Wal-Mart’s impact on supplier profits Qingyi Huang1 Vincent Nijs2 Karsten Hansen3 September 11, 2009 1 Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University School of Management, Northwestern University 3 Rady School of Management, University of California, San Diego 4 Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University 2 Kellogg Eric T. Anderson4 Abstract Previous academic research on the expansion of dominant retailers such as Wal-Mart has looked at implications for incumbent retailers, consumers, and the local community. Little is known, however, about Wal-Mart’s influence on suppliers’ performance. Manufacturers suggest Wal-Mart uses its power to squeeze their profits. In this paper we study the validity of that claim. We investigate the underlying mechanisms that may cause changes in manufacturer profits following Wal-Mart market entry. Our data contains information on supplier interactions with retail stores, including Wal-Mart, for a period of five years. We find that post-entry supplier profits increased by almost 18% on average, whereas profits derived from incumbent retailers decreased only marginally. Contrary to predictions from analytical work our results show wholesale prices are not the main driver of post-entry supplier profit changes; market expansion is. We observe a significant increase in shipments to 45% of markets studied. Furthermore, our analysis demonstrates supplier shipment and profit increases are highest for markets in which incumbents offer a wide variety of products and carry items that Wal-Mart does not sell. Key words: Wal-Mart, market entry, supplier profits, wholesale prices, shipments, product line, assortment. “It’s a complicated question, but for business people, it is the essential question about WalMart: Will doing business with Wal-Mart help my business or hurt it?” —The Wal-Mart Effect 1 Introduction Wal-Mart, reporting over $400 billion in net sales for 2008 (Wal-Mart Stores Inc. 2009), has been ranked the number one non-oil company on the FORTUNE 500 for the past nine years. As the world’s largest retailer Wal-Mart has become the biggest buyer for manufacturers such as Disney, Gillette, Kellogg’s, Mattel, Procter & Gamble, and Sarah Lee (Useem 2003). Passing-through cost savings and quantity discounts, the low-overhead, low-inventory retailer won the battle for the grocery dollar by offering consumers its (in)famous “Every Day Low Prices”. Although over 200 million people shop at Wal-Mart’s 4000+ U.S. locations each year (Wal-Mart Stores Inc. 2008), public opinion is not all favorable. Trade unions and special interest groups (e.g., McGee and Festervand 1998, Kinzer 2004), local politicians (Moreton 2006, Parsons 2006), and the media eagerly portray the retailer as a “world-wide chain of exploitation” destroying communities while squeezing its employees and suppliers alike (e.g., Akron Beacon Journal 2000). Its sheer size and power compelled manufacturers to ask whether or not to “... say no to Wal-Mart?” (Bowman 1997). The demise of Rubbermaid is an often cited example of the retailer’s power. When the durable housewares producer, then one of America’s most reputable companies, tried to pass-on a cost based price increase, Wal-Mart pulled all Rubbermaid products from its shelves in 1994. As the big-box retailer was Rubbermaid’s largest outlet, the manufacturer could not recuperate and was forced to sell-out to Newell several years later. Over 700 suppliers have now built offices close to company headquarters in Bentonville, Arkansas in an attempt to strengthen ties with the dominant chain (Fishman 2006). 1 Previous academic research on discount chains mainly focuses on implications for incumbent retailers (e.g., Stone 1988, 1995, Basker 2005, Gielens et al. 2008, Ailawadi et al. 2009), consumers (e.g., Basker 2005, Hausman and Leibtag 2005, Luchs 2008), and the local community (e.g., Bianchi and Swinney 2004, Moreton 2006, Goetz and Rupasingha 2006, Neumark and Ciccarella 2008, Halebsky 2009). Five recent empirical studies on Wal-Mart in marketing and economics emphasize its market entry impact on incumbents and consumers. First, studying seventeen products in ten categories, Basker (2005) reports a post-entry decline in market prices. Effects for cigarettes, cola, pants, shirts, and underwear are, however, not significant. Singh et al. (2006) – focusing on changes in sales and consumer purchase behavior following one Wal-Mart entry – conclude the incumbent supermarket studied suffers a 17% volume loss, mainly resulting from fewer consumer visits. Interestingly, the authors detect little change in basket size; the number of products bought by the supermarket’s loyal customers is comparable to pre-Wal-Mart conditions. Third, Jia (2008) finds that the multinational’s expansion in the 1980s and 1990s accounted for a 34% to 41% drop in the number of discount stores. Gielens et al. (2008) study incumbents’ stockprice changes after Wal-Mart acquired UK based Asda supermarket group. The authors demonstrate assortment as well as positioning similarities between Wal-Mart and incumbents are detrimental to the latter’s post-entry stock performance. Finally, a recent paper on competitive reactions to eleven Wal-Mart entries by Ailawadi et al. (2009) reports negative effects on incumbent retailers’ revenues. Moreover, the authors show increasing assortment size can successfully mitigate entry impact. Despite discount chains more than doubling their market share since the late 1960s (Jia 2008), analytical and empirical work analyzing entry implications for manufacturers is scarce and provides inconsistent results. The trade press proclaims suppliers are forced to offer attractive trade deals, merchandise support, and slotting allowances to please powerful retailers (Bloom and Perry 2001). Although suppliers have reported for years that big-box retailers demand financially-damaging concessions that undermine channel profits (Huey 1998, Brunn 2 2006), current analytical studies provide limited support for a directional hypothesis on how dominant retailers’ actions affect supplier performance. Chen (2003) concludes that a dominant retailer’s bargaining power reduces a manufacturer’s share of joint profits. He theorizes that manufacturers should decrease incumbent wholesale prices, who, in turn, will lower retail prices to boost sales and counter the dominant retailer’s rise. Dukes et al. (2006), on the other hand, suggest that a dominant retailer’s power need not diminish supplier profits. The authors argue that suppliers should increase rather than lower wholesale prices charged to incumbents. Their analytical results suggest that while rival retailers may suffer, manufacturers can achieve enhanced performance by leveraging the channel efficiencies the dominant retailer offers. Dukes et al. (2009) study product line decisions in the presence of a dominant retailer. They argue that incumbent retailers should broaden their assortment when a dominant retailer chooses to stock fewer products. Their analytical results imply that both the size of the incumbents’ assortment and its overlap with the dominant retailer’s product selection affects their performance. In addition, depending on assortment costs, suppliers may choose to distribute specialty items through incumbents only. Selling to Wal-Mart, which carries a shallow assortment in many categories, will therefore impact manufacturers’ profits and product line decisions (Dukes et al. 2009). Even though some authors examine the link between Wal-Mart and supplier performance in an empirical setting, their results are also inconsistent and none of them, to the best of our knowledge, quantifies Wal-Mart entry impact on suppliers. Ailawadi et al. (1995)’s industry level analysis of relative retailer and manufacturer profitability shows Wal-Mart surpassed manufacturers on most performance metrics between 1982-1992. Whether working with Wal-Mart is detrimental or beneficial for suppliers remains unclear, however, as they do not examine the relationship between Wal-Mart and its vendors directly. Using Compustat data, Bloom and Perry (2001) find a negative correlation between financial performance and collaboration with Wal-Mart for most manufacturers who self-identified the retailer as 3 a ’primary customer’. However, Mottner and Smith (2009), who test Bloom and Perry’s model on a longer time-series of Compustat data, conclude working with Wal-Mart will not affect supplier performance. In contrast, Gosman and Kohlbeck (2006), using Compustat and CRSP data, estimate higher gross-margins for Wal-Mart vendors. In sum, as studies on the costs and benefits for manufacturers of working with WalMart are scarce and inconclusive and empirical research on the impact of Wal-Mart entry on supplier performance is lacking, we propose the following two research questions: • Does Wal-Mart market entry impact supplier profits? • What processes drive post-entry profitability changes? The fact that some retailers do not share data with third parties, such as Nielsen and IRI, is one of the most important reasons empirical work on big-box retailers is still lacking at present. As Wal-Mart has refused to contribute to national consumer sales databases since 2001 (Sachdev 2001), our study significantly adds to the scarce empirical literature examining the company’s impact on suppliers by directly analyzing historical data collected by a vendor. Our unique database contains detailed records on profits, wholesale prices, and shipments for a major consumer packaged goods manufacturer, allowing us to quantify changes in supplier performance following Wal-Mart entry. Our data not only captures the items shipped to each Wal-Mart every week, but also their price. As our dataset spans thousands of retail stores and hundreds of products for a period of five years, we are able to to analyze Wal-Mart entry impact in a broad set of geographical markets while accounting for market structure effects. As we expect Wal-Mart to strategically choose markets in which to open new stores, controlling for endogeneity in entry decisions is crucial to accurately estimate its impact. We use propensity score matching to construct a research design of experimental and control markets. Subsequently, we specify a hierarchical Bayesian model to estimate Wal-Mart’s entry impact on supplier profits. We use a differences-in-differences format for the first stage 4 model and link entry impact variation to retailer assortment profiles in the second stage (Dukes et al. 2009). The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. We introduce the data and the propensity score method in Section 2 and discuss the hierarchical Bayesian model in Section 4. Section 5 describes our empirical results while Section 6 provides managerial implications. 2 Data In this study we use weekly data for a packaged goods category offered by a major manufacturer in the industry. Detailed information is available on supplier profits, wholesale prices, and shipments for over 200 products from December 1999 to January 2005.1 The data provides complete retail coverage in the U.S. including supermarkets, convenience and drug stores, and mass-merchandisers. Figure 1 shows the spatial distribution of the 759 Wal-Mart market entries observed in the data. None of these markets has another Wal-Mart store in the same zip-code area. The number of entries by year are shown in Table 1. [Insert Figure 1 about here] Year 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 No. of entries 105 167 152 144 191 Table 1: Number of Wal-Mart entries in the U.S. by year For each market we observe the key dependent variables (profits, wholesale prices, and shipments) both before and after Wal-Mart entry. Shipments are the number of standard units of goods transported to a market in a week. Wholesale price reflects the average weekly price charged to retailers across all goods sold in a market. Supplier profit is measured as 1 For confidentiality reasons we can disclose neither manufacturer nor industry. 5 wholesale price minus supplier cost of goods times shipments. As an initial estimate of entry impact we calculate the change in weekly supplier profits, wholesale prices, and shipments in pre- versus post-entry periods (see Table 2). Supplier profits Wholesale prices Shipments % change +22.011% +6.247% +13.509% Table 2: Pre versus post Wal-Mart entry change in weekly supplier profits, wholesale prices, and shipments Supplier profits increased by 22% on average, shipments to entry markets by nearly 14%, and wholesale prices charged to retailers by just over 6%. Note that the results in Table 2 should be interpreted with caution. For example, demand for the supplier’s products might have increased regardless of entry. Since data on the same markets over the same time period but without entry do not exist, we compare outcome data for markets with and without WalMart entry. To the extent that markets with and without entry experience similar changes over time the latter serve as valid controls. Table 3 shows changes in outcome variables for entry and non-entry markets. Supplier profits Wholesale prices Shipments Non-entry Entry Non-entry Entry Non-entry Entry Before 1.000 3.350 1.000 1.037 1.000 3.172 After 1.101 4.087 1.062 1.102 1.029 3.601 Diff Diff-in-Diff 0.101 0.637 0.738 0.062 0.003 0.065 0.029 0.399 0.429 For confidentiality reasons numbers are indexed to the value of the outcome measure for non-entry markets before the Wal-Mart entry date Table 3: Before and after Wal-Mart entry measures of profits, wholesale prices, and shipments for entry and non-entry markets Estimating Wal-Mart entry effects using a differences-in-differences approach controls for changes common to both types of markets (Angrist and Krueger 1999). Impact estimates on supplier profits, wholesale prices, and shipments, expressed as a percent of the average value 6 in entry markets before Wal-Mart, are 19% (0.637 / 3.350), 0.2% (0.003 / 1.037), and 12.6% (0.399 / 3.172), respectively. As each of these effects is smaller compared to the weekly pre versus post entry changes (Table 2), particularly wholesale price for which the impact estimate is near zero, the results reported in Table 2 may not be attributable to entry. Even though these numbers are more reliable than those in Table 2, they are not without limitations. They have a causal interpretation only if we can reasonably assume that, except for entry, markets with and without entry are comparable. This would imply that WalMart selects entry markets at random. The fact that entry markets appear, on average, to generate much higher supplier profits and shipments suggests such an assumption is highly questionable. If Wal-Mart is strategic in its selection of markets to enter, the results in Table 3 are invalid. Our approach to dealing with potential selection bias is described next. 3 Selection bias Matching and Instrumental Variables are two common techniques to correct for selection bias (Angrist and Krueger 1999). In the context of our study it is difficult to identify instruments that are correlated with Wal-Mart’s entry decisions but uncorrelated with supplier outcomes (see Qian 2007, Gensler et al. 2009, Tripathi 2009 for similar arguments). Matching replicates a randomized experiment by using covariates to pair experimental (EM) and control markets (CM) (Rubin 2006, Gensler et al. 2009). It ensures that, conditional on covariates, the assignment of markets to the experimental or control condition is independent of market outcomes (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983). Whereas matching on one or a few binary variables is generally straightforward, exact matching on multiple, possibly continuous, variables is infeasible (Angrist and Krueger 1999, Gensler et al. 2009). Propensity Score Matching (PSM) is a commonly used method to reduce the dimensionality of the matching problem (Rubin 2006). Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983) have shown that if the conditional independence assumption is satisfied by conditioning on 7 Variable Estimate Intercept -22.666∗∗ Median age -0.024∗ 2.423∗∗ log(Population density) log(Population density)2 -0.211∗∗ 9.919∗∗ log(Income per capita) -1.519∗∗ log(Income per capita)2 No. of other supercenters -0.021∗∗ Herfindahl index -10.592∗∗ N Nagelkerke’s R2 ∗∗ p-value < .01, ∗ p-value Standard error 2.998 0.011 0.222 0.018 1.976 0.329 0.005 0.574 22186 0.360 < .05 Table 4: Logit estimates for propensity score matching covariates (X), it is also satisfied by conditioning on the propensity score P (X). When the propensity scores for two markets are identical, they are equally likely to receive a treatment because “as far as we can tell from the values of the confounding covariates, a coin was tossed to decide who received treatment 1 and who received treatment 2” (Rubin 2006, p. 448). In our study the propensity score is the probability that Wal-Mart will enter a market given the value of observables.2 Propensity scores are calculated as the predicted value from a logistic regression with market treatment as the dependent variable (i.e., 1 if Wal-Mart entered a market, 0 otherwise) (Angrist and Krueger 1999). To minimize selection bias and ensure only relevant covariates are included in the model a stepwise estimation procedure was employed (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1984). Table 4 shows the estimated coefficients and standard errors for the selected variables. Population size has been used in previous research on Wal-Mart entry (Jia 2008, Zhu and Singh 2009). Our estimated non-linear effect suggests entry is less likely for markets with extremely low or extremely high population density. Although Wal-Mart is known to prefer lower income markets (Graff and Ashton 1994, Moreton 2006, Vedder and Cox 2006, Halebsky 2009) we find the retailer avoids both the lowest and the highest income markets. The negative coefficient for age suggests Wal-Mart opts for areas with younger families (see 2 In this study we equate markets to zip-code areas. 8 alsoSingh et al. 2006). The number of non-Wal-Mart supercenters within a 20-mile radius captures competitive interaction with Target and K-Mart (Jia 2008, Zhu and Singh 2009). The coefficient for the Herfindahl index indicates a preference for markets with more but smaller competitors. We also include state fixed-effects to control for unobserved regional differences (Jia 2008). It is important to ensure that the distribution of propensity scores for experimental and control markets share a common support to avoid biased estimates (Busse et al. 2006). Figure 2 shows the propensity score distributions for EM and CM. To achieve common support, we trimmed the dataset using bounds suggested by Gertler and Simcoe (2006), i.e., we excluded CMs with propensity scores below the 1st percentile of P (X) for EM and excluded EMs with propensity scores above the 99th percentile of P (X) for CM. Trimming reduced our sample size to 629 EM and 10,728 CM. Figure 3 shows the adjusted propensity score distributions. [Insert Figure 2 about here] [Insert Figure 3 about here] After ensuring selected markets lie on the overlapping support of observables, markets with and without entry were paired based on propensity score similarity (Gensler et al. 2009) using nearest available matching (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1985). The steps in this procedure are as follows: 1) EMs and CMs are listed in random order; 2) when the first EM is matched to the nearest CM based on P (X) both markets are removed from the list; 3) repeat step 2 until every EM is matched. After matching the propensity score distributions of EM and CM are virtually identical (see Figure 4). Matching each EM with one CM allows us to avoid bias in the estimated treatment effect that may occur when linking multiple, potentially dissimilar, CMs to an EM (Smith 1997). Moreover, by treating each EM-CM pair as a separate experiment, we are able to investigate variability in entry effects. [Insert Figure 4 about here] 9 Before matching Median age log(Population density) log(Income per capita) No. of other supercenters Herfindahl index N with entry without entry 35.502 5.887 2.943 7.721 0.119 759 37.693 4.893 2.893 5.577 0.466 21427 ∗∗ p-value < .01, t-statistic -11.608∗∗ 18.289∗∗ 4.824∗∗ 5.600∗∗ -78.605∗∗ ∗ After matching with entry without entry t-statistic 35.783 5.935 2.936 8.378 0.119 629 35.855 5.922 2.935 8.394 0.123 629 -0.251 0.150 0.044 -0.028 -1.008 p-value < .05 Table 5: Variable means before and after matching The sample means reported in Table 5 show that experimental and control groups were successfully matched (Rubin 2006). By using PSM, “the observational study equivalent of randomization in an experiment” (Rubin 2006, p. 461), our data were transformed into a quasi-experimental design. 4 Model We use a hierarchical Bayesian model to estimate Wal-Mart entry effects on supplier performance. Our model provides a differences-in-differences estimator, as extensively used in economics (Angrist and Krueger 1999) and marketing (e.g., Ailawadi et al. 2009, Tripathi 2009). Our dependent variables are supplier profits, wholesale prices, and shipments in week t. For each pair of matched experimental and control markets we have P ROF ITiet = α0i + α1i EMie + α2i W Miet + α3i EMie × W Miet + "1iet , (1) W Piet = β0i + β1i EMie + β2i W Miet + β3i EMie × W Miet + "2iet , (2) SHIPiet = γ0i + γ1i EMie + γ2i W Miet + γ3i EMie × W Miet + "3iet , (3) where i indexes a matched pair of markets i = 1, 2, ...N; e indexes an experimental or control market; t indexes time t = 1, 2, ..., T ; P ROF ITiet is supplier profit; W Piet is the wholesale price charged; SHIPiet is shipment volume; EMie is an experimental market dummy (1 for 10 a market with entry, 0 otherwise); and W Miet is the Wal-Mart entry dummy (1 if week t is after entry, 0 otherwise). Note that the times series data for the matched experimental and control markets are stacked for estimation. We assume ("1iet , "2iet , "3iet )" ∼ N(0, Σi ) for i = 1, 2, ..., N. The coefficients α3i , β3i , γ3i capture the treatment effect (i.e., Wal-Mart entry) in our before-and-after-with-control-group analysis (Ailawadi et al. 2009). Model parameters are allowed to vary across markets. The second stage is given by θi = ∆" Zi + ξi , (4) where θi" is the vector of parameters in equations (1-3); ∆ = [δ1 , δ2 , ..., δnz ], ξi ∼ N(0, Vθ ); and Zi is an nz × 1 vector of covariates used to capture heterogeneity in entry effects. We explore whether cross-sectional impact differences can be linked to variation in the products offered to, and carried by, incumbent retailers and Wal-Mart. We also include the covariates from the propensity score model in the Z matrix as controls. Additional details on the estimation algorithm are provided in Appendix A. 5 Results We estimate equations (1-4) twice: First with data from all retailers in a market combined, including Wal-mart (total market), and again with data from incumbents only (incumbents). By isolating the impact of entry on, for example, supplier profits generated from incumbents, we are able to investigate a potential source of changes in the outcome metrics for markets as a whole. For example, profits from a market might increase after entry due to a direct boost from Wal-Mart at the expense of profits from incumbents. Providing results for both total markets and incumbents separately provides additional insight into processes affecting supplier performance following entry. 11 5.1 Wal-Mart entry impact The mean percentage change in manufacturer total market profits is +17.77% (see Table 7) across all markets with Wal-Mart entry; profits from incumbents drop only slightly (-1.34%).3 The supplier studied clearly benefits from the collaboration with Wal-Mart. Compared to the size of Wal-Mart entry effects on manufacturer profits the magnitude of impact on wholesale prices is much smaller. On average, wholesale prices increased only 0.55% and 0.32% for total market and incumbents, respectively. Interestingly, shipments to incumbents drop only 2.52% following entry. When we include Wal-Mart, however, total market shipments increase by 14.95%, on average, which is similar in magnitude to the post-entry profit change mentioned above. As the estimated Wal-Mart entry effects differ substantially from those reported in Table 2, controlling for selection bias is clearly important in our application. Profits Wholesale price Shipments Total market Incumbents Total market Incumbents Total market Incumbents Mean 17.77% -1.34% 0.55% 0.32% 14.95% -2.52% 25th perc 1.45% -15.29% -3.40% -3.77% -1.34% -16.88% 50th perc 12.26% -3.16% 0.65% 0.47% 11.13% -3.68% 75th perc 30.72% 7.81% 4.46% 4.25% 26.28% 7.99% Parameters were converted to percentages for reasons of confidentiality. Table 6: Wal-Mart entry effects The magnitudes of entry impact on supplier profits and shipments are intriguing. To ensure these effects are not an artifact of the estimation procedure used we conducted several robustness checks (see Table 7). A fixed-effects differences-in-differences estimator was employed to calculate the main effects at the total market level (Angrist and Krueger 1999). The estimates for profits, wholesale prices, and shipments were 19.01%, 0.32%, and 12.59% respectively; very similar to the results based on matching. We also estimated two differences-in-differences models with alternative matching procedures. First, we used the 3 For confidentiality reasons we do not report the parameter estimates from Equations 1-3 directly. Rather, we transform them to a percentage change after entry relative to the average weekly profits, wholesale prices, and shipments before Wal-Mart entry. 12 same covariates in the logit model as reported in Table 4 but estimated the model five times, once for each year in our dataset. Markets were matched based on the parameters of the logit model for the year in which entry occurred. If Wal-Mart’s entry strategy changes over time this matching procedure should produce results different from those reported in Table 5.1. The estimates for profits, wholesale prices, and shipments derived using the ’matching by year’ procedure were 17.52%, 0.33%, and 13.91% respectively; again, very similar to our earlier results. Finally, we estimated a matching model with a broader set of covariates including quadratic terms for all variables but excluding state-fixed effects, regardless of statistical significance. Note that we did not use trimming as part of this matching procedure. The estimates for profits, wholesale prices, and shipments from the ’matching without trimming’ model were 16.95%, -0.25%, and 15.53% respectively; again, very similar to the results reported in Table 5.1. Profit fixed effects differences-in-differences matching by year matching without trimming 19.01% 17.52% 16.95% Wholesale price 0.32% 0.33% -0.25% Shipments 12.59% 13.91% 15.53% Table 7: Robustness checks on total market impact of Wal-Mart entry Figures 5, 6, and 7 contain histograms of the θi estimates derived from equations 1-4. All three graphs show that entry impact estimates vary significantly; the vertical black line in each figure is drawn at the median value. We investigate plausible causes of this variability in Section 5.3 below. [Insert Figure 5 about here] [Insert Figure 6 about here] [Insert Figure 7 about here] 13 Table 8 shows the percentage of positive, non-significant, and negative estimates of entry impact on supplier profits from total markets (i.e., incumbents plus Wal-Mart) and incumbents respectively. In nearly 56% of the markets studied post-entry market profits increased significantly; they decreased in only 9% of markets. Supplier profits from incumbent retailers are down in nearly a third of post-entry markets, whereas in 20% of cases incumbent contributions increased. Interestingly, over two-thirds of markets generate as much, if not more, profits for the supplier after entry even when excluding contributions from Wal-Mart. Total market Incumbents % (non)significant effects + ns 55.92% 34.99% 9.09% 19.90% 47.17% 32.93% For significant estimates zero is not contained in the 95% credibility region. Table 8: Wal-Mart entry impacts on supplier profits The three scatter plots in Figure 8depict the relationship between supplier profits from Wal-Mart, incumbents, and the total market following entry. The first panel shows the correlation between profits from incumbents and Wal-Mart is limited (r = 0.065), demonstrating that the benefits derived from Wal-Mart’s market presence need not come at the expense of profits the manufacturer generates from other retailers. Interestingly, the correlation between profits from Wal-Mart and the total market, shown in the second panel, is not especially strong either (r = 0.361). As Wal-Mart accounts, on average, for 19.19% of total post-entry market profits, this result is surprising. In contrast, the correlation between profits from incumbents and total market, shown in the bottom panel, is very high (r = .954), which suggests maintaining profit levels generated from incumbents is key to the supplier’s post-entry performance. [Insert Figure 8 about here] We find that Wal-Mart entry can affect wholesale prices charged to incumbent retailers, even though the size of the effect is, on average, small (Table 7). Table 9 shows the percentage 14 of markets with a significant increase, no significant change, and a significant decrease in wholesale prices. The distribution of wholesale price changes is clearly very balanced: we observe each effect in approximately one-third of markets. Even though previous research has suggested that Wal-Mart entry may depress retail prices (Basker 2005, Ailawadi et al. 2009), we do not find a clear directional pattern for wholesale prices. Total market Incumbents % (non)significant effects + ns 37.39% 32.08% 30.53% 36.02% 31.73% 32.25% For significant estimates zero is not contained in the 95% credibility region. Table 9: Wal-Mart entry impact on wholesale prices Estimates of Wal-Mart’s impact on shipments are presented in Table 10. In 44.77% of markets we observe significant expansion, whereas in 44.60% of markets suppliers experience no net gain. Interestingly, after comparing pre- to post-entry conditions, we conclude that in nearly 70% of markets incumbents generate as much, if not more, supplier shipment volume post-entry. Total market Incumbents % (non)significant effects + ns 44.77% 44.60% 10.63% 18.35% 49.23% 32.42% For significant estimates zero is not contained in the 95% credibility region. Table 10: Wal-Mart entry impact on supplier shipments The three scatter plots in Figure 9depict the relationship between supplier shipments to Wal-Mart, incumbents, and the total market following entry. The first panel demonstrates that the correlation between shipments to incumbents and Wal-Mart is negligible (r = −0.011), suggesting limited post-entry cannibalization. Surprisingly, the second panel shows that the correlation between shipments to the total market and profits generated by WalMart is not particularly strong either (r = 0.258). As Wal-Mart accounts, on average, for 18.85% of total market shipments after entry, this effect is surprising. In contrast, the 15 correlation between shipments to incumbents and total market, shown in the bottom panel, is very high (r = .963), demonstrating the importance of maintaining post-entry shipment levels to incumbents. [Insert Figure 9 about here] 5.2 Drivers of post-entry profitability change As mentioned above, Dukes et al. (2006) argue that manufacturers can boost profits when faced with a dominant retailer by charging higher wholesale prices to incumbents, whereas Chen (2003) theorizes they should lower them. We use the correlation between the total market estimate for α3 and the β3 estimate for incumbents to evaluate their contradictory hypotheses (see equations 1 and 2). A strong positive correlation between the parameters would provide support for Dukes et al. (2006)’s hypothesis, whereas a strong negative correlation would affirm Chen (2003)’s theory. Figure 10 shows a scatter plot of Wal-Mart’s impact on both wholesale prices charged to incumbents and manufacturer profits. The loosely scattered points clearly indicate that the correlation between manufacturer profit changes and wholesale price changes is negligible (r = −0.024). Interestingly, the results from our empirical analysis support neither hypothesis. Although the results in Table 9 show wholesale prices can change, Figure 10 clearly demonstrates they are not the key driver of manufacturer profit changes following Wal-Mart entry. [Insert Figure 10 about here] The fact that wholesale prices are, on average, only marginally affected by Wal-Mart entry implies that shipments must be the key driver of the manufacturer profit changes reported in Table 7. The scatter plot in the left-hand panel of Figure 11 depicts the link between changes in profits and total market shipments following Wal-Mart entry; the one on the right shows the correlation between profit and shipments to incumbent retailers. In 16 contrast to Figure 10 both plots show a positive relationship, confirming that shipments are indeed the prominent driver of supplier profit change. The slope in the right-hand panel (r = 0.884) clearly demonstrates that incumbents are important to the supplier’s overall profitability in post-entry periods. While selling to Wal-Mart generates financial benefits, the manufacturer obviously fairs best when incumbent shipments either increase or remain unchanged following entry. [Insert Figure 11 about here] 5.3 Moderators of Wal-Mart entry impact Results reported in Section 5.1 show considerable variation in Wal-Mart entry effects on supplier performance. Manufacturers could learn how to influence outcomes in their favor by understanding the sources of variation. As mentioned in our introduction, Dukes et al. (2009) theorize incumbents retailers should carry a broader assortment in the presence of a dominant retailer that chooses to offer a limited product selection per category. Their results imply that both the incumbents’ assortment size and the overlap with Wal-Mart impacts performance. Recent work by Ailawadi et al. (2009) confirms that incumbents can mitigate Wal-Mart entry effects by increasing assortment size.4 Retailers who’s assortments overlap substantially with Wal-Mart’s are vulnerable according to Gielens et al. (2008). Moreover, Dukes et al. (2009) also suggest that a supplier may choose to sell its specialty items only to incumbents in the presence of a dominant retailer. Even though a dominant retailer will only stock the most popular items to reduce assortment costs, incumbents will benefit from carrying a larger assortment despite the additional cost. In sum, previous research implies that, because WalMart carries a limited selection of goods in most categories (e.g.,Stone 1988, O’Keefe 2002), incumbents should offer a relatively large assortment focused on products Wal-Mart does 4 Since the authors do not have information on products carried by Wal-Mart, they cannot address the implications of assortment overlap. 17 not sell. Therefore, we expect that the impact of Wal-Mart entry on supplier profits will be moderated by incumbents’ assortment choices. Figure 12 depicts the distribution of assortment overlap between Wal-Mart and incumbents in experimental markets pre- and post-entry. Surprisingly, it seems that incumbent retailers’ product assortment becomes more like Wal-Mart’s after entry. Since this effect could, at least partly, be explained by changes in the supplier’s product line we express the assortment characteristics for experimental markets relative to their matched control market. In fact, our focal supplier’s product line contracted by 35% as depicted in Figure 13.5 We define change in assortment overlap as (ope1 − ope0 ) − (opc1 − opc0 ) where e (c) identifies an experimental (control) market. op1 is the percent overlap in post-entry assortment between incumbents and Wal-Mart, whereas op0 represents the assortment similarity between incumbents before entry and Wal-Mart upon entry. Although Dukes et al. (2009) suggest incumbents should diversify, the median assortment overlap change is +3.3%, even after controlling for variation in the manufacturer’s product line. We define change in assortment size as ( ne1 −ne0 ) ne0 −( nc1 −nc0 ) nc0 where e (c) is defined as before and n1 (n0 ) captures the num- ber of products in the incumbents assortment after (before) Wal-Mart entry. The median assortment size change is -0.02%. [Insert Figure 12 about here] [Insert Figure 13 about here] Equation 4 describes the second stage model used to correlate entry effects on supplier performance to changes in incumbents’ assortment. Table 11 contains the ∆ estimates for the total market and incumbent level analyses.6 The impact of Wal-Mart entry on supplier 5 Although the percentage of total shipments accounted for by Wal-Mart increases over time, it never exceeds 5% in the time span of our data. Hence, we assume the reduction in assortment size is not related to Wal-Mart. 6 To simplify exposition we do not report parameter estimates for the control variables included in the Z matrix. 18 profits from the total market and incumbents are both positively correlated with incumbent assortment size changes. Consistent with predictions by Dukes et al. (2009) and extending results reported in Ailawadi et al. (2009), we demonstrate that carrying a wider assortment not only benefits incumbents but also boosts suppliers’ overall profits. Change in assortment overlap Change in assortment size Total market Profits Shipments -0.654%∗ -0.543%∗ 0.039%∗ 0.041%∗ Incumbents Profits Shipments -0.517%∗ -0.428%∗ 0.037%∗ 0.038%∗ * zero is not contained in the 99% credibility region. Parameters were converted to percentages for reasons of confidentiality. Table 11: Posterior means for ∆ divided by average pre-entry profits/shipments Confirming Dukes et al. (2009) Table 11 shows the manufacturer benefits most, at both the market and incumbent level, when incumbent retailers assortment overlap with WalMart is limited. Holding other variables constant, a 1% decrease in assortment overlap increases weekly post-entry supplier profits from incumbents by 0.517% and shipments to incumbents by 0.428%. Interestingly, a reduction in overlap has an even stronger impact on supplier profits from the total market. A 1% decrease in overlap increases post-entry supplier total market profits by 0.654% and shipments by 0.543%. This result suggests that increased assortment differentiation does not diminish supplier profits generated by WalMart; to the contrary, it increases them. In addition, even though changes in assortment size are statistically significant, effect sizes are small. A 1% increase in assortment size increases weekly post-entry supplier market profits by 0.039% and shipments by 0.041%. The impact on profits from and shipments to incumbents are similar in magnitude (0.037% and 0.038% respectively). 19 6 Conclusion In this paper, we study a broad set of geographical markets to determine whether Wal-Mart entry impacts supplier profits and, if so, what processes drive post-entry profitability change. Our unique database, collected by a Wal-Mart vendor, spans thousands of retail stores and hundreds of products for a period of five years. We employed propensity score matching to control for potential selection bias before analyzing the drivers of profit change: wholesale prices and shipments. A hierarchical Bayesian model was used to quantify the effects of entry and link the results to differences in retailer assortment characteristics across markets. We find that mean post-entry supplier profit increased by 17.77% for the total market, whereas profits derived from incumbents decreased only marginally. While the size of this effect is surprising, various analyses demonstrate its robustness. Interestingly, over twothirds of markets generate as much, if not more, profits for the supplier after entry even when excluding contributions from Wal-Mart. Contrary to both Chen (2003) and Dukes et al. (2006) our results clearly show that changes in wholesale prices are not the main driver of post-entry supplier profit changes; market expansion is. We observe a significant increase in shipments to 45% of markets studied. Surprisingly, as post-entry incumbent shipments drop less than 3%, on average, cannibalization by Wal-Mart is limited. Furthermore, our analysis demonstrates that both supplier shipments and profits increases are highest for markets in which incumbents offer a wider array of products and carry items that Wal-Mart does not sell. Our study’s managerial implications are threefold. First, in addition to other benefits that partnering with Wal-Mart may offer, e.g., improved distribution processes and inventory management systems, (e.g.,Bergdahl 2004, Vedder and Cox 2006) our study shows that selling to Wal-Mart can directly boost suppliers’ bottom line. Even though news stories threaded with manufacturer complaints about Wal-Mart resonate with critics and general public alike, we argue that some complaints about selling to Wal-Mart may be overstated as the supplier studied is clearly better off post-entry. 20 Second, we show that while suppliers benefit from the additional volume Wal-Mart generates they perform best when post-entry shipments to incumbents increase or remain unchanged. In addition, the strong link between assortment characteristics and shipments to incumbents suggests suppliers should encourage them to carry larger and non-overlapping assortments, which could have important implications for retail competition. Wal-Mart is known for its aggressive competitive strategy, as David Glass (CEO Wal-Mart Stores Inc. 1988-2000) explained: “We want everybody to be selling the same stuff, and we want to compete on a price basis, and they will go broke 5 percent before we will.”(Fishman 2006, p. 48, 68). Trying to beat Wal-Mart at the pricing game is infeasible (Bergdahl 2004) but, as one grocer put it, “They can’t beat our price on items they don’t have.” (O’Keefe 2002). Retailers selling the same goods as Wal-Mart not only put themselves in jeopardy (e.g., Stone 1995, Gielens et al. 2008), our results demonstrate they also bring down supplier shipments and profits. Increased retail differentiation will not only boost supplier profits from incumbents but, surprisingly, also from Wal-Mart. Therefore, we suggest that suppliers motivate incumbents to diversify, for example, by offering them specialty products, slotting allowances, services, or training that Wal-Mart does not need or want. Third, to enhance incumbents assortment options manufacturers should maintain product lines. Wal-Mart has become the primary customer for many suppliers, who devote a large chunk of their marketing resources to serve the retailer (Useem 2003, Fishman 2006). Some manufacturers even prune their product lines to better target Wal-Mart’s customers (Fishman 2006), offering incumbents little room to diversify. They are setting up a “loselose” situation, as retailers cannot but carry the same products Wal-Mart does. Just as Wal-Mart continually improves itself by studying its customers buying habits (Huey 1998), manufacturers should not only develop and market products for Wal-Mart, but also learn from and cater to incumbent retailers’ consumers. Future research could extend our findings in several ways. For example, while we focus on one major manufacturer in large number of geographical areas in the U.S., researchers could 21 expand our findings to additional industries and countries. Moreover, whereas our study quantifies Wal-Mart entry impact on supplier profits, wholesale prices, and shipments, its implications on incumbent retailer profits have yet to be addressed. Since our results clearly indicate limited cannibalization from incumbents, it would be interesting to investigate the underlying causes of the Wal-Mart entry shipment boost. Is it an income effect? Is the increase driven by a disproportionate change in the demand for products in a specific quality tier? Are incumbent retailers lowering prices for certain products? Furthermore, retailers, suppliers, and consumers may benefit if future studies could determine how retailers can best differentiate their assortments from Wal-Mart. Wal-Mart’s influence on today’s global economy is unlike that of any other retailer. Our study provides several new and important insights into Wal-Mart’s impact on its suppliers. We hope that, with manufacturer and retailer cooperation, researchers will be able to paint a comprehensive picture of the costs and benefits for all constituents when Wal-Mart comes to town. 22 A Estimation algorithm A system of regression equations (see equations 1-3) is estimated for each pair of matched markets, where the errors are assumed to follow a normal distribution with mean 0 and covariance matrix Σi . In the second stage the θi coefficients from the first stage are linked to a set of cross-sectional characteristics Zi . Natural conjugate priors are specified for the ¯ Vθ ⊗ A−1 ) where %̄ = 0 hyper prior parameters: Vθ ∼ IW (w0 , W0 ), vec(∆)|Vθ ∼ N(vec(∆), , A = 0.01I, w0 = nz + 3, W0 = w0 I. The prior for the first stage error structure is Σi ∼ IW (ν0 , V0 ) where ν0 = 6 and V0 = ν0 I. Thus, we constructed a Gibbs sampler for this model by 1) drawing the regression parameters θi |Σi and Σi |θi given the parameters of the first stage prior, ∆ and Vθ 2) drawing ∆ and Vθ conditional on θi , Σi using a multivariate regression. The sampler is run for a total of 20,000 iterations to simulate the posterior distributions of the parameters. Every 5th draw of the last 10,000 is selected, leaving 2,000 draws for inference. Since we use a standard linear hierarchical Bayesian model, we refer to Rossi et al. (2005) for further details. 23 References Kusum L. Ailawadi, Norm Borin, and Paul W. Farris. Market Power and Performance: A Cross-Industry Analysis of Manufacturers and Retailers. Journal of Retailing, 71(3): 211–248, 1995. Kusum L. Ailawadi, Jie Zhang, Aradhna Krishna, and Michael Kruger. When Wal-Mart Enters: How Incumbent Retailers React and How this Affects Their Sales Outcomes. Journal of Marketing Research, Forthcoming, 2009. Akron Beacon Journal 2000. Wal-mart bounces rubbermaid. Joshua D. Angrist and Alan B. Krueger. Empirical strategies in labor economics. In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, editors, Handbook of Labor Economics, volume 3, chapter 23, pages 1277–1366. Elsevier Science, 1st edition, 1999. Emek Basker. Selling a Cheaper Mousetrap: Wal-Mart’s Effect on Retail Prices. Journal of Urban Economics, 58(2):203–229, 2005. Michael Bergdahl. What I learned from Sam Walton. How to Compete and Thrive in a Wal-Mart World. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., Hoboken, New Jersey, 2004. Dan Bianchi and Dan Swinney. Wal-Mart: A destructive force for Chicago communities and companies, March 25 2004. Center for Labor and Community Research, Chicago, IL. Paul N. Bloom and Vanessa G. Perry. Retailer Power and Supplier Welfare: The Case of Wal-Mart. Journal of Retailing, 77:379–396, 2001. Robert J Bowman. Should You just Say No to Wal-Mart? Distribution, 96(12):52, 1997. S. D. Brunn. Wal-mart world: the world’s biggest corporation in the global economy. CRC Press, 2006. 24 Meghan Busse, Jorge Silva-Risso, and Florian Zettlemeyer. $1000 cash back: The passthrough of auto manufacturer promotions. The American Economic Review, 96(4):1253– 1270, 2006. Zhiqi Chen. Dominant Retailers and the Countervailing-power Hypothesis. RAND Journal of Economics, 34(4):612–625, 2003. Anthony J. Dukes, Esther Gal-or, and Kannan Srinivasan. Channel Bargaining with Retailer Asymmetry. Journal of Marketing Research, XLIII:84–97, 2006. Anthony J. Dukes, Tansev Geylani, and Kannan Srinivasan. Strategic Assortment Reduction by a Dominant Retailer. Marketing Science, 28(2):309–319, 2009. Charles Fishman. The Wal-Mart Effect. How the World’s Most Powerful Company Really Works - and How It’s Transforming the American Economy. the Penguin Group, New York, NY, 2006. Sonja Gensler, Peter Leeflang, and Bernd Skiera. Influence of Online Use on Product Usage Behavior and Consequences for Customer Channel Migration Strategies. Working paper, January 2009. Paul J. Gertler and Tim S. Simcoe. Disease Management. SSRN eLibrary, 2006. Katrijn Gielens, Linda M. Van de Gucht, Jan-Benedict E.M. Steenkamp, and Marnik G. Dekimpe. Dancing with a Giant: The Effect of Wal-Mart’s Entry into the United Kingdom on the Stock Prices of European Retailers. Journal of Marketing Research, XLV:519–534, 2008. Stephan J. Goetz and Anil Rupasingha. Wal-Mart and Social Capital. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 88(5):1304–1310, December 2006. Marty Gosman and Mark J. Kohlbeck. The effects of wal-mart on the profitability and investor valuation of its suppliers. SSRN eLibrary, 2006. 25 O.Z. Graff, Thomas and Dub Ashton. Spatial Diffusion of Wal-Mart: Contagious and Reverse Hierarchical Elements. The Professional Geographer, 46(1):19–29, 1994. Stephen Halebsky. Small Towns and Big Business. Challenging Wal-Mart Superstores. Rowman & Littlefield publishers, Inc., Lanham, MD, 2009. Jerry Hausman and Ephraim Leibtag. Consumer Benefits from Increased Competition in Shopping Outlets: Measuring the Effect of Wal-Mart. Working paper, October 2005. John Huey. Discounting Dynamo Sam Walton, 1998. Panle Jia. What Happens When Wal-Mart Comes to Town: An Empirical Analysis of the Discount Retailing Industry. Econometrica, 76(6):1263–1316, 2008. Stephen Kinzer. Wal-Mart’s big-city plans stall again. New York Times, page A.27, May 6, late edition 2004. Ryan J. Luchs. Three Essays Addressing Issues in Retail Channels. PhD thesis, the Katz Graduate SChool of Business, University of Pittsburgh, PA, 2008. J.E. McGee and T.A. Festervand. When Wal-Mart comes to town: A look at David’s response to the arrival of retailing’s Goliath. Journal of Business Strategy, 7(3):15–27, 1998. Bethany E. Moreton. The Would of the Service Economy: Wal-Mart and the Making of Christian Free Enterprise, 1929-1994. PhD thesis, Yale University, 2006. Sandra Mottner and Steve Smith. Wal-Mart: Supplier performance and market power. Journal of Business Research, 62(5):535–541, May 2009. Junfu Zhang Neumark, David and Stephen Ciccarella. The effects of Wal-Mart on local labor markets. Journal of Urban Economics, 63:405–430, 2008. B. O’Keefe. Meet your new neighborhood grocer. Fortune, 145(10):93–96, 2002. 26 Larry Parsons. Vote makes way for Wal-Mart: Marina planning commission’s action can’t be appealed to city council. The Monterey County Herald, page 1, April 28 2006. Yi Qian. Do national patent laws stimulate domestic innovation in a global patenting environment? a cross-country analysis of pharmaceutical patent protection, 1978 –2002. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1):436–453, 2007. Paul R. Rosenbaum and Donald B. Rubin. The Central Role of the Propensity Score in Observational Studies for Causal Effects. Biometrika, 70(1):41–55, 1983. Paul R. Rosenbaum and Donald B. Rubin. Reducing bias in observational studies using subclassification on the propensity score. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 79(387):516–524, 1984. Paul R. Rosenbaum and Donald B. Rubin. Constructing a Control Group Using Multivariate Matched Sampling Methods That Incorporate the Propensity Score. The American Statistician, 39(1):33–38, 1985. Peter E. Rossi, Greg M. Allenby, and Robert E. McCulloch. Bayesian Statistics and Marketing. John Wiley and Sons, West Sussex, England, 2005. Donald B. Rubin. Matched Sampling for Causal Effects. Cambridge University Press, New York, 2006. Ameet Sachdev. Wal-Mart Cuts Data Supply: Researchers Say Scanner Numbers Hard to Replace. Chicago Tribune, May 15 2001. Vishal P. Singh, Karsten T. Hansen, and Robert C. Blattberg. Market Entry and Consumer Behavior: An Investigation of a Wal-Mart Supercenter. Marketing Science, 25(5):457–476, 2006. Herbert Smith. Matching with multiple controls to estimate treatment effects in observational studies. Sociological Methodology, 27(1):325–353, 1997. 27 Kenneth E. Stone. The effect of Wal-Mart Stores on businesses in host towns and surrounding towns in Iowa. Department of Economics, Iowa State University, 1988. Kenneth E. Stone. Impact of Wal-Mart Stores on Iowa Communities: 1983-93. Economic Develop Review, (Spring):60–69, 1995. Manish Tripathi. Spillovers from Offline Entry: An Analysis of Buyer and Seller Behavior on eBay. Working paper, June 2009. Jerry Useem. One Nation under Wal-Mart. Fortune: New York, 147(4):65, 2003. Richard Vedder and Wendell Cox. The Wal-Mart Revolution. How Big-box Stores Benefit Consumers, Workers, and the Economy. American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 2006. Wal-Mart Stores Inc. 2008. Wal-Mart Corporate Fact Sheet. Wal-Mart Stores Inc. 2009. Wal-mart reports financial results for fiscal year and fourth quarter. Ting Zhu and Vishal Singh. Spatial Competition with Endogenous Location Choices - An Application to Discount Retailing. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 7(1):1–35, 2009. 28 Figure 1: Location of Wal-Mart entries 29 80 60 Density 0 20 40 Control Market Experimental Market 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Pr[Entry=1|X] Figure 2: Propensity score distribution for experimental and control markets 30 20 15 10 0 5 Density Control Market Experimental Market 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 Pr[Entry=1|X] Figure 3: Propensity score distribution for experimental and control markets on common support of P (X) 31 Experimental Market 0 0 1 1 2 2 Density Density 3 3 4 4 Control Market 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.0 Pr[Entry=1|X] 0.1 0.2 0.3 Pr[Entry=1|X] Figure 4: Propensity score distribution for matched markets 32 0.4 0.5 Supplier Profits (Incumbents) Frequency 80 50 60 40 0 20 0 Frequency 100 100 120 150 140 Supplier Profits (Total Market) − 0+ − 0+ Figure 5: Wal-Mart entry impact on supplier profits 33 Wholesale Prices (Incumbents) 60 0 20 40 Frequency 40 20 0 Frequency 60 80 80 Wholesale Prices (Total Market) − 0+ − 0 Figure 6: Wal-Mart entry impact on wholesale prices charged 34 + Shipments (Incumbents) 40 60 Frequency 60 40 0 20 20 0 Frequency 80 80 100 100 120 120 Shipments (Total Market) − 0+ − 0+ Figure 7: Wal-Mart entry impact on supplier shipments 35 0+ Profits from incumbents − 0 + 0+ − Profits from total market Profits from Wal−Mart 0 + 0 − Profits from total market + Profits from Wal−Mart − 0 + Profits from incumbents Figure 8: Profits from Wal-Mart, Incumbents, and Total market 36 0+ Shipments to incumbents − 0 + 0+ − Shipments to total market Shipments to Wal−Mart 0 + 0+ − Shipments to total market Shipments to Wal−Mart − 0 + Shipments to incumbents Figure 9: Shipments to from Wal-Mart, Incumbents, and Total market 37 0+ − Wholesale Prices − 0 + Supplier Profits Figure 10: Wal-Mart entry impact on supplier profits versus Wal-Mart entry impact on wholesale prices charged to incumbents 38 − 0+ Shipments to Incumbents 0+ − Shipments to Total Market − 0+ − Supplier Profits 0+ Supplier Profits Figure 11: Wal-Mart entry impact on supplier profits versus Wal-Mart entry impact on shipments to total market (left panel) and incumbents only (right panel) 39 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 Density pre−entry post−entry 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Assortment Overlap Figure 12: Density of assortment overlap 40 1.0 110 100 90 80 Quarterly Assortment Index 70 60 50 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Product line length is indexed to December 1999 for confidentiality reasons. Figure 13: Change in length of supplier product line 41 2005