.774 0.425, or 42.5% DFI */ GDP* = 3.634 /12.774 0.285 or 28.5% L */ GDP* = 0.893 / 12.774 = 0.07, or 7.0% 134 These figures suggest that: Domestically financed investment (DK) is still the largest contributor to the economic growth in both regions. In the Eastern region, 42.5% of GDP growth was accounted for by the increase in domestically financed investment from 1984 to 1995. In the Western region, domestically financed investment is even more important in determining economic growth, contributing to 57% of GDP growth over the same period. This implies that the economic growth in the Western region is more dependent on domestic investment than in the Eastern Region. FDI is an important factor contributing to divergent economic growth rates between the Eastern and Western regions. Between 1984 to 1995 period, FDI contributed 3.634% points of the GDP growth rate of the Eastern region, which accounted for 28.5% of the economic growth (12.05%). In other words, nearly 1/3 of the GDP growth in the region was brought by FDI. FDI has become the second largest contributor to the economic growth of the Eastern region. In comparison, FDI contributed 1.24% point of the GDP growth rate in the Western region, accounting for 12.5% of the GDP growth (9.12%). 135 This suggests that FDI alone resulted in a 2.392 % point difference (3.6341.242=2.392) in the growth rates of GDP between the two regions. This can explain 81.6% of the overall difference in growth rates (12.059.12=2.93) between the Eastern and Western regions (i.e. 2.392/2.93=0.816). This indicates that FDI is the most important factor contributing to the differential economic growth and income inequality existing between the Eastern and Western regions during the reform era. Labour force (L) contributes to economic growth differently in each of the regions. In the Eastern region, 7% of GDP growth was generated by the increase of labour force compared to 11.6% in the Western region. This suggests that economic growth in the Western region is more responsive to and more dependent on an increase in the labour force. The relative contribution of the labour force to economic growth is more significant in the less-developed Western region than in the Eastern region. The estimated coefficient for the constant ‘c’ of the production function for the Eastern region is significantly higher than that for the Western region. This points to other factors especially technology, management and economic structure having played a more important role in the economic development of the Eastern region than in the Western region. The above findings spell out that the differential growth rates of domestically financed investment, FDI and improvement of productivity are the primary reasons for the divergent economic growth of the Eastern and Western regions. A higher investment rate, increased openness of the economy especially FDI, technological progress, macro and micro-economic reforms and industrial structural changes, contributed significantly to economic growth in the Eastern region. Therefore, the divergence of the economic growth rate and income inequality between the two regions have further widened in the past 18 years. The increased inter-regional economic disparity reveals that the economic boom of the Eastern region has not diffused effectively to the Western region. The diffusion of growth (the ‘trickle down effect’) from the Eastern region to the Western region has not happened or has not been empirically evidenced. The major reasons for the deficiency of the diffusion of growth is the lack of effective inter-regional industrial linkages and the lack of an integrated and well-functioning domestic market. Under the open-door policy, the Eastern region has been encouraged to be more involved in the international markets for both the export of products and the imports of inputs. This development strategy was formally confirmed at the 13th Congress of the Chinese Communist Party in 1987. Consequently, the economy of the Eastern region become more foreign market-oriented. This is particularly the case in Guangdong and Fujian provinces. 136 Their economic integration with Hong Kong and Taiwan has developed rapidly in the past ten years and is an important characteristic and major cause of economic development of the Southeast Region of China, As the coastal region has increasingly shifted emphasis to overseas markets, the economic linkages between the coastal region and inland regions including the Western region have weakened. In addition, the less-developed domestic market has worked against developing effective regional economic linkages. Since the early 1980s, the Chinese economy has been undergoing a transformation from the traditional centrally-planned system to a market economy. The market-oriented reforms are more progressive and far-reaching in the Eastern region than in the Western region. The regional imbalance in progress towards economic reforms and opening has impeded the formation and development of the integrated domestic market and restrained the economic linkages and cooperation between the two regions. Even at the current stage, regional market segments still prevail in China, As a result, economic growth in the Eastern region cannot effectively diffuse to the Western region, as the ‘dualism’ theory predicts. Consequently, the inter-regional economic disparity and income inequality has widened. Conclusion In the reform era since 1979, the Chinese economy ahs experienced rapid growth and a widening disparity in economic indicators between regions. Many factors have contributed to the regional divergence in economic growth and increased income inequality. The factors contributed to the inter-regional differences in economic growth and income per capita are: ● Industrial structure and resource conditions, ● Coast-oriented foreign investment and economic openness, ● Regional development policy with emphasis on the Eastern region, ● The unbalanced growth of exports and foreign direct investment, ● Rural industrial development, and ● Domestic capital flows from the Western region to the Eastern region Using production function analysis, we has found that ● The higher rate of domestic investment, ● Enormous inflow of foreign direct investment, and ● Greater openness are the major reasons for the higher economic growth rate of the Eastern region compared to the Western region. 137 Without a large amount of FDI inflow and greater openness, the economic growth rate of the Eastern region would not be significantly higher than that of the Western region. This suggests that foreign investment, exports and greater involvement in international market have promoted capital formation and productivity, which are the major determinants of a higher rate of economic growth in the Eastern region. As a result of divergent growth rates, the economic gap and income inequality between the Eastern and Western regions have been further widened in the reform era. The disparity which has arisen is also closely related to the regional policy of the Chinese government. In essence, the regional policy throughout the reform era was based on regional comparative advantages. Under this policy, the coastal region, due to its superior geographic location and factor endowment, has been given a pivotal role as ‘growth pole’ or ‘engine of growth’. To promote the growth of this region, the central government implemented special economic policies and committed a large amount of capital to improve infrastructure. As a result, the investment environment in the coastal region was more attractive than in the inland. Domestic and foreign capital therefore flowed into the coastal region, accelerating its regional economic growth. However, due to the lack of effective inter-regional industrial linkages and a well-functioning domestic market, the economic boom in the coastal region has not noticeably spread to the inland, further resulting in a widening interregional economic disparity and income inequality. Policy Implications Some implications can be drawn from the Chinese experience. First, inter-regional disparity is unavoidable in the process of economic development, especially for a developing country. Since the conditions for development for development in each region are different, the regional policy based on comparative advantages tends to reinforce the existing regional difference. Thus, regional ‘equality’ and ‘efficiency’ of development are two primary issues faced by the government of a developing country. In the initial stage of development, a government may place priority on a coastal (well established) region which can lead to rapid growth of the national economy as a whole. Second, a government should pay particular attention to the growing interregional disparity, 138 In order to facilitate the diffusion of growth from the booming region to a relatively stagnant region, inter-regional economic linkages should be promoted through a series of policy tools and encouragement of economic cooperation across different regions. The artificial barriers to inter-regional economic linkage and integration should be removed, and in the Chinese context, some regulations which isolate the SEZs or other coastal areas from the inland regions should be eliminated. Furthermore, bilateral trade, investments and other linkages between the coastal and the inland regions should be promoted, rather than the coastal region being encouraged to rely solely on foreign markets. Another important point for a less-developed market economy or for one undergoing the transformation from a central planning system to a market economy, is the enhancement of the market mechanism. As a well-developed market can allocate resources efficiently, the overall efficiency of an economy can be significantly improved. However, since market forces may fail to facilitate a balanced growth and may even result in regional inequality in the first stage of development, a suitable regional policy is critical. The government should foster market efficiency and domestic market integration and promote economic linkages and cooperation between regions. Therefore, the role of the government in achieving a balanced growth is important. Third, as the coast-oriented open policy has tended to widen the economic gap between the Western and the Eastern regions, it is necessary for the Chinese government to standardize the open policy in all regions and to eliminate the existing regional discrimination in foreign trade autonomy. The open policy should be extended as much as possible to the vast inland regions where a huge potential for development exists. This would enable the Western region to improve economic conditions and explore its great development potential. Finally, improvement in transportation and communication facilities is essential for enhancing inter-regional economic linkages and cooperation.\ The central government should allocate funds to finance some important transportation projects, and should also encourage local capital to invest in infrastructure so as to improve the local investment environment. Some special programs stimulating investment in the Western region are necessary. Reference Chapter 6: Industrial Linkage Effects of FDI on Domestic Sectors, in Sun, H. S., (1998), Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China: 1979-1996, Ashgate, Aldershot, UK 139 Lecture ??: Trade regimes (WTO), Regionalization and Global Development: Intervention, Control and Policy International Organization for Trade Two most extraordinary but seemingly contradicted phenomena: global agreement and regional economic integration Bretton Woods Agreement 1944 (still in WWII) made by US, Britain and their western allies (in New Hampshire) decided to form three institutions: International Monetary Fund (IMF) is to ensure the convertibility of currencies…now helping the rich International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (the World Bank) is to facilitate the international flows of capital… now mainly helping the poor; International Trade Organization (ITO) to reduce the barriers to world trade. ITO died in 1947-48 due to being too ambitious: Although it was ratified by participating countries (54), but they perceived it as a threat to their sovereignty. But GATT (General Agreement On Tariffs and Trade) immediately emerged in 1948, which was in about 45 years later, replaced by WTO in 1995. GATT – General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade Initial 23 countries reconvened in Geneva to find an alternative way to bring order to world trade and produce GATT which went effect in 1948. It committed the participating countries to reduce tariff on 45,000 items and laid down a set of rules and principles governing trade among the signatories: 140 Reciprocity: One reduce tariff to others and the respecting side must do the same. Non-discrimination: No preferential treatment to each others and all are treated as the most favoured – known as the Most Favoured Nation rule – China got this status from USA permanently just in 2000 Transparency: replace non-tariffs with tariffs, which subject to scrutiny and reduction by further negotiation Developing countries – special provision for developing countries Great Success: Membership grew steadily and now covered majority of trading nations (134 in 1999). After series of “Round” of negotiations, tariff cut from 40% to 10% in mid 1970s and further cut to an average 5%. Now tariff rate in DCs is about 5-7% (or less than 10%) and in LDCs about 1520%. However, in this period regional integration aim at protectionism also grew rapidly and caused growth rate of trade not to be increased considerably. Weaknesses: Original design is to reduce tariff and enforce rules for trade in manufactured goods. It has increasingly become inadequate and unsuitable for today’s world trade scene, such as the important agricultural product and internationally tradable services not covered at all by GATT. 141 Thus, the far-reaching Uruguay Round of trade negations resulted in 19861990-1994: Agricultural Trade: most difficult talks but far-reaching breakthrough – USA free trade victory Textiles and clothing: the most nasty conflicts of trade between DLs and LDCs. Intellectual property: patent and copyright protection, such as computer software, semiconductor designs, biotechnology, musical recordings, books – against fierce pirating and counterfeiting activities which cause the loss of billions of dollars of revenue for holders of intellectual property rights. Services: the fastest-growing sector in advanced economies, constituting 90% of jobs and substantial trade volume. Internationally traded services include banking, insurance and other financial services, tourism, advertising, architecture and construction engineering, planning, consultancy, transportation. And telecommunications (now the internet) – will besthe most lucrative business for trade in the coming decades Investment: National policy distorted international capital flow and foreign investor, such as joint-venture rule and limitation of the area to foreign investment. Dispute settlement 142 The Uruguay Round failed to reach anything by the deadline in 1990, but the whole world felt the cost and resumed the talks and finally reached agreement that was also ratified by all participation countries. The 2200-pages GATT treaty of Uruguay Round is the broadest, most farreaching trade pact in world history – agricultural breakthrough, two new agreements on telecom sector and on service sector. But the contents of the GATT are now far beyond the regulation “Tariff” – thus, a world supranational organization born - WTO. WTO - a world supranational organisation, literally for trade, in fact for almost every thing! Tariffs: One-third cut on the whole, developed cut by 36% and developing by 24% Quotas: Illegal and should be eliminated Health and Safety: Cannot be used to against trading partners, thus it ends the most pervasive technology used by bureaucrats to exclude a wide range of goods, from foodstuff to motor cars. Intellectual property: All signatories must protect patent, copyright, trade secrets and trademarks and to commit to end the wholesale pirating and counterfeiting of software and series of products relating to intellectual property rights. Local content: prohibits members from requiring a high local content in products manufactured within their borders. Landslide effect on world trade: Europe and Japan – agricultural good, while US manufactured and auto goods; The rich countries phase out Quotas, while the poor commit to more transparency; The pact also calls for free trade in financial services – the Financial Services agreement (FSA). The pact also call for opening in telecom, internet markets and audiovisual product - - the Information Technology Agreement (ITA) and the Agreement on Basic Telecommunications (ABT) 143 Again, great success: the pact will add US$510 billion into global economy, of which US gain US$122, Europe US$164, Japan $27, LDCs $116. The world as a whole shall benefited more. Controversy: Sovereignty, Environment, Labour, Equality, Sanitary and safety… Regional Economic Integration Why integration? To achieve growth through the enlargement of the market To raise standard of living and to reduce regional disparity To strengthen bargaining power in global polity and economic affairs To develop cooperative solution for a variety of social and political problems 144 Integration Theory Integration is a form of selective discrimination because it combines elements of free trade with greater protection – free trade with members and restrictions on trade with non-members Five levels of integration: Figure 12.5 Elements conducive to successful integration: Parallel economies, Proximity, Contiguous countries within a compact area, Large combines territory with many small countries, Best customers and suppliers, Major world trader and high trade barriers; The “second-best solution” to world trade problems Trade creation (good) and trade diversion (bad) Most importantly, benefit from scale economy and “increasing returns” - the bigger the better; creating new trade and making trade diversion is not necessarily “bad” Integration for Development But one dilemma: less than one-fifth of all LDC trade is with other LDCs, most trade is DCs with DCs and LDCs with DCs. Great Success in Europe: The European Union The Global competitiveness of US High-Tech Industries Reference: Chapter 12: Berry B.J.L., Conkling E.C. and Ray D.M. (1997), The Global Economy in Transition (second edition), Prentice Hall Inc., New Jersey, United States. 145 Lecture IV: China's WTO Accession, State Enterprise reform, and Spatial Economic Restructuring Background: After a 13-year conscientious bid and serious negotiations, China has at last been able to enter WTO this year, congratulations! This is a great, in fact the greatest, historical event for China. Its significance is comparable to, or even larger than, China's first-attempt of reform and the implementation of open-door policy launched in 1978. The fundamental meaning of China's WTO accession is far beyond "trade" or "market opening/access." It has been Chinese Premier Zhu Rongji's last-ditch effort to break through the many formidable impasses and deadlocks he encountered in pushing his grand reform packages that have by and large remained unsuccessful so far. That is, China's WTO accession can be seen as the panacea that Zhu Rongji or China desperately needs to transform China's whole economic system in general, and to reform the deadwood state enterprise sector in particular. In essence, it is about fundamentally transforming China's existing "socialist" system and about building-up a newly internationalized system, harmonizing its rule with "outside" rules or “the global way”, with the help of foreign or international forces foreign capital, competition, and experiences and networks. Hence, its implication is far-reaching and goes beyond the economic, social, political, geographical, and even in the “rule of law”, personal freedom and human right realms. With a brief introduction to this general background, this talk will focus on the interrelationship between China's WTO Accession and state enterprise reform and their profound impact on China's spatial economic restructuring, including the possible rise and fall of China's regional economic centers, such as Shanghai, Beijing, and even Hong Kong, and sectoral regionalization. 146 Euphoria of China's WTO Accession: A long-waited for the door opened, a real breakthrough A Win-Win deal for both China and USA; HK people says a Win-Win-Win deal plus Hong Kong; Politician says a Win-Win-Win deal for Zhu Rongji, Jiang Zemin and Bill Clinton To Chinese: "If we say that Deng Xiaoping opened China to the world in 1979, we can say that this time China has entered the world." To Foreigner: "With Deng's open policy, you can “see” China, now you can do business in China" Entry to the WTO should integrate the mainland economy into a global capitalist system that offers both tremendous growth opportunities and, potentially, ruinous competition. What we concern and interested: What this means for us, from American farmers to the AT&T boss to Chinese farmers to China Telecom directors? And particularly to our geographers, what this means to us spatially - to our places, HK, Shanghai, Beijing, Guangdong, Northeast, and Sichuan? 147 1. Theoretical Framework and China’s Economic Backgrounds: A. Old&New Trade Theories - The world double/triple gains/benefits from trade: Trade is always beneficial to the both sides of the trading parties or multi-trading participants. The world as whole will benefits from trade twice/triples: Comparative Advantages that maximizes the outputs and consumption for both or multiple sides of trading countries (Smith 1937; Ricado 19??) - As long as there is trade, no one lose or every trading country will be better off; This is called "arm-length trade". Increasing Returns embedded in FDI and MNE enhance on specialization and concentration and increase the trade volume second time from intra-firms/sectors/industries trade, hence maximize output/benefits for firms/sectors/industries (Krugman 1990) - trade for the trade sake and every trading party/firm will be increasingly better off; This is MNE or own trade Trade embedded in both MNE and joint-venture corporations gives rise to opportunities for a relative disadvantage catching up with an absolute advantage or breakthrough the dominance and superiority of the absolute advantages (Simon Zhao 20??; Porter 1990) - Japanese car industry and China's WTO accession and market opening. B. Trade is not mere "trade" or more precisely "trading of goods" - Nowadays Trade becomes very comprehensive and complicate – A world of “no boundaries” for the manufacturing, service and finance sectors. In fact, today’s world includes everything, particular services. Global Trade organization is a supranational and suprastructural organization. In the face of globalization era, IT and internet and time-space transcending to conversion era, every thing can be traded and trade instantly - trade finance, trade service, trade information, trade technology, trade intellectual property, etc. Trading in this area 148 becomes more important, crucial and more profound in this postmodernism era, in which huge amount of financial capital flows instantly transfer around the world and easily leave a national economy in ruins. Facing this new or super trade form, the “border” and sovereignty of every nation is increasing under threat and hence every sovereignty nation seeks a global supranational organizational structure that can govern this modern, new and super trade form. Thus, global trade organization, namely WTO, is increasingly become such a supranational organization. There are three major and strategic multilateral agreements negotiated since the Uruguay Round – the Information Technology Agreement (ITA), the Agreement on Basic Telecommunications (ABT), and the Financial Services agreement (FSA). But, the power of these three agreements is just calling for free trade and open market in these three areas, without a concrete measure and provision for enforcing these agreements. In these three strategic areas - IT, BT, and FS, and particular the service sector, Mainland China is one of the largest but the most “closed” markets to which foreign companies have been for years trying to gain the access but failed so far. China also renowned with bad practice in intellectual property protection, counterfeiting and piracy of foreign goods and technology. That is why Seattle Round of WTO Negotiation is very important and that is why US and the whole world are so eager to bring China to this “world trade club”. C. China's bid for WTO accession is not merely for trade. In essence, it is about fundamentally transforming China's existing "socialist" market system and about integrating China into the global system, harmonizing its rule with "outside" rule, with the helps of foreign or international forces - foreign capital, competition, and experiences and networks, as well as market accountability. 149 It has been Chinese Premier Zhu Rongji's last-ditch effort to break through the many formidable impasses and deadlocks he encountered in pushing his grand reform packages that have by and large remained unsuccessful so far. That is, China's WTO accession can be seen as the panacea that Zhu Rongji or China desperately needs to transform China's whole economic system in general, and to reform the deadwood and “incurable” state enterprise sector in particular. Let’s take a look at the basic facts and background: Consecutively two years of unprecedented deflationary spiral, with severe lack of demand in consumption and huge amount of inventory; A substantial drop in both foreign trade and foreign investment, particular FDI: 20% drop in August 2000, but now there is a sign of recovering - year-on-year 6.2% decline by September 2000. By 1998 China accumulate foreign investment worth US$300billion, with amount of US$40 billion each year with this year 30 billion. Huge non-performing loan and bad loan in state-own enterprise (SOE) sector: Current total SOE fix assets amounted 9600 billion yuan, but dead/bad loan in the Central Bank amounted to 5800 billion yuan, accounts for about 60% debt/equity ratio. Totaling 29,000 SOEs has current capital less than 3000 billion yuan; Many many SOEs and banks virtually bankrupted. Chronically and extremely poor efficiency in SOEs - more than 50%, some says 70% firms lost-making, compounded with massive redundancy - 10% unemployment rate and massive off-duty workers - about 50% urban workers and cadres under off-duty threat; Extremely poor social security and welfare systems GDP stagnant around 7% (7.4% in the first 3 quarters) China's 7% growth means no or low growth and normally 8% to 9% regarded as OK - catching up employment needs and social security needs. Currency under devaluation pressure All Zhu Rongji's grand reform packages - reforms in civil servant or government sector, financial sector (banking, 150 insurance, security), food marketing sector, urban housing sector, and SOE sector - by and large remained unsuccessful (Only one thing Zhu has done so far can be regarded as successful is his anti-smuggling South China tour in early 2000) But Chinese citizens holds 6000 billion yuan deposit saving, this accounts for more than 60% of GDP in China, and 1000 billion cash in hands; But how China could solve these “crisis” with the emergence of the WTO accession? D. Integration Theory - Increasing returns by specialization, agglomeration and spatial economic grouping/restructuring 2. Terms of China's WTO Accession: China's offers - Nov terms: Overall tariffs: Significant cuts in tariffs that will be completed by January 2004. Overall average for agricultural products will be 17 per cent and for US priority products 14.5 per cent. China will make significant liberalization on importing agricultural products, especially wheat, corn, cotton and other bulk commodities. According to the bilateral agriculture-trade agreement, China would eliminate all quantitative restrictions on agricultural bulk commodities. For industrial products, tariffs cut to an average of 9.4 per cent overall and 7.1 per cent on US priority products. It will cut tariffs on imported cars from the current 80-100 per cent to 25 per cent by 2006 and allows foreign financial institutions to finance the purchase of cars by Chinese citizens. 151 China will eliminate non-tariff quotas within five years, some in two to three years. It will allow 49 per cent foreign investment in telecommunications firms from the date of entry, rising to 50 per cent in two years, and will allow foreign banks to conduct local currency business with domestic companies two years after accession and with domestic individuals five years after. Beijing also agreed to lift the ban on foreign investment in Internet related businesses. These are substantial concessions and, if fully implemented, will give foreign firms far greater access to the China market than they currently enjoy. USA offers: In return, Beijing received a concession on textiles, with Washington backing down from its demand that quotas on China's exports remain until 2010. Instead they will end in 2005, but with an "anti-import surge" mechanism remaining for a further four years, to prevent a flood of exports. USA have already granted the “Permanent Normal Trade Relations” (PNTR) status to China in late 2000, which is formally known as “Most Favorable Nation” (MFN) status. Summary (based on both Nov. and the April Version) (also See Appendix I) Market Access and Tariff Reductions: Overall 17% from current 22%; farm goods 17% and 14.5% to US product; Industrial goods tariffs cut to an average of 9.4 per cent overall and 7.1 per cent on US priority products; and phaseout most Tariff Rate Quota (TRQ) system for bulk commodities by 2005/6; Bindings for all tariffs and no export subsidies; 152 Decentralization of Trade Right and Distribution (wholesaling, retailing, to both private sector and foreign firms; Opening up the strategic and lucrative sectors and market for foreign investor and investment with 50-50 joint venture and foreign majority control (some up to 100% ownership - hotel or reinsurance): telecommunications & internet, banking, insurance, securities, travel & tourism, and professional service (legal, accountancy, taxation, management consultancy, architecture, engineering, urban planning, medical &dental, I.T.-related services) Opening up audiovisual and intellectual property market to foreign investment and investor who can build and run video and sound recordings shop and cinemas with joint or own ventures. Binding China to comply with all WTO rules and particular the three agreements (ITA, ABT and FSA); Guarantee private participation; impose SOE reform and act on a commercial basis without any privilege power In short: China's WTO accession not only allows American/foreign goods and capital enter China, but American/foreigner, American/foreigner interest/firms into China, and into the most strategic and lucrative sectors, where they can open or build up their own business in an environment similar to their home. 4. China's WTO Accession's Impact on Economic Sectors - Industries Hit Hardest and China's Selfdefense Mainland industries that have been cushioned from international competition are expected to be hit hardest. Agriculture, automobiles, banking, telecommunications, insurance and distribution would experience the greatest competitive pressure, 153 1) Agriculture: Analyst at China International Capital Corp (CICC) Shawn Xu Xiaonian estimated the value of the country's agricultural imports would be double that of last year under the Sino-US Agricultural Agreements signed in April. He said that, even if the value of grain imports increased threefold after the mainland's entry into the WTO, the country's grain self-sufficiency ratio would drop only from 97 per cent to 92 per cent. The Chinese government controls the rights of trade and distribution in key products such as wheat, corn, rice, cotton, surgar, and chemical fertilizers. All these goods are under TRQ control and China Food Corp. is the sole agent to trade and distribution 2) Car industry: High tariffs and government protection have made car-production one of the Mainland's least efficient industries. China has more than 120 car factories could be facing closure because of the Mainland's entry into the World Trade Organization. China has 120 car factories and produced 1.6 million cars annually , less than any of the world's top 10 car-makers. Toyota, Japan's largest carmaker and the world's third-biggest, made 5.3 million vehicles last year. In China only three automakers (Shanghai auto, No.1 auto and No.2 auto) produce more that 0.1 million, most of them around 1000; last year three factories produce nothing and 30 factories produce 100 cars The mainland's 10 biggest plants make more than 90 per cent of national output. Beijing wants to centralize production in these 10 but cannot because of the protection of local governments and special interests which see cars as a pillar industry. 48 per cent lost money last year, up from 42.3 per cent in 1997. Total losses rose 175 per cent to 2.2 billion yuan (about HK$2.05 billion) and profits fell 55.4 per cent to 3.44 billion yuan. Inventory rose 15.7 per cent to a record of 114,000 vehicles. 154 WTO terms: It will cut tariffs on imported cars from the current 80-100 per cent to 25 per cent by 2006 and allow foreign financial institutions to finance the purchase of cars. The difference of price between the Mainland and foreign cars in same rank is about 50%, which means to buy a similar model of car in the Mainland, a consumer need to pay double the price as purchasing the same car in the overseas market But: (1) China import 40,000 vehicles last year, occupying 2.4% market, but smuggled 100,000-150,000 cars annually (10% output/market). With 10 to 15% growth quota and 5 to 10% reduction in tariffs annually in opening its market for about 7 years, The number of foreign import cars are less than or may just amounted to the smuggling cars. (2) China hold firmly the rights of car trading (right of import and export - not open at all), foreign car cannot “flooded” into China markets (3) It is still the best way for foreign car makers to enter mainland market through joint-venture in car industry with FID or under the Debt-to-Share scheme. This will be a win-win deal for the Chinese and the foreign side. (4) The Chinese civilian purchasing power is still too weak for to the purchase and usage of the private CAR, which is currently most luxury consumer goods in China – The market is not as large as others thought. 3) Similar to cars, China hold the rights of trade and distribution in petroleum and petrochemical goods; foreign petroleum is much cheaper than in China e.g. cost for one barrel oil in China is amounted to US$13.5 and in USA, US$8.8. China should import more foreign petroleum, which is much cheaper. 4) Telecommunications and internet (lucrative market): After China’s ascension to the WTO, foreign investors could take controlling stakes in the Mainland's telecommunications sector and also open the door for investments in the Internet sector. The mainland is to allow up to 50 per cent foreign ownership and control in its telecom and Internet markets sooner than previously agreed. 155 The timetable had called for 25 per cent maximum foreign ownership in value-added services such as Internet-related services by next year in Shanghai, Beijing and Guangzhou, expanded to 51 per cent of nationwide services by 2004. As for Mobile services, 25 per cent of foreign ownership would be allowed in the three areas by 2001, extending to 49 per cent of nationwide services by 2005. As for Fixed-line businesses in the three key areas, 25 per cent foreign ownership by 2002 would be allowed, growing to 49 per cent of nationwide networks by 2006. During talks in 2000, US negotiators reportedly insisted on 51 per cent of foreign ownership rights in the mainland's telecom sector but Beijing refused to go beyond the allowance of minority holdings for foreign investors. But: All telecom/internet business cannot be sole foreign own. Foreign control power up to 49% in 2 years and to 50% later. It will be a 50-50 joint-venture business in the telecommunication sector. 5) Banking: Although foreign banks are allowed to conduct local currency business with domestic companies two years after accession and with domestic individuals five years after, Beijing may impose restrictions on the number of branches a foreign bank can operate in an individual province or city. "If a foreign bank is allowed to have just one branch in a city like Beijing, how can it compete with China Construction Bank, for example?" All financial and service firms cannot be sole foreign owned. Foreign control stakes in banks shall be up to 33% in 3 years and to 49% 3 year later. 156 6) Insurance, Financial and Professional Services: The provision of insurance, financial and professional sector is very weak in China. The foreign entries in such industries provide massive room for development in these areas. In the WTO agreement, foreign entry to this sector shall be a 50-50 joint-venture business and it would be again operate under a “one-city-one-office basis. In summary: China has largely opened its goods market but less openness or even no openness in the service and distribution market for goods- the right of trade and distribution; China hold the controlling stake in most business and investment; Compared to April version, China offers more tariffs cut in return of more control or US gets more market opening but less control power in businesses and joint ventures 50-50 Joint-venture is the most likely form and the best form for foreign business and investors to march in the vast Mainland markets. And this is a win-win deal for all parties according to economic and trade theories - FDI and MNE, rather than goods itself, are the best way to export one’s goods to other markets. No foreign goods shall flood in, but there a chance of foreign capital buyout 157 5. Package of Further SOE Reforms Background: Existing China's Stock Market establishment and Sharefloating Firms Development - An act of Nationalization, rather than privatization Reform Package: Privatization scheme - withdraw the state majority control from 51% share-holding to 30% (legal shares) and the “grand” sell-out the remaining shares to the private markets, including institutional and private investors; Listing of the large and strategic companies, such as China Unicom, China petroleum, China Natural Gas etc in foreign markets with the encouragement of substantial foreign ownership "Hold the large and release the small" scheme - State owns, controls and operates 1000 the country's largest and strategic SOEs/companies and let others SOEs go, and therefore the shares of these SOEs are available to the markets for both foreign and domestic investors. Debt-share Swapping scheme (or called Debt-to-equity conversions scheme) - China's largest SOEs with huge debt and negative assets can convert their debts to shares which can be bought or owned by both domestic and foreign investors (selling them into markets). Along with this scheme, the Ministry of Finance is considering a massive sell-out of SOE assets which is largely in debt (5800 billion yuan out of 9600 billion yuan or 60% of SOE assets are debts) for recovery of the fiscal capability of the central government. Cases: H share Anshan Iron and Steel Complex, one of the Mainland's largest state-owned steel firms, has signed a 6.85 billion yuan (about HK$6.39 billion) debt-for-equity swap agreement with creditors. Xinhua news agency said Anshan's swap agreement was the largest so far signed between a state-owned enterprise (SOE) and the asset-management corporations Beijing set up this year to liquidate non-performing loans at state-run commercial banks. Creditors included the China Huarong Asset Management 158 Corporation, China Development Bank, China Cinda Asset Management Corporation and the China Oriental Asset Management Corporation. China's many large SOEs, for example, publicly listed in HK H-share companies Jilin Chemical (China’s largest Chemical company), Jinwei Textile and Qinling Motor are under this scheme, Share-option scheme - the payment shares, as a bonus, to successful SOE senior managers. This is performance-linked bonus scheme Private Company Listed Scheme - Allowing private companies publicly listed in stock market and encouraging private enterprise development and protecting their interest. Such private assets worth about 7000 billion (70% GDP) yuan Implications: Grand and massive sell-out of assets of SOE, but who bought it and where was the money came from? For big caps: conditional sell-out – that is, no foreign majority control in the large or the largest strategic industries or in the manufacturing sector. Foreign investor, particular big players, must become jointventure in order to tap mainland market in a massive way. For small caps: unconditional sell out - SOEs can be sell-out to both private and foreign investors. This means foreign investors can solely own their business in a wide range of manufacturing sectors, and in some in agricultural sectors (?) Joint-venture with FDI and MNEs is still best way to go to China. As long as in this way, China's industry has the chance to grow - that is the relative disadvantage can catch up the absolute advantage where Joint-venture of FDI and MNEs hold. 159 6. WTO Pact and SOE Reform package Combined - Spatial Impacts (WTO goods+ services and SOE manufacturing): Grand Opening China's manufacturing and service sector, also including agricultural sector, not only the market but in investment: Massive Chinese and foreign encounter in almost all fronts; agriculture, manufactury, service, hi-tech etc. That is, the fundamental meaning of China's WTO accession is the last-ditch effort of the Chinese Premier, Zhu Rongji, to break through the many formidable impasses and deadlocks he encountered in pushing his grand reform packages that have by and large remained unsuccessful so far, with the helps of foreign or international forces - foreign capital, competition, and experiences and networks. What will happen from now on, in both short and long turns? Along with the big surge of trade volume, at least three waves which are mutually inter-related or cause-and-effected, can be foreseeable in neat future: A wave of deals/business/investment in manufacturing, telecommunication & internet, IT sectors will first emerge, in which corporate activities (enterprise buy and sell, mergers and acquisitions) will be very active. Along with this wave, enterprise listing/floating will boom. Many big players as well as small players, both private and foreigner, queue to shoot as playing field levels out. This is particularly attractive for big foreign caps aiming at tapping the mainland market in the largest and most strategic industries, such as in iron and steel, petroleum, chemical, cars, telecommunication and internet industries through joint-venture and debt-to-share schemes. This wave is particular good for China's Northeast region, where is dominated by heavy industries, and many urban manufacturing centers. In this wave, American, Japanese and European firms are relatively the major actors. The availability of jobs shall come down and moving up, but shall be dominated by “moving up” . 160 A wave of deals/business/investment in financial and service sector will unprecedentedly emerge, following the first wave. Many financial institutions, both foreign and domestic (as required in 50-50 joint venture rule), such as banks, investment and development banks, stock and equity brokers, insurance companies, securities firms, will be spring out. Immediately following this outburst is another unprecedented boom of professional services: legal, accountancy, taxation, management consultancy, architecture, engineering, urban planning, medical & dental, computer-related services, environmental services, and travel & tourism. In this boom Hong Kong and America are relatively the active players. Huge amount of job opportunities will be created. A wave of new regulatory rules/laws/policy and vast information and innovations will subsequently emerge, in which Beijing is the absolutely major or even sole player. A new round of licensing and franchising, redistributing/reallocating TRQs (ensuring private and foreign firms participation), decentralizing trading rights and right of distribution, is intensively encountered by government, both central and local, particularly ministerial (China's industries are still under ministerial management). Establishment of new governing bodies, both official and sectoral, and of new rules/laws and new policies governing all these new activities in trade, manufacturing, and service sectors is urgently needed. Sectoral and civil management organizations handling industrial disputes and civilian complaints, both international and local, are also needed accordingly. Along with this wave of regulatory measures establishments, vast information and innovation, both regulatory and business, are induced and float around China major cities, particular Beijing and Hong Kong. Many jobs will be created. 161 So, what is the spatial impact of all these three wave? Which place is winner or loser, comparable to their gain and loss, and in what areas? Overall Outcomes: The largest is the best and The worst is the best - Large SOEs bailed out by foreign capital, and agriculture/husbandry also have chance to upgrade their efficiency and productivity by foreign participation and competition. Hong Kong, Beijing, Northeastern and Western regions are the relative winners while Shanghai and East region (Jiangsu, Zhejiang) are the relative loser; Hong Kong will maintain and even advance its dominance in financial services, trade, transportation (port and airport), IT, hi-tech development, tourism and a service center as a whole; Hong Kong will grow into the world’s third largest international financial center, just right next to New York and London (Tokyo is now the third largest financial center but not an “international” one) Beijing will overtake Shanghai and emerge as China's Financial Center, economic center, IT and Hi-tech industrial base – Beijing would still maintains to be China's No. 1 political and economic center, and will emergence as the No.1 financial and hi-tech center as well; Shanghai benefits greatly from textile production and export, high value-added and large-scale manufacturing, such as car and aerospace industries. Thus, Shanghai will China's manufacturing center. But, apart from those advantages it holds, Shanghai is an overall loser. It is not only because the manufacturing sector is a loser generally in this WTO deal, but also because Shanghai loses its position as a financial and service center to Beijing, and it suffers from lack of 162 transportation, IT and telecommunication and hi-tech development - the most strategic and lucrative sectors for the new millennium. The outlook of WTO deal for Guangdong (GD) is mixed, but GD is a relative winner, comparable to other provinces. Why? Spatial Economic Structure restructuring: Heavy Industry and possible agriculture are winner and manufacture is definitely the loser in this deal - The largest and worst SOEs will have a chance to be bailed out by foreign capital; while agriculture/husbandry also have chance to upgrade their efficiency and productivity to face foreign participation and competition. Northeast – with a heavy industry like the South Korean development model and agriculture base: H share Anshan Iron and Steel Complex and Jilin Chemical, China’s largest Iron and Steel and Chemical producers respectively, have completed the Debt-toequity scheme, and therefore, could maintain as a competable force facing foreign competition. South (HK + Guangdong): Financial/Service, trade, IT and Hi-tech development, and low & high value added manufacturing; West (Sichun + Xinjiang) Agriculture, husbandry and materials and tourism East (Jiangsu, Shanghai Zhejiang) low and high value-added manufactory, machinery, textiles Shanghai has completely sidelined in this surge of financial and service development. No doubt, most foreign and domestic big players will set their headquarters first in Hong Kong and second in Beijing. Now a sudden outburst/emerge and flourishing of Beijing Financial Street and the 10-year bleak of Pu Dong, so called China's No 1 financial center are the best evidence. In Beijing's Financial Street, located both the headquarters of Chinese and foreign banks, the State Stock and Security Commission - China's governing body for company's 163 floating/listing, for stock exchange and for financial regulation, China's first investment bank - China International Capital Corp (responsible for corporate listing, mergers and acquisitions), and China's most largest firm in the management of shares - Everbright Security and many financial institutions are also flourishing in. Beijing is also the home for the most headquarters of Red-chips and H-share companies (China's largest companies listed in HK; they are all subsidies of or affiliations to the State Council and various ministries). Beijing is also the center for the grandfathering for all WTO term implementation and, in fact, all business activities. This is the result of the peculiarity of Chinese economic system - sectoral/ministerial management. Hong Kong dominates in its enriched international, trading and financing information and Beijing national and regulatory. Both are financial center but at different levels - international and national. It seems Shanghai is being “casted out” in this context. Precondition of IT and Hi-tech industrial Development: Excellent telecommunication infrastructure, competitive economic system (free trade and stable currency), rule of law and intellectual property right protection, highly educated people who renowned for scientific innovation and business entrepreneurship. Many Hi-tech directors, including Microsoft, Intel, Yahoo, AT&T etc said Hong Kong has every ingredient for IT and hi-tech development. Hong Kong plus Shenzhen will be China's major IT and hi-tech center. Beijing shall be in the second place. Shanghai again is left behind because of its disadvantageous position it is in and the lack of ingredients for IT and Hi-tech development. Shanghai will also suffer because it shall became less influential in China's foreign trade position as a result of its reduced volume of foreign trade and its lack of natural conditions for container port development. Guangdong now accounts 40% of China foreign trade and Hong Kong's container port and Shenzhen's Yantian port are and will be the largest port in the world and in China. In addition, Shanghai suffers from the unprecedented vicious circle of real estate – the financial development in the past decade, which has severely undermined both the municipal government and the commercial fiscal ability, and the city’s financial vitality (its annual construction volume of office buildings for once was equal to the same volume for ten year in 164 Hong Kong), and its total number of office space constructed is more than HK, in just in a 8 year construction spree. But the vacancy rate in Shanghai is about 70% in office building and 50% in residential buildings – the world largest real estate bubble). Shanghai also suffers from the long-term strict central control, which so far has not relaxed much. To the worst, Shanghai has profoundly suffered from its unique or peculiar “Shanghainese Culture” Guangdong (GD) is one step ahead for capitalism and the WTO entry, with least SOEs and most developed market system – widely practices privatization well ahead the central reform plan. GD occupies 40% total China foreign trade with 4 major categories: machinery, electronics, textile/garments/toys and watch/clocks/small metal tools , with the first two accounts 50% and the last two 50% of the total trade volume. The category of Machinery manufacturing shall suffers after China’s entry to the WTO; the category of electronics neutral or slightly positive (GD electronics is very competitive and export around the world, particular developing countries); the category of textile & garments & toys shall be in a very positive position (as now it suffer from both mainland central quota auctioning system, which means 10% increase in cost, and quota restriction from other countries; the category of watch/clock and Small metal/tools shall perform neutral or slightly positive. Overall, the entry to the WTO helps trade, which in turn helps GD. GD has also benefit substantially from its superiority in overall infrastructure in general and telecommunication structure in particular. Just recently, the central government designated GD as China’s IT and telecom industrial center and Shenzhen as a hi-tech center and high valued added manufacturing center, in which a “China hi-tech fair” held in Shenzhen annually. Hence, in a longer run, GD will be again one step ahead to meet the challenge of WTO and grow into China’s major trade and IT center. Appendix I Ten Market Breakthrough for China with China's WTO Accession Nov 17,1999 - 13:50:44 HKT Accession to the WTO means China will open its various sectors for foreign participation. It is expected that China will soon: 1. Reduce its average tariff on foreign goods to 17% from 22.1%. 165 2. Open the market for agricultural products including wheat, rice and cotton; 3. Ban its dumping of goods to other foreign countries. 4. Open its retail market and allow US companies to have more distribution rights and after-sales services. 5. Open the professional services market covering the legal, accounting and medical sectors. 6. Open its market for foreign films. The number of imported foreign films will be doubled to at least 20 every year. 7. Open its automobile market. Tariffs for automobiles will be reduced yearly. 8. Open its telecommunications industry. Two years after China has entered the WTO, foreign investors can invest in the Internet market. 9. Open its banking industry. Two years after the WTO entry, foreign banks can operate RMB business for mainland enterprises; and 10.Open its securities industry. Foreign financial companies can hold up to a 33% stake in fund management corporations. Spot the Difference - the Deals between April and Nov. versions (see transparency) Appendix II Sino-USA Economic Relation and WTO Trade Impact: 1) China's trade 60% processing trade and 40% ordinary trade; China-US trade US$60 billion with 600million surplus; China is US the 4th trade partner and US is China the 2nd trade partner. China is No2 FDI recipient country next to US and US is the 2nd largest FDI investor next to HK. Mainland China occupies 7% US commodity market, plus Taiwan and HK 12% of the market. Currently about 200 thousand jobs and 18 billion export in US depends on Mainland China trade, according to the US Chamber of Commerce. 2) According to a recent report of ITC (International Trade Commission), the Impact of China's Accession to WTO to both parties: GDP Growth To China 4.1% To USA 0.05% To Hong Kong about 10% Export Growth 12.2% 10% about 10% 166 To Hong Kong Very positive for HK's service export to mainland overall 10% growth at least Import from USA/China 14.3% 7% 3) Large trade deficit of USA to China is not a problem for America, in stead is a advantage for The peculiarity of Sino-US trade: Re-export trade increases value 30% to 40% US$3 out to China > 2 > 3 > 10 back to USA USA MNE trade and large sell to China by this firms FID and MNEs prevailed Reference: Zhao, X.B., S.P. Tong, and J.M. Qiao (1999) “China's WTO Accession, State Enterprise reform, and Spatial Economic Restructuring" paper presented in the Colloquium Series of Geography Department, Univ. of Washington, USA, under review by World Development. Zhao, X.B. (2000) “Spatial restructuring of financial centers in the region of mainland and Hong Kong in the face of China’s WTO accession: a theoretical framework of geography of finance perspective” paper presented in the 29th International Geographical Congress, Seoul, Korea, under review by Economic Geography. 167 Lecture V: Geography of Money and Finance – An Overview and Introduction The Emergence of An Entire New Sub-discipline of Economics and Geography: August Losch (1939 and 1954) The Economics of Location Richardson (1972, 1973) attributed the neglect of money in regional economics to the fact that regional economists borrowed too readily from neoclassical growth theory Gunnar Myrdal (1957) directed attention to the question of regional financial flows in his theory of cumulative, uneven regional development Kerr’s (1965) empirical paper on the geography of finance and the rise and decline of financial centers in Canada was alone Even in most 1980s, the “geography of money” remained an underdeveloped subject. However, since beginning of 1990s, both geographers and regional economists have begun to remedy that neglect. In economics, regional economists focused on topics of regional interest rate, inter-regional fund flow and regional credit availability, while economist made significant advances in theorising the geographical structure and spatial evolution of financial systems. One strand of this is the geography of banking and credit allocation and another is the growth of, and competition between, financial centers. In geography, the recent years in 1990s have seen increasing recognition of the theoretical and empirical importance of finance and money for understanding the forces shaping the economic landscape. The general inquiries of geography of money and finance are: Key role of finance in David Harvey’s Marxist theorisation of the uneven development and crisis-prone tendencies of capitalist space economy; Spatial organisation and operation of particular financial institutions, service and markets, such as banking, venture capitalism, stock markets and pension funds; 168 Economic, political and social dynamics of the world’s major international financial centers, such as London, New York and Tokyo and off-shore centers; Links between regional flows and regional industrial organization and economic development Now, in late 1990s, it seems valid to argue that the “geography of money/finance” is firmly established as a new subdiscipline, or called the “end of the beginning” of the development of the subdiscipline Why Geography ? - Landscapes of Money and Finance Locational Structure of the Financial System Institutional Geography of the Financial System – interlocking locational structure, from the local, regional, national, international to the global Financial System are also Regulatory Space (US dollar-based Bretton Woods System in 1945-73 – currency boards; off-shore centers such as Bahamas, Hong Kong and Singapore) Public Financial Space of the State The four interrelated geographies of the financial system shape the flows of money across space The Background and Dynamics of the Change Three intersecting and mutaully reforcing processes of change, namely deregulation, technological innovation and globalization 169 Deregulation In the year of 1973 saw the collapse and abandonment of the post-war Bretton Woods System of pegged exchange rates, dollar convertibility and capital controls. During the course of the 1980s and 1990s, a tidal wave of deregulation (re-regulation) swept across the globe, beginning in the Unite State and the UK but quickly spreading to other developed and developing countries. A process of “competitive deregulation” in a “race to the bottom” to free money and finance from regulatory structure. Restrictions on capital movements were relaxed or abolished; stock market were deregulated; financial market and product boundaries were dismantled; control on the operation of banks and other financial institutions were removed; and large sections of state-owned activities were sold off /privatized. Technological Innovation A historic process of TI has been transforming money and capital markets – cashless society, electronic or “virtual” money combined with sophisticated telecommunication networks – make every transaction and transfer electronically, instantly, globally, and in massive scale Money has always been mobile and now it is truly hypermobile! Globalization Globalization refers to the increasing integration, hybridization, convergence and stretching of economic relation across space. Rendered by the force of globalization, the world has now increasingly become “homeless”, “seamless”, and “stateless”. It is particularly in financial sector – deregulation, technological innovation and globalization makes the financial world truly “stateless” and “boundaryless”. Thus, it is argued by O’Brien (1992), the resultant effect is the “end of geography” as far as monetary relationship and transactions are concerned. As O’Brien put it: “The end of geography….” See transparency 170 However, opposite direction is also evident in this IT and globalization age – centralization and concentration forces, paralleling the forces of decentralization and dispersal, are equally powerful and sometime override the decentralization force. Nowadays, under deregulation, IT innovation, and globalization, financial market have become increasingly volatile and crisis-prone, and individual financial markets have increasingly become geographically unstable. The Dynamics and Global Changes of Financial Landscape – See Table 1 What we want to learn from the Geography of Money and Finance Focuses of the book Ch2: Stages of Banking development Ch5: The Development of Financial Center – Geography of Finance Ch8: Venture Capital – Financing entrepreneurship Ch9: Corporate Finance Ch12: Pension Fund Capitalism – retreat of the state Ch6&Ch11: Hypermobility of capital and Crisis of Territorial Control Reference: Ch1: Martin R. (eds) (1999), Money and the Space Economy, Wiley, England. Above Ch.s: Martin R. (eds) (1999), Money and the Space Economy, Wiley, England. 171