DISINFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT On the Non-Neutrality of Monetary Policy Heinz-Peter Spahn "The object of the higher bank rate is to involve entrepreneurs in losses and the factors of production in unemployment, for only in this way can the money rates of efficiency earnings be reduced. It is not reasonable, therefore, to complain when these results ensue." John M. Keynes (1930, 245) 1. Introduction The most serious challenge that the existence of unemployment poses to the theory of credibility and reputation is this: the most reputable type of a monetary economy is plagued by a lot of it.1 The most reputable economy is, of course, the Bundesbank-governed system of a monetary economy. It is the cornerstone of the notion of neutrality of money that neither expansive nor restrictive monetary policies should have a real impact on the economy. Whereas traditional classical and monetarist theory held this to be true in the long run, new classical writers claim that it all depends on expectations which in turn are derived from the credibility of policy programs and the reputation of policy institutions. Accordingly in the last decade much effort has been invested in institutional reforms of monetary policy. At present many central banks throughout the world have gained political independence, but disinflation seems to be as costly as before. This paper therefore aims to collect the arguments which might explain the rise of unemployment when monetary policy in a credible way turns restrictive in order to fight inflation. The first section describes some controversies between old and new monetarists on the conditions of monetary neutrality. The second section presents some empirical evidence on the sacrifice ratio, i.e. the employment costs of disinflation in various countries. 1 This phrase is, of course, a modified quotation from Frank Hahn's (1982, 1) famous dictum on the non-role of money in general equilibrium. 2 Spahn Three analytically different approaches which might shed some light on the rise and persistence of unemployment succeeding a contraction of monetary demand are sketched out in the following three sections; these approaches − which should be seen as complementary rather than alternative elements − deal with microeconomic "rational" rigidities, macroeconomic dynamic instabilities in a setting of flexible prices and supply-side reactions to a decrease of goods and labour demand. Another section asks whether monetary policy especially in Germany is to blame for impeding economic recovery by deliberately slowing down the process of interest rate reduction. The last section concludes with a short summary. 2. Disinflation in a new classical world: Lucas’s private lessons for David Hume The neutrality of a change in the standard of value2 is regarded as a matter of course throughout the history of economic thought. David Hume, the classical founder of the quantity theory of money, however was convinced that gradual changes in the quantity of money had a different effect: economic activity measured in nominal magnitudes would flourish or shrink, and only in the long run the result would be a proportionate change in the price level. More than two hundred years later, similar ideas could be found in Friedman's treatment of the relation between money and nominal income. However, one important difference between neoclassical Monetarism and the classical quantity theory must not be neglected: whereas Friedman in his famous helicopter parable suggests that an injection of additional money is equally distributed between all market agents, Hume depicts a monetary disturbance essentially as an incipient unequal distribution of money, an abundance or a lack of liquid funds in some sections or places in the economic system, which causes a disequilibrium and a reallocation of resources or a general increase or reduction of transactions before, after a series of adjustments, a new equilibrium is reached which differs from the old one only by an upscaling or downscaling of nominal variables. The Friedman approach is susceptible to the rational expectations movement as the description of the helicopter scenario abstracts from any market structure complications embedded in the macro adjustment process. Hence, it seems reasonable to assume that market agents anticipate the final outcome so that an instantaneous transition from the old to the new equilibrium will occur. In terms of a formal model the supply function s, p$ = p$ e + y$ - y$ * 2 (1) The currency reform of substituting 10 new francs for 1000 old francs provides a typical example. Disinflation and unemployment 3 derived from a Phillips-curve relationship where p$ e denotes the expected rate of inflation and y$ * the full employment growth rate, has to shift downwards in the very moment when the monetary budget restriction of the economy, i.e. the demand function d, y$ = m$ - p$ (2) derived from a simple quantity equation with constant velocity where m$ represents the money growth rate, is being curtailed (move from A to C in figure 1). Figure 1: Supply and demand functions of inflation and growth p y$ * s1 A s0 B d1 y$ C d0 Obviously, the necessary shift of the supply function depends on the adjustment of the expected rate of inflation. The rational expectation solution of the above model reveals that p$ e = m$ e - y$ * . If then a highly reputable central bank announces a policy shift to m$ = y$ * market agents may judge this to be a credible policy program. Accordingly m$ e = m$ may hold so that point C is reached. This sequence of economic logic probably would not have been accepted by Hume (and is questioned by the traditional, Friedman-orientated "mark I" Monetarism); at least during some transition period (of undetermined length) the economy may have a stop-over in B. New classical Nobel Prize winners nowadays strongly object to such a "soft" reasoning which − in their view − cannot be defended if a rational behaviour is ascribed to market agents. For Lucas, the idea "that changes in money are neutral units changes” is incompatible with the hypothesis that they induce movements in employment and production. The fact that Hume failed to comprehend this implication of mere economic logic is attributed to his lack of knowledge with respect to the 4 Spahn rational expectations revolution. Proudly looking back on the progress of economic thought Lucas finally adds some excuse for the limits of Hume's analytical capabilities: "This is too difficult a problem for an economist equipped with only verbal methods."3 The general issue of progress of economic thought cannot be tackled here4, but, first, it is interesting to note that Lucas explicitly5 identifies the quantity theory with the trivial case of a change in the standard of value thereby disregarding what neoclassical writers like Wicksell and Fisher elaborated on that subject, namely the transition periods between two monetary equilibria. Second, in doing so he obscures the economic significance of the process of money creation: the central bank charges a price for modifying the liquidity status of some agents in the financial sector so that a change in the policy stance has immediate repercussions on the whole structure of the yields of capital assets; the working of a monetary impulse thus show more resemblance to Hume's scenario of a partial abundance or lack of money in the market system as a starting point than to Friedman's tale of a monetary rain which in turn amounts to a variety of a units change of the monetary standard of value. 3. Empirical evidence on the costs of disinflation: The sacrifice ratio It is now widely recognised that short term, central-bank governed interest rates are one of the best predictors of real economic activity.6 Figure 2 suggests that it is the nominal short rate which "causes" the outbreak of a recession maybe because its movement is able to signal the intentions of monetary policy makers to banks and investors so that the pure price effect of interest rate changes is reinforced by induced shifts in profit expectation and re-evaluations of investment projects.7 Notice that from cycle to cycle the lag between the peak of short term interest rates and the low of inflation rates has increased up to five years. A more or less distinct increase of unemployment is part of the stylised facts of a restrictive monetary policy which aims at lowering inflation. The 3 Lucas 1996, 664. For a comparison of Keynes' and Lucas' contribution to economic science and an assessment of the rational expectations hypothesis see e.g. Blinder (1987) and Niehans (1987). 5 Lucas 1996, 662. 6 Cf. Bernanke/Blinder 1992, Filc 1992, Perry/Schultze 1993, Ragnitz 1994, Taylor 1995, Moersch 1996 and Krupp/Cabos 1996. 7 The rise of real short rates in 1987 had no serious repercussions on investment and growth as it did not signal the threat of a restrictive monetary policy which could not be expected given the very low rates of inflation. 4 Disinflation and unemployment 5 "sacrifice ratio" may be measured as the cumulative increase in unemployment during a period of disinflation. If the countries are ranked according to their performance the leading position of some countries like Portugal, Finland and Greece and the marked change of some of the positions in the 1980s and 1990s are striking (table and figure 3). The costs of disinflation have increased in Finland, Switzerland, Sweden and France, they became smaller in Greece, Ireland and in the UK. A remarkable event has been the success of the Netherlands: starting from a very bad performance this country achieved a negative sacrifice ratio in the 1990s. But the most surprising fact − with respect to the new classical approach − is that Germany with her famous Bundesbank-type of monetary policy reached only a lower rank in both decades. The sacrifice ratio has been generally higher in the 1990s. The level of inflation was higher in the 1980s; employment losses decreased in the 1990s, but rose in relation to disinflation. As Germany typically exhibits lower inflation compared to most of the other countries her high sacrifice ratio may simply mirror the general problem that the trade-off between unemployment and inflation increases as the economy approaches the zero-inflation line. But even the existence of a non-linear Phillips curve does not provide a convincing explanation of rising marginal costs of disinflation because we should expect the curve to shift downwards in cases of anticipated monetary restriction. A flat slope of the Phillips curve in the range of low inflation rates recently has been explained by a widely spread norm which excludes absolute nominal wage cuts.8 If then monetary policy aims at zero inflation the process of competition and reallocation of resources responding to market shocks will produce unemployment because relative prices cannot adjust. However, this one-sided stickiness of nominal wages may just be the result of the experience of an ever-creeping inflation in the past and may wane after a credible switch to a zero-inflation regime. Furthermore only few central banks really aim at zero inflation (New Zealand just modified her target to some small positive rate). The Bundesbank has a two-percent target which should allow to cope with moderate structural disturbances. The puzzle is still unsolved why it has been so costly to reduce inflation, particularly in Germany where it should have been apparent to all market agents by looking at the history of monetary policy making that the Bundesbank would not tolerate the 5-6 % inflation prevalent in the beginning of the 1980s and 1990s, respectively.9 It has been argued that having a high reputation may pose a problem for restrictive central bank policies be 8 Cf. Akerlof et al. 1996. The disinflation crisis in 1973-75 is different because the policy change at the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system went unnoticed to the general public and thus was followed by even more vigorous nominal wage rises in early 1974. 9 6 Spahn Figure 2: Interest rates, growth, investment, unemployment and inflation in Germany. (a) call money rate 16 12 bond rate 8 4 0 60:1 real call money rate 65:1 70:1 75:1 80:1 business cycle low 700 real GDP growth (right scale) 600 85:1 90:1 95:1 month private real gross investment (DM bill., left scale) (b) 10 8 6 500 4 400 2 300 0 200 1960 -2 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 (c) 12 unemployment 9 6 inflation 3 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Data source: Bundesbank, German Council of Economic Advisers. Disinflation and unemployment 7 Table: Employment losses in disinflation period in the 1980s and 1990s. Periods are defined by the maximum and minimum of the rate of inflation. The employment loss is the sum of annual additional percentage points of unemployment compared to the unemployment rate u at the beginning of the disinflation period. In order to take into account the lag between quantity and price movements in many cases the series p$ i have been compared to the series ui -1 . Data source: German Council of Economic Advisers, OECD Economic Outlook. rank country period disinflation D= p$ max - p$ min 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. Portugal Finland Switzerland Sweden Norway Japan Italy France Denmark Austria USA Canada Greece Belgium Ireland Germany UK Netherlands Spain employment loss L= ∑ sacrifice ratio /u − u 4 L D i 1984-88 1981-86 1981-86 1980-86 1981-85 1980-88 1980-87 1980-86 1981-86 1981-87 1980-86 1981-85 1981-84 1981-86 1981-87 1981-86 1980-87 1980-87 1980-88 18,6 8,6 6,4 9,8 7,5 7,6 15,5 10,6 9,1 6,5 8,4 7,5 4,6 7,9 17,0 6,9 12,0 7,2 11,5 1,4 2,4 2,5 4,1 4,5 4,7 14,7 14,4 13,5 9,9 14,0 14,1 9,2 17,1 41,8 19,5 40,1 37,2 74,7 0,1 0,3 0,4 0,4 0,6 0,6 0,9 1,4 1,5 1,5 1,7 1,9 2,0 2,2 2,5 2,8 3,3 5,2 6,5 average 9,6 17,9 1,9 8 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. Spahn Netherlands Greece Portugal Ireland Japan Norway UK Denmark USA Canada Italy Switzerland Austria Germany Sweden Belgium France Spain Finland 1991-95 1990-94 1990-96 1989-93 1991-95 1990-94 1991-94 1989-93 1990-96 1991-94 1991-96 1991-96 1992-96 1992-96 1991-96 1990-95 1989-95 1989-96 1990-95 2,3 8,9 10,1 1,7 3,0 3,4 4,9 3,3 3,2 4,1 2,9 4,7 1,8 3,3 8,7 2,0 1,8 3,1 4,7 -1,8 4,8 6,5 1,3 2,3 3,0 8,6 5,9 6,3 8,5 6,4 14,2 5,5 10,5 28,7 6,7 8,0 22,6 42,6 -0,8 0,5 0,6 0,7 0,8 0,9 1,8 1,8 2,0 2,1 2,2 3,0 3,1 3,2 3,3 3,4 4,4 7,3 9,1 average 4,1 10,0 2,4 Figure 3: Evaluation of the preceding table. Ranking of countries according to average sacrifice ratios. 9 8 Sacrifice ratios in selected countries and disinflation periods 1980s 1990s 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 SPA FIN FRG FRA BEL UK AUT NLD CAN SWE USA CH DMK IRL ITA GRC NOR JAP POR -1 Disinflation and unemployment 9 cause the expectation of long term price stability expands the duration of nominal contracts thereby flattening out the Phillips curve10; a cut in nonminal money growth thus turns into a real contraction because of wage and price inertia.11 But the logic of the argument is questionable: the very reason that induces long contracts when inflation is low ought to shorten them when everyone expects a restrictive policy change in times of high inflation. In the following the credibility of anti-inflation policies is taken for granted. The aim is to look for other causes of emerging and sustained unemployment in a period of disinflation.12 These causes will be grouped under three headings: microeconomic impediments to wage and price flexibility; macroeconomic interplay between disinflation, profit expectations and effective demand; and supply-side reactions to lower demand. 4. Towards an explanation of disinflation costs 4.1 Sticky nominal market claims It has been recognised since many years that the stickiness of nominal wages and prices serves important microeconomic purposes, namely to enhance fairness and efficiency in the organisation of the process of production and to stabilise "optimal" market positions of firms.13 In the case of a policy shift towards lower inflation some additional aspects have to be taken into account. The usual assumption in new classical models that the rate of inflation can be taken as an instrument variable of the central bank conceals an analytical flaw in the argument that a credible disinflation policy would entail no output losses. If really p$ = m$ , the lower rate of inflation appears as new macroeconomic "fact" which leaves all market agents with the obligation of adjustment of individual market claims. However, the empirical evidence of a one or two years' lag between a change in the growth path of money and a change in the rate of inflation (and a more careful modelling of the economy) helps market agents to learn that inflation only comes down as an aggregate result of their own individual pricing behaviour. As seen from the 10 An almost vertical slope of the Phillips curve in the range of high rates of inflation can ease monetary stabilisation because money then may have already begun to lose its functions and the spread of nominally fixed contracts will have decreased; this makes possible a more rapid wage adjustment. This phenomenon is well known from the study of hyperinflations (cf. Dornbusch et al. 1990). 11 "Countries with highly independent central banks seem to face the largest real costs of inflation reduction" (Walsh 1995, 25; cf. Jordan 1997). 12 Some common knowledge on disinflation is provided by Fischer (1985) or Ball (1995). 13 For a survey see e.g. Romer (1993). 10 Spahn point of view of the unions, a lower rate of inflation cannot be assessed as a "gift" provided by the central bank which in turn − as a matter of fairness − should be "honoured" by the diminishing of wage claims; on the contrary, it is just this reduction of wage claims which brings about a change in the path of prices. The necessary reduction of wage claims cannot be taken for granted as a straightforward implication of rational expectations. Rather, it seems reasonable to assume that wage claims only will be reduced by the experience of market pressure. Furthermore, the incentives and motives governing the market decisions of individuals and groups might work in an asymmetric way with respect to changes in the state of demand. Because the general principle of economic behaviour favours to demand prices as high as possible − claims which then are corrected by market forces, i.e. by the opposite trader − we should expect that improved economic prospects more easily lead to rising prices compared to a more sluggish response in cases of economic decline. As a consequence, an expected rise in the rate of inflation most probably will bring about a more or less immediate reaction of rising wage claims whereas in the case of an announced disinflation workers may try to defend the expected rise of their real wage. Three reasons can cause a delay of downward wage adjustments: • As unions and workers in general are concerned about their relative position in the field of wage income distribution each of them maybe would accept a proportionate real wage cut by means of a higher price level, but would hesitate to be the first who voluntarily cuts his or her wage claims. • Outside the hypothetical world of a one-good model the policy-induced demand restriction will have a distinct and unknown impact in different sectors of the economy. Therefore it seems reasonable to wait whether and to what extent workers should respond by wage moderation to a sectorspecific loss of demand. • If already unemployment has emerged in some locations the market power of labour market "insiders" might prevent a sufficient amount of wage restraint to develop so that an endogenous stabilisation is precluded. 4.2 Macroeconomic dynamic instability Modern macroeconomic theory highlights the role of inflationary expectations and its impact on wage formation and endogenous stabilisation via the real balance effect. The simple solution of equations (1) and (2) yields the result that income growth y$ depends with a negative sign on the expected rate Disinflation and unemployment 11 of inflation p$ e . This approach however confines the importance of price expectations on its impact on wage formation and neglects possible other transmission channels. A different perspective unfolds if the effect of disinflation on asset markets, and investment decisions in particular, is analysed. The demand side of an IS-LM model is captured by / 4 1 6'J J( i = i − p JJ M = P L/ Y , i 4 ) Y = C Y + I re , ir e r 1 Y = Y M P , r e , p e ⇒ 6 (3) where all symbols have the standard definitions and r e denotes the expected rate of return of investment ("marginal efficiency of capital"). Approximating (3) by using growth rates yields / 4 1 y = α m − p + β dr e + dp e 6 (4) The growth of demand thus depends, firstly, on the change of real balances; but it becomes apparent that the expansive effect of disinflation may be neutralised by changes of profit and inflation expectations. The crucial aspect is the different sign of inflation and the expected change of inflation. Thus the macroeconomic consequences of credible anti-inflation policies are ambiguous as expected disinflation lowers productions costs via wage moderation, but at the same time lowers investment by increasing the real rate of interest. One of the typical features of such a market constellation is the weakening of the links between earned profits and profit expectations. Given unemployment real wages then might fall to meet the labour supply curve and yet extra profits per unit employment − measured as the difference between marginal productivity of labour and the real wage − will not induce additional investment which is necessary for increasing the level of employment. A more fundamental problem is the threat of an instable adjustment process. This can be studied by interpreting (4) as a full employment condition where y$ = y$ * . In figure 4 equation (4) represents a positively sloped line YY because the restrictive real balance effect of a higher rate of inflation (given the rate of money growth) can be compensated by a positive change in the expected rate of inflation which lowers the real rate of interest.14 Starting from A a restrictive demand shock, e.g. by reducing m$ causes the full employment line to shift downwards to Y'Y'. Full employment then can be maintained by an expected increase of the rate of inflation (B) or by a lower effective rate (C). The first option can be ruled out right away as it lacks a solid economic rationale. An instantaneous jump to C seems to be 14 The diagram is a simplified version of the one given by Tobin (1993); see also Tobin (1975). 12 Spahn implausible because of the reasons given in the preceding sections. Thus we are left with a gradual process of disinflation accompanied by a change of the expected rate of inflation. Stability rests on the relative speed of both movements: Figure 4: Adjustment processes with flexible prices and inflation expectations p$ Y Y' A B (a) Y (b) C Y' dp$ e (a) If the decrease of dp$ e is very large compared to the reduction of p$ investment-driven demand continues to shrink; therefore a stabilisation by expansive policy measures is required. (b) If on the other hand actual disinflation is faster than the expected reduction of inflation the process will meet the full employment line. Below Y'Y' prices and inflation expectations would rise again until a stable equilibrium is reached in C. The instability problem is intensified if the expected rate of return r e depends positively on the expected rate of inflation. Such an assumption can be justified if there is some lag between price and wage movements. In times of inflationary expectations the propensity to invest furthermore might be strengthened in case of an imperfect adjustment of the long term nominal interest rate when debtors are favoured compared to creditors. If dr e dp$ e > 0 each percentage point of expected inflation encourages investment not only by lowering the real rate of interest but also by supporting the marginal efficiency of capital. Therefore a larger increase of the actual rate of inflation is necessary to stabilise demand. The slopes of the goods market equilibrium lines YY and Y'Y' then are steeper (figure 4). As a consequence, if applied to a Disinflation and unemployment 13 disinflation scenario, a formerly stable adjustment path, e.g. arrow (b), now might lead to cumulative instability. Flexible wages and prices thus do not guarantee the stability of a full employment equilibrium. The Great Depression of the early 1930s has been intensified by means of an excess, not of a lack of flexibility. Wide-spread nominal wage rigidity after the demise of the gold standard may be interpreted as an outcome of increased union power heading for distribution goals; by their resistance against nominal wage cuts workers demonstrate to be − as Keynes argued − "instinctively more reasonable economists than the classical school"15 because such a behaviour enhances macroeconomic stability. Wage rigidity therefore is far from constituting a market failure but rather represents an answer to an existing systemic instability in a monetary economy.16 The factual relevance of the threat of macroeconomic instability because of nominal wage and price flexibility today is controversial. Even Post Keynesians assessed it to be of minor importance in the early 1980s as the large share of nominal fixed expenditure, credit-financed budget deficits, built-in stabilisers and expansive social policy programs would support consumption, prices and profits thereby excluding the possible outbreak of true deflation.17 At the same time the institutional design of wage contracts seemed to implement a solid base line for the national price level. In the mid 1990s because of fiscal consolidation, deregulation and the dwindling of the unions' market power things look different. After fighting inflation for more than two decades it seems that central banks now have to keep an eye on the risk of deflation as well. The next section however provides some theoretical evidence that even a persistent abundance of labour may not lead to a corresponding wage deflation. 4.3 Supply-side effects and hysteresis The basic result so far is that a restrictive monetary policy cannot avoid a real negative demand shock to occur: A lowering of m$ in equation (4) can only be neutralised by an immediate reduction of p$ ; this variable however according to (1) depends on inflation expectations and excess demand mar- 15 Keynes 1936, 14. "Maybe the social institutions, attitudes, and behavior patterns that make for wage and price stickiness in real life should be seen in part as adaptive mechanisms, and not merely as obstacles to the achievement of a frictionless economy. If the observed or imagined consequences of perfect wage-price-flexibility are damaging, then institutions that resist wage-price-flexibility might evolve. (...) Wage stickiness could then emerge as a form of self-defense" (Hahn/Solow 1995, 134). 17 Cf. Minsky 1982. 16 14 Spahn ket pressure. If market agents recognise that inflation is not determined by monetary policy directly, but rather as the aggregate outcome of individual wage and price setting, it seems unconvincing to argue that inflation expectations will go down in the first place. Therefore market pressure, i.e. excess supply on the goods and labour markets finally has to carry out the task of bringing down the rate of inflation. Excess capacity and labour hoarding characterise only the onset of an economic crisis. The crucial feature of a recession however is not the excess but rather the reduction of supply.18 If then the demand for the factors of production is being reduced some medium and long term deterioration of the productive endowment of the economy is bound to happen. The postponement or cancellation of investment stops the growth of the capital stock which implies that the future growth path will be located lower. The consequence is a more narrow constraint for the development of productivity, output and employment.19 The reduction of labour demand can take the form of short-time work or of layoffs. The first alternative seems to be an obvious solution as the problem is an abundance of labour input measured in working hours. If instead we assume that due to some organisational rigidities full-time work is required layoffs cannot be avoided. But how does the entrepreneur decide who is going to be dismissed? In macroeconomic theory labour in general is taken to be an homogenous entity. If all workers were alike the entrepreneur might through a dice. Because this is not observed on a large scale two conclusions might be drawn: • Entrepreneurs suppose that their workers have a different qualification and productivity. • This profile of the employed workforce is not mirrored by a corresponding wage structure.20 Otherwise the decision as to whom to dismiss again could be solved by a lottery because the firm could not gain by firing a "bad" worker. Employment decisions and wage contracts then might be modelled according to a simple scheme where workers are ordered following their individual productivity q which − by taking into account given output prices P and the mark-up on wage costs k − determines the value productivity line X (figure 5). Whereas employment N d Y is given by goods demand and the production function the contract wage w has to equilibrate nominal wage costs and average nominal productivity (so that the shaded triangles are of equal size); /4 18 Cf. Greenwald/Stiglitz 1993. Cf. Bean 1989. 20 Explanations for this wide-spread fact can easily be found in the efficiency-wage and fairness literature. 19 Disinflation and unemployment 15 note that a conjecture on output and prices is necessary to agree on some w .21 If output and employment are increased during the contract period prices have to rise because of rising marginal costs.22 An increase of nominal wages would be passed on to the goods market by raising P. If labour demand drops from N1 to N0 the entrepreneur will dismiss those workers with the lowest productivity.23 Profit per unit of employment then is increased as average productivity is higher. If at the same time output prices decrease X shifts downwards; then the profit effect is absent but real wages rise. Only in case of a large decrease of prices wages have to be lowered to maintain normal profits. Figure 5: Wages and employment in case of heterogeneous workers /4 w Nd Y w X= N0 N1 Pq 1+ k N The crucial point is that the explanation of unemployment needs giving up the assumption of homogeneous labour. This sheds light on the state of competition on the labour market, in particular in post-crisis times. The unemployed are unable to compete with the active workforce at given wages because their very status of being unemployed reveals their inferior qualification − if each entrepreneur expects that all his colleagues behave like he 21 Obviously the firm might be tempted to capture a higher rent by dismissing some of the "worst" workers. But then it would run the risk of losing some of its market share; and most probably workers will urge for a new negotiation aiming to raise w . 22 This has been Keynes' (1936, 41, 295) argument for the necessity of a decreasing real wage when employment would rise whereas neoclassical economics usually base rising marginal costs on an over-utilised given capital stock. 23 Legal and other regulations restricting the choice of the persons to be fired are neglected. 16 Spahn does himself. The occurrence of unemployment causes a segmentation in the labour market. The "qualification boundary" between the employed workforce and the unemployed is microeconomic in substance, but is drawn as an endogenous variable in the macroeconomic process. The welfare costs of existing shortcomings of qualification and productivity at the lower end of the ranked workforce are shared by all workers (by earning a lower real wage) in the case of full employment; after a restructuring of firms which use the enforced cut of their workforce for enhancing efficiency these costs are born by the unemployed only, namely in form of a reduced opportunity of finding a job. Of course they might become re-employed in case of an exogenous rise of demand. But otherwise firms hardly have an incentive to hire unemployed workers as substitutes for employed "insiders" even if the former claim a lower wage. The achievement of a higher average productivity for the firm offers better prospects than the alternative strategy of running a low-quality production at low wages. The labour market segmentation will be intensified by additional forces: • As a recession typically is accompanied by a faster rate of structural change the human capital of unemployed persons being fired in shrinking branches is further devalued. • As individual unemployment protracts qualification decays because of being separated from the steady process of learning on the job. The dilemma becomes nearly perfect as the entrepreneurs in turn use the individual duration of unemployment as a screening device for assessing the expected productivity of applicants.24 The upshot of all this is that the endogenous loss of marketability of dismissed workers amounts to a transformation from cyclical, demand-determined to structural unemployment. It implies that the effective labour curve shifts inwards following an unemployment shock which in turn weakens the response of wages to unemployment and finally blocks the road for the real balance effect. The more fundamental result is that the equilibrium level of full employment is lower: the market process exhibits hysteresis as the equilibrium position of the NAIRU depends on the history of employment variations. In Germany, the NAIRU seemed to have increased after each recession (figure 6). The supply-side endowment of an economy cannot be unambiguously defined without taking into account the state and the path of effective demand. It seems quite obvious that in such an economic system monetary policy cannot be neutral.25 24 Cf. Nickell 1988, Pissarides 1992. The NAIRU looses its information function for deciding on the stance of macro policies (cf. Galbraith 1997). 25 Disinflation and unemployment 17 Figure 6: Increase of the German NAIRU in the recessions 1973-75, 1980-83, 1992-94 2,5 increase of inflation '71 '89 '79 1,5 unemployment 0,5 -0,5 -1,5 '76 '67 '83 '94 -2,5 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 Data source: as in figure 2. 5. The recovery from recession: The role of monetary policy The pattern of monetary policy during disinflation periods − at least in Germany − has changed over the decades (figure 2 a). Comparing the path of short term interest rates around business cycles' lows at 1967, 1975, 1982 and 1993 it is apparent that the Bundesbank shaped a more cautious trend of monetary relaxation especially in the last years. The impression that the "natural" decrease of interest rates in a recession deliberately has been slowed down is confirmed by the Bundesbank which is proud to have corrected "exaggerated" market expectations of interest rate reductions by means of controlling the terms at which refinancing transactions with the private banking systems are carried out.26 Two possible justifications for retarding the interest rate slow down may be given. • A temporary overshooting of money supply figures compared to the announced growth targets caused a credibility problem in the field of implementation of monetary policy; the Bundesbank maybe felt obliged to signal to the private sector that the path of intermediate monetary targets is taken serious and has some repercussions on the decisions on changing short term interest rates. However, in some cases the Bundesbank preferred to play down the significance of actual money growth and argued 26 Deutsche Bundesbank 1994, 67, 72. 18 Spahn that the gains of overall stabilisation allowed some further monetary ease.27 • Nevertheless, in assessing the general tendency of policy decisions, an observer might conclude that the Bundesbank chose a more cautious policy of monetary expansion because of the assumption that inflationary expectations are still vivid. As market estimates and conjectures in the private sector during the business cycle phase of disinflation may be contradictory the central bank has to pursue the difficult task of supporting the investment-driven process of income creation without rekindling inflationary expectations. In this context the step-wise course of interest rate reduction has been founded on the argument that financial markets after each step still could and should expect a further cut which ought to keep alive the tendency of declining long term interest rates; a step assessed to be the "final" one however would already work on the capital market like the first move towards monetary restriction.28 On the other hand, because inflationary expectations as such are hard to measure interest rate policies at times seem to be executed by keeping an eye on actual inflation. The problem is that by orientating monetary policy by a "lagging" indicator like the rate of inflation the central bank aggravates macroeconomic disturbances and causes an unnecessary delay in the process of economic recovery.29 In any case this is the general effect of an artificially slow process of interest rate reductions. If there is some flexibility as to the urgency of investment projects, the expectation of a further decrease of interest rates may lead to a temporary postponement of investment. The central bank and the entrepreneurs thus can be modelled in a non-cooperative negative-sum game30: Both players prefer an economic upswing, but the central bank fears to revive inflation and the firms are able to wait for more profitable financing conditions. If both parties wait too long the weakness of demand may worsen the general prospects of economic development so that even further interest rates reductions then cannot neutralise deteriorated profit expectations. Therefore the final question is whether the Bundesbank did not overrate the risk of inflation in the last years. On the one hand, given the tendencies of hysteresis one has to concede that an increase of goods and labour demand may lead to rising wage claims long before statistical full employment is reached.31 On the other hand, excess capacities, opening trade relations, 27 28 29 30 31 Deutsche Bundesbank 1996, 19. Sievert 1995, 5. Krupp/Cabos 1996. Caplin/Leahy 1996. Cf. Lindbeck/Snower 1988, Blanchard 1991. Disinflation and unemployment 19 technical progress and the increasing opportunities for firms to use the 32 world excess labour supply work as dampening factors with respect to wage and price inflation. Figure 7 reveals that the Bundesbank may act overly sensitive to the inflation risk if compared to other hard currency countries. The conclusion might be drawn that a more rapid process of interest rate reduction might have been appropriate which most probably would not have had any negative consequences with respect to the desired monetary stabilisation. Possibly the stance of the Bundesbank's monetary policy in the mid 1990s thus cannot be explained by referring to the inflation-disinflation issue alone but also by taking into account the bank's role in the field of European currency policies, a topic which is beyond the purpose of this paper. Figure 7: Monthly and annual rates of interest, nominal and real, respectively, in selected countries. 10 call money rates 8 real call money rates 7 5 6 3 4 1 2 0 92:1 -1 94:1 1990 96:1 FRG 1992 98:1 NLD 1994 1990 1996 1992 CH 1994 1996 JAP Data source: Bundesbank, German Council of Economic Advisers, OECD Economic Outlook. 6. Summary and conclusions The new classical hypothesis of neutral money is being derived from a model which captures the role of institutions and economic policy preferences, but which is inappropriate to grasp the complexity of micro-macro market inter32 Cf. Krugman 1995, Freeman 1995. 20 Spahn action. The simple logic of costless disinflation is displayed in the shaded area of figure 8. Only by affecting the expected rate of inflation the central bank has a direct influence on the process of wage and price formation. In case of success the policy-induced monetary restriction is being neutralised so that real money balances remain constant. Accordingly, a lack of credibility on the part of the central bank's policy course appears to be the most important cause of non-neutrality. If however even the high reputation of the Bundesbank does not help to keep unemployment low in periods of disinflation at least some additional problems have to be taken into account. From a microeconomic point of view rational wage and price setters will recognise that a desired lower rate of inflation is not "given" by the decision of the central bank (as suggested by simple new classical models) but rather is the aggregate outcome of their own market behaviour. A lowering of wage and price claims therefore has to be enforced by experienced or expected market pressure. Given the doubt that the central bank can succeed in bringing about an immediate reduction of the rate of inflation various microeconomic efficient rigidities, including the struggle for relative income positions and the lack of knowledge about the impact of expected general decrease of demand in different sectors and branches of the economy, will cause a delayed and staggered adjustment of individual market claims. Figure 8: Market mechanisms (bold arrows) thwarting a neutrality of monetary policy during disinflation. Restrictive monetary policy Reduced expected inflation Real money Wages Prices Rational rigidities Unemployment Goods demand Capital stock Labour demand Real wage Marketable labour suppy Disinflation and unemployment 21 As real money balances therefore are decreasing the economy will be set on a path of recession accompanied by a continuous, but not simultaneous process of actual and expected disinflation, deteriorating profit expectations and rising unemployment. At the same time realised profits may nevertheless rise but do not encourage investment as the prospects of further development of demand are vague. The crucial analytical point is that actual and expected reductions of the rate of inflation have an opposite impact on effective demand. Whereas in the theoretical model this scenario may lead to cumulative instability in practise a probable outcome is a prolongation of recession or an only weak recovery. If then recovery is delayed supply-side reactions may take effect. The (growth of the) capital stock is lower and the effective labour supply to some extent adjusts to the size of the employed workforce. Decay and obsolescence of non-used factors of production more generally indicate that the amount and quality of resources in monetary economies in the long run are governed by demand-side forces. The macroeconomic consequence in any case is that the real balance effect as an endogenously stabilising mechanism is weakened and that supply-side constraints to a future demand expansion will be felt earlier. The attitude of monetary policy (at least) in Germany to control the interest rate slow down in order to prevent the revival of inflation thus seems to be an ambiguous strategy. Unused capacities and unemployment in the depth of a recession would reduce the rate of inflation anyway; the downward stickiness of short term interest rates however tends to postpone the recovery and to restrain the scope of future growth. The general message is that institutional reforms apt to strengthen credibility and reputation of monetary institutions will not necessarily lower the costs of future disinflation policies. There is no reason to believe that this will not hold true in the European Monetary Union. References Akerlof, G. A. et al. (1996): The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation, in: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1-76. Ball, L. (1995): Disinflation with Imperfect Credibility, in: Journal of Monetary Economics, 35, 5-23. Bean, C. (1989): Capital Shortages and Persistent Unemployment, in: Economic Policy, 8, 11-53. Bernanke, B. S., Blinder, A. S. (1992): The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission, in: American Economic Review, 82, 901-921. Blanchard, O. J. (1991): Wage Bargaining and Unemployment Persistence, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 23, 277-292. Blinder, A. S. (1987): Keynes, Lucas, and Scientific Progress, in: American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 77, 130-136. 22 Spahn Caplin, A., Leahy, J. (1996): Monetary Policy as a Process of Search, in: American Economic Review, 86, 689-702. Deutsche Bundesbank (1994): Die Geldmarktsteuerung der Deutschen Bundesbank, in: Monatsbericht Mai, 61-75. Deutsche Bundesbank (1996): Senkung des Diskont- und Lombardsatzes, in: Monatsbericht Mai, 19-24. Dornbusch, R. et al. (1990): Extreme Inflation − Dynamics and Stabilization, in: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1-64. Filc, W. (1992): Monetäre Fundierung einer angebotsorientierten Stabilitätspolitik, in: Konjunkturpolitik, 38, 316-339. Fischer, S. (1985): The Problem of Disinflation, in: Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, 105, 123-131. Freeman, R. B. (1995): Are Your Wages Set in Beijing? In: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, 3, 15-32. Galbraith, J. K. (1997): Time to Ditch the NAIRU, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 1, 93-108. Greenwald, B., Stiglitz, J. (1993): New and Old Keynesians, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 1, 23-44. Hahn, F. H. (1982): Money and Inflation. Oxford. Hahn, F. H., Solow, R. M. (1995): A Critical Essay on Modern Macroeconomic Theory. Oxford. Jordan, T. J. (1997): Disinflation Costs, Accelerating Inflation Gains, and Central Bank Independence, in: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 133, 1-21. Keynes, J. M. (1930): A Treatise on Money, Vol. 1: The Pure Theory of Money. Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 5, London / Basingstoke 1971. Keynes, J. M. (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 7, London / Basingstoke 1973. Krugman, P. (1995): Growing World Trade − Causes and Consequences, in: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 327-377. Krupp, H. J., Cabos, K. (1996): Geldpolitik und Beschäftigung. In: Gahlen, B. et al. (Eds.): Arbeitslosigkeit und Möglichkeiten ihrer Überwindung. Tübingen, 363387. Lindbeck, A., Snower, D. J. (1988): Long-Term Unemployment and Macroeconomic Policy, in: American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 78, 38-43. Lucas, R. E. (1996): Nobel Lecture − Monetary Neutrality, in: Journal of Political Economy, 104, 661-682. Minsky, H. P. (1982): Debt Deflation Processes in Today's Institutional Environment, in: Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, Quarterly Review, 35, 375-393. Moersch, M. (1996): Interest Rates or Spreads as Predictors of Real Economic Activity? In: Konjunkturpolitik, 42, 40-51. Nickell, S. (1988): Why Is Wage Inflation in Britain So High? In: Cross, R. (Ed.): Unemployment, Hysteresis and the Natural Rate Hypothesis. Oxford, 256-283. Niehans, J. (1987): Classical Monetary Theory − New and Old, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. 19, 409-424. Perry, G. L., Schultze, C. L. (1993): Was This Recession Different? Are They All Different? In: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 145-211. Pissarides, C. A. (1992): Loss of Skill During Unemployment and the Persistence of Employment Shocks, in: Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 1371-1391. Ragnitz, J. (1994): Zinsstruktur und Wirtschaftswachstum, in: Kredit und Kapital, 27, 11-29. Romer, C. D. (1993): The New Keynesian Synthesis, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 1, 5-22. Disinflation and unemployment 23 Sievert, O. (1995): Grundzüge der Bundesbankpolitik − Wirtschaftsentwicklung in den neuen Bundesländern, in: Deutsche Bundesbank (Ed.): Auszüge aus Presseartikeln, No. 24, 28.3.95, 3-9. Taylor, J. B. (1995): The Monetary Transmission Mechanism − An Empirical Framework, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, 4, 11-26. Walsh, C. E. (1995): Central Bank Independence and the Short-Run OutputInflation Trade-off in the European Community, in: Eichengreen, B. et al. (Eds.): Monetary and Fiscal Policy in an Integrated Europe. Berlin et al., 12-37. Tobin, J. (1975): Keynesian Models of Recession and Depression, in: American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 65, 195-202. Tobin, J. (1993): Price Flexibility and Output Stability − An Old Keynesian View, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 1, 45-65.