Defined ambition pension schemes Standard Note: SN 6902 Last updated: 22 September 2014 Author: Djuna Thurley Section Business and Transport Section At present, there are two types of occupational pension: Defined Benefit (DB) schemes that typically promise a pension linked to salary and length of service; and Defined Contribution (DC) schemes that pay out a sum based on the value of a member’s fund on retirement. The last few decades have seen a decline of DB schemes, with a number of factors combining to make them less attractive to employers. Membership of DC schemes has increased, and is expected to increase further as automatic enrolment is rolled-out. A key difference between the scheme types is who bears the risk. In DB schemes, longevity, inflation and investment risks are borne by the employer, whereas in DC schemes they are borne by the employee and there is a very high level of uncertainty about the level of income they can expect in retirement. The Government has been consulting on the possibility of encouraging the development of ‘defined ambition’ (DA) pension schemes, the aim of which would be to create greater certainty for members than is provided by a pure DC pension, but at less cost volatility for employers than current DB pensions. In particular, it has looked at how collective defined contribution schemes might work in the UK. Its proposed model for this would have a fixed contribution rate for employers, a target pension income for employees (with provision for this to be adjusted if the scheme is under-funded); and pooling of scheme assets (rather individual funds for each member), with an income paid from this pool at retirement. The Government found that this approach could provide greater stability of outcomes for individuals than traditional DC, with pension incomes less dependent on market conditions at the point of retirement. However, certain conditions appeared necessary to enable them to operate successfully – in particular, large scale and strong governance. (DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, chapter 5). The Pensions Schemes Bill 2014/15 would provide for new categories of pension schemes: defined benefit, shared risk and defined contribution and a framework for schemes to provide ‘collective benefits’. This note looks at the development of the proposals for defined ambition schemes and the relevant provisions in the Bill. The Bill had its Second Reading on 2 September. Other provisions in the Bill are discussed in Library Research Paper RP Pension Schemes Bill (21 August 2014). This information is provided to Members of Parliament in support of their parliamentary duties and is not intended to address the specific circumstances of any particular individual. It should not be relied upon as being up to date; the law or policies may have changed since it was last updated; and it should not be relied upon as legal or professional advice or as a substitute for it. A suitably qualified professional should be consulted if specific advice or information is required. This information is provided subject to our general terms and conditions which are available online or may be provided on request in hard copy. Authors are available to discuss the content of this briefing with Members and their staff, but not with the general public. Contents 1 Introduction 3 2 Consultation process 6 Response 8 3 4 5 6 Proposals for introducing more flexibility in DB 10 3.1 Background 10 3.2 The Labour Government’s Deregulatory Review 11 3.3 The current Government’s proposals 12 The ability to pay fluctuating benefits. 13 Automatic conversion to DC for early leavers 13 Ability to change scheme pension age 13 Responses 14 The Government’s response 15 Proposals for providing greater certainty within DC 15 4.1 Money-back guarantee 16 4.2 Capital and investment return guarantee 17 4.3 Retirement income insurance 18 4.4 Pension income builder 19 Proposals for collective benefits 19 5.1 Occupational pension provision in the Netherlands 20 5.2 Proposals for the UK 22 5.3 Debate 24 Outcomes 24 Viability of CDCs in the UK 25 Intergenerational equity 26 Compatibility with the Budget 2014 announcements 27 Pension Schemes Bill 2014/15 28 1.1 The legislative approach to ‘defined ambition’ 29 1.2 Part 1 – definitions 32 Defined benefits 33 Shared risk 34 Defined contributions 35 Meaning of pension promise 35 2 1.3 1.4 1 Treatment of a scheme as two or more separate schemes 36 Interpretation of Part 1 37 Amendments to do with Part 1 37 Part 2 – general changes to pensions legislation 38 Promise obtained from a third party 38 Disclosure of information 39 Extension of preservation of benefit under occupational schemes 39 Early leavers: revaluation of accrued benefits 40 Early leavers: transfer values 41 Indexation requirements 41 Rules about modification of schemes 42 Part 3 – collective benefits 43 Approach to legislation 43 Definition 47 Targets 47 Investment strategy 48 Valuation reports 49 Policy for dealing with a deficit or surplus 50 Other provisions 51 Introduction There are currently two main types of occupational pension schemes: - Defined Benefit (DB) schemes, that typically promise to pay a pension linked to salary and length of service; and - Defined Contribution (DC) schemes, that typically pay out a sum based on the value of a member’s fund on retirement. The level of pension depends on factors such as the level of contribution paid and investment returns. A key difference between these types of schemes is who bears the risk. In DB schemes, the risks inherent in pension saving – for example, those associated with longevity, investment and inflation - are borne by the sponsoring employer. In DC schemes, they are borne by the individual.1 DB schemes are in decline. Total active membership peeked in the 1960s at 8.1 million, and has fallen to 1.7 million by 2012.2 The reasons for this have been the subject of much debate. 1 2 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Impact Assessment, June 2014, page 12, para 9 Ibid page 10-11 3 A report by the Pensions Policy Institute (PPI) in 2012, identified a number of contributory factors including: Increased Life Expectancy: Increases in life expectancy over the last 30 years due to medical advances and improved lifestyles have meant that people are living longer. […] Investment risk: Investment risk can be a significant issue for sponsors of DB schemes. The returns on bonds and equities will affect the funding position of DB schemes. Where a scheme is in deficit, lower returns will increase the level of contributions required to close the deficit. Over the last decade, bond yields and equity returns have been volatile, and over the longer term the outlook for investment returns remains uncertain. Inflation: The value of the pension received and the cost of providing pensions may be affected by changes in price inflation. In DB schemes revaluation of accrued benefits and indexation of pensions in payment are key parts of scheme design. There is a cap on mandatory indexation and revaluation in DB schemes. For the scheme sponsor the cap reduces the level of inflationary risk but it does not eliminate it entirely. Wage inflation can also increase the cost of providing DB pensions. For example, if an active member of a final salary DB scheme receives a substantial increase in pay at the end of their career, this can disproportionately increase the cost of providing the resulting annual pension. Changes in regulation and legislation: Many different pieces of legislation have been introduced since the 1970s, predominantly with the aim of protecting individual pension rights. However, many of these changes have also led to increased costs for DB schemes, or reduced the attractiveness of providing DB pensions. These include: · · · · · measures to protect members’ rights and the security of pension benefits; changes in the taxation of pension funds; EU regulations, such as equal treatment of men and women’s pensions; tighter accounting standards for DB pensions; revised standards for DB pension scheme funding. However, the Government recently changed the measure of inflation required to be used for the indexation and revaluation of DB pensions from the Retail Prices Index (RPI) to the Consumer Prices Index (CPI). Those DB pension schemes that are able to make this change are likely to reduce their costs of providing a DB pension. 3 It found that overall these factors had significantly increased the cost and risks to employers of providing DB pensions.4 The decline in DB has, to some extent, been offset by an increase in DC provision. DWP explains: Between 1997 and 2012, the proportion of employees with a DB occupational pension scheme fell from 46 per cent to 28 per cent, while DC pension scheme membership, 3 4 PPI, The changing landscape of pension schemes in the private sector in the UK, 27 June 2012 Ibid 4 including group personal and group stakeholder pensions, rose slightly, from 10 per cent to 17 per cent - though not enough to replace the fall in DB membership.5 In its Second Report, published in December 2005, the Pensions Commission said that a delayed response to rising costs had meant that manner of the adjustment, when it happened, had exacerbated inequalities in pension provision: The exceptional equity returns in the 1980s and 1990s allowed many private sector DB schemes to ignore the rapid rise in the underlying cost of their pension promises. When the fool’s paradise came to an end, companies adjusted rapidly, closing DB schemes to new members. A reduction in the generosity of the DB pension promises which existed by the mid1990s was inevitable. That generosity had not resulted from a consciously planned employer approach to labour market competition, and would never have resulted from voluntary employer action well informed by foresight as to the eventual cost, or operating within rational expectations of equity market returns. But the suddenness of the delayed adjustment, its extremely unequal impact as between existing and new members, and the major shift of risk occurring as many people move from DB to DC provision, have severely exacerbated the gaps that have always existed in Britain’s pension system.6 The Commission recommended the introduction of auto-enrolment as a way of addressing the decline in pension saving.7 It was legislated for by the Labour Government in the Pensions Act 2008.8 The current Government, following a review, decided to continue with its implementation.9 The policy is therefore being introduced in stages over the period 2012 to 2018.10 The Government expects auto-enrolment to increase the number newly participating or saving more in a workplace pension saving scheme by between six and nine million. The policy is also expected to reduce the numbers facing inadequate retirement incomes.11 However, the vast majority of those automatically enrolled will be saving into DC pension plans, in which outcomes are uncertain and individuals bear the risks of pension saving.12 In its November 2012 discussion paper, Reinvigorating workplace pensions, the Government said that while engagement with pensions might increase as auto-enrolment was implemented, many individuals would not be comfortable with the level of risk and uncertainty involved in saving in DC pension schemes. It was therefore keen to explore the scope for what it termed ‘Defined Ambition’ (DA) schemes, which would seek to give “greater certainty for members than a DC pension about the final value of their pension pot and less cost volatility for employers than a DB pension.” 13 5 DWP, Framework for the analysis of future pension incomes, September 2013, para 4.3 Pensions Commission, Second Report, December 2005, p125 7 Pensions Commission, A New Pension Settlement for the Twenty-First Century; The Second Report of the Pensions Commission, November 2005, p2-4 8 Part 1 9 ‘Making automatic enrolment work. A review for the Department for Work and Pensions’, October 2010; HC Deb 27 October 2010 c12WS; For more detail, see SN 6417 Pensions: automatic enrolment – 2010 onwards 10 HC Deb, 31 January 2012, c31-2WS; SI 2012/1813 11 DWP, Framework for the analysis of future pension incomes, September 2013 12 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Impact Assessment, DWP, 2014-0911, 26 June 2014 13 DWP, Reinvigorating workplace pensions, Cm 8478, November 2012, p56 6 5 2 Consultation process In its November 2012 discussion paper, Reinvigorating workplace pensions, the Government said that while engagement with pensions might increase as auto-enrolment was implemented, many individuals would not be comfortable with the level of risk and uncertainty involved in saving in DC pension schemes. It was keen to explore the scope for what it termed ‘Defined Ambition’ schemes. These would: […] seek to give greater certainty for members than a DC pension about the final value of their pension pot and less cost volatility for employers than a DB pension. 14 In November 2013, it launched a public consultation, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations (Cm 8410). This set out the challenges it thought Defined Ambition needed to respond to, as follows: Structural: the polarisation of risks represented by traditional DB and DC pension schemes creates the perception of an incomplete system, with the burden of risk falling wholly on the employer or, increasingly, being placed on the individual. DA should provide the space for a greater amount of risk sharing. Regulatory: the criticism that the DB promise brings too great a regulatory and funding burden to the employer. DA should consider reducing some of the regulatory requirements on DB and any new DA framework should be clear about the limits of employer liabilities, and avoid creating new regulatory burdens. Supply/demand: demand from employers and employees for something between DB and DC is not being met by the market. There is a need to examine the extent to which Government intervention is needed to stimulate innovation. Member-driven product design: the extent to which uncertainty about pension savings and retirement incomes from a DC scheme (however good) is a disincentive to save in a pension.15 It proposed a number of principles for their development: A DA scheme should be: 14 15 Consumer focused – address consumer needs (members and employers). Sustainable – affordable to the providers/members) over the long term. Intergenerationally fair – not biased to pensioners, but also take on board needs of future pensioners. Risk sharing – incorporate genuine risk sharing between stakeholders. Proportionately regulated – the regulatory structure needs to be permissive to enable innovation in risk sharing, while protecting member interests. stakeholders (employers/pension DWP, Reinvigorating workplace pensions, Cm 8478, November 2012, p56 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p10 6 Transparent – there should be high governance standards with clarity for members about any promise made and any associated risks.16 The Government said it would review the regulatory structure, with a view to enabling a more equitable sharing of risk: 13. The Government’s role in private pensions involves regulating schemes, products, providers and employers in a number of ways – with member protection at the heart of these activities. 14. With automatic enrolment into workplace pensions, the Government is intervening to address the need for more people to be saving for their retirement, recognising that inertia can lead to individuals not saving. 15. With DA, the Government proposes to review the regulatory structure where it inhibits employers, or the wider market, innovating and providing pensions which meet consumer needs, while providing a more equitable sharing of risk and ensuring where promises are made, they are kept. This balance should ensure the voice of the consumer is heard while there is less prescription about the offer that employers or the market should make.17 From its discussions with employers, it had found that: Employers were positive about offering pensions but wanted schemes that were simple to set up, where costs will not increase in future; They were concerns about generating a pension liability that would have an adverse impact on business accounts; In some sectors, a major factor influencing decisions on pension provision was what other employers were offering. Employers often positioned themselves to match the market rather than lead it; Willingness of employee benefit consultants to advise and recommend new products, and of established providers of pensions administrators to support them, was key to these products becoming established in the market.18 Key considerations were that the new schemes should not cost more than traditional DC and that there should be no funding liability on the employer’s balance sheet.19 For savers, the evidence suggested that a savings product that could provide more certainty about savings or about income in retirement might be better able to earn consumers’ trust and confidence than individual DC products.20 An industry working group looked at a number of possible models, including: lighter versions of DB, DC pensions with an element of guarantee, and collective defined contribution schemes. These are discussed in more detail below. 16 Ibid p 11 Ibid p 11 18 Ibid p13-14 19 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, p9 and 12 20 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p15; See also NEST, Pensions insight – 2014 17 7 In June 2014, the Government said the consultation had confirmed the need for a new framework that would “create a clear DA space with its own regulatory protections to encourage innovation in risk sharing and enable new kinds of collective models.” It would retain its original approach, with some refinements: We intend to retain the overall approach and principles set out in the consultation document, with some refinements. We will continue, as intended, to establish mutually exclusive definitions for scheme type based on degrees of certainty for members. We will also ensure proportionate regulation by applying requirements to certain features – where there is a promise, for example, ensuring it is funded – while still maintaining transparency in the law so that employers are clear on the extent of their obligations. We are committed to avoiding legislation that is overly prescriptive; instead, we want to allow schemes to evolve and innovate. Where we have deviated from the ideas set out in the consultation, we have put additional safeguards in place to ensure the new schemes work to their full potential. We are introducing a new definition of collective benefit, which could be offered under DA or defined contribution (DC) schemes. We will refine the definition of DB scheme to take account of certain discretionary features which already exist in some DB schemes and broaden the definition of DC to cater for self-annuitising and CDC schemes (that do not provide a promise or guarantee during the accrual phase). Money purchase schemes will fall within the DC scheme definition. 21 It said it had decided not to proceed with proposals for flexible DB. This was because, to make enough of a difference, the suggested changes would need to have applied to accrued rights, which was not the Government’s intention.22 Regarding its proposals for providing greater certainty for DC scheme members, it thought the detail of some of its proposals (capital and investment guarantee, retirement income insurance and pension income builder) should be worked out within the legal parameters of the new legislative framework.23 It would also legislate for schemes to provide collective benefits. The issues connected the proposals are discussed in more detail below. Response The responses to the consultation indicate a general support for creating a new space in the legislative framework for DA pensions to develop. The RSA, for example, has argued the case for a new type of pension provision: Britain is witnessing the collapse of its Defined Benefit pension system throughout the private sector. Individual DC pensions are struggling to fill the gap. But they alone cannot provide an efficient pension savings system for everyone. Collective, pooled pensions such as Target Pension Plans provide employers with an alternative way to offer pensions that meet the needs of their employees, without taking on additional burdens themselves.24 The National Employment Savings Trust (NEST) has also welcomed proposals for DA, arguing that it was unlikely that any traditional DC scheme could give satisfactory answers to three basic questions put by savers: 21 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014 22 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, 24 June 2014, page 28 23 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, chapter 2 24 RSA, Collective pension plans briefing note, 2014 8 What will I get out at the end? What happens to my money when it’s in the scheme (‘where does my money go?’) How safe it my money?25 The ABI has welcomed the opportunity to debate a “range of alternative ways to improve certainty for pension savers.”26 The TUC questioned whether a new legislative framework to enable innovation would be enough: While we welcome changing the law to allow Dutch-style target pensions, this will not automatically result in any being set up. We need government action to ensure that workers have access to target pensions as the bigger they are, the better they work. Leaving it to the market is never a solution when it comes to pensions. 27 The National Association of Pension Funds (NAPF) agreed it was important to have a legislative framework that would develop as the pensions landscape continued to evolve.”28 However, the focus must remain on providing good outcomes for DC scheme members: CDC may well have a role to play in this, but the fundamentals still apply. Good outcomes for members are built on strong governance, low charges and investment strategies based on members' needs. The real goal here has to be schemes operating at scale. Scale is a necessary precondition for CDC but it also enables a much wider range of member benefits. As a result of automatic enrolment we are already seeing the emergence of large pension schemes in the form of master trusts, which are able to offer their members high quality investment strategies and great value for money.29 Unite stressed the importance of employer contribution rates and action on charges to improve outcomes for DC scheme members.30 Age UK said that new proposals should not distract from other priorities, such as the ‘guidance guarantee’ announced at the 2014 Budget: These new proposals must not distract us from the major changes happening now. The Government’s clear priority must be to deliver on its commitment to provide highquality, impartial pensions guidance, to help people to be more secure in later life.31 There are also, of course, a range of views on specific proposals. These are discussed in more detail below. NEST, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations – consultation response, 2014 ‘ABI response to the DWP Defined Ambitions Pensions consultation’, 7 November 2013 27 ‘Pensions bills pull in opposite directions, says TUC’ 4 June 2014 28 NAPF, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations – the NAPF’s response, December 2013 29 NAPF comments on Queen’s speech, 4 June 2014 30 Unite response to Reshaping workplace pensions, December 2013, p11 31 Age UK’s response to Queen’s Speech, 4 June 2014; HC Deb 19 March c793 25 26 9 3 Proposals for introducing more flexibility in DB 3.1 Background In its 2007 report on the changing landscape for private sector Defined Benefit pension schemes, the Pensions Policy Institute explained how and why regulation had developed to that point: The number and scope of legislative and regulatory rules have been increasing since the 1970s. The aim of much legislation affecting pensions has been to increase the protection of early leavers’ and pensioners’ rights, and to make occupational pension scheme provision fairer and more transparent. The Government would argue that the policies have helped maintain public confidence in pensions. But in certain cases, critics have argued that these rules have added to the cost of pension promises. Increased regulation Government regulatory policy focuses on three main themes: to increase the level of members’ benefits; and/or to increase the security of members’ benefits; and/or to improve the running of schemes: To increase the level of members’ benefits. A sponsoring employer of a DB scheme is expected to pay sufficient contributions to ensure that the promised pension benefits are paid once the employee retires. However, until recently the level of guarantee backing a pension promise has not been clearly defined. A key change to pension schemes over the last 20 years has been the replacement of discretionary benefits by guaranteed benefits; in particular, increases to pensions in payment (i.e. pensions already being paid to members in retirement) and to pensions in deferral (i.e. pension rights of members that are no longer contributing into the scheme). For example, early leavers were granted greater protection under the Social Security Acts of 1973 and 1985. Initially, only those who stayed in the scheme for more than 5 years were entitled to a preserved pension. Then the time limit was reduced to 2 years. This reduced the cross-subsidy from early leavers to stayers, which had previously helped to keep costs down. Statutory increases to pensions in payment originated in the Pensions Act 1995. The original law stated that post 1997 accrued rights were required to increase in line with the Retail Price Index, capped at 5%. This requirement is called Limited Price Indexation (LPI) and is often cited as having a large impact on the cost of running DB schemes. Later revisions to the law in the Pensions Act 2004 reduced the requirement. From 6 April 2005 any pension built up in a salary-related scheme now has to increase in payment by 2.5% per annum, or in line with the RPI if this is less.[…] To increase the security of members’ benefits. The Pension Protection Fund (PPF), established in 2005, is intended to provide compensation should an employer with an underfunded pension scheme became insolvent. This is done by pooling the assets and liabilities of all DB schemes; so that, broadly speaking, wellfunded schemes can subsidise weaker schemes through a levy that is charged to all of them.[…] To improve the running of schemes. The Pensions Act 2004 introduced tighter regulations for DB scheme funding, which came into effect from September 2005. 10 Trustees of schemes providing defined benefits must now adopt a new statutory funding objective. This requires the scheme to have sufficient assets to cover an actuarial estimate of the amount needed to pay the benefits when due. Trustees must prepare a statement of funding principles specifying how this objective will be met along with a schedule of contributions specifying rates of contributions due to be paid by the employer and by active members. If the statutory funding objective is not met, the trustees must prepare a recovery plan to correct the shortfall within a specified period. This process is to be monitored by The Pensions Regulator (TPR), which has powers to seek additional funding for a pension scheme.32 3.2 The Labour Government’s Deregulatory Review In October 2007, the Labour Government set up a Deregulatory Review of Private Pensions. The background to this was that: 3. The present regulatory system governing occupational pensions has grown incrementally over the course of the past thirty years. It is now, by common consent, lengthy, complicated and hard to understand. Although each successive layer usually had the aim of protecting scheme members or simplifying the regulatory structure, there have been unintended consequences, leading to undesirable outcomes. Whilst by no means wholly attributable to the growth of regulatory burdens, there is little doubt that the weight of regulation has contributed to a belief by some employers that the costs and risks of having their own pension schemes are becoming too great. Its objective was to reduce legislative burdens while recognising that there was a balance to be struck between reducing legislative complexity and protecting members’ interests.33 In their report, published in December 2007, the review team said that if the two problems of DB schemes (regulatory burden and open-ended risk) could be alleviated sufficiently, this would make it easier for companies to consider DB schemes, or at least an element of DB provision, once again. They had placed the emphasis in their recommendations on: encouraging the introduction of risk-sharing DB schemes, where the employer is unwilling to bear all the risks on an open-ended basis; removing or easing regulatory obstacles in DB schemes which are hindering sensible courses of action by companies (such as some of the employer debt regulations, and regulations restricting to an unreasonable extent the ability of the employer to reclaim any surplus which arises); moving towards simple outcome-related principles in some areas of regulation, leaving companies and trustees free to achieve these outcomes in their own ways, with resulting economies and efficiency, and hopefully a greater understanding by pensions professionals of what outcomes are required. None of their recommendations would affect accrued rights. They suggested that, in addition to looking at ways to deregulate DB schemes, the Government should also “examine ways in which some of the risks for the members of DC schemes could be lessened where the company is willing to do so.” 34 32 PPI, The changing landscape for private sector Defined Benefit pension schemes, October 2007 DWP, Deregulatory review – Government response, October 2007, p35 34 Deregulatory Review of Private Pensions, An independent report to the Department for Work and Pensions, July 2007; Foreword 33 11 In its response, the Labour Government said it was “difficult to strike the right balance between removing legislative burdens and protecting members.” It did not believe that there was “a single measure or even a series of measures which would guarantee that employers would continue to provide and even strengthen their existing pension provision.”35 It agreed with the reviewers that “it would not be appropriate to make changes which would affect rights which have already accrued.”36 Following further consultation, it legislated in the Pensions Act 2008 to: reduce the cap applying to the revaluation of deferred pension rights from 5% to 2.5% (intended to apply to future rights, accrued from January 2009); and repeal the rules on “safeguarded rights”, which currently apply when a pension is shared on divorce or dissolution of a civil partnership.37 As part of a consultation on risk-sharing launched in June 2008, the Government considered whether to allow conditional indexation (where indexation depends on the financial health of the scheme).38 However, it decided against this on the grounds that the consultation had not provide sufficient evidence that it was likely to make the significant impact on the level of DB provision to justify overriding the concerns of member representatives. 39 For more detail, see Library Note SN 4515 Deregulatory Review of Private Pensions (September 2009). 3.3 The current Government’s proposals The current Government’s motivation for a “lighter version of DB” was to stem the long-term decline in DB pension provision: Without government intervention to allow more flexibility and reduce constraints for employers sponsoring DB pensions, DB is likely to disappear almost completely from future pension arrangements.40 However, the Government did not think that employers should have the power to transfer or modify accruals built up under the previous arrangements into new arrangements, beyond what was allowed under existing legislation. This meant that: […] deferred and pensioner members, and the past accrued benefits of active members, would not be affected as a consequence of introducing DA pensions. 41 Specific measures under consideration included removing, for future accruals only, the statutory requirements for the indexation of pensions in payment.42 This flexibility would add to those already scheduled to occur with the abolition of contracting-out in April 2016: 9. The introduction of the single-tier State Pension means that contracting will end. Formerly contracted out DB pension schemes will no longer have to provide specific benefits for future accruals and this will mean that requirements to automatically 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 DWP, Deregulatory review – Government response, October 2007, Executive Summary Ibid Sections 101 to 102 Ibid, p3-4 DWP, ‘Risk sharing consultation: Government response’, December 2008, page 2 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 p16 Ibid p25 Ibid p18 12 provide rights for survivors on future accruals will fall away. This provides an opportunity to simplify the administration of DB pensions. 43 Flexibilities already available for DB scheme sponsors included switching to schemes providing benefits on the basis of career average revalued earnings rather than final salary or moving to a cash balance scheme.44 In addition employers could place a cap on the level of earnings that would count as ‘pensionable pay’. However, these features were not in widespread use.45 As part of the development of its proposals for DA, the Government considered three specific proposals for flexible DB: the ability to pay fluctuating benefits, automatic conversion to DC when an employee left the scheme early, and the ability to change scheme pension age. The ability to pay fluctuating benefits. For example, employers could choose to provide additional benefits - such as indexation above the simplified DB level when the scheme funding position allowed. Legislation to enable this could include: - Changing the legislation on requirements such as preservation, revaluation, scheme funding, employer debt and the Pension protection Fund levy so that they applied only in respect of statutory provisions and benefits that were required to be paid under scheme rules, not in respect of the discretionary elements; - Reviewing governance requirements to ensure employers, trustees and scheme managers were properly equipped to deal with such discretion; - A ‘statutory override’ to enable schemes to change rules in relation to future accruals more easily.46 Automatic conversion to DC for early leavers In this scheme design, active scheme members would build rights to pension benefits during a period of employment as now. However, if they left the employment before retirement, the amount of pension accrued in the scheme would be crystallised and the cash value transferred to a nominated DC fund. The Government considered that a number of safeguards would need to be put in place: employees would need to have a clear explanation of how accrued benefits were valued at crystallisation; there would need to be regulatory protection for members; and measures address risks of avoidance activity, such as prescribing the time by which employers would be required to calculated and transfer benefits when a member leaves employment.47 Ability to change scheme pension age The Government proposed to give employers greater flexibility to manage risks by adjusting their normal pension age: 43Ibid p17 In a cash balance scheme, the employer specifies the pension fund amount for the member for each year they work, so the size of the member’s overall pension fund is defined, with the actual value dependent upon the revaluation factor specified in the scheme rules. When the member retires the total pension fund is then available for the purchase of an annuity. (Cm 8478, p31) 45 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 46 Ibid p19 47 Ibid p20-21 44 13 35. This would enable future pension provision to be based on the projected number of years in retirement, rather than being tied to a fixed age that does not take into account changes to longevity. From the date the model is implemented, the age at which members are entitled to the full scheme pension could be adjusted in line with changes to longevity assumptions, so that members would be expected to spend broadly the same length of time in retirement, regardless of changes to life expectancy. 48 To enable this, the Government proposed to make it easier for schemes to link their normal pension age with the State Pension age if they chose, but also to require the Government Actuary’s Department to publish, at predetermined intervals (say every three years) an objective index on pension ages based on the latest longevity assumptions.49 Pensioner members would not be affected, and there would need to be protection for those closest to retirement – for example, a prohibition on changes affecting people already within ten years of the scheme’s existing normal pension.50 Numerous respondents to the consultation thought it was already possible to adopt this scheme design under current legislation.51 Responses EEF said employers who had gone through the difficult process of closing a DB scheme were unlikely to consider another form of DB in future: The future of workplace pensions therefore is one where DC schemes will be the predominant workplace pension platform. The reasons why employers have chosen DC schemes are the costs and liabilities incurred in offering DB schemes. Many EEF members have closed their DB schemes in recent years, and others are on a flight-path towards closure. Their views provide a useful barometer of the consultation proposals. For employers who have firstly incurred a sharp increase in their liabilities for a DB scheme, and then gone through the very difficult process of closing such a scheme, they are very unlikely to consider in the future another form of DB scheme. In addition, they will be unlikely to consider a different form of DC scheme which exposes them to a future liability, particularly if that liability cannot be quantified and limited. In discussions with our members then, we have not found any desire for a model of risk-sharing, where the employer shoulders any liability for a defined level of future retirement income.52 However, the National Association of Pension Funds (NAPF) argued that deregulation might encourage some existing providers to keep DB schemes open for longer: […] it is unlikely that we will see a dramatic revival of DB pensions as employers increasingly shift investment, inflation and longevity risks off their balance sheets. However, ambitious deregulation of DB pensions might encourage those currently considering closing their DB schemes to new members or to future accrual to keep their schemes open for longer or switch to more innovative risk-sharing models.53 48 Ibid p22 Ibid p23 50 Ibid p 24 51 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, 24 June 2014, page 34 52 EEF response on reshaping workplace pensions for future generations - summary 53 NAPF, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations – the NAPF’s response, December 2013 49 14 Trade unions were sceptical that this would be the result and were concerned about the impact on scheme members. The TUC said: Employers willing to accept pensions risk already have many ways to negotiate changes to reduce costs, and we are particularly opposed to abolishing indexation as that just means pensioners getting poorer every year. 54 The Government’s response In June 2014, the Government said it would not proceed with the proposals for flexible DB: It was clear that there are already flexibilities available to employers, such as linking the scheme’s normal pension age with State Pension age, to reduce cost and volatility without the need for new legislation. We have therefore considered the consultation responses and have concluded that introducing new legislation, to make it easier to sponsor DB schemes, will not be our priority at the present time. Separate research findings have shown that, to make enough of a difference to employers, the suggested changes would need to apply to accrued pension rights. We are absolutely clear that we will not be making changes that affect past accruals that could reduce the pension benefits that individuals have already built up with their employer. The view most respondents expressed was that the greater prize was to deliver changes that enable collective schemes and greater ability to share risks in the DC world.55 4 Proposals for providing greater certainty within DC DWP research on consumer perspectives on defined ambition found that the concept of providing greater certainty held an overall appeal. However, when specific models were discussed, questions were raised around issues such as cost.56 Research by NEST also found a strong bias among savers for certainty. It said: Everyone understands that the goal of a pension is to grow their contributions but people are less clear where this growth will come from. Many people expect their pensions to grow in a uniform upward fashion. People in a pension scheme struggle to picture what happens to their money or where it actually goes. For unpensioned workers retirement planning is about safety and securing the future, and therefore at odds with ideas of chance, risk and uncertainty. For the automatically enrolled member risk is inherently negative and is more to do with the chance of making a loss than making a gain. TUC welcomes paper on defined ambition, 7 November 2013; UNITE, ‘Response to Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations’, December 2013; See also NASUWT, Consultation response, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, 19 December 2013 55 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, page 28 56 Defined Ambition: Consumer perspectives. Qualitative research among employers, individuals and employee benefit consultants, DWP RR 866, June 2014, Executive summary 54 15 Similarly, uncertainty is always perceived in a negative light and suggests the possibility of a disappointing or worst-case scenario outcome, rather than the possibility of getting a better outcome than expected or even just slightly less. 57 As part of the Government’s work on this issue, an industry working group considered a number of models, in particular: a money back guarantee; capital and investment return guarantee, retirement income insurance and pension income builder.58 As the Pensions Policy Institute has pointed out, a common feature of these models (and of collective DC) is that none place any risk on the employer. In each case, the employer would determine their level of contributions into the scheme but take no further risk.59 4.1 Money-back guarantee Model 1 - Money-back guarantee is intended to ensure that the amount of accumulated savings at retirement did not fall below the nominal value of contributions made to the scheme. In practice, the probability of such a low level guarantee being exercised were small. However, the Government said it was unlikely that the market would offer this sort of guarantee and that government intervention did not seem justified: 66. From the supply side, it is clear that at present UK insurers have little appetite for providing guarantees. The ABI in their recent publication, Identifying the Challenges of a Changing World, questioned whether customers would be prepared to meet the premium required to provide guarantees. They also raised concerns about increasing pressures from conduct and prudential regulators to avoid policyholder detriment. 67. On the money-back guarantee model, we have considered whether the Government should intervene directly and concluded that, in light of the significant hurdles that would need to be negotiated, we cannot justify direct Government intervention in providing money-back guarantees. We will however, continue working with providers, who have modelled the possibilities and found some market-based models affordable.60 Its consumer research found that although the principle of a ‘money back guarantee’ was initially greeted with enthusiasm by risk-averse individuals, on reflection they thought that “such a guarantee suggested that the pension scheme was a poor investment.” Concerns were also expressed about “the likely cost and who would pay.” 61 In its response to the consultation, the Government said this model could operate within the new DA space. However, it did not intend specific legislation to enable it: In the consultation paper we explored options for delivery by both the market or by the public sector and we rejected the latter. Consultation responses also confirm that the case has not been made to legislate for the regulatory enablers that have been suggested make market provision easier – such as including a safe harbour for trustees, employers and providers against mis-selling or compulsion, or money back as a default fund. Our conclusion therefore is not to change legislation or bring in new legislation specifically to address these issues or offer public sector provision for this NEST, Pensions insight – 2014 Cm 8710, chapter 4 59 PPI, Defined Ambition in workplace pension schemes, December 2013 60 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p42 61 Defined Ambition: Consumer perspectives. Qualitative research among employers, individuals and employee benefit consultants, DWP RR 866, June 2014 section 5.1 57 58 16 model. But a money-back model could operate within the new DA space if there was sufficient demand and supply appetite.62 4.2 Capital and investment return guarantee The second model - capital and investment return guarantee – is intended to offer guarantees at the mid-point of the pension cycle: when a member had built up a sum and was concerned to protect the loss of capital, while still maintaining a need to grow the fund further. The guarantee would be purchased by a fiduciary on behalf of the member to secure a guarantee against part of the capital and possibly the investment return, for a fixed period.63 Consumer research found this principle was seen as attractive only by individuals who were highly risk averse. As with the money back guarantee, questions were raised by individuals, employers and consultants regarding: How would the guarantee work in practice – a one-off or an on-going premium? How would the guarantee work if an employee moved jobs and pension schemes? What impact would the cost of the guarantee have on investment returns? 64 The Pensions Policy Institute points out that guarantees come with a cost: Guarantees may mitigate the investment risk borne by members of a DC scheme. However, the guarantees must be paid for either by the employer or the members. Some empirical analyses have found that the cost of providing capital guarantees can be relatively cheap as they could cost less than 10 basis points of the assets accumulated. However, this is only if some assumptions relating to minimum years of contributions and a pre-set investment strategy are maintained throughout the accrual period. Relaxing any of these assumptions could increase the estimated cost of guarantees significantly. The guarantees also only relate to the size of the pension fund and not the retirement income that the fund will generate. 65 Unite argued that promoting guarantees could have negative effects. It argued that a better way of building member confidence would be to increase employer contribution rates and take action on charges: The best means of building member confidence is to ensure that members achieve a strong return relative to the contributions that they pay themselves through a high level of employer contribution and a favourable ratio between employee and employer contributions. The level of employer contributions required under auto-enrolment needs to be revisited at an early date. A further important contribution needs to come from a drive to reduce charges and encourage the development of larger scale schemes which would have the potential to progress some risk-sharing as between members. 62 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, p13 63 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p32 64 Defined Ambition: Consumer perspectives. Qualitative research among employers, individuals and employee benefit consultants, DWP RR 866, June 2014 section 5.2 65 PPI, Defined Ambition in workplace pension schemes, Briefing Note Number 65, 22 December 2013 17 The demand for guarantees may be perceived as being greater for those on lower incomes and with smaller pension contributions who may naturally be more risk averse. Promotion of guarantees could amount to encouraging a new form of ‘reckless conservatism’ which will only serve to widen the disparity in pension outcomes between those in this group and those who have higher incomes and pension contributions. The cost of guarantees could be seen as going against the general thrust of policy to reduce the charges which members face. 66 In its response to the consultation, the Government said detailed design features should be worked out within the new legislative framework: In the consultation document we identified some design issues which included: the ability of the scheme to hedge the guarantee; the potential for this product to operate on a cohort basis; cost of the guarantee; and whether it would fit with the tax regime. The intent is that the more detailed design features should be worked out within the legal parameters of the new legislative framework.67 4.3 Retirement income insurance The third model - retirement income insurance – would involve a fiduciary using a portion of the member’s fund to buy, on the member’s behalf, an income insurance product that insures a minimum level of income, which would grow each year as further insurance was purchased. At retirement, the saver draws their pension from the fund and only if their fund is only reduced to zero does the income guarantee kick in. Products of this type already existed in the United States. However, the Government thought it was unlikely that this model would be introduced in the UK in the short to medium term. Reasons for this included: It requires insurers to be willing to offer standardised and transparently-priced products. All else being equal, the greater price pressure exerted by this approach makes it less attractive to insurers. In the US, the scale of the plans on which this insurance is sold compensates insurers for the relatively low prices. Scale is a significant barrier. As it works in the US, a panel of insurers competes to supply standardised income insurance. In such an arrangement, insurers typically want to deal with plans with large enough asset bases to make the business profitable for them. The fragmented nature of the UK market means that this scale is not achieved. It may work on a smaller scale but only if business was limited to one insurer – in which case the benefits of competitive pressure on pricing disappear, with the outcome being worse for members. Prudential regulation of insurance companies is more exacting in the UK than the US and, combined with the costs of hedging such insurance, these products end up costing significantly more in the UK than the US, for the same level of guarantee. There is an administrative burden to this proposal since it involves significant data requirements: at a minimum, insurers need data over time on members’ ages, fund choices, contributions and incomes drawn from the fund.68 66 Unite, Response to reshaping workplace pensions, December 2013, p11-12 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, p13 68 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p32 67 18 4.4 Pension income builder The fourth model considered was the pension income builder. This is similar to the Dutch General Practitioners’ pension fund and the mandatory ATP scheme in Denmark). In this model, contributions are used for different purposes. A proportion is used to purchase a deferred nominal annuity each year, payable from pension age. The residual proportion is invested in a collective pool of risk-seeking assets: 35. In this model contributions are used for two different purposes. A proportion is used to purchase a deferred nominal annuity, payable from the current pension age. For every year of contributions each individual has a pension made up of a series of these deferred annuities. Thus the individual can see their pension income increasing over time (albeit at different rates depending upon the cost of each year’s deferred annuity, which varies in line with market interest rates and market expectations of future longevity). 36. The residual proportion of contributions is invested into a collective pool of riskseeking assets along with the residual proportions of other scheme members. This could be done on a single collective basis or among smaller cohorts (although these do need to be large enough to allow for enough variation in investment experiences among members such that there is potential for smoothing). This pool is used to provide future indexation on a conditional basis, with rights adjusted by way of bonus allowances based on the financial status of the scheme. 37. As a result the individual has a degree of pre-retirement certainty over their retirement income and can always see some benefit for each additional year of contributions, as the guaranteed element increases (although clearly the cost of an additional year’s annuity may vary, potentially affecting the individual’s perception of value for money). In general this year-on-year increase should be confidence-inspiring for members.69 DWP noted that this model entailed genuine risk-sharing. However, it needed to operate at large scale for some of the key benefits to be realised and the issue was how to achieve this in the UK. Possibilities included a multi-employer scheme or single employer with a large and relatively stable workforce.70 Other issues for consideration included: who would stand as guarantee provider; how to balance the interests of different cohorts of members and the requirement for a strong governance framework and regulatory oversight. It was also legitimate to debate whether members would be better served using their contributions to seek higher returns. However, it could address the desire of consumer for greater certainty.71 Unite thought that, of the four models outlined for providing an element of guarantee through a conventional DC vehicle, the pension income builder had the most potential to produce beneficial outcomes for members. However, it thought collective DC was the most promising proposal overall.72 5 Proposals for collective benefits The Government has considered Collective Defined Contribution (CDC) schemes as a possible structure for Defined Ambition. Its model for this is drawn from the experience of 69 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 p7 and chapter 4; See also, Lars Rohde, Using a Hybrid Pension Product in a Collective Framework to Distribute Risk: Denmark’s ATP in Governance and Investment of Public Pension Assets, The World Bank, 2011 70 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 p39-40 71 Ibid chapter 4 72 Unite response, Reshaping workplace pensions, December 2013, p12 19 occupational pension provision in the Netherlands. While its proposed model would have important differences – it is not proposing compulsory participation for employers in industrywide schemes, for example – it has looked at what positive lessons can be learned from the Dutch system. Key features of the schemes are that they feature risk-sharing between members and cost certainty for employers through a fixed contribution rate.73 5.1 Occupational pension provision in the Netherlands The Dutch pension system has three pillars. The first pillar is the state old age pension (AOW), the second is constituted by occupational pensions, and the third by individual savings for retirement.74 In arrangements dating back to 1949, participation in the second pillar is mandatory for employers where the government has agreed that it should be so, in response to a request from a sufficiently representative portion of an organised industry or sector. 75 For employees, participation is mandatory through their contract of employment. These arrangements have resulted in extensive coverage, with more than 90% of employees covered by supplementary funded pension schemes. They have also helped to ensure industry-wide funds with sufficient economies of scale, enabling cost efficient management of schemes: more than 80% of active scheme members are in sectoral funds.76 The bulk of assets are managed by non-commercial pension funds, which are legal entities separate from the employer. They are usually trust-based, governed by employer and employee representatives.77 The dominant model originated from a pure DB system. However, whereas in traditional DB the sponsoring employer generally stands behind the pension promise, in the Dutch model it depends on returns in the financial markets, interest rates and inflation rates.78 An overview of the system by the Dutch associations of pension funds explains: The majority of the Dutch DB (Defined Benefit) pension schemes are in fact not pure DB schemes, but are hybrid schemes. This means that if a fund gets into financial difficulties, all parties involved, employer, employees and those drawing their pension, contribute to the recovery. > The pension contributions can be increased. This will increase the wage costs for the employer and decrease the net salary for the employee. Another option is that the employer commits paying the extra contributions required to incidentally pay an extra contribution. > The indexation can be limited. Most pension schemes include a clause stating that indexation is conditional. Each year the pension fund’s executive board will decide whether the fund’s financial position will permit indexation of the pensions and accrued rights. In indexed average salary schemes such indexations constraints affect pensioners, members still contributing and early leavers. 73 DWP, Reinvigorating workplace pensions, Cm 8478, November 2012, p39 For more detail, see OECD, Pensions at a glance 2013: country profiles – the Netherlands; Dutch Association of Industry-wide Pension Funds and Dutch Association of Company Pension Funds, The Dutch Pension System: an overview of the key aspects, 2010 75 O.W. Steenbeck and SG Van der Lecq, Costs and Benefits of Collective Pension Systems, 2007, chapter 10 76 Lans Bovenberg, Roel Mehlkopf and Theo Nijman, The Promise of Defined-Ambition Plans Lessons for the United States, Network for Studies on Pensions, Aging and Retirement, March 2014 77 OW Steenbeek and S.G. van der Lecq eds, Costs and Benefits of Collective Pension Systems, 2007 78 Broeders D and Ponds E, Dutch pension system reform – A step closer to the ideal system? CESifo DICE Report 3/2012, 65-78 74 20 > An extreme measure is to reduce the pension rights. In many pension schemes the contribution amount as well as the level of indexation depends on the coverage ratio. This is known as intergenerational risk sharing for pension funds. Furthermore, when determining the investment mix a balance must be found between the needs of those drawing a pension for security and on the other hand, the needs of the younger contributor for the opportunity to achieve a good return on investment.79 The effect of these arrangements is that investment and longevity risks are borne collectively rather than by the individual. If a scheme becomes underfunded, its governing body decides how to restore it to a full funding position over a period of three years (extended to five recently). The minimum funding level is 105% (i.e. assets exceed liabilities by 5%). In addition, the fund must have buffers to be able to cope with financial setbacks. The average pension fund needs to be 125% funded, with the exact level dependant on factors such as the scheme’s investment strategy and the age profile of its members.80 In general, scheme participants are treated uniformly. This means that scheme members accrue benefits at the same rate (around two per cent of salary a year), all active members contribute at the same rate and the indexation rate is the same for all participants, although some funds differentiate between active members and retirees.81 Contribution rates are high, as are the benefits provided. In 2012, the average contribution rate was about 17.5% (6.2% from employees and 11.3% from employers). In 2013, schemes typically aimed at an annuity level of about 80% of average pay (including the AOW) after 40 years’ service. 82 Reforms have been introduced over time in response to funding pressures. In 2003, there was a shift to providing pensions based on career average rather than final salary, and the introduction of a conditional indexation mechanism, whereby accrued rights would only be increased in line with inflation if the scheme was fully funded.83 Further reforms have been under consideration following the financial crisis in 2007-08, when the funding level fell in many schemes. A fall in the total funding from 130% to 95% in 2008, meant many funds had to put in place recovery plans and take action to restore funding levels.84 A recent academic study explained the effects: The biggest wave of cuts in pensions in payments occurred in 2013. During that year, 68 pension funds (out of 415) were required to cut nominal pension rights. The cuts in 2013 affected around 2.0 million active participants (who pay contributions), 1.1 million retired participants and 2.5 million inactive participants who neither pay contributions nor receive benefits.[…] Around 2 million participants faced a relatively large cut of 6 to 7 per cent. A cut of 7 per cent is observed frequently because the Dutch government allowed pension funds to cap the level of pension cuts in 2013 at 7% and defer the remainder to 2014. 79 Dutch Association of Industry-wide Pension Funds and Dutch Association of Company Pension Funds, The Dutch Pension System: an overview of the key aspects, 2010 80 Ibid 81 Broeders D and Ponds E, Dutch pension system reform – A step closer to the ideal system? CESifo DICE Report 3/2012, 65-78 82 Lans Bovenberg and Raymond Gradus, Reforming Dutch occupational pension schemes, 2014 83 Theo Nijman, Pension Reform in the Netherlands: Attractive options for other countries? Bankers, Markets and Investors No 128, January-February 2014 84 IMF Country Report No. 11/209, July 2011 - Netherlands: Publication of Financial Sector Assessment Program Documentation - Technical Note on Pensions Sector Issues 21 Moreover, most pension funds have been unable to provide (full) indexation in recent years. […] on average retirees have experienced a decline of around 10% of their replacement rates as a consequence of inadequate indexation. This decline is expected to increase further because the current low funding rates will not allow pension funds to provide full indexation in the near future.85 Funding levels have since recovered somewhat and were expected to reach an average of 112% in May 2014.86 Thirty funds had to curtail pensions in April 2014, affecting 200,000 retirees, 300,000 members and 600,000 early leavers (people with non-contributory entitlements that remain with previous employers). These difficulties led to proposals for reform. In 2010, the social partners - employers and trade unions - agreed in a Pension Accord that pension contracts needed to be modified.87 In particular, it was agreed that: - unexpected increases in life expectancy should be met by changes in pension rights rather than in recovery contributions paid by employers and workers; - the new pension contracts should be transparent and complete and pension funds should communicate to participants the risks implied by the pension contract (including investment policies); and - eligibility for the public pension (AOW) and the accrual rate in occupational pensions would be linked to life expectancy.88 It appears that the proposals to move towards a new ‘defined ambition’ contract are still under consideration, with complex issues, such as whether the new contracts should apply to accrued rights and the extent to which pension funds should offer nominal guarantees, as yet undecided.89 5.2 Proposals for the UK In its November 2013 consultation document, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, the Government said that some employers currently sponsoring DB schemes were interested in CDC as an alternative.90 It set out the core characteristics of the models under discussion for the UK. These included: - A fixed rate of employer contribution, with the employer having no further liability to the scheme (unless it chose to support it further) and no balance sheet risk; - Rather than being retained in an individual fund for each member, or each member having rights to their own specific contributions and investment returns attributable to those contributions, in a CDC scheme assets are pooled. When they retire, members do not select an individual retirement income product, rather the income is paid from the asset pool. The rights of a CDC scheme member are therefore not related to the contributions made by or on behalf of that member; Lans Bovenberg, Roel Mehikopf and Theo Nijman, The Promise of Defined Ambition Plans – Lesson for the United States, Netspar Occasional Papers, March 2014 86 ‘Dutch pension funds at three-year high as ratios improve’, Financial Adviser, 26 June 2014 87 Stichting van de Arbeid, Memorandum Detailing the Pension Accord of 4 June 2010 88 Lans Bovenberg, Roel Mehikopf and Theo Nijman, The Promise of Defined-Ambition Plans – Lessons for the United States, Netspar Occasional Papers, March 2014, Section 6 89 Ibid 90 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 85 22 - Large scale provides for efficiencies in the costs of administration and investment management. It also enables the collective element to function more efficiently – “very simply, for a scheme that shares risks among members, the more members there are, the greater the opportunities for risk sharing”; - In one of the main models of the scheme, individuals are provided with a target pension income they might receive in retirement (often including a fluctuating conditional indexation payment). The actual pension income received is dependent on the available assets in the scheme. If funding is insufficient, there are a number of pressure valves to enable the scheme to continue to deliver benefits, such as not paying the conditional indexation element or reducing the target pension income for members, with a decision to be made on how risks are shared between different classes of members; - One form of CDC includes the possibility of benefits in payment being reduced in order to manage the fund. An alternative would be to fix a core part of the pension which cannot be changed once it is in payment, so it would be only the conditional indexation payments that could be cut.91 In its response to the consultation published in June 2014, the Government said that such schemes were currently not catered for in pensions or tax legislation. It would therefore define collective schemes in primary legislation and create a framework for them: Evidence suggests that collective schemes provide a greater degree of stability in pension incomes than individual DC, because demographic and financial risks are pooled across the membership. In recognition of this, the responses received during the consultation period were largely positive. Collectives are not currently possible in the UK in practice because they are not catered for in either pensions or tax legislation. The Department for Work and Pensions has had discussions with Her Majesty’s Treasury (HMT) and Her Majesty’s Revenue and Customs (HMRC) to examine this issue. In order to enable collective schemes that are run safely and regulated appropriately, we propose to define benefits provided on a collective basis in primary legislation for the first time. We will create a framework that draws on the experiences of other countries where collective schemes operate and places the interests of members firmly at the heart of that design, prioritising clarity and transparency. Collective schemes are complex and can be opaque – because of the indirect relationship between contributions and benefits. This necessitates strong standards of communication and governance. We intend collective schemes to be overseen by experienced fiduciaries acting on behalf of members, taking decisions at scheme level and removing the need for individuals to make difficult choices over fund allocations and retirement income products. We will also introduce a robust regulatory regime in respect of targeting benefits and internal accounting, providing regulators with the appropriate mandate and tools to supervise schemes properly. We believe it is crucial that members fully understand the risks associated with collective arrangements when they join the scheme, and while it is not for the state to determine the benefit design of these schemes, we will ensure that schemes set out clearly (to members) in advance how their rights are defined, 91 Ibid, p45-6 23 what they can expect from the pool, and how positive and negative shocks will impact on their pension benefits. Collective schemes, as with all DC arrangements, do not come without risk, but with proper standards of governance and a suitable regulatory regime, we believe that we can mitigate these appropriately. A definition of collective benefits and associated key requirements will be included in the Pensions Bill while secondary legislation is likely to include more detailed provisions in relation to areas such as benefit targeting, risk management, communications and governance. The legislative measures we will introduce will not address tax rules; however we will continue to work with HMRC and HMT to consider how collective schemes would operate within the pensions tax regime.92 5.3 Debate Differing views on the possible advantages and disadvantages to providing pension benefits on a collective basis are discussed below. Outcomes An assessment of how CDC schemes might work in the UK conducted by the Labour Government in 2009 found that CDC schemes could produce higher pensions and greater stability in outcomes for individuals: - In the median case, CDC schemes produced higher pensions than standard DC schemes. This was mostly due to the fact that CDC schemes could remain invested in equities throughout the entire accumulation period, whereas typical DC schemes tended to move into safer, but lower-returning assets as the member approached retirement.93 - There was greater stability in outcomes for individuals i.e. an individual’s starting pension was less dependent on whether they happened to retire in a downturn or a boom. However, there was uncertainty about indexation throughout retirement, as it was only granted when investment returns permitted. 94 A report published by the RSA in November 2013 included modelling to show that: On the best like-for-like comparison, a collective pension would on average have outperformed an individual pension by 33% That in 37 of the past 57 years, a collective pension would have outperformed the individual pension That the variability of the pension, and thus the risk the saver would have taken, would be lower with a collective rather than an individual pension. 95 Modelling for the current Government showed CDC to out-perform individual DC. This was primarily driven by lower costs and remaining for longer in risk-seeking assets, factors not necessarily inherent to CDC: 92 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014 93 Ibid para 3.2 94 DWP, Collective Defined Contribution Schemes – An assessment of whether and how such schemes might operate in the UK, December 2009 95 David Pitt-Watson, Collective Pensions In the UK II, RSA, November 2013 24 14. There is a lively debate within the industry around the theoretical benefits of CDC plans compared to individual DC plans; in particular, the extent to which CDC outperforms DC. This was explored by the DWP and GAD in 2009. The modelling indicated that there was a good likelihood of better outcomes compared to individual DC, although this arose from CDC following a more aggressive investment strategy over time, which is not inherent in the design, and the same strategy could be replicated in DC. It also indicated that a stable active membership was required to keep the scheme sustainable. The modelling also indicated this effect was radically diminished where there was no continuing stream of ne member contributions. 15. As part of the Department’s current work on CDC, consultants Aon Hewitt have modelled the position of an individual who for 25 years set aside 10 per cent of their salary for a pension. It then looked at how they would have fared had they retired in 1955, and then in every other year up until the present. 16. The median of the average salary replacement has been compared for the 13following; (i) a CDC plan invested 80 per cent in equities and 20 per cent in bonds; (ii) an all equity individual DC plan; and (iii) a lifestyle individual DC plan. In Aon’s results the average replacement rate for the CDC plan is 32 per cent, for DC equity it is 27 per cent, and for lifestyle it is 22 per cent. The dispersion of the individual DC plans is significantly greater than for the CDC. 17. Our understanding is that out-performance is driven primarily by lower costs and remaining invested for longer in risk-seeking assets. Neither of these is inherent to CDC schemes and it is possible to achieve both low costs and to hold risk-seeking assets for as long as desired in individual DC schemes. 96 However, it said the ability to share risks amongst members did seem to create more stable outcomes than are possible in individual DC: and the greater the ability to share risk and so the lower the dispersion in outcomes.97 Viability of CDCs in the UK When the Labour Government looked at this in 2009, it decided to take no further action. Part of the reason for this was that it thought demand for employers would be low: […] employers (including DB scheme sponsors considering closing their schemes) seem to be reluctant to subscribe to a new type of pension scheme which their employees may not fully understand and remain sceptical of their potential liability if investment performance is poor.98 However, in November 2013, the current Government said some employers were interested in CDC as an alternative to DB: We know that some DB employers are interested in CDC as an alternative to DB schemes, rather than moving to individual DC schemes. CDC schemes may also be feasible as multi-employer schemes, perhaps sector based as in the Netherlands. Longer term, once established they might enable smaller employers to participate, offering them and their employees the benefits of scale.99 It commented that CDC schemes perform better on a larger scale. This is because: 96 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p46 Ibid para 18 98 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p12 99 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p44 97 25 Scale can provide the potential for efficiencies in the costs of administration and investment management. However, these advantages apply equally to other forms of pension scheme, and it is important to note that while CDC needs scale, it does not provide it automatically. The other benefit of scale for CDCs is that it enables the collective element to function more efficiently – very simply, for a scheme that shares risks among members, the more members there are, the greater the opportunities for risk sharing.100 The Pensions Policy Institute has suggested that intervention by industry or Government may be needed for sufficient scale to be achieved.101 There may also be cultural barriers to their introduction here. Morten Nilsson, CEO of Now: Pensions, has pointed out that such schemes in the Netherlands and Denmark operate in a very different context: Whilst innovations such as collective DC schemes have been successful in Denmark and the Netherlands, both of these markets are highly unionised and have had mandatory or quasi mandatory pension saving for many years. The populations are relatively homogenous and the collective DC schemes operate on an occupational basis with people from similar professions sharing risk with one another – a much fairer approach than manual workers sharing risk with white collar workers. The UK is a much more fragmented market and while changing legislation to allow these schemes could have merit, in many ways it feels as though we are running before we can walk. Like it or not, UK companies have limited appetite for pension liabilities and consumers have limited interest in locking themselves up in risk sharing arrangements. As the market grows and matures, this position might alter but I think we have some distance to travel.”102 Intergenerational equity A number of commentators have objected that CDCs are unfair to younger contributors. Huw Evans of the ABI, has said, for example: CDC can hit the young. CDC schemes work by sharing risks between all members, pooling the investment in one fund. This brings down overheads but involves transferring risks from old to young, with younger scheme members bearing the risk of reduced future payouts to ensure the benefits of older members are preserved. 103 The Government acknowledges this as a potential issue but points out that the way in which risk is shared between different groups of members depends on how the scheme is designed: 11. CDC schemes share risk between members. Scheme design governs which members bear risk and how much of it. For example, in a scheme where the design reduces the benefits of active and deferred benefits before it does so for pensioners, the risk in relation to investment returns and funding position is borne to a greater extent by younger members where the target is reduced. The variation on this design – to make a promise on the pension in payment – would increase the element of intergenerational risk transfer further. This intergenerational risk sharing, which arises 100 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, November 2013, Cm 8710, chapter 5 PPI, Defined Ambition in Workplace Pension Schemes. PPI Briefing Note 65, 2013 102 Now:pensions comments on pension proposals outlined in Queen’s speech, 4 June 2013 103 Huw Evans, Ten things you should know about CDC, ABI blog, 28 January 2014 101 26 from collectivisation, requires a considerable increase in the level of trust required from members of those running these schemes in comparison to traditional DC. 104 This is borne out by recent analysis of proposals for reform of CDCs in the Netherlands, which said: Typically, in case of high funding ratios, the elderly benefit from excess indexation. They also stand to gain from a higher discount and contribution rate. These measures will increase pay outs in the short run. By contrast, at low funding ratios, benefit cuts, a less ambitious indexation target and more prudence are favorable to the young. The young stand to gain from benefit cuts at low funding ratios, greater prudence via more buffering and a less ambitious indexation target, which will all reduce benefit pay-outs in the short run.105 Uniform accrual rates and contribution rates, as in the Netherlands, can in themselves entail a transfer from younger to older workers. For example, the contributions of a younger worker participating in a scheme early in life will generate returns over a long period, whereas those of an older worker will generate lesser returns. So, a younger worker who leaves the scheme early to become self-employed might have gained more by saving in an individual DC scheme, In contrast, an older worker who leaves their free-lance work to join the scheme later in their career would benefit from the relatively low premium they were required to pay. Questions about the fairness of this sort of effect are more likely to arise in a fluid labour market. Consideration of possible remedies, such as age-related accrual rates or premiums, would need to take account of equality legislation. 106 Compatibility with the Budget 2014 announcements Others have questioned whether CDC would work in an environment where, following the announcement in Budget 2014, individuals aged 55 and over have flexibility to draw their pension saving as and when they choose, subject to their marginal rate of income tax.107 Responding to the Queen’s Speech, Shadow Pensions Minister, Gregg McClymont asked: Finally, the Minister made great play of his defined ambition agenda, which is buried in his statement. How can one develop the collective pensions to which he subscribes when they depend on intergenerational risk-sharing? As we understand it, intergenerational risk-sharing becomes extremely difficult, if not impossible, if people exit the system at the age of 55.108 Craig Berry of the Sheffield Political Economy Research Institute, for example, said the risk that a large number of savers could choose to take their money in a lump sum would make the CDC business model unworkable on the kind of scale needed to make a difference: The CDC business model depends, fundamentally, on retirees’ pensions being paid directly out of the scheme’s funds, rather than via an externally-held annuity. This means cash can remain invested in high-return assets right until the very moment it is 104 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 D Broeders and E Ponds, Dutch pension system reform – A step closer to the ideal system? CESifo DICE Report, 3/2102, 70DW 106 J B Kune, Solidarities in collective pension schemes, in O.W. Steenbeek and S.G. van der Lecq (Eds), Costs and Benefits of Collective Pension Systems, July 2007; Lans Bovenberg and Raymond Gradus, Reforming Dutch occupational pension schemes, 2014 107 HM Treasury, Budget 2014, March 2014, para 1.164-5 108 HC Deb 20 March 2014 c953 105 27 needed to be used to make monthly pension payments. It also means members must be required to take their pension from the scheme rather than “shopping around”. 109 Towers Watson said people could be allowed to transfer their money out if the value was adjusted first: Portability and individual control were at the heart of the Budget reforms, but are called into question with CDC. You can allow people to transfer out of a CDC fund, but that is likely to mean adjusting the value of their savings first. How this is done must be transparent and could prove controversial. It’s also unclear whether starting to receive a CDC retirement income will be a big one-off decision that you cannot reverse, like buying an annuity. If retirees can cash out their CDC pensions at any point, that could play havoc with the longevity risk-sharing they are meant to provide.110 However, as Towers Watson also pointed out, there are possible implications for risk-sharing between generations. One of the features of collective DC schemes is that if they become underfunded, they take action to address this – for example, by increasing contribution rates, reducing or suspending indexation or reducing pensions in payment. If members fear their pensions may be reduced, they might be tempted to transfer their savings out of the scheme. This would presumably be one of the factors a scheme would account of when deciding how to restore scheme funding levels. 6 Pension Schemes Bill 2014/15 The Queen’s Speech on 3 June 2014 announced a Private Pensions Bill to: Provide wider choice, with Defined Ambition pensions encouraging greater risk sharing between parties and allowing savers to have greater certainty about their retirement savings. The main benefits of the Bill would be to: Introduce new definitions in into the current legislative framework. Encourage new forms of pension schemes that provide more certainty for individual members about their pension than current Defined Contribution schemes, which currently dominate the market, while limiting costs for employers to realistic levels. Enable ‘collective schemes’ that pool risk between members and potentially allow for more stability around pensions outcomes in retirement. The main elements of the Bill are: General changes to Pensions Legislation The Bill would make provisions for a new legislative framework in relation to the different categories of pension schemes. It would establish three mutually exclusive definitions for scheme type based on degree of certainty in the benefits that schemes offer to members. The Bill would define schemes in terms of the type of ‘pensions promise’ they offer to the individual as they are paying in. A scheme would be categorised as a Defined Benefit scheme, a Defined Ambition (shared risk pension) scheme or a Defined 109 110 Craig Berry, The Queen’s speech leaves pensions in a royal muddle, The Conversation, 4 June 2014 Towers Watson, Collective pensions are no magic wand, 4 June 2014 28 Contribution scheme, corresponding to the different types of promise – full promise about retirement income, a promise on part of the pot or income, or offering no promise at all. Collective Benefits Enabling ‘collective schemes’ that pool risk between members and potentially allow for greater stability around pension outcomes. It would also contain a number of measures relating to the valuation and reporting requirement for collective schemes. Rationale Defined Contribution pensions – where individual scheme members bear the risks of longevity, inflation and investment returns – currently dominate the UK pensions market. Defined Benefit pensions – where the employer bears the risks by promising a pension usually related to salary – are in decline. Defined Contribution pensions can be the right product for many savers, but outcomes will be less certain and more volatile than those with Defined Benefit Pensions. The Bill is needed to encourage new Defined Ambition pensions, in the middle space between Defined Contribution and Defined Benefit pensions that share more of the risk between parties.111 The Pension Schemes Bill 2014/15 was published on 26 June 2014. It had its Second Reading on Tuesday 2 September 2014.112The Bill, Explanatory Notes and an Impact Assessment can be found on the Parliament website. 1.1 The legislative approach to ‘defined ambition’ In November 2013, the Government said it proposed to create a specific DA space in legislation. It would also define DB schemes in their own right. It hoped that the new definitions would enable greater clarity about the requirements applying to the different types of scheme: 3. Historically, pensions legislation has broadly classified schemes as either money purchase or non-money purchase, with a money purchase scheme being one which only offers money purchase benefits. Although money purchase schemes are commonly referred to as DC, they are not defined as such in legislation. 4. With the introduction of DA there is the opportunity to recast the legislation, distinguishing between DB and DA schemes in the non-money purchase space. We therefore propose to create a specific DA space in the legislation, taking the opportunity to move away from the polarity created by the existing definitions and giving explicit recognition in legislation to the potential for innovation in risk sharing in the middle ground. 5. At the same time, we propose to define DB schemes in their own right. With the creation of new definitions of DA and DB schemes, distinct from each other and from money purchase schemes, we can more easily provide clear and proportionate 111 112 Gov.UK,Queen’s Speech 2014 – what it means for you - Private Pensions Bill, 4 June 2014 HC Deb 2 September 2014 c195-250 29 regulation according to scheme type, giving clarity and reassurance to employers and providers. 6. To enable schemes to evolve and change, we do not propose to create entirely new and separate legislative regimes for the different types of schemes, but instead will use the new definitions to help make clear the distinct requirements that apply to each type of scheme. We see ease of transition as vital to make DA attractive to employers. 7. The aim would be to create a conceptual linkage for the different types of pension scheme that would fall within the DA space and set out the common requirements that recognise their characteristics as distinct from DB and money purchase schemes. 8. It would represent a shift in the legislation, setting out an approach based on the scheme as a whole. This could encourage innovation and act as a greater incentive for schemes to offer a mix of benefits. It would also provide a very clear space for us to set out the characteristics of being a DA scheme, and make it easier for existing schemes to change shape in relation to future accruals.113 A change in the status of schemes would result in schemes becoming subject to different requirements.114 It said that for DA schemes issues such as governance, member communications and funding would need special attention: […] We believe that the areas of governance, member communications and funding will need special attention, because in DA schemes where some benefits may be discretionary or where the outcome for the member is less certain than in DB schemes but more complex than in money purchase schemes, there will be new responsibilities for the trustees or those running the schemes, and a need to explain to members clearly what the benefits and risks of the schemes are, and what any guarantee means.115 In terms of governance, it said: […] there could be a case for introducing requirements to ensure that where there is discretion in a scheme, trustees or scheme managers give proper and regular consideration to the exercise of that discretion. 35. In addition, given the extra responsibilities on those running such schemes, there is a strong case for imposing different requirements to reflect the greater emphasis on discretion and risk sharing – for example in relation to the levels of knowledge and understanding required and internal controls and processes. There may also be a need to make clearer the expectations about how trustees should manage DA schemes as long-term propositions – with appropriate mechanisms for allowing schemes to evolve.116 For communications, it said that the nature of DA schemes might mean there was a clear case for a specific set of information requirements. This was because they offered a degree of guarantee but not absolute certainty, so the “nature of the pension promise may be harder to understand and more complex to communicate without being misleading.”117 113 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p50 Ibid, p55-6, para 43-6 115 Ibid, p54 para 33 116 Ibid p55, para 34 117 Ibid p55, para 37 114 30 As regards funding requirements, the element of guarantee inherent in DA meant there would inevitably be some degree of overlap with DB schemes in relation to scheme funding requirements. However, the requirements would depend on the extent of any promise or guarantee and who stood behind it: 41. Schemes which make a promise in relation to the benefit will need to be funded to be able to meet that promise, but funding requirements should only apply to the extent of the promise or guarantee, and the nature of the funding obligation will depend on who is standing behind the promise. • An employer-sponsored occupational pension scheme which offers a salaryrelated pension with discretionary indexation would need to be funded in accordance with the current scheme funding requirements which apply to occupational pension schemes, equal to the technical provisions – but only to the levels needed to cover the basic pension liability. • A Regulatory Own Fund vehicle offering deferred annuities and discretionary benefits would need to be funded to the level required to meet the discounted capital value of the liabilities (technical provisions) plus an appropriate buffer. 42. Where the employer stands behind the promise in an occupational pension scheme, Pension Protection Fund protection and employer debt obligations would continue to apply as now. These provisions will however need amendment to reflect the different structures of DA schemes and to take account of altered employer obligations. While Pension Protection Fund levies would continue to apply, they would need to be calibrated to reflect the liability accruing as a result of the given promise. 118 The Government also set out its thinking in relation to ongoing initiatives in relation to DC scheme quality, automatic transfers and auto-enrolment: […] the Government is keen to ensure that there are appropriate minimum standards for workplace DC schemes – particularly as they will be heavily used for automatic enrolment. 52. However, requirements that might be applied to money purchase schemes, such as bans or caps on certain types of charge currently being consulted on will not necessarily be appropriate for DA schemes in the same way. This reflects the fact that a partial guarantee offers a degree of protection over pot erosion and that DA schemes may be more complex (and hence involve additional cost). 53. In a similar vein, and given the potential variety of DA schemes, we anticipate we would not necessarily propose to impose the same quality standards on DA schemes as those on which the Government issued its call for evidence in July, especially since some aspects (such as governance) will be covered under specific DA requirements. 54. It is also our current intention that DA schemes would be outside any system of automatic transfer (pot follows member) since this would involve transfers of incommensurable benefits. 55. We will however, need to ensure that DA schemes are able to be qualifying schemes for automatic enrolment purposes, which may require amendments to the automatic enrolment legislation, certification guidance and regulations.119 In June 2014, it said it had made some changes to its proposed approach: 118 119 Ibid p55 Ibid p57. For more detail, see Library Note SN 6956 Improving outcomes for DC pension savers 31 We will continue, as intended, to establish mutually exclusive definitions for scheme type based on degrees of certainty for members. We will also ensure proportionate regulation by applying requirements to certain features – where there is a promise, for example, ensuring it is funded – while still maintaining transparency in the law so that employers are clear on the extent of their obligations. We are committed to avoiding legislation that is overly prescriptive; instead, we want to allow schemes to evolve and innovate. Where we have deviated from the ideas set out in the consultation, we have put additional safeguards in place to ensure the new schemes work to their full potential. We are introducing a new definition of collective benefit, which could be offered under DA or defined contribution (DC) schemes. We will refine the definition of DB scheme to take account of certain discretionary features which already exist in some DB schemes and broaden the definition of DC to cater for self-annuitising and CDC schemes (that do not provide a promise or guarantee during the accrual phase). Money purchase schemes will fall within the DC scheme definition. 120 The Bill creates a new category of “shared risk scheme (sometimes known as ‘defined ambition’). 1.2 Part 1 – definitions Historically, legislation has broadly classified pension schemes as either money purchase, or non-money purchase.121 The definition in the Pensions Schemes Act 1993, as amended by the Pensions Act 2011 provides that: In order for a benefit to qualify as a money purchase benefit, the amount or rate of the benefit must be calculated only by reference to assets which must necessarily suffice to provide the benefit. If any other factor such as a guaranteed investment return or other guarantee of the amount where used at any time to calculate the benefit, it is not a money purchase benefit.122 The Government said amendment was needed following the decision of the Supreme Court in Houldsworth vs Bridge Trustees. The Supreme Court had decided that that certain benefits should be treated as “money purchase benefits” even though it was possible for them to develop funding deficits.123 The Government said that the decision had created uncertainty about the types of benefits that fell within the money purchase definition and that amendment was needed in order to ensure scheme members were protected appropriately.124 Following consultation, the details were provided for in two statutory instruments.125 Part 1 of the Bill define three mutually exclusive definitions of pension. The definitions are based on the type of promise the scheme offers members during the accumulation phase 120 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations: government response to the consultation, Cm 8883, 25 June 2014 121 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, November 2013, Cm 8710 122 Pensions Act 2011 – Explanatory Note, para 157 123 The Supreme Court produced a press summary of the decision 124 Pensions Bill 2011 – factsheet 2 – Government amendments to the definition of “money purchase benefits”, 17 October 2011; HC Deb 13 October 2011 c46-8WS; SI 2014/1954 Explanatory Memorandum 125 The Pensions Act 2011 (Transitional, Consequential and Supplementary Provisions) Regulations 2014 (SI 2014/1954); The Pensions Act 2011 (Transitional, Consequential and Supplementary Provisions) Regulations 2014 (SI 2014/1711) 32 about the retirement benefit (retirement income or a retirement lump sum provided to members).126 Briefly: - A defined benefits scheme is one that provides a pre-determined retirement income to all members, beginning at pension age and continuing for life. There must be a ‘full pensions promise’ to members, which means that the level of benefit is determined wholly by reference to that promise in all circumstances; - A shared risk scheme is one that offers a ‘pension promise’ but not a full pension promise, to all members at some point during the accumulation phase in relation to at least some of the retirement benefit that members might receive; and - A defined contributions scheme is one that gives no promise during the accumulation phase in relation to any of the retirement benefits that may be provided to members. These are discussed in more detail below. The new definitions apply only where the legislation expressly states that they should. They do not apply in any public service pensions legislation (clause 1 (2)). The new definitions do not require employers to offer DA models or to bear more risk. There may be some costs for current schemes, arising from the need to assess how the new definitions apply to them and identify themselves under the current framework.127 Defined benefits In June 2014, the Government said it would “refine the definition of DB scheme to take account of certain discretionary features which already exist in some DB schemes”.128 Clause 2 provides that a defined benefits (DB) scheme is one that provides a predetermined retirement income to all members: This type of scheme provides a pre-determined retirement income to all members, beginning at the scheme’s normal pension age or decumulation point and continuing for life. This income is pre-determined insofar as it is set at a rate that is calculated according to promised factors as stipulated in the scheme rules or other scheme documentation. This is expressed as a ‘full pensions promise’ to members. The normal pension age or earliest occasion for accessing the full benefits is fixed – that is, the only way the age or period of accumulation can change is by change to the scheme rules. Schemes where the normal pension age changes in line with state pension age, without requiring a change to the scheme rules, are thus excluded. Also excluded are schemes which apply a longevity factor to the benefit entitlement. 129 Clause 5 (1) provides that: […] there is a full ‘pensions promise’ provided to members, if, at all times before the benefit comes into payment, there is a promise about the level of benefit that will be 126 Bill 12 EN, para 31 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Impact Assessment. Summary of Impacts, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, p15-6, para 23 and 31 128 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations: government response to the consultation, Cm 8883, 25 June 2014, p40 129 Bill 12 EN, para 32 127 33 received and the level of benefit is determined wholly by reference to that promise in all circumstances. The promise refers to a member’s retirement income, but may also include the ability to withdraw a retirement lump sum at an amount that is set out within the scheme.130 An example of a DB scheme is a salary-related scheme, providing benefits based on a proportion of salary (whether final or career average) and length of service: A salary-related pension scheme where the retirement income to be paid out is determined according to a formula based on salary: for example, 1/80 x average salary x years in pensionable service. The age or point at which this income can start to be paid in full to members can only be changed by a change to the scheme rules.131 Key to the definition is the fact that there is a full pension promise i.e. that the member is given complete certainty about the level of benefit they will receive in retirement. This means that a scheme may be DB “regardless of its status as an occupational or personal pension scheme and regardless of who stands behind the promise made by the scheme.”132 Clause 5 (6) provides that a benefit does not fail the test (of providing benefits determined wholly by reference to the promise in all circumstances) just because the scheme confers discretion to vary the benefit for reasons related to a member’s individual circumstances. One example would be provision for early payment of a full pension on ill-health grounds - a common feature of current DB schemes.133 There is regulation-making power to enable DWP to further examine and consult on those discretions which should not impact on whether a benefit is considered as having a full pensions promise. This is because: Where a discretion is capable of being used only in relation to individual circumstances, subsection 6 (a) provides for it to be disregarded so that this would not affect the categorisation of a defined benefits scheme because there is still a full pensions promise –for example, providing for benefits on grounds of ill health before the normal pension age. However, there are also some wider discretions in some schemes which could potentially affect whether a benefit meets the requirement under subsection (1) (b).134 Shared risk Clause 3 provides that a shared risk scheme is one that offers a ‘pension promise’, but not a full one, in relation to at least some of the retirement benefit that members might receive. 135 Clause 5 (2) provides that for the purpose of shared risk and defined contribution schemes, a pension promise is provided if: […] there is a promise to members during the accumulation phase, in relation to a retirement benefit, about the level of benefit that will be received. The level is the rate of the income or the amount of the lump sum (see clause 7). The promise must be expressed at a time before the benefit comes into payment, but unlike under a defined 130 Ibid para 39 Ibid para 36 132 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations: government response to the consultation, Cm 8883, 25 June 2014, p38 133 Ibid para 43 134 Clause 5 (6) (b); DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911 135 Bill 12 EN, para 32 131 34 benefits scheme, does not need to be expressed at all times before payment, i.e. throughout the accrual phase.136 The Explanatory Notes explain that a shared risk scheme is one where some contributions are used to purchase a deferred annuity or otherwise secure a promise about part of the income that will be received in retirement: A pension scheme into which the employer and employee pay contributions. These contributions are then invested, and so the retirement benefit in part depends on how those investments perform, but some contributions are used to purchase a deferred annuity or otherwise secure a promise about part of the income that will be received in retirement. The retirement benefit is a combination of that promise and the funds accumulated via contributions and investment returns.137 A cash-balance scheme would also fall within this definition. This is because: A cash-balance scheme gives its members ‘some form of guarantee but not complete certainty on the level of income’, because: the sum accrues on a defined basis; the actual amount of income that the member will receive in retirement is unknown because it will depend on market factors at the time the sum is used to purchase an annuity. 138 A money purchase scheme with an element of guarantee would also be defined as a shared risk scheme.139 Defined contributions In June 2014, the Government said it would: […] broaden the definition of DC to cater for self-annuitising and CDC schemes (that do not provide a promise of a guarantee during the accrual phase). Money purchase schemes will fall within the DC scheme definition. 140 Clause 4 provides that a scheme is a defined contributions (DC) scheme if there is no pensions promise in relation to any of the retirement benefits that may be provided to member. For example: A pension scheme into which the employer and employee pay contributions, which are then invested. The retirement benefit depends wholly on the money contributed to the scheme and the investment return, and potentially any pooling of risk between members, and so the employee is given no certainty at all during the accumulation phase.141 Meaning of pension promise Clause 5 explains what is meant by a pension promise. 136 Ibid para 40 Ibid para 36 138 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p51 139 Bill 12 EN para 43 140 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations: government response to the consultation, Cm 8883, 25 June 2014, p40 141 Bill 12 EN para 36 137 35 For example, Clause 5 (3) provides that a pensions promise would include a promise about the factors used to calculate the level of retirement benefit but not a promise to pay benefits by reference to what a pension pot or pool of assets can provide: 41. Any promise about a level of retirement benefit includes a promise about the factors that will be used to calculate the level of a retirement benefit (subsection (3) (a). These factors, may, for example, include the length of pensionable service, or be linked to the member’s salary but do not include longevity factors. A promise that the level of retirement benefit will be calculated by reference to what the pot of contributions or investment returns can provide does not constitute a ‘pensions promise’ for the purposes of defining a defined benefits or shared risk scheme (subsection (3) (b). Neither is it a promise where a scheme specifies the factors that will be used to distribute the assets between members and establish the value of a collective benefit (subsection (3) (c)).142 Clause 5 (4) provides that a promise is provided if the scheme sets out the promise, or requires it to be obtained from a third party. This “enables a pension scheme to be defined on the basis of a pensions promise regardless of whether it comes from the scheme itself, the employer or a third party.”143 Under clause 5 (5) there is a promise if the scheme offers it as an option. This means that: […] the scheme categorisation depends on what the scheme offers to members, not the offer that individual members take up. Should a scheme offer a money purchase pension with the option for members to purchase a guarantee, because there is the potential promise to be given, this scheme would be defined as a shared risk scheme.144 Clause 5 (7) provides that when working out whether there is a particular kind of promise in relation to benefits, account can be taken of benefits that may be provided only after a period of time: […] for example where members start in a scheme with money purchase benefits and no promise but then after a certain number of years or a certain age start accruing benefits to which a promise attaches.145 Treatment of a scheme as two or more separate schemes Clause 6 provides for a scheme to be treated as two or more separate schemes. The Explanatory Notes say: 47. This clause requires regulations to be made for a pension scheme that does not fit within any of the categories set out in the clauses above (it is not a defined benefits, defined contributions or shared risk scheme) to be treated as if it were two or more separate schemes, each then fitting within a category, for the purposes of these definitions and other specified legislation. 48. An example of such a scenario would be where an existing scheme has a defined benefits section which is not open to new members, and a defined contributions 142 Ibid para 41 Ibid para 42 144 Ibid para 43 145 Ibid para 46 143 36 section for new members. This type of scheme would not be defined as a shared risk scheme, since, though there are some elements of a pensions promise, the promise is not available to all members. Instead, regulations must be made providing for the scheme to be treated as if it were two schemes for the purpose of the categorisation – in the example given above, it is likely that the power would be used to treat the scheme as if it were a defined benefits scheme and a defined contributions scheme. 146 The Government expects this to ensure that “all schemes fit into the categories set out in Part 1.”147 Interpretation of Part 1 Clause 7 defines some of the terms in Part 1, in particular, the terms retirement benefit, retirement income and retirement lump, which are important in defining the pension promise. For example, under clause 5 (1), there is a full pension promise in relation to a retirement benefit if there is a promise about the level of benefit that will be received, which is determined wholly by reference to that promise in all circumstances. Clause 7 provides that ‘level’ of retirement benefit means: (a) in the case of retirement income, the rate of that income, and (b) in the case of a retirement lump sum, the amount of that lump sum; Furthermore, that: “retirement income”, in relation to a member of a pension scheme, means pension or annuity payable to the member on reaching normal pension age; “retirement lump sum”, in relation to a member of a pension scheme, means a lump sum payable to the member on reaching normal pension age or available for the provision of other retirement benefits for the member on or after reaching normal pension age. Normal pension age in relation to retirement benefits refers to: […] the earliest age at which, or occasion on which, the pension scheme member is entitled to receive benefits from the scheme without adjustment for taking benefits early or late. If there is no such age or occasion, ‘normal pension age’ will be normal minimum pension age as defined by section 279(1) of the Finance Act 2004 – that is, before 6th April 2010, 50, and on or after that date, 55. A ‘fixed’ normal pension age means a pension age (or other decumulation occasion) that cannot be changed except by an amendment to the scheme rules.148 Amendments to do with Part 1 Clause 8 and Schedule 1 makes consequential amendments to existing pensions legislation to take account of these new categories. It also replaces some references to money purchase schemes with references to a scheme under which all the benefits that may be provided are money purchase benefits.149 The Explanatory Notes set out where the effect of the amended legislation is changed. In particular: 146 Ibid DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, para 18 148 Bill 12 EN para 51 149 Ibid para 54 147 37 1.3 Section 124 of the Pension Schemes Act 1993 places a duty on the Secretary of State to pay unpaid contributions to schemes in the event of employer insolvency and consequent default on employer contributions. The Schedule amends the wording to replace ‘money purchase scheme’ with ‘defined contribution scheme, or a shared risk scheme under which all of the benefits that may be provided are money purchase benefits.’ In conjunction with an amendment included in Part 3 of Schedule 4, this updates the provision to ensure that it applies in the right way to schemes that offer collective benefits, as well as ensuring that “all schemes which are shared risk and have only money purchase and collective benefits, and schemes which are defined contributions and provide a guaranteed income after the point of retirement, are captured.”150 Section 51 and 51A of the Pensions Act 1995 require pensions in payment to be increased in line with inflation capped at 5% for rights accrued between 1997 and 2005 and at 2.5% for rights accrued from 6 April 2005. The requirements have not applied to money purchase schemes since April 2005. These provisions are amended to ensure that all defined contributions schemes, including money purchase schemes, schemes offering collective benefits and those defined as self-annuitising, are exempt from the indexation requirements.151 Sections 20 to 28 of the Pensions Act 2008 set out the requirements that a pension scheme must meet if it is to be a ‘qualifying scheme’ for automatic enrolment purposes. The provisions are amended to reflect the new definitions in Part 1. The quality requirements are on the whole unchanged (except where stated).152 Part 2 – general changes to pensions legislation Promise obtained from a third party Clause 9 relates to the possibility of a promise being obtained from a third party as set out in clause 5 of the Bill. The Explanatory Notes say: […] It contains a power to enable the Secretary of State to make regulations to require that trustees or managers of a scheme must not obtain any such promise from a third party unless conditions set out in the regulations are met. Regulations may also provide for a prescribed person to enforce compliance with this requirement, and allow civil penalties to apply to a person who fails to comply with them. This clause also makes changes to section 34(7) of the Pensions Act 1995 to add this clause to the list of provisions that section 34, which makes its own provisions in relation to trustees’ power of investment, cannot override.153 The intention is to enable additional member protections: 22. We intend regulations under this provision to enable additional member protections where the scheme itself is not liable for the guarantee, and where there may not be a direct contractual relationship between the member and the provider of the third party guarantee in new styles of shared risk and defined benefits schemes, and where the Pension Protection Fund and the Financial Services Compensation Fund may not apply. The conditions would be intended to ensure that the risk being taken with such an arrangement was proportionate.154 150 Ibid para 58 Ibid para 60 152 Ibid para 67 153 Ibid para 68 154 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP 2014-0911 151 38 Disclosure of information The Pension Schemes Act 1993 (section 113) provides for the Secretary of State to make regulations requiring pension schemes to keep certain persons informed of various matters including the scheme’s constitution, its administration and finances and the rights and obligations that may arise under the scheme. Following consultation, the requirements for occupational and personal pension schemes were consolidated and are now in the Occupational and Personal Pension Schemes (Disclosure of Information) Regulations 2013 (SI 2013/2734).155 Clause 10 would amend section 113 of the 1993 Act to remove the ‘non-exhaustive’ list of those people to keep informed. This list would in future be in secondary legislation. The Government said this would “enable the Department to take account of the new categories of scheme and members in terms that are meaningful.” Clause 10 (4) would require schemes to have regard to guidance prepared by the Secretary of State when complying with disclosure requirements. 156 The Government has consulted on whether it would have guidance addressing areas of good practice. Some respondents said this would helpful on specific areas such as lifestyling or electronic communications. 157 The Government has indicated an intention to bring forward a specific set of information requirements relating to DA schemes: 37. The nature of DA schemes may mean there is a clear case for a common set of information requirements distinct from those for DB and money purchase schemes. The fact that DA provision will offer members some degree of guarantee but not absolute certainty about their pensions means that the nature of the pension promise may be harder to understand and more complex to communicate without being misleading. As a result, we would consider the need to set out specific disclosure and information requirements for DA schemes ensuring that members receive clear and consistent explanations of their pension rights in the scheme. 38. We would look to ensure the approach to what we require is consistent with the principles behind the new harmonised disclosure regulations which comes into force in April next year. We expect that many of the elements of disclosure required for DB and money purchase schemes may also be applicable and will ensure it is clear and easy to identify what disclosure is required for DA.158 Regulations under section 113 are subject to the negative resolution procedure.159 Extension of preservation of benefit under occupational schemes Before the Pensions Act 2014, legislation required occupational pension schemes to offer a refund of contributions, or a cash transfer to a member leaving a scheme after three months and before two years of service, who had not accrued any right to future benefits under the scheme.160 The refund applied to the member contribution only, the employer contribution remained in the scheme and could be used to cover future employer contributions, scheme Details of the consultation are on the Gov.UK website – Occupational and Personal Pensions (Disclosure of Information Regulations) 156 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, para 25-6 157 DWP, The Occupational and Personal Pension Schemes (Disclosure of Information) Regulations 2013. Government response to the consultation, July 2013 158 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, page 55, para 37 159 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP 2014-0911, para 28 160 Pensions Schemes Act 1993, section 101 155 39 administration costs or one-off scheme costs. There was no equivalent rule for workplace personal pensions. In January 2011, DWP said it was concerned that this difference could act as an incentive for employers to set up occupational pension schemes specifically to take advantage of the short service refund rules. It was therefore examining the role short service refund rules could play following the introduction of automatic enrolment.161 In December 2011, it said it had decided to abolish the use of short-service refunds for occupational DC schemes.162 Section 36 of the 2014 Act therefore introduced a requirement that, where all members are money purchase benefit, a preserved benefit must be provided after 30 days’ service. The right to a refund of contributions was removed.163 Clause 11 would extend this to apply to all cases where the pension benefit is not salaryrelated: 75. The clause states that schemes must provide a short service benefit where leavers have at least 30 days’ qualifying service and all the pension benefit is a non-salary related one (that is, not calculated either by rate or amount with reference to the member’s salary). If any of the pension benefit is salary related, the two year rule still applies. 76. Where a benefit may be calculated on a salary related basis in some circumstances and a non-salary related basis in others (e.g. an underpin benefit which pays the higher of the two calculations), it will be treated as salary-related for these purposes. 77. If a member’s pensionable service began before the amendments came into force, the previous requirements for preservation of benefits will continue to apply. 164 Early leavers: revaluation of accrued benefits Clause 12 would make provision for the way in which the deferred benefits of early leavers are revalued. Given the aim of encouraging personal pension schemes to provide benefits other than money purchase benefits, the purpose is to ensure that revaluation methods currently not available to personal pension schemes could be made suitable: 30. Following the changes made by this Bill, personal pension schemes will be encouraged to provide benefits other than money purchase benefits. The power will enable regulations to amend Chapter 2 in order to modify the current revaluation provisions to ensure that the revaluation methods that are currently not available to personal pension schemes are made suitable for those schemes. This will enable those schemes to appropriately revalue deferred benefits for early leavers if new personal pension schemes evolve so that the average salary or final salary method is considered more appropriate. The power is restricted so that the revaluation method used for a benefit to which a right has already accrued may not be changed (see new section 85A(2)(b). This power will be subject to the negative resolution procedure. Although it is a power to amend primary legislation, any regulations will be limited to technical changes which build on existing requirements, and will be responsive to new benefit structures. The negative procedure was therefore considered appropriate. 165 161 DWP, Preparing for automatic enrolment: Regulatory differences between occupational and workplace personal pensions. A call for evidence. January 2011 162 DWP, Meeting future workplace pension challenges: improving transfers and dealing with small pension pots, Cm 8184, December 2011 163 Pensions Act 2014 – Explanatory Notes, para 154-5 164 Bill 12 EN 165 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP 2014-0911 40 Early leavers: transfer values Clause 13 and Schedule 3 would make amendments relating to transfer values to reflect the new scheme categories defined in Part 1 of the Bill. The Explanatory Notes say: 87. Schedule 3 amends Chapter 4 of Part 4 of the Pension Schemes Act 1993, which sets out provisions governing how members of an occupational or personal pension scheme may apply for, take and use the cash equivalent value of their rights in the scheme, and how that transfer value is to be calculated. 88. The existing provisions provide for two ways to calculate and give effect to transfer rights. If the rights are to money purchase benefits, the transfer value is the realisable value of the member’s rights in the scheme on any given date, which is relatively straightforward to calculate. For salary related benefits the situation is more complex as trustees have to convert a promised benefit into a cash equivalent. As there is no direct correlation between the member’s benefits and the money available to pay them, trustees are required to give the member a guaranteed cash equivalent that is valid for a prescribed period of time. 89. This Schedule amends Chapter 4 to reflect the new scheme categories defined in Part 1 of the Bill. Under the changes there will still be the same two methods to offer a transfer value – members of defined benefits schemes, members of shared risk schemes and members of defined contributions schemes that provide benefits other than money purchase benefits will get a guaranteed cash equivalent, and members of defined contributions schemes providing money purchase benefits will get the realisable value of their assets. 90. As now, the details about how trustees and managers calculate a cash equivalent will be described in regulations. 166 Indexation requirements For DB schemes, there is a statutory minimum by which pensions in payment must be increased. Under the Pensions Act 1995 indexation in line with prices, capped at 5%, was required for rights accrued from 1997.167 Under the Pensions Act 2004, the cap was reduced to 2.5% for rights accrued from 2005 onwards.168 Clause 15 would exempt Regulatory Own Funds (ROF) from the indexation requirements in the Pensions Act 1995. The Government has said that the primary option for a CDC scheme providing some form of promise or guarantee, would be a vehicle set up as a ROF. 169 The reason for exempting ROFs from the indexation requirements is presumably that being able to suspend indexation is one of the key levers available to CDCs needing to restore funding levels (see section 3.4 below). Clause 16 would introduce a regulation-making power to exclude other pensions of a prescribed description from the indexation requirements for future accruals. Such regulations would be subject to the affirmative resolution procedure, so need to be approved by both Houses of Parliament before becoming law.170 166 Bill 12 EN Section 51 168 Section 278 169 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, page 53 170 Bill 12 EN, para 96 167 41 Rules about modification of schemes Section 67 of Pensions Act 1995 sets out the conditions under which the subsisting rights of members of occupational pension schemes can be modified. As originally enacted, it prohibited changes to the rules of a scheme which would reduce a member’s accrued pension rights without the member’s consent. The 2002 Pickering Report on pension simplification argued that this prevented DB schemes from making perfectly sensible changes which would leave the members no worse off overall, and was a contributory factor in many decisions to close down defined benefit schemes.171 Section 67 was substantially amended by the Pensions Act 2004. Under the new rules, only detrimental changes to subsisting rights were covered, and trustees may make changes without consent, so long as each member from whom consent has not been obtained retains benefits that are actuarially equivalent to those he had prior to the change.172 The Pensions Regulator explains the applications of these provisions in Code of practice 10: Modification of subsisting rights (January 2007). In consultation on its proposals for DA, the Government said it did not think DB scheme sponsors should have the power to modify subsisting rights beyond what was allowed under existing legislation. 47. The Government believes that employers should not have the power to transfer or modify accruals built up under previous arrangements into new arrangements, beyond what is allowed under current legislation, otherwise there is a risk that members could lose out on legitimate expectations. 48. This means that deferred and pensioner members, and the past accrued benefits of active members, would not be affected as a consequence of introducing DA pensions. 49. We do, however, want to support employers, scheme trustees and members who, properly advised, wish to alter the shape of past accruals through options that already exist, such as incentive transfer exercises and changes made with member consent. Such options are legitimate ways for employers to manage their risks as long as they are well run in line with best practice. 50. In order to protect members we believe the principles set out in the Incentive Exercises for Pensions: A Code of Good Practice, published in June 2012, should broadly apply in these circumstances. In addition, we are considering whether there should be a requirement to provide independent financial advice in all cases where an employer offers to transfer a member’s accrued rights from a traditional DB scheme to a new arrangement.173 Reflecting the new definitions to be introduced by the Bill, clause 18 would provide for the existing protection arrangements in section 67 to apply to a proposal to replace benefits to which a promise is attached, with benefits where there is no promise. The Explanatory Notes say: 99. Section 67 of the Pensions Act 1995 contains provisions to protect members against detrimental modifications to their ‘subsisting rights’ – that is, ‘any right which at that time has accrued to or in respect of [the member] to future benefits under the 171 Alan Pickering, A simpler way to better pensions, July 2002, para 4.26-4.33 Pensions Act 2004, section 262; Lewin and Sweeney, Deregulatory Review of Private Pensions, An independent report to the Department for Work and Pensions, July 2007, p14 173 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p25 172 42 scheme rules; or any entitlement to the present payment of a pension or other benefit which [the member] has at that time, under the scheme rules’. 100. Some changes can only be made if the member agrees: these are called ‘protected modifications’. Section 67A sets out the circumstances in which a modification to members’ rights is a ‘protected modification’. 101. Currently, section 67A states that a change must be considered as a ‘protected modification’ where money purchase benefits would replace non-money purchase benefits, or where the change would result in a reduction to a pension in payment. This clause amends section 67A to include a proposed modification where a right to benefits that include a pensions promise is to be replaced by a right to benefits where there is no pensions promise.174 Part 2 of Schedule 4 would provide for the protection arrangements also to apply to a proposal to replace non-collective benefits with a right to collective benefits.175 1.4 Part 3 – collective benefits Approach to legislation In November 2013, the Government set out the approach it would take to legislating for collective schemes. It said: 22. CDC schemes can take different forms. Some could potentially operate within the existing legal framework in the UK; others, where there is no guarantee or promise are more difficult to reconcile with it and may need a new regulatory vehicle. 176 Schemes offering some form of promise or guarantee, such as the pensions income builder model, could operate within the proposed DA regulatory framework. The primary option for this would be a vehicle set up as a Regulatory Own Fund (ROF). CDC schemes that provide a promise or guarantee 23. CDC schemes that provide the member with some form of promise or guarantee, such as the pension income builder explored in Chapter 4, could operate within the proposed DA regulatory framework. As with any other scheme containing a promise, they would need to be funded on a technical provisions basis and meet the appropriate solvency requirements. 24. However, the means by which these funding requirements can be satisfied are likely to be different from traditional DB arrangements where a sponsoring employer stands behind the arrangement (and is effectively responsible for any deficit that arises in the scheme). 25. The primary option for a CDC scheme providing some form of promise or guarantee would be a vehicle set up as a Regulatory Own Fund. As a first step, we would need to modernise the current Regulatory Own Funds legislative requirements, not least to bring them into line with the other DA reforms and to ensure they work from a practical perspective. 26. In European terms, such schemes fall within the terms of Article 17 of the Institutions for Occupational Retirement Provision (IORP) Directive. This sets out the 174 Bill 12 EN Ibid, para 127-8 176 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p53; 175 43 requirements for institutions that, themselves – rather than the sponsoring employer – underwrite the liabilities or guarantees investment performance or benefits level. 27. Besides setting out the regulatory vehicle for these schemes we will need to consider whether the framework should include other requirements to enable them to provide the high levels of governance that would be needed to protect member interests. For example, there may be a case for a more formal approval arrangement on set-up, possibly by requiring schemes to obtain a licence from a regulator, as well as being subject to regulatory oversight of their funding levels. 28. While we have identified Regulatory Own Funds as a potentially suitable vehicle there may be other vehicles (which emerge either now or in the future) which could also provide this type of collective arrangement. We are therefore not looking to restrict the types of vehicles that could be used, simply to provide an enabling framework.177 As regards scheme funding requirements, these would apply to the extent of any promise or guarantee: A Regulatory Own Fund vehicle offering deferred annuities and discretionary benefits would need to be funded to the level required to meet the discounted capital value of the liabilities (technical provisions) plus an appropriate buffer.178 A ROF is a scheme which itself, rather than any employer, underwrites liability to cover against biometric risk (linked to death, disability or longevity), or guarantees a given investment performance of a given level of benefits. Article 17 of the European Directive on the Supervision of Institutions for Occupational Retirement Provision (2003/41/EC) requires such schemes to hold additional assets above normal funding levels. The requirements of Article 17 were transposed into UK law by the Occupational Pension Schemes (Regulatory Own Funds) Regulations 2005 (SI 2005/3380). At that time the Government was not aware of any such schemes operating in the UK.179 In June 2014, the Government said it was introducing a new definition of collective benefit, which could fall within the DA or DC definition. Those collective schemes that did not provide a promise or guarantee during the accrual phase would fall within the DC category: Collectives are not currently possible in the UK in practice because they are not catered for in either pensions or tax legislation. The Department for Work and Pensions has had discussions with Her Majesty’s Treasury (HMT) and Her Majesty’s Revenue and Customs (HMRC) to examine this issue. In order to enable collective schemes that are run safely and regulated appropriately, we propose to define benefits provided on a collective basis in primary legislation for the first time.180 Because such schemes were complex and could be opaque, they would need strong standards of communication and governance: We will create a framework that draws on the experiences of other countries where collective schemes operate and places the interests of members firmly at the heart of that design, prioritising clarity and transparency. 177 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, November 2013, Cm 8710, p53; See also, DWP, Collective Defined Contribution Schemes, December 2009 178 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, November 2013, Cm 8710, p55 179 SI 2005/3380 – Explanatory Memorandum 180 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, p22 44 Collective schemes are complex and can be opaque – because of the indirect relationship between contributions and benefits. This necessitates strong standards of communication and governance. We intend collective schemes to be overseen by experienced fiduciaries acting on behalf of members, taking decisions at scheme level and removing the need for individuals to make difficult choices over fund allocations and retirement income products. We will also introduce a robust regulatory regime in respect of targeting benefits and internal accounting, providing regulators with the appropriate mandate and tools to supervise schemes properly. We believe it is crucial that members fully understand the risks associated with collective arrangements when they join the scheme, and while it is not for the state to determine the benefit design of these schemes, we will ensure that schemes set out clearly (to members) in advance how their rights are defined, what they can expect from the pool, and how positive and negative shocks will impact on their pension benefits. Collective schemes, as with all DC arrangements, do not come without risk, but with proper standards of governance and a suitable regulatory regime, we believe that we can mitigate these appropriately. A definition of collective benefits and associated key requirements will be included in the Pensions Bill while secondary legislation is likely to include more detailed provisions in relation to areas such as benefit targeting, risk management, communications and governance. 181 The necessary changes to tax rules would be addressed separately: The legislative measures we will introduce will not address tax rules; however we will continue to work with HMRC and HMT to consider how collective schemes would operate within the pensions tax regime.182 Part 3 of the Bill defines the concept of collective benefits and makes provision for regulation-making power in relation to them. These include powers to make regulations requiring trustees/managers of such schemes to: - - Set targets in relation to the rate or amount of benefits scheme members can expect, which should be at a level which ensures that the probability of meeting them is equal to or higher than a level of probability set out in regulations. Request a certificate from an actuary confirming that the scheme has sufficient assets to meet the initial targets, to a degree of probability specified in regulations; Providing a statement of the scheme’s investment strategy, and keeping the strategy under review; Request regular valuation reports to assess the likelihood of the scheme being able to meet the targets it has set relation to benefits; and Have a policy for dealing with circumstances in which the probability of a scheme being able to meet a target in relation to a collective benefit falls above or below a level of probability set out in regulations. This emphasis on setting targets, communicating with members and keeping the scheme’s ability to meet them under review, would appear to reflect lessons learned from experience in the Netherlands, summarised by DWP as follows: 181 182 Ibid Ibid 45 19. Although historically schemes in the Netherlands have been described as CDC, they were presented to the members as DB, with members developing expectations that pensions were guaranteed, when in practice there was scope within the rules for pensions (including those in payment) to be reduced in the event of under-funding. Employers viewed them as defined contribution, so considered they had more control over their costs than under DB. 20. Whilst the model seemed sustainable during a period of strong economic growth, the downturn and the resulting pressure on scheme funding has led to benefits being reduced and to the structure of the schemes being reviewed, with a new pensions contract being introduced in 2015. As well as being explicit that there are no guarantees, a new funding regime is being introduced. The changes are expected to lead to a significant consolidation in the number of schemes.183 Detailed provisions in relation to areas such as benefit targeting, risk management, communications and governance are to be in secondary legislation.184 In terms of governance, the Government said it intended collective schemes to be “overseen by experienced fiduciaries”: Collective schemes are complex and can be opaque – because of the indirect relationship between contributions and benefits. This necessitates strong standards of communication and governance. We intend collective schemes to be overseen by experienced fiduciaries acting on behalf of members, taking decisions at scheme level and removing the need for individuals to make difficult choices over fund allocations and retirement income products.185 Throughout Part 3, there are references to “the trustees or managers of a pension scheme”, suggesting that there is scope for them to be either trust-based or contract-based. The RSA has argued that collective schemes (CDCs) should be trust-based: Pension provision is notoriously open to conflicts of interest. And these are exacerbated by the fact that individuals have little knowledge of what their pension provider is doing and little leverage over their actions. We would therefore strongly recommend that: 1. CDC pensions, like DB pensions should only be introduced under trustee management; that is where the governance of the fund owes loyalty only to its beneficiaries. 2. That the primary duty of the trustees is to represent the interest of the members. The trustee body should have amongst its members adequate expertise to manage the investment and benefit issues they will confront. 3. The trustees should make public their investment and benefit policy, and their proposed response to known risks. These should be made available to all beneficiaries. 183 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013, p47 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, p22 185 DWP, Government response to the consultation. Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8883, June 2014, p22 184 46 4. There should be clear rules as to the decisions which can be made by the trustees and those which need the authorisation of the regulator.186 Definition Clause 19 would provide for the definition of collective benefits. The Explanatory Notes say that: 103. Where in all circumstances the rate or amount of the benefit payable to or in respect of a member depends entirely on (a) the amount available to pay that member’s and other members’ benefits and (b) factors used to determine what proportion of that amount is available for the provision of the particular benefit. 187 Clause 19 (3) would provide that a benefit which is a money purchase benefit is not a collective benefit.188 A scheme that provides collective benefits would fall within one of the definitions in Part 1 of the Bill, depending on whether or not it provides a ‘pension promise’. A scheme like the pensions income builder, where a proportion of the contributions paid are used to purchase a deferred annuity each year, would fall within the shared risk definition.189 A scheme that offers no pensions promise would fall within the DC category.190 Targets Clause 20 would provide for regulations to require trustees or managers of schemes offering collective benefits to set targets in relation to the rate or amount of those benefits: In particular, regulations can be made about, amongst other things, the way that targets are expressed, recorded and published. The intention is that members of a scheme with collective benefits should be provided with a reasonable estimate of the benefits that they can expect to receive from the scheme; in the absence of a welldefined pot over which the individual has clear ownership, the target is a way of illustrating for the member what they might receive. 191 It also provides for regulation-making powers to require trustees/managers to obtain a certificate confirming that “the actuary is of the opinion that the probability of the assets being sufficient to meet the initial targets is in line with the level set out in the regulations.” 192 In more detail, DWP explains that: 51. The setting of targets in relation to collective benefits is key to ensuring that schemes providing collective benefits operate in as transparent a manner as possible. Whilst the target is unenforceable, it will provide a clear indication of the level of benefits that the scheme is seeking to provide for its members. 52. When a scheme first starts to offer collective benefits, the Department intends to require the trustees or managers to obtain a certificate from an actuary which confirms that the initial targets set by the scheme have been set at an appropriate level. This level will be measured by reference to a level of probability specified by the Secretary 186 RSA, Collective pensions in the UK II, November 2013, p13 Bill 12-EN, para 103 188 Ibid 189 DWP, Reshaping workplace pensions for future generations, Cm 8710, November 2013 p34 and p51 190 Clause 5 (3) (c); Bill 12-EN, para 41 191 Ibid para 104 192 Ibid 187 47 of State in regulations (and this level of probability is also relevant to regulation-making powers in subsequent clauses). In other words, at the point that the scheme begins to offer collective benefits, there should be a tenable link between the contributions paid into the scheme, the investments held by it and the target level of benefit to be provided by those investments. 53. This level of probability will need to be set at a level which takes into account a number of different matters. Concerns about scheme transparency and the important of ensuring that members understand the rate or amount of benefit that the schemes is aiming to provide will need to be balanced with the need to ensure that there is sufficient flexibility about the link between assets and target levels to allow schemes to take advantage of risk sharing options that are inherent to schemes that offer collective benefits – for example, the ability to smooth investment across the membership. The Department intends to canvas industry opinion as to the appropriate level of probability before setting on a definite figure […]193 Investment strategy Section 35 and 36 of the Pensions Act 1995 outline the requirements governing investments for trust-based schemes. These include a requirement to produce a Statement of Investment Principles (SIP): “a written statement of the investment principles governing decisions about investment for the purpose of the scheme”.194 The required detail for the SIP is set out in the Occupational Pension Scheme (Investment) Regulations 2005 (SI 2005 No 3378). Scheme investments are covered in the Pensions Regulator’s Trustee guidance. Clause 23 would provide a regulation-making power to require trustees or managers to “produce a statement about the investment strategy to be followed in connection with the provision of ‘collective’ benefits.” The Government has explained that although there are potential similarities with existing legislation applying to trust-based schemes, it would be important to have specific regulation-making powers in relation to the investment strategy for collective benefits: This is not only so that there is consistency in terms of investment requirements and obligations between trust-based and contract-based schemes that offer collective benefits, but also because, given the different nature of collective benefits to other forms of pension benefits as a result of the opportunities associated with risk-sharing between members, it is appropriate to have separate provisions relating to investment strategy and decisions. For example, it may be appropriate for the investment strategy for collective benefits to be revisited on a more regular basis than an investment strategy which relates to the provision of other types of benefits – a requirement to review the strategy on an annual, rather than a triennial, basis might be appropriate. 195 Clause 24 would provide a regulation-making power to impose requirements on trustees or managers of schemes in relation to their choice of investments in connection with the provision of collective benefits. This could include specifying criteria to be applied in choosing investments and requiring diversification of investments.196 193 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill - Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911 Tolley’s Pension Law, E.40; IDS Pension Service, Pension trustees and administration, para 7.10; Occupational Pension Schemes (Investment) Regulations 2005 (SI 2005/3378) 195 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill -Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, para 66 196 Ibid, para 68 and 68; clause 41 194 48 Clause 25 would provide a regulation-making power to require the trustees or managers of a pension scheme that provides collective benefits to obtain reports about investment performance relating to collective benefits. DWP explains that: This power is necessary to ensure that trustees or managers are actively reviewing the performance of investments so that appropriate steps can be taken as quickly as possible to address any issues with investment choices or strategy. This is important in ensuring that there is transparency in the way that the scheme is run and also for member protection.197 Valuation reports Clause 26 would provide a regulation-making power to require those schemes offering collective benefits to obtain, from an actuary, a ‘valuation report’ which values the assets held by the scheme for the purposes of providing collective benefits and assesses how likely it is that the scheme will be able to meet targets in relation to those benefits.198 It is anticipated that such reports will need to be obtained on an annual basis, in order for the trustees or managers to be able to monitor to what extent the assets held by the scheme are likely to be sufficient to provide the target level of benefits.199 It also provides for regulations to require the actuary to certify whether the probability of the scheme being able to provide the target level of benefits is equal to, higher or lower, than a specified level of probability. This would be “key to the steps that the trustees or managers take to respond to the outcome of the valuation” and links with the policy for dealing with a deficit or surplus required under clause 28.200 Regulations may also require the report to be obtained from an actuary who has specified qualifications or meets other specified requirements. The Government has explained that this is to protect scheme members: […] Again, this comes down to member protection – the actuary will be required to make judgement calls when valuing assets held by the scheme and assessing the likelihood of the scheme meeting any targets in relations to those benefits which potentially impact on the level of benefits the member actually receive from the scene.[…] it is particularly important in the context of collective benefits that the actuary has a sufficient and appropriate level of technical expertise, since the risk in relation to collective benefits lies entirely with the members; the consequence of poor actuarial advice could be lower benefits for members. Unlike under a traditional salary-related pension arrangement where the employer stands behind any promise offered by the scheme and is therefore responsible for meeting any funding shortfall, trustees or managers may not have recourse to additional funds from an employer (or from the member) in the context of providing collective benefits. The accuracy of the valuation report and actuarial certification is likely to be of paramount importance. 201 Clause 27 would provide for a regulation-making power to make provision about the methods or assumptions to be used by an actuary valuing assets, assessing the likelihood of a scheme meeting a target in relation to collective benefits and in relation to the methods and 197 Ibid para 71 Bill 12-EN, para 112 199 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, para 76 200 Ibid para 74 201 Ibid para 75 198 49 assumptions used in preparing a valuation report.202 The Government has explained that this is in regulations rather than primary legislation for a number of reasons: The provisions in this clause will involve a detailed and technical process that is most suitably set out in secondary legislation. Its implementation will require further consideration and consultation with interested parties, such as the actuarial profession. It is also felt to be important to retain a significant degree of flexibility in establishing the details of the process, so that the Department can make a quick and effective response to any concerns raised. As schemes that provide collective benefits do not currently exist within the occupational pension sphere in the UK, the Department will need sufficient flexibility to ensure that the valuation process and the methods or assumptions to be used by an actuary valuing target benefits, are fit for purpose.203 Regulations under clause 27 will be subject to the negative resolution procedure.204 Policy for dealing with a deficit or surplus Clause 28 contains a regulation-making power to require trustees/managers of schemes offering collective benefits to have a policy for dealing with circumstances where the probability of meeting a target falls above or below a level of probability set out in regulations: 115. Under clause 28, regulations may provide that trustees or managers of schemes offering collective benefits are required to have a policy for dealing with circumstances where the probability of a scheme meeting a target in relation to a collective benefit falls above or below a level of probability set out in regulations - termed in the Bill as ‘deficit’ or ‘surplus’ in relation to the target. 116. The clause also sets out powers to require the policy to contain provision for a deficit or surplus to be dealt with in one or more of a range of ways, to contain an explanation of the possible effect of the policy on members in different circumstances and to be drawn up with a view to achieving certain results within a specified period of time.205 DWP explains that the main objective behind this clause is to ensure that schemes offering collective benefits operate in a “transparent and accountable manner” as the policy would set out how benefit levels might change for members under different economic scenarios.206 Clause 28 (3) provides for regulations to require trustees/managers to consult about this policy, make provision for the content of the policy and about how it is reviewed or revised. The requirement to consult (clause 28 (3) (a)) is important because a change to the surplus/deficit policy in a collective scheme could potentially involve a redistribution of assets amongst the membership.207 The power to make provision about reviewing and revising the policy may be used to require reviews on a regular basis - possibly on an annual basis to tie in with valuation reports.208 While the intention is to allow trustees/managers flexibility as to how they deal with any deficit or surplus, there may be some restrictions on this: 202 Bill 12-EN, para 114 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, para 80 204 Ibid para 81 205 Bill 12-EN 206 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911, para 84 207 Ibid, para 87 208 Ibid 203 50 […] Whilst the intention is to use the powers to make provision about what information the policy should contain (including the types of scenarios that the policy should address), there should also be a degree of flexibility available to trustees and managers as to the way that any deficit or surplus should be dealt with. The appropriate action might, for example, differ depending on scheme design. This is why subsection 4 (b) contains a power to require the policy to contain provision for a deficit or surplus to be dealt with in one or more of a “range of ways.” However, it is important that some safeguards are put in place in relation to acceptable ways or time periods for dealing with a deficit or surplus; this is why a power has been included at subsection 4 (a) to require the policy to be formulated with a view to achieving results described in the regulations within a period or periods described in the regulations. 209Clause 29 provides for a regulation-making power to allow an amount to be treated as a debt due from an employer to a scheme offering collective benefits in situations where a deficit in relation to a target benefit has resulted from a specified offence or the imposition of a specified levy.210 Other provisions Clause 30 contains a regulation-making power to require trustees/managers of schemes offering collective benefits to have, and to follow a policy for the calculation and verification of collective benefits.211 DWP explains: 96. This clause also contains powers to make other provision about the content of the policy, the review and revision of the policy, and may require trustees or managers to consult about the policy. This policy will be a key scheme document and it is important that, as schemes providing collective benefits develop, there is an opportunity to adjust the detail as to the content of the policy to take account of the way that a variety of schemes operate in practice.212 Clause 31 provides for regulations to be made regarding the winding-up of collective schemes. It: […] provides for regulations to modify the application of sections 73, 73A, 73B and 74 of the Pensions Act 1995, which concern the winding up of occupational pension schemes, in relation to collective benefits. 121. The clause also provides for regulation-making powers to be used to make provision in relation to collective benefits corresponding or similar to any provision made by sections 73, 73A, 73B and 74 of the Pensions Act 1995.213 DWP explains: 99. The rules setting out the winding up of a pension scheme are important in providing protection and transparency for members in the event of the scheme being wound-up. Rules governing the winding up of existing occupational pension schemes (other than money purchase schemes and other exempted schemes) are set out in the 1995 Pensions Act. However, the winding up provisions were not drafted with collective benefits in mind, and it is likely that collective benefits will not be compatible with these provisions as currently drafted. We envisage that collective benefits may therefore need to be taken out of the existing wind-up rules and a more appropriate set of rules put in place governing their wind-up. It is likely that the Regulations will need to include 209 Ibid, para 85 Bill 12-EN, para 117 211 Ibid, para 118 212 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911 213 Bill 12-EN 210 51 a greater degree of technical detail than would be suitable for inclusion in primary legislation.214 Clauses 32 includes a regulation-making power to require trustees or managers to consult a scheme actuary before taking action or decisions in relation to the provisions in Part 3 of the Bill. This is important to ensure that scheme decision-making incorporates expert advice.215 In addition, regulations may provide the scheme actuary to have regard to guidance when advising on these matters. The Government explains: There is precedent within pensions legislation for including provisions which require the actuary to have regard to prescribed guidance, for example under section 230(3) (matters on which advice of actuary must be obtained) of the Pensions Act 2004. The provision in clause 32(2) is a technical requirement to ensure that scheme actuaries can be required to have recourse to the most recent and appropriate professional guidance when advising those with responsibilities in schemes offering collective benefits.216 Clause 34 provides a power to impose requirements in regulations about the publication of scheme documents described in clauses 21-28 (regarding the processes for contributions, investment and valuation in collective schemes). Regulations may also specify to whom such documents should be sent.217 Clause 35 provides a power to make regulations regarding enforcement: […] conferring functions on a specified person to enforce regulations relevant to this Part of the Bill, and a power for civil penalties to apply of the relevant requirements in the regulations are not complied with.218 The Government has explained: 104. Clause 35 allows regulations made under Part 3 of the Bill to confer functions on a specified person in connection with enforcement of those regulations. In addition, clause 35 allows those regulations to provide for Section 10 of the Pensions Act 1995 to apply where there is non-compliance. 105. The Pensions Regulator has an existing enforcement power under section 10 of the Pensions Act 1995. This prescribes that, where the Regulator is satisfied that by reason of any act or omission this section applies to any person, they may by notice in writing require that person to pay, within a prescribed period, a civil penalty in respect of that act or omission not exceeding the maximum amount. The maximum amount of any penalty under Section 10 of the Pensions Act 1995 is £5,000 in the case of an individual or £50,000 in the case of a company, or such lower amount as might otherwise be prescribed.219 Clause 37 and Schedule 4 would make amendments to other legislation to reflect the introduction of collective benefits. These include the provisions in the Pensions Act 1995 to protect members against detrimental modifications to their subsisting rights. The Explanatory Notes say: 214 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911 Ibid para 101 216 Ibid para 102 217 Ibid para 103 218 Bill 12-EN 219 DWP, Pension Schemes Bill Delegated Powers, June 2014, DEP2014-0911 215 52 127. As noted for clause 18 above, section 67 of the Pensions Act 1995 contains provisions to protect members against detrimental modifications to their ‘subsisting rights’. 128. Currently, section 67A states that a change must be considered as a ‘protected modification’ where money purchase benefits would replace non-money purchase benefits, or where the change would result in a reduction to a pension in payment. This clause adds a further case to that list so that if a right to non-collective benefits would be replaced by a right to collective benefits under the scheme rules, this is a protected modification. Part 2 also modifies the 1995 Act to exclude collective benefits from the existing framework of subsisting rights provision. 220 In addition, Schedule 4 would provide for: - Collective benefits to be exempt from the employer debt provisions in section 75 of the Pensions Act 1995 which apply where a DB scheme in wind-up is in deficit.221 - Occupational schemes offering only collective benefits (or only money purchase benefits and collective benefits) will not be eligible for the Pension Protection Fund (set up under the Pensions Act 2004 to provide compensation to members of defined benefit pension schemes winding up underfunded on the insolvency of the sponsoring employer).222 - Schemes providing collective benefits are to be exempt from the scheme funding requirements in the Pensions Act 2004 (which currently apply to occupational pension schemes but not to money purchase schemes or schemes of a prescribed description).223 - Provisions requiring trustees or managers of occupational money purchase schemes to prepare schedules of payments for scheme members are to be amended so that it applies to all DC or shared risk schemes under which either all of the benefits to be provided are money purchase benefits or money purchase benefits and collective benefits.224 220 Bill 12-EN Ibid para 131 and 132 222 For detail, see the website of the Pension Protection Fund. For more on the background to the scheme, see Library Note SN 3917 Pension Protection Fund (July 2012) 223 For more detail, see Library Note SN 4877 Pension scheme funding requirements (March 2013) 224 Bill 12-EN, para 137 221 53