Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Employee representation and financial leverage CSEF-EIEF-SITE Conference 2015, Rome Chen Lin1 Thomas Schmid1 1 2 Yuhai Xuan2 University of Hong Kong University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign August 31, 2015 Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Summary Research question: What is the impact of employee power on financial leverage? Setting: Direct influence of employees via supervisory board seats in German firms Identification: 50% employee representatives if > 2,000 domestic employees by law → regression discontinuity design Main finding: Employee power increases financial leverage Explanation: Interest alignment with debt providers as employee power reduces firm risk Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Content 1 Theoretical framework Background Hypotheses Empirical setting 2 Empirical results Main results Robustness Further tests 3 Conclusion Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Employee representation in Germany Board system Two-tier board system with management and supervisory board (“Vorstand” and “Aufsichtsrat”) Management board is responsible for the daily business; supervisory board has to elect and supervise managers Employee representation Employee co-determination is regulated by law (“MitbestG”) This law only applies to firms with > 2,000 domestic employees Supervisory board has to consist of an equal number of owners’ and employees’ representatives (parity employee representation, PER) → direct voice Literature Not the first to exploit this setting (e.g. Fauver & Fuerst 2006, Kim, Maug & Schneider 2015) Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting The influence of employees - the Volkswagen example (a) Martin Winterkorn (CEO) (b) Ferdinand Piech (Chairman) (c) Bernd Osterloh (d) Berthold Huber Source: Bild & Welt Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting The influence of employees - the Volkswagen example Source: Volkswagen AG Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting The influence of employees - the Volkswagen example Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Literature Bargaining literature A large literature argues that firms use debt as a strategic bargaining tool to reduce the influence of labor For example Bronars & Deere (1991), Perotti & Spier (1993), Matsa (2010) Job security literature Another literature focuses on how unemployment protection/benefits and job risk affect leverage For example Berk, Stanton & Zechner (2010), Agrawal & Matsa (2013), Simintzi, Vig & Volpin (2014) Indirect influence Both strands of the literature mainly focus on an “indirect” influence of labor on corporate decision making, e.g., via industry-level unionization or employment protection laws Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting The setting of this paper is different Legally mandated shift of power Power of employees in the firm increases At the same time, the influence of owners’ decreases We look at the “direct” influence of employees Employee representatives sit on the board and are firm insiders This makes the usage of debt as “bargaining tool” unattractive for managers as employee representatives possess insider knowledge, can fire managers, and are permanent monitors of executives In particular, they are more likely to monitor managers tightly and less likely to re-elect them if debt levels are (too) high Consequences Not bargaining or job security concerns, but another effect may be of first-order importance if employees have a direct and legally binding voice: interest alignment with banks Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Influence via unions Source: www.igmetall-bmw.de Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Influence via employee representatives Source: www.audi-mediacenter.com Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Interest alignment Employees and banks Both banks and employees are interested in the long-term survival and stability of the firm to secure jobs and debt repayments Fauver & Fuerst (2006) argue that “labor seats on the board should enhance monitoring of managers [...] and reduce private blockholder privileges in much the same way as bankers on corporate boards do” Thus, labor representatives who aim to protect the interests of employees may (unintentionally) also represent banks’ interests Hypotheses Interest alignment may enable firms to access bank debt more easily and at better conditions → higher debt levels Furthermore, firms with PER are expected to have lower firm risk → less cash flow / equity volatility Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Dataset Sample construction Public and private German firms between 2005 and 2013 Firms with ≥ 1,000 ≤ 3,000 domestic employees are considered This leads to about 160 sample firms with over 700 firm-years Main data sources Accounting data comes from Hoppenstedt (HS) Number of domestic employees: HS and hand-collected Additional data from Dealscan, SDC Platinum, and Datastream Main variables per equals one if the firm has parity employee representation leverage is defined as total debt total debt + book value of equity Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Background Hypotheses Empirical setting Empirical strategy Identification strategy We exploit that PER is regulated by law and not a voluntary decision of firms ( 1 if DEi,t > 2000 German law mandates that: PERi,t = 0 if DEi,t ≤ 2000 Regression discontinuity design We use a parametric strategy and limit the sample to firms with around 2,000 DE (i.e., 1,000 to 3,000 DE) The empirical model is: → Levi,t = α + βPERi,t−1 + ν X i,t−1 + 4 P p=1 γp Api,t−1 + 4 P p=1 δp Api,t−1 T0|1 + i,t Ai,t = DEi,t − 2000 This approach controls for any direct impact of domestic employees on leverage (on both sides of the threshold) Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Content 1 Theoretical framework Background Hypotheses Empirical setting 2 Empirical results Main results Robustness Further tests 3 Conclusion Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Plot Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Leverage & parity employee representation Model I II III IV V PER 0.068** (2.16) 0.12*** (3.09) 0.11*** (2.91) 0.14*** (3.20) 0.15*** (3.22) Size -0.0038 (-0.17) -0.11 (-0.96) -1.05*** (-6.27) -0.023 (-0.80) 0.028 (0.67) -0.092** (-2.21) -0.0015 (-0.067) -0.094 (-0.85) -1.05*** (-6.21) -0.014 (-0.55) 0.033 (0.79) -0.096** (-2.33) -0.0022 (-0.098) -0.082 (-0.73) -1.06*** (-6.27) -0.019 (-0.69) 0.035 (0.85) -0.10** (-2.46) -0.0034 (-0.15) -0.073 (-0.67) -1.05*** (-6.24) -0.012 (-0.43) 0.033 (0.81) -0.098** (-2.40) -0.0030 (-0.13) -0.071 (-0.65) -1.04*** (-6.17) -0.015 (-0.49) 0.031 (0.73) -0.096** (-2.31) 725 158 0.33 yes yes no no 725 158 0.34 yes yes one no 725 158 0.34 yes yes two no 725 158 0.35 yes yes two yes 725 158 0.36 yes yes four yes Tangibility ROA TobQind Listing Acc. Std. Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Identification threats Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Identification threats cont. Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Identification threats cont. Is there evidence for large-scale manipulation? The law exists since 1976 without fundamental changes In 2005, a Government Commission (Biedenkopf Commission) was set up to review the law Some quotes from the final report: “[t]he academic members stated that they saw no reason to propose a fundamental revision of the German system of board-level representation” “the protection for employee interests provided by the existing regulations remains appropriate” “only very few cases of companies avoiding boardlevel representation are known” Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Identification threats cont. Model PER I law deviations IIa IIb placebo test 0.20** (2.09) DE1,500 -0.0036 (-0.093) DE2,500 0.037 (0.71) TE2,000 Size Tangibility ROA TobQind Listing Acc. Std. Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side III -0.051 (-1.03) -0.011 (-0.47) 0.0018 (0.017) -1.11*** (-6.53) 0.024 (0.74) 0.032 (0.76) -0.097** (-2.30) -0.0011 (-0.055) -0.20* (-1.94) -0.88*** (-7.16) 0.027 (0.75) -0.013 (-0.34) -0.099** (-2.57) 0.013 (0.51) -0.15 (-1.15) -0.89*** (-5.30) -0.092** (-2.32) 0.029 (0.75) -0.090** (-2.21) -0.0020 (-0.078) 0.034 (0.32) -0.88*** (-6.14) 0.036 (0.68) -0.035 (-0.98) -0.044 (-1.17) 679 152 0.36 yes yes four yes 934 187 0.32 yes yes four no 557 142 0.32 yes yes four no 653 155 0.33 yes yes four no Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Interest alignment Idea Alignment of interests between employees and banks may provide an intuitive explanation for higher leverage Test 1: bank ownership Equity stakes are a substitute for banks to affect firm policy directly; thus, PER should be less relevant if banks hold equity stakes Bank equity holdings in industrial firms have been (and still are) popular However, bank ownership is likely endogenously determined → use the 2001 capital gains tax reform which increased incentives for German banks to sell their equity stakes (i.e., banks could sell equity stakes without paying capital gain taxes) We construct a second sample around this event (only listed firms) Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Bank ownership & tax reform Model Ia PERpre 0.11 (1.00) 0.17* (1.84) PERpre x post Ib 0.18** (2.44) Ic 0.35*** (4.40) Bankpre PER x bankpre Post x bankpre PERpre x post x bankpre Size Tangibility ROA TobQ Acc. std. Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Firm FE Polynomial / either side Polynomial x post IIa IIb -0.088* (-1.94) 0.041 (1.00) 0.13* (1.72) -0.089 (-0.99) -0.18** (-2.38) 0.21** (2.39) -0.12* (-1.76) 0.20** (2.44) 0.0044 (0.12) 0.033 (0.70) -0.011 (-0.055) -0.56* (-1.94) -0.097* (-1.74) -0.029 (-0.42) -0.066 (-0.66) 0.033 (0.079) 0.014 (0.080) 0.0027 (0.076) 0.032 (0.57) -0.11 (-1.51) 0.22 (0.92) 0.23* (1.69) -0.014 (-0.43) 0.042 (0.91) 0.032*** (3.34) 0.28*** (3.63) -0.13 (-1.27) -0.073*** (-5.24) 0.0071 (0.24) 0.072*** (2.74) 0.37*** (3.54) -0.21*** (-3.43) 0.0039 (0.20) 0.010 (0.37) 160 57 0.32 yes yes no four yes no 160 57 0.21 yes yes yes four yes no 160 57 0.51 yes yes yes four yes yes 1,103 264 0.23 yes yes no no no no 1,103 264 0.13 yes yes yes no no no Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Interest alignment cont. Test 2: loan characteristics Based on data from Dealscan, we analyze interest rate and other loan characteristics We expect more favorable financing conditions for firms with PER Test 3: cash flow sensitivity of cash We expect less financial constraints for firms with PER As empirical proxy for financial constraints we apply the cash flow sensitivity of cash (Almeida et al. 2004) We find that the cash flow sensitivity of cash is lower in firms with PER Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Interest rate Model I IIa IIb III PER -0.017*** (-5.67) -0.013*** (-3.09) -0.011* (-1.82) -0.018*** (-3.89) Leverage -0.0023 (-0.49) -0.0019** (-2.21) 0.015** (2.18) -0.026* (-1.87) -0.0013 (-0.55) 0.0026 (1.64) -0.0017 (-1.08) 0.010*** (9.35) 0.0051 (1.07) -0.0053*** (-4.61) 0.00043 (0.078) -0.018* (-1.86) 0.00075 (0.31) -0.00032 (-0.18) -0.0012 (-0.72) 0.019** (2.50) -0.0028* (-1.97) 0.0038 (0.40) -0.0071 (-0.29) -0.020*** (-2.97) 0.00089 (0.35) -0.0033 (-1.20) 0.0099* (1.73) -0.0029** (-2.58) 0.036*** (3.00) -0.050** (-2.54) 0.0066 (1.38) 0.0027 (1.29) -0.0031* (-1.71) 253 61 0.64 no no four yes 253 61 0.63 no yes four yes 253 61 0.53 yes no four yes 253 61 0.68 yes yes four yes Size Tangibility ROA TobQind Listing Z-score class Ind/year mean Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Deal characteristics lenders covenants PER 0.22** (2.60) maturity 0.20** (2.46) -0.34* (-1.84) -3.10** (-2.15) Leverage 0.077 (0.43) 0.071* (1.80) 0.28* (1.75) 0.90** (2.01) -0.0061 (-0.048) -0.10* (-1.94) -0.041 (-0.81) -0.046 (-0.29) 0.070** (2.12) 0.18 (1.29) 0.74* (1.89) 0.057 (0.43) -0.097** (-2.14) -0.026 (-0.57) 0.73*** (2.75) 0.028 (0.30) -0.52 (-1.08) 0.51 (0.65) 0.61*** (2.75) -0.075 (-0.61) 0.22 (1.64) 1.15 (0.35) 0.17 (0.28) 5.32 (1.57) 4.18 (0.62) -1.36 (-0.60) 3.09*** (2.77) -2.11*** (-2.64) 735 133 yes yes four yes OLS 735 133 yes yes four yes Poisson 763 134 yes yes four yes Poisson 763 134 yes yes four yes Poisson Listing Size Tangibility ROA TobQind Z-score class Observations Firms Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Model Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Cash flow sensitivity of cash Model Sample Ia PER Ib no PER IIa all IIb CF≥0 IIa -0.023 (-0.30) 0.098*** (2.88) 0.015 (1.33) 0.10*** (2.91) -0.12* (-1.83) 0.024** (2.27) 0.12*** (4.40) -0.19*** (-2.85) 0.019* (1.90) 0.064* (1.91) -0.13** (-2.11) 0.027** (2.37) 0.21 (1.46) -0.24** (-2.08) 0.0021 (0.44) 0.0023 (0.13) 0.0010 (0.38) 0.0034 (0.24) 0.0013 (0.62) 0.0040 (0.39) -0.00048 (-0.25) 0.0011 (0.11) 0.0015 (0.64) 0.015* (1.74) -0.17* (-1.82) 0.17*** (4.74) -0.0015 (-0.048) -0.00066 (-0.12) 0.0015 (0.60) 0.014 (1.59) -0.16* (-1.88) 0.17*** (4.74) -0.0072 (-0.25) -0.00044 (-0.079) 154 44 0.11 yes yes four yes no 436 106 0.084 yes yes four yes no 590 146 0.057 yes yes four yes no 567 144 0.056 yes yes four yes no 590 146 0.17 yes yes four yes no 590 146 0.19 yes yes four yes yes PER Cash flow PER x cash flow Size Growth−1y ,+1y ∆ Short debt ∆ NWC Capex M&A deal Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Poly. x cash flow Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan IIb all Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Channel for interest alignment Lower firm risk Risk averse employees may have strong incentives to reduce firm risk due to their firm-specific human capital (Gorton & Schmid 2000) This may provide an intuitive explanation for interest alignment between employees and banks Empirical findings I: M&A Firms with PER have lower probabilty for M&A deals (and fewer deals) If they engage in M&A deals, capital market response is more favorable Empirical findings II: stability & firm risk The standard deviation of cash flows and ROA is lower in firms with PER We also find evidence for lower idiosyncratic (and total) firm risk based on stock returns Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests M&A deals M&A deals CAR−1,+1 dummy # deals CER−1,+1 CAR−2,+2 PER -0.78*** (-3.00) -0.84*** (-2.58) 4.16** (2.45) 4.99*** (3.01) 3.98** (2.54) Leverage -0.18 (-0.46) 0.56*** (4.76) -0.37 (-0.65) 0.98 (0.90) 0.22 (0.52) 0.42** (2.40) -0.0023 (-0.0044) 0.79*** (6.42) -1.12 (-1.48) 0.24 (0.17) 0.19 (0.31) 0.85*** (3.17) 2.93 (0.81) -1.18 (-0.91) -4.46 (-1.53) -34.9** (-2.59) 5.43 (1.47) -2.07 (-1.41) -4.78 (-1.53) -32.4** (-2.51) 0.60 (0.12) -2.39* (-2.04) -4.05* (-1.76) -33.4 (-1.65) 0.85 (0.60) -0.84 (-0.95) -0.048*** (-3.19) -1.21** (-2.15) 1.50* (1.70) 0.95 (0.70) -0.22 (-0.21) -0.046*** -0.015 (-4.02) -1.33** (-2.22) 1.53* (1.93) 0.82 (0.38) 0.10 (0.11) (-0.86) -0.83 (-0.86) 1.69 (1.30) 182 yes yes four yes OLS 182 yes yes four yes OLS 182 yes yes four yes OLS Size Tangibility ROA TobQind Listing TobQ Market cap. Free float Diversifying deal International deal Observations Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Model 688 yes yes four yes Probit 692 yes yes four yes Poisson Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Firm risk Model Variable I σidio II log (σidio ) III σtotal PER -6.94** (-2.47) -0.15** (-2.01) -0.88** (-2.11) Leverage 6.57 (0.98) 7.08** (2.18) 0.74 (0.099) -57.1*** (-2.98) 8.25*** (4.71) -6.79*** (-2.84) 0.014 (0.50) 0.13 (0.86) 0.18** (2.18) 0.011 (0.050) -1.03*** (-3.25) 0.17*** (3.27) -0.18*** (-3.00) 3.4e-06 (0.0042) 0.93 (0.91) 1.32** (2.46) -0.014 (-0.011) -9.93*** (-3.11) 1.73*** (5.47) -1.11*** (-2.79) 0.0097* (1.87) 258 58 0.66 yes yes four yes 258 58 0.64 yes yes four yes 258 58 0.70 yes yes four yes Size Tangibility ROA TobQ Market cap. Free float Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Main results Robustness Further tests Stability Model Variable Period Ib SD(cash flow) 4y Ic IIa 5y 3y IIb SD(ROA) 4y IIc 3y PER -0.030** (-2.06) -0.028* (-1.96) -0.038** (-2.26) -0.031 (-1.57) -0.032* (-1.85) -0.048* (-1.91) Leverage -0.013 (-0.76) 0.0073** (1.99) 0.029* (1.67) -0.018 (-0.41) -0.0043 (-0.32) 0.032 (0.97) -0.013* (-1.88) 0.014* (1.79) -0.021 (-1.02) 0.0066 (1.65) 0.053** (2.10) -0.022 (-0.29) 0.0060 (0.29) 0.037 (1.10) -0.013 (-1.45) 0.015 (1.59) -0.018 (-0.84) 0.0083 (1.65) 0.052 (1.44) 0.052 (0.58) 0.0025 (0.11) 0.026 (1.06) -0.011 (-1.06) 0.011 (1.00) -0.013 (-0.76) 0.013*** (2.69) 0.030 (1.23) -0.077 (-0.88) -0.0031 (-0.20) 0.019 (0.68) -0.0070 (-0.67) 0.012 (1.19) -0.021 (-1.01) 0.013** (2.32) 0.044 (1.46) -0.051 (-0.58) 0.00012 (0.0056) 0.031 (1.02) -0.0073 (-0.55) 0.012 (1.04) -0.017 (-0.66) 0.016** (2.14) 0.062 (1.33) 0.023 (0.22) 0.0030 (0.12) 0.022 (0.83) 0.0014 (0.088) 0.0014 (0.11) 344 97 0.40 yes yes four yes 256 90 0.44 yes yes four yes 170 63 0.57 yes yes four yes 347 98 0.41 yes yes four yes 258 91 0.45 yes yes four yes 171 64 0.54 yes yes four yes Size Tangibility ROA TobQind Growth−1y ,+1y Listing Acc. Std. Observations Firms R2 Industry FE Year FE Polynomial / either side Ia Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan 5y Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Content 1 Theoretical framework Background Hypotheses Empirical setting 2 Empirical results Main results Robustness Further tests 3 Conclusion Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion Summary We analyze how employee codetermination affects financial leverage The German environment allows us to investigate a direct impact of employees (which complements prior evidence on indirect influence) The supervisory board of German firms has to consist of 50% employee representatives if the firm has > 2,000 domestic employees → regression discontinuity design We find that parity employee representation increases leverage Different tests point to a supply side effect: as banks interests are similar to those of employees, employee power reduces agency conflicts with debt providers Further tests reveal lower firm risk as possible channel for this alignment “Bright” side of employee representation Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Theoretical framework Empirical results Conclusion End For questions, please contact me: schmid@hku.hk Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Backup Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Literature German co-determination Several papers analyze the impact of the German co-determination The empirical evidence on valuation and firm performance is rather inconclusive (e.g., Gorton & Schmid 2004, Fauver & Fuerst 2006) Kraft et al. (2011) finds no impact on innovation, whereas Kim et al. (2015) find that employee representation protects skilled workers against layoffs during industry shocks Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Variables I Main variables PER DE Leverage Dummy which equals one if the firm has parity employee representation. Source: hand-collected. Number of domestic employees. Source: Hoppenstedt and hand-collected. Total debt divided by total debt plus book value of equity. Total debt includes current and long-term liabilities and excludes provisions and accruals. Source: Hoppenstedt (HS). Control variables Listing Size Tangibility ROA TobQ TobQind Acc. Std. Z-Score Z-Score class Dummy that equals one if preferred or voting shares of the firm are listed on any EU-regulated or exchange-regulated market in Germany. Source: hand-collected. Natural logarithm of total assets in Mio e . Source: HS. Long-term tangible assets scaled by total assets. Source: HS. Earnings before interest and taxes, scaled by total assets. Source: HS. Market value of equity plus total liabilities divided by the sum of book value of equity and total liabilities ( wc08001+wc03351 ). Source: WC. wc03501+wc03351 Mean of TobQ in an industry (based on the 17 industries classification) and year. Source: Own calculation. Dummy which equals one if a firm applies international accounting standards. Source: HS. Z-Score is calculated as 0.717*x1 + 0.847*x2 + 3.107*x3 + 0.420*x4 + 0.998*x5 with x1 retained earnings EBIT = short-term assets−short-term liabilities ; x2 = ; x3 = ; x4 = total assets total assets total assets total equity sales ; x5 = ; Source: own calculation based on HS. total liabilities total assets Equals minus one if Z-Score is above 2.9, one if Z-Score is below 1.22, and zero if Z-Score is between 1.22 and 2.9. Source: own calculation. Dealscan variables (source: Dealscan) Spread Maturity Lenders Covenants Amount Purpose Spread all-in-drawn. Ln of deal maturity in months. Ln of number of lenders. If Dealscan reports no information on lender shares, we assume that only one lender exists. Number of covenants for the deal. If no information on covenants is availabe, we set the variable to zero. Ln of the facility amount. Dummy which equals one if primary purpose is “corporate purpose”. HS stands for Hoppenstedt, DS for Dealscan, and WC for Worldscope. Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Variables II Tax event Post ERpre−ref Bankpre−ref Dummy for post tax reform period. Equals one for years 2002 to 2004. ER as of 1998. Source: hand-collected. Dummy which equals one if a German bank owns voting rights in any year between 1996 and 1998. Source: HS. M&A deals (source: SDC Platinum) M&A deal # deals CAR CER Diversifying deal International deal Dummy which equals one if a firm conducts a M&A deal. Number of M&A deals. Cumulative abnormal return around the announcement of a M&A deal. Normal returns are estimated with a market model; the CDAX is used as market index. The estimation period is 200 trading days ending two months before the announcement date (Cai & Sevilir 2012). Events for which we have less 150 observations during the estimation period are not considered. The CAR is measured during a symmetric three or five day window around the event. Cumulative excess return. Excess return is defined as return above the market index, i.e., the CDAX. Dummy which equals one if the firm acquires a target outside its main business segment (as indicted by the SDC macro industry). Dummy which equals one if the target is located outside Germany. Stability & risk SD(cash flow) SD(ROA) σidio σtotal Standard deviation of cash flow over the specific time period. Source: HS. Standard deviation of ROA over the specified time period. Source: HS. Yearly measure for idiosyncratic risk (Panousi & Papanikolaou 2012). Calculated as volatility of weekly residuals. Residuals are obtained from a regression of firm’s equity returns on the market return (CDAX). r P 2 i,t σidio for firm i in year t is then calculated as σ = ; with i,τ being the residual from i,τ idio the first regression in week τ . Equity returns are calculated based changes of the Datastream item RI (return index) between week t-1 and t. Some adjustments are made for equity returns (i.e., deletion of all observations with unadjusted price below one and observations where the same price is reported for at least three consecutive weeks) Yearly standard deviation of weekly equity returns. The same adjustments as above are conducted. Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Variables III Worldscope database Leverage Market leverage Size Tangibility ROA Total debt [wc03255] / (total debt + book value of equity [wc03501]). Total debt [wc03255] / (total debt + market value of equity [wc08001]). Ln of total assets [wc02999] in thousand e . Property, plant, and equipment [wc02501] / total assets. EBIT [wc18191] / total assets. Other variables Cash flow Cash Growth−1y ,+1y ∆ Delta short debt Capex ∆ NWC Free float Market cap. Sales minus total expenses plus depreciation divided by total assets. Source: HS. Cash and liquid assets divided by total assets. Source: HS. salest+1 Sales growth between year t+1 and year t-1. Calculated as − 1. Source: HS. salest−1 Difference in trade liabilities between t-1 and t, divided by total assets. Source: HS. Additions to fixed assets in year t divided by total assets at the end of year t-1. Source: HS. Difference in working capital, scaled by total assets. Source: HS. Fraction of shares in free float. Source: DS. Natural logarithm of one plus market capitalization in Mio e . Source: DS. Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Descriptive statistics Variable PER DE Leverage Listing Size (mio Eur) Tangibility ROA TobQind Acc. Std. N Mean SD p25 p50 p75 min max 768 797 797 791 797 797 797 797 797 0.25 1785.27 0.53 0.40 740.25 0.30 0.08 1.30 0.53 0.44 518.38 0.19 0.49 1042.76 0.17 0.08 0.30 0.50 0 1394 0.4 0 272 0.19 0.04 1.11 0 0 1662 0.56 0 452 0.27 0.08 1.24 1 1 2127 0.65 1 765 0.38 0.12 1.43 1 0 1000 0.04 0 43.2 0.02 -0.5 0.93 0 1 2998 1 1 8794 0.94 0.62 3.94 1 Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage Backup References Agrawal, A. K. & Matsa, D. A. (2013), ‘Labor unemployment risk and corporate financing decisions’, Journal of Financial Economics 108(2), 449–470. URL: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X12002413 Almeida, H., Campello, M. & Weisbach, M. S. (2004), ‘The cash flow sensitivity of cash’, Journal of Finance 59(4), 1777–1804. URL: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00679.x/full Berk, J. B., Stanton, R. & Zechner, J. (2010), ‘Human capital, bankruptcy, and capital structure’, Journal of Finance 65(3), 891–926. Bronars, S. G. & Deere, D. R. (1991), ‘The threat of unionization, the use of debt, and the preservation of shareholder wealth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(1), 231–254. URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2937914 Cai, Y. & Sevilir, M. (2012), ‘Board connections and M&A transactions’, Journal of Financial Economics 103(2), 327–349. URL: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X11002170 Fauver, L. & Fuerst, M. E. (2006), ‘Does good corporate governance include employee representation? Evidence from German corporate boards’, Journal of Financial Economics 82(3), 673–710. Gorton, G. & Schmid, F. A. (2000), ‘Universal banking and the performance of german firms’, Journal of Financial Economics 58(1), 29–80. URL: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X00000660 Gorton, G. & Schmid, F. A. (2004), ‘Capital, labor, and the firm: A study of German codetermination’, Journal of the European Economic Association 2(5), 863–905. Kim, E. H., Maug, E. & Schneider, C. (2015), Labor representation in governance as an insurance mechanism. Kraft, K., Stank, J. & Dewenter, R. (2011), ‘Co-determination and innovation’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 35(1), 145–172. URL: http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/content/35/1/145.short Matsa, D. A. (2010), ‘Capital structure as a strategic variable: Evidence from collective bargaining’, Journal of Finance 65(3), 1197–1232. URL: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01565.x/full Panousi, V. & Papanikolaou, D. (2012), ‘Investment, idiosyncratic risk, and ownership’, Journal of Finance 67(3), 1113–1148. URL: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2012.01743.x/full Perotti, E. C. & Spier, K. E. (1993), ‘Capital structure as a bargaining tool: The role of leverage in contract renegotiation’, American Economic Review 83(5), 1131–1141. URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117552 Simintzi, E., Vig, V. & Volpin, P. (2014), ‘Labor protection and leverage’, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming . Chen Lin, Thomas Schmid, Yuhai Xuan Employee representation and financial leverage