POWER RELATIONSHIPS ALONG THE SUPPLYCHAIN: MULTINATIONAL FIRMS, GLOBAL BUYERS, AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS’ PERFORMANCE Carlo Pietrobelli Federica Saliola CREI, University of Rome 3 CREI, University of Rome 3 c.pietrobelli@uniroma3.it and The World Bank Development Research Group1 saliola@uniroma3.it Introduction The increasing globalization of the world economy has changed the economic setting faced by industries and individual firms in developing countries, as they have in the industrialized world. Two important features have been the increasing fragmentation of production processes and the evolution of internationally-dispersed but functionally-integrated economic activities. These transformations have also led to the spread across countries of Global Value Chains, with a variety of network forms of governance situated between arm’s length markets and large vertically integrated corporation. Global Buyers have been key agents in this transformation by creating international production and distribution networks between firms and subsidiaries operating in and among different locations, and undertaking the functional integration and co-ordination of these 1 The authors would like to thank Giuseppe Iarossi and Giovanni Tanzillo for making the data available. We also wish to thank Jens Matthias Arnold, Davide Castellani, Beata Smarzynska Javorcik and Antonello Zanfei for helpful comments. Financial contributions from the PRIN project on “Capabilities dinamiche tra organizzazione di impresa e sistemi locali di produzione” are gratefully acknowledged. The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. Page 1 of 21 activities. Through these networks, Global Buyers might play a significant role in influencing the worldwide generation and exploitation of knowledge and technology, and offering learning opportunities to their suppliers along a “supply chain”, often in developing countries. Since multinational companies (MNCs) have mediated a large fraction of world trade in recent years, in this paper we focus on the role of multinationals acting as Global Buyers. The purpose of this study is threefold. First, we investigate the relationship between MNCs and their local supplier’ performance. The role of MNCs is not confined to production but increasingly extends to planning and management of global networks of suppliers and firms. Therefore, instead of concentrating merely on the case of the relationships between MNCs and their majority-owned suppliers (i.e. MNCs’ subsidiaries) we consider MNCs sourcing their inputs from developing countries’ firms – both independent and equity-controlled by the same MNC. Second, we include in the analysis the issue of the “governance” of the value chain, looking at the way the buyer-supplier relationship is coordinated and at the strategic role played by the buyers along the supply chain. The concept of governance is especially important in view of the impact it may have on suppliers’ efficiency in developing countries. We particularly focus on the differences between firms which are part of a multinational's production and distribution network and firms which participate in supply chains led by national buyers. Finally, we attempt to study which firms’ characteristics are more correlated to different types of supply chains’ governance. The analysis has been carried out with new microeconomic evidence from Thailand on a sample of 1,385 manufacturing firms from 2001 to 2003. Related Research The importance of Global Buyers has been emphasized by several schools of thought. Among these, in the 1990s Gereffi and others developed a framework called “global commodity chains” that tied the concept of the value-added chain directly to the global organization of industries (see Gereffi and Korzeniewicz 1994). This work not only highlighted the importance of coordination across and beyond firm boundaries, but also the growing importance of new global buyers (mainly retailers and brand marketers) as key drivers in the formation of globally dispersed and organizationally fragmented production and distribution networks. The recent “global value chain approach” (GVC) (Gereffi, 1999; Gereffi and Kaplinsky, 2001; Schmitz 2004) focuses on the role of global buyers in defining upgrading opportunities for their suppliers. They pay particular attention to the position of developing country firms selling to large, global buyers. This literature stresses the role played by the GVC leaders, and particularly by the buyers, in transferring knowledge along the chains, and thereby affecting firms’ learning and performance.. Page 2 of 21 The concept of internal governance of the value chain is central in the analysis. We use the term governance to denote co-ordination of economic activities through non market relationships. The internal governance of the value chain importantly affects the generation, transfer and diffusion of knowledge and the scope of local firms’ upgrading (Humphrey and Schmitz, 2000). The literature highlights two critical parameters of the value chain governance: what is to be produced, and how it is to be produced. “In each case, the level of detail at which the parameters are specified can vary. In the case of product definition, the buyer can provide different levels of specification. It can set a design problem for the producer, which the producer then solves by providing its technology and design. The buyer might provide a particular design for the producer to work on, or the buyer might even provide detailed drawings for the producer. Buyers can also specify process parameters. Once again, these can be specified at different levels of detail. In some cases, the buyer may merely refer to the process standards to be attained. In other cases, the buyer will specify precisely how particular standards should be attained by requiring and perhaps helping to introduce particular production processes, monitoring procedures, etc. When the buyer plays this role, we refer to it as the "lead firm" in the chain” (Sturgeon 2001). A recent study by Gereffi, Humphrey and Sturgeon (2003) proposes a more complex typology of the governance structure of the chain, highlighting three central factors: “the complexity of information and knowledge transfer required to sustain a particular transaction; the extent to which this information and knowledge can be codified; the capabilities of actual and potential suppliers in relation to the requirements of the transaction”. The second body of literature to which our paper relates is the empirical work on multinational firms. The literature has traditionally considered MNCs as possessing some technological lead and exploiting this proprietary advantage in international markets (Dunning, 1993), and thereby potentially creating opportunities for knowledge diffusion and learning for their local suppliers. Moreover, in response to the rising importance of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), a recent theoretical literature has focused on the relationship among multinationals, foreign direct investments and spillovers, and on the impact these may have on local industry.2 Within this framework, recent papers have provided evidence of positive FDI spillovers through vertical linkages along supply chains (backward linkages).3 In particular, they emphasize two arguments to suggest that supply chains may be a conduit for technology transfer. First, insofar as multinationals seek to minimize technology leakage to competitors, they have 2 This vast literature has been effectively surveyed by Blomstrom and Kokko (1996), Saggi (2002), and others. Yet this literature has not been reached consensus. In one of the most cited papers on FDI spillovers, Aitken and Harrison (1999) show absence of spillovers in Venezuelan manufacturing; Djankov and Hoekman (2000) found similar results for Czech Republic, and Jozef Konings (2001) for Bulgaria, Romania, and Poland. Others instead suggest the existence of spillovers in industrialized countries, as the study by Jonathan E. Haskel et al. (2002) and Wolfgang Keller and Stephen R. Yeaple (2003). 3 See Schoors and van der Tol (2001), Lopez-Cordova (2002), Javorcik (2004) and Blalock and Gertler (2005) Page 3 of 21 incentives to improve the productivity of their suppliers through training, quality control, and inventory management. To reduce dependency on a single supplier, the multinational may establish such relationships with multiple vendors, and benefits spill over all firms which purchase these vendors’ output. Second, while the technology gap between foreign and domestic producers may limit within-sector technology transfer, multinationals are likely to procure inputs requiring less sophisticated production techniques (for which the gap is narrower and technology transfer easier). A third body of literature to which our work relates includes the studies on “knowledge transfer and co-ordination through supply-chain relationships” (Dunning 1993; Turok, 1993; Albio et al., 1999; Beecham and Cordey-Hayes, 1998; Best, 1991; Lincoln et al., 1998; HewittDundas et al. 2002) which emphasize the importance of inter-firm linkages “as mechanisms of technology transfer … collaboration as part of normal trading relationships between firms may prove the most important means of technology transfer” (Phelps, 1996). This literature highlights that the realization of these potential knowledge transfers depends on ‘the extent to which the technology of multinationals is made available to potential users and that ‘beneficial effects will occur only if the foreign affiliates of TNCs do become linked to local firms. Furthermore, Dunning (1993) suggests that deliberate knowledge transfers will only occur where MNC plants perceive there to be a direct benefit (e.g. improved input quality, reduced cost, or improved service) then it may pay the company to invest resources in upgrading the efficiency of its suppliers’ (Dunning, 1993, p. 456). Research Issues In light of the issues briefly surveyed above, and on the basis of the available empirical evidence, we try to address the following theoretical hypotheses. 1) According to the existing literature, we expect firms involved in multinational's production and distribution networks to perform better than firms selling their products only to domestic buyers. The underlying assumption is that, due to buyer-supplier relationships, firms face remarkable opportunities for acquisition of knowledge and best practices, and for technical and product design assistance. In this context, the role of multinationals acting as buyers can be (positively) significant, whether or not direct ownership links multinationals to their suppliers. Such better performance, however, will also depend upon the fact that foreign investors choose domestic plants with an above average performance, a pattern sometimes called “cherry picking” in the literature (Arnold and Javorcik 2005). These two aspects might spark a process of circular (cumulative) causation between choices made by the multinational and firms’ performance. As for similar research (e.g. “learning by exporting” literature), however, we are conscious of the difficulties to define the direction of causality between MNC buyer-supplier relationships and suppliers’ performance. More precisely, do such relationships cause suppliers’ Page 4 of 21 performance improvements or rather MNCs select more efficient firms as their suppliers? Unluckily, the limited number of years for which data are available cannot help us to establish the direction of causality with sufficient confidence in this paper. 2) One important contribution of our paper is to define a measure of Value Chains’ governance. According to the present framework, we develop a measure which takes into account different levels of buyers’ involvement in the suppliers’ specification of product and process standards and on technology. In addition, we include the nature of the activities in which buyers’ involvement occurs, and we distinguish among Design and Quality, R&D and Technology activities, paying particular attention to the last one (for further details see the section above). The reasons behind our definition are various. First, we believe these dimensions represent important conditioning factors for knowledge transfer; second, as the choice of a “wrong” supplier is onerous for the buyer, it is likely to observe an ex ante selection from MNCs of more efficient firms as their suppliers (i.e. “cherry picking”); and third, they provide possible suggestions about suppliers’ capabilities that in turn are expected to affect the governance structure. We expect different forms of governance, arising in supply chains led by multinationals compared to those led by national buyers. There are several motives to support our belief. First, local suppliers are expected to meet requirements which may vary according to whether they sell their products to a multinational company or not. According to these differences, the coordination of the supply chain, in terms of products specification and the enforcement of standards related to product design and production processes, will be more or less severe. We assume that parameters set by multinational will be more complex, and, for this reason, requiring greater product and process assistance. This assumption does not contrast to the hypothesis of “cherry picking”. MNCs, in fact, carefully select their suppliers if they need to invest to improve their competences; it means that they must posses some specific superior characteristics compared to other firms in the domestic market. 3) Firms’ capabilities We expect the intensity and the extent of Buyers’ influence on suppliers’ performance to vary between firms which are part of multinational’ s network and firms in supply chains led by national buyers. Specifically, we expect that the governance of the supply chain especially matters for domestic value chains. Since, as highlighted above, we assume multinationals’ suppliers to be more productive than domestic firms, we suppose domestic firms heavily depend on the way the buyer assists them in improving products’ features and production processes. In other words, efficiency improvements are expected to be powerfully linked to the governance of the supply chain. Page 5 of 21 Thailand Economy 4 Thailand’s economy has achieved very high rates of growth over the past quarter century, an average of 6 percent per year between 1977 and 2003, and an even higher 8 percent rate in the years prior to the 1997-98 crisis. However growth has been mainly dominated by high rates of capital accumulation. Improvements in total factor productivity (TFP) have been relatively modest and largely due to shifts of labor out of agriculture into higher productivity industry and services. The country is very much in the middle of the pack with respect to growth in both labor productivity and TFP. While the gains in education have been comparable to other countries, the overall level of educational attainment in Thailand is still quite modest relative to countries such as Korea and Taiwan. Empirical evidence presented in the ICA 2005 suggests that poor technological performance in Thailand is related to poor production technological capabilities and weak linkages, both which lead to less innovation. Finally, from the World Bank’s study emerge that firms in Thailand identify the lack of appropriate skills as one the most binding constraints to doing business. More than a third of Thai firms surveyed report inadequate worker skills as a major obstacle to their activities. Concerns about skills of the labor force are pervasive and are felt equally by exporters and non-exporters, by domestic as well as foreign-owned firms. These concerns affect firms in all regions of Thailand, including the North East, which may suggest a changing nature of the labor demand as the manufacturing sector transitions to high-technology products. Estimation Strategy and Main Results The data come from the “Productivity and the Investment Climate Private Enterprise Survey” (PICS), conducted by the World Bank on a representative (stratified) sample of 1,385 Thai firms from 2001 to 2003. The database contains comparable qualitative and quantitative information on firm characteristics. i) Descriptive statistics of Thai multinationals’ suppliers We start the empirical analysis by comparing firms which are suppliers of multinational companies (MNS) to firms which are not (no-MNS) using measures of firm size, wages, sales, innovation and upgrading. The data reveal some major differences between the two groups (Table 1). On average, multinationals’ suppliers are larger, pay higher wages and show a greater value of total sales. The share of firms exporting more than 5% of sales is considerably higher for MNS. Finally, data show that MNS are more likely to introduced new technologies. 4 This paragraph is drawn from the Investment Climate Assessment elaborated by the World Bank in 2005. The analysis is based mainly on the results of the Thailand PICS 2003 surveys, although additional sources are also used, such as the World Bank Doing Business indicators and Transparency International. Page 6 of 21 ii.) Total Factor Productivity and Multinationals' supplier status We study the empirical correlation between firms’ efficiency and multinationals’ supplier status. As the performance measure, we employ total factor productivity, defined as the residual of a Cobb-Douglas production function. In order to take into account the problem of potential correlation between input levels and the unobserved firm-specific productivity shocks in the estimation of production coefficients,5 we carry out a panel data analysis using both parametric and semi parametric techniques to estimate TFP. The semi-parametric estimator is that proposed by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) with intermediate input use serving as a proxy for productivity shocks. More specifically, we utilize the information on the amount of electricity consumed by each plant. As electricity cannot be stored, its consumption is likely to follow changes in production activity more closely than the use of materials (appendix A). Once we estimate our TFP measure, we investigate the existing relationship between firms’ performance and multinational supplier status: TFPi 0 1 Multinational X e (1.1) We perform the analysis separately for the two measure of TFP. In the 1.1, Multinational denotes if firms are suppliers of Multinationals or not; X captures a variety of observed, firmspecific characteristics including size ownership, age, industry, region and year of observation; e is the error term. Table 2 shows the results of estimating equation (1.1). Consistent with previous studies, we find that MNCs’ supplier status is positively correlated with firms’ productivity. Column (1) shows the results obtained through the OLS, while column (2) displays results for the non parametric one. iii.) Firms’ characteristics and multinationals' supplier status. As a third step, we investigate which firms’ characteristics enhance the probability of becoming MNCs’ suppliers. This further step might be helpful in shedding some light about the “cherry picking” phenomenon. As a theoretical model we consider an empirical probit model in which the MNCs’ suppliers status depends on a variety of observed, firm-specific characteristics: MNS (TFP, Skills , Training , R & D, Pr ofessional , X ) (1.2) where TFP is our estimated total factor productivity (parametric and semi parametric respectively), Skills are proxied by the log of average wages, Training indicates whether the firm run training programs, R&D is the log of R&D expenditure, Professional captures the 5 Explain the problem.. Page 7 of 21 share of professional workers, and X is a vector which captures industry, region, size, age and year of observation. We compute the marginal effect of each explanatory variable (dy/dx). Since a multicollinearity problem may arise when the independent variables are significantly correlated among themselves, we compute both parametric and non parametric tests of correlation (i.e. Pearson and Kendall test). Table 3 shows the results of estimating equation (1.2). All the variables considered are significant and positively correlated to the MNCs’ supplier status; only the TFP in its semi parametric specification does not seem very significant. We would be tempted to interpret this result as a sign that firms which become multinational suppliers have better characteristics a priori, and that a self selection mechanism is taking place. However, due to the lack of information, we cannot test this hypothesis properly. iv.) Total Factor Productivity and supply chains' governance Next, we include the governance of the supply chain into the analysis. We define five types of governance of the supply chain by using different combinations of the following key variables (Table A): - Percentage of sales made exclusively to (suit) buyer’s unique specification - Whether the buyer provided information on design/quality (product characteristics) and imposed product quality standards (DQ) - Whether the buyer engaged the firm in process or product R&D type of activities (RD) - Whether the buyer developed technology in cooperation with supplier firms and if it sent employees (personnel exchanges) to disseminate and diffuse new technologies into firms’ production facility (Tech). It should be mentioned that our index does not intend to reflect a growing involvement of buyers with their suppliers in all aspects of production, but rather focuses on specific (crucial) elements of the buyer-supplier relationship as setting product standards, quality requirements, and technology support. Using Type A as baseline category, we investigate the relationship between governance and firms’ efficiency through the following specification: TFPi 0 1TypeB 2TypeC 3TypeD 4TypeE X ei (1.3) where X captures again firms’ specific characteristics. We estimate two different specifications of the above equation: first, we take our entire sample, and then we look at the sub samples of firms which are suppliers of multinational and firms which are not. Again, we compute both parametric and non parametric tests for correlation among independent variables. Page 8 of 21 Table 4 documents some descriptive evidence about the differences between MNS and nonMNS in terms of their relationships with buyers. We do not observe significant differences between the two groups in terms of percentage of sales made exclusively to buyers' unique specification. In a different way, for almost half of MNS surveyed, buyers get engaged in their suppliers’ process or product R&D (30% for no-MNS); finally buyers send their experts to work to disseminate and diffuse new technologies to the supplier’s more often in MNS (45% versus 25% of no-MNS). Table A – Classification of Supply Chains’ governance Types of Supply Chains’ Governance % of sales made according to buyers’ unique specification Design/qua lity and product quality standards Technology and process and product R&D Type A Less than 20% No No More than 20% No No More than 20% Yes No More than 20% No Yes More than 20% Yes Yes Low requirements Type B Higher requirements Type C Higher requirements&DQ Type D Higher requirements&Tech_RD Type E Higher requirements&DQ&Tech_RD Table 5 presents the results of estimating equation (1.3). Columns (1-3) uses parametric techniques, and columns (4-6) non parametric ones. While the results for the whole sample show a significant relationship between firms’ productivity and both governance Type C and Type E, the picture emerging from the two sub-samples suggests a different conclusion. Data reveal that the way the supply chain is organized does not matter for local firms supplying multinational buyers (MNS), although it is very relevant for non MNCs’ suppliers. “Domestic firms” (no-MNS) with high customization of products to buyers’ standard, which also receive assistance about design & quality definition and technology (Type E), seem to be more productive. Can we interpret these results to suggest that firms participating in national VCs rely on a greater involvement of the chain leader to foster their process of learning and efficiency improvement? Once again we should interpret these results very cautiously, due to the problem of causality. On the one hand, MNCs may select their suppliers among the most Page 9 of 21 efficient firms – and indeed firms which are suppliers of multinationals are more efficient than “domestic” firms. We may explain this for example by observing that firms are often forced to improve their efficiency before starting the relationship with the MNCs in order to qualify as MNCs’ suppliers, therefore the form of governance of the VC would not matter for them.6 On the other hand, if the self-selection hypothesis were not confirmed, the test of the existence of a learning process would require longer (dynamic) observations. Another possible explanation of these results might be due to the different nature of the information and knowledge exchanged along global and domestic chains. In GVC, the gap of competencies between multinationals and their suppliers is expected to be smaller, and this makes it easier to have cooperative relationships. In contrast, hierarchy is more likely to occur in national chains due to the suppliers’ poor level of skills and competencies. v.) Firms’ characteristics and supply chains' governance Finally, in order to investigate the correlation between firms’ characteristics and different levels of governance of the supply chain, we use a multinomial logit model estimated by maximum likelihood method. Basically, we consider a 1 X K vector of explanatory variables to examine the correlation between these variables and the y-th alternative in terms of governance levels. The components of the vector are: Multinational - indicates whether firms are suppliers of Multinationals or not; TFP – both parametric and semi parametric measures; the share of professional workers, Train - captures the formal training; Export; Skills; R&D investments; Brand – possession of a brand name; Owner – indicates whether the firm is foreign or domestic. We control for industry, age, year and region. Let x be the 1 X K vector, the multinomial logit model response probability takes the following form: j P( y j | x) exp( x j ) /[1 exp( x h )] h 1 (1.4) We define a multicategory variable (y) as dependent variable which takes value 0 – 5 according to the five levels of governance. We first estimate the marginal effect (dy/dx) of the explanatory variables on each of the governance levels. Since the interpretation of parameters and marginal effects sometimes is not straightforward for logit models, we also compute the effects of X on the odds of the outcome. Given two realizations of X, say X1 and X0, we can define the odds ratio as (Y 1 | X 1 ) e ( X 1 Xo) (Y 1 | X 0 ) (1.5) A careful test of this hypothesis would require a dynamic analysis of the learning and efficiency improving process that is not feasible with only three years available. 6 Page 10 of 21 This statistics tells us how the odds of observing Y = 1 change when X changes from X0 to X1 (see Ichino 2003). More specifically, the odds ratio is the ratio of two odds and is a summary measure of the relationship (effect size) between two variables. Then, to measure the strength and direction of relationship between our variables, we use the odds ratios of the estimated coefficients. The ratio of odds ratios of the independents is the ratio of relative importance of the independent variables in terms of effect on the dependent variable's odds. The odds ratio has frequently been used as measures of relationship (effect size). For example for the variable j: e j tells us how the odds of observing Y = 1 change when Xj changes by one unit. • If e j > 1, the variable j increases the odds of observing Y = 1. j • If e < 1, the variable j decreases the odds of observing Y = 1.7 We first present the results in terms of marginal effect for each explanatory variable (Table 6). According to the results highlighted above, we focus only on Type C and Type E of governance. Forms of supply chain’s governance featured by buyers’ involvement in both design and quality and technology activities (Type E) are enhanced by the relationship with MNCs. The other variables included in the model also reveal a positive marginal effect. On the contrary, we do not find significant effects related to governance featured by buyers’ involvement only in design and quality activities (Type C). Finally, possessing a brand name seems to reduce the probability to observe both the forms of governance considered. Table 7 presents the results in terms of log odds ratios (RRR). For each explanatory variable of the vector we focus on three ratios: the odds of observing Type C as opposed to Type A (column A); the odds of observing Type E as opposed to Type A (column B); and the odds of observing Type E as opposed to Type C (column C). Variables increasing the odds to observe forms of governance featured by buyers’ involvement in design and quality and technology activities (Type C and Type E) vs. governance with no involvement of buyers and low requirements (Type A) are: MNCs’ supplier status, TFP (both parametric and non parametric) and the export status (Columns A and B). Differently, possessing a brand name increase the odds in the opposite way. 7 More precisely, when the odds ratio is less than 1, going from the value of the independent variable associated with the denominator to the value associated with the numerator decreases the odds that the dependent variable equals a given value. For the case where the odds ratio is greater than 1, then increases the odds that the dependent variable equals a given value. The larger the odds ratio, the stronger the relationship, meaning the higher the ratio of success versus failure for those in that category compared to the reference category. Page 11 of 21 Table 6 - Multinomial Logit Model - Marginal effects on supply chains' governance dy/dx on governance Type C MNCs' supplier status TFP (OLS) TFP (Levinsohn and Petrin) Professional Skills Training R&D Brand Owner Export dy/dx on governanceType E -0.023 (-1.47) 0.029 (-1.42) 0.003 (1.28) -0.1007 ( -0.63 ) -.0102 (-1.56 ) -.051 ( -2.95 )* .002 (1.30 ) -.064 ( -4.22)** -.055 (-3.09)** 0.028 (1.58 ) 0.152 (9.34)** 0.027 (1.25) 0.005 (2.04)* 0.106 (0.63) .0398 ( 5.72 )** .0738 (4.15 )** .001 ( 0.74) -.094 (-5.80)** 0.082 (4.21)** .029 (1.76) Robust z statistics in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% The variables increasing the odds to observe forms of governance featured by buyers’ involvement in technology activities (Type E) vs. governance featured by buyers’ involvement in design and quality (Type C) are (Column C): MNCs’ supplier status, Skills, training and foreign ownership. TABLE 7 - Multinomial Logit Model - Log odds ratios BASE Type A Type C/Type A Type E/Type A MNCs' supplier status TFP (OLS) TFP (Levinsohn and Petrin) Professional Skills Training R&D Brand Owner Export 1.35 (2.45)* 1.50 (2.82)* 1.06 (2.08)* 0.50 (-0.62) 1.03 (-0.63) 0.93 (-0.59) 1.03 (-1.97) 0.49 (-6.01)** 1.29 (-1.62) 1.72 (-4.22)** Robust z statistics in parentheses Source: authors' calculation on PICS 2004 data - The World Bank Page 12 of 21 2.25 (6.76)** 1.47 (2.7)* 1.07 (2.24)* 0.95 (-0.05) 1.19 (3.56)** 1.36 (2.39)* 1.02 (-1.76) 0.47 (-6.46)** 1.94 (-4.45)** 1.69 (-4.12)** BASE Type C Type E/Type A 1.67 (5.86)** 0.98 (-0.19) 1.00 (-0.38) 1.88 (-0.73) 1.16 (4.04)** 1.46 (4.05)** 1.00 (-0.43) 0.96 (-0.52) 1.51 (-4.13)** 0.98 (-0.23) To sum up: - On average, the involvement of the buyer in the supply chain is more likely to happen with firms which are suppliers of multinational, have good performance in terms of TFP and do not possess its own brand name. - Specifically, Type E of governance (i.e. high requirements’ standards, involvement of the buyer in design and quality and technology activities) appears to prevail frequently with firms which are suppliers of multinational, have higher skills, positive TFP, run training programs for its employees and do not have its own brand name. - The variables which increase the probability to observe buyers’ involvement in technology activities (Type E) instead of a simply involvement in design and quality are (Type E vs. Type C): MNCs’ supplier status, skills, training and foreign ownership. Difference in TFP does not seem to matter, as well as the brand name. Conclusions In this paper we have examined the relationship between the presence of multinationals and their local supplier’ performance, using a representative sample of 1,385 Thai firms from 2001 to 2003. Since the role of MNCs is not confined to production but increasingly extends to planning and management of global networks of suppliers and firms, instead of concentrating merely on the case of the relationships between MNCs and their majorityowned suppliers (i.e. MNCs’ subsidiaries) we consider MNCs sourcing their inputs from developing countries’ firms – both independent and equity-controlled by the same MNC. As the performance measure, we employ total factor productivity, defined as the residual of a Cobb-Douglas production function. In order to take into account the problem of potential correlation between input levels and the unobserved firm-specific productivity shocks in the estimation of production coefficients, we carry out a panel data analysis using both parametric and semi parametric techniques to estimate TFP. We find that MNCs’ supplier status is positively correlated with firms’ productivity. We include in the analysis the issue of the governance of the value chain, looking at the way the buyer-supplier relationship is coordinated and the strategic role of the buyers along the supply chain. We define a measure to capture Value Chains’ governance. Our definition includes the intensity of buyers’ requirements in terms of process and products parameters’ specification, and the nature of activities in which the buyer is involved. Regarding the latter, we distinguish among Design and Quality, R&D and Technology activities. We especially consider the differences between firms which are part of a multinational's production and distribution network and firms which participate in supply chains mediated by national buyers Data reveal that the governance of the supply chain does not matter for local firms supplying multinational buyers, although it is very significant for non MNCs’ suppliers. “Domestic firms” (no-MNS), with high customization of products to buyer’s standard, which also Page 13 of 21 receive assistance about design & quality definition and technology, seem to be more productive. Finally, we attempt to study which firms’ characteristics are more correlated to different types of supply chains’ governance. Results reveal that on average, the involvement of the buyer in the supply chain is more likely to happen with firms which are suppliers of multinational, have good performance in terms of TFP and do not possess its own brand name. Specifically, governance with high requirements’ standards, involvement of the buyer in design and quality and technology activities appears to prevail frequently with firms which are suppliers of multinational, have higher skills, positive TFP, run training programs for its employees and do not have its own brand name. The variables which increase the probability to observe buyers’ involvement in technology activities instead of a simply involvement in design and quality are: MNCs’ supplier status, skills, training and foreign ownership. Difference in TFP does not seem to matter, as well as the brand name. Certainly more research is needed to fully understand the determinants of supply chain governance. In particular, it would be useful to confirm the findings of this paper using data that allow addressing the issue of causality. It is to be hoped that improved data availability will allow us to address these issues in the future. Furthermore, the explicit inclusion of sectoral peculiarities is currently being explored by the authors. Page 14 of 21 References o Aitken, Brian, and Ann E. Harrison (1999). “Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct Foreign Investment?” American Economic Review 89: 605- 18. o Archibugi D., Pietrobelli C. (2003), “The Globalisation of Technology and its Implications for Developing Countries. Windows of Opportunity or Further Burden?”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol.70, pp.861–83. o Arnold, Jens Matthias and Katrin Hussinger (2005a). Exports vs. FDI. Empirical evidence using German firm level data. ZEW Working Paper, Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim, Germany. o Barba Navaretti, Giorgio and Castellani, Davide (2004), "Investments Abroad and Performance at Home: Evidence from Italian Multinationals". CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4284. o Blalock, Garrick and Paul Gertler (2002). “Technology Diffusion from Foreign Direct Investment through Supply Chain,”Working Paper, Cornell University. o Blomström, Magnus, and Edward W. Wolff. (1994). “Multinational Corporations and Productivity Convergence in Mexico.” In W. Baumol, R. Nelson, and E. Wolff, eds., Convergence of Productivity: Cross-national Studies and Historical Evidence. Oxford: Oxford University Press. o Blundell, Richard and Steve Bond (1999). GMM Estimation with Persistent Panel Data: An Application to Production Functions. Working Paper W99/04, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London. o Castellani D., Zanfei A. (2002) “Multinational experience and the creation of linkages with local firms. Evidence from the electronics industry” (con A. Zanfei), Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 26, N. 1, pp. 1-15. o Dunning J. H. (1993) 'Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy'. AddisonWelsley, Wokingham. o Gereffi, G. (1994) 'The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: how U.S. retailers shape overseas production networks', in G. Gereffi and M. Korzeniewicz (eds) Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism, Westport: Praeger, pp. 95--122. o Gereffi, G. (1999) 'International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain', Journal of International Economics 48: 37--70. o Gereffi, G. and Memodovic, O. (2003) ‘The global apparel value chain: what prospects for upgrading by developing countries?’ United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO), Sectoral Studies Series, available for downloading at <http://www.unido.org/doc/12218>. o Giuliani E., Pietrobelli C. and Rabellotti R. (2004). “Upgrading in Global Value Chains: lessons from latin American clusters,” University of Piemonte Orientale Quaderno n°72 o Giuliani E., Rabellotti R. and van Dijk M.P. (2005). “Clusters Facing Competition: The Importance of External Linkages o Humphrey J., Schmitz H. (2002b). “Developing Country Firms in the World Economy: Governance and Upgrading in Global Value Chains“, INEF Report, No. 61, Duisburg: University of Duisburg. Page 15 of 21 o Humphrey, J. and Schmitz, H. (2002) 'How Does insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters?', Regional Studies 36 (9): 1017--27. o Javorcik-Smarzynska, Beata K. (1999a). "Technological Leadership and the Choice of Entry Mode by Foreign Investors: Evidence from Transition Economies," mimeo. o Javorcik-Smarzynska, Beata S. (2004). “Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of Domestic Firms? In Search of Spillovers Through Backward.” American Economic Review 94, 605-627. o Kaplinsky, R. (2001), “Learning Networks in the South African Auto Components Industry”, Innovation News. o Kaplinsky, R., Readman, J. (2001). “How can SME producers serve global markets and sustain income growth?”, Mimeo, Brighton: University of Brighton and University of Sussex. http://www.ids.ac.uk/ids/global/valchn.html o Lall, Sanjaya (1980). “Vertical Inter-Firm Linkages in LDCs: An Empirical Study.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 42, 203-206. o Levinsohn, Jamesand Amil Petrin (2003). Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables Review of Economic Studies v70, n2: 317-41. o Pack, Howard and Kamal Saggi (2001). “Vertical Technology Transfer via International Outsourcing,” Journal of Development Economics 65, 389-415. o Rodriguez-Clare, Andre (1996). “Multinationals, Linkages, Development,” American Economic Review 86, 852-873. and Economic o Saggi, Kamal (2002). “Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and International Technology Transfer: A Survey,” World Bank Research Observer 17, 191-235. o Schmitz H. (1999a). “Increasing returns and collective efficiency”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 23, No. 4: 465-483. o Schmitz H. (1999b), “Global competition and local co-operation: success and failure in the Sinos Valley, Brazil”, World Development, Vol. 27, N°9. o Sturgeon, T. (2002) 'Modular production networks: a new American model of industrial organization', Industrial and Corporate Change 11 (3): 451--496. o Sturgeon, T. and Lester, R. (2004) “The new global supply-base: challenges for local suppliers in East Asia.” in S. Yusuf, A. Altaf and K. Nabeshima (eds.) Global Production Networking and Technological Change in East Asia, New York: Oxford University Press. o Zanfei, A. (2000) “Transnational firms and the changing organisation of innovative activities” Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 515-42. o Zanfei, A. (2004) “Globalisation at bay? Multinational growth and technology spillover”Critical perspectives on international business, n.1, (7-19) Page 16 of 21 TABLE 1 - Descriptive statistics of the sample No MNCs' suppliers Number of firms Age Export share >5% 638 15.76 31.82 MNCs' suppliers 747 17.04 80.46 Percentiles 10% 25% Number of employees 20 45 32 94 50% 68 215 75% 90% 160 370 521 1348 Skewness Kurtosis 5.2 38.5 7.5 97.8 Percentiles 10% 25% Sales (in US dollars) 112,877 495,926 289,676 1,281,528 50% 855,125 4,518,952 75% 3,360,246 14,808,257 90% 13,000,677 50,056,081 11.9 197.0 7.1 64.4 Skewness Kurtosis Percentiles 10% 25% Average wages (in US dollars) 19,835 52,715 39,560 131,603 50% 101,899 412,499 75% 90% 278,089 794,872 1,123,944 3,406,594 Skewness Kurtosis 4.858436 32.32842 11.17144 170.0937 % of sales to large customer 43.7 45.8 Share of sales from new products 6.31 11.11 ISO 9002 18.65 54.78 Introduced new technology 34.48 66.12 Source: The World Bank - Private Sector Investment Climate (PICS) survey 2004 Page 17 of 21 TABLE 2 - The relationship between MNCs' suppliers status and firms' Total Factor Productivity Dependent variable TFP Column 1 Column 2 OLS Lev-Pet MNCs' supplier status P>|t| N Robust z statistics in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% Source: authors' calculation on PICS 2004 data - The World Bank 0.031 (2.33)* 4085 0.212 ( 2.21)* 4021 TABLE 3 - Firms’ characteristics which enhance the probability of MNCs’ suppliers status. Dependent Variable: MNCs' supplier status TFP (Levinsohn and Petrin) Skills Training R&D Professional Size dummies Industry dummies Region dummies Year dummies Pseudo R2 N 0.012 -1.82 0.147 (7.23)** 0.358 (7.07)** 0.026 (4.98)** 1.939 (4.50)** included included included included 0.1625 4018 Robust z statistics in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% Source: authors' calculation on PICS 2004 data - The World Bank Page 18 of 21 TFP (OLS) Skills Training R&D Professional Size dummies Industry dummies Region dummies Year dummies Pseudo R2 N 0.132 (2.12)* 0.253 (16.39)** 0.393 (7.99)** 0.028 (5.36)** 1.565 (3.68)** included included included included 0.1508 4081 Table 4 - Descriptive statistics on firms' relationships with buyers BY MNCS' SUPPLIER STATUS Brand MNCs' suppliers No MNCs' suppliers Cl.spec (mean)* 55.3 46.5 Client enforcement*** MNCs' suppliers No MNCs' suppliers 84.6 71.6 47.5 47.1 R&D activiities **** 46 30.5 Prod inf. by client ** 78.6 68.7 Empl. for tech diff. 44.2 25.4 BY INDUSTRIES Brand Textile and Clothing Food Processing Machinery Electonics Wood Rubber and Plastics Automotive Parts Cl.spec (mean)* 37.1 81.0 70.6 56.0 35.2 43.7 44.1 Client enforcement*** Textile and Clothing Food Processing Machinery Electonics Wood Rubber and Plastics Automotive Parts 84.7 76.0 75.7 83.7 72.0 70.6 83.5 52.6 40.0 37.3 50.8 52.4 46.6 48.5 R&D activiities **** 38.6 43.6 37.3 47.0 28.0 34.9 42.1 Prod inf. by client ** 79.1 69.8 71.8 78.3 71.2 68.5 76.6 Empl. for tech diff. 31.3 39.7 32.2 48.2 18.4 39.5 38.6 Source: The World Bank - PICS 2004 * % of sales made exclusively to buyers' unique specification ** Information on design/quality provided by the buyer *** Product quality standards enforced by the buyer **** Engagement of the buyer in process or product R&D type of activities ***** Employees from the buyer to work to disseminate and diffuse new technologies into suppliers' production facility Page 19 of 21 TABLE 5 - The relationship between firms' TFP and supply chains' governance Dependent Variable: Total Factor Productivity (Levinsohn-Petrin) Type B Type C Type D Type E Size dummies Industry dummies Region dummies Year dummies N ALL FIRMS NO-MNS 0.206 0.251 -1.51 -1.72 0.34 0.568 (2.56)* (3.09)** 0.088 0.108 -0.66 -0.72 0.386 0.567 (2.68)** (2.72)** included included included included included included included included 4015 1851 MNS 0.141 -0.54 0.005 -0.03 -0.027 -0.12 0.137 -0.63 included included included included 2164 Dependent Variable: Total Factor Productivity (OLS) Type B Type C Type D Type E Size dummies Industry dummies Region dummies Year dummies N ALL FIRMS NO-MNS 0.046 0.039 -1.67 -1.19 0.059 0.089 (2.49)* (3.08)** 0.013 0.003 -0.48 -0.09 0.052 0.065 (2.31)* (2.36)* included included included included included included included included 4079 1873 Robust z statistics in parentheses Source: authors' calculation on PICS 2004 data - The World Bank Page 20 of 21 MNS 0.052 -1.07 0.011 -0.27 0.01 -0.22 0.021 -0.55 included included included included 2206 APPENDIX A Following Olley and Pakes (1996) and Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) we estimate a Total Factor Productivity measure employing a semi-parametric technique. We use intermediate inputs to proxy for the unobservable productivity term. The production function considered is the following: Yit 1lit 2 k it 3 mit it it (1.2) where mit is the intermediate input (electricity), wit the transmitted component and εit the i.i.d. component. Then, we construct our TFP measure as: wˆ exp( y ˆl ˆk ˆm) (1.3) The Cobb-Douglas production function specification is of the following form: Yit 1lit 2 k it 3 mit it while the TFP measure is defined as ˆ exp( y ˆl ˆk ˆm) Page 21 of 21