Basic Exchange Rate Concepts Nominal Exchange Rate e Nom units of foreign currency unit of domestic currency Real Exchange Rate e Foreign currency price of domestic good e Nom P units of foreign goods Foreign currency price of foreign good PFor unit of domestic goods Dollar Appreciation Nominal Appreciation: Dollar buys more units of foreign currency: e Nom Real Appreciation: Sale of domestic goods purchases more foreign goods: e Dollar Depreciation Nominal Depreciation: Dollar buys fewer units of foreign currency: e Nom Real Depreciation: Sale of domestic goods purchases less foreign goods: e Purchasing Power Parity Goods have equal values in each country: e e Nom P 1 PFor Short-Run Real Exchange Rate Determination While Purchasing Power Parity offers a reasonably satisfactory explanation of longrun trends in nominal exchange rates, financial market conditions are more important for the determination of the equilibrium real exchange rate in the short run. Suppose that some domestic traders are interested in acquiring foreign assets, like foreign stocks or bonds. Such purchases (net of foreign traders' purchases of domestic assets) are referred to as Net Capital Outflow (NCO). Net Capital Outflow is the net amount of payments made to foreigners for the purchase of assets, so NCO is also identically equal to the Capital Account Deficit. That is: NCO KA CA We also find it useful to identify NCO as the supply of dollars in the foreign exchange market. To engage in a positive amount of NCO, domestic residents must sell (supply) dollars to buy the foreign currency needed to buy the foreign assets. 2 Currency transactions also result from trade in goods. In particular, when foreigners want to buy U.S. goods, they need to exchange their own currency for dollars to make their purchases. We therefore identify net exports (NX) as the demand for dollars in the foreign exchange market. The other current account items, net factor payments and net unilateral transfers, also result in a need to demand dollars, but we continue to assume that these two items are approximately zero. Equilibrium in the foreign exchange market occurs when the supply of dollars equals the demand for dollars. How does this equilibration take place? The supply of dollars due to Net capital outflow is determined primarily by financial conditions (factors like savings and investment flows, foreign and domestic real interest rates, and expected future appreciation or depreciation of the dollar) that are unrelated to the current level of the real exchange rate. Alternatively, the demand for dollars due to net exports is likely to be predictably related to the real exchange rate. In particular, when the real exchange rate, e , rises, U.S. goods rise in value (price) relative to foreign goods. Therefore, we expect that foreigners would want to buy fewer U.S. goods, and U.S. residents would want to buy more foreign goods. We therefore assume that net exports are negatively related to the real exchange rate. The foreign exchange market is in equilibrium when supply and demand are equal as in the diagram below. This diagram represents short-run equilibrium in the foreign exchange, and e may be greater or less than one; because Purchasing Power Parity may not hold in the short run. e NCO KA Supply of $' s e NX Demand for $' s 0 Figure 1 Short-Run Exchange Rate Determination NCO KA Supply of $' s S , D for $' s 3 Perfect Asset Substitutability In chapter 5 of the text, we assumed that the real interest rate was constant throughout the world. In the small open economy, the real interest rate is fixed. In the large open economy, the real interest rate is determined by the interaction of domestic and foreign levels of desired savings and investment. However, the large country open economy model determines a common real interest rate for both the domestic and the foreign economies. To determine the real exchange rate in these models, we first use graphical means to determine equilibrium Net capital outflow as the horizontal distance between domestic desired savings and domestic desired investment. This distance is equal to the current account balance. That is: NCO S I CA KA Graphically, this distance is measured as in Figure 2, below. r Sd rw NCO Id S, I I S Figure 2 Net Foreign Investment with Perfect Asset Substitutability We now simply draw the distance, NCO , from Figure 2, as a vertical line in Figure 1. The resulting level of e gives the equilibrium real exchange rate. Figure 2 could also refer to the domestic half of the diagram we use to find equilibrium in the large open economy case. Again we plot the equilibrium level of Net capital outflow in the domestic economy as a vertical line spaced the distance, NCO , from the origin as in Figure 1, and read off the resulting equilibrium real exchange rate. 4 Imperfect Asset Substitutability Our earlier discussions of the small open economy and the large open economy both share the characteristic that the real interest rate is identical everywhere in the world. Practical applications are more complicated. Suppose that you could earn a real interest rate of 5% by depositing your savings in a local domestic bank. Also suppose that you could earn a real interest rate of 5.1% depositing your savings in a foreign bank, perhaps a bank in Australia. Are you likely to withdraw all of your funds from your local bank and deposit them in the Australian bank? Because of the added safety and convenience of keeping your funds in a domestic bank, you are likely to keep at least some of your funds in the domestic bank, even though you are receiving a lower real rate of interest on these funds. Now consider the net amount of savings allocated to foreign lending (that is, the net acquisition of foreign assets). This flow of funds is likely to depend on the level of the foreign real interest rate relative to the level of the domestic real interest rate. Therefore, for any given level of the foreign real interest rate, r w , the amount of Net capital outflow is likely to be negatively related to the domestic real interest rate, r , as in Figure 3, below. r NCO d NCO 0 Figure 3 Desired Net Foreign Investment We are now ready to explain the determination of the domestic real interest rate in a world with imperfect asset substitutability. The domestic real interest rate must exactly balance desired domestic national savings, S d , with the sum of desired domestic investment, I d , plus the desired amount of foreign net investment, NCOd . For a given level of the world real interest rate, r w , we first add domestic investment and net capital outflow as in Figure, 4, below. Finally, we equate the sum of desired domestic investment and desired net capital outflow with the level of desired domestic national savings, as in Figure 5, below. This diagram shows the equilibrium domestic real interest rate, and the equilibrium amount of net capital outflow. Finally, once we have found the equilibrium amount of net capital outflow, we may compute the equilibrium real exchange rate by equating the supply and demand for dollars in the foreign exchange market. This last step is depicted in Figure 5, below. r r I r I d NCO d d I NCO d NCO Figure 4 The Demand for Dollars I NCO r r Sd r I d NCO d NCO d NCO S , I NCO 0 e NCO e NX Figure 5 Exchange Rate Determination with Imperfect Asset Substitutability 7 Capital Flight An important application of the preceding model is the phenomenon of capital flight. While capital flight does not typically apply directly to the U.S. economy, nevertheless the U.S. economy is affected when other, primarily developing countries, experience capital flight. Principle applications would be the Mexican experience in the early 1990's and the East Asian experience in the late 1990's. Take for example the case of Thailand, whose domestic currency is called the bhat. Perhaps due to local political instability, or due to a financial crisis in Thailand, foreign investors suddenly become concerned that loans, either to the Thai government or private sector, might not be repaid. In this situation, foreign lenders may try to quickly liquidate their holdings of Thai assets, and refuse to grant any new loans to Thailand. This disturbance, from the point of view of Thailand, is a sudden rightward shift in the desired net capital outflow schedule, as depicted in Figure 6, below. r r Sd r I d NCO d NCO d NCO S , I NCO 0 e NCO e NX Figure 6 Capital Flight in a Developing Economy As a result of this disturbance, domestic interest rates in Thailand suddenly increase, but not enough to entirely eliminate the increase in net capital outflow. Therefore, the supply of bhats increases and the value of the bhat declines. Furthermore, as the foreign exchange market re-equilibrates, net exports in Thailand increase. While this last development suggests an improvement in Thailand's balance of payments, it comes about 8 because Thailand can no longer afford the imports of energy, natural resources and capital equipment that is sorely needed for Thai development. From the standpoint of the developing world, including the U.S., the shifts in the curves work exactly the same way, but in the opposite direction. The developed world sees a reduction in real interest rates, a reduction in net capital outflow, a real appreciation of the currency, and a decline in net exports. Because the developed world is a lot bigger in economic size than the developing countries under attack, the effects are much smaller in absolute magnitude. However, during these foreign exchange market crises, U.S. attention usually focuses on the deterioration of the current account balance, which primarily shows up as a reduction in exports to the affected countries. Political pressure in the U.S. to try to quell the crises is often most vocal from special interests in the affected export industries, primarily from labor unions and from industry business interests.