The yield curve and forecasting recession in South Africa: does monetary policy explain the yield spread’s predictive power? By Melvin Muzi Khomo* And Meshach Jesse Aziakpono Abstract The yield curve, as represented by the spread between long-term and short-term interest rates has gained prominence in recent years as a useful tool for forecasting future economic activity and the likelihood of recession. We apply the probit and modified probit models proposed initially by Estrella and Mishkin (1996) in this paper to explore the yield curve’s ability to predict recession in South Africa. We also test for the influence of monetary policy on the yield spread’s predictive power in an effort to explain the source of the yield curve’s forecasting abilities. The results show that the yield curve is still a simple and reliable forecasting tool and recession indicator for both policymakers and private investors in South Africa. In addition, the results show that monetary policy is an important determinant of the term structure spread but the yield curve’s predictive power is also driven by other factors independent of monetary policy. Key Words: Yield curve, monetary policy, South Africa, probit model. JEL Classification: C53, E3, F1. * Senior Lecturer, South African Reserve Bank College, P.O Box 427, Pretoria, South Africa, Tel +27 12 399 6914, E-mail: melvin.khomo@resbank.co.za Corresponding author: Professor, Development Finance, University of Stellenbosch Business School, P.O. Box 610, Bellville 7535, South Africa, Tel: +27 (021) 918 4261, E-mail: meshach.aziakpono@usb.ac.za Disclaimer: The views presented in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of their respective employer institutions. 1. Introduction Several studies have demonstrated that the slope of the yield curve or the term spread, as represented by the difference between yields on long-term and short-term treasury securities, is a useful indicator for future economic activity and thus a good leading economic indicator. The inversion of the yield curve, where short term interest rates rise above longterm interest rates, has in the past provided a positive statistical relationship with the odds of a recession ahead and is thus widely regarded as a harbinger for an economic downturn. Such evidence is extensively documented in the United States and other developed countries with a few studies also confirming such a behavior or relationship in South Africa ( Moolman 2002; Khomo & Aziakpono 2007). The Fed consistently publishes GDP growth forecasts and recession probabilities for the US economy based on the simple yield curve model 1. The ability to predict future levels of economic activity is not only appealing to policymakers but is also key to investors and all economic agents since good or accurate forecasts of economic activity can directly translate into earnings. Although empirical evidence on the ability of the yield curve to predict recession is abundant (not in South Africa), considerably less attention has been paid the theoretical reasons explaining the yield curve’s predictive power. The focus of this article is on the usefulness of the term spread in forecasting the onset of recession in South Africa. Our aim is to contribute to the literature by; i) revisiting the ability of the yield curve to predict recession in South Africa following the recently experienced great recession and some observations that the yield curve’s predictive power in some countries has deteriorated in recent years, ii) providing some insights into whether monetary policy explains the yield curve’s predictive power in South Africa. Evidence that monetary policy actions of the central bank explain the yield’s curve’s predictive powers can provide support to building the theory that explains the yield spread’s ability to predict recessions and its usefulness as a forecasting tool. The paper is structured as follows; a brief theoretical and literature review is presented in chapter 2; chapter 3 presents the empirical relationship between the business cycle in South Africa, the yield spread and monetary policy; chapter 4 is the methodology and chapter 5 presents the results and conclusion. 2. Theory and literature review 2.1 Theory The yield curve can be purely defined as the relationship between interest rates with different terms to maturity. It represents the term structure of interest rates and is normally characterized by a plot of bond yields with the same risk, liquidity and tax considerations (normally government bonds) against time to maturity. The shape and slope of the yield curve changes daily and attracts the attention of everyone from analysts to economists and 1 The Cleveland Fed uses past values of the yield spread to calculate and post predictions of real GDP growth and the probability that the US economy will be in recession one year forward. See www.clevelandfed.org/research/data/yield_curve/index.cfm forecasters since empirical studies have shown that changes in the shape of the yield curve is closely linked to the movement of economic variables like inflation, future interest rates and economic growth. In essence, although a myriad of factors determines the general level of interest rates in an economy, the focus of the yield curve is on those elements that define the yields on bonds with different terms to maturity. It also makes sense to differentiate between short-term (normally less than two years) and long-term sectors of the yield curve since different factors appear to drive different segments of the curve and hence the shapes of the yield curve. The difference between any two maturity sectors of the curve is termed the yield spread or maturity spread and fluctuations in such spreads helps us infer changes in the slope and shape of the yield curve and mainly for the purposes of this paper, the relationship between shortterm and long-term interest rates. High long-term interest rates relative to short-term rates (positive spread) displays a normal or upward sloping yield curve, with a flat curve showing similar yields regardless of maturity and a negative spread signalling an inverted yield curve where short-term interest rates exceed long-term interest rates. Explanations for the term structure of interest rates (i.e. the shape of the yield curve and relationship between long-term and short-term interest rates) fall predominantly between two theories; the expectations theory and the market segmentation theory (Fabozzi, 2012: 185). Fabozzi defines three forms of the expectations theory which are the pure expectations theory, the liquidity theory and the preferred-habitat theory. Given the objective of the study, we briefly review the fundamental assumptions behind these theories in explaining the shape of the yield curve. We specifically focus on the theoretical justification as to why the yield curve would invert before a recession and hence its predictive powers. The pure expectations theory explains the term structure in terms of expected future short-term interest rates such that at any given moment in time, the yield curve reflects the market’s current expectations of future short-term interest rates (Saunders & Cornett, 2011: 229). An upward sloping yield curve under this theory would reflect that the market expects short-term rates to rise in the future whilst a flat term structure reflects expectations of unchanged rates. An inverted yield curve would imply the market expects interest rates to decline in the future. Since the yield curve has historically inverted prior to all observed recessions in RSA, it could be a reflection of market expectations about a decline in interest rates. Adrian et.al (2010:4) note that an inverted yield curve could be seen as a reflection of market expectations of low future interest rates which in turn are attributed to weakness in expected credit demand, diminished inflation expectations and central bank policy in response to subdued economic conditions. Dueker (1997:42) notes that if investors expect a recession to occur, the yield curves’ response will be determined by the market’s assessment of the recession’s influence on short-term interest rates and the yield curve inversion will mainly be driven by a decline in long-term interest rates. Although the pure expectations theory explains the tendency of the yield curve to invert at times, its fundamental drawback is that it does not account for the risk associated with fixed income investments. In practice, it can be observed that the volatility of a bond’s price (risk of holding that bond) is directly related to its term to maturity (i.e. long-term bonds are more risky). The liquidity premium theory improves on the pure expectations theory by asserting that investors will hold long-term bonds if they are offered a risk premium (also called term premium) above expected future short-term interest rates to compensate for the higher risk. The theory implies that long-term interest rates are a function of expected future short-term interest rates plus a liquidity or risk premium and such premium will increase with the maturity of the bond (Fabozzi; 2012:188). This theory explains well the observed tendency or a bias towards a positively sloped shape of the yield curve since rational investors would demand a premium for duration risk. This theory is however poor in explaining the observed tendency of the yield curve to invert before recessions since its main perceptive is that expectations of a steep decline in interest rates in the future might overcome the term or liquidity premium associated with holding long-term bonds. The preferred habitat theory is highly similar to the liquidity premium theory with its major deviation being that the former rejects the assumption that the liquidity premium increases with a bond’s duration or term. The theory proposes that the shape of the yield curve is determined by expectations about future short-term interest rates plus a risk premium (which can be either positive or negative) that is determined by the investors’ preferred habitat at any given period in time (Fabozzi; 2012:189). According to this theory, expectations of a steep decline in short-term interest in anticipation of monetary easing, lower GDP growth or low inflation would induce investors to shift funds from short-term instruments (the normally preferred habitat) to long-term bonds (in anticipation of higher returns) and thus cause the yield curve to flatten and then finally invert. All the three theories mentioned above emphasize on the importance of expectations about future interest rates as the key determinant of the yield curve shape with an inverted curve associated with an expected decline in short-term interest rates due to a countercyclical monetary policy, lower GDP growth, lower inflation or a combination of any of the variables. The last theorem; the segmented markets theory, assumes that investors regard the maturity sectors of the yield curve as completely separate such that bonds with different maturities cannot be regarded as substitutes (Mishkin 2004: 132). Demand and supply dynamics for a particular maturity segment of the curve determines the yields for that portion of the yield curve with no links to other maturities. The theory assumes that the shape of the yield curve is determined by asset-liability management constraints of investors and issuers of bonds at any maturity sector of the curve. The segmented markets theory does not explain the tendency of the yield curve to invert before recession since it assumes investors will not shift funds across maturity sectors (there is no relationship between demand and supply of shortversus long-term bonds) in anticipation of changes in interest rates, growth or inflation. Given the term structure theories, Moneta (2003:10) provides three reasons for the relationship between the term structure of interest rates and economic growth and hence the yield curve’s information about future recessions. This relationship is generally positive and mainly reflects the expectations of financial market participants about future economic growth. Moneta attributes the relationship to market expectations about future interest rates, monetary policy effects and investor hedging. Why would an inverted yield curve then precede recessions? The answer lies in the expectations theory such that if financial market participants expect slower growth, low inflation or even a recession ahead, they will lower or reduce their forecasts of future short-term interest rates. Since long-term interest rates are determined by expected future short-term interest rates, the yield curve will flatten and eventually invert depending on how much the market expects interest rates to fall. Since monetary policy determines short-term interest rates, the market will expect the central bank to ease monetary policy (Rosenberg & Mauer 2011). We show later on in the paper that monetary policy actions of the central bank in South Africa have an influence on the shape of the yield curve and there is reason to believe monetary tightening might cause the yield curve to invert before recession. The investor hedging concept is sometimes referred to as the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model and assumes movements in asset prices are associated with developments in economic activity (Alessandrini, 2003:3). A general perception in the financial markets that the economy is heading for a slowdown may cause investors to shift their funds into financial instruments such as long-term bonds that will deliver payoffs during the recession. The rush for long-term bonds will cause their prices to rise (and their yields to decline). Further, to finance their purchases of long-term bonds, investors will liquidate their holdings of short-term instruments and their yields will rise. The shifting of funds from shortterm to long-term securities in anticipation of a recession will cause the yield curve to flatten and possibly invert. This explanation also ties with the preferred-habitat theory of the term structure. 2.2 Literature The literature on the yield curve’s ability to predict recessions is extensive with several conclusions observable2. First and most importantly, there is still lack of a universally acceptable theoretical explanation for this relationship (Estrella & Trubin, 2006:1); and this is important for confidence to be built around this indicator. Benati and Goodhart (2008) (in Wheelock & Wohar 2009:436) note that “much of the literature examines empirically how well the term spread forecasts output growth and recessions, with less emphasis on why the yield curve predicts economic activity”. Secondly, the probit model features prominently in such studies whereby it is used to convert a measure of a yield curve’s steepness into the probability of recession several quarters ahead. Thirdly, although empirical evidence on the yield curve’s predictive power is clearly abundant; most studies have focused on developed countries such as the United States and Europe with limited evidence from emerging markets and South Africa in particular. Nel (1996), Moolman (2002) and Khomo & Aziakpono (2007) have used South African data to determine the predictive ability of the yield curve. All the studies mentioned above have mainly focused on proving the term spread’s ability to forecast recession with limited attempts to explain why this happens. Wheelock and Wohar (2009:423) note that the usefulness of the term spread for forecasting economic activity remains a stylized fact in search of a theory. A few studies though make an attempt into explaining the theory and there seems to be a general agreement in these studies that central banks can directly influence the short-end of the yield curve in an effort to achieve their long-term objectives of either low & stable inflation or output stabilization. A monetary policy tightening in response to high inflation can lower expectations about future inflation, interest rates and thus result in lower long-term interest rates (Wu, 2003). A monetary policy induced rise in short-term interest rates could be expected to lead to lower future economic activity and demand for credit thus exerting pressure on real interest rates (Estrella & Trubin: 2006). Expectations for future declines in short-term interest rates would cause long-term interest rates to fall and thus the yield curve will flatten. This observation is consistent with the expectations hypothesis of the term structure. Estrella and Hardouvelis (1991), who pioneered the use of the yield spread to predict recessions, argue that current monetary policy has a definite influence on the slope of the yield curve. They state that a monetary policy contraction would raise the level of nominal, Wheelock & Wohar (2009) provide a good comprehensive survey of the literature on the term spread’s ability to predict output growth and recessions. 2 and with price rigidities, real short-term interest rates whilst leaving long-term rates intact thus causing the yield curve to flatten. The high real rates would lead to low current investment opportunities and lower future output, thus resulting in a positive relationship between the yield slope and future output (Estrella & Hardouvelis, 1991:567). To assess the effect of monetary policy on the yield curve’s predictive power, they add a variable that represents the current monetary policy stance of the central bank (US Fed funds rate) to the simple probit model to see if the yield curve correctly predicts recessions and continues to have statistically significant regression coefficients. Their results showed that the predictive power of the yield curve remained almost intact; implying that the information in the yield slope is more about other variables than current monetary policy. Estrella & Mishkin (1995) examine the relationship between the term structure of interest rates, monetary policy instruments and subsequent economic activity and inflation in the US and European countries. They estimate a multi-variate probit model that includes the term spread, central bank rate, 3m TB rate and the real central bank rate to test whether there is predictive power of the term spread over and above that provided by variables that reflect the central bank’s monetary policy stance. They show that monetary policy is an important determinant of the term structure spread but is unlikely to be the only factor. Estrella and Mishkin conclude that the spread’s predictive power does not seem attributable solely to monetary policy variables. Wu (2001) studies the relationship between the US Federal Reserve’s monetary policy shocks and changes in the slope of the yield curve in the US. The study indicates that there exists a strong correlation between monetary policy changes and the slope of the yield curve in the very short run up to 2 months. Wu concludes that monetary policy tightening leads to high nominal short-term interest rates, but due to its anti-inflationary effects, these rates fall back since long-term rates have embedded expectations about the future behavior of short-term rates. This therefore leads to a flattening of the curve when contractionary monetary policy is implemented. Estrella (2005) uses an analytical rational expectations model to investigate reasons for the empirical observation that the slope of the yield curve is a significant predictor of output and real economic activity. He concludes that the extent to which the yield curve is a good predictor of both future output and inflation depends on the form of monetary policy reaction function, which in turn is influenced by the policy objectives. The main implication from the model is that monetary policy does explain to some extent the yield curve’s predictive power, but nonetheless it is not the only factor. Since monetary policy changes directly influence short-term interest rates, Estrella and Trubin (2006) use US data to assess if yield curve inversions that occurred prior to recessions were highly influenced by changes in the short-term or long-term interest rates. They observe that increases in short-term rates preceded all recessions observed, whilst changes in long-term rates were not as consistent (2006:6). This implies that changes in the slope of the yield curve were mainly driven by short-term interest rates which move in lockstep with the monetary policy rate. Wright (2007) estimates a number of probit models using the yield curve combined with several variables to forecast recession, of which one of the models includes the term spread and the nominal fed funds rate. He concludes that models that use both the level of the fed funds rate and the term spread give better results than a model with the yield spread alone (2007:10). Kucko and Chin (2010) also investigate whether the yield spread is a predictor of recessions in the US and European countries and augment the conventional two-variable recession/yield curve specification with the fed funds rate. Their intention is to test the yield curve’s predictive powers following the recent great recession and current conditions in global bond markets and also to isolate the effect of changes in short-term interest rates (monetary policy effect). Their findings are generally inconsistent across countries, with the model correctly predicting recessions in the US, Germany and Sweden. With regards to monetary policy effects, they find that adding the short-term rate to the simple probit model resulted in a decrease in the economic and statistical significance of the yield spread. Adrian, Estrella & Shin (2010: 15) note that the significant impact of changes in the fed funds (monetary policy rate) rate is not on the level of long-term interest rates but on the slope of the yield curve. They use data from the US to show a near perfect relationship between changes in the fed funds rate and changes in the term spread. Their study proposes an explanation of the yield curve’s predictive power from the balance sheet management of financial intermediaries. Adrian et.al conclude that monetary policy tightening is associated with a flattening of the yield curve and a reduction in net interest margins, which in turn makes lending less possible, thus reducing the supply of credit. This then leads to slower economic growth ahead. With specific reference to South Africa, Nel (1996) used cointegration techniques to test the relationship between the term structure of interest rates and growth in real economic activity using data covering the period 1974 to 1993. He showed that the slope of the yield curve is positively related to growth in real economic activity and concluded that the term spread contains information about the real sector of the economy and may be used to forecast future economic activity. Moolman (2002) uses the probit model to predict turning points of the South African business cycle using the yield curve. Quarterly data for the period 1979 to 2001 is used in the analysis and Moolman finds that the probability of a recession in a specific quarter is a negative function of the yield spread lagged two quarters (2002:48). The results indicated that the yield curve successfully predicts turning points of the business cycle in South Africa. Khomo & Aziakpono (2007) also use the probit model to examine the ability of the yield curve to predict recession in South Africa and its predictive power is compared to other variables that include the growth rate of money supply, changes in stock prices and the index of leading economic indicators. The study revealed that the yield spread was still a useful indicator for predicting recession in South Africa and it produced better forecasts as compared to the other variables. However, while these studies show the relevance of the yield curve in predicting economic activities in South Africa, none of them attempted to explain the reasons behind the predictive power of the yield and whether it can be attributed to the role of monetary policy or not. These studies, although not conclusive, do provide some form of credibility that changes in monetary policy influences the slope of the yield curve and its ability to forecast recessions. Adding a variable that represents the monetary policy stance of the central bank to the two-variable probit model can be used to ascertain the influence of monetary policy on the spread’s predictive power. In the next section we briefly review the evolution of the yield spread, monetary policy cycle and business cycle in South Africa. 3. The yield spread and the business cycle in South Africa Figure 1: the yield spread and business cycle in RSA Shaded areas indicate official recession periods as identified by the SARB Figure 1 shows the movement of the yield spread (as represented by the difference between yields on the 10-year RSA government bond and the 91-day Treasury bill) across the business cycle in South Africa since 1980. The graph provides some evidence that a relationship has indeed existed in South Africa between changes in the shape of the yield curve and the various phases of the business cycle with the yield curve flattening and eventually becoming inverted (yield spread becomes negative) prior to all five recession periods observed over this period. This relationship is consistent even with the most recent recession over the period 2007 to 2009 thus confirming the value of the yield spread as a good leading economic indicator. Since the predictive power of the yield curve is most likely influenced by the monetary policy stance of the central bank, the relationship between the business cycle and the SARB’s repo rate is shown in Figure 2 below. The idea is to explore the movement of the policy interest rate over the business cycle and before the onset of past recessions in RSA. We follow the approach by Adrain et al (2010) and define the end of a monetary policy tightening cycle as when either one of the following criteria is met: (1) the repo rate is higher than at any time from 12 months before to 9 months after and is at least 50 basis points higher than at the beginning of the period or (2) the repo rate is higher than at any time from 6 months before to 6 months after and is 150 basis points higher than the average at these points. Both these criteria show six monetary policy tightening cycles since 1980 (Figure 2) and all monetary contraction cycles except for one (2004) were followed by official recession. The lag between the end of the tightening cycle and the onset of recession is not consistent over the different periods but interest rates have in the past normally peaked well into the recession. This means the central bank could do better by improving its forecasts for business cycle turning points. Figure 2: repo rate, monetary policy tightening cycles & business cycle in RSA Shaded areas indicate official recession periods Red lines indicate the end of a monetary policy tightening cycle Figure 3 below shows the movement of the term spread against its individual components (short-term vs. long-term rates) over the business cycle. The idea is to ascertain if changes in the yield spread are highly driven by movements in the shorter or longer end of the curve. An inversion of the yield curve can be caused by either a rise in short term interest rates, a decline in long term interest rates or a combination of both. Figure 3 shows that in the period studied, long-term and short term interest rates have generally moved together in the past (0.74 positive correlation) with the only difference being the magnitude of changes in both. Short-term rates have generally risen faster than long-term rates during a tightening cycle and causing the yield curve to flatten and then invert prior to recessions. In the most recent recession (2007 – 2009), short-term interest rates rose by 207 basis points compared to an increase of 67 basis points in long-term rates in the 12 months before the onset of the recession in December 2007. The same is observable in the previous recession of 1996 where short-term rates rose by 206 basis points in the 12 months before the start of the recession compared to a rise of 153 basis points in long-term rates. One can conclude from this analysis that the inversion of the yield curve before past recessions is partly explained by a rise in short-term interest rates which move in direct proportion to the SARB’s repo rate (Estrella & Trubin (2006) find a similar link in the US). Figure 3: the yield spread components and business cycle in RSA 10Y Yield Term Spread Figure 4 shows the relationship between changes in the repo rate and changes in the yield spread, and confirms the existence of relationship between the two. Changes in the repo rate have in the past exhibited a strong negative relationship with the yield spread; implying that increases in the repo rate have to a great extent explained the inversion of the yield curve before all recessions observed. Changes in long-term interest rates appear to have no relationship with changes in the spread (Figure 6). One can conclude that long-term bond yields are independent of current monetary policy and are driven by a wide range of factors. Market expectations about future monetary policy actions of the central bank would however play a role in determining long-term bond yields. Figure 4: change in the repo rate versus yield spread Figure 5: change in 10Y yields versus the yield spread 4. Data and model estimation In this section, we present the probit methodology used in estimating the likelihood of recession given the slope of the yield curve. 4.1 Indicators and data used a) Yield Spread: since the yield curve normally inverts prior to recessions, an inverse relationship should be observable between the yield spread and the probability of a recession. The yield spread in the paper is calculated as the difference in yields between the 10-year government bond and the 91-day Treasury bill in South Africa (10-year rate minus the 91-day rate). An inverted yield curve will be observable where short-term interest rates are higher than long-term interest rates. b) Monetary policy stance: this is represented by the SARB’s repo rate and an increase in the central bank rate should normally cause the yield spread to decline and the probability of recession to increase. Monthly data from January 1980 to July 2012 is used in the study with all data obtained from the South African Reserve Bank. c) Recession indicator: The recession indicator in the study is obtained from the SARB’s official recession dates. The central bank applies the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) methodology3 in dating official downswings of the business cycle and this method goes beyond the general two consecutive quarters of declining GDP. Applying this convention, the SARB identified five recessions since 1980 in the 3 The NBER, the organisation responsible for officially dating the beginnings and ends of US recessions, defines a recession as “a broad decline in aggregate economic activity (which is measured as a common movement in output, income, employment and trade), using lasting from six months to a year, and marked by widespread contractions in many sectors of the economy” (Filardo, 1999:36). following periods; September 1981 to March 1983, July 1984 to March 1986, March 1989 to May 1993, December 1996 to August 1999 and December 2007 to August 2009. 4.2 Model and estimation methods Following previous studies, we estimate a non-linear probit model that directly estimates the probability of a recession at a given time horizon based on the steepness of the yield curve. The main input into the model is the value of the term spread; i.e. the difference between long-term and short-term interest rates at time t-k, and the output is the probability of a recession occurring at time t. The probit model is therefore used in the study to relate the probability of a recession in South Africa as dated by the SARB during the current period to the slope of the yield curve observed several months earlier. The probability of a recession at time t, with a forecast horizon of k periods is given by the following probit model that is estimated: Prob(Rt = 1) = Φ(c0 + c1Xt-k) (A) Where Φ(..) denotes the normal cumulative distribution function and X is the set of explanatory variables (only the term spread in this case) used to forecast recession. The parameters c0 and c1 are estimated by maximizing the log-likelihood function (Atta-Mensah and Tkacz, 1998:5). If the coefficient c1 is statistically significant, then the term spread, Xt-k is deemed useful for forecasting recession in periods ahead (Wheelock & Wohar, 2009:432). Dueker (1997:45) notes that the general probit model stated above (A) assumes the random shocks in the model are independent and identically distributed with a mean of zero, whilst for many time series applications this is not a plausible assumption. According to Estrella and Mishkin (1998:47), the probit model has an overlapping data problem such that the forecast errors are likely to be serially correlated. Dueker proposes a method to remove the serial correlation in the error term by adding a lag of Rt to the probit model (A) stated above4. He observes that adding a lag of the dependent variable increases the validity of the assumption that the error term has a mean of zero, conditional on availability of information over time t+k. The new probit model proposed by Dueker stated below is also estimated to remove potential serial correlation: Prob(Rt = 1) = Φ(c0 + c1Xt-k +c2Rt-k ) (B) Since the main objective of this study is to test for the influence of monetary policy on the yield spread’s predictive power, we follow Kucho and Chin (2010) and augment the modified probit model (B) with the a variable that represents the current level of short-term interest rates (SARB’s repo rate in this case) as follows; Prob(Rt = 1) = Φ(c0 + c1Xt-k +c2Rt-k +c3REPOt-k ) (C) 4 Karunaratne (1999), Atta-Mensha and Tkacz (1998), and Moneta (2003) also recommend this approach and when applied in Khomo &Aziakpono (2007) it produced better results than the ordinary probit model. The objective is to isolate the effect of changes in official interest rates and test whether there is extra information in the slope of the yield curve over and above the information which the slope carries about current monetary policy actions (Estrella & Hardouvellis; 1991:566). If c1 is statistically significant in equations (A) and (B) but not in equation (C), then the ability of the spread to predict recessions is not robust to the inclusion of a variable that represents the current monetary policy stance of the central bank. An opposite observation however would imply that the predictive power of the yield spread goes beyond the current monetary policy stance of the central bank and is explained by other factors. The principal measure of the goodness-of fit for the probit model estimation suggested by Estrella (1995) and subsequently used in several studies that include Dueker (1997), Bernard and Gerlach (1996), Estrella and Mishkin (1998) and Moneta (2003) is used in the paper. The pseudo R², a measure of the goodness of fit of the estimated equation that corresponds intuitively to the coefficient of determination in a standard linear regression (Estrella and Mishkin, 1998:47) is defined as; Pseudo R² = 1 - (Lu/Lc) –(2/N) Lc Where Lu is the value of the log-likelihood of the estimated model (unrestricted) and Lc is the value of a constrained model containing only the constant term (all coefficients are zero except constant). N is the number of observations. The pseudo R2 is used together with t statistics from the estimated regressions to find the lags that give the best fit for all the variables studied. 5. Empirical Analysis 5.1 The yield spread and recession in South Africa Presented in this section are the results based on the 3 probit equations estimated. The simple probit model with only the yield spread as an explanatory variable (A) is estimated first and results are presented in Table 1 below. We report the estimated coefficients (z-statistics), pvalues, pseudo R2, root mean squared error (RMSE) and variance proportion (VP) for the model at different forecasting lags. The results indicate that the slope coefficients of the spread conform to the theoretical expectations as they exhibit an inverse relationship between the term spread and the probability of a recession occurring. The results are also statistically significant up to 18 months with the lag representing the best fit observed at around 2 quarters (highest pseudo R2 is at 5 months). The probit model therefore still allows us to estimate the probability that the South African economy will be in recession in a given month on the basis of the interest rate spread observed some months earlier. Table 1: probit results: Prob(Rt = 1) = Φ(c0 + c1Xt-k) Lags k=1 k=3 k=5 k=6 k=9 k = 12 k = 15 k = 18 k = 21 Z-Stat Prob Pseudo R² -9.7392 0.0000 0.2980 -10.4699 0.0000 0.3810 -10.6691 0.0000 0.4145 -10.6945 0.0000 0.4133 -10.0596 0.0000 0.3315 -8.5431 0.0000 0.2148 -5.9977 0.0000 0.0989 -3.4660 0.0005 0.0324 -1.4726 0.1408 0.0058 RMSE VP 0.4075 0.3163 0.3868 0.2617 0.3775 0.2440 0.3761 0.2490 0.3966 0.3046 0.4281 0.3984 0.4606 0.5392 0.479 0.7015 0.4861 0.8596 Adding a dynamic structure to the simple model (A) through a lagged dependent variable should improve the forecasting power of the model by making the residuals free of serial correlation (Karunaratne 1999:11). Table 2 below presents results from the modified probit model that includes the yield spread and a lagged dependant variable (B). Table 2: probit results: Prob(Rt = 1) = Φ(c0 + c1Xt-k +c2Rt-k ) Variables SPREAD Z-Stat Prob LAG Dep. Z-Stat Prob k=1 k=3 k=5 k=6 k=9 k = 12 k = 15 k = 18 -3.7465 0.0002 -6.2895 0.0000 -7.3034 0.0000 -7.5691 0.0000 -7.3914 0.0000 -6.6071 0.0000 -5.1791 0.0000 -3.7283 0.0002 11.3393 0.0000 11.2895 0.0000 10.0882 0.0000 8.8769 0.0000 5.3616 0.0000 2.4305 0.0151 0.1213 0.9035 -1.5045 0.1324 Pseudo R² RMSE VP 0.0510 0.4277 0.0188 0.1450 0.3746 0.0568 0.1813 0.3734 0.1530 0.1892 0.3777 0.2037 0.1669 0.4075 0.3341 0.1263 0.4341 0.4381 0.0747 0.4276 0.5423 0.0381 0.4752 0.6501 Several observations can be made from the results of the modified probit model presented in Table 2 above. The yield spread does not lose its statistical significance and its forecasting power over the 18-month horizon. Coefficients of the lagged dependent variable are statistically significant up to 12 months and the lag that presents the best fit remains 5 months as the value of the pseudo R2 is the highest at 0.1892. The estimated probabilities of recession obtained from running model B (dynamic probit) are plotted in Figure 6 together with past recession periods. This is compared to the estimated probabilities obtained previously running the standard probit model (A) based on a 6 months horizon which is the best forecast lag for both models Figure 6: Probability of RSA recession 6M ahead as predicted by yield spread Figure 6 shows that both probit models correctly predicted past recessions over 6m horizons, with the dynamic model appearing to exhibit a greater degree of fit. The modified probit model appears to improve the forecasting power of the probit model as it predicts better the occurrence, severity and duration of observed recessions. Figure 6 shows how both models (A & B) performed in predicting past recessions and confirms that the modified model produces better forecasts. As an example, the dynamic model showed a 94% chance of recession in April 2009, compared to an 84% chance from the simple model. Although both models give a false signal in 2004, the extent of the misnomer is lower for the modified probit model than in the bi-variate probit model. Based on the analysis above, we can therefore confirm that the yield curve is still a valuable economic leading indicator and an increase in the yield spread in negatively associated with the odds of a recession in South Africa. 5.2 Monetary policy and the predictive power of the yield spread It is without doubt that the central bank’s current monetary policy stance has an influence on the slope of the term spread, mainly through direct influences on short-term interest rates (section 3 above). Movements in the repo rate are in lock-step with the 91-day TB rates (98% correlation in the data used) whilst there is also a positive relationship between the repo rate and the 10-year bond yield (we found a 75% positive correlation in the same data). It can be safely postulated that the SARB’s current monetary policy at any given moment in time may cause the slope of the yield curve and future real output (the likelihood of recession in this study) to move in the opposite direction and hence the observed association between an inverted yield curve and a positive probability of recession. The fundamental question however, is whether or not there is extra information in the slope of the yield curve about future economic developments over and above the information which the slope carries about current policy actions of the central bank (Estrella & Hardouvellis, 1991:566). Table 3: probit results: Prob(Rt = 1) = Φ(c0 + c1Xt-k +c2Rt-k +c3REPOt-k ) Variables SPREAD Z-Stat Prob LAG DEP. Z-Stat Prob REPO RATE Z-Stat Prob k=1 k=3 k=5 k=6 k=9 k = 12 k = 15 k = 18 -2.2893 0.0221 -3.9635 0.0001 -4.4652 0.0000 -4.5719 0.0000 -4.2348 0.0000 -3.6314 0.0000 -2.6127 0.0090 -1.5279 0.1265 10.3041 0.0000 9.9002 0.0000 7.5134 0.0000 6.0479 0.0000 2.4161 0.0157 0.0884 0.9296 -1.6042 0.1087 -2.8513 0.0044 2.1486 0.0317 3.6488 0.0003 4.4666 0.0000 4.7411 0.0000 5.0118 0.0000 4.4095 0.0000 3.7101 0.0002 3.3311 0.0009 Pseudo R² RMSE VP 0.0667 0.3589 0.0202 0.1900 0.3287 0.0555 0.2434 0.3316 0.1165 0.2570 0.3364 0.1498 0.2369 0.3703 0.2481 0.1782 0.4085 0.3490 0.1114 0.4467 0.4402 0.0682 0.4677 0.5221 Primarily, a positive relationship is expected between the repo rate and the probability of a recession. An increase in interest rates should lower future economic growth and increase the probability of a recession whilst a reduction in the repo rate is expected to have the opposite effect. In order to isolate the possible effects of monetary policy on the yield spread’s predictive power, we estimate the third model (C), and add a variable that represents the central bank’s current monetary policy stance to the modified probit model. Table 3 above displays the results from this model. Table 3 confirms that increases in the repo rate by the SARB in South Africa are positively associated with the odds for a recession in the future. The repo rate parameter in the model is statistically significant at 5% over a period of 3 years. This positive correlation is supported by the monetary policy transmission mechanism since higher interest rates can imply lower investment and consumption expenditure and hence lower future real output. Such developments should lead to an increase in the odds for recession. The more interesting observation from the findings above is that the predictive power of the yield spread remains almost intact when the repo rate is added. The yield spread parameters are nonetheless statistically insignificant (at 1%) over a shorter horizon of up to 15 months (it was up to 22 months in model B). Most importantly, the forecasting power of the modified probit model does not improve with the inclusion of the variable indicating the current monetary policy stance of the Reserve Bank. The dynamic probit model with the yield spread and lagged dependent variable as regressors produces the best forecasts. This leads us to conclude that current monetary policy does not dominate the yield spread and the information in the yield spread for predicting recessions is mostly about other variables other than the SARB’s monetary policy stance. Figure 7 below compares the estimated recession probabilities and shows that forecasts do not improve with the addition of the repo rate to the modified probit model. Figure 7: Probability of recession: modified probit vs. modified probit + repo 5.3 Conclusion In this paper, we present further evidence that movements in the yield curve still possess significant predictive power for distinguishing between economic expansions and contractions in South Africa. A non-linear probit model that directly estimates the probability of a recession at a given time horizon based on the steepness of the yield curve is used in the study. Changes in the shape of the yield curve, especially its inversion, still provides a good indicator of a possible future recession in South Africa and such an indicator can still play a role in economic forecasting for policy makers, economic researchers and market participants. Although there is reason to believe that monetary policy has an influence on the yield curve, it is only one part of the explanation since the slope of the yield curve is driven by other factors as well. Although we find evidence of a positive relationship between the repo rate and the likelihood of recession, our findings suggest that current monetary policy actions of the SARB are not primarily responsible for the yield curve’s predictive powers. A word of caution though as Fernandez and Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy (2011:4) point out that “no standard theoretical approach exists to relate the yield curve to forecasts of future economic activity….and the curve’s close association with subsequent changes in production, consumption, investment and other components of real GDP remains purely empirical”. The ability of the yield curve to predict recession is not necessarily policy invariant and there is no guarantee its performance will continue unaffected in the current global economic phase and the near future. There is reason to believe that in countries like the US, the yield spread indicator has been compromised by the unusual run of monetary policy in recent years. With US short-term interest rates virtually zero since late-2008, an inverted yield curve is highly unlikely to be experienced. Furthermore, other nonconventional monetary policies like Quantitative Easing, Permanent Open Market Operations and “Operational Twist” that are specifically targeted at suppressing the yield curve raise questions about the information that one can read from current yield curve shapes. For emerging markets like South Africa that offer attractive fixed income market yields relative to the developed markets, substantial global capital inflows in search for better returns would indeed have an impact on the yield curve. But even under the best of circumstances, relying on one economic indicator is risky. More robust models that combine multiple predictors might prove useful. A model that captures the influence of current plus expected future actions of the central bank might yield better clues about the impact of monetary policy on the yield curve. References ADRIAN, T, ESTRELLA, A and SONG SHIN, H (2010). Monetary Cycles, Financial Cycles and the Business Cycle. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report no. 421. [Online] www.ny.frb.org ALLESANDRINI, F (2003). Do financial variables Provide Information about the Swiss Business Cycle? University of Lausanne, Department of Economics. [Online] Available www.hec.unil.ch ATTA-MENSAH, J. and TKACZ, G. (1998). Predicting Canadian recessions using financial variables; a probit approach. Bank of Canada working paper 98-5. [Online] www.bankofcanada.ca BERNARD, H and GERLACH, S (1996). Does the term structure Predict Recessions? The International Evidence. BIS Working Paper no. 37 [Online] www.bis.org DUEKER, M.J. (1997). Strengthening the case for the yield curve as a predictor of US recessions. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Review, 79:41-51. [Online] www.stlf.frb.org ESTRELLA, A and HARDOUVELIS, G. (1991). The term structure as a predictor of real economic activity. The Journal of Finance, 46:555-576. ESTRELLA, A and MISHKIN, F. (1996). The yield curve as a predictor of US recession. Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Federal Reserve Bank of New York June 1996. [Online] www.ny.frb.org ________ (1998). Predicting US recessions: financial variables as leading indicators. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80:45-60 _________(1995). The term structure of interest rates and its role in monetary policy for the European Central Bank. NBER working Paper Series, working Paper no. 5279 FERNANDEZ, A.Z. and NIKOLSKO-RZHEVSKYY, A (2011). Forecasting the end of the global recession: did we miss the early signals? Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Staff Working Papers (No.12) 2011 FILARDO, A.J. (1999). How reliable are recession indicator models? Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, November-December 1998. KARUNARATNE, N D. (1999). The yield curve as a predictor of growth and recession in Australia. The University of Queensland: Department of Economics Discussion Paper no. 255. [Online] www.uq.edu.au KHOMO, M and AZIAKPONO, M (2007). Forecasting recession in South Africa: a comparison of the yield curve and other economic indicators. South African Journal of Economics. Vol 75:2 KUCHO, K and CHINN M. (2010). The predictive power of the yield curve across countries and time. NBER Working Paper No. 16398 [Online] www.nber.org/papers MONETA, F (2003). Does the yield spread predict recessions in the euro-area? European Central Bank Working Paper no. 294, December 2003. [Online] www.ecb.org MOOLMAN, E. (2002). The term structure as a predictor of recessions. Journal for studies in Economics & Econometrics, 26(3): 43-51 NEL, H. (1996). The term structure of interest rates and economic activity in South Africa. The south African Journal of Economics, 64(3): 161-174 WHEELOCK, D and WOHAR, E (2009). Can the term spread predict output and recessions? A survey of the literature. Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review, September – October 2009. WRIGHT J.H. (2006). The yield curve and predicting recessions. Federal Reserve Board, Washington DC Staff Working Papers. [Online] www.federalreserve.gov