PERCEPTIONS OF RISK DISTRIBUTION IN CONSTRUCTION CONTRACTS Anita M.M. Liu, City Polytechnic of Hong Kong S.O. Cheung, University of New South Wales, Australia KEYWORDS Risk distribution, perception, standard forms of contract Summarv Risk has different meanings to different individuals. Since the construction industry has always been described as having a high risk nature, how risks can be shared and thus properly managed among the parties is a major concern. Standard forms of building contracts are therefore drafted in response to the needs and practices of the industry. They then form the basis for identifying and allocating risks and uncertainties associated with the construction works. By widespread use of the standard forms, the distributions of risks are well-known to the parties, yet the frequent occurrence of amendments has often altered this distribution pattern. This paper will study the risk distribution in the Australian Standard General Conditions of Contract AS2 1241992, and compare it with the standard form (HKIA/RICS 1976) used in Hong Kong. A survey will be carried out in Australia to examine the project participants' identification of major risk items and their views on the distribution of these risks. Their perceptions will be compared with a similar study of their counterparts in Hong Kong. Contract Systems Traditional discrete economic transaction favours 'sharp in by clear agreement, sharp out by clear performance' (Macneil 1974), but many contractual relations are not of this well-defined kind, hence, planning contractual transactions and relations becomes essential. According to Macneil (1975), two processes are essential to contract planning, namely, defining goals (along with related costs of their attainment) and communications. The perfect contract is, quite often referred to, one that anticipates and disposes of all possible hture problems and questions. Perfection, however, is rare if not at all impossible to attain and, since like any other human activity, engaging in contractual behaviour involves risks of loss, risk planning in contracts is therefore an important issue. The concept of risk is a recognition that human beings are in a constant state of partial ignorance about the future, including future losses. Risk is reduced whenever man acquires more certain knowledge about the occurrence or non-occurrence of future losses. Risk planning in connection with contracts is actually one facet of risk management in the economic world. However, no contract can ever be fully planned and this is particularly hue of the risk aspects of the contract. Risk and uncertainty are different. Risk is where the outcome of an event, or each of a set of possible outcomes, can be predicted on the basis of statistical probability. Other events have outcomes which are uncertain, they cannot be predicted via statistical probability and the probability of their occurrence is random. It is common for risk (and uncertainty ) to be considered as only negative, i.e. the risk of making a loss or of not realising the forecast profit. The degree of riskiness varies with the complexity, size, and duration of the contract. Contractual provisions distribute risks between the parties who, in turn, seek compensation, usually financial, for the risks which they assume. The application of risk management provides explicit recognition of the risks which parties to a building project are required to take in terms of what the risks are and their sizes. The pattern of risk distribution is a major influence on project price, and in extreme cases, the distribution of risks can result in a party withdrawing from the proposed scheme. Hence, a study of project participants' perceived risk distribution patterns will be useful. Classifications of risk are plenty (Greene and Serbein 1983, Grose 1987, Moore 1983, Doherty 1985) and include pure, speculative, static, dynamic, and inherent risks. These risks may not all be handled in terms of explicit allocation to the parties through contract planning, nevertheless, the standard forms of contract do address most of these risks. Under the neo-classical contracting system (Williamson 1986 classified contracting systems into three categories, neo-classical contracting system is the one that provides 'gaps' and 'flexibility' for the contracting parties such as provision of arbitration clauses rather than straight litigation; the other two contracting systems being the classical system and the relational system). Risk planning plays the role of handling 'gaps' and offering 'flexibility' in the contract . Indemnity clauses and variation clauses are examples of the provision of this 'flexibility'. The 'gaps' and 'flexibility' (Williamson 1986) allowed in contract planning include: 1. Third-party assistance - arbitrator I mediator I adjudicator This is used in resolving disputes and one important purposive difference in arbitration and litigation that contributes to the procedural differences is that, whereas continuity (at least completion of the contract) is presumed under the arbitration machinery, this presumption is much weaker when litigation is employed. 2. Third-party assistance - architect I engineer I quantity surveyor A third party consultant is employed to evaluate performance and acts as a relatively independent expert to determine the content of construction contracts. 3. One party control of terms The contract may provide that one of the parties to the contract will define, directly or indirectly, parts of the relation. (This may go so far as to allow one party the free will to terminate the contract relation). One important point to note is that whenever a party is not clearly paying for the privilege of retaining a free will not to perform his own contractual 'obligations', the danger is that the consideration doctrine may make the party's 'rights' unenforceable. 4. Use of standards An example is the fluctuation clauses in standard forms of building contract where a certain published price index is referred to. Risk Distribution Various practitioners and researchers alike have written extensively on the allocation principles of risk sharing. Some suggested guidelines as the criteria for sharing the project risks are as follows: 1. All risks are rightfully the owners unless transferred to or assumed by another party for a fair compensation, when the risk is so transferred, consider whether the receiving party has both the competence to fairly assess the risk and the expertise necessary to control or minimise it (Casey 1979), 2. if a risk is imposed upon a party, an opportunity for reward to the party should exist for properly dealing with the risk (Nadel 1979), 3. a risk should be allocated to the party which is in the best position to control it and to undertake it financially (Nadel 1979), 4. steps should be taken to assure that risks are actually allocated as intended (Nadel 1979) Risk distribution reasoning of this kind was implicitly approved by the House of Lords in Photo Production v. Securicor Transport 1980 (Furmston 1986) in Lord Diplock's statement, "it is generally more economical for the person by whom the loss will be directly sustained to do so rather than it should be covered by the other party by liability insurance". The framework for studying the risk distribution pattern in the standard forms of contract, Australian ~ ~ 2 1 2 4and ' Hong Kong HKIAIRICS~, is as follows: Australian Standard 8 General conditions of contract (AS 2124-1992) with General conditions of tendering andform of tender AS 2125-1992, and Form offormal instrument of agreement AS 2127-1992, Standards Australia, 1992. Agreement and Schedule of Conditions of Building Contract (Standard Form of Building Contract) for use in Hong Kong, Private Edition with Quantities, Second Edition 1976 (May 1979 Revision), Hong Kong Institute of Architects, Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors (Hong Kong Branch), 1979 PHYSICAL RISK AS2124 clause nos. 27 12 35.5 NSP 40 NSP Site access Latent conditions Weather Acts of God Quantity variations FINANCIAL RISK Rise and Fail Funding - PERFORMANCE RISK Nominated Sub-contractors' failure Defective work 1 Accidents Managerial competence Labour, materials, equipment Acceleration and Suspension Time for completion Third party delay Adiacent ~ r o ~ e r~rotection tv LEGALPOLITICAL RISK Regulations Public disorder NSP = No specific provision HKIAIRICS clause nos. 21,23,24 NSP 23 20 11, 12 (2) 36 1 42.44.43 . 1 26.30 9.3, 10, 43, 27,17,30,23 35.5 2, 31, 42.2, 23, 1, 6, 15, 30 30 NSP NSP NSP NSP 29 1, 6, 14 33,34,35 2 1,23,24,26 1 33.35 21.23 135 23,24 1 16. 17 1 18. 19 14 4 , 1 1 NSP 23,26 Fig. 1 Provisions in Standard Forms Certain risk items listed above are not being explicitly dealt with under contract planning of the standard forms. In particular, 'accidents' and 'managerial competence' (whether that of the employer, contractor, or subcontractors) are thought of as inherent in business efficacy. The contract provisions tackle some of the consequences of these two items, for example, accidents are dealt with under indemnity and insurance clauses, and consequences of managerial competence (or incompetence) are dealt with under defective work, delay, suspension, payment, determination and removal of personnel from site. Risk Perceptions Individuals are known to perceive risks differently. The difference in the individuals' perceptual/judgmental process is well explained in the literature of organisational behaviour and 110 (industriallorganisational) psychology (Tversky 1967, 1972, Naylor et a1 1980, Locke and Latham 1990). A preliminary research was conducted to investigate the major perceived risk factors (under the risk distribution framework described previously) by various practitioners in both the Hong Kong and the Australian construction industries. 40 and 20 returned questionnaire were collected in Hong Kong and Sydney respectively. This pilot test was administered to part-time post-graduate students who were working in the construction industry. The questionnaire is in two parts, the first part is to elicit the perceived major risks by asking the respondents to insert 1 (least important) to 5 (very important) against each of the risk items, the second part is to elicit the preferred risk distribution pattern by indicating whether 'employer-biased', 'equally shared' or 'contractorbiased', ie. the respondent is asked to indicate against each risk item whether hislher preference is to allocate the particular risk to the employer (employer-biased), the contractor (contractor-biased) or on an equally-shared basis. The risk items for the respondents to consider are the same as those listed in Fig. 1. The findings are to be discussed according to the following: Overview of the respondents' perceptions of risk items (expressed in weighted average scores) in the two samples Major risk items (expressed in weighted average scores greater than 50%) -- comparison of the Hong Kong and Australian samples Respondents' preferred risk distribution pattern for the major risk items -- comparison of the Hong Kong and Australian samples ANOVA (Analysis of Variance) to test for null hypothesis (Ho: pl=p2) between the two samples regarding the perception of major risk items and preferred risk distribution pattern PHYSICAL RISK 1 I FINANCIAL RISK PERFORMANCE RISK I Importance 5 <--------------------5 1 HK yo Site access 18 8 Latentconditions Weather 25 I 110 Acts of God Quantity variations 5 Rise and Fall 28 8 Funding 22 NSC's failure 5 Defective work Accidents 8 Managerial 30 comDetence I Labour, materials,ll5 Adjacent property 2 protection LEGAL/ Regulations 15 POLITICAL RISK Public disorder 5 HK = Hong Kong; AU = Australia Fig. 2 4 2 3 AU 24 5 14 I 124 10 0 33 14 19 10 19 HK 15 18 28 I I8 12 22 28 25 28 18 25 AU 24 43 5 I I I I 10 29 24 24 29 29 29 24 1 HK 22 42 22 I 118 40 30 35 30 50 35 22 AU 19 24 38 I 119 24 38 19 29 38 14 33 HK AU 32 19 30 24 18 I 24 I 132 114 28 133 20129 25 10 12 24 15 14 32 33 18 10 I I I I I HK 12 2 8 I 132 15 0 5 10 2 8 5 I ( 1 9 125 ( 1 9 ( 3 8 ( 3 3 ( 2 0 ( 2 4 12 AU 14 5 19 I I43 5 10 14 5 0 14 14 Weighted average score HK AU 48 56 55 49 61 43 I 1 132 I17 41 51 64 44 63 52 59 56 63 54 46 46 64 56 I I 15 158 156 I I 1 I 5 5 24 35 29 45 29 12 14 35 44 5 10 15 8 24 10 38 30 33 14 25 35 19 43 8 22 19 24 51 34 44 35 Overview of the respondents' perception of risk items The weighted average scores expressed in percentages are calculated by allocating weights of 1, 0.75, 0.50, 0.25 and 0 to the 5-point scale in descending order. The percentage of respondents giving an answer of 5 on the 5-point scale is multiplied by 1; the percentage of those giving an answer of 4 is multiplied by 0.75 and so forth. These are then added and divided by the total percentage of respondents who actually have answered the question, ie., excluding those who have given no response to the particular question. Respondents answered all questions in both the Hong Kong and the Australian samples). A weighted average score of over 50% is taken to mean that the respondent considers the risk item as major. After the calculation of the weighted average scores, it is found that the risk items which both the Hong Kong and Australian practitioners perceive to be major are those under Performance Risk, ie., NSC failure, defective work, managerial competence, labour/materials/equipment, and time for completion. Each group of respondents (Hong Kong and Australia) has nine major risk items, however, not all nine items are common amongst the two groups and they are also ranked differently by the two groups. Of the nine items in each group, six of these are common items. They are funding, NSC failure, defective work, managerial competence, labour/material/equipment and time for completion. Five out of six of these items are under 'PerformanceRisk'. The results are shown below (fig. 3): LEGAL/ POLITICAL RISK Fig. 3 competence Labour, materials, 6 equipment 1 Time for completion 9 Regulations 58 4 56 72 51 3 61 Comparison of major risk items 'Latent conditions' is one of the major risks perceived by the Australians and their standard form has expressed provision to deal with this item. 'Latent conditions' is not explicitly dealt with under the Hong Kong standard form but there again, this is not a major risk item perceived by the Hong Kong sample. Likewise with the other item 'Rise and Fall' (price fluctuation), the Hong Kong sample perceives this as a major risk and the standard form has a fluctuation clause (optional), but the Australian standard form makes no provision for this and quite justifiably too, since this is not a major perceived risk item. Apart from 'managerial competence' (which is an inherent part of business efficacy) and the two items just mentioned, all the other risk items are explicitly dealt with in both the Hong Kong and Australian standard forms to various extent. Next, the respondents' preferred risk distribution patterns for the major risk items are compared. The risk distribution preference is again expressed as a weighted average score being calculated as previously described and shown in fig. 2. The weights being allocated to 'employer-biased', 'equally shared', and 'contractor-biased' are respectively 1 .O, 0.50 and 0. Therefore a score of over 50% indicates employer-biased distribution whereas a score below 50% indicates contractor-biased distribution. Fig. 4 shows the weighted average scores of all the responses regarding risk distribution pattern and a summary is given in Fig. 5. Note particularly in fig. 5 that the Hong Kong and Australian respondents do not disagree on the distribution patterns for all common major risk items, ie. those marked "HK and AU". They all agree that contractors should bear the performance risk and the employer should bear the funding risk. But how significant do they differ in their judgement regarding 'perceived major risk items' and 'preferred risk distribution pattern'? ANOVA is then performed on the two samples to test for the null hypothesis (Ho: p 1=p2) at a = 0.01 for all the questions. The test is conducted upon the two groups of Hong Kong contractors (a total of 17) and Australian contractors (a total of 14). The results are given below to show the significant difference in perception between these two samples of contractors: Fig. 4 Preferred risk distribution pattern MAJOR RISK ITEMS (AU = Australian sample PHYSICAL RISK FINANCIAL RISK PERFORMANCE RISK . 1 ( Site access Latent conditions Weather Quantity variations Rise and Fall Funding NSC failure Defective work Managerial competence I Labour, materials, / eaui~ment availabilitv ' Time for completion Regulations E AU IE I AU E E C C IC (C HK HK AND AU HK AND AU HK AND AU ( HK AND AU [ HK AND AU 1 1 C C HK AND AU LEGAL/ HK POLITICAL RISK Total of 6 common risk items (HK and AU), 5 of which are marked "C", ie. contractors to bear the risk. Fig. 5 Comparison of the preferred risk distribution pattern 1 1 AUSTRALIAN CONTRACTORS HONG CONTRACTORS KONG risk Rank of risk 1 Preferred risk item distribution 2 E (54%) NA C (26%) NA C (34%) NA E (66%) 8 E (54%) Rank of risk 1 Preferred distribution item 11.04 17 Rise and Fall NA E (74%) 11.3560 Site access 4 E (67%) 12.0684 Latent conditions 8 E (64%) 8.4394 Quantity variations 9 E (90%) 2 1.2043 Funding 1 E (86%) E= employer-biased; C = contractor-biased; NA = not perceived as a major risk item, ie. weighted average score <50% in Fig. 2 Fig. 6 ANOVA results -- Hong Kong vs. Australian Contractors The percentages given in brackets in Fig. 6 are the weighted average scores being calculated for risk distribution as described previously (ie., weights of 1, 0.5 and 0 being allocated to employer-biased, equally shared, and contractor-biased distribution). A score of over 50% indicates employer-biased and under 50% indicates contractor-biased. These five items shown above are perceived quite differently by the two groups. 'Rise and Fall' (fluctuation clauses) of prices are regarded as a major risk item in Hong Kong whereas it does not even come within the nine ranked major risk items in the Australian sample (see fig. 3). 'Site access', 'latent conditions' and 'quantity variations' are all perceived by the Australians as major risk items, but they in turn do not come within the nine ranked risk items in the Hong Kong sample. The preferred risk distribution patterns are significantly different too. When the mode is examined, it is found that the mode is the same for 'latent conditions' in the two samples, ie. an equally shared pattern. The rest of the above items in the two samples do not even share the same mode. In the Australian sample, the modes of the risk distribution for 'quantity variation' and 'funding' are both of the employer-biased pattern, but in the Hong Kong sample, these are both of the 'equally-shared' pattern. 'Site access' provokes two distinct views, the Australian sample favours 'employerbiased' and the Hong Kong sample favours 'contractor-biased'. Discussion Only the ANOVA results regarding the two groups of Hong Kong contractors and Australian contractors are presented above. In the Hong Kong total sample, there are three groups of project participants, 42.5% employers, 15% consultants and 42.5% contractors. ANOVA has also been performed to test for significant differences amongst the different groups of participants within both the Hong Kong and the Australian samples. In this pilot survey, it is found that the three groups of participants in the Hong Kong sample hold different views as to the risk distribution of 'Third Party Delay' and 'Time for completion'. The difference (multiple range test: Tukey-HSD test with significance level of 0.05) arises mainly from the fact that the consultants hold a different view to the employers and contractors regarding risk distribution in 'Third Party Delay'. Both the employers and contractors favour an equally-shared distribution but the consultants favour a contractor-biased pattern. As for 'Time for Completion', there is a significant difference between the employers and the contractors. The contractors favour an equally-shared pattern but the employers favour a contractor-biased pattern. The Australian total sample on the other hand, contains mainly contractors (70%), and there are no other significant ANOVA results found. Risk distribution affects contractors' pricing (Levitt et a1 1980) and various research indicate that a ljust and acceptable' risk distribution between the parties should be a goal in contract planning. If so, the preferred risk distribution must first be found between the two parties to the contract. Most of the perceived major risk items, except managerial competence which is an inherent part of business efficacy, are dealt with by the standard forms to various extent. Both the Hong Kong and the Australian practitioners identify nine major risk items, of which six are common to these two groups of practitioners. Mostly these are related to contractor's performance, such as defective work and time for completion. The majority of the practitioners in the two groups agree that these risks should be borne by the contractors. In the Hong Kong sample, the preferred risk distribution pattern for seven out of the nine major risk items are labelled as contractor-biased. No significant difference in perception is identified between the three groups of participants, contractors, employers and consultants. Therefore, contractors in Hong Kong do, and are expected to, take more risks. In the Australian sample, on the other hand, only the preferred risk distribution pattern for the 'performance risks' (ie. five out of the nine major risk items) are labelled as contractor-biased. The other four items are preferred to be allocated to the employer. It is also found that in certain aspects, the consultants hold a different view to these two parties and this may affect project management. Since this type of 'third party assistance' which provides 'gaps filling' and 'flexibility' in contract planning has become an essential element in contract administration, the consultants' subjective judgements are relied upon in all stages of the construction process. Their different perceptions may result in undesirable biased decisions. A better understanding of the views of different parties is thus beneficial. References Casey J.J., Identification and nature of risks in construction project: a contractor's perspective. Construction Risks and Liability Sharing. Conference Proceedings. American Society of Civil Engineers. vol. 1. 1979. Doherty, N.A., Corporate Risk Management. McGraw Hill 1985. Furmston, M., The liability of contractors: principles of liability in contract and tort. In Lloyd H. (ed), The liability of contractors. Centre for Commercial Law Studies, Queen Mary College, London, 1986. Greene, M.R., Serbein, O.N., Risk Management, Test and Cases. Prentice Hall, 1983 Grose, M.R., Managing Risk. Systematic Loss Prevention for Executives. Prentice Hall, 1987 Levitt, R.E., Ashley D.B., Logcher, R.D., Allocating risk and incentive in construction. Journal of the construction division, ASCE, C03, Sept. 1980. Locke, E.A., Latham, G.P., A theory of goal setting and task performance. Englewood Cliffs, NJ Prentice Hall 1990. Macneil, I.R., The many futures of contract. Southern California Law Review Vol. 47:691, 1974. Macneil, I.R., A primer of contract planning. Southern California Law Review Vol. 48:627, 1975. Moore, P., The Business of Risk. Cambridge University Press, 1983. Nadel, N.A. Allocation of risks: a contractor's view. Construction Risks and Liability Sharing. Conference Proceedings. American Society of Civil Engineers. vol. 1. 1979. Naylor, J., Pritchard, R. D., Ilgen, D. R., A theory of behavior in organisations NY Academic Press, 1980. Tversky, A., Additivity, utility and subjective probability. Journal of Mathematical Psychology 4, 5-202, 1967. Tversky, A., Eliminating by aspects: a theory of choice. Psychological Review 79,28 1-299, 1972. Williamson, O.E., Transaction-cost Economics: The governance of contractual relations. Economic Organisation, Sussex, Harvester-Wheatsheaf, 1986.