Thai Competitiveness in US Markets Thai Farmers Research Center September 2000 Table of Contents page 1. Introduction 1 2. Transportation Costs 6 3. Foreign Exchange 10 4. Labor Costs 16 5. Tariffs 23 6. Cost Analysis 30 7. Discussion and Recommendations 36 8. Bibliography 46 9. Tables 48 9.1 US Imports Market, Market Share 48 9.2 Transportation Costs to the United States 50 9.3 Foreign Exchange Rate Changes Relative to the Dollar Since 1993 54 Foreign Exchange Rate Changes Relative to the Baht Since 1993 55 9.5 International Labor Costs by Sector 56 9.6 International Labor Costs as a Percent of Thai Labor Costs 57 9.7 Tariffs for Important Thai Exports 58 9.8 Market Share for Important Thai Exports 60 9.9 Share of World GDP and Trade 67 9.4 danlewis@tfrc.co.th 1 Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : Introduction This paper looks at Thai competitiveness in the US market and attempts to determine why Thailand has had such poor performance. Unlike our neighbors in South East Asia, Thai exports to the US have actually experienced a small drop in market share since 1992. Overall, Asia has been losing ground in terms of US share, a fact that has been masked by the huge increase in US imports overall. However, higher income countries (Japan, and the NICs) have shown most of the decrease in market share, with middle income countries such as Thailand mostly showing small increases, and lower income countries such as China and Vietnam showing stronger growth in market share. Thailand is an exception in our group in that we have been losing market share. Our poorer performance can partly be explained by the composition of our exports, with more emphasis on agricultural and labor intensive goods which compete with lower income countries, and less on electronics and consumer goods. Asian Market Share of US Imports (%) 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 High Income 0.20 0.15 0.10 Higher Income CountriesJapan Singapore Taiwan Hong Kong Australia New Zealand Brunei Medium Income Medium Income CountriesThailand Malaysia Philippines South Korea Fiji 0.05 Low Income 0.00 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Source: USITC Dataweb, Classification follows World Development Report 1999-2000 Low Income CountriesChina Indonesia Vietnam Cambodia Burma Papua New Guinea Although our neighbors in ASEAN have mostly been doing better then us in terms of market share, our real competition for the US market comes from elsewhere, from the combined expansion of Chinese and Mexican imports into the US market. These two countries export many products that compete directly with Thai exports, and that are often cheaper. In an effort to better understand this competition, the core of this paper takes a serious look at the factors that determine the cost of Thai products. By looking carefully at transportation costs, foreign exchange rates, labor costs, and tariffs, we can begin to understand what in particular is influencing Thailand's lack of competitiveness. World GDP The US economy is enormous accounting for 27 percent of world GDP. The United States is by far our largest export market, and deserves special attention. Last year, the US accounted for 21 percent of our exports. Furthermore, the US share in our total exports has been steadily rising, increasing our reliance on that market. Exports to United States 27% ROW 59% Japan 14% Source: World Development Report 1999/2000 2 the United States are now equal in value to about ten percent of the value of Thai GDP. The United States is important in another way. As a long term defender of free trade both in principle and in practice, it is the importer of last resort. It has been instrumental in instituting many of the trade policies in effect today. The average tariff on imports to the US is only 2 percent on a trade weighted basis. Nevertheless some sectors are still heavily protected, and we shall see that trade barriers on textiles and agricultural products to most of the world, have had a significant effect on import patterns particularly in shifting production of labor intensive goods to Latin America. These special trade bloc programs of the US are likely to increase in importance in the short term, further reducing our competitiveness. The importance of the US market and our lackluster performance therein inspires this cost-based analysis. It is only by understanding our competitive strengths and weaknesses that we can ready ourselves for ever increasing competition. As with all our work here at Thai Farmers Research Center, we have tried to include suggestions and opportunities for investors and exporters throughout the paper. The Current Situation ASEAN-4 Market Share of US Imports 2.50% 2.00% Market Share 1992 1.50% Market Share 2000 1.00% 0.50% Ph ilip pi ne s In do ne si a ai la nd Th M al a ys ia 0.00% Source: USITC Dataweb Note: these numbers are in terms of value, and are market shares. Falling market share tells us that imports from Thailand are rising slower than US imports overall. Measuring in value terms means that as the baht devalues, export levels fall. For the sake of comparison, all of these countries currencies have experienced similar levels of devaluation since 1992, except Indonesia, which has devalued more. Relative to our neighbors in ASEAN we are doing poorly, as the only country which has lost market share since 1992. The dominant features of US imports has been the fall in market share of Japan and the ascendance of Mexico and China. 3 Largest Trading Partners - US Imports 25.00% 20.00% Market Share 1992 15.00% 10.00% Market Share 2000 5.00% na hi C M ex ic o pa n Ja C an ad a 0.00% Source: USITC Dataweb The Asian newly industrialized countries (NICs) as a group have been losing market share in the US, though incidentally, their market share in world exports have not fallen. High costs have prompted them to invest in neighboring countries. NIC Share of US Import Market 5.00% 4.00% 3.00% Market Share 1992 2.00% Market Share 2000 1.00% ga po re H on g Ko ng Si n Ko re a Ta iw an 0.00% Source: USITC Dataweb Looking at these charts together we can see several things. Although China and Mexico are doing very well in terms of market share, they have not yet had a big impact on ASEAN countries. Market share has grown at the expense of Japan and the higher income NICs. As those higher income countries have suffered market share losses, they have invested in other source countries, following in the footsteps of Japan. Critically, unlike in the late 1980s and early 1990s, much of that investment has gone to other countries, especially China. Although ASEAN has not yet been strongly affected by the growing dominance of Mexico and China, we predict that those countries will soon have a more direct effect on Thailand. Industries in China and Mexico are growing very rapidly in precisely those exports 4 in which we are doing the best. Therefore it is only a matter of time before they start directly affecting our own market share. Those predictions will also be borne out in a lter section on factor cost analysis. U.S. Imports of Knitted Apparel 3,500 US Million Dollars 3,000 Mexican Dominance in Apparel 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 Thai Growth Slow and Unimpressive 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 Mexico 1996 China 1997 1998 1999 Thailand Source: USITC Dataweb The dominant feature of this graph is the astonishing rise in imports of garments from Mexico, from a very low base in 1992. Mexico has benefited from proximity to the US as well as low tariffs and an absence of quotas due to its participation in NAFTA. Many countries (not just the US) have invested in Mexico because of its special privileges under NAFTA. 5 U.S. Imports of Computer Monitors 1800 US Million Dollars 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 Thailand Losing Competitiveness 400 200 0 1996 1997 Mexico 1998 China 1999 Thailand Source: USITC Dataweb In this graph, both Mexico and China are dominating growth in the import market for computer monitors. China's advantages are low labor costs, and an enormous and dynamic domestic market that makes FDI attractive. Although Thailand is not yet losing much market share, if current trends continue, loss of market share is inevitable. Focus of Study This series will focus on: Macroeconomic Factors - rather than microeconomic factors. The study is broad and it would be difficult to talk about individual conditions for every product. Nevertheless numerous specific examples are given. Foreign Data - rather than Thai data. There are many studies that start from Thai data and work outwards. This study does the opposite. US data is comprehensive and freely available from a variety of sources, many of which are listed in the bibliography. Cost-Based Approach - rather than a strategic or marketing approach. This paper tries to look at the costs involved in producing products rather than the strategies of competing nations, or the marketing of particular products. Chapters Over the coming weeks, the following topics are scheduled to be addressed. Each chapter is a free standing article, which can be found in its entirety on our English language website. Transportation Costs discusses the role transportation costs play in restricting low value goods in favor of high value goods, and looks at actual transportation costs for many Thai products. The effect of rising oil prices on transportation costs is also discussed. 6 Foreign Exchange discusses the gradual depreciation of the currencies of many developing currencies relative to developed countries and the relationship between exchange rate shifts and export performance. Labor Costs discusses wage rates by sector for many countries around the world. Labor costs, although a surprisingly small part of total costs, play a major role in some industries. Thailand's performance in a number of labor intensive industries is discussed. Tariffs discusses the three main strands of US trade law: 1) Global free trade, 2) Free Trade Area for the Americas, and 3) Support for least developed nations, and the tensions that arise between them. Also covered - typical tariff rates for Thai products, the effects of changes in trade status for competitors such as China, Caribbean countries, and Vietnam, and non-tariff barriers. Cost Analysis divides exports into three broad sectors, and gives predictions for each. Then it discusses price sensitivity and the effects different shocks would have on price competitiveness. Finally the different cost factors from this paper are summed together to give a sense of how we compare to China and Mexico. Conclusions and Recommendations summarizes findings from this paper, and suggests some ways to address our competitive situation in the future. Finally, the Appendix of Tables is an extensive collection of data related to Thai trade with the US and comparing Thai costs with those of other countries in the world. 7 Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : Transportation Costs Transport costs have long played a significant role in determining the flow of imports and exports. A few centuries ago, spices from South East Asia were sold for exorbitant prices in Europe, while tea from India was sold for exorbitant prices in China and America. Spanish galleons carried gold from Latin America, and British brigs carried diamonds from South Africa. In short, the only goods transported internationally were small, valuable, and commanded enormous premiums. Since the advent of modern shipping and air freight transportation costs have diminished in importance, but they still play a significant role in the flow of trade for some of Thailand's most important exports, especially those of lower unit value. With transportation costs, the most important relationship is of the value of the good relative to the cost of transporting it. So, for example, a valuable good (e.g. frozen shrimp) may be expensive to ship, but compared to its final value the transportation cost is reasonably low. Other valuable goods (e.g. hard drives, jewelry) are so cheap to transport that their final cost is hardly affected by transport costs. Goods that are of low value must be cheap to transport in order to make it economical to ship them. (Shoes and clothing can be transported because they require neither speed nor special care. Fresh jackfruit and rose apples are not transported.) Transportation costs play the least role with goods that are of high value and easily shipped, and play the largest role with goods that have low value and are expensive to ship. Some Goods are More Economical to Transport Than Others High Transport Cost Low Transport Cost Okay Best High Value Cannot Transport Okay Low Value The cost of transport something will depend on how it is transported. When transporting by water, bulky goods are expensive, since prices often reflect volume rather than weight. For air transport, weight is the critical factor. When shipping by land, both of these factors can be important. The speed with which the good must be delivered (perishability), and any special conditions the good requires (e.g. keep frozen) also have a large effect on the shipping cost. In terms of competitiveness, generally if a good is expensive to ship from one country, it is also expensive to ship from another. Advantages arise only in being closer to the final market. If the good is expensive to transport distance matters a great deal. The following table shows actual transport costs for imports to the United States from a variety of different countries. Values shown are the percent of the value of the good that must be added for transport costs, and are calculated by taking the difference between custom value and C.I.F. value in US trade data, and dividing by the custom value. Custom value is the price paid for the good before shipment to the US. C.I.F. value includes all costs including insurance and freight of bringing the good to the customs port in the US. Therefore transportation costs within the US are not included in these numbers. Transportation costs are averaged for the years 1996-1999. 8 Transportation Costs as a Percent of the Value of the Product of Goods Arriving in the United States From Several Countries, Average for 1996-1999 Hard Shrimp Garments Grain Jewelry Wooden Cars and Plastics Drives incl. Rice Frames Parts HS Code 8471704065 160520130 HS62 HS10 HS71 HS4414 HS87 World 1.0 2.1 4.0 9.2 0.5 4.8 1.8 Thailand 0.5 1.9 5.0 14.2 1.1 5.7 5.3 Mexico 1.0 1.7 0.9 4.2 0.4 1.0 1.1 Canada 0.8 2.2 0.7 6.5 0.1 3.0 0.9 Honduras ---2.2 1.9 ----------------Mainland 1.6 3.5 4.7 16.8 4.3 7.4 8.8 China Philippines 1.0 12.8 5.2 --------7.5 5.6 Malaysia 1.5 ----4.7 --------7.1 9.2 Indonesia ----1.8 5.8 ----1.9 8.1 6.1 Italy --------2.8 8.5 0.8 6.6 3.5 India ----6.6 8.5 8.1 0.5 10.7 7.2 Source: United States National Trade Data Base, Dataweb, World Trade Analyzer In this table, some goods, such as hard drives, shrimp, and jewelry, have low transport costs that do not influence Thai competitiveness for US markets. In other categories, such as plastics, grain (rice), wooden articles and garments, there is a clear transportation cost advantage to being close to the US. There is not a clear distance based relationship here because of 1) economies of scale, 2) efficiency in ports and airports, and 3) the composition of goods within a category may vary. Clearly transportation costs are not prohibitive for any of the above categories, since they are all important Thai exports, but in terms of long term competitiveness Thailand is at a disadvantage. The economic benefit of producing these goods close to the United States might eventually move centers for their production closer to the final market. The location of other goods, such as electronics and jewelry will be influenced by other factors such as tariffs, exchange rates, and conditions in the producing countries. We can look at a more complete list of Thai exports to discover what other goods might have a long term competitive disadvantage. HS39 5.1 11.2 1.9 2.4 ----8.6 ----10.1 11.3 6.5 8.2 9 Thai Products that have Different Levels of Transportation Costs Low Transport Cost Medium Transport Cost High Transport Cost 2-5% 0-2% Hard Drives Monitors Jewelry Rubber Gloves Shrimp Vehicle Wiring Sets Integrated Circuits Fax Machines Ink Jet Printers Footwear VCRs Tuna Photocopy Machines Power Supply Units Very High Transport Cost 5-8% Garments Wooden Frames Keyboards Ceiling Fans Toys Microwaves Rubber Ceramics Plastics Pineapples Cement Rice Speakers Furniture 9% 11% 15% 42% 14% 12% 10% Based on US merchandise trade data, NTDB Some products have already shown a marked tendency to shift towards more local production. For example, garments imported into the United States are increasingly coming from a variety of Latin American countries, rather than Asia, although Asia is still the largest source. Garment exports to the United States from Thailand have increased over the past five years, and they have also increased from China, but the largest increases have been from Latin American countries. US Imports from Several Regions of Articles of Apparel, or Clothing Accessories, Not Knitted or Crocheted (HS62) 1999 1995 Indian Subcontinent 12% ROW 17% Asia 47% Latin America 24% Indian Subcontinent 12% ROW 16% Asia 42% Latin America 30% Based on US merchandise trade data, NTDB The transportation sector is strongly sensitive to energy costs. Because of this, Thai competitiveness in US markets may be decreased if the oil price rises. The following table gives an idea of the effect on transportation costs of a change in oil price. 10 Effect of Changes in Energy Prices on the Cost of Transportation Sector Percent Change in Cost for a 1 percent Change in Oil Price Ocean and Coastal Water Transportation 0.306 Road Freight Transport 0.270 Railways 0.183 Air Transport 0.143 Source: TDRI, "The economic impact of the liberalization of the oil market," May 1998. Based on data from the 1990 Input-Output Table for Thailand, NESDB We can calculate the effect the recent rise in oil prices might have on Thai competitiveness via transport costs. The average price of oil (Brent Crude) from 1996 to 1999 was $17.70 dollars a barrel. In the first 10 months of this year, the average price was $28.80, an increase of 63 percent. Ocean transport costs should therefore rise by .63 * .306 = .193 or 19.3 percent. Then if transport costs are 10 percent of the value of the product, the increase in the final cost of the product, due only to transport costs, would be .10 * .193 = .0193, or 1.93 percent of the price of the good. Unfortunately, goods that already have high transport costs will show more of an effect than those with low transport costs. Effect of Higher Oil Prices on Thai competitiveness Through Transport Costs Product Average Transport Cost 1996-1999 Estimated Transport Cost This Year (percent added to Thai export price) (percent added to Thai export price) Ceramics 9 10.7 Plastics 11 13.1 Garments 5 6.0 Shrimp 1.9 2.3 Cement 42 50.1 Electronics 1.9 2.1 Source: Thai Farmers Research Center estimates. Compared to other neighboring countries, such as China, Malaysia, and Indonesia, Thailand seems to have slightly lower transport costs, category by category. Therefore higher energy costs might improve our competitiveness vis-à-vis our closest neighbors, but would surely hurt our competitiveness vis-à-vis the majority of nations that are closer to the United States. In summary, although transport costs do not matter as much as they once did, nevertheless Thailand's distance from the United States still acts to reduce the competitiveness of many low value, high volume goods. In particular, there is the potential for transportation costs to preclude long term competitiveness in plastics, in ceramics, in wooden products, in basic agricultural commodities, and in garments. Some other goods are not significantly affected by transport costs, such as high value computer parts, shrimp, and jewelry. To reduce the effect of transport costs on competitiveness, Thailand should continue to increase the value-added in its exports. Transport costs are only important as a percentage of the value of a product, and so they diminish in importance as the good becomes more expensive. 11 Chapter Three Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : Foreign Exchange Of all the factors that affect Thailand's exports to America, the exchange rate has the largest effect on competitiveness. The devaluation in the baht over the last several years has made Thai goods 40 percent cheaper for Americans (excluding flow-through of goods that must be first imported into Thailand). In comparison, tariffs and transportation costs may give only a few percent price advantage. Our exchange rate relative to our competitors therefore plays a very large role in our international competitiveness. The exchange rate can be viewed as the price of all our country's goods together. If we take the analogy of Thailand as a business, if we charge a lower price (weaker exchange rate), then more people will buy our goods. However, we will receive less money - less to live on, less to invest in the future, and less to buy the inputs that we need. Also like a business, if we lower our prices/exchange rate there will be great pressure on our competitors (once they see the effect on their sales in terms of trade figures) to lower their prices/exchange rate as well, so that competitive devaluations are likely. The exchange rate is a price that affects all of the country's exports and imports. Each good also has its own price. Some goods need to have reduced prices, others are competitive at existing price levels. Why then doesn't the price of each of the individual goods change rather than the overall price? One reason is that prices of both goods and factors of production tend to be sticky. A firm does not wish to decrease the price of the goods it sells. Even more so, it cannot reduce the wages of the people it employs. The exchange rate adjusts if other factors cannot. Often the effect of a devaluation is to reduce the value of Thai labor relative to imported goods, so that for the Thai producer the labor component of locally produced goods becomes cheaper relative to the good component. Overseas, Thai goods are cheaper because in terms of dollars the labor component has become cheaper. The price that can be charged for Thai goods in the international market depends on what other competitors are charging. Therefore it is important to know about changes in the level of our exchange rate relative to that of other countries. If the productivity and price levels of our competitors are similar to ours ( a big assumption) then our prices will depend on our relative exchange rates. We compare exchange rates both to the US dollar, and to the Thai baht. Both are important. Comparing to the US dollar tells us about the price of imports relative to locally made goods in the US market. Also, if imports are getting cheaper, probably more of that kind of good will be demanded. Comparing to the Thai baht tells us how our prices are relative to our competitors. Many goods will be too expensive to produce in the US so in that case our prices relative to our competitors is the most important. The period of comparison is 1993 to 1999, which covers the period just before the most recent Chinese devaluation, to the present. Because we are looking only at competitiveness in the US market we need only look at exchange rates relative to the US dollar, not to other measures such as the real or nominal effective exchange rate. 12 The Change in Market Share of US General Imports and the Change in Exchange Rates Relative to the Thai Baht and US Dollar over the Six Years from 1993 to 1999. Country Canada Japan Mexico China Germany United Kingdom Taiwan Korea France Italy Malaysia Singapore Thailand Philippines Brazil Venezuela Ireland Hong Kong Israel Switzerland Indonesia Belgium India Netherlands Market Share Rank 1999 Change in Market Share 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 Constant Rapid Decline Strong Growth Strong Growth Constant Constant Decline Constant Constant Constant Growth Decline Constant Strong Growth Decline Decline Strong Growth Rapid Decline Growth Constant Constant Constant Growth Decline Change in Exchange Rate Change in Exchange Rate RELATIVE TO THE THAI BAHT RELATIVE TO THE US DOLLAR Appreciation Rapid Appreciation Rapid Depreciation Neutral Rapid Appreciation Rapid Appreciation Appreciation Neutral Rapid Appreciation Appreciation Neutral Rapid Appreciation Neutral Neutral Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Rapid Appreciation Rapid Appreciation NA Rapid Appreciation Rapid Depreciation Rapid Appreciation Neutral Rapid Appreciation Depreciation Neutral Rapid Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Neutral Neutral Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Neutral Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Neutral Rapid Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Rapid Depreciation Neutral Neutral NA Neutral Rapid Depreciation Neutral Depreciation Depreciation Based on Information from the US Department of Commerce as reported in USITC Dataweb, Exchange Rates from US Federal Reserve Bank, and CEIC. Notes: For Market Share and Exchange Rates - over a six year period, Strong Decline/Rapid Depreciation = 30% or More; Decline/Depreciation = 10 to 30%, Constant/Neutral = -10 to 10%; Growth/Appreciation = 10 to 30%; Rapid Growth/Rapid Appreciation = 30% or More. This table shows us a number of interesting things. 1) The Thai baht is quite cheap now relative to many other currencies, and should not face strong devaluation pressures. 2) The US dollar is appreciating in value against many currencies. Actually, it is the more developed countries' currencies which are appreciating versus the less developed countries, as currencies of the more economically advanced countries of Asia seem to be moving together with the US dollar. 3) The more economically advanced countries of East Asia are doing poorly in terms of market share, even if their absolute level of exports might be rising. If this holds out in their other export markets, it may put downward pressure on their exchange rates. 4) The strong growth in the region comes from China because of many different kinds of goods (not especially garments though), and from the Philippines and Malaysia, who are apparently exporting electronics that were previously provided by the East Asian countries. 13 5) There is a clear relationship between exchange rates and export success. Generally if a country's currency is depreciating relative to the Thai baht, it has a good chance of increasing or at least maintaining market share; whereas if a country's currency appreciates versus the Thai Baht, it has a good chance of losing, or at least just maintaining market share. 6) The per unit value of US imports is probably falling as the US dollar appreciates versus many other currencies. 7) If a currency is depreciating, then more exports in terms of volume need to be shipped just to maintain the same level of exports. Therefore, countries in which strong growth in market share is matched by rapid depreciation have exceptionally high levels of export growth in volume terms. (e.g. Mexico) Countries with appreciating currencies may show export growth in value terms, when volume is constant, perhaps because their exports are not price sensitive. How is the exchange rate determined? How much can we control our exchange rate? How much do we want to control it? The determination of the exchange rate is complicated and is strongly affected by a number of factors: Interest Rates Interest rates affect the exchange rate through capital flows. As the interest rate in Thailand increases relative to the interest rate in other countries, it means that investors can earn more money in interest if they have their money in Thailand. Having money in Thailand means having Thai baht. As people buy Thai baht they increase demand for it and increase its value. Interest rates also have a large effect on domestic GDP. Most investment is financed with debt. If the interest rate is low, it encourages people to invest. Therefore policies to expand the economy through investment often weaken the exchange rate as people move money overseas to get higher returns on capital. Inflation and Price Levels Economic theory predicts that arbitrage will act to make price levels the same in all countries. The law of one price states that absent of transportation costs and barriers to entry, a good in one country should have the same price as in another. A looser version of this rule is absolute price parity. The price level in one country will be the same in every country, even if not for every good. The weakest form, relative price parity, is which is what is used in practice. Because of differences in labor productivity or the labor capital ratio, prices may be different from one country to another. However the relative differences will be maintained over time unless inflation rates are different. Any differences in inflation rates will be reflected in exchange rates. Therefore countries with high inflation rates will have depreciating exchange rates. Future Expectations The value of a currency reflects not only current conditions, but also expectations about the future. Current demand for currency is a result of the balance of payments. If the number of people wanting to buy baht is more than the number of people wanting to sell baht, then the currency will appreciate. If it is perceived that in the future, fewer people will want to buy baht, that will be factored into the current price of the baht. Since there is a direct link between the economic health of the country, and the number of people who want to buy the baht, the exchange rate is tied to expectations of Thailand's future prospects. 14 Capital Flows Capital flows could be influenced by number of factors including portfolio investment based on the health of the stock market, foreign direct investment to take advantage of opportunities or because of low valuations, or a number of other factors including debt payments to the IMF, payment of private foreign debt, etc. Currency as an Asset Currency is itself an asset, and one that can pay very high returns if you can predict what direction an exchange rate will move. The interest per day on 1 million baht is about 100 baht if kept in the bank. The profit on foreign exchange using 1 million baht is 250 baht for each satang move in the exchange rate. Enterprises with access to low spreads, and holding a lot of cash may try to benefit from this market, as evidenced by the enormous amount of currency that trades hands each day. All of these factors contribute to making it very difficult to have an active foreign exchange policy. However, even if we could control the exchange rate, it would probably not be wise to do so. Why are the exchange rates of developing countries falling relative to developed countries? The exchange rate of developing countries may be falling because of competition in the production of commodities and manufactured goods. As more countries develop stable macroeconomic policies and use export led growth strategies, there is more competition for the export markets. A strategy that worked well for some countries has come of age, and now is less effective when used by all. There is also more competition for FDI. Manufactured goods are becoming commodities that can be produced in many locations, and that do not have a lot of profit margin. Low quality manufactured goods are to developing countries like agricultural commodities were in the 1960s. There has been enormous excitement about opening the Chinese domestic market, but the average Chinese does not have the income to buy many manufactured goods, and the Chinese government does not want the domestic market dominated by foreigners. In order to get an eventual foothold in this market, many international companies have built exportoriented plants in China to eventually supply local demand. Short-term profitability has not always been the criteria for investment. Asian countries have practiced an export strategy based on maximizing market share rather than profit, which is useful for opening up markets, but is not sustainable in the long run. The recent recession may have a silver lining in that it cut back investment to Asia, which will eventually make the surviving companies more profitable. Currencies are strongly linked to each other, especially within a region. The Thai baht moves closely in orchestration with other regional currencies. The following table shows correlations between the baht and some other currencies since 1997. 15 Correlation Coefficients Between the Thai Baht and Other Currencies for the Period 1997 to June 2000 Currency Correlation 1997-2000 ASIA 1.00 Thailand 0.90 Malaysia 0.88 Korea 0.85 Philippines 0.81 Taiwan 0.80 Singapore 0.72 Indonesia 0.19 Japan 0.03 Hong Kong -0.80 China SOUTH ASIA 0.53 India 0.48 Bangladesh 0.44 Pakistan 0.38 Sri Lanka EUROPE 0.39 Germany 0.34 Turkey 0.16 United Kingdom SOUTH AMERICA 0.36 Mexico 0.19 Brazil Based on Monthly Data From CEIC Several interesting results can be seen in this table. Clearly Thailand's currency is closely linked with the currency of other countries in the region. The exception is China, whose currency has slowly been appreciating over the period, probably due to capital inflows, and Hong Kong, which has a currency which is essentially pegged to the US dollar, therefore showing little variability. Currencies from South Asia are also linked to the Thai baht, but to a lesser degree than East and Southeast Asian currencies. European and South American Currencies also have positive correlations with the Thai baht. Correlations are positive with almost all countries, which is to be expected since one half of the variation should be due to changes in the US market which should affect most countries in the same way. (i.e. if the US increases interest rates it should cause the US dollar to appreciate against almost all currencies.) Why is geography so important with exchange rates? Why should neighboring countries have similar foreign exchange trends? There are a number of similarities between neighboring countries that can encourage this, such as similar political and institutional structures. Trade flows between the countries can mean that as one does well, so does its neighbors. Significant influences in the region, such as Japan in Asia, or a political conflict can have an effect on all its neighbors. Finally the perceptions of foreigners who aggregate the world in certain ways, may play a role in determining exchange rates as well. 16 Suggestions for Thai Exporters The goods Thailand exports are losing value versus the US dollar. The best remedy for this is not just increasing the value added of goods, but also to increase the uniqueness of Thai goods. We need to look for goods that others are not exporting, and we need to build brands. European goods still do well because they rely on goods that are hard to duplicate antiques, wines and cheeses, and branded fashions. Without brands we cannot build market power. Thai competitiveness does not necessarily have to be built upon high technology, but it does need to be based on uniqueness, be it based on brand, unique products, or provided services. Furthermore, although it is clear that depreciating currencies increases our competitiveness, but just as a shop that decreases prices must expect others to do so, we also have to expect that competitive devaluations will follow. It also may decrease our income to the point where we cannot expand or compete. It is important to realize that developing nations are in this together, and as a group of exporters we should try to maintain exchange rates just as we do with specific commodities, and minimize the effect of competitive devaluations that have occurred in the past, even if it means fewer exports for each of us. This needs to be kept in mind when considering the seemingly all important export growth figures. Recent history of competitive devaluations: Year Event 1994 China devaluation 1995 Mexico/Latin American devaluation 1997/1998 Asian devaluation. Effect of Flexible versus Fixed Currencies There is no evidence to suggest that developing countries with flexible exchange rates have depreciated any less than those with fixed exchange rates. Countries that have flexible exchange rates have depreciated just as much as ones that didn't, but since the devaluation occurred over a number of years, it was not so obvious. For instance, all the South Asian currencies have depreciated as much as the baht over the past 6 years, but more gradually. 17 Chapter Four Labor Costs Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : The price of labor is a direct measure of the wellbeing of the Thai people. When the World Bank wants to compare the level of development between countries, it looks at per capita income - so that the higher wages are, the better off we are. However, wage rates can also be too high to make us competitive internationally. This can lead to a long term decline in our prosperity. One of the biggest factors determining our wage competitiveness in the international market is the exchange rate. The wage rate for traded goods essentially falls and rises with the exchange rate. Domestic factors are also very important in that wage rates are mostly set by supply and demand in the domestic market. Supply and demand are in turn influenced by the domestic demand for goods, the supply and demand of the imports and exports of the country, demographics, and the productivity of workers in the country. When measuring wages we can either consider the wages or earnings that the worker receives (including or not bonuses and fringe benefits), or we can consider the whole cost to the firm of hiring the worker. Clearly the latter is preferable for comparing competitiveness between nations, but obtaining data is difficult because that is not the way data is usually collected. In Thailand, non-wage costs average 30-50 percent of the wage costs, and can range from very low (<10 percent) for construction workers, to very high (>200 percent) for some tourism facilities. The productivity of labor is also very important. In the end, it is the amount of product that can be produced for a certain total labor cost that is important, not how many laborers are employed. If it takes 100 workers to cook a pizza, we don't care how cheap each one is to hire. One well paid worker would be better. In practice productivity is easy to measure, but difficult to interpret and compare. A simple measure of productivity is to divide output in an industry by the labor cost. This, however, does not account for 1) how much capital is used or 2) if business cycles are keeping workers busier or less busy then usual. Although these factors can be taken into account, differences in capital quality and different ways of measurement make international comparisons somewhat suspect. Productivity in Thailand is increasing, but slowly. Thailand has traditionally been a popular location for foreign investment, in part because of its cheap labor supply. Leading up to the economic crisis of 1997, the conventional wisdom was that wage rates had risen to the extent that Thailand was no longer competitive as a location for labor intensive production. After the crisis and devaluation, despite a 35-40 percent drop in the effective price of labor, it is still believed that labor costs are too high to compete in labor intensive industries such as apparel, wood working, footwear, textiles, leather and rubber goods. Is there truth in this assessment? To help look at this issue, we will look at manufacturing wages relative to our largest competitors for US markets. 18 Manufacturing Wage in Some Selected Countries as a Percent of the Thai Manufacturing Wage Bangladesh 25 Brazil 406 300 Canada 1139 919 54 22 1237 483 146 265 104 747 796 100 478 293 1484 33 250 Bangladesh India 200 Percent HongKong India Indonesia Italy Korea Malaysia Mexico Philippines Singapore Spain Thailand Taiwan Turkey USA China 150 100 Indonesia Malaysia Mexico Philippines Thailand 50 China 0 Source: TFRC database. Derived from UNIDO, ILO, CEIC, and US Fed Data. Note: All countries, Wages in US dollars in 1998 There is quite a range of wage rates, with some countries much cheaper than us, and some much more expensive. Even the high wage countries are doing well in the world, so we should not be overly discouraged. Rather we need to think of the things that the high wage countries produce that we can produce as well. This is NOT just about technology - many of the exports of these countries are luxury goods, or are scarce for some reason. Some industries use more labor than others. Clearly an industry that uses a lot of labor (labor intensive) will be more sensitive to labor costs than one that does not (capital intensive). Even for labor intensive industries, labor costs are not typically a large part of the total costs. In labor intensive industries, labor costs are rarely more than 20 percent of total costs, while the overall percent is 7.2 as the following table shows. 19 Percentage of Labour Cost in Total Cost by Industry, 1998 ISIC Code Rev.3 361 322 362 332 314 331 323 324 321 356 355 311 354 351 353 300 Sector LABOR INTENSIVE Ceramics Wearing apparel, except footwear Glass products Wooden Furniture Tobacco Wood products, except furniture Leather products Footwear, except rubber or plastic MIDRANGE Textiles Plastic products Rubber products Food products CAPITAL INTENSIVE Misc. petroleum and coal products Industrial chemicals Petroleum refineries TOTAL MANUFACTURING Percent 28.8 18.2 17.0 15.2 14.9 14.7 13.4 13.2 10.4 10.4 7.5 5.6 3.4 2.3 0.5 7.2 Source: Employment Survey Report, Ministry of Labour and Social Welfare 1998 One effect of the low share of labor costs in total costs is that wage rate advantages can be dwarfed compared to some other factors. For example, in the apparel industry, wages in China are 27 percent of our wages. Their total costs are therefore .27*.182 + 1*(1-.182) = .867, or 86.7 percent of our costs, a significant cost advantage. The same calculation for food products in which labor is only 5.6 percent of total costs and Chinese wages are 34 percent of our wages, gives us .34*.056 + 1*(1-.056) = .958, or 96.3 percent of our costs, which is not nearly so threatening This cost advantage could be compensated by higher productivity, lower raw material costs, lower transportation costs, etc. Even the apparel cost advantage could be overcome by a 15 percent further depreciation of the exchange rate which given all domestic products, would make our prices cheaper. Unfortunately, this would likely cause China to depreciate in turn, meaning lower income for all of us, and no change in competitive advantage! Our wage rates are considerably cheaper than wage rates in the United States, so that it is unlikely that we will be competing directly with domestic production. To give a sense of comparison, the average manufacturing wage in the US is 14.84 times greater than in Thailand. Even for the sectors where wage rates are most similar, (apparel: 6.81 times, printing: 7.26 times) US rates are still significantly higher. Now that we have a sense of general wage levels, it is helpful to see how wages vary in some important export markets. The following table gives the local wage in dollars, the market share, and the growth rate for several labor intensive industries that are important export industries to the United States. 20 US Imports of Electrical and Non-Electrical Equipment 84 Nuclear Reactors, Boilers, Machinery Total Market Size 165,575 Million US$ Thai Annual Wage 2,874 1998 US Dollars Country Wage98 MS99 AGR9699 Japan 1065 19.2% -8% Canada 1253 10.3% -1% Mexico 172 8.6% 14% Germany NA 7.5% -3% China (Taiwan) 446 7.2% -1% Singapore 678 7.0% -7% China 36 6.1% 20% United Kingdom 1036 5.6% 4% Malaysia 137 4.6% 13% Korea, Republic Of 417 4.2% 4% France NA 3.1% 3% Italy 1174 2.6% -2% Thailand 100 1.8% 0% Philippines 106 1.5% 59% Ireland NA 1.3% 23% 85 Electrical Machinery And Equipment Total Market Size 145,901 Million US$ Thai Annual Wage 2,874 1998 US Dollars Country Wage98 MS99 AGR9699 Mexico 172 19.8% 8% Japan 1065 18.1% -8% China 36 10.3% 11% Canada 1253 7.9% 7% Korea, Republic Of 417 7.8% -3% Malaysia 137 6.5% -7% China (Taiwan) 446 6.4% 2% Philippines 106 3.9% 11% Germany NA 2.7% -1% Thailand 100 2.3% 0% Singapore 678 2.2% -12% United Kingdom 1036 2.0% -1% Hong Kong 869 1.4% -6% France NA 1.3% -2% Indonesia 20 1.0% 6% Source: TFRC database. Derived from UNIDO, ILO, CEIC, and US Fed Data. Notes: Wage98 is the wage as a percent of the Thai wage in the same industry in 1998, MS99 is the market share of US imports in 1999, and AGR9699 is the average annual growth rate during the 1996-1999 period. These two categories include an eclectic mix of machinery, computers, and circuits. Important Thai exports included in these categories are: HS84: Hard Drives, Monitors, Printers, Keyboards HS85: IC Circuits, Vehicle Wiring, Fax Machines, Power Supplies, Telephones, VCRs, TVs Some clear trends are evident in these tables. Countries with wage rates much higher than Thailand's wages (>400 percent), are generally losing market share, while others (<400 percent) generally are not. The reasons for increases and decreases in market share are complicated, include many factors besides price, but a general trend away from very high cost producers is evident. Most of these goods are not produced by countries with cheaper labor costs than Thailand, so in terms of wages we should be competitive. The size of both of these markets are growing quickly, so Thailand's 0% change is not all bad news. We are not competing well, however, if we compare ourselves with Malaysia, the Philippines ,and China. The first two of these have similar wage structures to our own. 21 US Imports of Apparel and Footwear 61 Articles Of Apparel, Knitted Total Market Size 23,712 Million US$ Thai Annual Wage 2,835 1998 US Dollars Country Wage98 MS99 AGR9599 Mexico 168 14.0% 19% Hong Kong 660 9.2% -10% China 27 8.5% -4% Honduras NA 6.2% 19% China (Taiwan) 295 4.9% -11% Korea, Republic Of 309 4.2% -1% El Salvador NA 3.9% 18% Dominican Republic NA 3.8% 3% Thailand 100 3.4% 0% Canada 552 3.4% 11% Philippines 67 3.0% -6% Macao NA 2.7% -4% Guatemala NA 2.2% 21% Turkey 151 2.2% -5% 64 Footwear Total Market Size Thai Annual Wage Country China Italy Brazil Indonesia Mexico Spain Thailand United Kingdom Dominican Republic Korea, Republic Of Vietnam China (Taiwan) India Portugal 14,068 Million US$ 1,787 1998 US Dollars Wage98 MS99 AGR9699 40 60.0% 6% 1151 8.5% 0% 406 6.8% -7% 23 5.3% -8% 306 2.5% 7% 605 2.3% -6% 100 2.3% -9% 1238 1.7% 16% NA 1.7% -4% 486 1.2% -27% NA 1.0% 299% 510 0.8% -28% 47 0.8% -1% NA 0.7% 3% Source: TFRC database. Derived from UNIDO, ILO, CEIC, and US Fed Data. Notes: Wage98 is the wage as a percent of the Thai wage in the same industry in 1998, MS99 is the market share of US imports in 1999, and AGR9599 is the average annual growth rate during the 1995-1999 period. Imports of apparel are increasingly coming from Latin America. Unfortunately it was not possible to calculate wage rates for all of the Latin countries, but based on World Development Report statistics they should not be too different from our wages. Thailand is again maintaining its share of a growing market, but cannot match the enormous growth in the Latin American countries. Generally Asian countries are not doing well in apparel. The foot wear market is increasingly dominated by China with 60 percent of the market, and an average growth rate of 6 percent. Italy is not losing market share to China even though it's wages are almost 30 times the Chinese wage. This shows the strength that brands can have. In both of these markets, but especially footwear, a large share of production is by countries with cheaper wages than us, suggesting that we may not be very wage competitive. US Imports of Leather Goods and Furniture 42 Articles Of Leather Total Market Size 6,038 Million US$ Thai Annual Wage 1,522 1998 US Dollars Country Wage98 MS99 AGR9699 China 47 49.8% 1% Italy 1681 6.3% -3% Thailand 100 5.8% 6% Philippines 121 4.9% 6% Indonesia 21 4.0% 9% Korea, Republic Of 715 4.0% -12% Mexico 265 3.9% 8% India 56 3.3% -1% China (Taiwan) 733 2.8% -16% France NA 2.5% -2% Sri Lanka NA 1.8% 14% Hong Kong 1659 1.4% -2% 94 Furniture; Bedding, Cushions Total Market Size 20,378 Million US$ Thai Annual Wage 1,635 1998 US Dollars Country Wage98 MS99 AGR9599 China 36 27.2% 10% Canada 1318 23.2% -1% Mexico 238 16.4% 6% China (Taiwan) 650 6.3% -17% Italy 1580 5.7% -3% Malaysia 167 2.4% -7% Indonesia 21 2.2% 0% United Kingdom 1601 1.8% 4% Germany NA 1.6% -3% Philippines 91 1.5% -7% Thailand 100 1.4% -7% Japan 1085 1.1% -12% Source: TFRC database. Derived from UNIDO, ILO, CEIC, and US Fed Data. Notes: Wage98 is the wage as a percent of the Thai wage in the same industry in 1998, MS99 is the market share of US imports in 1999, and AGR9599 is the average annual growth rate during the 1995-1999 period. 22 Leather goods are another industry that China dominates, but Thailand is also doing well. A very large proportion of leather goods are produced by countries with wages cheaper than us. In the furniture market, the market is dominated by several big players, who seem to be squeezing other players out. Lower wages do not afford protection from this. General Comments on Charts Mexico and China are increasingly dominating the US import market, as evidenced by their presence at the top of almost every list. Wage and price competitiveness may be enough to compete successfully in a business, but may not be enough to attract FDI. FDI will likely be drawn to the very best locations. For example, our apparel prices may not be too high in the world market, but if we want to build that industry, we have to do it ourselves. Thailand seems to be at a point in which it is cheap for the production of higher value manufacturing goods, but does not have sufficient facilities to do so, and is still competitive in labor intensive goods, but is not very interesting to foreign investors. There is some evidence that once an industry is located at one location it does not easily move. Industries that are growing quickly such as electronics suffer when there are insufficient funds for investment. for electronics, Thailand's problems may depend more on a lack of capital to invest than any inherent lack of competitiveness. As with most of the Asian countries, Thailand has done an inadequate job of building brands and unique products. Is the wage policy Thailand has adopted appropriate? One very interesting ILO study by a team of researchers that included Acharn Lae Dilokvidharat from Chula and Chanin Mephokee from Thammasat came to the following conclusions: 1) The Thai wage rate is not too high to be competitive - rather it was Thailand's policy of fixing the baht to a basket of currencies, primarily the dollar, that made our wages uncompetitive. Since the devaluation, wages have effectively dropped 35-40 percent. 2) Real minimum wages grew an average of 4.1% in the 1990-1996 period. 3) Manufacturing productivity growth in Thailand did not keep up with real wage increases in the 1990s. Productivity was increasing, but not as quickly as wages. Manufacturing productivity grew at 3.1% during the 1990-1996 period. (Agricultural productivity grew much faster.) 4) Minimum wage legislation is very important in Thailand because of the lack of collective bargaining and the weakness of unions. There is currently no other effective way to set wage rates. 23 5) Minimum wages have had a stronger effect at the bottom of the wage scale, so that many who were previously paid poorly, often those with the fewest skills, had their salaries increased, but the wage increases did not move up the pay scale. Those who were well paid had significantly smaller pay raises. This has had the effect of compressing the wage scale, and leaving many people earning near the minimum wage. 6) The compression in the wage scale likely has had an adverse effect on productivity, as there is little incentive to do well when there is no differentiation by training, experience or seniority. Bonuses and performance rewards do function in that capacity, but are estimated to be only about 10 percent of total pay, and are not entirely discretionary. 7) There is insufficient training by companies. It is believed that after training occurs, the employees will leave for another job. However, the reason they do this is because they now have higher skills and are worth more. Therefore they should be paid better after training, in keeping with their benefit to the company, and to keep from moving. 8) Minimum wages in the more rural provinces, are still too high. The rural wage is about 80% of the Bangkok wage. Compliance is low. Low wages do not act as a primary motive for firms to move to rural areas. In other studies: Thai workers work hard. According to a study by the Japan Federation of Employers' Associations, Thai workers work more hours and more days than in any other of the ASEAN countries. In the total East and South Asian area, only workers in some of the countries of the Indian subcontinent work more than Thais. Training in the workplace is very important A number of studies called for an increase in training in the workplace as a means to increase productivity. Training in general skills is the most useful for employees, training in specific work related skills are most useful for employers. There are clear productivity gains from training, and clear indications that Thai employees are not well trained. The government already offers some incentive in the form of tax breaks on training related expenses. 24 Chapter Five Tariffs Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : The United States is often said to be the importer of last resort, even though imports, at 12 percent of GDP, are relatively small. Out of the twenty largest economies, only four (India, Japan, Argentina, and Brazil) have smaller shares of imports to GDP. The American economy is then fairly self sufficient. The reason that America is the exporter of last resort is because it is so big; at 27 percent of World GDP it dwarfs all other possible importers. Share of World GDP and World Trade in 1998 for Several Countries Country GDP (% of World Total) Trade (% of World Total) Ratio United States 27.4 15.1 = 0.55 Imports 17.6, Exports 12.6 Japan 14.2 6.2 0.44 Germany 7.4 9.3 1.27 France 5.1 5.5 1.09 United Kingdom 4.4 5.5 1.25 China 3.2 3.0 0.93 India 1.5 0.7 0.48 Indonesia 0.5 0.7 1.48 Thailand 0.5 0.9 1.90 Malaysia 0.3 1.2 4.43 Philippines 0.3 0.6 2.08 Source: Based on data from World Development Report 1999/2000 Note: Trade refers to the sum of merchandise imports and exports. Ratio refers to Trade Column/GDP Column The US is thought to be a free trade haven because of its strong defense of free trade policies, its low tariff rates (about 2 percent weighted by actual imports, and its maintenance of openness even in the face of large trade deficits with the rest of the world. The average tariff rate hides some high tariffs and quota systems, with the highest tariffs applied to agricultural goods and textiles and apparel. When tariffs are high they matter more since the advantages for countries in free trade zones are much greater. Trade Policy The United States is involved in most major international trade forums. In terms of objectives, US trade policy has three strands: 1) to promote free trade in the world at large, 2) to promote an Americas free trade zone, and 3) to promote trade with the poorest countries. All of these are actively pursued through separate trade agreements. Also the US uses trade extensively as a foreign policy tool, both as an incentive to its allies, and as a punishment to its enemies. Normal Trade Relations 25 Almost all countries in the world currently enjoy normal trade relations with the United States. A few (e.g. China, Mongolia, Kyzstirstan) must have normal trade relations renewed annually. Only five countries do not have normal trade relations with the US: Vietnam, Laos, Afghanistan, North Korea, and Cuba. A few other countries face separate trade embargoes (Cuba, Iran, Iraq, Libya, North Korea, Sudan, and Syria) under the International Emergency Economic Powers Act. Tariffs for countries that do not have normal trading relations, at about 40 percent, are almost high enough to be prohibitive. Global Free Trade or Americas Free Trade? The US pursues both objectives, but eventually we feel that global free trade will win. As a strong proponent of the WTO, the US has reduced tariffs across the board. In the few sectors in which the US still has high tariffs, it has already reduced them for some of its neighbors to the south. As these low cost countries capture market share from domestic producers, the US will no longer gain any advantage in restricting entry for other countries. This implies a short term advantage for Latin American countries and long term free trade. However, The Location of US Investment is Important. Trade law is designed to protect not only domestic producers but also national producers operating abroad. (Think of canned pineapple antidumping laws.) If there were enough investment by US companies in the Americas, it might provide the incentive to maintain existing barriers for producers outside the trade group. Actually, US foreign direct investment in Latin America is only about 18 percent of US FDI, and has been growing slower than US FDI overall. US Foreign Direct Investment 1994-1999 Latin America 17.9% Hong Kong 2.0% Africa 1.7% China 1.1% Indonesia 1.0% South Korea 0.8% Middle East 1.0% Thailand 0.6% Japan 2.5% Malaysia 0.5% Asia Pacific 15.4% Other 1.0% Europe 55.4% Canada 8.6% Singapore 2.6% Australia 3.2% Source: US BEA Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) TFRC feels that Thailand will continue to receive GSP privileges, but these will diminish in importance. The GSP system in America has expired and been reinstated a number of times, and as a means of supporting the poorest nations, will likely continue to be a mainstay of American trade policy. After the devaluation, Thailand's per capita income dropped precipitously, decreasing the chance that it will be dropped from GSP privileges. However, the GSP will probably diminish in importance as the US focuses on alternative 26 programs that help the Least-Developed countries. These include a special classification within the GSP for Least-Developed countries, and a new program passed last year for the support of sub-Saharan nations. In a review of Thailand's progress under the WTO, it was noted that general GATT standards were preferred to GSP benefits since GSP benefits could be withdrawn at any time. GSP benefits can be and often are withdrawn for individual products which are successful. They can be withdrawn if: 1) a country supplies more than fifty percent of US imports of a certain product 2) the level of imports of a product exceeds a specific dollar amount indexed to the nominal growth of US GDP since 1984. 3) if it is determined that importation is harmful to domestic industry. In practice, many of Thailand's top exports that would otherwise be eligible for GSP benefits have had their benefits revoked. Top Thai Exports Subject to GSP Benefits in the US Commodity Status Tariff Rate Gold or Platinum Jewelry Okay 5 percent Wiring Sets for Vehicles Revoked 5 percent Photocopy Machines Revoked 3.7 percent Silver Jewelry Revoked 5 percent Wooden Painting Frames Okay 3.9 percent Ceiling Fans Okay 3.9 percent Source: National Trade Data Base, Harmonized Trade Schedule of the US (2000) It should be noted that China is not currently eligible for GSP benefits. Entry into the WTO will not automatically give them benefits. Policy under Bush or Gore Both George W. Bush and Al Gore are strong supporters of free trade. In general Asians are more wary of the Democratic Party because of its links to labor, the environmentalist movement, and its interventionist stance on human rights. However, Al Gore is thought to have a great deal more experience in foreign relations than George W. Bush. Both candidates speak Spanish and have ties to Latin America which might bias them towards regional trade agreements over global ones. It should also be noted that Spanish speakers make up more than 10 percent of US residents now, which gives them a strong lobby. WTO and China China's normal trade relations were suspended in 1989 because of Tiananmen Square, but the US congress has each year approved 'temporary' normal trading relations. Despite the yearly debate, it was always unlikely that the US could impose what would essentially be prohibitive tariffs on its fourth largest trading partner. It is now clear that normal trade relations will be permanently reinstated this year to coincide with China's entry into the WTO. The direct effect on competition for the US market should be minimal since China has enjoyed normal trading relations for some time. There could be a significant effect on 27 investment flows, however, as China will have to open its domestic markets significantly. This could switch investment that would otherwise have gone to South East Asia, and could lead to more exports to the US. (Note for Investors: Entry into the WTO also allows access to Thai entrepreneurs who wish to expand into the Chinese market.) Since 1995, when China threatened Taiwan with missile tests in the Taiwan Strait, Taiwan has followed a 'Go Slow' policy of investing in Mainland China, restricting investment in many sectors, especially electronics and hi-tech industries. This may be partially responsible for China's low market share in some of these markets. In response to its own and Mainland China's entrance into the WTO, Taiwan plans to relax this plan. This is likely to increase competition from electronics manufacturers in China, and particularly to shift Taiwan investment in electronics away from Thailand towards China. Normal Trade Relations for Vietnam Vietnam has not had normal trade relations with the US since they fought in the 1970s. It now is likely that Vietnam will be granted normal trading relations next year. This will probably not have an strong effect on producers in Thailand in the short run (especially since Vietnamese rice is of low grade), but within five years, Vietnam will be producing significant amounts of rubber, shrimp and coffee all of which may have a very significant effect on Thailand's competitiveness. Thai investors should be aware of the opportunities presented by investing in these sectors in Vietnam. In general, Thailand's neighbors do not enjoy very good relations with the US (see Normal Trade Relations above). The exception, surprisingly, is Cambodia, which now exports as much to the US as does Vietnam. Most of its exports are apparel and textiles. As a Least-Developed Country it is not subject to quotas under the ATC. Again, this is an excellent opportunity for Thai investors. Key Trade Programs Thailand is affected both by trade laws that do pertain to it, and to those that pertain to its competitors. Those that do pertain to Thailand in terms of its trade with the US include WTO and GSP. Those that affect its competitors include NAFTA, CBERA, the ATPA (Andean Pact), the Israel-US Free Trade Area and other laws to support the Least-Developed Countries. North America Free Trade Area (NAFTA) is intended to eventually allow free trade in all goods between Canada, Mexico, and the United States. By 2004 all barriers should be eliminated except for a few sensitive agricultural items to be phased out in 2008. This will and already has had an enormous impact on products which the US protects strongly, such as agricultural products and textiles and apparel. Average tariffs for textiles are 17.5 percent, while Mexico pays 6 percent, soon to be zero, and is not subject to quotas. Caribbean Basin Economic Recovery Act (CBERA): Since 1974 the US has supported Caribbean and Central American Countries so as to increase political good will towards the US, to encourage political stability and to reduce immigration to the United States. Recent additions to the treaty allow for no quotas and Mexico tariff rates for most apparel. Much of the production in this area is in cooperation with US companies, who ship materials to be processed, and then re-import them. Because of their connections to US companies, they have unusual political protection. 28 Andean Trade Pact Area (ATPA): The Andean Pact consist of the Northern South American countries. They are accorded some but not all of the benefits of the CBERA area. They are included in the new tariff agreement on apparel Israel-US Free Trade Area: In it's long standing support of Israel especially vis-à-vis its Arab neighbors, in 1985 the United States offered free trade or reduced tariffs to many products from Israel. Thailand competes with Israel mostly in jewelry, in which Israel is the market leader. For the moment Thailand still receives GSP treatment on gold jewelry, but does not for silver jewelry. Israel producers do not have to pay the approximately 5 percent tariff for either type. (Gems enter the US free of duty. In many countries, there is a general rule that the lower the level of processing, the lower the tariff rate.) US products typically face the following tariff rates in the US Sector Typical Tariff Rates for Thailand (%) Tariffs for some Competitors (%) Apparel 17.5 6 - Mexico, soon to be zero Electronics 0 0 - All Jewelry 5 0 - Israel Rice 1.4 cents/kilo 0.6 cents/kilo - Mexico Car Parts 2.5 0 - NAFTA Steel Parts 2 0 - NAFTA Tobacco 60 cents/kilo 0 - Caribbean countries Vehicles 25 0 - Canada Source: Harmonized Trade Schedule of the United States (2000) Textiles and Apparel are subject to strict quotas, item by item. As part of the Agreement on Textiles and Apparel (ATC), which is one of the sections under the GATT, member countries are still allowed to use quotas to restrict the import of textiles and apparels. These quotas were initially allowed under bilateral multi-fiber arrangements (MFAs). Under the original MFAs countries were allotted a quota and a growth rate. The quota was to increase yearly by the specified growth rate. After the ATC was passed in 1995, these growth rates were accelerated. All quotas are to be eliminated by 2005 under the agreement, although high tariffs will still be in place. There is also doubt as to whether the US will actually follow through on the requirements to dismantle tariffs. Given the competitive position of others, Thai exporters will likely be hurt by eliminating the quotas. 29 Non-Tariff Barriers Environmental - In 1996 exports of Thai shrimp were banned because it was claimed that shrimp were being caught without using turtle exclusion devices on nets. Later overturned. Health - This year, Hong Kong questioned the safety of Thai fruit, and at one time it appeared as though much fruit would have to be discarded. GMO - at the beginning of 2000 one hundred and thirty governments signed the treaty on Genetically Modified Organisms which permits countries to ban imports of genetically altered organisms that they consider dangerous to health or environment. Sweatshops - Activists at the WTO meeting in Seattle protested what they felt to be exploitation of cheap labor in developing countries via inappropriate working conditions (low wages, long hours, unhygienic surroundings) . The answer to all of these barriers for exporters is to be aware of the political and social conditions in the countries to which they export and prepare themselves for barriers that might arise before it is too late. One warning sign: If the regulation is already in place for domestic producers there is a good chance it will be applied to imports as well. Anti-Dumping As the WTO reduces tariff protections for US businesses it is likely that the use of anti-dumping laws will increase. Anti-dumping laws are used because they are legal under the GATT, generally with the intent of 1) stopping illegal dumping of surplus goods outside of the main market (a form of price discrimination), and 2) preventing firms from creating monopoly power in markets by pricing low enough to drive out competitors. In practice, mostly anti-dumping laws are used to protect domestic industries that are in trouble. The number of dumping cases in the US is thought to depend largely on exchange rate movements, the strength of the US economy, and the competitive standing of exports in the market. A downturn in the US would probably lead to increased use of this unfair practice. The best protection for producers is to: 1) Keep prices in line with market prices - don’t decrease prices sharply to speed up market access. Firms are not allowed to follow the same sorts of strategic pricing strategies that they might follow at home. 30 2) Keep watch on industry trends in the United States, and be particularly careful if the domestic industry is weak. 3) Be aware of risk factors. Risk Factors for Anti-Dumping Rapid Growth in Market Share Unusually Low Prices Devaluation of the Baht Ill Health of Domestic Industry (for whatever reason) Economic Downturn in Importing Country Antidumping cases are fought in the US court system, and can be very expensive. Anti-dumping laws are clearly biased against foreign firms. In the US, 80 percent of cases lead to some punitive tariffs, but some of these cases were a result of no response by the defendant. Not fighting will almost certainly lead to prohibitive tariffs. Clearly the best strategy is avoidance, perhaps through coordination in information at the industry level. Incidentally, the anti-dumping claim can be against firms, countries, or groups of countries. 31 Chapter Six Analysis Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : Cost In order to evaluate the costs of Thai products, we first divide Thai exports into three very broad sectors: Agricultural and Food Products, Labor Intensive Products, and Electronics and Machinery. Thai exports to the US are broad based, with some products from each group. Because of Thailand’s extensive arable land, we have more agricultural exports than other Asian neighbors. We have more labor intensive goods than some of our neighbors in ASEAN who have become dependent especially on electronics. In terms of our biggest competitors for US markets, Mexico has more electronics and particularly machinery exports than Thailand, and of course, China’s exports are heavily weighted towards labor intensive products. Exports to the US by Sectors 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% Agricultural and Food Products hi na e Ph xic ilip o pi n M es al ay si a C Machinery and Electronics M Th ai la nd Labor Intensive Source: US National Trade Data Base, Notes: 1999 data; For purposes of this paper exports are divided by: Agricultural HS01-23, Labor Intensive HS24-83&94-99, Electronic and Machinery HS84-93 Looking at the market share data found in the appendix tables, part 9.8, we can make some generalizations and formulate some expectations for each of the three sectors. Agricultural products appear to be doing alright even though they often experience price volatility. Although there are threats from every corner, Thai products have been reasonably successful in terms of market share. Success depends on fertile land, low input prices, and productivity which in Thailand is still low. Threats in the future will come from other countries with large amounts of arable land, such as Vietnam and some Latin American countries. Labor intensive goods have so far been merely maintaining market share. Looking at market share data shows us that China and Mexico have been expanding extremely quickly. Because of lower costs, it is likely that our market share for some of these products will be severely affected in a few years time. 32 The threat from the two countries is different. Chinese labor is virtually unlimited in quantity, and at current exchange rates receives wages roughly a third of Thai labor. For our labor costs to be the same as theirs, the Thai baht exchange rate relative to the US dollar, would have to fall to below 100 baht to the dollar, which is not likely to happen anytime soon. (However, Indonesian labor is already cheaper than Chinese labor.) Foreign companies are also very interested in investing in China because of the enormous and fast growing market. Other countries with similar advantages to China include Indonesia, India and other countries of the Indian sub-continent, and least-developed countries dotted around the world. Unlike China, Mexican labor costs are higher than in Thailand, but they have other advantages due to lower tariffs, better access to some raw materials and proximity to the US. The benefits that now are afforded to Mexico will also be offered to other neighboring Latin American countries due to expansion of trade programs. Both of these sources of competition are likely to put strong pressure on labor intensive industries that rely on unskilled labor, and that have low economies of scale. The market share tables and cost analysis below both support this pessimistic conclusion. The electronics and machinery sectors have been doing quite well in Thailand in the last few years. Will they be able to make up for the shortfall in labor intensive exports? In terms of electronics, Thailand has not been successful relative to its immediate neighbors. The advantages we have from local content and many small supporting industries in the automobile industry, are just what we lack in the electronics industry. A wafer plant would certainly help by reducing the extremely high import content of electronic equipment, but without the supporting industries it is unlikely the sector will take off. Policy should be directed at both large ticket items such as chip making capacity, as well as support for SMEs. It must be acknowledged, however, that we may have missed the wave for this sector, especially if the electronics industry begins to move en-mass to China. In that case, further government investment in the sector may be wasted. The automobile industry does have good potential in Thailand especially because cars are such a large ticket item that a few exports can have a very significant effect on the balance of payments. The automobile industry still faces a number of risks and unresolved questions, in particular: 1) Are we the best place to produce for the region? 2) Will the car industry regionalize? 3) Will the region do well enough to support us? In terms of exporting to the US, it is unlikely that Thailand will have a significant role. Our hopes are rather at the level of producing for South East Asia. The US does import many automobile components but the market for those is well developed and would be difficult to challenge. For example, Mexico exports more than 25 billion US dollars in car parts to the US a year, which is worth more than the entire automobile sector in Thailand. 33 Sensitivity Analysis Which cost factor is the most important in determining competitiveness? We can estimate how sensitive costs of different products are to economic shocks. Apparel Cost Sensitivity to Shocks 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% -0.5% -1.0% -1.5% Baht from Change in 40:1 to 41:1 US Tariffs (if 40% 1989-2004 Foreign Content) Oil Price $25/brl to $30/brl Min Wage up 10 baht -2.0% Source: Thai Farmers Research Center estimates Electronics Cost Sensitivity to Shocks 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% -0.5% -1.0% -1.5% Baht from Change in 40:1 to 41:1 US Tariffs (if 80% 2000-2004 Foreign Content) Oil Price $25/brl to $30/brl Min Wage up 10 baht -2.0% Source: Thai Farmers Research Center estimates Clearly, of the factors considered, the exchange rate is the most important in determining our price competitiveness in the US. A one baht change in the exchange rate has a larger price effect than a 10 baht (6.1%) change in the minimum wage, even for labor intensive goods. Of course depreciation in the baht often is linked to depreciation in other currencies, so that if we devalue we may get paid less, with no improvement in competitiveness. 34 Factor Cost Analysis What is the overall price level of goods reaching the US from different countries? By putting together the factor costs we discussed in previous chapters, we can get a sense of the cost of producing goods in each countries. This will give us a basis for comparing the final cost to US customers. We have discussed four cost components: Transportation Costs Foreign Exchange Labor Costs Tariffs Transportation costs and tariffs we can add right on top of manufacturing cost. Labor costs are a part of manufacturing cost, so we set Thailand to be 100 and adjust other countries by wage rates and by labor intensity. Foreign exchange presents a problem because it is changes in relative foreign exchange rates that matter. This factor is best addressed through sensitivity analysis. There is one very significant cost factor that we cannot consider, which is raw material costs. Raw materials often make up about 60 percent of the value of a product, so that a small price advantage can significantly affect manufacturing costs. The below tables make the assumption that raw material costs are the same for the countries compared. Therefore for each individual industry we must consider what raw materials are likely to be. Thai Mfg Cost = 100 Cost of Wooden Frame Exports to the United States 150.0 100.0 50.0 0.0 Thailand Manufacturing Cost China Transport Costs Mexico Tariffs Source: Thai Farmers Research Center estimates Wooden picture frames are a typical labor intensive product in which Thailand has had success. We see that China has the cheapest costs, even though they have to pay both the highest transportation cost, and the highest tariff (since they are not part of NAFTA and are not eligible for GSP treatment as is Thailand.) Thailand is shown to have cheaper costs than Mexico, but more expensive than China. If raw materials were included, probably Mexican prices would be cheaper, since in Thailand 35 wood must be imported. Currently Mexico has the highest market share in this good, followed by Thailand and China. China has a very high growth rate and is likely to surpass Thailand this year. Thai Mfg Cost = 100 Cost of Apparel Exports to the United States 140.0 120.0 100.0 80.0 60.0 40.0 20.0 0.0 Thailand Manufacturing Cost China Transport Costs Mexico Tariffs Source: Thai Farmers Research Center estimates A graph for apparel again shows China with the cheapest costs in spite of high tariffs and transportation costs. Lower tariffs (soon to be zero percent) and low transportation costs keep costs cheaper in Mexico than in Thailand. Actually, Mexico has had enormous growth in this sector and China has not. This is undoubtedly due to the US system of quotas for textiles and apparel which restricts the growth rate of apparel and textiles by country (and by product.) This suggests that if the US actually does comply with its commitment to GATT to abolish quotas (but not tariffs) by 2004, there could be an enormous flow of apparel production to China. Thai apparel manufacturers clearly benefit by keeping quotas in place, since we are far from the price leader. Thai investors should also note that as a "Least-Developed" country, Cambodia is not subject to export quotas on textiles, and has wages that are cheaper than those in China. (Laos and Vietnam currently do not enjoy normal trade relations with the US, but if that eventually occurs (2001?) they will also offer good investment opportunities) Finally a graph of electronics also shows China as the cheapest producer, due to low transportation costs and tariffs for all. (The US has a policy of zero tariffs on all electronic products.) Because there are no other costs to discuss, labor again makes Chinese products the cheapest. This sector enjoys economies of scale and is sensitive to skilled labor. At the present, China does not play a major role in many electronics industries, in part because of a Taiwanese policy not to invest in that sector in China. However, it is likely that this sector will grow quickly in the next several years because of low costs, a possible reversal of the Taiwanese policy, and lots of interest in FDI. 36 Thai Mfg Cost = 100 Cost of Electronic Exports to the United States 100.0 50.0 0.0 Thailand Manufacturing Cost China Transport Costs Mexico Tariffs Source: Thai Farmers Research Center estimates Competitiveness How competitive is Thailand? According to the Global Competitiveness Report, between 1996 and 1999 Thailand's competitiveness ranking fell from 14th in the world to 30th. This occurred at a time when foreign exchange made Thai prices cheaper, labor costs became cheaper in world terms again due to foreign exchange, tariffs continue to fall due to the GATT and transport costs (as of 1999) were very low. Export competitiveness is clearly not the same as "global competitiveness". What in fact is measured in the Global Competitiveness Report" is weighted towards a strong financial system, economic integration with the rest of the world, domestic economic strength, infrastructure, and in the year 2000, creativity and innovation. Export competitiveness has less to do with the domestic sector, but there are still important linkages. If companies are bankrupt or cannot obtain loans they cannot increase capacity or invest in the latest equipment and technology. At times during the recent crisis, companies with cash flow problems could not even get money to buy raw materials. If domestic demand is stagnant, foreign companies are less interested in investing in Thailand, and crucial linkages are not built to outside markets. This paper has argued that costs are very important for competitiveness. However, as noted above, we have just come through a period of falling costs. If all of our prices are cheaper, why aren’t Thai exports doing better? Our prices are down, but so are other's prices - chapter three shows that many developing countries have depreciating currencies relative to the US dollar. Thailand had lost competitiveness before the crisis. What originally led to the economic crisis was an overvalued exchange rate and a corresponding slowdown in exports. Thailand is not the very cheapest location for production - New FDI is going elsewhere. Our factories may be reasonably competitive in the short run, but new FDI will chase the very best locations. FDI is much more profitable if there is both a domestic and a foreign market. Right now the Thai domestic market is quite weak. 37 Domestic investors do not have the capital or the right products to capture the world market. Because of the crisis and corresponding debt overhang, few Thai capitalists have the resources to expand production into ever changing markets. Some key exports have a very high import content, meaning prices didn't really decrease. US Imports Are Slowly Becoming Concentrated Among Fewer Exporting Countries Concentration Measures 1992 1999 48.2% 50.9% CR4 65.2% 66.5% CR8 83.2% 83.9% CR20 Derived from USITC Dataweb Notes: CR4 is the sum of the market share of the four largest trading partners in terms of imports, CR8 is the sum of the market share of the eight largest trading partners, and CR20 is the sum of the market share of the 20 largest trading partners. Finally it is interesting to note that US imports show a trend of coming from a more limited group of exporters. This argues against the notion that free trade opens up the world for all nations, and suggests that the pursuit of free trade may not benefit everyone, only the most competitive or those with special relationships. Canada Japan Mexico China Germany United Kingdom Taiwan Korea France Italy Malaysia Singapore Thailand Philippines Brazil Venezuela Ireland Hong Kong Israel Switzerland Market Share Rank 1992 Market Share Rank 1993 Market Share Rank 1994 Market Share Rank 1995 Market Share Rank 1996 Market Share Rank 1997 Market Share Rank 1998 Market Share Rank 1999 1 2 3 5 4 7 6 8 9 10 14 11 17 23 16 15 32 13 25 18 1 2 3 4 5 7 6 8 9 10 12 11 14 23 17 15 31 13 26 18 1 2 3 4 5 7 6 8 9 11 12 10 13 22 15 16 32 14 24 19 1 2 3 4 5 7 6 8 11 12 10 9 13 20 16 15 27 14 25 18 1 2 3 4 5 7 6 8 10 11 12 9 14 19 17 13 27 15 24 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 11 12 10 14 15 17 13 27 16 22 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 9 8 10 11 12 13 14 16 18 22 15 20 19 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Source: USITC Dataweb 38 Chapter Seven Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : Conclusions and Recommendations The general outlook for exports to the US based on macroeconomics is stable to weak. Although Thailand has managed to maintain a stable share of US imports over the last seven years, (only a small loss in percentage terms) it has done poorly in relation to its neighbors in ASEAN such as the Philippines, Malaysia and Indonesia, who have all had significant increases. Thai exports are much more concentrated on labor intensive and agricultural products then are Philippine or Malaysian exports. These countries have done well because of growth in the electronics industry. There has been a general trend for Asian countries with low labor costs to do well in terms of US market share, while higher labor cost countries including the NICs have been losing market share. At the current exchange rate Thailand cannot compete in labor intensive products with lower labor cost countries such as China, Indonesia, and even cheaper neighbors in South Asia. This has resulted in a steady loss of market share in a number of different product lines. US imports of low cost goods are increasingly coming from China and Mexico. Many Thai exports which have shown success lately, such as wooden frames and leather products, will inevitably face off against the incredibly expanding exports from China and Mexico and will likely not be able to continue their present growth rates. Although to date, most of the growth in China's and Mexico's exports comes at the expense of countries with still higher labor costs, as those countries bow out of the market, the competition will increasingly be more direct. Chinese costs are still a lot lower than Thai costs for many products. Overall, unless Thailand has a special advantage in a product it will likely be produced elsewhere. Of great concern is the lack of investment in key growth sectors. Thailand is no longer the best location (in terms of growth, costs, external markets) for foreign investment. Meanwhile the need to recapitalize Thai businesses as well as banks restrains domestic investment, especially due to debt overhangs, and unwillingness to lend by the banks. At the current exchange rate (42 baht/dollar) Thai companies can be profitable, but many of them cannot expand. Industries tend to show a great deal of stability. Once a firm is set up and producing it continues to do so, leading to stable levels of exports. However, as the level of investment falls, businesses that were established during the boom years will stagnate, and will lose out in terms of market share. As the level of investment falls, it also reduces Thailand's ability to adjust to changing trade patterns. Some sectors require constant changes in technology in order to succeed. That technology is much more expensive due to the decline in the value of the baht. Other sectors need investment to take advantage of new opportunities in international trade. For example, in today’s boom market most electronics firms would be successful, but there is no money in Thailand to invest in them, and foreigners feel that prospects are better elsewhere. 39 Although China's costs are cheaper than ours, China cannot produce everything. Foreign exchange markets will ensure that eventually China will specialize in what it does best. Long term competition in some sectors will likely come from elsewhere. The biggest potential loser in the next couple of years is the apparel and textile industries. The advantages that NAFTA have given Mexico in the apparel and textiles sector are also being offered to Caribbean and Latin American countries reducing an average tariff rate of 17.5 to about six percent, destined to be zero percent in 2004. Savings on tariffs and transportation costs, and an absence of quotas has made Mexico preeminent in US imports of apparel. As other quota-free Latin American countries increase production, they will make meaningless the era of apparel imports driven by quotas, at least insofar as Thailand is concerned. Interestingly, our calculations suggest that even with zero tariffs for Latin American products, Chinese apparel will still be cheaper, so that quota faze outs set to be completed in 2004 under GATT rules might shift some textiles back to this region, if not to Thailand. Investors might look at Cambodia which is not limited by quotas and has cheap labor costs. Some bright lights in terms of exports include air conditioners, silver jewelry, and some auto parts. Agricultural products do not currently experience the same level of risk as labor intensive goods. Agricultural goods have been reasonably successful in US markets, and although they will continue to face risks from other agricultural exporters such as Vietnam and South American countries, many products will remain competitive for a number of years. Thailand has been successful in the US perhaps more than other regions because its products are mostly upscale. Building a reputation for quality standards may be useful. Although the electronic sector has come to dominate the export tables, relative to its neighbors, Thailand has been an underachiever in this sector. The relative lack of success is due to little domestic content, insufficient supporting industries, lack of R&D, and a lack of skilled labor. With support from the government some of these problems could be resolved. However, the critical factor to watch is whether the electronics industry begins to move wholesale to China. In that case, government investment in the mostly foreign owned sector could be wasted. A better bet is the still growing automobile industry. This sector has the necessary local content and supporting industries to allow it to succeed. One critical factor is whether South East Asia will grow rapidly enough to support its own car industry. Potential for exports to the US will depend on whether exchange rates fall sufficiently to substantially undercut Mexican production costs. There has been a long term decline in exchange rates and terms of trade for developing countries in this decade. The devaluation in Thailand reflects previous devaluations in other regions and with the increasing emphasis on export-led growth this downward trend in exchange rates will likely continue. (Average decline since 1992 of about six percent a year) This will not help our competitiveness as other developing nations will also devalue. We can list the following results as stemming from our research: 40 Transportation Costs Transportation costs favor the transport of small valuable items over the transport of heavy cheap items. For many bulky low value items we will never be competitive. High oil prices have a strong effect on the competitiveness of heavy products– e.g. cement, but will have minimal effects on most other products. Distance can also be measured in time or in cultural differences which affect FDI. Foreign Exchange Exchange rates are the most significant determinant of price competitiveness. For exports, our exchange rate relative to competing nations is probably more important than our exchange rate relative to the US dollar. The currencies of developing countries have been falling versus developed countries for a number of years. Currencies in countries with floating currencies have devalued to a similar extent to those with fixed exchange rates. Although devaluations can make us more price competitive, devaluations by one competitor inevitably lead to devaluations by others. Devaluations make us poorer in terms of the world which will make it more difficult to finance industrial expansion domestically, and makes domestic consumers poorer. As a group, developing countries should work to maintain exchange current rates. Labor Costs Labor costs are generally a small part of total costs at an average of 7 percent for manufacturing products. Because labor costs are small compared to raw material cost, for many industries they will not be the deciding factor. It is unit productivity that is important, not wages per se. If we increase our productivity we can make the same product with lower labor costs. Training can improve productivity and make us more competitive for semiskilled labor intensive jobs. Our labor costs in US dollar terms are about where they were in 1992. Tariffs We find three main strands in US trade policy - Global Free Trade 41 - Free Trade Area for the Americas (FTAA) - Aid for Least Developed Countries In addition, the US regularly use trade policy as a political tool to punish its enemies and occasionally to reward its friends. There are tensions between the different programs that have bee resolved as follows: 1) Free trade or low tariffs for most goods 2) Protection for a few sectors, while selectively offering free trade in those sectors to Latin American countries. 3) Reduced tariffs and no quotas to Least Developed Countries. Tariff policy towards Latin America is very important for Thailand because of competition for apparel and some agricultural products. The risk of antidumping is probably the most serious threat in terms of tariffs: Warning signs are a weak domestic industry, rapid rise in imports, and a faltering US economy. In terms of non-tariff barriers – any rules that apply to domestic industries will eventually be applied to foreign companies (e.g. turtle exclusion devices for shrimp were required on US fishing vessels first) Cost Analysis Raw materials are a very large part of total costs – if they are cheap enough we can overcome differences in labor costs. For manufactured goods we reduce raw material costs by building supporting industries and through import substitution (increasing local content). We also need to increase productivity and increase R&D. For agricultural products we reduce raw material costs by increasing productivity, and local production of seeds and other inputs. Overall Competitiveness China and Mexico are increasing market share in many products and will eventually challenge Thailand's market share in the US. China is strong because of low labor costs (33 percent of Thai costs in 1998) and because of interest in FDI in their enormous dynamic market. Mexico has higher manufacturing costs than Thailand but benefits from proximity and tariff reductions on apparel and agricultural products that the US has carefully guarded. There is a significant risk of a crash in export value of labor intensive goods (based on our costs, expanding world capacity, and the relaxation of some quota restrictions.) Our agricultural goods (although experiencing price volatility) are for the moment doing satisfactorily. The electronics industry, although currently strong, can not compare with other electronic sectors in the region. 42 Electronic industries depend as much on support for small and medium industries as they do on a wafer plant. If the prices of labor intensive goods fall, they will fall everywhere, not just Thailand. Price leaders such as China will win. A fall in labor intensive exports will most likely to manifest itself in a further fall in the exchange rates of developing countries vis-a-vis the United States. US firms have begun to invest in India. Italy competes with Thailand for a surprising number of markets, but at a higher level of fashion. It might be worth taking a better look at this country. Recommendations We can improve our competitiveness by reducing our costs and by increasing demand for our products. The Thai government already has programs to address most of these. Lower Costs 1) Better supporting industries – lowers cost through more efficient production 2) More local content – saves on transportation and tariffs, increases control 3) Better training for our workforce to improve productivity We lower costs in agricultural by: 1) More appropriate use of inputs - (e.g. fertilizer) 2) Better stock and strains - to get better yields 3) Better technology – to get better quality Build Brands There is little markup when selling a commodity. To the extent that we can make our products unique in terms of culture, fashion, style, service, quality we can build our market power and increase profitability. Europe has done a very good job of building brands and Asia a rather bad job. We should put Thai advertising expertise to work. Know our Customers and Competitors 1) Follow industry trends and issues in the US to avoid unexpected threats 2) Perform market research to find out about tastes – especially for consumer oriented products. 3) Watch competitors to avoid unexpected shocks Invest In Cheaper Cost Neighbors One of the long standing traditions in Asia is that when your own costs get too high, invest in your lower cost neighbors to build the same thing. 43 Look to New Markets Do not ignore our growing gigantic neighbors – China and India. More Specific Recommendations Government Support for Small Enterprises Many of the sectors that have done well at exporting in the past are a result of FDI from foreign multinationals. This is not surprising as it is estimated that a full fifty percent of international trade is between related companies – that is with at least some joint ownership. Large multinational companies have plenty of expertise at marketing, selling, accounting, distribution and operations and do not want or need much support from the government in those areas. At this moment, FDI is limited and big capital projects are beyond the reach of most investors. Continuing to build support for small local enterprises is a good alternative. This should be the era of government support for smaller scale enterprises. Home grown enterprises can use a great deal of help in some of the business functions listed above. Indeed the Thai government already helps with many of them. Further help might be in the form of information and advice about export markets such as is offered by the Small Business Administration in the US. In addition, there are a number of areas in which economies of scale might dictate a larger governmental role. If we consider, for example, the possibility of e-commerce for small enterprises, we might find that small enterprises could not 1) handle payments using credit cards, 2) write English language web pages, or 3) distribute products efficiently. All of these services could be offered by the government, and in fact in one form or another are often offered by commercial shopping sites in the US. Were the government to handle credit card clearing and give support for web page design – probably by subcontracting to the many small internet shops already in existence - it might be possible to have direct selling of products by quite small enterprises in the US. Thailand has an internationally renowned advertising industry, but none of it is addressed to overseas customers. There may be areas in which advertising of Thai products makes sense. Marketing research is another very expensive enterprise at the individual level, but one that could pay very high dividends. Government support – perhaps by helping support Thai business students in the US in exchange for marketing research – might be useful. Turning to the private sector, there may be room for marketing cooperatives of small producers. For example, with the slowdown in South East Asia it is likely that auto parts manufacturers will have excess capacity. It may be easier to sell those parts in the US under a uniform brand or through a single marketing cooperative. This would give them the scale that would allow them to negotiate with big customers in the US. Food 44 One of our strongest competitive advantages is in the food industry. We could protect it by building a reputation for strictness in food quality. We could run ads showing Thais rejecting food leaving Thailand because they don’t meet Thai standards. Think Seriously about GMOs and Biotechnology With the potential to be one of the world's premier food exporters, we need to think seriously about what the role of biotechnology will play in the future. Certainly there is an enormous potential to increase yields in Thailand. If the way to get increased yields is to welcome foreign investment and resources in biotechnology then it should be done. More than this, biotechnology has been widely ignored in Asia, and this is a chance to get in at the beginning of a technology cycle rather than at the end as with electronics. We have a natural application in agricultural production. If there will be an opportunity for labor intensive production, or even land intensive production in the biotechnology sphere, this is the time to welcome it, before we are again behind the curve. This is not the time to waffle and speculate about what the negative effects of GMOs might be. The negative effects might be real, but they should be seriously studied, and ways to avoid risks should be found, just as they have been in other industries. There is a strong movement among NGOs to ban or avoid GMOs. There are several reasons for this including 1) They correctly perceive that there are health and ecological risks of producing GMO food, and feel that multinationals in their search for profits will ignore these risks. The answer is to address those risks head-on, and determine which are real and which are imagined, and respond on a case by case basis. Just as drugs undergo, extensive testing, so must engineered products. 2) GMOs tend to be used by large agribusiness rather than by small farmers, challenging a way of life that NGOs would like to protect. It is natural for increased productivity to come from less use of resources, including labor. Nevertheless, with adequate government support smaller farmers could use them as well. 3) Thais have a very strong attachment to land (an irrational attachment when viewed through my American eyes). So although it is acceptable for multinationals to come and make use of the most basic factor of production (people), it is not acceptable for them to do the same with land. The biggest barrier to implementation of agricultural biotechnology is of course trade barriers by places such as Europe that have reacted to potential risks by not taking any chance and closing the door. This is bound to change over time as the benefits and safety of bioengineered products become more obvious. If Thailand were to welcome such products, however, labeling and very strict control would be required. Support for Farmers - What Kind? Thailand puts a lot of resources into supporting farmers every year, almost none of it addressed towards increasing Thai farmers long term competitiveness. Competition for agricultural products is quite intense in the world. However, its low cost structure and fertile land gives Thailand the chance to be competitive in the long run. Being competitive means recognizing that prices for agricultural products will drop continuously in the future, and that policies to increase productivity and technology are required to counteract that drop. It is impossible to shore up the wall of prices in the long run. Other Marketing Suggestions 45 Isn't there some ritual that goes with Thai food? (And I don't mean sitting on the floor and putting your food on newspapers.) Thai food is very popular worldwide, yet one problem is that there is little profit in the food industry supplying Thai restaurants. If there is little value added in the food perhaps we can make the value added in the accessories, which of course must come from Thailand. Thailand is the biggest exporter of shrimp to the US. Although shrimp is viewed by Americans as a healthy alternative to beef, pork and even chicken, it is about as popular on an American’s plate as beef is on a Thai plate. Certainly there is a lot of opportunity to promote the use of shrimp on a regular basis which would directly benefit us. Ease Immigration Restrictions Stop the policy of making it hard for poor foreigners to live in Thailand. First and foremost, many of those foreigners are English teachers. Thailand desperately needs to improve its level of English if it is to be integrated into the world economy. It is hard to imagine a group of foreigners that is more useful to Thailand. Skilled workers are valuable too. Countries are beginning to realize the value of skilled labor and are easing immigration policies for this category worldwide. The competition in the future is to attract talented people to your country. A skilled foreigner is much more likely to create jobs for Thais then to take jobs from them. Lets not be the last to adopt this coming trend. International Issues The rental rate on information and intellectual property is too high and should not be allowed to be set by market rates in the developed world. The developing world cannot afford a one price fits all rule on intellectual property. The alternative - ignoring intellectual property rights - will eventually cut off access to many resources. FDI is a regional issue, not a Thai issue. We need to work together through ASEAN to remind investors why they were here in the first place – large markets, hard working people, well developed business acumen. Stability will be the central issue for the next few years. Be aware of China as a neighbor. The Chinese economy appears to be on track for a number of year of prosperous growth. Although there is little money available for investment right now, there are certainly opportunities for Thai investors. Tourism could also become a bigger trade, especially given overt hostility to the Chinese in Indonesia and discrimination in Malaysia. Thailand would need to do a better job of making itself accessible through Chinese character signs and Chinese language. Becoming a Chinese wedding center would be particularly attractive. It may take a few years for Chinese income levels to rise sufficiently. The Indian Sub-continent is also likely to become much more outward oriented in coming years as investment starts to come in. This might present opportunities for Thai manufacturers of equipment, etc. Support the Web 46 Expertise at using the web, and designing web pages is likely to be an important supporting industry for many types of businesses in the future. The government should encourage this expertise, perhaps by hiring people to design web pages as suggested above. The web will also be the source of much of the new information and business that comes into Thailand in coming years. Thailand needs to establish the legal, financial and physical infrastructure that goes with this industry. Finally, there is the potential for e-commerce. Although the widespread use of ecommerce within Thailand is many years off, it is still the only way a small Thai enterprise could reach a customer in the US. Given global trends, it may be that e-commerce between businesses develops more quickly than direct sales to final consumers. If Thai companies are not prepared for this they may be cut off from their customer base. Do a Better Job of Selling Thai Culture We should take a cue from Japan and try to do a better job of selling Thai culture. As mentioned above, foreigners love Thai food, which is a gateway into further interest in Thai culture. Creating accessories – perhaps based on historical practices – might work for this purpose. The world loves snobbery including doing things the “right” way, with the “right” things. Thai styles and motifs could also be subtly incorporated into cheap exports of wood and apparel to make them more fashionable, and to differentiate them. 47 Thai Competitiveness in US Markets : Bibliography Campbell, D.C., M. Mahmood, A. Marinakis, Chanin Mephokee, Gosah Arya, Lae Dilokvidharat (1998) Wage Policy and Labour Competitiveness in Thailand, ILO, unpublished study document CEIC Data Company, Online data service Heritage Foundation (2000) "Breaking up a triple play on poor countries", US policy research, http://www.heritage.org/library/backgrounder/ International Labor Organization, Labor Database, http://laborsta.ilo.org Lall, Sanjaya (1998) "Thailand's Manufacturing Competitiveness," World Bank , Competitiveness and Sustainable Economic Recovery in Thailand, Background Papers for Conference Middleton, Jon and Zafiris Tzannatos (1998), "Skills for Competitiveness," World Bank , Competitiveness and Sustainable Economic Recovery in Thailand, Background Papers for Conference OTEXA Office of Textiles and Apparel, Information about tariff and quotas for textiles in the US, http://otexa.ita.doc.gov/tarfchrt.html Reuters, Subscriber data service Thai Department of Labour Protection and Welfare (1998), รายงานผลการสารวจดัชนีผลิตภาพแรงงานประจาปี 2541, (Employment Survey Report), Bangkok Thai Ministry of Commerce (2000) บทสรุ ปสาหรับผูบ้ ริ หารนโยบายการค้าสิ นค้าเกษตรของสหรัฐอเมริ กาและผลกระทบต่อประเทศไทย, http://www.moc.go.th/thai/dbe/research/vijai25.html Thailand Development Research Institute, (1998) "The economic impact of oil market" Thomas Legislative Information on the Web, US legislation on line, http://thomas.loc.gov, H.R.454 UNIDO Data, labor costs and productivity by country, http://www.unido.org/doc.cfm?cfm=/Regions.cfm?area=GLO US Bureau of Economic Analysis, (Various Years) Foreign Direct Investment Abroad http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/di1usd.htm U.S. Congress, (2000), "Trade and Development Act of 2000", http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgibin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=106_cong_bills&docid=f:h434enr.txt.pdf US Council for International Business, http://www.uscib.org 48 US Department of Customs (2000) Harmonized Trade Schedule of the United States (2000), comprehensive tariff and HS schedule information, http://www.usitc.gov/taffairs.htm#HTS US Department of the Treasury, Current import quotas for textiles, http://www.customs.ustreas.gov/quotas/1999/reports.htm US Federal Reserve Bank, Historical foreign exchange rates, daily monthly, annual, http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/H10/hist/ US International Trade Commission, Information about antidumping, http://www.usitc.gov/ US International Trade Commission Dataweb, Market share by product, http://dataweb.usitc.gov/ US National Trade Database, Market share by product - subscriber based, http://www.statusa.gov/tradtest.nsf World Bank (2000) World Development Report 1999/2000, full text on-line at http://www.worldbank.org/wdr/2000/fullreport.html World Economic Forum (2000,1999) Global Competitiveness Report, summary at http://www.weforum.org/ World Trade Analyzer, world trade flows, but a bit out of date, http://oracle.tradecompass.com/owsbin/oowa/ExpSrv610/dbxwdevkit/xwd_init?wrldcode/sysstart World Trade Organization, WTO Report on Thailand, (1999) http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tpr_e/tp122_e.htm 49 Thai Competitiveness in US Markets: Tables Total Market Share of US General Imports by Country of Some Important Trading Partners (In Terms of Value) Source: Derived from USITC Dataweb Country Market Market Market Market Market Market Market Market Share Share Share Share Share Share Share Share 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Total 100.00% 100.00% 100.00% 100.00% 100.00% 100.00% 100.00% 100.00% Canada 18.51% 19.11% 19.42% 19.52% 19.78% 19.31% 19.13% 19.35% Japan 18.27% 18.48% 17.95% 16.62% 14.56% 13.95% 13.35% 12.82% Mexico 6.61% 6.88% 7.46% 8.30% 9.22% 9.87% 10.36% 10.71% China 4.83% 5.43% 5.84% 6.13% 6.51% 7.19% 7.79% 7.98% Germany 5.42% 4.93% 4.78% 4.96% 4.92% 4.95% 5.45% 5.38% United Kingdom 3.79% 3.74% 3.78% 3.62% 3.65% 3.76% 3.81% 3.82% Taiwan 4.62% 4.32% 4.02% 3.90% 3.78% 3.75% 3.62% 3.43% Korea 3.14% 2.95% 2.96% 3.25% 2.86% 2.66% 2.62% 3.05% France 2.78% 2.63% 2.53% 2.31% 2.35% 2.38% 2.63% 2.53% Italy 2.31% 2.28% 2.22% 2.22% 2.30% 2.22% 2.30% 2.19% Malaysia 1.55% 1.82% 2.11% 2.35% 2.25% 2.07% 2.08% 2.09% Singapore 2.13% 2.20% 2.31% 2.50% 2.57% 2.31% 2.01% 1.77% Thailand 1.41% 1.47% 1.55% 1.53% 1.43% 1.45% 1.47% 1.40% Philippines 0.82% 0.84% 0.86% 0.94% 1.03% 1.20% 1.31% 1.21% Brazil 1.43% 1.29% 1.31% 1.19% 1.11% 1.11% 1.11% 1.10% Venezuela 1.54% 1.40% 1.26% 1.31% 1.63% 1.55% 1.02% 1.10% Ireland 0.43% 0.43% 0.44% 0.55% 0.61% 0.67% 0.92% 1.07% Hong Kong 1.84% 1.65% 1.46% 1.38% 1.25% 1.18% 1.15% 1.03% Israel 0.72% 0.76% 0.79% 0.77% 0.81% 0.84% 0.94% 0.96% Switzerland 1.06% 1.03% 0.96% 1.02% 0.98% 0.96% 0.95% 0.94% Indonesia 0.81% 0.94% 0.98% 1.00% 1.04% 1.06% 1.02% 0.93% Belgium 0.84% 0.89% 0.96% 0.81% 0.86% 0.91% 0.92% 0.90% India 0.71% 0.78% 0.80% 0.77% 0.78% 0.84% 0.90% 0.89% Netherlands 0.99% 0.94% 0.91% 0.86% 0.84% 0.84% 0.83% 0.83% Saudi Arabia 1.95% 1.33% 1.16% 1.11% 1.11% 1.10% 0.69% 0.80% Sweden 0.89% 0.78% 0.76% 0.84% 0.90% 0.84% 0.86% 0.79% Colombia 0.54% 0.52% 0.48% 0.51% 0.54% 0.54% 0.51% 0.61% Russia 0.09% 0.30% 0.49% 0.54% 0.45% 0.49% 0.63% 0.57% Australia 0.69% 0.57% 0.48% 0.45% 0.49% 0.53% 0.59% 0.52% Spain 0.56% 0.52% 0.54% 0.52% 0.54% 0.53% 0.52% 0.49% Nigeria 0.95% 0.91% 0.67% 0.64% 0.74% 0.73% 0.46% 0.43% Dominican Rep 0.45% 0.46% 0.47% 0.46% 0.45% 0.50% 0.49% 0.42% Iraq 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.03% 0.13% 0.41% Norway 0.37% 0.33% 0.36% 0.42% 0.49% 0.43% 0.31% 0.40% Costa Rica 0.27% 0.27% 0.25% 0.25% 0.25% 0.27% 0.30% 0.39% South Africa 0.32% 0.32% 0.31% 0.30% 0.29% 0.29% 0.33% 0.31% Chile 0.26% 0.25% 0.27% 0.26% 0.29% 0.26% 0.27% 0.29% Austria 0.25% 0.24% 0.26% 0.26% 0.28% 0.27% 0.28% 0.28% Finland 0.22% 0.28% 0.27% 0.31% 0.30% 0.28% 0.28% 0.28% Denmark 0.31% 0.29% 0.32% 0.26% 0.27% 0.25% 0.26% 0.28% Honduras 0.15% 0.16% 0.17% 0.19% 0.23% 0.27% 0.28% 0.26% Turkey 0.21% 0.21% 0.24% 0.24% 0.22% 0.24% 0.28% 0.26% Argentina 0.24% 0.21% 0.26% 0.24% 0.29% 0.25% 0.25% 0.25% Angola 0.43% 0.36% 0.31% 0.30% 0.34% 0.32% 0.25% 0.24% Guatemala 0.20% 0.21% 0.19% 0.21% 0.21% 0.23% 0.23% 0.22% Peru 0.14% 0.13% 0.13% 0.14% 0.16% 0.20% 0.22% 0.19% Bangladesh 0.16% 0.15% 0.16% 0.17% 0.17% 0.19% 0.20% 0.19% Hungary 0.07% 0.07% 0.07% 0.07% 0.09% 0.12% 0.17% 0.18% 50 Algeria Ecuador New Zealand Sri Lanka Pakistan El Salvador Gabon Kuwait Portugal Trin & Tobago Macao Poland Czech Republic United Arab Em Jamaica Aruba Egypt Vietnam Cambodia Greece Ukraine Nicaragua Romania Congo (ROC) Morocco Brunei Netherlands Ant Panama Cote d'Ivoire Malta & Gozo Luxembourg Iceland Haiti Liechtenstein Slovenia Qatar Mauritius Estonia Burma (Myanmar) 0.30% 0.25% 0.23% 0.15% 0.16% 0.07% 0.17% 0.05% 0.12% 0.16% 0.14% 0.07% 0.00% 0.15% 0.11% 0.04% 0.08% 0.00% 0.00% 0.07% 0.02% 0.01% 0.02% 0.10% 0.03% 0.01% 0.12% 0.05% 0.04% 0.02% 0.04% 0.03% 0.02% 0.01% 0.02% 0.01% 0.03% 0.00% 0.01% 0.27% 0.24% 0.21% 0.17% 0.15% 0.08% 0.16% 0.31% 0.14% 0.14% 0.12% 0.08% 0.05% 0.13% 0.12% 0.08% 0.11% 0.00% 0.00% 0.06% 0.03% 0.02% 0.01% 0.09% 0.03% 0.01% 0.07% 0.05% 0.03% 0.02% 0.04% 0.04% 0.03% 0.02% 0.04% 0.01% 0.03% 0.00% 0.01% 0.23% 0.26% 0.21% 0.16% 0.15% 0.09% 0.17% 0.22% 0.14% 0.17% 0.12% 0.10% 0.05% 0.07% 0.11% 0.07% 0.08% 0.01% 0.00% 0.07% 0.05% 0.03% 0.03% 0.06% 0.03% 0.01% 0.06% 0.05% 0.03% 0.01% 0.04% 0.04% 0.01% 0.01% 0.04% 0.01% 0.03% 0.00% 0.01% Source: Derived from USITC Dataweb 0.22% 0.26% 0.20% 0.17% 0.16% 0.11% 0.19% 0.18% 0.14% 0.13% 0.12% 0.09% 0.05% 0.06% 0.11% 0.06% 0.08% 0.03% 0.00% 0.05% 0.05% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.01% 0.04% 0.04% 0.03% 0.02% 0.03% 0.03% 0.02% 0.02% 0.04% 0.01% 0.03% 0.01% 0.01% 0.27% 0.24% 0.18% 0.18% 0.16% 0.14% 0.25% 0.21% 0.13% 0.13% 0.11% 0.08% 0.06% 0.06% 0.11% 0.07% 0.08% 0.04% 0.00% 0.06% 0.06% 0.04% 0.03% 0.04% 0.03% 0.01% 0.08% 0.04% 0.05% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.02% 0.01% 0.04% 0.02% 0.03% 0.01% 0.01% 0.28% 0.24% 0.18% 0.19% 0.17% 0.15% 0.25% 0.21% 0.13% 0.13% 0.12% 0.08% 0.07% 0.11% 0.08% 0.07% 0.08% 0.04% 0.01% 0.05% 0.05% 0.05% 0.05% 0.05% 0.03% 0.01% 0.07% 0.04% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.02% 0.01% 0.03% 0.02% 0.03% 0.01% 0.01% 0.18% 0.19% 0.18% 0.19% 0.19% 0.16% 0.14% 0.14% 0.14% 0.11% 0.12% 0.09% 0.07% 0.07% 0.08% 0.05% 0.07% 0.06% 0.04% 0.05% 0.06% 0.05% 0.04% 0.03% 0.04% 0.02% 0.03% 0.03% 0.05% 0.04% 0.04% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.02% 0.03% 0.01% 0.02% 0.18% 0.18% 0.17% 0.17% 0.17% 0.16% 0.15% 0.14% 0.13% 0.13% 0.11% 0.08% 0.07% 0.07% 0.07% 0.07% 0.06% 0.06% 0.06% 0.06% 0.05% 0.05% 0.04% 0.04% 0.04% 0.04% 0.04% 0.04% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.03% 0.02% 0.02% 51 Transport Costs for Exports of Thailand Imported By the United States Transportation Cost as a Percent of Value of Each Product, Average 1996-1999 Reference numbers are HS codes. There are 2 lists: HS2 and HS10 Products are listed in order of value in 1999 All commodities 85 Electrical Machinery And Equipment And Parts There 84 Nuclear Reactors, Boilers, Machinery And Mechanica 03 Fish And Crustaceans, Molluscs And Other Aquatic I 61 Articles Of Apparel And Clothing Accessories, Knit 16 Edible Preparations Of Meat, Fish, Crustaceans, Mo 71 Natural Or Cultured Pearls, Precious Or Semiprecio 62 Articles Of Apparel And Clothing Accessories, Not 40 Rubber And Articles Thereof 42 Articles Of Leather; Saddlery And Harness; Travel 64 Footwear, Gaiters And The Like; Parts Of Such Arti 90 Optical, Photographic, Cinematographic, Measuring, 94 Furniture; Bedding, Cushions Etc.; Lamps And Light 95 Toys, Games And Sports Equipment; Parts And Access 20 Preparations Of Vegetables, Fruit, Nuts, Or Other 44 Wood And Articles Of Wood; Wood Charcoal 25 Salt; Sulfur; Earths And Stone; Plastering Materia 73 Articles Of Iron Or Steel 39 Plastics And Articles Thereof 10 Cereals 69 Ceramic Products 99 Special Import Reporting Provisions, Nesoi 98 Special Classification Provisions, Nesoi 63 Made-Up Textile Articles Nesoi; Needlecraft Sets; 52 Cotton, Including Yarns And Woven Fabrics Thereof 76 Aluminum And Articles Thereof 87 Vehicles, Other Than Railway Or Tramway Rolling St 72 Iron And Steel 91 Clocks And Watches And Parts Thereof 55 Manmade Staple Fibers, Including Yarns And Woven F 21 Miscellaneous Edible Preparations 70 Glass And Glassware 96 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles 27 Mineral Fuels, Mineral Oils And Products Of Their 67 Prepared Feathers And Down And Articles Thereof; A 83 Miscellaneous Articles Of Base Metal 68 Articles Of Stone, Plaster, Cement, Asbestos, Mica 54 Manmade Filaments, Including Yarns And Woven Fabri 74 Copper And Articles Thereof 19 Preparations Of Cereals, Flour, Starch Or Milk; Ba 05 Products Of Animal Origin, Nesoi 48 Paper And Paperboard; Articles Of Paper Pulp, Pape 34 Soap Etc.; Lubricating Products; Waxes, Polishing 23 Residues And Waste From The Food Industries; Prepa 08 Edible Fruit And Nuts; Peel Of Citrus Fruit Or Mel 24 Tobacco And Manufactured Tobacco Substitutes 09 Coffee, Tea, Mate And Spices 49 Printed Books, Newspapers, Pictures And Other Prin 4.0% 2.6% 2.0% 2.8% 5.4% 2.9% 1.2% 4.9% 6.6% 7.2% 4.7% 2.3% 9.5% 7.8% 12.4% 7.6% 39.4% 8.9% 10.5% 14.3% 9.0% 0.0% 1.9% 5.3% 3.4% 5.7% 5.5% 7.3% 3.6% 4.4% 9.2% 11.9% 6.9% 17.1% 9.7% 8.3% 8.3% 5.3% 4.8% 12.0% 6.8% 14.0% 9.2% 7.1% 11.5% 5.4% 5.1% 6.1% 52 92 Musical Instruments; Parts And Accessories Thereof 17 Sugars And Sugar Confectionary 32 Tanning Or Dyeing Extracts; Tannins And Derivative 22 Beverages, Spirits And Vinegar 12 Oil Seeds And Oleaginous Fruits; Miscellaneous Gra 81 Base Metals Nesoi; Cermets; Articles Thereof 82 Tools, Implements, Cutlery, Spoons And Forks, Of B 11 Milling Industry Products; Malt; Starches; Inulin; 65 Headgear And Parts Thereof 57 Carpets And Other Textile Floor Coverings 35 Albuminoidal Substances; Modified Starches; Glues; 59 Impregnated, Coated, Covered Or Laminated Textile 58 Special Woven Fabrics; Tufted Textile Fabrics; Lac 41 Raw Hides And Skins (Other Than Furskins) And Leat 50 Silk, Including Yarns And Woven Fabrics Thereof 66 Umbrellas, Sun Umbrellas, Walking-Sticks, Seat-Sti 33 Essential Oils And Resinoids; Perfumery, Cosmetic 97 Works Of Art, Collectors' Pieces And Antiques 38 Miscellaneous Chemical Products 56 Wadding, Felt And Nonwovens; Special Yarns; Twine, 29 Organic Chemicals 13 Lac; Gums; Resins And Other Vegetable Saps And Ext 06 Live Trees And Other Plants; Bulbs, Roots And The 60 Knitted Or Crocheted Fabrics 18 Cocoa And Cocoa Preparations 07 Edible Vegetables And Certain Roots And Tubers 37 Photographic Or Cinematographic Goods 80 Tin And Articles Thereof 30 Pharmaceutical Products 04 Dairy Produce; Birds' Eggs; Natural Honey; Edible 14 Vegetable Plaiting Materials And Vegetable Product 28 Inorganic Chemicals; Organic Or Inorganic Compound 15 Animal Or Vegetable Fats And Oils And Their Cleava 46 Manufactures Of Straw, Esparto Or Other Plaiting M 36 Explosives; Pyrotechnic Products; Matches; Pyropho 89 Ships, Boats And Floating Structures 88 Aircraft, Spacecraft, And Parts Thereof 86 Railway Or Tramway Locomotives, Rolling Stock, Tra 26 Ores, Slag And Ash 47 Pulp Of Wood Or Other Fibrous Cellulosic Material; 93 Arms And Ammunition; Parts And Accessories Thereof 53 Vegetable Textile Fibers Nesoi; Yarns And Woven Fa 51 Wool And Fine Or Coarse Animal Hair, Including Yar 31 Fertilizers 45 Cork And Articles Of Cork 79 Zinc And Articles Thereof 01 Live Animals 75 Nickel And Articles Thereof 78 Lead And Articles Thereof 43 Furskins And Artificial Fur; Manufactures Thereof 5.4% 11.2% 4.3% 10.3% 3.8% 1.7% 4.5% 22.2% 4.8% 10.0% 11.7% 4.0% 6.6% 3.9% 3.7% 4.7% 6.8% 3.0% 8.7% 11.5% 11.8% 8.7% 41.9% 13.6% 3.2% 10.6% 0.8% 4.3% 5.7% 7.6% 16.6% 16.1% 7.2% 15.7% 16.4% 10.3% 4.8% 14.8% 3.7% 23.0% 4.6% 10.1% 5.5% 14.3% 5.3% 8.0% 17.0% 7.9% 14.8% 15.1% 53 Transportation Costs (Continued) 10 Digit HS codes listed in order of value of exports to the US in 1999 8471704065 Hard Disk Drive Unt, Nesoi, W/Out Extnl Powr Suply 8471603500 Color Cathode-Ray Tube (Crt) Monitors 0306130040 Shrimps And Prawns, Peeled, Frozen 1605201030 Shrimps And Prawns, Prepared Nesoi, Frozen 7113195000 Gold Or Platinum Jewelry, Plt/Cld Or Not, Nesoi 8471606400 Printers, Nesoi, Ink Jet 8542138072 Monolithic Ic, Digital, Silicon,(Mos),(Asic),(Pla) 4015110000 Surgical & Med Glove, Vulcanize Rubber, Nesoi 8544300000 Insulated Wiring Sets For Vehicles Ships Aircraft 8542300065 Monolithic Ic, Operating Frequency <100 Mhz,Analog 8517210000 Facsimile Machines 1604143040 Tunas/Skipjack Nesoi No Oil Airtite Cntr Over 7kg 9009120000 Electrostatic Photocopying Image, Indirect Process 4202128070 Trunks,Suitcases,Vanity Case,Etc,Of Man-Made Fiber 8504406012 Power Suppls Fr Inc Into Adp Mach/Units, 150-500w 7113115000 Slvr Jwlry Etc Val Ov $18 Per Doz Pcs 9999950000 Estimated Imports Of Low Valued Transactions 9403608080 Wooden Furniture, Nesoi 8517110000 Line Telephone Sets With Cordless Handsets 8521106000 Video Cassette & Cartridge Recorder/Players, Color 8542300090 Monolithic Ic, Freq.,<100 Mhg(Analog/Digital)Nesoi 2523290000 Portland Cement, Other Than White Portland Cement 8528121201 Tv Rec,Non-Hi Def,Col,Sngl Pict Tub N/O 34.29cm 8542138051 Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Exc Vol(Eeprom) < 80,000 Bits 4202923031 Travel,Sportsbags,Etc,Not Backpacks,Manmade-Fiber 1006309010 Rice, Semi/Wholly Milled, Nesoi, Long Grain 8473305000 Pts & Accessories Of Mach Of Heading Of 8471,Nesoi 8542138060 Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Ex Vol,(Eprom) > 900,000 Bits 0306130015 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 67-88 Per Kg Frzn 8473301000 Prts Of Adp Mch, Not Incrprtng Crt,Prt Crct Assem. 6105100010 Men'S Shirts Of Cotton, Knit 8471602000 Keyboard Units 4414000000 Wooden Frames Paintings, Photographs, Mirrors, Etc 8414510030 Ceiling Fans,Perm Inst,Slf-Cont Elec Mtr < 125w 6111206020 Babies' Grmnts & Clthng Access Sets Of Cotton,Knit 8471704035 Floppy Disk Drive Unt, Nesoi, W/Out Extrnl Pow Spy 8528123235 Tv Rec,Non-Hi,Col,Sing Tube,Non-Proj,Disp Ex 45-50 7615193000 Aluminum Cooking & Kitchen Ware Enameled Not Cast 2008200090 Pineapples, Prepared Or Preserved, Nesoi 8528122800 Recp App Fr Tv,No-Hi,Col,Sing Pct Tube,Disp >35.56 7103910020 Sapphires Cut But Not Set For Jewelry 8528122025 Tv Rec,Non-Hi,Col,Sin Pct Tube,Non-Proj, > 26 Cm 6403999030 Ftwr S R/P U-L Exc Pgskn V>2.50pr Tenis Women Miss 0306130012 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 56-66 Per Kg Frzn 9503900045 Toys And Models, Nesoi 8529901300 Prnt Cir Assem,Othr Than Tuner,Pc Brd Or Tv, Nesoi 8471605760 Dot Matrix Printer Units W/ Cntrl & Prt Mechanism 6111206040 Babies' Ot Grmnts & Clothing Access Of Cotton,Knit 8542138057 Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Exc Vol,(Eeprom) >900,000 Bits 8516500030 Microwave Ovens Having Capacity <=22.5 Liters 8518220000 Multiple Loudspeakers,Mounted In Same Enclosure 0.5% 2.7% 2.0% 1.8% 0.7% 1.7% 1.1% 4.3% 4.0% 1.0% 2.7% 4.5% 1.3% 9.1% 2.6% 2.2% 0.0% 10.3% 3.0% 0.9% 1.0% 41.6% 3.9% 1.3% 8.6% 14.1% 2.0% 1.1% 2.3% 1.8% 4.7% 5.2% 5.7% 5.7% 6.9% 1.1% 4.7% 5.2% 15.0% 2.6% 0.7% 5.9% 4.2% 2.1% 5.8% 2.9% 4.0% 5.7% 1.5% 6.7% 12.4% 54 6201933000 M/B Garments Water Resistant; Mmf, Not Knit 8517198080 Multiline Telephones Incl Key, Call Director 7103910010 Rubies Cut But Not Set For Jewelry 8527214040 Motr Veh Radio-Comb(Inc Optical Disc)Playes,Record 6110102030 Women'S Sweaters Of Other Wool Or Fah, Knit 0306130009 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 46-55 Per Kg Frzn 7323930030 Cooking Ware Of Stainless Steel, And Parts Thereof 6107110010 Men'S Underpants And Briefs, Of Cotton, Knit 2523100000 Cement Clinkers 8516500090 Microwave Ovens Having Capacity >31.0 Liters 4001210030 Natural Rubber In Smoked Sheets, Grade 3 8519990045 Optical Disc (Incluiding Compact Disc) Players 4001220025 Technically Specified Natural Rubber, Grade 20 8534000020 Printed Circuits Of Plastic/Glass =>3 Layers, Cndt 6110202075 W/G Other Apparel Of Cotton, Knit 8708915000 Radiators For Vehicles, Nesoi 8542138058 Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Ex Vol,(Eprom) N/O 80,000 Bits 8525408085 Still Image Video Camera,Vdeo Camera Recordr,Nesoi 1605102040 Crabmeat, Prepared, Nesoi, In Airtight Containers 8527211015 Motor Vehicle Radio-Tape Players, Cassette, Stereo 7113112000 Slvr Jwlr Etc Nt Ov $18 Per Doz Pcs Or Pts 6403996040 Ftwr Sol R/P Up Lthr Exc Pigskin Tenis-Gym Shoe Me 6110202065 M/B Other Apparel Of Cotton, Knit 8415100040 Air-Conditioners,Wind/Wall,Self-Contain <2.93kw/Hr 6204624020 Women'S Trousers & Breeches Other Cotton, Not Knit 8542138066 Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos(Asic)&(Pla)Microproces 8bits&< 6111206010 Babies' Sunsuits & Similar Apparel Of Cotton, Knit 0306130006 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 33-45 Per Kg Frzn 1604143020 Tuna, Albacore, No Oil Airtight Cntnr Ov 7kg Nesoi 1604144000 Tunas/Skipjack No Oil, No Airtite Cntr, Over 6.8kg 8528121600 Tv Rec,Non-Hi Def,Col,Singl Pict Tub Diag >33.02cm 9401696010 Hshld Seat W Wooden Frame For Chrs, Exc Uphl Nesoi 0306130018 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 89-110 Per Kg Frz 9018907570 Pts & Accessories Of Dialysis Inst & Apparatus 6212109020 Bras Not Containing Lace Net Or Embroidery Mmf 8528122420 Tv Rec,Non-Hi Def,Col,Sing Pt Tub,Non-Pro, Ov33.02 8471801000 Control Or Adapter Units For Adp Machines 4001210050 Natural Rubber In Smoked Sheets, Nesoi 8504406007 Powr Suppls Fr Inc Into Adp Mach/Units, 50w - 150w 7103991000 Gemstones, Nesoi, Cut But Not Set Suitbl Fr Jewlry 8516500060 Microwave Ovens Having Capacity >22.5l <=31.0l 8525203025 Radio Transcievers, Hand-Held, Freq >400 Mhz 8504408500 Static Converters For Telecommunication Apparatus 6202934500 W/G Garm Desgn Rnwr Mmf <36% Wgt W/Fah N Kt Or Crc 6110303055 W/G Other Sweaters Of Other Manmade Fibers, Knit 4419008000 Tableware And Kitchenware, Of Wood, Nesoi 2009404040 Pineapple Juice, Unfermented, Nesoi, Not Frozen 4202126000 Trunks,Suitcases,Etc,Veg Fiber,Not Pile,Nesoi 2008921040 Fruit/Nut/Plant Mxtrs Canned No Apricot Citrus Etc 4.2% 3.1% 0.5% 0.5% 5.2% 2.2% 4.8% 5.3% 45.2% 6.9% 5.7% 1.1% 8.3% 4.5% 4.7% 3.8% 0.9% 1.7% 2.8% 0.9% 2.7% 4.7% 4.7% 6.0% 6.2% 1.2% 5.3% 2.0% 2.7% 4.3% 1.7% 11.3% 2.4% 3.7% 4.0% 2.5% 2.5% 4.0% 3.4% 1.2% 6.3% 2.4% 12.9% 4.3% 5.6% 10.8% 9.5% 9.9% 13.1% Source: US National Trade Data Base. Numbers represent the percent difference between custom or declared value (FOB) and the price actually paid when collected at the port of entry into the USA (CIF). Shipping costs within the US are not included. 55 Appreciation or Depreciation of Currencies Relative to the US Dollar since 1993 COUNTRY 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 AUSTRALIA 0.0% -7.1% -8.2% -13.1% -8.6% 8.1% 5.3% AUSTRIA 0.0% 2.0% 15.5% 9.9% -4.6% -6.0% -9.9% BELGIUM 0.0% 3.5% 17.3% 11.7% -3.4% -4.8% -8.7% BRAZIL 0.0% -8.8% -15.0% -21.1% -49.7% CANADA 0.0% -5.6% -6.0% -5.4% -6.8% -13.0% -13.2% CHINA,P.R. 0.0% -33.1% -30.9% -30.7% -30.5% -30.4% -30.2% DENMARK 0.0% 2.0% 15.8% 11.8% -1.9% -3.2% -7.2% FINLAND 0.0% 9.4% 30.8% 24.6% 10.2% 7.1% 2.6% FRANCE 0.0% 2.2% 13.6% 10.8% -3.0% -3.9% -8.0% GERMANY 0.0% 2.0% 15.5% 9.9% -4.6% -6.0% -9.9% GREECE 0.0% -5.3% -0.9% -4.6% -16.0% -22.3% -25.0% HONG KONG 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% -0.1% -0.1% -0.3% INDIA 0.0% -0.3% -3.5% -11.9% -13.9% -24.3% -27.4% INDONESIA 0.0% -3.5% -7.3% -11.0% -29.2% -78.8% -73.2% IRELAND 0.0% -2.2% -8.7% -8.4% -3.4% 2.8% 8.3% ITALY 0.0% -2.4% -3.4% 2.0% -7.7% -9.4% -13.4% JAPAN 0.0% 8.7% 18.2% 2.1% -8.2% -15.2% -2.3% MALAYSIA 0.0% -1.9% 2.7% 2.3% -8.6% -34.4% -32.3% MEXICO 0.0% -7.7% -51.5% -58.9% -60.5% -65.9% -67.3% NETHERLANDS 0.0% 2.2% 15.8% 10.2% -4.8% -6.3% -10.2% NEW ZEALAND 0.0% -8.8% -17.5% -21.3% -18.3% 1.0% 2.2% NORWAY 0.0% 0.6% 12.1% 9.9% 0.2% -6.0% -9.0% PORTUGAL 0.0% -2.9% 7.5% 4.4% -8.2% -10.6% -14.4% PAKISTAN 0.0% -7.5% -11.2% -22.2% -31.4% -37.4% -43.1% PHILIPPINES 0.0% 3.5% 5.6% 3.9% -9.4% -33.3% -30.6% SINGAPORE 0.0% 5.8% 14.0% 14.6% 8.8% -3.4% -4.7% SOUTH AFRICA 0.0% -7.9% -9.8% -23.9% -29.0% -40.9% -46.5% SOUTH KOREA 0.0% -0.1% 4.3% 0.1% -15.0% -42.5% -32.3% SPAIN 0.0% -4.8% 2.3% 0.6% -13.0% -14.7% -18.4% SRI LANKA 0.0% -2.0% -5.6% -12.8% -18.3% -25.8% -32.0% SWEDEN 0.0% 1.0% 9.2% 16.2% 2.0% -2.0% -5.8% SWITZERLAND 0.0% 8.2% 25.1% 19.6% 1.8% 1.9% -1.8% TAIWAN 0.0% -0.2% -0.3% -3.8% -8.2% -21.3% -18.3% THAILAND 0.0% 0.7% 1.7% -0.1% -18.5% -38.6% -33.1% UNITED KINGDOM 0.0% -2.0% -4.9% -3.8% -8.3% -9.4% -7.1% VENEZUELA 0.0% -58.1% -64.2% -68.1% -71.2% Notes: EU members' currencies for 1999 are brought forward by using the Euro rate times the original conversion rate as of Jan 1, 1999. Venezuela and Brazil are relative to the dollar in 1995. Source: TFRC, derived from CEIC, and US Federal Reserve Data 56 Appreciation or Depreciation of Currencies Relative to the Thai Baht Since 1993 COUNTRY 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 AUSTRALIA 0.0% -7.7% -9.7% -13.1% 12.1% 76.0% 57.6% AUSTRIA 0.0% 1.3% 13.6% 10.0% 17.0% 53.1% 34.8% BELGIUM 0.0% 2.8% 15.4% 11.8% 18.4% 55.1% 36.6% BRAZIL 0.0% -7.2% 6.0% 30.7% -23.5% CANADA 0.0% -6.2% -7.5% -5.3% 14.3% 41.6% 29.9% CHINA,P.R. 0.0% -33.6% -32.1% -30.6% -14.8% 13.4% 4.4% DENMARK 0.0% 1.4% 13.9% 11.9% 20.4% 57.6% 38.8% FINLAND 0.0% 8.6% 28.7% 24.7% 35.2% 74.4% 53.4% FRANCE 0.0% 1.5% 11.8% 10.9% 19.0% 56.5% 37.6% GERMANY 0.0% 1.3% 13.7% 10.1% 17.0% 53.1% 34.8% GREECE 0.0% -5.9% -2.5% -4.5% 3.1% 26.5% 12.1% HONG KONG 0.0% -0.6% -1.6% 0.1% 22.5% 62.6% 49.1% INDIA 0.0% -1.0% -5.0% -11.8% 5.6% 23.2% 8.5% INDONESIA 0.0% -4.1% -8.8% -10.9% -13.2% -65.5% -60.0% IRELAND 0.0% -2.8% -10.1% -8.3% 18.5% 67.4% 61.9% ITALY 0.0% -3.0% -5.0% 2.1% 13.3% 47.6% 29.5% JAPAN 0.0% 8.0% 16.3% 2.2% 12.5% 38.1% 46.1% MALAYSIA 0.0% -2.6% 1.0% 2.4% 12.1% 6.8% 1.3% MEXICO 0.0% -8.4% -52.3% -58.9% -51.6% -44.4% -51.1% NETHERLANDS 0.0% 1.5% 14.0% 10.3% 16.7% 52.6% 34.4% NEW ZEALAND 0.0% -9.4% -18.9% -21.2% 0.2% 64.5% 52.9% NORWAY 0.0% 0.0% 10.3% 10.0% 22.9% 53.1% 36.0% PORTUGAL 0.0% -3.6% 5.7% 4.5% 12.6% 45.6% 28.0% PAKISTAN 0.0% -8.2% -12.6% -22.1% -15.9% 1.9% -14.9% PHILIPPINES 0.0% 2.8% 3.9% 4.0% 11.2% 8.7% 3.8% SINGAPORE 0.0% 5.1% 12.2% 14.7% 33.4% 57.4% 42.6% SOUTH AFRICA 0.0% -8.5% -11.3% -23.8% -12.9% -3.8% -20.0% SOUTH KOREA 0.0% -0.8% 2.6% 0.2% 4.3% -6.3% 1.3% SPAIN 0.0% -5.4% 0.6% 0.7% 6.7% 39.0% 22.1% SRI LANKA 0.0% -2.6% -7.1% -12.7% 0.2% 20.8% 1.7% SWEDEN 0.0% 0.3% 7.4% 16.3% 25.1% 59.7% 40.9% SWITZERLAND 0.0% 7.4% 23.1% 19.7% 24.9% 66.0% 46.9% TAIWAN 0.0% -0.9% -1.9% -3.7% 12.6% 28.3% 22.2% THAILAND 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% UNITED KINGDOM 0.0% -2.6% -6.4% -3.7% 12.5% 47.6% 38.9% VENEZUELA 0.0% -57.4% -55.4% -47.2% -56.2% Notes: EU members' currencies for 1999 are brought forward by using the Euro rate times the original conversion rate as of Jan 1, 1999. Venezuela and Brazil are relative to the baht in 1995. Source: TFRC, derived from CEIC, and US Federal Reserve Data 57 1998 Wages and Salaries per Employee by Sector, in US dollars Year 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 UNIDO Data from Year 1992 1995 1998 1994 1998 1998 1997 1994 1998 1997 1998 1998 1997 1998 1998 1994 1996 1998 1998 1998 canada china hongkong india indonesia italy japan korea malaysia mexico 1392 564 32145 25883 12549 3790 6881 2706 19404 20698 2599 12423 bangladesh brazil philippines singapore spain thailand taiwan turkey uk usa 7611 30742 38582 TOTAL MANUFACTURING(300) 649 10544 29593 851 23887 Food products(311) 693 6411 25164 706 21965 863 NA 34327 16403 10027 3319 5343 2585 17874 16960 2057 12004 7128 26105 27394 Beverages(313) 925 8952 34471 707 32008 1148 420 40915 26139 12994 5340 5288 4484 25083 28232 2364 15701 9337 34306 37623 Tobacco(314) 316 14078 39133 1291 37608 336 308 24186 57998 21087 2291 11547 2781 NA 30202 3574 21153 10567 68649 51980 Textiles(321) 643 7046 27326 700 21767 1168 NA 26809 13827 10137 3315 5647 2083 15066 14766 2262 10636 5497 23149 26210 Wearing apparel,except footwear(322) 383 NA 15642 766 18713 700 355 20543 9727 8757 2599 4755 1891 11093 11790 2835 8350 4267 17197 19310 Leather products(323) 654 NA 19648 717 25254 845 324 25581 11140 10882 2696 NA 1837 14118 15521 1522 11156 4715 21615 27571 Footwear,except rubber or plastic(324) 1533 NA 16442 717 13924 832 402 20571 13460 8688 2891 5465 1352 15681 10818 1787 9109 4322 22118 22876 Wood products,except furniture(331) 466 5056 27899 543 21814 547 NA 25756 9632 11333 2257 3447 1575 14724 13449 1785 9156 4824 22391 24567 Furniture,except metal(332) 526 5589 21538 594 21601 777 335 25834 17734 11079 2730 3887 1495 13806 14760 1635 10628 4476 26162 23580 Paper and products(341) 1631 11835 33718 664 24506 1442 623 33881 24582 12741 3756 6494 2869 19650 23856 3920 12465 9830 31359 40295 Printing and publishing(342) 827 14255 26363 696 30484 2089 NA 43471 27991 12265 4759 7994 2739 22582 22402 4413 14211 7527 35472 32062 Industrial chemicals(351) 1693 NA 42921 NA 2437 NA 40599 45003 17378 8748 8138 4387 32895 32292 4657 18721 14038 42813 51222 Other chemicals(352) 1384 NA 30947 843 NA 1539 800 45331 39513 13413 5387 10938 6824 33723 30114 3940 13387 13951 37213 44266 Petroleum refineries(353) 4869 NA 41281 1176 NA 4786 1433 NA 55977 NA 11829 NA 16813 NA 43097 15016 28511 20983 42895 62503 Misc. petroleum and coal products(354) 707 NA 35110 1302 NA 1667 370 NA 11459 NA 7573 9201 2833 NA NA 3032 20418 14729 19176 41093 Rubber products(355) 544 11904 33344 824 22146 1466 NA 33815 29920 13408 3808 9020 2757 17874 28121 2044 10901 12708 30193 34065 Plastic products(356) 817 8507 21731 1530 22368 1100 382 30649 20686 11055 3435 5169 2333 15227 20233 2029 11637 6399 26099 29411 Pottery,china,earthenware(361) 486 NA 17636 796 12088 1254 507 29316 24573 9695 3248 6103 2336 NA 19394 1617 11221 8946 23439 27509 Glass and products(362) 1027 NA 28770 796 30157 1378 596 34031 33253 14826 4099 9489 3738 NA 22701 4328 11344 16141 27707 34947 Other non-metallic mineral prod.(369) 366 NA 27207 796 23974 1018 NA 32882 17570 12941 4202 9240 3147 19876 19220 3422 12896 7052 29075 33629 Iron and steel(371) 1151 NA 38912 1324 34607 2056 817 35832 39561 15560 4852 12073 3363 29868 27704 2590 15505 10604 34443 44322 Non-ferrous metals(372) 1006 NA 38303 1082 32843 1524 628 34492 33612 13320 4770 8607 4112 16955 26397 2787 12552 10436 29437 36339 Fabricated metal products(381) 508 NA 24343 747 23737 1507 641 29586 20029 12336 3969 6434 2067 18016 19264 2214 11315 6083 27639 31839 Machinery,except electrical(382) 1059 13241 33149 868 25722 1844 560 34559 29494 13175 5763 5828 2371 17351 25128 2540 12525 8782 36926 47645 Machinery electric(383) 798 13277 36002 1034 24971 1996 566 33742 31471 11990 3947 4931 3055 19473 24905 2874 12828 10660 29781 58329 Transport equipment(384) 997 17215 37085 1019 36090 1908 685 31988 39164 16460 4489 7799 3290 21051 26430 3465 14300 9853 37206 48983 Professional & scientific equipm.(385) 499 NA 27415 847 22165 1528 526 34496 28386 11225 3896 8231 2549 19060 22818 4697 11076 6412 30038 44382 Other manufactured products(390) 393 NA 25091 705 24119 935 NA 25950 16223 10109 2935 7684 1953 16571 16335 1856 10591 6226 24621 27734 Source: Unido Website, www.unido.gov, some data brought forward by appreciating wages by the local cpi, and depreciating by change in US currency. 58 Wages and Salaries in Various Countries as a Percentage of Wages and Salaries in Thailand, per Employee, by Sector, 1998 Year 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 UNIDO Data from Year 1992 1995 1998 1994 1998 1998 1997 1994 1998 1997 1998 1998 1997 1998 1998 1994 1996 1998 1998 1998 canada china hongkong india indonesia italy japan korea malaysia mexico 996 483 146 265 104 Country bangladesh brazil philippines singapore TOTAL MANUFACTURING(300) 25 406 1139 33 919 54 22 1237 Food products(311) 34 312 1224 34 1068 42 NA 1669 798 488 161 260 126 Beverages(313) 39 379 1458 30 1354 49 18 1731 1106 550 226 224 190 Tobacco(314) 9 394 1095 36 1052 9 9 677 1623 590 64 323 78 Textiles(321) 28 312 1208 31 962 52 NA 1185 611 448 147 250 Wearing apparel,except footwear(322) 14 NA 552 27 660 25 13 725 343 309 92 Leather products(323) 43 NA 1291 47 1659 56 21 1681 732 715 Footwear,except rubber or plastic(324) 86 NA 920 40 779 47 23 1151 753 Wood products,except furniture(331) 26 283 1563 30 1222 31 NA 1443 540 Furniture,except metal(332) 32 342 1318 36 1321 48 21 1580 Paper and products(341) 42 302 860 17 625 37 16 Printing and publishing(342) 19 323 597 16 691 47 Industrial chemicals(351) 36 NA 922 NA Other chemicals(352) 35 NA 785 21 Petroleum refineries(353) 32 NA 275 8 Misc. petroleum and coal products(354) 23 NA 1158 Rubber products(355) 27 582 Plastic products(356) 40 419 Pottery,china,earthenware(361) 30 Glass and products(362) 747 spain thailand taiwan turkey uk usa 796 100 478 293 1183 1484 869 825 100 584 347 1269 1332 1061 1194 100 664 395 1451 1592 NA 845 100 592 296 1921 1454 92 666 653 100 470 243 1023 1159 168 67 391 416 100 295 151 607 681 177 NA 121 928 1020 100 733 310 1420 1812 486 162 306 76 878 605 100 510 242 1238 1280 635 126 193 88 825 754 100 513 270 1255 1377 1085 678 167 238 91 845 903 100 650 274 1601 1443 864 627 325 96 166 73 501 609 100 318 251 800 1028 NA 985 634 278 108 181 62 512 508 100 322 171 804 726 52 NA 872 966 373 188 175 94 706 693 100 402 301 919 1100 NA 39 20 1151 1003 340 137 278 173 856 764 100 340 354 945 1124 NA 32 10 NA 373 NA 79 NA 112 NA 287 100 190 140 286 416 43 NA 55 12 NA 378 NA 250 303 93 NA NA 100 673 486 632 1355 1631 40 1083 72 NA 1654 1464 656 186 441 135 874 1376 100 533 622 1477 1666 1071 75 1102 54 19 1510 1019 545 169 255 115 750 997 100 573 315 1286 1449 NA 1091 49 748 78 31 1813 1520 600 201 377 144 NA 1200 100 694 553 1450 1702 24 NA 665 18 697 32 14 786 768 343 95 219 86 NA 525 100 262 373 640 807 Other non-metallic mineral prod.(369) 11 NA 795 23 701 30 NA 961 513 378 123 270 92 581 562 100 377 206 850 983 Iron and steel(371) 44 NA 1502 51 1336 79 32 1384 1528 601 187 466 130 1153 1070 100 599 409 1330 1711 Non-ferrous metals(372) 36 NA 1374 39 1178 55 23 1237 1206 478 171 309 148 608 947 100 450 374 1056 1304 Fabricated metal products(381) 23 NA 1099 34 1072 68 29 1336 904 557 179 291 93 814 870 100 511 275 1248 1438 Machinery,except electrical(382) 42 521 1305 34 1013 73 22 1361 1161 519 227 229 93 683 989 100 493 346 1454 1876 Machinery electric(383) 28 462 1253 36 869 69 20 1174 1095 417 137 172 106 678 867 100 446 371 1036 2030 Transport equipment(384) 29 497 1070 29 1042 55 20 923 1130 475 130 225 95 608 763 100 413 284 1074 1414 Professional & scientific equipm.(385) 11 NA 584 18 472 33 11 734 604 239 83 175 54 406 486 100 236 137 640 945 Other manufactured products(390) 21 NA 1352 38 1299 50 NA 1398 874 545 158 414 105 893 880 100 571 335 1326 1494 Source: Unido Website, www.unido.gov, some data brought forward by appreciating wages by the local cpi, and depreciating by change in US currency, china data brought forward as ratio to total mfg wage 59 Tariff Rates for Exports of Thailand Imported By the USA Top 100 exports to the US listed by HS code Products are listed in order of value in 1999 Thailand 0306130006 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 33-45 Per Kg Frzn 0306130009 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 46-55 Per Kg Frzn 0306130012 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 56-66 Per Kg Frzn 0306130015 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 67-88 Per Kg Frzn 0306130018 Shrimp/Prawn Shell-On Count Size 89-110 Per Kg Frz 0306130040 Shrimps And Prawns, Peeled, Frozen 1006309010 Rice, Semi/Wholly Milled, Nesoi, Long Grain 1.4c/kg 1604143020 Tuna, Albacore, No Oil Airtight Cntnr Ov 7kg Nesoi 12.5% 1604143040 Tunas/Skipjack Nesoi No Oil Airtite Cntr Over 7kg 12.5% 1604144000 Tunas/Skipjack No Oil, No Airtite Cntr, Over 6.8kg 1.1c/kg 1605102040 Crabmeat, Prepared, Nesoi, In Airtight Containers 1605201030 Shrimps And Prawns, Prepared Nesoi, Frozen 2008200090 Pineapples, Prepared Or Preserved, Nesoi 35c/kg 2008921040 Fruit/Nut/Plant Mxtrs Canned No Apricot Citrus Etc 5.6% 2009404040 Pineapple Juice, Unfermented, Nesoi, Not Frozen 1c/lt 2523100000 Cement Clinkers 2523290000 Portland Cement, Other Than White Portland Cement 4001210030 Natural Rubber In Smoked Sheets, Grade 3 4001210050 Natural Rubber In Smoked Sheets, Nesoi 4001220025 Technically Specified Natural Rubber, Grade 20 4015110000 Surgical & Med Glove, Vulcanize Rubber, Nesoi 4202126000 Trunks,Suitcases,Etc,Veg Fiber,Not Pile,Nesoi 6.0% 4202128070 Trunks,Suitcases,Vanity Case,Etc,Of Man-Made Fiber 18.6% 4202923031 Travel,Sportsbags,Etc,Not Backpacks,Manmade-Fiber 18.6% 4414000000 Wooden Frames Paintings, Photographs, Mirrors, Etc 4419008000 Tableware And Kitchenware, Of Wood, Nesoi 6105100010 Men'S Shirts Of Cotton, Knit 20.2% 6107110010 Men'S Underpants And Briefs, Of Cotton, Knit 7.6% 6110102030 Women'S Sweaters Of Other Wool Or Fah, Knit 16.4% 6110202065 M/B Other Apparel Of Cotton, Knit 18.2% 6110202075 W/G Other Apparel Of Cotton, Knit 18.2% 6110303055 W/G Other Sweaters Of Other Manmade Fibers, Knit 32.9% 6111206010 Babies' Sunsuits & Similar Apparel Of Cotton, Knit 8.6% 6111206020 Babies' Grmnts & Clthng Access Sets Of Cotton,Knit 8.6% 6111206040 Babies' Ot Grmnts & Clothing Access Of Cotton,Knit 7.3% 6201933000 M/B Garments Water Resistant; Mmf, Not Knit 7.3% 6202934500 W/G Garm Desgn Rnwr Mmf <36% Wgt W/Fah N Kt Or Crc 17.0% 6204624020 Women'S Trousers & Breeches Other Cotton, Not Knit 17.3% 6212109020 Bras Not Containing Lace Net Or Embroidery Mmf 8.5% 6403996040 Ftwr Sol R/P Up Lthr Exc Pigskin Tenis-Gym Shoe Me 10.0% 6403999030 Ftwr S R/P U-L Exc Pgskn V>2.50pr Tenis Women Miss 7103910010 Rubies Cut But Not Set For Jewelry 7103910020 Sapphires Cut But Not Set For Jewelry 7103991000 Gemstones, Nesoi, Cut But Not Set Suitbl Fr Jewlry 7113112000 Slvr Jwlr Etc Nt Ov $18 Per Doz Pcs Or Pts 7113115000 Slvr Jwlry Etc Val Ov $18 Per Doz Pcs 5%* 7113195000 Gold Or Platinum Jewelry, Plt/Cld Or Not, Nesoi 7323930030 Cooking Ware Of Stainless Steel, And Parts Thereof 7615193000 Aluminum Cooking & Kitchen Ware Enameled Not Cast Mexico 0.6c/kg 6.6% 6.6% 0.5c/kg 2.1% 1.9% 6.0% 6.0% 5.1% 6.0% 6.0% 2.5% 3.0% 60 8414510030 8415100040 8471602000 8471603500 8471605760 8471606400 8471704035 8471704065 8471801000 8473301000 8473305000 8504406007 8504406012 8504408500 8516500030 8516500060 8516500090 8517110000 8517198080 8517210000 8518220000 8519990045 8521106000 8525203025 8525408085 8527211015 8527214040 8528121201 8528121600 8528122025 8528122420 8528122800 8528123235 8529901300 8534000020 8542138051 8542138057 8542138058 8542138060 8542138066 8542138072 8542300065 8542300090 8544300000 8708915000 9009120000 9018907570 9401696010 9403608080 9503900045 9999950000 Ceiling Fans,Perm Inst,Slf-Cont Elec Mtr < 125w Air-Conditioners,Wind/Wall,Self-Contain <2.93kw/Hr Keyboard Units Color Cathode-Ray Tube (Crt) Monitors Dot Matrix Printer Units W/ Cntrl & Prt Mechanism Printers, Nesoi, Ink Jet Floppy Disk Drive Unt, Nesoi, W/Out Extrnl Pow Spy Hard Disk Drive Unt, Nesoi, W/Out Extnl Powr Suply Control Or Adapter Units For Adp Machines Prts Of Adp Mch, Not Incrprtng Crt,Prt Crct Assem. Pts & Accessories Of Mach Of Heading Of 8471,Nesoi Powr Suppls Fr Inc Into Adp Mach/Units, 50w - 150w Power Suppls Fr Inc Into Adp Mach/Units, 150-500w Static Converters For Telecommunication Apparatus Microwave Ovens Having Capacity <=22.5 Liters Microwave Ovens Having Capacity >22.5l <=31.0l Microwave Ovens Having Capacity >31.0 Liters Line Telephone Sets With Cordless Handsets Multiline Telephones Incl Key, Call Director Facsimile Machines Multiple Loudspeakers,Mounted In Same Enclosure Optical Disc (Incluiding Compact Disc) Players Video Cassette & Cartridge Recorder/Players, Color Radio Transcievers, Hand-Held, Freq >400 Mhz Still Image Video Camera,Vdeo Camera Recordr,Nesoi Motor Vehicle Radio-Tape Players, Cassette, Stereo Motr Veh Radio-Comb(Inc Optical Disc)Playes,Record Tv Rec,Non-Hi Def,Col,Sngl Pict Tub N/O 34.29cm Tv Rec,Non-Hi Def,Col,Singl Pict Tub Diag >33.02cm Tv Rec,Non-Hi,Col,Sin Pct Tube,Non-Proj, > 26 Cm Tv Rec,Non-Hi Def,Col,Sing Pt Tub,Non-Pro, Ov33.02 Recp App Fr Tv,No-Hi,Col,Sing Pct Tube,Disp >35.56 Tv Rec,Non-Hi,Col,Sing Tube,Non-Proj,Disp Ex 45-50 Prnt Cir Assem,Othr Than Tuner,Pc Brd Or Tv, Nesoi Printed Circuits Of Plastic/Glass =>3 Layers, Cndt Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Exc Vol(Eeprom) < 80,000 Bits Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Exc Vol,(Eeprom) >900,000 Bits Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Ex Vol,(Eprom) N/O 80,000 Bits Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos,Ex Vol,(Eprom) > 900,000 Bits Mono Ic,Dig,Sil,Mos(Asic)&(Pla)Microproces 8bits&< Monolithic Ic, Digital, Silicon,(Mos),(Asic),(Pla) Monolithic Ic, Operating Frequency <100 Mhz,Analog Monolithic Ic, Freq.,<100 Mhg(Analog/Digital)Nesoi Insulated Wiring Sets For Vehicles Ships Aircraft Radiators For Vehicles, Nesoi Electrostatic Photocopying Image, Indirect Process Pts & Accessories Of Dialysis Inst & Apparatus Hshld Seat W Wooden Frame For Chrs, Exc Uphl Nesoi Wooden Furniture, Nesoi Toys And Models, Nesoi Estimated Imports Of Low Valued Transactions 2%* 2%* 2%* 3.9%* 5.0% 5.0% 2.9% 5%* 3.7%* Source: Harmonized Tariff Schedule of the United States (2000) Note: Figures marked with a (*) have had GSP privileges revoked. If the column is blank then there is no tariff for that item. Some items, such as apparel and textiles, face quotas as well as tariffs. 61 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 030613 Shrimps and Prawns 900 800 700 Thailand US Million Dollars 600 Ecuador Mexico 500 Indonesia India Bangladesh 400 Venezuela Vietnam 300 Honduras 200 100 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 1006 Rice 160 140 120 US Million Dollars Thailand India 100 China Pakistan Italy 80 Mexico Australia 60 Egypt Canada 40 20 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 16 Edible Preparations Of Meat, Fish, Crustaceans, Molluscs Or Other Aqua 800 700 US Million Dollars 600 500 Thailand Canada Brazil 400 Indonesia Ecuador Philippines 300 200 100 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 62 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 20 Preparations Of Vegetables, Fruit, Nuts, Or Other Parts Of Plants 500 450 400 US Million Dollars 350 Canada 300 Spain Mexico 250 Brazil Thailand 200 Philippines 150 100 50 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 4015 Rubber Gloves and Aprons 700 600 500 US Million Dollars Malaysia Thailand Indonesia 400 China Mexico Sri Lanka 300 United Kingdom Taiwan India 200 100 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 42 Leather and Products Thereof 3,500 3,000 2,500 US Million Dollars China Italy Thailand 2,000 Philippines Indonesia Korea 1,500 Mexico India Taiwan 1,000 500 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 63 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 4414 Wooden Frames 120 100 Mexico US Million Dollars 80 China Thailand Indonesia Taiwan 60 Canada Italy India 40 Malaysia 20 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 61 Articles of Apparel and Clothing Accessories, Knitted or Crocheted 3,500 3,000 2,500 US Million Dollars Mexico Hong Kong China 2,000 Honduras Taiwan Korea 1,500 El Salvador Dominican Rep Thailand 1,000 500 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 62 Articles of Apparel and Clothing Accessories, Not Knitted or Crocheted 5,000 4,500 4,000 US Million Dollars 3,500 Mexico China 3,000 Hong Kong Dominican Rep Indonesia 2,500 Bangladesh India 2,000 Korea Philippines 1,500 1,000 500 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 64 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 64 Articles of Footwear 9,000 8,000 7,000 China US Million Dollars 6,000 Italy Brazil 5,000 Indonesia Mexico Spain 4,000 Thailand United Kingdom 3,000 Dominican Rep 2,000 1,000 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 711311 Articles of Jewelry, Of Silver 180 160 140 Italy US Million Dollars 120 Thailand China 100 Mexico Dominican Rep Indonesia 80 Canada India 60 Hong Kong 40 20 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 711319 Articles of Jewelry, Of Gold or Other Precious Metals 1,400 1,200 1,000 US Million Dollars Italy India Hong Kong 800 Thailand Israel Turkey 600 Canada Dominican Rep Mexico 400 200 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 65 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 8471 Computers and Parts 12,000 10,000 Japan US Million Dollars 8,000 Singapore Taiwan Mexico China 6,000 Malaysia Korea Thailand 4,000 Philippines 2,000 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 8471704065 Hard Magnetic Disk Drive Units, Nesoi, Not Assembled In Cabine 8000 7000 US Million Dollars 6000 Singapore 5000 Japan Malaysia Thailand 4000 Philippines Hungary 3000 China 2000 1000 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 8471606400 Printers, Nesoi, Ink Jet (SIC3577) 1200 1000 US Million Dollars 800 Mexico Malaysia Singapore 600 Thailand China Japan 400 200 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 66 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 8471603500 Color Cathode-Ray Tube (Crt) Monitors (SIC3577) 2000 1800 1600 US Million Dollars 1400 Mexico China 1200 Korea, Republic Of China (Taiwan) Japan 1000 Thailand Malaysia 800 Indonesia Philippines 600 400 200 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 8542 Integrated Circuits 12,000 10,000 Korea US Million Dollars 8,000 Japan Malaysia Philippines Taiwan 6,000 Singapore Canada Hong Kong 4,000 Thailand 2,000 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 851650 Microwave Ovens 500 450 400 US Million Dollars 350 Korea China 300 Thailand Malaysia Singapore 250 Sweden Germany 200 Japan Taiwan 150 100 50 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 67 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 8521 Video Cassette Players and Recorders 1,800 1,600 1,400 Japan US Million Dollars 1,200 China Malaysia 1,000 Indonesia Mexico Korea 800 Thailand Singapore 600 India 400 200 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 854430 Ignition Wiring Sets 4,500 4,000 3,500 Mexico US Million Dollars 3,000 Philippines Thailand 2,500 China Canada Japan 2,000 Indonesia Honduras 1,500 France 1,000 500 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 U.S. Imports from Various Countries of: 870891 Radiators 250 200 US Million Dollars Mexico Thailand 150 Canada Japan China Indonesia Korea 100 Germany Philippines 50 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Sources for this series of tables: USITC Dataweb, US National Trade Data Base 68 Share of World GDP and Trade for Some Selected Countries. Trade as a share of GDP included as a measure of how externally-oriented economies are. Country GDP Trade, Exports Trade, Imports % of World Total % of World Total % of World Total 1992 1998 1992 1998 1992 1998 United States 25.7% 27.4% 11.8% 12.6% 14.6% 17.6% Japan 15.9% 14.2% 9.5% 7.2% 6.1% 5.2% Germany 7.8% 7.4% 12.0% 10.0% 10.8% 8.7% France 5.7% 5.1% 6.5% 5.7% 6.3% 5.4% United Kingdom 3.9% 4.4% 5.3% 5.0% 5.9% 5.9% Italy 5.3% 4.0% 5.0% 4.4% 4.9% 4.0% China 2.2% 3.2% 2.4% 3.4% 2.1% 2.6% Brazil 1.6% 2.6% 1.0% 0.9% 0.6% 1.1% Canada 2.1% 2.1% 3.7% 4.0% 3.2% 3.8% Spain 2.5% 1.9% 1.8% 2.0% 2.6% 2.5% India 0.9% 1.5% 0.6% 0.6% 0.6% 0.8% Netherlands 1.4% 1.3% 3.9% 3.7% 3.6% 3.4% Mexico 1.4% 1.3% 0.8% 2.2% 1.3% 2.4% Australia 1.3% 1.3% 1.1% 1.0% 1.1% 1.2% Korea, Rep 1.3% 1.3% 2.1% 2.5% 2.2% 1.7% Russia 1.7% 1.2% 1.1% 1.4% 1.0% 1.1% Argentina 1.0% 1.1% 0.3% 0.5% 0.4% 0.6% Switzerland 1.0% 1.0% 1.8% 1.5% 1.7% 1.5% Belgium 0.9% 0.9% 3.4% 3.2% 3.3% 3.0% Sweden 1.0% 0.8% 1.6% 1.6% 1.3% 1.3% Hong Kong 0.3% 0.5% 0.8% 3.2% 3.3% 3.5% Indonesia 0.5% 0.5% 0.9% 0.9% 0.7% 0.5% Thailand 0.48% 0.47% 0.91% 0.99% 1.07% 0.78% Singapore 0.2% 0.3% 1.8% 2.0% 1.9% 1.9% Malaysia 0.2% 0.3% 1.1% 1.4% 1.0% 1.1% Philippines 0.2% 0.3% 0.3% 0.5% 0.4% 0.6% Vietnam 0.1% 0.2% 0.2% Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% Source: Calculated from World Development Report 1999/2000 Trade, Imports & Exports As a % of GDP 1992 1998 16.4% 20.5% 15.5% 16.3% 46.8% 47.4% 35.7% 40.5% 45.6% 46.6% 29.7% 39.0% 32.7% 34.9% 16.4% 14.8% 51.4% 68.5% 28.5% 43.7% 19.7% 18.1% 85.6% 98.4% 22.8% 64.7% 27.2% 31.7% 53.3% 61.3% 19.8% 39.5% 11.8% 17.5% 54.3% 55.7% 113.3% 127.6% 47.9% 67.0% 197.6% 229.2% 48.3% 55.1% 66.18% 70.96% 294.6% 222.2% 137.3% 165.2% 48.2% 77.7% 78.1% 31.9% 37.3%