The Monetary Value of the Soft Benefits of Green Roofs FinalReport Prepared by: Ray Tomalty, Ph.D. and Bartek Komorowski, MUP with the assistance of Dany Doiron SmartCitiesResearchServices,Montreal Prepared for: CanadaMortgageandHousingCorporation(CMHC) August, 2010 1 Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank the following project advisors for their invaluable guidance in conducting this study: Hitesh Doshi (Ryerson University), Jamie Meil (Athena Institute), Steven Peck (Green Roofs for Healthy Cities), Douglas Pollard (CMHC), and Ralph Velasquez (Tremco Inc.). 2 TableofContents 1 Introduction.........................................................................................................................i 2 ValuationMethodologies.................................................................................................i 3 ValuationofBenefits........................................................................................................ii PropertyValues...................................................................................................................................ii MarketingBenefits............................................................................................................................vi FoodProductionandFoodSecurity..........................................................................................vii SoundAttenuation..........................................................................................................................vii StormwaterRetention.....................................................................................................................ix AirQuality.............................................................................................................................................x GHGSequestration............................................................................................................................xi 4 CaseStudies.....................................................................................................................xiii 901CherryAvenue,SanBruno,CA...........................................................................................xiii FairmontWaterfrontHotel,Vancouver,BC..........................................................................xiii 401Richmond,Toronto,ON.......................................................................................................xiv RooftopVictoryGardens,Chicago,IL......................................................................................xiv TheLouisa,Portland,OR................................................................................................................xv 5 Conclusions........................................................................................................................xv Bibliography............................................................................................................................xix 1 Introduction........................................................................................................................1 2 ValuationMethodologies................................................................................................3 2.1 2.2 2.3 RevealedPreferenceMethodologies................................................................................4 StatedPreferenceMethodologies......................................................................................5 AvoidedCostMethodologies...............................................................................................6 3 ValuationofBenefits........................................................................................................8 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 Propertyvalueincrease........................................................................................................9 Marketing................................................................................................................................16 Foodproductionandfoodsecurity................................................................................20 SoundAttenuation................................................................................................................24 StormwaterRetention........................................................................................................27 AirQualityImprovement...................................................................................................32 GreenhouseGasSequestration........................................................................................36 4 CaseStudies......................................................................................................................40 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 CaseStudy1–901CherryAvenue,SanBruno,CA...................................................42 CaseStudy2–FairmontWaterfrontHotel,Vancouver,BC...................................49 CaseStudy3–401Richmond,Toronto,ON................................................................56 CaseStudy4–RooftopVictoryGardens,Chicago,IL...............................................64 CaseStudy5–TheLouisa,Portland,OR......................................................................72 5 Conclusions.......................................................................................................................80 3 Interviewees............................................................................................................................84 Bibliography............................................................................................................................86 4 Summary 1 Introduction The use of green roofs can offer a tangible solution to many challenges faced by communities across Canada today. Articulating the value of those benefits in monetary terms provides an estimate of their contribution to local and regional economies and permits governments, land developers and building owners to assess short- and long-term public and private gains. While some benefits are directly measurable and have ‘hard’ values (such as the energy savings due the insulation provided by the soil and vegetation of a green roof), many benefits are not readily measurable and their values are difficult to estimate (such as the health benefits of a rooftop garden). For the purpose of this study, those benefits that are not directly measurable (or calculated based on any line item on the buildings budget) will be defined as ‘soft’ benefits. The purpose of this report is to provide methodologies and case studies that can offer guidance in attributing economic value to selected soft benefits of green roofs. We offer methodologies that can be easily employed by stakeholders with limited information about the property concerned. In other words, our goal is to put forward heuristic methods that can be used with data that is usually readily at hand. Needless to say, this approach entails a trade-off between ease of use and the level of detail and precision. Keeping this in mind, the results obtained with the proposed methods should be applied prudently. 2 Valuation Methodologies The soft benefits of green roofs are not directly tradable and therefore do not have directly measurable monetary values. To determine their monetary value, nonmarket or indirect valuation techniques must be employed. Estimating the total economic value of a non-market good or service entails calculating the sum of all values associated with that good or service. The two main categories of value are use and non-use values. Use values can either be direct or indirect. Direct use value refers to the value that is derived from actual or planned use of a particular environmental service or good. Recreation and food production are two examples of direct use values. Indirect use value occurs when people benefit from an environmental amenity without consciously using it. Water filtration, climate regulation are examples of the indirect use values of environmental amenities. Non- use value refers to the value that individuals place on an environmental amenity without having any planned use for it. An example of a non-use value is the intrinsic value that people attribute to an environmental amenity (like the boreal forest) simply for its existence. The methods used to estimate non-use values are considerably more complex and are beyond the scope of this report. Non-market valuation techniques have been developed in order to estimate the net value that the public or individuals attribute to environmental amenities such as green infrastructure. Three general categories of nonmarket valuation methodologies exist. The first category,revealed preference methods (i.e., travel cost, hedonic pricing, market comparables, and cost avoidance) uses behaviours and information observed in markets to estimate non-market values. The second category, stated preference methods, which includes the contingent valuation technique, attributes economic value by asking people their willingness to pay for a service or willingness to accept compensation to voluntarily forgo a service. The third category is avoided cost analysis, which can be used to determine the value of green infrastructure by quantifying the costs that would be incurred if the services provided by the infrastructure were not available or had to be provided by building conventional infrastructure. 3 Valuation of Benefits The objective of our research is to provide readers with non-technical methods for estimating the soft benefits associated with a green roof project based on readilyavailable information and without the need for undertaking major research. The benefits that are included here are those for which we could find relatively simple valuation methods that could be applied by non-specialists with limited resources for data gathering. The proposed methods were gathered from current practices and the existing literature. Property Values Green infrastructure investments have been shown to positively affect the property value and marketability of nearby real estate. In the case of green roofs, this benefit would accrue to the owner or owners of a building with a green roof and, to a lesser degree, to owners of surrounding properties. Hedonic valuation techniques have been used to measure the relationship between the selling price of a residence and its distance from an urban greenspace, park, community garden or wetland. At present, there are no studies that have measured the potential of green roofs to increase the selling price of a condominium or other residential building. In the absence of hedonic pricing studies looking specifically at green roofs, we can use estimates of property value increases generated by other types of green infrastructure, e.g., an at-grade community garden or park. ii View onto a Green Roof Assuming that having a view onto a green roof has a similar effect to new tree plantings, the value of the benefit accrued to owners of properties is 9% of the value of the portion of a building that affords a direct view onto a green roof. This is based on Wachter’s (2004) finding that tree planting along a street in front of a property increases the property's value by up to 9%. Where neighbours of the green rooftop are concerned, we assume that greening a rooftop is equivalent to tree planting atgrade – it adds greenery but does not change the amount of recreational green space to which they have access. We do not attribute any increased value to a green roof without trees. Assuming that having a view onto a green roof has a similar effect to new tree plantings, the value of the benefit accrued to owners of properties is 9% of the value of the portion of a building that affords a direct view onto a green roof. This is based on Wachter’s (2004) finding that tree planting increases property values up to 9%. Where neighbours of the green rooftop are concerned, we assume that greening a rooftop is equivalent to tree planting at-grade. For them, the greening of the rooftop has much the same effect as tree planting – it adds greenery but does not change the amount of green space to which they have access. We do not attribute any increased value to a green roof without trees. For the purpose of estimating the value of the benefit for a wholebuilding, we assume that only half the neighbouring storeys above the green roof are oriented so as to afford a view onto it. The increase in property value that accrues to a building with a view onto a green roof can therefore be estimated using the following formula: 1 h −h ⋅ vv b = 0.09⋅ ⋅ v 2 hv = 0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vv hv Where: • b = value of benefit ($) • vv= value of neighbouring property with a view onto the green roof ($) • h = height of the green roof host building (storeys) • hv = height of the building with a view onto the green roof (storeys) For the purpose of estimating the value of the benefit for a singleunit in a building that has a direct view onto a green roof, we propose using the following formula: iii oftop Garden n Recreeational Roo A roo oftop garden n that is acccessible to building b dweellers will o offer recreattional beneefits that maay be reflectted in the vaalue placed on the build ding. To estimate this valuee, we turn to o studies that have asseessed the im mpact on ho ousing valuees in locattions abuttin ng public paarks. Using the hedonicc method, C Crompton (2 2005) has suggested that homes h adjaccent to public parks havve about a 2 20% higher property d from m parks.. Givven that an aabutting paark offers valuees than simiilar homes distant both recreationaal and view benefits, we deduct the view beneefit (9% of p property valuee) calculated d above to arrive a at a recreational benefit of 1 11%. We propose p the increase in property value yielded d by a recreeational rooftop garden n be esstimated usiing the follo owing formu ula: b = 0.11⋅ v Wherre: • b = value of th he benefit ($) • v = value of th he green roo of host prop perty ($) Produ uctive Roofto op Garden Assuming that having h a pro oductive roo oftop garden n is tantamo ount to abuttting an atgradee communitty garden, we w propose that the vallue of the lo ong-term benefit accru ued to the owner of thee property be b estimated d at 7% of th he value of the property. This iss based on Voicu V and Been’s (2008 8) finding th hat, on averaage, y gardens in ncreased in vvalue by 7.4 4% by five properties abuttting typical community yearss after the construction c n of the gard den. As we d do not know w from thesee findings whatt the effect is in the longger term, we w assume th he value rem mains consttant at the five-y year level. We propose p the increase in property value yielded d by a privaate, productive rooftop gardeen be estimated using the t followin ng formula: Wherre: • b ($) b = value of benefit • v = value of grreen roof ho ost propertyy ($) iiv If thee productivee rooftop gaarden is opeen to non-occcupants of the building then it is moree likely that benefits wiill accrue to owners of n neighbourin ng properties. In this case, we assumee that the ro ooftop gardeen behaves exactly likee an at-gradee comm munity gard den. In the lo ong-term, th he value of tthe benefit accrued to neigh hbouring prroperty own ners is 7% for f owners iin the buildiing with thee rooftop comm munity gard den and the immediate vicinity of tthe host buiilding, 5% ffor those up to 50 00 feet away y, and 2% fo or those up to t 1,000 feeet away. Agaain, the valu ues are based d on Voicu and a Been (2 2008) and assumed to h hold at theirr five-year llevel. We propose p the increase in property value accrueed to a neigh hbouring prroperty of a publiicly accessib ble productive rooftop garden be eestimated u using the folllowing form mula: Wherre: • b = value of benefit b ($) • v = property value v ($) • d = distance from f green roof r host prroperty (meeters) • F= distance factor f (functtion of d) • F = 0.07 when n0≤d≤5m • F = 0.05 when n 5 m < d ≤ 150 m • n 150 m < d ≤ 300 m F = 0.02 when • F= 0 when d > 300 m Let: Area‐‐Wide Beneffit The above a stated d formulas are a intendeed for calculating the vaalue of proxximity beneefits that acccrue to indiv vidual properties. Mun icipal decision makers may be moree interested d in the totall, area-widee increase in n property vvalues resullting from a green n roof projeect. In this caase, it is neccessary to su um the valu ues of the beenefit accru uing to the host h properrty with thosse accruing to neighbouring propeerties. Wherre: v • btootal = total arrea-wide prroperty valu ue benefit ($$) • bn = property y value beneefit of an ind dividual pro operty ($) Marketing Ben nefits The mass m mediaa and the pu ublic’s intereest in enviroonmentally friendly pro oducts and serviices continu ue to rapidly y increase in n North America. Green n roofs and other green n infrastructure on or near a building can n therefore be considered as a maarketing nity that inccreases a deevelopment’’s exposure and enhancces the abso orption ratee amen of itss units. Appllying the comparable co osts method dology, one way of estiimating the mark keting beneffits of green n infrastructture would be to assesss the value o of the publiicity gained d as a direct consequencce of green infrastructu ure investm ments. The marketing m benefits b of green g roofs will w depend d on a numb ber of factorrs that are unkn nown in adv vance or diffficult to quaantify, such aas the curreent interest of local mediia in green infrastructu i ure and greeen buildingss. The best w way to estim mate the mark keting beneffits is by bassing it on th he value of tthe publicityy received d due to the preseence of the green g roof in i the project. The valu ue of the freee publicity rreceived can n be esstimated by comparison n to the cost of advertizzing in threee media: raadio, telev vision, and print. p The co ost for each of the threee media is b broken down n into the production cost plus the cost of runnin ng the ad. Th he former caan be assum med to be consttant as it is a onetime cost. c The lattter is the coost of havingg the ad aireed on radio and television t an nd printed in i newspapers. The value v of freee publicity can c in principle be estim mated accorrding to thee following form mula: Wherre: • he benefit ($) b = value of th • pradio = radio ad a productiion cost ($) r • rraadio = radio ad a running cost c (airtim me) ($/30s sspot) • traadio = total raadio equivalent airtimee (30s spotss)* • ptvv = tv ad pro oduction cost ($) • rtvv = tv ad run nning cost (aairtime) ($//30s spot)* • ttvv= total tv equivalent airtime (30s spots) vvi • ppaper = newsp paper ad production coost ($) p • rpaaper = newsp paper ad run nning cost ((printing) ($$/column in nch) • l = total equiv valent colum mn length (ccolumn inch hes) * Totaal airtime is divided by 30 to o convert to number of spotts. Food d Production and Food Securitty Green roofs and at-grade gaardens can provide p imp portant opp portunities ffor healthy food production n. Rooftop an nd commun nity gardenss can help m meet nutritio onal requirements an nd reduce household exxpendituress on food wh hile encouraging stew wardship of land l by site users. Urbaan agricultu ure can provvide city-dw wellers with a sourcce of fresh produce, p improved diett and imporrtant househ hold budgettary savingss. Comb bining averaage garden plot yields and cost savvings from tthe purchasse of produce (based on market prices) p can help us evaaluate the m monetary vallue of urban n food production n. From m our review w of existingg urban gard dens, we esttimate that their produ uctivity rangees between $20,000 an nd $200,000 0 per hectarre per growiing month. It appears that mixed m fruit and vegetab ble gardenss are at the llow end of tthe producttivity range whilee gardens fo ocused more on flowers, herbs, an d lettuces aare at the higgher end. The productivity p y of an urbaan garden allso dependss on the durration of thee growing seaso on – i.e., the number of months bettween the laast spring frrost and thee first fall frost. We propose p the value of thee food production beneefit be estim mated using the follow wing formu ula: Wherre: • b = annual vaalue of benefit ($/year) • g = duration of o the growing season ((months) • P = productiv vity ($/m2•m month) • a = green roo of area (m2) Soun nd Attenua ation Vegeetated surfacces provide important sound insullation propeerties and aare often emplloyed for their noise reduction pottential in urrban settinggs. Green roo ofs can provide importaant noise red duction opp portunities ffor buildinggs, especially those vvii undeer flight path hs or elevatted transit systems. Hed donic pricin ng and contiingent valuaation metho odologies haave both beeen employeed to assess the social ccosts of noisse and estimate e vallues for noisse reduction n measuress such as greeen roof impleementation. Soun nd attenuation provided d by a green n roof will d depend on th he properties of the choseen substrate and on thee substrate’’s thickness . In the abseence of dataa on the noisee attenuatio on propertiees of differen nt substratees with diffeerent thickn nesses, we propose a low (5 5 dB attenuation) and a high scenaario (13 dB attenuation n) based on Conn nelly & Hodg gson’s (2008) findings on the soun nd attenuatiion of 75 mm m and 150 mm green g roof substrates. s The T aforementioned fin ndings are tthose for low w- and mid-rangee frequenciees; we assum me that most ambient noise in an urban setting falls into o this category. c We W assume th hat a green roof would primarily rreduce noisees from overh head sourcees, such air traffic t and elevated e roaadways and d trains; it w would have little or no effectt on street level traffic noise. Thuss, the benefit would onlly accrue to properties affectted by overhead noise. When n using the hedonic priicing technique, the cosst of noise iss measured d by the Noisee Sensitivity y Depreciatiion Index (N NSDI), which representts the averaage perceentage decrrease in totaal property value v per 1--decibel inccrease in noise level abov ve a baselinee level. Baseed on the fin ndings of Baateman et all (2000), forr propertiess near airports or under airport flight paaths, we proopose using an NSDI of 0.33%; for properties near elevated ro oadways or railways r thaat are abovee roof level,, we proposse using g an NSDI off 0.64%. We assume a that a green roo of would only affect noiise levels on nly on the to op floor of the building. b Forr the purposse of estimaation, we asssume that eeach floor iss worth an equaal portion off the total prroperty valu ue. Hence, th he value of the top floo or is the totaal property value divided d by the t number of storeys. p the value of thee sound atteenuation beenefit be esttimated usin ng the We propose follow wing formu ula: Wherre: • b ($/yeear) b = value of benefit • d n index (/d dB) NSSDI = noise sensitivity depreciatio • n = green roo of sound atteenuation (d dB) • h = building height h (storeys) • v= = property value v ($) viiii Using g the valuess given abov ve for the low attenuatiion scenario o and for airr traffic, we obtaiin: b = (0 0.0033 dB)⋅ (5dB)⋅ = 0.0165⋅ 0 v h v h Stormwater Re etention Vegeetated surfacces on roofttops can rettain consideerable amou unts of storm mwater and d reduce peak flow ws into the stormwater s r system during storm events. Lesss peak runoff means that new storm sewer sy ystems can h have a smalller capacityy or existingg systeems can sup pport more developmen d nt before beeing upgrad ded, which trranslates to o lower capital exp penditures for develop pers and mu unicipalitiess. Lower peaak flows mean ns lower exp penditures by the municipality in erosion con ntrol measu ures along streaams and riveers. Thus, we w propose that t the ben nefit of this m measure bee estimated by caalculating th he avoided cost c of expanding storm mwater treaatment facilities and in erosiion control measures. For the t stormwaater retentio on benefit, Cunningham C m (2001) prrovides figu ures for the cost of o three typ pes of storm mwater reten ntion infrasttructure, including: a surface storm m water reteention pond d, valuated at a $20.13/m m3 of stormw water; mixeed at-grade BMPs, valuated at $212.15//m3 of storm mwater; and d an undergground reten ntion basin,, 3 nefit, the Cityy of valuaated at $1,059.44/m of stormwateer. For the eerosion ben Wateerloo (2005) estimates that conven ntional storrmwater maanagement infrastructure reelated to ero osion control requires a one-time expenditurre of 3.66/m3 of stormwater.. C$13 The values v per unit u of area of the green n roof of thee stormwateer services tthat we are consiidering depend criticallly on the waater retentiion capacityy of the greeen roof. For estim mation purposes, we wiill assume an a average rretention caapacity of 42 2.7L/m2roof, as ussed by Carteer and Keeleer (2008), which w we takke to be a tyypical figuree for an exten nsive green roof. We propose p the value of thee storm watter retention n benefit bee estimated using the follow wing equatiion: Wherre: • b ($) b = value of benefit iix • R = stormwatter retention n cost ($/m m3water) • E = erosion mitigation m co ost ($/m3watter) • C= average green g roof reetention cap pacity (m3waater/m2roof) • a = green roo of area (m2rooof) Using g the valuess for stormw water retenttion cost (foor the cheap pest alternative, a reten ntion pond) and erosion n mitigation n cost given n above, we get: Air Q Quality Green plants abssorb gaseou us pollutantts through th heir leaf sto omates (porres). Vegeetations can also capturre some of th he particulaate matter in the air. Byy mitigatingg the heat h island effect, e urban n vegetation n can furtheer help reduce smog givven that higheer temperattures favourr smog form mation. Air p pollution ad dds to the bu urden of thee healtth care systeem, causes disabilities d or prematu ure death, an nd reduces tthe productivity of the t workforrce. In orderr to assess th he economiic value of this service, we caan estimatee the avoided cost of health care. The critical c deteerminants of a green roof’s capacitty to mitigatte pollution and yield healtth benefits include its area a and thee mix of plan nt species th hat is used, as some speciies absorb more m pollutaants than otthers. Otherr factors incclude the levvels of air pollu ution at the given g locatiion and the climate. In tterms of thee latter, the pollution mitig gation proviided by the green roof may m be limiited outsidee the growin ng season, partiicularly if it is covered with w snow. We W take a sseven-month h growing sseason to bee the baseline b casee. We have h calculated values for f the pollu utant removval health beenefit usingg Yang, Yu and Gong’s G (200 08) and Kow wal’s (2008)) findings (ssee Table S-1). Table e S‐1 ‐ Value e of annual p pollutant rem moval healtth benefit fo or different ttypes of 2 green n roof vegettation (US$//m ∙year) Type o of vegetation SO2 N02 PM M10 O3 Total x Short G Grass Tall He erbaceous Plantss Decidu uous Trees 0..0010725 0..0013695 0..0016665 0.0157275 0.0198450 0.0240975 0.00504 0.00684 0.00972 0.0303075 0.0392175 0.0483975 0.05221 0.06773 0.08339 Combining data from Yang, Yu an nd Gong (2008 8) and Kowal (2008) We propose p the following fo ormula for estimating e tthe annual vvalue of thee health beneefit of pollution mitigatiion provided by green rroofs: Wherre: • b = value of benefit b ($/yeear) • g = growing season s (mon nths) • Hsg b for sh hort grass p pollution ab bsorption ($ $/m2•year) s = health benefit • asgg = green ro oof area cov vered by shoort grass (m m2) • Htg b for taall grass* poollution abssorption ($//m2•year) t = health benefit • atgg = green ro oof area covered by talll grass* (m2) • Hd = health beenefit for deeciduous plaant pollutio on absorptio on ($ $/m2•year) • ad = green roo of area coveered by deciiduous plan nts (m2) *tall herbaceouss plant Using g the annuaal pollutant removal r vallues cited in n the table, w we obtain: GHG G Sequestra ation A furrther benefit of green ro oofs and oth her green in nfrastructurre is their ab bility to captu ure and storre – i.e., sequ uester – carrbon dioxidee. Valuatingg the carbon n dioxide sequestration beenefit of greeen infrastru ucture entaails estimating the margginal social cost of o damages that would d have been caused duee to temperaature increaases if not for th he sequestraation carrieed out by thee vegetation n involved. xxi Our formula f for estimating the value of sequestereed carbon iss based on tthe findingss of thee David Suzzuki Foundaation (see Taable S-2). W We assume th hat the annual carbon uptak ke of these types t of veggetation is the same on n a green roo of as at grad de. As the meth hodologies reviewed r esstimate the sequestratio s on value of trees on a large scale basiss (square killometres orr hectares), and becaus e the valuess are relativvely small, we use hectares rather than n meters as units of areea. Table e S‐2 ‐ Carbo on sequestraation values per hectaree for Greateer Golden Ho orseshoe Greenbelt land tyypes Stored carbon Annual carbon uptake Forest Grassland d Agriculturral Lands Cropland Idle land Hedgerow ws Orchards 919 $2 213 $3332 $317 $3228 $2998 $9 $39.11 $28..46 N N/A $28.59 $28.559 $28.559 Source: David Suzuki Foundation n, 2008 We propose p the following fo ormula for calculating c the value off annual carrbon sequestration prrovided by a green roof: Wherre: • b = value of benefit b ($/yeear) • Sd = value of carbon c sequ uestration b by deciduou us plants ($//ha•year) • ad = area of grreen roof co overed by d deciduous pllants (ha) • Sg = value of carbon c sequ uestration b by grasses ($$/ha•year) • ag = area of grreen roof co overed by grasses (ha) • Sf = value of carbon c sequ uestration byy productivve agriculturre ($ $/ha•year) • af = area of grreen roof co overed by prroductive crrops (ha) • asgg = area of green g roof covered c by sshort grassees (ha) • atgg = area of green g roof covered by ttall grasses (ha) Note: xxii 4 Case Studies In this section, we apply the methodologies developed in the last section to five case studies in order to estimate the actual benefits associated with these green roofs under realistic conditions. The information for these scenarios is drawn from sources such as Steven Peck's 2008 book AwardWinningGreenRoofDesigns, project web sites, and interviews with architects and developers. The case studies were chosen in order to represent a variety of building types and locations. Together, they provide opportunities for the use of all the calculation methods presented in the last section. 901 Cherry Avenue, San Bruno, CA The 901 Cherry Avenue building houses offices of the clothing maker GAP Inc. The building includes a number of sustainable design features, of which the centerpiece is an undulating 6,400 m2 (69,000 sq ft) semi-extensive green roof. The roof features a 15 cm (6”) growing medium planted with grasses and wildflowers native to the San Francisco Bay Area. A notable feature of the 901 Cherry building is that it is located under the flight path of air traffic landing at the San Francisco International airport and, as such, is exposed to considerable overhead noise. The green roof helps provide an acoustic barrier that attenuates sound transmission from aircraft taking off from and landing at the airport. benefit sound attenuation stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration type one time one time annual annual value $303,829 – $783,101 $9,216 – $293,248 $568/year $18/year Fairmont Waterfront Hotel, Vancouver, BC The Fairmont Waterfront Hotel is a luxury hotel on the downtown Vancouver waterfront. When the hotel was built in 1991, a green roof with ivy and pea gravel paths was initially installed on the large third floor terrace on the building’s south side; the hotel has a total of 23 storeys. The southern portion of the terrace was converted to an herb garden in 1994. The garden is maintained year round and harvested between late march and late fall by the hotel’s restaurant staff. The produce is used primarily in the hotel restaurant but consumers also include hotel staff and patrons. benefit property value (host) type one time value $7,593,888 xiii property value (neighbour) food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration one time annual one time annual annual $4,409,406 $3,121 ‐ $31,210 $281 ‐ $8,939 $11.54 ‐ $18.73 $0.56 ‐ $0.76 401 Richmond, Toronto, ON Originally constructed in 1899, the building’s 18,580 m2 (200,000 sq ft) floor area now houses over 140 artists and entrepreneurs. In 1998, a 603.9 m2 (65,000 sq ft) cedar deck was constructed on a portion of the roof and covered with numerous planters with flowers, bushes, and vines. In 2005, a further 241.5 m2 (2,600 sq ft) of the roof were covered with a lightweight extensive green roof system, consisting of a 2-inch growing medium planted with sedum. The 401 Richmond roof garden has attracted a considerable amount of attention from the media in Toronto, providing publicity for the company that owns and manages the building, and indirectly for the building’s tenants. Residents living in the 14-storey District Lofts building, directly across Richmond Street enjoy the view onto the 401 Richmond roof garden. benefit property value (host building) property value (neighbouring condo unit) marketing stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration type value one time $1,379,756 one time $24,482 one time one time annual annual $83,126 $1,217 ‐ $38,736 $43.79 ‐ $71.01 $2.41 ‐ $3.31 Rooftop Victory Gardens, Chicago, IL The 163.5 m2 (1,760 sq ft) Rooftop Victory Garden is hosted by True Nature Foods, an organic food cooperative and neighbourhood recycling centre in the Edgewater district on the north side of Chicago. Urban Habitat Chicago (UHC), a local non-profit group promoting sustainable practices in urban environments, initiated the project in 2005. The first harvest occurred in the summer of 2007. The produce grown during the 2007 and 2008 seasons was mostly distributed among project volunteers and some was sold at the store below. benefit property value (host) property value (neighbour) proximity to productive garden type one time one time value $7,057 $20,660 xiv property value (neighbour) view onto green roof marketing food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration one time $9,546 one time annual one time annual annual $2,289 – $22,890 $235 – $7,491 $8.47 – $13.73 $0.47 – $0.64 The Louisa, Portland, OR The Louisa is a residential high-rise apartment building with 242 apartments and ground floor retail, situated in the historic Pearl District of downtown Portland. The Louisa building is composed of a large podium at the base, which houses the retails spaces, and a tower set at the back of the podium, which contains the bulk of the apartments. The green roof is situated on top of the podium and can therefore be viewed directly from at least half of the apartments in the tower. The green roof features both extensive and intensive components. The larger (749.8 m2) portion of the roof is an accessible recreational rooftop garden with intensive vegetation. The garden is flanked on either side by non-accessible extensive green roofs (292.5 m2 each). These are two storeys higher than the garden as they sit on top of two-storey townhouse units facing into the garden. Both the intensive and extensive portions are planted with drought-tolerant native species, which can withstand Portland’s relatively dry summers with minimal watering. benefit property value (view) type value one time $2,189,385 $5,641,117 property value (accessible recreational garden) one time stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration one time annual annual $1,922 ‐ $61,156 $88.89 ‐ $144.15 $3.80 ‐ $5.22 5 Conclusions This report has provided evidence that soft benefits produce economic advantages for individual property owners, municipalities, and society at large. Despite the fact that the benefits depend on the local context, we have provided heuristic methods to estimate the economic value associated with seven soft-benefits. These are methods that can be used by property owners, developers, architects, municipal officials, and xv other stakeholders with information that is often readily-at-hand. The reader should keep in mind the assumptions that had to be made in order to arrive at these quick calculation methods. Some of these assumptions, along with the beneficiaries, benefiting period, and a short statement of the valuation method appear in the Table S-3. xvi Table S‐3 ‐ Summary of Soft Benefit Valuations Benefit Category Beneficiaries Assumptions Property Value Type Valuation view onto a green roof property owner* and/or neighbours independent of area one‐time recreational garden property owner independent of area one‐time property owner occupant access, independent of area one‐time up to 7% property value neighbours (adjacent) public access, independent of area one‐time up to 7% property value neighbours (150 m) public access, independent of area one‐time up to 5% property value neighbours (300 m) public access, independent of area one‐time up to 2% property value one‐time see Table 3 productive garden up to 4.5% property value (portion above green roof) up to 11% property value Marketing property owner Food production property owner excluding labour and material costs ongoing $2‐$20/m2 per growing month Sound attenuation property owner affects top floor only, air traffic noise only, independent of area but assuming extensive coverage one‐time 1.6% to 4.3% property value of top floor Stormwater retention developer, municipality 42.7L/m2 retention capacity one‐time $1.44/m2 to 2 $45.82/m Air quality municipality, state ongoing $521/ha to $839/ha per year GHG sequestration municipality, state ongoing $28/ha to $39/ha per year *If the green roof can be seen from at least part of the host property The case studies presented in this report show that the proposed valuation methodologies can be applied in real-life situations without requiring large (or difficult to obtain) data inputs. In general, the valuations returned by applying the methodologies seem to be of a reasonable magnitude. Among the one-time benefits proposed here, the property value benefits are by far the most significant. Properties with accessible green roofs are subject to a 11% property value premium, while those with rooftop food gardens gain 7% in property value. Neighbours of both types of green roofs also stand to benefit significantly from their presence. Those who have views onto a green roof could gain up to 4.5% of property value, while those adjacent to rooftop food gardens could gain from 2% to 7%. It should be noted that the sum of the all the property value gains accruing to xvii neighbouring properties could be considerably larger than the value of the benefit accruing to the host property. Sound attenuation offers one-time benefits on a similar order of magnitude, ranging from a 1.6% to a 4.3% property value premium on the value of the top floor. However, this benefit only arises if there is a significant source of overhead noise, such as air traffic or an elevated train nearby. As for the marketing benefit, also a one-time benefit, the experience of the 401 Richmond building in Toronto suggests that it is relatively small – 0.6% of property value in this case. The value of the stormwater management benefit varies considerably when viewed as a fraction of property value. In the 401 Richmond case, for example, it is estimated to be worth between 0.01% and 0.28% of property value, whereas in the case of the True Nature Foods Victory Garden, it is estimated to be worth 0.2% to 6.9% of the property value. This benefit is not tied to property value but rather to the area of the green roof; True Nature Foods has low property value but a relatively large roof and the stormwater benefit is therefore much larger relative to property value. Where ongoing benefits are concerned, the food production benefit is much more valuable than the air quality and GHG sequestering benefits, according to our methods of estimation. We propose that the value of the food produced on a rooftop garden is worth $2 to $20 per square metre per month in the growing season. As most of the North American population lives in places where the growing season is at least 6 months long, the benefit is therefore worth at the very least $12/m2 of rooftop growing area per year. In places with a year-round growing season, such as in the southern coastal states, the benefit could be worth up to $240/m2 per year. In contrast, the air quality benefit is worth between $0.0521/m2 to $0.0839/m2 per year and the GHG sequestration benefit is worth $0.0028/m2 to $0.0039/m2 per year. The difference between food production and air quality/GHG benefits is well illustrated by the two case studies that feature rooftop food production. On the Fairmont Waterfront Hotel herb garden, food production is estimated to be worth $3,121 to $31,210 per year, while air quality improvement is worth $11.54-$18.73 per year and GHG sequestration is worth a mere $0.56-$0.76 per year. On the True Nature Foods Rooftop Victory Garden, food production is estimated to be worth $2,289 to $22,890 per year, while air quality improvement is worth $8.47-$13.73 per year and GHG sequestration is worth a mere $0.47-$0.64 per year. Given how small the air quality and GHG sequestration benefits are, it is almost meaningless to include them in an assessment of the benefit values for individual green roofs. Both of these benefits would be more meaningful if calculated for numerous green roofs covering a substantial portion of a neighbourhood or city. For example, as reported above, Bating et al (2005) calculated that if all flat rooftops across the City of Toronto were extensively greened, the annual cost savings xviii attributable to reduction in air pollution would amount to US$1,970,000 (C$2,700,000 in 2008). Readers are reminded that the methodologies offered here are heuristic in nature; they are rough estimations based on a number of assumptions that are reasonable in most cases but may not be applicable in specific contexts. Changes in the assumptions will of course lead to a different evaluation of benefits. Also, the report provides calculation methods for a range of greenroof conditions. These are meant to serve as benchmarks only and of course do not cover all potential situations. The user is asked to use their own best judgment as to whether and how the assumptions made and range of conditions covered in this report can be usefully applied or adapted to their own unique situation. As already noted, the goal of this report was to allow users to make rough calculations of benefits without undertaking a major research effort. For the most part, this has been achieved: the equations require data that is usually readily available such as property value, building height, roof area, and so on. The sole exception is the marketing benefit, which requires detailed information on publicity gained due to the green roof. Our experience with the case studies suggests that most green roof property owners do not have precise information on media coverage, if they track it at all. Future research might address this by tacking media coverage across many green roof projects and generating a more generic formula for estimating the value of the marketing benefit. To our knowledge, this is the first attempt in the growing literature on green roofs to offer a means for calculating the value of a range of soft benefits associated with the use of the technology. Clearly, however, it is not the last word. Future research may not only allow us to refine the approaches offered here but to expand the range of soft benefits covered to include, for example, habitat creation and community building. If this report has helped put us on this path, then it has served its purpose. Bibliography Bateman, I., Day, B., Lake, I., & Lovett, A. (2000). TheEffectofRoadTrafficon ResidentialPropertyValues:ALiteratureReviewandHedonicPricingStudy. Edinburgh: Scottish Office, Development Department. Carter, T. & Keeler, A. (2008). Life-cycle cost–benefit analysis of extensive vegetated roof systems. JournalofEnvironmentalManagement 87, 350-363. City of Waterloo (2005). GreenRoofFeasibilityStudyandCityWideImplementation Plan. Public document (http://www.city.waterloo.on.ca/Portals/57ad7180-c5e7- xix 49f5-b282c6475cdb7ee7/LIBRARY_Plans_documents/GRReport2005Complete.pdf). Connelly, M. & Hodgson, M. (2008). Sound Transmission Loss of Extensive Green Roofs - Field Test Results. Acoustics Week in Canada, October 6-8, 2008. Vancouver, BC: Canadian Acoustical Association. Crompton, J. (2005). The Impact of Parks on Property Values: Empirical Evidence from the Past two Decades in the United States. ManagingLeisure 10(4), 203-21. Cunnigham, N. (2001). RethinkingtheUrbanEpidermis:astudyoftheviabilityof extensivegreenroofsystemsintheManitobacapitalwithanemphasisonregional casestudiesandstormwatermanagement. Master’s thesis dissertation, Department of Landscape Architecture, University of Manitoba, Winnipeg, Manitoba. David Suzuki Foundation (2008). Ontario’sWealth,Canada’sFuture:Appreciating theValueoftheGreenbelt’sEco‐Services. Public document (http://www.davidsuzuki.org/files/Conservation/DSF-Greenbelt-web.pdf). Kowal, C. (2008). Measuring Urban Green. TheNewPlanner, Winter (http://www.planning.org/thenewplanner/2008/win/measuringurbangreen.htm) Peck, S. (2008). AwardWinningGreenRoofDesigns. Toronto: Green Roofs for Healthy Cities. Voicu, I. & Been, V. (2008). The Effect of Community Gardens on Neighboring Property Values. RealEstateEconomics36(2), 281-243. Watcher, S. (2004). TheDeterminantsofNeighborhoodTransformationsin Philadelphia‐IdentificationandAnalysis:TheNewKensingtonPilotStudy. University of Pennsylvania, The Wharton School. Yang, J., Yu, Q., & Gong, P. (2008). Quantifying air pollution removal by green roofs in Chicago. AtmosphericEnvironment 42, 7266-7273. xx 1 Introduction The use of green roofs can offer a tangible solution to many challenges faced by communities across Canada today. Vegetated surfaces offer social and environmental benefits to building occupants and owners, municipal governments and surrounding communities, from improved stormwater management, habitat creation, absorption of air pollutants, and reduced energy requirements, to crime reduction, community building, and opportunities for food production. In short, the implementation of green roofs can improve the overall functionality of the ecosystem, contribute to economic efficiency, and enhance the quality of human life. Articulating the value of the numerous environmental and social services of green roofs in monetary terms provides an estimate of their contribution to local and regional economies and permits governments, land developers and building owners to assess short- and long-term public and private gains. While some benefits are directly measurable and have ‘hard’ values (such as the energy savings due the insulation provided by the soil and vegetation of a green roof), many benefits are not readily measurable and their values are difficult to estimate (such as the health benefits of a rooftop garden). For the purpose of this study, those benefits that are not directly measurable (or calculated based on any line item on the buildings budget) will be defined as ‘soft’ benefits. Green roofs and other green infrastructure1 have traditionally been thought of as cost centres that contribute little or no economic benefit. However, recent work in the field of environmental economics has brought to light the vital economic contribution that green infrastructure makes in terms of providing "services" (such as purifying water and air) to society and individuals alike.2 Excluding soft benefits from assessments of the value of green roofs could lead to a underestimation of their real benefit to society and less policy attention devoted to promoting the infrastructure that gives rise to them. Moreover, without a quantified value, soft benefits cannot be objectively classified or compared to one another or other benefits, making rational decisions about the best return on public and private investment difficult to make. Soft benefit valuation is therefore a critical undertaking to better inform public policy initiatives and private development decisions. By considering soft benefits, we obtain a more complete picture of all the direct and indirect impacts of green roofs on individual buildings, on their 1 Green infrastructure includes wetlands, urban forests and parks, green roofs, community gardens, vegetated swales, rain gardens and other natural or constructed vegetated areas that perform environmental ecological services for surrounding human populations. 2 Costanza (1998) has estimated that the world’s ecosystem services provide a benefit in the range of US$16 – 54 trillion (10) per year, with an average of US$33 trillion per year. Global gross national product total is around US$18 trillion per year. surroundings, and on society at large. The purpose of this report is to provide methodologies and case studies that can offer guidance in attributing economic value to selected soft benefits of green roofs. Since very few studies to date have focused directly on the economic valuation of green roof soft benefits, we draw where necessary on studies related to other types of green infrastructure. It is important to note that our intention here is to offer methodologies that can be easily employed by stakeholders with limited information about the property concerned. In other words, our goal is to put forward heuristic methods that can be used with data that is usually readily at hand. Needless to say, this approach entails a trade-off between ease of use and the level of detail and precision. Keeping this in mind, the results obtained with the proposed methods should be applied prudently. 2 2 Valuation Methodologies The soft benefits of green roofs are not directly tradable and therefore do not have directly measurable monetary values. To determine their monetary value, nonmarket or indirect valuation techniques must be employed. Estimating the total economic value of a non-market good or service entails calculating the sum of all values associated with that good or service. The two main categories of value are use and non-use values. Use values can either be direct or indirect. Direct use value refers to the value that is derived from actual or planned use of a particular environmental service or good. Recreation and food production are two examples of direct use values. Indirect use value occurs when people benefit from an environmental amenity without consciously using it. Water filtration, climate regulation are examples of the indirect use values of environmental amenities. Nonuse value refers to the value that individuals place on an environmental amenity without having any planned use for it. An example of a non-use value is the intrinsic value that people attribute to an environmental amenity (like the boreal forest) simply for its existence. The methods used to estimate non-use values are considerably more complex and are beyond the scope of this report. Non-market valuation techniques have been developed in order to estimate the net value that the public or individuals attribute to environmental amenities such as green infrastructure. Three general categories of nonmarket valuation methodologies exist. The first category,revealed preference methods (i.e., travel cost, hedonic pricing, market comparables, and cost avoidance) uses behaviours and information observed in markets to estimate non-market values. The second category, stated preference methods, which includes the contingent valuation technique, attributes economic value by asking people their willingness to pay for a service or willingness to accept compensation to voluntarily forgo a service. The third category is avoided cost analysis, which can be used to determine the value of green infrastructure by quantifying the costs that would be incurred if the services provided by the infrastructure were not available or had to be provided by building conventional infrastructure. Table 1 presents a summary of non-market valuation methods explored in this report and the strengths and limitations of each. The methodologies and specific valuation frameworks applicable to green infrastructure benefit valuation are outlined in greater detail below. 3 Table 1 ‐ Non‐market valuation techniques Methodology Hedonic pricing Market comparables Contingent Valuation Avoided Cost Analysis Description Assumes that the environmental characteristics (e.g., a pleasant view or the disamenity of a nearby landfill site), as well as other property features, are reflected in property prices. The value of the environmental component can therefore be captured by modeling the impact of all possible influencing factors on the price of the property. Hedonic pricing can measure direct and indirect use value. Uses data on the price of similar goods or services that are traded in the market as a proxy for willingness‐to‐pay. Typically administered through a public survey. Consumer or clients are asked how much they would be willing to pay for a good or service, or how much they would be willing to accept in compensation for its loss. Uses cost of replacing ecosystem services with conventional infrastructure, or avoided health costs to estimate value of ecosystem services. Value captured Strengths Limitations Direct and Indirect use Based on market data and prices – relatively important figures. Very data‐intensive approach to economic valuation (e.g.: identifying all relevant attributes for a particular good). Choosing the appropriate variables is difficult. Direct and indirect use Market data readily available and robust Limited to benefits for which markets exist. Use and non‐ use Captures use and non‐use ecosystem functions Based on individual responses, people tend to under‐value amenities. Direct and indirect use Costs can often be estimated from market prices Avoided costs do not necessarily reflect the social value of an ecosystem service. Source: Adapted from DEFRA, 2007 p.37 2.1 Revealed Preference Methodologies Revealed preference methodologies are relevant for estimating the monetary benefit accrued to occupants and/or owners of a building as a result of the addition of a green roof. These methodologies rely on observed market behaviours - i.e., how much people actually pay for existing goods and services available on the market. Prices of non-market goods are inferred by associating them with consumers’ purchase decisions using a defined theoretical framework. Below, three revealed preference methods are described: hedonic pricing, travel cost, and market comparables. 2.1.1 Hedonic Pricing Hedonic pricing is a methodology that has been extensively used to estimate the economic value ascribed to various non-market environmental goods and services 4 such as air and water quality, aesthetic views and proximity to green spaces or recreational sites. It is most commonly used to evaluate the individual contribution of environmental amenities on real estate prices. The technique regards a good as a set of attributes and considers the total economic value of that good as the sum of values of each attribute. First, a good or service must be decomposed into its constituent attributes. Regression analysis is then used to estimate the individual contribution of each attribute to the total value of the good. The hedonic pricing model is usually expressed using the following function (Hidano, 2002): valueofagood = (valueofattribute1) (quantityofattribute1) + (valueofattribute2) (quantityofattribute2) + …+ (valueofattributen) (quantityofattributen) Variations in real estate value are dependent on a large number of factors. Hedonic pricing models have estimated the variations based in the following attributes: the square footage of a property, the age of the property, number of bedrooms, number of bathrooms, number of units, number of storeys, distance from the central business district (CBD), transportation access and the neighbourhood’s socioeconomic characteristics. Hedonic pricing may be used to estimate direct and indirect use values. One shortcoming of the hedonic pricing approach is that it’s a very data intensive methodology. Identifying every relevant attribute that makes up the total value of a good can be a long and difficult process. 2.1.2 Market Comparables The market comparables method examines the amount that is charged and paid for by consumers of a good or service traded in the market that is comparable to the one being assessed. When a good or service is provided in the private sector, charges collected by firms offer good proxies for people’s willingness to pay for a similar good or service that is offered for free or below market price through the public sector. Private sector market comparables provide good estimates of the value of a non-market good given that they are based on the actual cost of provision and consumer preferences and demand for this good. When no similar good or service is provided by the private sector, values can be derived from charges collected by public sector providers such as municipal, provincial or federal levels of governments (e.g., park entrance fees). In most cases, these institutions will charge well below market rates or actual willingness to pay for a good or service. For this reason, the prices charged by public sector providers are usually well below people’s willingness to pay and should be considered as the absolute minimum value of a good or service. 2.2 Stated Preference Methodologies Stated preference methodologies attribute monetary value to environmental goods 5 and services based on people’s stated preferences rather than their observed behaviour. Surveys are used to collect information about how much an individual is willing to pay for a particular environmental good or service. The technique can also be used for assessing order of preference for a set of goods. A number of problems have been associated with stated preferences methods. One critique is that people are potentially unwilling or unable to express willingness to pay truthfully or accurately - i.e., there can be a discrepancy between how much people state they are willing to pay and how much they actually pay for a given good or service, resulting in inaccurate estimates of that good’s or service’s monetary value. Nevertheless, this valuation method is useful in estimating the value of goods and services that are not sold on the market. This can include goods and services that are provided by the public sector for free or below cost. It can also include goods and services that are not widely available and for which revealed preferences therefore cannot be observed (Champ et al., 2003). The most common stated preference methodology is contingent valuation. Surveys are used to ask people how much they are willing to pay for a particular environmental service or good. Alternately, the public can be asked how much they would be willing to accept in compensation for the loss of an environmental amenity. Contingent valuation is the economic valuation technique most commonly employed when revealed preferences techniques are not applicable. Contingent valuation could be applied, for example, to a project to enhance a freshwater wetland, which would improve sport fishing opportunities. The direct beneficiaries are people who fish recreationally. Valuation would be used to estimate the maximum that anglers would pay for this improvement in fishing. Each angler’s expression of his or her maximum willingness to pay represents how much the angler is prepared to compensate the rest of society for the increased individual enjoyment gained from the improved recreational fishing. Maximum willingness to pay is aggregated for all anglers who benefit to determine whether the benefits of the wetland project exceed the costs, which facilitates an assessment of whether public funds should be spent on the project. 2.3 Avoided Cost Methodologies In circumstances where an ecological service is difficult to value by any of the above methods, analysts advocate using avoided cost methodologies. This approach can be used to determine the value of green roofs and other green infrastructure by quantifying the costs that would be incurred if the services were to be provided with conventional infrastructure. For example, the presence of a wetland may reduce the cost of municipal water treatment for drinking water because the wetland system filters and removes pollutants. We can therefore use the cost of an alternative treatment method, such as the building and operation of an industrial water treatment plant, to represent the value of the wetland’s natural water treatment service (De Groot, 1992). 6 It is important to note that this method does not provide a direct estimate of the value of the ecological service to the public, but only the cost of replacing that service if it were lost. It is a valid approach if the human-made alternatives are equivalent in quantity and magnitude to the natural functions; the alternative is the least-cost alternative method of performing the function; and individuals in aggregate would be willing to incur these costs to obtain the services (DEFRA, 2007). 7 3 Valuation of Benefits This section presents methodologies for valuating a variety of soft benefits that accrue to green roofs. While our primary focus is on green roofs, we include information related to other forms of green infrastructure if the information is readily transferrable to green roofs. The purpose here is to provide readers with non-technical methods for estimating the soft benefits associated with a green roof project based on readily available information and without the need for undertaking major research. The benefits that are included here are those for which we could find relatively straightforward valuation methods that could be applied by non-specialists with limited resources for data gathering. The proposed methods were gathered from current practices and the existing literature. The benefits covered are: • • • • • • • property value increases marketing sound attenuation food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration For each benefit, we discuss the nature of the benefit, review existing practices and literature that contributes to an understanding of the monetary value of the benefit, and offer a method that could be used by non-specialists to estimate the value of that benefit in a given context. It is important to note that the methodologies offered here are heuristic in nature; they are rough estimations based on a number of assumptions that are reasonable in most cases but may not be applicable in specific contexts. The assumptions are clearly stated in the description of each methodology below. The user is asked to use their own best judgment as to whether the methods provided can be usefully applied or adapted to their own unique situation (e.g., length of growing season, depth of growing medium, or mix of plant types). For most of the benefits included in this report, values for a reasonable range of situations is provided for readers to consider when evaluating the benefits of a specific green roof. The ranges provided are benchmarks only and of course do not cover all potential situations. Although all soft benefits tend to be context-specific to some degree, some benefits are simply too context-specific to include in an analysis of this type and are excluded from the following analysis. Examples of excluded soft benefits are improved 8 aesthetics, crime reduction, increased biodiversity, and building a sense of community. The different benefits covered in this section accrue to different stakeholders; some go to the owner(s) of the building on which the green roof is found (e.g., property value increases), others go to the municipality (e.g., stormwater retention), while some go to the regional (e.g., air quality improvements) or planetary (e.g., greenhouse gas mitigation) population. Benefits accrue either on a one-time basis (such as an increase in property value) or an annual basis (such as greenhouse gas mitigation). It is important to note that the methods presented below are intended to calculate the gross value of the benefits considered. The methods do not account for the costs involved in producing the benefits. In particular, we do not account for the extra costs involved in creating a green roof compared to a conventional roof. In the case of benefits that consist of an increase in property value, we do not consider the higher property taxes that could be applied as a result. In the case of food production, we do not account for direct inputs such as the cost of materials and labour. All monetary values given below are in US dollars unless stated otherwise. Where possible and relevant, we have adjusted the values for inflation to show the value in 2008 dollars. 3.1 Property value increase Green infrastructure investments have been shown to positively affect the property value of nearby real estate. In the case of green roofs, this benefit would accrue to the owner or owners of a building with a green roof and, to a lesser degree, to owners of surrounding properties. As property taxes are in most cases proportional to property value, a benefit in the form of increased property tax revenues can accrue to municipalities. Miller (2001), Morancho (2003), Voicu & Been (2008), Edwards (2007) and Wachter (2004) have all used the hedonic pricing methodology to measure the relationship between the selling price of a residence and its distance from an urban greenspace, park, community garden or wetland. Although it is a very data intensive methodology, the hedonic pricing model is the most common method used to measure the impact on property values from nearby green infrastructure. Essentially, the hedonic pricing model estimates the impact of green infrastructure on real estate market value by comparing properties that differ with respect to their distance from an amenity such as a park, wetland, open space or community garden. The positive relationship between the relative value of a dwelling and its distance from green infrastructure elements is called the proximity principle (Edwards, 2007). The proximity principal suggests that the value of parks and other green infrastructure is captured in the price of surrounding real estate. The value of the amenity is capitalized in the form of home prices and property taxes collected by 9 local governments. Here, we present a few case studies that have estimated the relative impact of green infrastructure investments on property prices using the hedonic pricing model. • Using data on over 3000 property sales between 1980 and 2003 in the New Kensington area of Philadelphia, Wachter (2004) quantified the effect that investing in green infrastructure would have on property values. Specifically, the author looked at the impact of converting vacant lots into green spaces on surrounding home prices. A hedonic regression model was developed that integrated variables on sales and structural characteristics of homes (e.g., date of sale, number of storeys, home size, lot size, elements of location). The model included data on the real estate’s proximity to green infrastructure as well as its distance from disamenities such as vacant lots. Study results suggested that replacing unsightly vacant lots with grass landscapes and trees increased surrounding property values by up to 30 percent. Houses sold within 50 feet from new tree plantings showed a 9 percent increase in property value. In the sample neighbourhood chosen for this study, property value increased by $12 million due to vacant lot conversion and $4 million due to tree plantings. Based on an effective tax rate of 2.64% accumulated over 20 years, the benefits gained from lot improvements and new tree plantings would represent a respective property tax base increase of $6,336,000 and $2,112,000 for the local government (Steve Wise, personal communication). • Also in Philadelphia, the Trust for Public Land (2008 a) used a hedonic pricing model to estimate the effect of proximity to a park on property value. They calculated the total assessed 2007 value of all properties within 500 feet of a park to $4,387,574,062 (or $13,776,982,555 when corrected for under assessment, calculated to 314% around “average parks”). Assuming conservatively that parks contribute on average 5% to the assessed value of properties, it was calculated that the portion of total assessed property value attributed to proximity to parks was $219,378,703 (or $688,849,128 corrected for under assessment). In terms of tax revenues, proximity to parks was calculated to yield additional annual property tax revenues of $82.64 per $1,000 of assessed property value. • Edwards (2007) conducted a similar study in the San Francisco region by dividing homes into two categories; residences that were 500 feet or less of a park and homes located between 500 and 1000 feet of a park. Results from a hedonic pricing model showed that, all else being equal, homes in the former category sold for an average of $125,838 more than residences in the latter category. The author underlines that this is an underestimation of the true premium of urban parks in 10 San Francisco because there is a wide range of other possible economic benefits associated with urban parks such as health benefits, environmental benefits, and revenue generated from special events. • An analysis of about 30 studies exploring the relationship between real estate value and proximity to parks confirmed the argument that parks and open spaces contribute to higher proximate property values (Crompton, 2005). The reviewed studies show that variations in size, usage and design of parkland and differences in residential zones that surround them influence the magnitude of the park proximity premium. In particular, certain studies, such as Miller (2001), have observed that lot size has a significant impact on magnitude of the premium. In general, properties with small lots that presumably have limited private open space appreciate parks more than properties on large lots with generous open space. Such variations notwithstanding, Crompton proposes a 20 percent increase in the value of properties abutting or fronting a park area as a point of departure that decision-makers may use to calculate property value increases attributed to urban green spaces. • Voicu and Been (2008), using a hedonic price model, found that the implementation of new community gardens had a significant impact on surrounding property values in New York City. They studied the effect of property values at four different points in time with respect to the completion of the community garden: at the moment of completion, one year, three years, and five years after completion. In all cases, the effect was calculated for three ranges of distance from the community garden: abutting the garden, up to 500 feet from the garden, and up to 1,000 feet from the garden (see results in Table 2 below). The authors observed that value of properties near community gardens, especially those abutting them, increased over time after implementation. The authors also found that the effect was significantly stronger in low-income areas than in high-income areas. Table 2 ‐ Impacts of a typical community garden on residential property values Time since completion Right after completion 1 year 3 years 5 years Distance to garden site (meters) 0 150 %* $** % 3.4 3,207 2.5 4.1 3,607 2.8 5.6 4,971 3.6 7.4 6,551 4.7 $ 2,191 2,450 3,172 4,111 300 % 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.9 $ 1,355 1,293 1,373 1,670 *percent change in price within ring versus outside the ring **change in price applying the percent change in price to the median per unit sale price of properties sold within the ring 11 Source: Voicu and Been, 2008 The hedonic pricing model would be an ideal technique to calculate green roofs’ effect on property value. Using this method, the value of buildings with green roofs could be compared to that of buildings with conventional roofs while controlling for other variables that are known to have an effect on property value. In the hedonic price model, green roofs could be represented as a single Boolean value, denoting whether the building has a green roof or not. This would be the least data intensive approach but would also provide the least accurate estimate, failing to account for qualitative differences between green roofs. A more accurate approach would be to use a continuous variable, denoting the percentage of the given roof that is green. Additional Boolean variables could be added to represent qualitative differences between green roofs (e.g., extensive versus intensive, accessible versus inaccessible, etc.). At present, however, there are no hedonic studies that have measured the potential of green roofs in increasing the selling price of a condominium or other residential building. In the absence of hedonic pricing studies looking specifically at the effect of green roofs on property values, we must make an estimate using studies performed on other types of green infrastructure. The selection of the appropriate type of green infrastructure for this purpose would depend on the features of the green roof being assessed, i.e., whether the roof is accessible, whether food is grown on it, and whether it is visible from other locations. An accessible green roof could be used in two broad ways: as a recreational space or as a food production space. In the former case, it would seem that the best comparable would be at-grade public parks; in the latter case, the best comparable would be at-grade community gardens. The key difference between rooftop green infrastructure and at-grade green infrastructure is that the former are likely to be accessible only to the occupants or users of the building with the rooftop facility whereas the latter are likely to be accessible to the community at large. Thus, the benefits of rooftop infrastructure accrue mostly, if not exclusively, to the properties on which it is located; the benefits, if any, accruing to neighbouring properties are likely to be limited. In the case of a green roof that is visible from surrounding buildings, however, benefits may accrue to neighbouring properties. In this case, an appropriate comparable would be the value of having a view onto an at-grade park or woodlot. Accessibility to the rooftop would not be a significant consideration in this case. 3.1.1 View onto a Green Roof Assuming that having a view onto a green roof has a similar effect to new tree plantings, the value of the benefit accrued to owners of properties is 9% of the value of the portion of a building that affords a direct view onto a green roof. This is based on Wachter’s (2004) finding that tree planting along a street in front of a property increases the property's value bys up to 9%. Where neighbours of the 12 green rooftop are concerned, we assume that greening a rooftop is equivalent to tree planting at-grade . For them, the greening of the rooftop has much the same effect as tree planting – it adds greenery but does not change the amount of recreational green space to which they have access. We do not attribute any increased value to a green roof without trees. Whole building gain in property value For the purpose of estimating the value of the benefit for a whole building, we assume that only half the neighbouring storeys above the green roof are oriented so as to afford a view onto it. The increase in property value that accrues to a building with a view onto a green roof can therefore be estimated using the following formula: 1 h −h b = 0.09⋅ ⋅ v ⋅ vv 2 hv = 0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vv hv Where: • b = value of benefit ($) • vv= value of neighbouring property with a view onto the green roof ($) • h = height of the green roof host building (storeys) • hv = height of the building with a view onto the green roof (storeys) Single unit gain in property value For the purpose of estimating the value of the benefit for a single unit in a building that has a direct view onto a green roof, we propose using the following formula: b = 0.09⋅ v v 3.1.2 Recreational Rooftop Garden A rooftop garden that is accessible to building dwellers will offer recreational benefits that may be reflected in the value placed on the building. To estimate this value, we turn to studies that have assessed the impact on housing values in locations abutting public parks. Using the hedonic method, Crompton (2005) has suggested that homes adjacent to public parks have about a 20% higher property values than similar homes distant from parks.. Given that an abutting park offers 13 both recreational and view benefits, we deduct the view benefit (9% of property value) calculated above to arrive at a recreational benefit of 11%. We propose the increase in property value yielded by a recreational rooftop garden be estimated using the following formula: b = 0.11⋅ v Where: • b = value of the benefit ($) • v = value of the green roof host property ($) 3.1.3 Productive Rooftop Garden Assuming that having a productive rooftop garden is tantamount to abutting an atgrade community garden, we propose that the value of the long-term benefit accrued to the owner of the property be estimated at 7% of the value of the property. This is based on Voicu and Been’s (2008) finding that, on average, properties abutting typical community gardens increased in value by 7.4% by five years after the construction of the garden. As we do not know from these findings what the effect is in the longer term, we assume the value remains constant at the five-year level. We propose the increase in property value yielded by a private, productive rooftop garden be estimated using the following formula: b =0.07⋅v Where: • b = value of benefit ($) • v = value of green roof host property ($) If the productive rooftop garden is open to non-occupants of the building then it is more likely that benefits will accrue to owners of neighbouring properties. In this case, we assume that the rooftop garden behaves exactly like an at-grade community garden. In the long-term, the value of the benefit accrued to neighbouring property owners is 7% for owners in the building with the rooftop community garden and the immediate vicinity of the host building, 5% for those up to 500 feet away, and 2% for those up to 1,000 feet away. Again, the values are based on Voicu and Been (2008) and assumed to hold at their five-year level. We propose the increase in property value accrued to a neighbouring property of a publicly accessible productive rooftop garden be estimated using the following formula: 14 b = F ⋅v Where: • b = value of benefit ($) • v = property value ($) • d = distance from green roof host property (meters) • F= distance factor (function of d) • F = 0.07 when 0 ≤ d ≤ 5 m • F = 0.05 when 5 m < d ≤ 150 m • F = 0.02 when 150 m < d ≤ 300 m • F= 0 when d > 300 m Let: 3.1.4 Area‐Wide Benefit The above stated formulas are intended for calculating the value of proximity benefits that accrue to individual properties. Municipal decision makers may be more interested in the total, area-wide increase in property values resulting from a green roof project. In this case, it is necessary to sum the values of the benefit accruing to the host property with those accruing to neighbouring properties. b = b total ∑ n Where: • btotal = total area-wide property value benefit ($) • bn = property value benefit of an individual property ($) The property value benefit for each individual property (bn) must be calculated using the appropriate formula for the given case – i.e., recreational or productive rooftop garden, nearby property, or property with a view. In cases where more than one formula applies, both values should be calculated but only the larger of the two should be used in the summation.3 For example, if a building affords views onto a directly adjacent productive rooftop garden, both the productive rooftop garden It is unknown whether these two benefits are additive. In such cases, it is common practice to use the larger of the two benefits. 3 15 formula (3.1.3) and the view onto a green roof formula (Error!Referencesource notfound.) apply. The benefit attributed to proximity to a productive garden will clearly be larger than that attributed to having a view onto it and should therefore be used in the area wide benefit summation. 3.2 Marketing Green infrastructure in general and green roofs in particular not only increase the monetary value of a property due to proximity benefits, but may also improve the marketability of real estate. The mass media and the public’s interest in environmentally friendly products and services is increasing rapidly in Canada. Green roofs and other green infrastructure on or near a building can therefore be considered as a marketing amenity that increases a development’s exposure and enhances the absorption rate of its units. Applying the comparable costs methodology, one way of estimating the marketing benefits of green infrastructure would be to assess the value of the publicity gained as a direct consequence of green infrastructure investments. The two Canadian case studies below illustrate green infrastructure and green roofs’ marketing potential. • Dockside Green, a 15-acre mixed–use community under development in Victoria, British Columbia. The development has focused on maximizing green space and green infrastructure amenities by taking steps such as locating 95 percent of all parking spaces underground, reducing the buildings’ foot print, installing green roofs on residential and commercial buildings, planting over 1,000 trees on the site, converting an adjacent piece of municipal land into a park and reducing or eliminating the need for streets on the property. Garden plots have been installed on the roofs of residential buildings and the connectivity of at-grade green space has ensured its accessibility to Dockside Green residents as well as citizens living outside the community. Dockside green is also integrating green wall elements in the development (City of Victoria, 2005). The project has garnered extensive amounts of media coverage for its green amenities. Since 2005, Dockside Green has benefited from media coverage worth about $5 million. A developer representative reports that they have had greater sales compared to other real estate presentation centers in the area. The first phase of the development is already occupied and 80 percent of units have been sold for the second phase, which is due to open in February 2009 (Martine Desbois, personal communication). • Urbanspace is a property group that owns and operates two heritage buildings in downtown Toronto, which have been retrofitted with green roofs. Robertson Building tenants have access to a 4,000 square feet rooftop garden, which covers approximately half of at the total 16 roof area. The 401 Richmond building has a 2,600 square feet extensive green roof and a 6,500 square feet deck that includes a container garden. This rooftop garden is accessible to both building tenants and the public at large. The roofs were created with the intention of providing common space where people can socialize and relax while improving the general livability of the buildings. Both of the buildings’ green roofs have garnered public attention through media exposure. The building owners have used the media attention the gardens have attracted as a way to market the buildings as a whole. Although Urbanspace has never invested in advertizing campaigns, vacancies in both buildings are rare to non-existent and waiting lists are extensive. Many of the properties’ prospective tenants have heard of the buildings because of the public attention they have gained due to their respective green roofs. Tenants have also expressed that the accessible green roofs are amenities that they value and improves the livability of the buildings. The marketing benefits of green roofs will depend on a number of factors that are unknown in advance or difficult to quantify, such as the current interest of local media in green infrastructure and green buildings. Nonetheless, as the case studies suggest, the marketing benefits can be estimated based on the value of the publicity received due to the presence of the green roof in the project. The value of the free publicity received can be estimated by comparison to the cost of advertizing in three media: radio, television, and print. The cost for each of the three media is broken down into the production cost plus the cost of running the ad. The former can be assumed to be constant as it is a onetime cost. The latter is the cost of having the ad aired on radio and television and printed in newspapers. The value of free publicity can in principle be estimated according to the following formula: b =(pradio + rradio ⋅tradio)+(ptv + rtv ⋅ttv )+(ppaper + rpaper ⋅ l) Where: • b = value of the benefit ($) • pradio = radio ad production cost ($) • rradio = radio ad running cost (airtime) ($/30s spot) • tradio = total radio equivalent airtime (30s spots)* • ptv = tv ad production cost ($) • rtv = tv ad running cost (airtime) ($/30s spot)* 17 • ttv= total tv equivalent airtime (30s spots) • ppaper = newspaper ad production cost ($) • rpaper = newspaper ad running cost (printing) ($/column inch) • l = total equivalent column length (column inches) * Total airtime is divided by 30 to convert to number of spots. Radio and television ad airtime is generally sold in 30-second blocks or ‘spots’. Unlike newspaper ad prices, radio and television ad prices are not published; rather, they are negotiated on an individual basis with every advertiser.4 For both media, ad prices are related to the size of the audience. For a radio station, the size of the audience will depend mostly on the time of day, the size of the market (i.e., the population within the radio broadcast’s reach), and the station’s relative popularity. Single radio spots (i.e., not sold as part of a bundle of several spots) generally range from $50 to $1,000. For television, the size of the audience depends more on the popularity of individual programs than on the popularity of any given station; the programs with the highest ratings command the highest advertizing prices. Spots that run on national networks during weekday prime time range between $80,000 and $600,000 and average around $120,000 per 30-seconds. However, spots on local stations during local programming, such as a local news report, are considerably less expensive. Market research shows that, in the US, the cost of television advertizing is on average US$20 (C$24) per 1,000 viewers (Grover, 2006) but the cost of airing an ad on a local stations in medium markets outside prime time can be as low as US$5 (C$6) per 1,000 viewers or even lower (Gaebler, undated). Thus, a show with 100,000 viewers will command a price in the range of $500 to $2,000 for airing a single 30 second spot. Newspaper space is priced by ‘modular agate lines’ (MALs) in Canada or by column inches in the US (there are 14 MALs per column inch). Generally, the cost of running an ad is proportional to the circulation of the newspaper – a local paper in a small market will have low prices while a leading paper in a large city or a nationally distributed paper will have higher prices. Some national papers (e.g., The Globe and Mail in Canada) run a few local or regional editions with different ads, which are usually priced lower than ads printed nationwide. As real estate ads are generally intended for the local audience, the advertizing prices of local papers or local editions of national papers are more relevant for estimating the value of free publicity. In performing an estimate of the value of free publicity, it would be very difficult to account for all the variations in advertizing cost between different media outlets and 4 We contacted a few television stations, all of which refused to send us their advertizing rate cards stating that they would only send to professional media buyers. 18 different times of day, in the case of radio and television. Ultimately, the key determinant of the cost of radio and television airtime and column inch price in a major newspaper is the size of the market, which is proportional to the population of the area covered by the given radio or television station or the distribution area of a newspaper. For the purpose of estimating free publicity, we propose using the population of the census metropolitan area (CMA) in Canada and of the metropolitan statistical area (MSA) in the US as proxies for market size. We propose that the size of the audience for any of the three media be assumed to be 5% of the metropolitan population. A sample of average advertising costs for the three media are summarized in Table 3 below. Where data was unavailable, costs are estimated. For the cost of television ads, a cost of US$10 per 1,000 viewers was assumed. Table 3 ‐ Average cost of radio, television, and newspaper advertizing in selected cities Radio (30s spot) City Toronto, ON Television (30s spot) Newspaper (column inch) Metro Cost per Cost per Cost per Population Average Average Average 1,000 1,000 1,000 cost cost cost listeners viewers readers 5,555,912 $250 $0.90 $2,778 $10 $392 $1.41 Vancouver, BC 2,285,900 $158 $1.38 $1,143 $10 $199 $1.74 Minneapolis, MN 3,175,041 $173 $1.09 $1,588 $10 $303 $1.91 19,750,000 $1,405 $1.42 $9,875 $10 $1,575 $1.59 New York, NY San Francisco, CA 7,264,887 $899 $2.47 $3,632 $10 $613 $1.69 Seattle, WA 4,038,741 $209 $1.03 $2,019 $10 $365 $1.81 $516 $1.38 $3,506 $10 $597 $1.69 Average Sources: www.gaebler.com, www.theglobeandmail.com, www.conestoga.ca, www.canada.com, and Lotz, personal communication. All prices in US dollars. Figures in italics are estimates. To convert mentions on radio or television to equivalent paid airtimes, we propose the following conservative rules and applying the discount factors described below. 1. A brief mention of a green roof project in a factual news report is equivalent to one 30-second spot 2. A factual news report on the subject of the green roof project is equivalent minute-to-minute to a television spot; the duration of the news report should be rounded down to the nearest 30 second increment (e.g., a 2:09 news report is rounded down to 2:00 and therefore equivalent to four 30 second spots). 19 3. A positive endorsement in an editorial or opinion piece is equivalent to twenty 30 second spots (Lotz, personal communication) Discount factor (D): • If mention is on a major network, D= 1 (no discount) • If mention is on a specialty channel, D = 0.1 (90% discount) • If mention is on a public access channel, D = 0.05 (95% discount) To convert mentions in the newspapers to column inches, we propose applying the following general rules and applying the discount factors described below: 1. In a factual article whose main subject is not the green roof project, each sentence in which the project is mentioned is worth one column inch. 2. A factual article whose main subject is the green roof project is worth double the number of column inches taken by the article 3. A positive endorsement in an editorial or opinion piece whose main subject is not the green roof project is equivalent to a half-page ad or 64 column inches. 4. A positive endorsement in an editorial or opinion piece whose main subject is the green roof project is equivalent to a half-page ad or 128 column inches. 5. If mention includes a picture, convert picture to column inches by dividing the area by 2 (one column is 1.96” wide). Discount factor (D): • If mention is in a major daily newspaper, D= 1 (no discount) • If mention is in a citywide weekly magazine, D = 0.25 (75% discount) • If mention is in a specialty or community publication, D = 0.1 (90% discount) 3.3 Food production and food security Urban agriculture (whether at grade or on rooftops) can provide city-dwellers with a source of fresh produce, improved diet and important household budgetary savings. Successes in cities across North America illustrate the potential relief that urban food production can offer to those in need. Combining average garden plot yields and cost savings from the purchase of produce (based on market prices) can help us evaluate the monetary value of urban food production. Furthermore, 20 calculating the amount of locally grown produce that can be distributed to lowincome citizens through community organizations such as food banks can provide an estimate of the food security benefits related to urban agriculture. Urban food production has many other potential benefits, such as CO2 absorption, social cohesion and health effects. With the exception of CO2 absorption, which is addressed in Section 3.6 below, these topics are not explored here due to a lack of existing research. To help assess the productivity and monetary value of urban agriculture, we have compiled some case studies from Canada and the US: • A study of the urban agriculture potential of an infill development in Vancouver, British Columbia, estimated that a market garden could yield 50,000 kg/ha of food. Market gardens generally grow a variety of produce, usually focusing on highly perishable items that fetch a high price. The authors calculated that gardening one hectare of land would fulfill 3% of the 10,900 to 13,800 community residents’ vegetable needs (Barrs, 2002). Given that Canadian households with middling incomes ($40-59K) spend around $20 per week on fruits and vegetables (Statistics Canada, 2002), we can estimate that 3% of annual household spending on the same would be $31.20. Given the average household size of 2.25 people (City of Vancouver, 2006), a community of 10,900 to 13,800 residents would have 4,844 to 6,133 households. Therefore, we can estimate that a market such as the one described in this scenario could save the community between $151,100 and $191,300. • The rooftop herb garden at the Fairmont Waterfront Hotel in Vancouver has provided important monetary benefits for the hotel’s restaurant. Herbs grown on the 195.1 m2 (2,100 sq. ft.) rooftop garden provide an estimated $25,000 to $30,000 annual saving in food costs for the hotel restaurant (September & Peck). • Commercial urban agriculture enterprises across North America offer important sources of income to urban and peri-urban food producers. The Kon Kai urban farm in Berkley California earns on average $250,000 to $300,000 per year from the gourmet lettuces it grows on 1618.76 m2 (17417.9 sq. ft.) of land (Barrs, 2002). • In 1991, a study revealed that, on the average 65 m2 (720 sq. ft.) community garden in Newark, New Jersey, annual vegetable production amounted to just over $500 (Patel, 1991). The net economic benefit of gardens was estimated to be $475 after deducting a $25 average input cost, not including labour. When adjusting for inflation this amounts to an economic benefit of over C$800 in 2008. 21 • Action Communiterre is non-profit organization that operates 10 collectively managed organic gardens in the Notre-Dame-de-Grâce area of Montreal. Vegetables harvested from the garden are shared among the volunteer gardeners and the rest is donated to community organizations such as local food banks and housing projects. Garden volunteers are also offered informational workshops on gardening, composting, recycling, and food security. In 2007, 1,547 kilos of vegetables were harvested from the 4,900m2 land area occupied by the organization’s 10 collective gardens. The organization has set a goal of harvesting 2,500 kilos in the gardens during the 2008 growing season. In 2007, the group initiated a rooftop vegetable garden pilot project, which produced 150 kilos of fresh vegetables. For the 2008 growing season, the group aims to cultivate around 750 kilos of vegetables on the 80 m2 of cultivable rooftop land area. • In Seattle, the P-Patch program provides gardening space to over 6,000 gardeners on 23 acres of land across the city and provides a source of fresh produce and economic opportunities to low income citizens. A 2007 survey of community gardeners in Seattle revealed that between the months of April and October, 36 percent of respondents received over half of their produce needs from their garden plot (Rich McDonald, personal communication). Seattle gardeners also contribute to local food security by donating approximately 44,000 pounds of fresh produce to local food banks in 2007. Out of this, about 11,000 pounds of fruit (mostly plums) were harvested from Seattle fruit trees and delivered to people with limited access to organic produce. At a retail price of $2.99 per pound, the organic plum harvested through the project represented a direct benefit of over $30,000 for the community. • The Homeless Garden Project based out of Santa Cruz, California grows herbs, produce and flowers on its 2.5-acre plot of land. Since its opening in 1990, the garden provides training and meaningful work experience to less fortunate citizens in the region. Apart from the produce that is donated to local charities, the organization sells its vegetables, flowers and herbs wholesale and through a community supported agriculture program. Through these sales, the garden raises an estimated $26,000 annually (Brown, 2002). The productivity of an urban garden depends on a number of factors: soil conditions, irrigation, mixture of plants, and farming intensity. In a rooftop setting, these factors are largely independent of location and can be controlled by the gardener. Other factors, such as climate and sun exposure, are location-specific and beyond the control of the gardener. The main constraint in terms of climate is the duration of the growing season – i.e., the number of days between the last spring frost and the first fall frost. In southern coastal regions, including parts of California, 22 Florida, and Texxas, outdoorr agriculturaal productioon is possiblle year roun nd. Further from m the coasts and furtherr north, the growing g seaason becom mes shorter (see Figure 1 for Canada). Cu urrent climate change predictionss suggest thaat the durattion of the grow wing season is set to inccrease in thee cooler parrts of the continent. Figurre 1 ‐ Duratio on of Growing Seasons in Canada Source: The Atlas of Canada (atlaas.nrcan.gc.ca)) Tablee 4 below su ummarizes key informaation from tthe examplees above thaat included moneetary valuess for agriculltural or horrticultural ooutput.5 To the data tak ken from the exam mples, we haave added th he duration of the grow wing season n for each location and we have standarrdized all monetary m vallues to be in n 2008 Canaadian dollarrs. To be ablle nt sizes and in differentt climates, w we have to compare dataa on gardenss of differen calcu ulated the mean m producctivity per unit u of area p per month o of growing season. Thee data suggest thaat the produ uctivity of ou utdoor rooft ftop gardenss ranges bettween 000 and $20 00,000 per hectare h per growing m month. It app pears that m mixed fruit $20,0 and vegetable v gaardens are at a the low end of the prroductivity range whilee gardens focussed more on n flowers, heerbs, and lettuces are aat the higher end. Table e 4 ‐ Producttivity of urban agricultu ure (selected d examples) City Area A (h ha) wing Grow seaso on (mon nths) Outpu ut type A Annual output ($*/year) Produ uctivity ($/mo onth•ha) This table t brings tog gether at-grade and rooftop gaarden informati on. We assume that rooftop gaardens have yields similar to at-grrade gardens un nder similar con nditions. 5 2 23 Vancouver, BC 1.000 Vancouver, BC Berkeley, CA Newark, NJ 0.020 0.162 0.007 Santa Cruz, CA 1.012 Assorted highly 8 perishable vegetables 8 Herbs 12 Gourmet lettuces 6 Vegetables Vegetables, 12 flowers, herbs 170,100 to 216,400 24,200 28,300 to 34,000 370,000 to 444,000 ~1,000 194,700 209,400 23,800 ~38,500 38,000 * Converted to 2008 CAD. We propose the value of the food production benefit be estimated using the following formula: b = P⋅ g⋅ a Where: • b = annual value of benefit ($/year) • g = duration of the growing season (months) • P = productivity ($/m2•month) • a = green roof area (m2) Low scenario (mixed fruits and vegetables) b =($2/m2 ⋅ month)⋅ g⋅ a High scenario (lettuces, herbs, & flowers) b =($20/m2 ⋅month)⋅ g⋅a 3.4 Sound Attenuation Vegetated surfaces provide important sound insulation properties, especially in urban environments where hard surfaces such as pavement and buildings tend to reflect noise. Plants and trees tend to absorb high-frequency sounds, which are the most bothersome to human-ear, and are often employed for their noise reduction potential in urban settings. Although the vegetated surface of other green infrastructure elements can provide noise reduction benefits, most of the available data pertains to green roofs (Navrud, 2002). Green roofs can provide important noise reduction opportunities for buildings, especially for those under flight paths or elevated transit systems.6 Hedonic pricing and contingent valuation 6 Less directly, by decreasing heat exchange between the building and the environment and by mitigating the heat island effect, green roofs can reduce the use of air conditioning, a source of noise. 24 methodologies have both been employed to assess the social costs of noise and estimate values for noise reduction measures such as green roof implementation. In a study commissioned by the European Union, Navrud (2002) attempted to establish interim values for noise reduction from different transportation modes (air, road, rail) by performing an extensive literature review of noise valuation studies. The economic values attributed to road and air noise level reductions ranged substantially from study to study, depending on the valuation method employed (e.g., hedonic pricing or contingent valuation). Based on stated preferences techniques, the author found that the average willingness-to-pay for reduction in road traffic noises ranged from €2 to €32 (3 to 45 $CAN) per household per dB per year.7 Too few stated preferences studies for aircraft noise had been conducted to narrow the large range of willingness-to-pay in the literature. When using the hedonic pricing technique, the cost of noise is measured by the Noise Sensitivity Depreciation Index (NSDI), which represents the average percentage decrease in total property value per 1-decibel increase in noise level above a baseline level. Typically, the cost of aircraft and road noise pollution is calculated above a 55 dB baseline. This implies that noise levels below this benchmark do not cause any depreciation of property value. Bateman et al. (2000) have compiled lists of NSDIs for road traffic and air traffic noise based on the findings of studies from the US and abroad. Road traffic NSDIs range between 0.08% and 2.22% of property value per decibel and air traffic NSDIs range between 0.29% to 2.3% of property value per decibel. Statistical analysis of these results showed an average NSDI of 0.64% for road traffic pollution and 0.33% for air traffic pollution. Navrud (2002) reports that NSDIs will be higher where households are relatively wealthy or where levels of sound pollution are relatively higher. Noise valuation estimates generated by hedonic pricing and contingent valuation techniques can help to quantify the noise reduction benefits of green roofs. To date, few research studies have estimated the noise reduction potential of green roofs. However, Connelly & Hodgson (2008) examined the sound transmission loss of two green roofs, one with a 75 mm substrate and the other with a 150 mm substrate. The authors report a transmission attenuation of 5 dB to 13 dB over the low- to midfrequency range (50Hz to 2000 Hz). In the higher frequency, range transmission attenuation ranged between 2 dB to 8 dB. Sound attenuation provided by a green roof will depend on the properties of the chosen substrate and on the substrate’s thickness. In the absence of data on the noise attenuation properties of different substrates with different thicknesses, we 7 Contingent valuation studies measure the willingness to pay per person, whereas Exposure Response Functions (ERF) express the cost per household. To convert the results of a valuation study to an approximate ERF, the results can be multiplied by the mean household size. In Europe, mean household size is 2.16 (Navrud, 2002); in the US, it is 2.6 (US Census Bureau, 2006); and in Canada it is 2.5 (Statistics Canada, 2007). 25 propose a low (5 dB attenuation) and a high scenario (13 dB attenuation) based on Connelly & Hodgson’s (2008) findings on the sound attenuation of 75 mm and 150 mm green roof substrates. The aforementioned findings are those for low- and midrange frequencies; we assume that most ambient noise in an urban setting falls into this category. We assume that a green roof would primarily reduce noises from overhead sources, such air traffic and elevated roadways and trains; it would have little or no effect on street level traffic noise. Thus, the benefit would only accrue to properties affected by overhead noise. Based on the findings of Bateman et al (2000), for properties near airports or under airport flight paths, we propose using an NSDI of 0.33%; for properties near elevated roadways or railways that are above roof level, we propose using an NSDI of 0.64%. We also assume that a green roof would only affect noise levels only on the top floor of the building. We therefore assume that only the portion of the property value represented by the top floor increases in value. For the purpose of estimation, we assume that each floor is worth an equal portion of the total property value. Hence, the value of the top floor is the total property value divided by the number of storeys. We propose the value of the sound attenuation benefit be estimated using the following formula: v b = NSDI ⋅ n⋅ h Where: • b = value of benefit ($/year) • NSDI = noise sensitivity depreciation index (/dB) • n = green roof sound attenuation (dB) • h = building height (storeys) • v= property value ($) Low attenuation scenario for air traffic v b = (0.0033/dB)⋅(5dB)⋅ ⋅ h v = 0.0165⋅ h 26 High attenuation scenario for air traffic b = (0.0033/dB)⋅(13dB)⋅ = 0.0429⋅ v h v h Low attenuation scenario for elevated road and rail b = (0.0064/dB)⋅(5dB)⋅ = 0.032⋅ v h v h High attenuation scenario for elevated road and rail b = (0.0064/dB)⋅(13dB)⋅ = 0.0832⋅ v h v h 3.5 Stormwater Retention Vegetated surfaces have the capacity to absorb and retain stormwater, reducing the amount of runoff. When located at-grade, vegetated surfaces absorb stormwater and allow some of it to infiltrate into the ground or slowly release it after storm events. Vegetated surfaces on rooftops can also retain considerable amounts of stormwater and reduce peak flows into the stormwater system during storm events. Less peak runoff means that new, conventional stormwater retention and conveyance systems can have a smaller capacity or existing systems can support more development before being upgraded, which translates to lower capital expenditures for developers or municipalities, depending on who pays for new stormwater infrastructure in the given context. Municipalities also stand to derive ongoing benefits in terms of reduced operating costs related to storm management infrastructure – less infrastructure means lower operating costs. Reducing the peak volume of runoff and increasing on-site re-absorption of stormwater helps to prevent water pollution. As runoff washes over various surfaces, especially impermeable surfaces such as road and parking, it picks up particles and various pollutants, which without mitigating measures end up draining into and polluting local waterways. Thus, by reducing the volume of runoff, green roofs can at least partially obviate pollution control measures. By reducing the amount of stormwater conveyed off-site, which causes additional swelling of local bodies of water during 27 storm events, green roofs can also at least partly obviate the need for erosion mitigation measures. In a recent lifecycle cost-benefit analysis of green roofs, Carter and Keeler (2008) looked at the financial dimensions of several benefits, including stormwater management. They estimated the costs and benefits per square meter of an extensive green roof, with a 7.62 cm (3 inch) layer of growing media, assuming a 40year reroofing cycle. The test site for which the estimates are calculated is the Tanyard Branch watershed, which covers much of the central area of Athens, Georgia. The test site has 53.8 % impervious land cover, with rooftops accounting for 15.9% of the total land cover. Data on the water retention capacity of the green roof was obtained from a test plot located on a rooftop on the University of Georgia campus. The 7.62 cm vegetated layer assumed in the test scenario can hold 4.27 cm of rainfall (or 42.7L of water per m2 of roof). Published retention and one-time cost data for stormwater best management practices (BMPs) (EPA, 1999) is used to determine the cost for an equivalent amount of rainwater retention at-grade given the available land cover in the watershed. A combination of bioretention areas, porous pavement, and sand filters would cost US$212.15/m3 of runoff treated, assuming an equal distribution of these three BMPs. The avoided cost is therefore US$9.06/m2 of green roof. Cunningham (2001, Chapter 5) explores a theoretical scenario in which extensive green roofing is implemented on a site containing mostly large, low-rise commercial and industrial buildings in the City of Winnipeg. The purpose of the exercise is to explore potential avoided costs for conventional stormwater infrastructure. The test site has an area of 43.06 acres (17.4 ha), while flat roofs cover 10.76 acres (4.4 ha). The study site was subdivided into three zones, each having a distinct pattern of land use. The total runoff in the site was calculated to be 60.77 cubic feet per second (cfs) (1.721 m3/s) for a 5-year storm; 80.25 cfs (2.272 m3/s) for a 20-year storm; and 91.17 cfs (2.582 m3/s) for a 50-year storm. Under the test scenario, roofs in the test site were extensively greened and assumed to have a run-off coefficient of 0.40, as compared to a coefficient of 0.95 for flat gravel roofs. The runoff from the roofs themselves was reduced by 58%. Site wide, this yielded a 17% reduction in the total volume of runoff.8 Based on estimated reductions in stormwater runoff volume, reductions in the diameter of drainage pipes required to convey runoff were calculated. In one of the three land use zones, it was estimated that pipes could be reduced from 48 inches to 42 inches under the green roof scenario; from 42 inches to 36 in the second of three zones; and would remain the same in the third of three zones. The author obtained per meter cost estimates to install different diameters of drainage piping in a development site and used these to estimate the cost of servicing the test site under Roofs account for only a fraction of the total area of the site – i.e., 4.4 ha of 17.4 ha. The reduction in runoff occurred only on the roofs; the volume of runoff remains the same elsewhere. Hence, site wide, the overall reduction is much smaller than it is on the roofs themselves. 8 28 existing conditions and the green roof scenario. On this basis, it was estimated that the latter would yield one-time material cost savings of 10% for stormwater drainage infrastructure. Cunningham also compared the cost of building conventional stormwater retention infrastructure – i.e., subgrade retention basins and stormwater retention ponds – with the cost of retaining stormwater with extensive green roofing. The cost of retaining water with green roofing is estimated to be $14.41 per cubic foot ($508.88/m3). The cost is $30.00 per cubic foot ($1,059.44/m3) for an underground retention basin and $0.57 per cubic foot ($20.13/m3) for a retention pond, not including the cost of land and maintenance costs. Thus, Cunningham concludes that, in terms of water retention, green roofing is about half as expensive as underground retention basins. According to his calculation, stormwater retention by means of extensive green roofing is about 25-fold more expensive than using a conventional stormwater retention pond.9 Clark et al (2008) valuate stormwater benefits of green roofs in terms of stormwater fee reductions accrued to property owners.10 In Ann Arbor, MI, which Clark et al use as a case study, the stormwater fee is US$0.28 /m2 per year for impervious surfaces. As the City of Ann Arbor considers a green roof to be a pervious surface, the annual benefit accrued to commercial property owners is US$0.28 for every square meter of green roof they add. The average stormwater fee charged by 11 municipalities in the US is US$0.17/m2 per year for impervious surfaces and US$0.08/m2 per year for green roofs. Thus, on average, property owners save US$0.09 annually in stormwater fees for every square meter of green roof they add. The City of Waterloo (2005), in a report on the feasibility of green roofs, valuated a number of related costs and benefits. In its calculations, the City assumed that stormwater management, whether by means of conventional infrastructure or a green roof, helps control both the quantity and the quality of runoff. In terms of quantity, stormwater management infrastructure reduces the volume of runoff by retaining and storing a certain amount of stormwater. Assuming that conventional stormwater storage infrastructure costs C$42/m3 and that an extensive green roof holds 37L/m2, it was estimated that the stormwater retention benefit provided by green roofs is worth C$1.56/m2. In terms of quality of the runoff, the City of Waterloo estimated that, at a cost of C$42/m3 of stormwater, conventional stormwater infrastructure for pollution This does not factor in land costs, which could be significant. For greenfield development in the periphery of a city, land costs can be so low that retention ponds can indeed be quite inexpensive. However, in already urbanized areas, land costs would most likely render retention ponds prohibitively expensive, making green roofs a viable alternative. 9 Some municipalities in North America assess stormwater fees, independent from fees or taxes for water and wastewater services. In some cases, the municipality provides stormwater fee discounts to property owners who implement recognized forms of on-site stormwater management, including green roofs. 10 29 control costs C$0.55/m2 (C$5,460/ha) of serviced land. Assuming that green roofs reduce pollutant loading in stormwater by 90%, the one-time value of the runoff quality benefit is C$0.49/m2 (C$4,914/ha). However, the authors point out that the values for the retention and pollutant reduction benefits are not additive because stormwater management infrastructure provides both benefits simultaneously. Therefore, only the benefit with the higher value is considered. The erosion reduction benefit, in contrast, is considered separately in the study. Based on calculations made by the City of Mississauga, the City of Waterloo estimated that conventional stormwater management infrastructure related to erosion control requires a one-time expenditure of C$0.51/m2 (C$5,055/ha) of developed land. Thus, assuming that extensive green roofs provide an equivalent service, the one-time value of the erosion control benefit is C$0.51/m2 of green roof, in addition to the other one-time stormwater benefits. Banting et al (2005) use the pollutant reduction and erosion reduction benefits calculated by the City of Waterloo to estimate the one-time value of stormwater benefits accrued to the City of Toronto if all of its flat rooftops (4,984 ha) were extensively greened. For the value of stormwater retention, they use their own estimates, which range from C$0.95/m2 to C$26.42/m2. The estimates are based on the cost of providing equivalent stormwater retention using the cheapest up to the most expensive BMPs. They use the same values for pollutant reduction (C$0.55/m2) and the same erosion mitigation (C$0.51/m2) values as the City of Waterloo. However, they discount pollution mitigation provided by green roofs by 50% rather than by 10%, as the City of Waterloo did and they consider the pollution benefit to be independent of the other benefits and therefore additive. The total value of the benefit, which is a sum of the retention, pollution mitigation and erosion control benefits, is in the range of C$1.73/m2 and C$27.20/m2. If all 4,984 ha of flat rooftops in Toronto were extensively greened, a one-time benefit worth C$41,800,000 and C$118,000,000 in avoided infrastructure costs would accrue to the City. To calculate the combined one-time value of the stormwater benefits provided by green roofs, we follow the methodology established by the City of Waterloo. Thus, we take the combined value of the benefit to be the higher value of either the stormwater retention service or the pollution mitigation service, plus the value of the erosion mitigation service provided by green roofs. From the literature reviewed above, we have figures for the cost of three types of stormwater retention infrastructure, including: a surface storm water retention pond, valuated at $20.13/m3 of stormwater; mixed at-grade BMPs, valuated at $212.15/m3 of stormwater; and an underground retention basin, valuated at $1,059.44/m3 of stormwater. For the surface retention pond, the figure cited here presumably applies to a greenfield development on the periphery of Winnipeg where land is likely to be relatively inexpensive. In tighter land markets, the cost of a surface retention pond could be considerably higher; for development in dense urban locations, the cost could be prohibitive. We will therefore consider the 30 aforementioned cost as the lowest possible cost for stormwater retention; this figure will be used to calculate the lower bound of the value of this green roof benefit. Based on the data taken from the City of Waterloo study, which assumed that a green roof retains 37L/m2, we calculate that pollution mitigation is worth C$13.28/m3 while erosion control is worth C$13.66/m3. Given that the lowest value for stormwater retention services cited in the literature reviewed here is C$20.13/m3 for a retention pond, as calculated by Cunningham (2001), it appears that the retention service will always be more valuable than the pollution removal service. As a result, we can ignore the value pollution removal benefit in our calculation of the total value stormwater benefits provided by green roofs. The values per unit of area of the green roof of the stormwater services that we are considering depend critically on the water retention capacity of the green roof. For estimation purposes, we will assume an average retention capacity of 42.7L/m2roof, as used by Carter and Keeler (2008), which we take to be a typical figure for an extensive green roof. We propose the value of the storm water retention benefit be estimated using the following equation: b =(R + E)⋅ C ⋅ a Where: • b = value of benefit ($) • R = stormwater retention cost ($/m3water) • E = erosion mitigation cost ($/m3water) • C= average green roof retention capacity (m3water/m2roof) • a = green roof area (m2roof) Low‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario For the purpose of estimating the lower bound of the stormwater retention benefit, we employ Cunningham’s (2001) calculation for the cost of a retention pond, the least expensive type of retention system, barring land costs. b =[($20.13/m3water )+ ($13.66/ m3water )]⋅(42.7m3water /m2roof )⋅ a =[$33.79/m3water ]⋅(0.0427m3water / m2roof )⋅ a = $1.44/ m2roof ⋅ a 31 High‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario For the purpose of estimating the upper bound of the stormwater retention benefit, we employ Cunningham’s (2001) calculation for the cost of an underground retention basin, the most expensive retention solution of among those explored above. b =[($1,059.44/ m3water )+ ($13.66/ m3water )]⋅(42.7m3water / m2roof )⋅ a =[$1,073.10/ m3water ]⋅(0.0427m3water / m2roof )⋅ a = $45.82/ m2roof ⋅ a 3.6 Air Quality Improvement Vegetation in urban areas affects air contaminant levels and therefore has an impact on air quality. Green plants absorb gaseous pollutants through their leaf stomates (pores). The gases then react with water to form acids and other chemicals. Vegetations can also capture some of the particulate matter in the air. By mitigating the heat island effect, urban vegetation can further help reduce smog given that higher temperatures favour smog formation. Smog is formed when nitrogen oxides react with volatile organic compounds that are released due to the combustion of fossil fuels; high temperatures accelerate this process. Thus, urban vegetation offers three distinct benefits in terms air quality: reduction of gaseous pollutant, reduction of solid particulate pollutants, and inhibition of smog formation. Air pollution’s impacts on human health entail significant albeit indirect costs. According to the Ontario Medical Association (OMA) (2000), air pollution related health problems have the following economic consequences: (1) cost to the health care system; (2) cost due to lost productivity in the workplace; (3) economic value of pain and suffering due to pollution induced illnesses; and (4) economic damages associated with premature death. As the OMA points out, the first two are out-of pocket expenses for taxpayers. The air pollution mitigating benefits of green roofs and other green infrastructure therefore accrue to society at large in the form of avoided health care costs. In the 1990s, the New York State Utilities Commission estimated the health care costs attributable to several atmospheric pollutants, including nitrogen dioxide (NO2), sulfur dioxide (SO2), carbon monoxide (CO), particulate matter of 10 micrometers or less (PM10), and ozone (O3) (Kowal, 2008) (see Table 5). These estimates were incorporated into the Urban Forests Effects (UFORE) computer model to calculate the value of the pollution removal benefit provide by trees and other vegetation in urban areas. The UFORE model was developed to calculate the pollution removal capacity of urban vegetation, and its monetary value. Pollution removal calculations, or downwardpollutantflux, consider several factors. The key factors are pollutant deposition velocity, which is related to wind, and the concentration of pollutants at the given location. Other factors include the length of 32 the in-leaf season, levels of precipitation, temperature and other meteorological variables (Nowak and Crane, 1998). Table 5 ‐ Costs of selected atmospheric pollutants Pollutant Nitrogen Oxide (NOX) Sulfur Dioxide (SO2) Carbon Monoxide (CO) Particulate Matter <10 μm (PM10) Ozone (O3) Cost (US$/ton) 6,750 1,650 950 4,500 6,750 Source: Kowal, 2008 Currie and Bass (2008) used UFORE to explore the pollution mitigating capacity of green roofs and green walls. Field data was collected from 72 circular plots, each 400m2 and having a different distribution of vegetation, in the Midtown area of Toronto. The data was fed into the UFORE model to estimate the 03, S02, N02, C0 and PM10 removal capacity of the current vegetation in the study area, to be used as a baseline scenario, and that of six hypothetical vegetation scenarios. The hypothetical scenarios either added new vegetative elements to the study area, such as green walls (i.e., juniper hedges), extensive and intensive green roofs, or subtracted existing vegetative elements, such as trees and shrubs. The difference between the baseline scenario and each hypothetical scenario was taken to be the pollution mitigating capacity of the individual vegetative element that was added or removed in the given scenario. The key findings of the study were that, while trees clearly have a greater pollution mitigating capacity, shrubs and grasses, which can be readily planted on flat rooftops, can nonetheless have a very substantial effect on air pollution and a significant monetary value. Covering all flat rooftops, equivalent to about 20% of all roof surfaces in the study area, with a grassy vegetated surface would augment the pollution mitigation provided by existing trees and shrubs by as much as 10% and be worth US$17,481 a year in terms of avoided healthcare costs. Based on the results of Currie and Bass’s study, Banting et al. (2005) calculated the annual monetary value of extensive green roofs in Toronto to be about US$0.0394/m2 (C$0.0541/m2 in 2008) of extensively vegetated roof area. If all flat rooftops across the City of Toronto (4984 ha) were extensively greened, the annual cost savings attributable to reduction in air pollution would amount to US$1,970,000 (C$2,700,000 in 2008). Yang, Yu and Gong (2008) quantified the volume of air pollution mitigation provided by green roofs in Chicago. They obtained detailed data on 71 out of some 170 green roofs, totaling 19.8 ha. Aerial photographs of the roofs were analyzed to determine the distribution of different types of surfaces on the green roofs. It was found that 63% of the green roofs’ aggregated area consisted of short grasses, 14% of large herbaceous plants, 11% of trees and shrubs, and the remaining 12% of various structures and hard surfaces. A pollutant deposition model for big-leaf plants employing atmospheric data collected in Chicago over a one-year period were used 33 to estimate the absorption of four principal air pollutants (SO2, NO2, PM10, and O3) by each of the three observed types of vegetation (summarized in Table 6). Yang, Yu and Gong’s (2008) results can be combined with the health cost data cited by Kowal (2008) to calculate the value of the pollution mitigation provided by each type of plant (see Table 7). Table 6 ‐ Annual pollutant removal by different types of green roof vegetation in Chicago (g/m2∙year) Type of vegetation SO2 N02 PM10 O3 Total Short Grass Tall Herbaceous Plants Deciduous Trees 8.59 11.1 13.91 0.65 0.83 1.01 2.33 2.94 3.57 1.12 1.52 2.16 4.49 5.81 7.17 Source: Yang, Yu and Gong, 2008 Table 7 ‐ Value of annual pollutant removal health benefit for different types of green roof vegetation (US$/m2∙year) Type of vegetation Short Grass Tall Herbaceous Plants Deciduous Trees SO2 0.0010725 0.0013695 0.0016665 N02 0.0157275 0.0198450 0.0240975 PM10 O3 0.00504 0.00684 0.00972 Total 0.0303075 0.0392175 0.0483975 0.0521 0.0673 0.0839 Combining data from Yang, Yu and Gong (2008) and Kowal (2008) As suggested by the studies cited above, the critical determinants of a green roof’s capacity to mitigate pollution and yield health benefits include its area and the mix of plant species that is used, as some species absorb more pollutants than others. Other factors include the levels of air pollution at the given location and the climate. In terms of the latter, the pollution mitigation provided by the green roof may be limited outside the growing season, particularly if it is covered with snow. The examples above, from Toronto and Chicago, estimate pollution mitigation of green roofs in locations with relatively short growing seasons (about seven months) and long, snowy winters. In places with a longer growing season, the annual volume of pollution absorbed is likely to be higher given the same plant species. We take a seven-month growing season to be the baseline case. Using the values for the pollutant removal health benefit that we have calculated using Yang, Yu and Gong’s (2008) and Kowal’s (2008) findings (Table 7), we propose the following formula for estimating the annual value of the health benefit of pollution mitigation provided by green roofs: g b= ⋅[H sg ⋅ asg + Htg ⋅ atg + Hd ⋅ ad ] 7⋅ months Where: • b = value of benefit ($/year) • g = growing season (months) 34 • Hsg = health benefit for short grass pollution absorption ($/m2•year) • asg = green roof area covered by short grass (m2) • Htg = health benefit for tall grass* pollution absorption ($/m2•year) • atg = green roof area covered by tall grass* (m2) • Hd = health benefit for deciduous plant pollution absorption ($/m2•year) • ad = green roof area covered by deciduous plants (m2) *tall herbaceous plant Using the annual pollutant removal values cited in Table 7, we obtain: g b= ⋅[($0.0521/m2 )⋅ asg + ($0.0673/m2 )⋅ atg + ($0.0839/m2 )⋅ ad ] 7⋅ months The above equation can only be applied if the distributions of the three categories of vegetation within the green portion of the roof are known. If the distribution is unknown, the estimate will lie somewhere between a lower bound defined by a green surface area composed entirely of short grass (the least absorbent) and an upper bound defined by a green surface composed entirely of deciduous plants (the most absorbent). Low scenario (100% short grass coverage) g ⋅[($0.0521/m2 )⋅(a)+ ($0.0673/m2 )⋅(0)+ ($0.0839/m2 )⋅(0)] 7⋅ months g ⋅[($0.0521/m2 )⋅ a + 0+ 0] = 7⋅ months 2 = ($0.0074/m ⋅ months)⋅ g⋅ a b= Where: a = area of the green roof (m2) 35 High scenario (100% deciduous tree coverage) g ⋅[($0.0521/m2 )⋅(0)+ ($0.0673/m2 )⋅(0)+ ($0.0839/m2 )⋅(a)] 7⋅ months g ⋅[0+ 0+ ($0.0839/m2 )⋅ a] = 7⋅ months 2 = ($0.0120/m ⋅ months)⋅ g⋅ a b= Where: • a= area of the green roof (m2) 3.7 Greenhouse Gas Sequestration Carbon dioxide is the most common greenhouse gas and its rising levels in the atmosphere are believed to contribute to global warming. Reducing emissions of carbon dioxide and capturing the carbon dioxide that is already in the atmosphere are increasingly being pursued as strategies to mitigate global warming. All photosynthesizing plant species have the capacity to capture and store atmospheric carbon dioxide (CO2). Trees and other plants in urban environments are no exception. Thus, a further benefit of green roofs and other green infrastructure is their ability to capture and store – i.e., sequester – carbon dioxide. Valuating the carbon dioxide sequestration benefit of green infrastructure entails estimating the marginal social cost of damages that would have been caused due to temperature increases if not for the sequestration carried out by the vegetation involved. Most studies on carbon dioxide sequestration provided by plants have focused on trees. Nowak and Crane (2002) assess the carbon sequestration capacity of urban trees across the US. The authors determined that there were approximately 281,000 km2 of urban tree cover across the US, storing 700 million metric tones of carbon and annually sequestering 22.8 million tons. The carbon storage and annual carbon uptake provided by urban trees are valued at US$14.3 billion and US$460 million per year, respectively. Based on these estimates, the average value of carbon storage by urban trees would be approximately $510/ha for stored carbon and $16/ha for annual carbon uptake. The authors note that carbon storage and uptake are lower in urban than non-urban tree stands because the density of the tree cover is generally much lower. On average, urban trees store 25.1 tonnes/ha of carbon whereas forest stands store 53.5 tonnes/ha – more than twofold as much. Urban trees sequester on average 0.3 tonnes/ha per year while natural growth tree stands sequester 1.0 tonnes/ha per year and tree plantations sequester as much as 2.6 tonnes/ha per year. 36 In a recent report, the David Suzuki Foundation (2008) examines a number of ecosystem services provided by the Greater Golden Horseshoe Greenbelt in southern Ontario, including carbon sequestration. Among other benefits, the annual carbon sequestration values for different biomes within the greenbelt are estimated (see Table 8). Carbon sequestration per hectare, in terms of both annual uptake and total storage, 11 is calculated for the different biomes in the Greenbelt using a software package called CITYgreen (similar to UFORE). To convert these sequestration capacities to monetary values, the author assumes a cost of $43/tonne (2005 US dollars) for global damages due to carbon dioxide levels in the atmosphere. This value is based on the average cost of global damages due to the level of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere in 2005, as reported by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) (2007). Table 8 ‐ Carbon sequestration values per hectare for Greater Golden Horseshoe Greenbelt land types Stored carbon Annual carbon uptake Forest Grassland Agricultural Lands Cropland Idle land Hedgerows Orchards $919 $213 $332 $317 $328 $298 $39.11 $28.46 N/A $28.59 $28.59 $28.59 Source: David Suzuki Foundation, 2008 While the aforementioned studies focus on the sequestration of atmospheric carbon provided by trees and other vegetative covers, other studies have explored indirect carbon dioxide emissions reductions provided by green infrastructure. Akbari and Konopacki (2003) calculated that mitigation of the urban heat island effect provided by trees and green infrastructure could reduce building carbon emissions by 5-20 percent. A number of authors have noted that green roofs produce energy savings by reducing heat exchange through the roof, resulting in lower energy use for heating in the winter and air conditioning in the summer. A recent paper by The Trust for Public Land (2008 b) on the greenhouse gas benefits of urban parks suggest other indirect energy saving benefits that could also apply to green roofs. The authors suggest that urban parks can reduce the amount of energy used to manage stormwater runoff. This is especially likely to be true in communities that do not have separate stormwater sewer systems and send stormwater mixed with regular wastewater through energy consuming sewage treatment plants. It is also suggested that some GHG emission reductions can result from reduced transportation use, given that the provision of parks (or accessible rooftop gardens) can provide more accessible leisure opportunities. The indirect carbon dioxide emissions reductions, though potentially significant, would be very difficult to valuate. Most depend on factors that could vary significantly from place to place and could be difficult to determine without a substantial research effort. For instance, the extent of emission reductions achieved Annual carbon uptake is a measure of the average amount of carbon sequestered per year by given plant or by a vegetated area. Carbon storage is the total amount of carbon sequestered over a longer period – for an individual plant, over its lifetime. 11 37 by reducing energy use depends crucially on how much of the local energy supply is fossil fuel based. For this reason, we do not attempt to devise a method for valuating the indirect benefits of CO2 emissions reductions afforded by green roofs; we restrict our method to valuating direct carbon sequestration. Our formula for estimating the value of sequestered carbon is based on the findings of the David Suzuki Foundation (2008). We chose these findings because they provide sequestration values for types of vegetation other than forests, namely grassland and croplands, both of which are more likely to be found on a green roof than trees. We assume that the annual carbon uptake of these types of vegetation is the same on a green roof as at grade. As the methodologies reviewed estimate the sequestration value of trees on a large scale basis (square kilometres or hectares), and because the values are relatively small, we use hectares rather than meters as units of area. We propose the following formula for calculating the value of annual carbon sequestration provided by a green roof: b = Sdad + Sgag + S f a f Where: • b = value of benefit ($/year) • Sd = value of carbon sequestration by deciduous plants ($/ha•year) • ad = area of green roof covered by deciduous plants (ha) • Sg = value of carbon sequestration by grasses ($/ha•year) • ag = area of green roof covered by grasses (ha) • Sf = value of carbon sequestration by productive agriculture ($/ha•year) • af = area of green roof covered by productive crops (ha) Note: ag = asg + atg • asg = area of green roof covered by short grasses (ha) • atg = area of green roof covered by tall grasses (ha) 38 Using the David Suzuki foundations sequestration data, and assuming that productive agriculture on green roofs resembles hedge rows or orchards, we obtain: b =($39.11/ ha)ad +($28.46/ ha)ag +($28.59/ ha)a f Low scenario (100% grass coverage) b = ($39.11/ ha)(0)+ ($28.46/ ha)(a)+ ($28.59/ ha)(0) = 0+ ($28.46/ ha)⋅ a + 0 = ($28.46/ ha)⋅ a Where: • a = area of the green roof (ha) High scenario (100% deciduous coverage) b = ($39.11/ ha)(a)+ ($28.46/ ha)(0)+ ($28.59/ ha)(0) = ($39.11/ ha)⋅ a + 0+ 0 = ($39.11/ ha)⋅ a Where: • a= area of the green roof (ha) 39 4 Case Studies The last section provided valuation methodologies that could be used to quantify several of the “soft” benefits associated with green roofs. In the following section, we apply these methodologies to five case studies in order to estimate the actual benefits associated with these green roofs under realistic conditions. The information for these scenarios is drawn from sources such as Steven Peck's book AwardWinningGreenRoofDesigns(2008), project web sites, and interviews with architects and developers. The case studies were chosen in order to represent a variety of building types and locations. Together, they provide opportunities for the use of all the calculation methods presented in Section 3 of this report. Not all of the benefits apply to each case study; only those benefits that apply to each case study and for which data was available are included in the write-ups. For each case study, we present key features of the project and associated green roof, a summary of the development context and process, and the benefit calculations themselves. We conclude each case study with some observations about the calculations, which are designed to help the reader interpret the results. The case studies use a consistent notation to signify variables that go into the calculation of benefits. Table 18 summarizes the variables needed as inputs into the equations and the notation used in the case studies. 40 Table 9 ‐ List of benefits, input variables, notations, and units benefit input variable notation unit property value (recreational garden) property value v dollars property value (productive garden) neighbouring property value vn dollars neighbouring property distance dn meters property value (property with view) property with view value vv dollars property with view height hv meters green roof height h stories growing season g months food production area af square meters actual value of food production vf dollars property value v dollars building height h stories stormwater retention vegetative roof area a square meters air quality growing season g months vegetative roof area (total) a square meters short grass area asg square meters tall grass area atg square meters deciduous plant area ad square meters vegetative roof area (total) a square meters food production area af square meters grass area (short + tall) asg + atg square meters deciduous area ad square meters food production sound attenuation GHG sequestration 41 4.1 Case Stud dy 1 – 901 Cherry Avvenue, San n Bruno, CA A 4.1.1 Key Featu ures location type of building numb ber of storeyys type of green roo of roof cconstruction n comp pletion date developer desiggner vegettative area depth h of growingg medium type of vegetatio on accesssibility 901 Cherrry Avenue, SSan Bruno, CA office buillding 3 semi‐exte ensive new consttruction 1997 GAP Inc. William M McDonough ++ Partners 6,400 m2 (69,000 sq ftt) 15.2 cm (6 6”) native graasses and wi ldflowers inaccessib ble 4.1.2 Summaryy of Project The 901 9 Cherry Avenue buiilding housees offices off the clothin ng maker GA AP Inc. The build ding was com mmissioned d by GAP ab bove all to bee a high quaality work eenvironmen nt with a number of o amenitiess, including a café and a fitness cen ntre. The bu uilding also inclu udes a numb ber of sustaiinable desiggn features, of which th he centerpieece is an undu ulating 6,400 m2 (69,00 00 sq ft) sem mi-extensivee green rooff. The roof ffeatures a 15 5 cm (6 6”) growing g medium pllanted with grasses and d wildfloweers native to o the San 4 42 Francisco Bay Area. Much liike wild graassland, the roof vegetaation is high hly selfsustaaining, requiring minim mal maintenance (Peck,, 2008). A nottable featurre of the 901 1 Cherry building is thaat it is locateed under th he flight path h of airr traffic land ding at the San S Franciscco Internatiional airporrt and, as su uch, is exposed to considerable ov verhead noisse. The greeen roof helps provide an acoustic barriier that atteenuates soun nd transmisssion from aaircraft takiing off from and landing at thee airport. 4 43 4.1.3 Benefits Calculations benefit property value ‐ recreational rooftop garden ‐ productive rooftop garden ‐ view onto a green roof marketing applicable sound attenuation food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration comment not accessible no food produced no taller building nearby data unavailable building lies under the runway flight path for the San Francisco International Airport no food produced 4.1.4 Variables See Table 9 for a definition of the variables. v h a g = = = = US$55,545,399 3 stories 6,400 m2 12 months 4.1.5 Calculations 4.1.5.1 soundattenuation Low attenuation scenario for air traffic Since the current property value includes the sound attenuation benefit, we let: vx = property value excluding the sound attenuation benefit ($) 44 v = vx + b and vx h therefore b = 0.0165⋅ vx ) h 0.0165 v = v x ⋅(1+ ) h v vx = 0.0165 1+ h ($55,545,399) = 0.0165 1+ (3) v = v x + (0.0165⋅ = $55,241,570 b = v − vx = ($55,545,399)−($55,241,570) = $303,829 45 High attenuation scenario for air traffic v = vx + b and vx h therefore b = 0.0429⋅ vx ) h 0.0429 v = v x ⋅(1+ ) h v vx = 0.0429 1+ h ($55,545,399) = 0.0429 1+ (3) v = v x + (0.0429⋅ = $54,762,298 b = v − vx = ($55,545,399)−($54,762,298) = $783,101 4.1.5.2 stormwaterretention Low‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $1.44/ m2 ⋅ a = $1.44/ m2 ⋅(6,400m2 ) = $9,216 High‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $45.82/ m2 ⋅ a = $45.82/ m2 ⋅(6,400m2 ) = $293,248 46 4.1.5.3 airquality Low scenario (100% short grass coverage) b = ($0.0074/m2 ⋅ months)⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0074/m2 ⋅ months)⋅(12months)⋅(6,400m2 ) = $568 Note: only the low scenario is calculated as it is known that the green roof is covered only with short grasses 4.1.5.4 GHGsequestration Low scenario (100% grass coverage) b =($28.46/ ha)⋅ a =($28.46/ ha)⋅(0.64ha) = $18.21 Note: only the low scenario is calculated as it is known that the green roof is covered only with short grasses 4.1.6 Benefits Summary benefit sound attenuation stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration type one time one time annual annual value $303,829 – $783,101 $9,216 – $293,248 $568/year $18/year 4.1.7 Observations The value of the sound attenuation benefit is estimated to be between $303,829 and $783,101. The value of the benefit is likely to be in the upper range given that the thickness of the green roof substrate is 15.2 cm. This corresponds almost exactly to thickness of the thicker, 150 mm substrate tested by Connelly and Hodgson (2008), which was determined to attenuate sound by 13 dB and which is the basis for calculating the upper bound of the value of this benefit. The value of the stormwater benefit is estimated to be between $9,216 and $293,248. Given that there is relatively little precipitation in the San Francisco Area, and given that the building is in a relatively low-density suburban setting, conventional stormwater infrastructure would not be 47 particularly expensive in this case. Thus, the value of the stormwater benefit is likely to be in between the bottom and middle of this range. The pollution mitigation and GHG sequestration benefits were estimated to be worth $568 and $18 per year respectively. As this green roof has 100% grass cover, only the lower bound calculation methods were used to estimate the values of these benefits. If other types of plants were present, such as deciduous bushes or trees, pollution mitigation and GHG sequestration would most likely be higher. 48 4.2 Case Stud dy 2 – Fairm mont Waterfront Ho otel, Vanco ouver, BC 4.2.1 Key Featu ures location type of building numb ber of storeyys type of green roo of roof cconstruction n comp pletion date developer desiggner vegettative area depth h of growingg medium type of vegetatio on accesssibility 900 Canad da Place Waay, Vancouveer, BC hotel 23 intensive new consttruction ivy garden n 1991, replaaced by herb b garden in 1994 Canadian Pacific Hoteels (now Fairrmont Hotelss) Musson C Cattell Mackeey Partnersh hip 2 195.1 m (2,100 sq ft)) 46 cm (18 8”) primarily herbs, somee flowers, fru uits and vegetables accessible e to hotel staaff and guessts 4.2.2 Summaryy of Project F Waterfront W Hotel H is a luxxury hotel oon the down ntown Vanco ouver The Fairmont wateerfront, adjaacent to the Canada Place cruise sh hip terminall and the Waaterfront train n station and d transit terrminal. Wheen the hotel was built in n 1991, a grreen roof with ivy and peaa gravel path hs was initially installeed on the larrge third flo oor terrace on th he building’ss south sidee; the hotel has h a total oof 23 storeyys. The hotell designers’ 4 49 inten ntion was to o provide pleasant view ws for occup pants of the rooms on th he south side of the high-rise tower above a the teerrace; room ms on the no orth side already had view ws into the harbour and the mountaains in the d distance. Th he City of Vaancouver supp ported the crreation of th he green terrrace, recoggnizing that it would alsso afford pleassant views for f the neigh hbouring bu uildings (CM MHC, 2003).. The southern s po ortion of thee terrace waas converted d to an herb b garden in 1994 at a cost of o C$25,000 0. The herb garden wass implementted on the ssouth terracce because sun exposure e waas not sufficcient elsewh here. The gaarden is maintained year round and harvested h between latee march and d late fall byy the hotel’s restaurant staff. The gardeen is divided into 11 pllant beds in which overr 60 speciess were grow wn in the 2008 8 season. Th he majority of o the species grown arre herbs but the garden n also produces leafy green g vegetaables such as a chard, aru ugula, bok cchoy, and Ch hinese green ns, as well as a a few smaall fruits succh as strawb berries, plum ms, and graapes. Severaal speciies of decorative and ed dible plantss are grown as well (Jam mieson, 200 08). The produce is used primarily in n the hotel restaurant r b but consum mers also incclude hotel staff and patrons. The gardeen also prov vides habitaat for a largee number of small birdss. Calculationss 4.2.3 Benefits C bene efit prope erty value ‐ recrreational roo oftop garden n appliccable ‐ prod ductive roofftop garden ‐ view w onto a green roof comment not recreational ble to tenantts/owners off not accessib surroundingg properties,, applies only tto the host p property ttested on Prricewaterhouse Cooperss Place at 2500 Howe, facin ng directly into the garden 5 50 marketing sound attenuation food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration data unavailable no significant source of overhead noise 4.2.4 Variables See Table 9 for a definition of the variables. v = C$116,078,000 vv = C$119,688,000* h = 3 stories hv = 20 stories* a = 195.1 m2 g = 8 months * PricewaterhouseCoopers Place at 250 Howe Street, directly across from the herb garden (source: City of Vancouver) 4.2.5 Calculations 4.2.5.1 propertyvalue Host property with productive rooftop garden Since the current property value includes the benefit, we let: vx = property value excluding the benefit ($) 51 v = vx + b and b = 0.07⋅ v x therefore v = v x + (0.07⋅ v x ) v = 1.07⋅ v x v 1.07 ($116,078,000) = 1.07 = $108,484,112 vx = b = 0.07($108,484,112) = $7,593,888 View onto a green roof: Whole building gain in property value Since the current property value includes the benefit, we let: vnx = property value of the neighbouring excluding the benefit ($) 52 v v = vnx + b and a b = 0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vnx hv therefore t v v = vnx + (0.045 5⋅ = vnx + (0.045 5⋅ hv − h ⋅ vnx ) hv (20)−(3) ⋅ vnx ) (20) v v = 1.03825⋅ vnx n vv 1.03825 ($433,856)) = 1.03825 593 = $115,278,5 vnx = b = v v − vnx 000)−($115 5,278,594) = ($119,688,0 6 = $4,409,406 4.2.5..2 foodpro oduction Low sscenario High scenario 53 4.2.5..3 stormwaterretention Low‐ccost stormw water retentio on infrastruccture scenarrio High‐‐cost stormw water retentiion infrastru ucture scenaario 4.2.5..4 airquallity Low sscenario (10 00% short gra ass coveragee) High scenario (10 00% deciduo ous tree coveerage) questration 4.2.5..5 GHGseq Low sscenario (10 00% grass coverage) High scenario (10 00% deciduo ous coveragee) 54 4.2.6 Benefits Summary benefit property value (host) property value (neighbour) food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration type one time one time annual one time annual annual value $7,593,888 $4,409,406 $3,121 ‐ $31,210 $281 ‐ $8,939 $11.54 ‐ $18.73 $0.56 ‐ $0.76 4.2.7 Observations The property value benefit of $7,593,888 that accrues to the hotel seems realistic. The PricewaterhouseCoopers Place across the street from the herb garden was calculated to receive a boost in property value on the order of $4,409,406, also seemingly realistic. The production food production value was estimated to be between $3,121 and $31,210. Given that the garden produces herbs, lettuces, and flowers primarily, all of which have a high market value, the total value of production is likely to be at the upper end of this range. The stormwater management benefit is estimated to range between $281 and $8,939. Given that the building is located in an extremely dense urban environment with very high land values, low cost stormwater management solutions (which are land intensive) are not an option. For this reason, the value of the benefit is likely to be at the upper end of the range in this case. The value of the air quality benefit is estimated to be between $11.54 and $18.73. Given the prevalence of leafy plants, the value is likely to tend towards the upper range. The GHG sequestration benefit is estimated to be worth between $0.56 and $0.76. Given that garden includes mostly small plants and few bushes and trees, the value of the benefit is likely to tend towards the lower end of the range. 55 4.3 Case Stud dy 3 – 401 Richmond d, Toronto,, ON 4.3.1 Key Featu ures location type of building numb ber of storeyys type of green roo of roof cconstruction n comp pletion date developer desiggner vegettative area depth h of growingg medium type of vegetatio on accesssibility 401 Richm mond Streett West, Toro onto, ON commerciial 4 semi‐inten nsive retrofit intensive portion buil t in 1998; extensive portion addded 2005 Urbanspace Property Group intensive portion by M Margaret Zeidler and Mo onika Kuhn; extensive portion by XXero Flor 603.9 m2 (6,500 sq ft)) intensive; 241.5 m2 (2,600 sq ft)) extensive; 65.0 m2 (7 700 sq ft) greeenhouse intensive portion madde up of con ntainers of vaarious depth h; extensive portion is 5 cm (2”) deeep intensive portion has flowers, vin nes, and bush hes; extensive portion is coovered in seedum accessible e to the geneeral public 5 56 4.3.2 Summaryy of Project The 401 4 Richmo ond buildingg was origin nally constru ucted in 189 99 and housed a factorry producing lithog graphed tinw ware. The building b wass expanded between 19 903 and 1923 3, taking on it current ‘letter A’ floo or plan (see aerial photto below). T The buildingg changed hands several s timees in the posstwar era an nd was slateed for demo olition when n Toronto impresaarios, the Zeeidler Familly, purchaseed the build ding. The bu uilding undeerwent majo or refurbish hment over next n few yeears. The building’s 18,5 580 m2 (200,000 sq ft) floor f area no ow houses over o 140 arrtists and en ntrepreneurrs, includingg fine artists, a desig gners, millin ners, architects, filmmaakers, gallerries, musicians, arts organ nizations, and magazin nes (Urbansp pace Properrty Group, 2 2008). The roof garden waas informallly initiated he third floo or roof on in 1995 on top of th the soutth side (back) of the property. Thee rooftop was alreadyy a popularr gathering space foor the buildiing’s tenantts. The property ty manager, a plant aficcionado, spearheeaded the deevelopmentt of the garden. In 1998, a 6 603.9 m2 (6 6,500 sq ft) nstructed on n a portion cedar deeck was con of the rooof and coveered with numerous planterss with floweers, bushes, and vines. The species s werre selected primarily p for their decoorative value (Urbanspace Property Group,, 2007a). A 65.0 6 m2 (70 00 sq ft) gre enhouse, w which servess as a winterr nts, was add ded in 2000 0. Later, in 2 2005, a furth her 241.5 m2 nurseery for some of the plan (2,60 00 sq ft) of the t roof werre covered with w a lightw weight exteensive green n roof systeem, consistin ng of a 2-incch growing medium plaanted with sedum (Urb banspace Property Group,, 2007b). 4 Richmo ond roof garrden has atttracted a con nsiderable aamount of aattention The 401 from m the media in Toronto, providing publicity p forr Urbanspacce Propertyy Group, the comp pany that ow wns and maanages the building, b and d indirectlyy for the building’s tenan nts. In 2008 8, the City off Toronto aw warded Urb banspace Prroperty Grou up a Green Toronto Award for the 401 Richmond roof garden n. a Urbanspaace, residentts living in tthe 14-storeey District According to an employee at Loftss building, directly d acro oss Richmon nd Street, saay that they enjoy the vview onto the 401 4 Richmon nd roof gard den. A group of residen nts at District Lofts wass reportedlyy inspiired to creatte their own n rooftop gaarden and coontacted Urrbanspace tto obtain inforrmation for this purposse. The initiaative has yeet to be realiized. 5 57 4.3.3 Benefits C Calculationss bene efit prope erty value appliccable comment ‐ view w onto a green roof ttested on a loft condom minium unit at 388 Richm mond St. Weest ‐ recrreational roo oftop garden n ‐ prod ductive roofftop garden markketing sound d attenuatio on food production storm mwater reten ntion air qu uality GHG sequestratio on primarily reccreational; ccurrently no ffood producction no source off significant overhead noise currently no o food produ uction 4.3.4 4 Variabless See Table T 9 for a definition of the variaables. v vv a g pradio rradio tradio ptv rtv ttv = = = = = = = = = = C$13,923,000 C$296,500** 845.4 m2 (= = 603.9 m2 + 241.5 m2) 7 months 0 note:therrehasbeenn noknownraadiocoverag geof401Riichmond $250/spot fromTable 3 0 umption $2,000 assu $2,778/spo ot fromTablee 3 2.3 spots seeecalculatio onbelow 5 58 pprint = $100 assumption rprint = 190.4 inches seecalculationbelow l = $392/inch fromTable 3 * Sale price of a condominium loft unit at 388 Richmond West with a view onto the 401 Richmond roof garden (source: REMAX) 4.3.5 Calculations 4.3.5.1 propertyvalue View onto a green roof: Single unit gain in property value Since the current property value includes the property view benefit, we let: vnx = property value of the unit with a view excluding the benefit ($) v v = vnx + b and b = 0.09⋅ vnx therefore v v = v vnr + (0.09⋅ vnx ) v v = 1.09⋅ vnx vv 1.09 ($296,500) = 1.09 = $272,018 vnx = b = v v − vnx = ($296,500)−($272,018) = $24,482 Host property with recreational rooftop garden Since the current property value includes the property value benefit, we let: vx = property value excluding the benefit ($) 59 v = vx + b and b = 0.11⋅ v x therefore v = v x + (0.11⋅ v x ) v = 1.11⋅ v x v vx = 1.11 (13,923,000) = 1.11 = 12,543,243 b = 0.11(12,771,513) = 1,379,756 4.3.5.2 marketing Table 10 – Media Coverage of the 401 Richmond Green Roof in Toronto TELEVISION Station Vision TV Program Recreating Eden Conv. Discount factor factor (D) Spots 1/min 0.1 2.3 Total 2.3 Type of mention factual Dimension 23 min Type of mention Dimension Conv. Discount factor factor (D) PRINT Source The Globe and Mail The Globe and Mail The Globe and Mail The Globe and Mail The Globe and Title "A garden rooted on the rooftop" "Zeidler combines building and activism" "The places that mattered to Jane Jacobs" "Growing an Eden up near heaven" "Growing an Eden up article 17” picture Column Inches 2 1 34” 9” X 6” 0.5 1 27.0” picture 6” X 4” 0.5 1 12.0” article 21.5” 2 1 43.0” picture 8.5” X 5” 0.5 1 21.3” 60 Mail Toronto Star Toronto Star Toronto Star Toronto Star Toronto Star Toronto Star Toronto Star near heaven" "It's easier being green" "Rooftop relief" "Rooftop relief" "Feeling the need for green" "Office oasis" "Office oasis" "Gardens in the sky yield earthly delights" "Look up, look way up" "Best Free Hangout" Green Toronto Award Nominations Eye Weekly Now Magazine Green Living Magazine Green Living "A roof that's a view" Magazine Our Arts Feature Neighbourhood The Liberty "Green groceries" Gleaner Your Source “Rooftop gardens” Magazine Source: Urbanspace Property Group sentence article picture 1 sentence 1” 7.5” X 4.5” ‐ 2 0.5 1 1 1 1.0” 2.0” 16.9” 2 1 3.0” 2 0.5 1 1 2.0” 11.9” article 1.5” article picture 1” 9” X 5.5” article 3.5” 2 1 7.0” article article 1.5” 2.5” 2 2 0.25 0.25 0.8” 1.3” article 2” 2 0.1 0.4” article 17” 2 0.1 3.4” picture 5.5” X 3.5” 0.5 0.1 1.0” article 3.5” 2 0.1 0.7” article 8.5” 2 0.1 1.7” Total 190.4” b =[pradio + rradio ⋅tradio ]+[ptv + rtv ⋅ttv ]+[ppaper + rpaper ⋅ l] =[(0)+ ($250)(0)]radio +[($2,000)+ ($2,778)(2.3)]tv +[($100)+ ($392)(190.4)]paper = 0+ $8,389.40+ $74,736.80 = $83,126 4.3.5.3 stormwaterretention Low‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $1.44/m2 ⋅ a = $1.44/m2 ⋅(845.4m2 ) = $1,217 High‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $45.82/ m2 ⋅ a = $45.82/ m2 ⋅(845.4m2 ) = $38,736 61 4.3.5.4 airquality Low scenario (100% short grass coverage) b = ($0.0074 / m2 ⋅ months) ⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0074 / m2 ⋅ months) ⋅(7months) ⋅(845.4m2 ) = $43.79 High scenario (100% deciduous tree coverage) b = ($0.0120/m2 ⋅ months)⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0120/m2 ⋅ months)⋅(7months)⋅(845.4m2 ) = $71.01 4.3.5.5 GHGsequestration Low scenario (100% grass coverage) b =($28.46/ ha)⋅ a =($28.46/ ha)⋅(0.08454ha) = $2.41 High scenario (100% deciduous coverage) b =($39.11/ ha)⋅ a =($39.11/ ha)⋅(0.08454ha) = $3.31 4.3.6 Benefits Summary benefit property value (host building) property value (neighbouring condo unit) marketing stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration type value $1,379,756 one time one time $24,482 one time one time annual annual $83,126 $1,217 ‐ $38,736 $43.79 ‐ $71.01 $2.41 ‐ $3.31 62 4.3.7 Observations The property value benefit of $1,379,756 that accrues to the owner of 401 Richmond seems realistic. The sale price of a condominium unit in the District Lofts building across the street was estimated to include a benefit of $24,482 attributed to its view onto the 401 Richmond rooftop garden. Since the construction of the rooftop garden, the 401 Richmond property has enjoyed an estimated $83,126 in free publicity. The estimate appears to be realistic. The stormwater management benefit is estimated to range between $1,217 and $38,736. Given that the building is located in an extremely dense urban environment with very high land values, low cost stormwater management solutions (which are land intensive) are not an option. For this reason, the value of the benefit is likely to be at the upper end of the range in this case. The air quality benefit is estimated to be worth between $43.79 and $71.01. Given the prevalence of bushes and vines and the relatively small area of the extensive portion of the roof, the value is likely to tend towards the upper range. The GHG sequestration benefit is estimated to be worth between $2.41 and $3.31. Given that the garden includes a mix of bushy plants, some small trees and various small plants (i.e., sedum on the extensive portion), the value of the benefit is likely to tend towards the middle of the range. 63 4.4 Case Stud dy 4 – Roofftop Victory Gardens, Chicago o, IL 4.4.1 Key Featu ures location 6034 Nortth Broadwayy, Chicago, IL type of building supermarrket; former auto mechaanic shop numb ber of storeyys 1 type of green roo of intensive roof cconstruction n retrofit comp pletion date 2006 developer Urban Habitat Chicag o and True N Nature Food ds desiggner Dave Ham mpton / Echoo Studio 2 vegettative area 163.5 m (1,760 sq ft))* depth h of growingg medium 1.3 cm to 10.2 cm (0.55” to 4”) type of vegetatio on various he erbs and veggetables accesssibility accessible e to project vvolunteers o only 2 * Inclludes 74.3 m (800 sq ft) f planned Phase II exp pansion. 6 64 4.4.2 Summaryy of Project The Rooftop R Victory Garden n is hosted by b True Nature Foods, an n organic fo ood cooperaative and neigh hbourhood recycling ceentre in the Edgewaterr district on the north side off Chicago. Th he garden takess its name frrom the factt that the saame site wass used as a ‘victory garden’ during the World W Wars. So-caalled victory y gardens orr war gardeens were plantted at privatte residencees in the US S, the UK, and Canada C duriing the wars to reduce pressure on n the public p food supply. s Urbaan Habitat Chicago (UHC), a local non-profit n group promoting sustainab ble practicess in urban nitiated the project in 2005. 2 UHC envirronments, in was awarded a a $5,000 $ gran nt from the City C of Chicaago Green Roof R Grants Program to owards the realizzation of the project. No other finaancing was p provided; th he project w was developed throu ugh volunteer labour an nd pro-bonoo architectu ural consultations. After den was imp plemented in n over a year of reesearch and design, thee first phase of the gard ber 2006. The T first harvest occurred the follo wing summ mer. Octob The garden’s g peak growing season is between Mayy and August. Species ggrown havee so farr included: amaranth, basil, b buckw wheat, collarrd greens, eeggplant, greeen beans, horseeradish, varrious tomato oes, lavendeer, mushroooms, mustarrd greens, o onions, bell and chili c pepperrs, potatoes,, sage, snap peas, thyme, wheat, an nd zucchini.. The speciees are rotated depeending on th he season. In addition, burdock, cleome, cloveer, cosmos, dand delions, marrigolds, and a variety off grasses ha ve been plaanted to help p establish the growing g med dium and atttract benefficial insectss. The produ uce grown d during the 2007 7 and 2008 seasons s was mostly disstributed am mong projecct volunteerrs and somee was sold s at the store s below w (UHC, 2008 8). According to thee UHC, the Rooftop R Victtory Garden ns have beco ome the “po oster child” he City of Ch hicago's Greeen Roof Graants Prograam. The projject has beeen the for th subjeect of news reports in local, nation nal and even n some interrnational m media (UHC, undaated). 6 65 66 4.4.3 Benefits Calculations benefit property value applicable ‐ view onto a green roof ‐ recreational rooftop garden ‐ productive rooftop garden marketing sound attenuation food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration comment tested on residential property at 1214 W Norwood St. not recreational assumed to accrue to host and to neighbouring properties; tested on residential property at 1214 W Norwood St. insufficient data no source of significant overhead noise 4.4.4 Variables See Table 9 for a definition of the variables. v = US$107,871 vv = US$433,856* d = 11 m h = 1 storeys hv = 2 storeys* a = 163.5 m2 g = 7 months * Four-unit residential property at 1214 W Norwood St., directly behind the True Nature Foods property (source: Cook County Assessor’s Office, 2009) 4.4.5 Calculations 4.4.5.1 propertyvalue View onto a green roof: Whole building gain in property value Since the current property value presumably includes the benefit of a view onto a green roof, we let: vnx = neighbouring property value excluding the benefit ($) 67 v v = vnx + b and b = 0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vnx hv therefore v v = vnx + (0.045⋅ = vnx + (0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vnx ) hv (2)−(1) ⋅ vnx ) (2) v v = 1.0225⋅ vnx vv 1.0225 ($433,856) = 1.0225 = $424,309 vnx = b = v v − vnx = ($433,856)−($424,309) = $9,546 Host property with productive rooftop garden Since the current property value includes the productive green roof benefit, we let: vx = property value excluding the benefit ($) 68 v = vx + b and b = 0.07⋅ v x therefore v = v x + (0.07⋅ v x ) v = 1.07⋅ v x v 1.07 ($107,871) = 1.07 = $100,814 vx = b = 0.07($11,602,500) = $7,057 Property neighbouring with a productive rooftop garden Since the current property value includes the productive green roof benefit, we let: vnx = neighbouring property value excluding the benefit ($) v = vnx + b and b = F ⋅ vnx therefore v = vnx + (F ⋅ vnx ) v = vnx +[(0.05)⋅ vnx ] v = 1.05⋅ vnx v 1.05 ($433,856) = 1.05 = $413,196 vnx = b = 0.05($413,196) = $20,660 69 4.4.5.2 foodproduction Low scenario b = ($2/ m2 ⋅ month)⋅ g ⋅ a =($2/ m2 ⋅ month)⋅(7months)⋅(163.5m2 ) = $2,289 High scenario b = ($20/ m2 ⋅ month)⋅ g ⋅ a =($20/ m2 ⋅ month)⋅(7months)⋅(163.5m2 ) = $22,890 4.4.5.3 stormwaterretention Low‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $1.44/m2 ⋅ a = $1.44/m2 ⋅(163.5m2 ) = $235 High‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $45.82/ m2 ⋅ a = $45.82/ m2 ⋅(163.5m2 ) = $7,491 4.4.5.4 airquality Low scenario (100% short grass coverage) b = ($0.0074 / m2 ⋅ months) ⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0074 / m2 ⋅ months) ⋅(7months) ⋅(163.5m2 ) = $8.47 70 High scenario (100% deciduous tree coverage) b = ($0.0120/m2 ⋅ months)⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0120/m2 ⋅ months)⋅(7months)⋅(163.5m2 ) = $13.73 4.4.5.5 GHGsequestration Low scenario (100% grass coverage) b =($28.46/ ha)⋅ a =($28.46/ ha)⋅(0.01635ha) = $0.47 High scenario (100% deciduous coverage) b = ($39.11/ ha)⋅ a = ($39.11/ ha)⋅(0.01635ha) = $0.64 4.4.6 Benefits Summary benefit property value (host) property value (neighbour) proximity to productive garden property value (neighbour) view onto green roof marketing food production stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration type one time value $7,057 one time $20,660 one time $9,546 one time annual one time annual annual $2,289 – $22,890 $235 – $7,491 $8.47 – $13.73 $0.47 – $0.64 4.4.7 Observations The property value benefit of $7,057 that accrues to the True Nature Foods store seems realistic. The residential building behind True Nature Foods, at 1214 W Norwood, was assumed to benefit from being close to what is more or less a community garden, gaining as much as $20,660 from its proximity to the garden. This assumption implies that the residents of 1214 W Norwood are able to participate in the gardening activities at True Nature Foods and they receive part of the garden’s yield. The 1214 W Norwood building also has a view onto the garden, which affords a considerably smaller benefit of $9,546. It should be noted that the garden is not designed 71 for visuall appeal and d therefore it is questioonable whetther the view w benefits apply in this t case. The prod duction food d production n value wass estimated to be betweeen $2,289 and $22,8 890. Given that t the garden producces many veegetables, in ncluding inexpensive staples but also som me high valu ue-added sp pecies such as herbs and lettuces, the valu ue of the beenefit is like ly to be in the middle o of the range. The storm mwater man nagement benefit b is esttimated to rrange betweeen $235 and $7,49 91. Given th hat the build ding is locatted in a med dium-densitty urban area with h moderate land valuess, high cost ((below grad de) stormwaater managem ment solutio ons are unlik kely to be n ecessary. A At the same ttime, being an urban environmeent, some beelow grade sstormwaterr retention infrastructure is likeely to be neeeded. For th hese reasonss, the value of the ng towards the higher benefit iss likely to bee in the middle of the raange, tendin end. worth betweeen $8.47 an nd $13.73. The air quality benefit is estimaated to be w Given thee prevalencee of leafy plants, the vaalue is likelyy to tend tow wards the upper ran nge. The GHG sequestratiion benefit is estimated d to be wortth between $0.47 and $0.64. Giv ven that garrden includees mostly sm mall plants,, the value o of the benefiit is likely to t tend towaards the low wer end of th he range. 4.5 Case Stud dy 5 – The Louisa, Po ortland, OR R 7 72 4.5.1 Key Features location type of building number of storeys type of green roof roof construction completion date developer designer vegetative area depth of growing medium type of vegetation accessibility 123 Northwest 12th Avenue, Portland, OR residential 18 semi‐intensive new construction 2005 Gerding Elden Development Walker Macy 584.9 m2 (6,296 sq ft) extensive; 749.8 m2 (8,071 sq ft) intensive 10.2 cm (4”) to 61.0 cm (24”) drought tolerant native species (grasses and bushes) accessible to tenants of The Louisa only 4.5.2 Summary of Project The Louisa is a residential high-rise apartment building with 242 apartments and ground floor retail, situated in the historic Pearl District of downtown Portland. The property was developed and is owned by Gerding Elden, a development firm specializing in mixed-use, sustainable urban development. The Louisa is part of the Brewery Blocks redevelopment project. The project, which covers five city blocks, takes its name from the defunct brewery that once occupied the site. The Louisa building is composed of a large podium at the base, which houses the retails spaces, and a tower set at the back of the podium, which contains the bulk of the apartments. The green roof is situated on top of the podium and can therefore be viewed directly from at least half of the apartments in the tower. The green roof features both extensive and intensive components. The larger (749.8 m2) portion of the roof is an accessible recreational rooftop garden with intensive vegetation. The garden is flanked on either side by non-accessible extensive green roofs (292.5 m2 each). These are two storeys higher than the garden as they sit on top of two-storey townhouse units facing into the garden. Both the intensive and extensive portions are planted with drought-tolerant native species, which can withstand Portland’s relatively dry summers with minimal watering (Peck, 2008). The Louisa was built to meet the US Green Building Council’s strict LEED criteria for new buildings. Its intensive and extensive green roofs are among its many green features, which have earned it a rating of LEED-Gold – the second highest sustainability rating given by the Green Building Council. In the 2007, the Green Roofs for Healthy Cities annual award for best intensive residential green roof project was conferred upon the Louisa. 73 74 4.5.3 Benefits Calculations benefit property value ‐ recreational rooftop garden ‐ productive rooftop garden ‐ view onto a green roof marketing applicable sound attenuation food production comment no food produced from upper floors of the Louisa data unavailable no source of significant overhead noise no food produced stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration 4.5.4 Variables v = US$56,924,000.00 vv = US$56,924,000.00 h = 2 hv = 18 a = 1,334.7 m2 (= 584.9 m2 + 749.8 m2) g = 9 months 4.5.5 Calculations 4.5.5.1 propertyvalue View onto a green roof: whole building gain in property value Since the current property value includes the view benefit, we let: vx = property value excluding the view benefit ($) 75 vv = vx + b and b = 0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vx hv therefore v v = v x + (0.045⋅ = v x + (0.045⋅ hv − h ⋅ vx ) hv (18)−(2) ⋅ vx ) (18) v v = 1.04⋅ v x vv 1.04 ($56,924,000) = 1.04 = $54,734,615 vx = b = vv − vx = ($56,924,000)−($54,734,615) = $2,189,385 Host property with recreational rooftop garden Since the current property value includes the property value benefit, we let: vx = property value excluding the benefit ($) 76 v = vx + b and b = 0.11⋅ v x therefore v = v x + (0.11⋅ v x ) v = 1.11⋅ v x v vx = 1.11 (56,924,000) = 1.11 = 51,282,882 b = 0.11(51,282,882) = 5,641,117 4.5.5.2 stormwaterretention Low‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $1.44/ m2 ⋅ a = $1.44/ m2 ⋅(1,334.7m2 ) = $1,922 High‐cost stormwater retention infrastructure scenario b = $45.82/ m2 ⋅ a = $45.82/ m2 ⋅(1,334.7m2 ) = $61,156 4.5.5.3 airquality Low scenario (100% short grass coverage) b = ($0.0074 / m2 ⋅ months) ⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0074 / m2 ⋅ months) ⋅(9months) ⋅(1,334.7m2 ) = $88.89 77 High scenario (100% deciduous tree coverage) b = ($0.0120/m2 ⋅ months)⋅ g ⋅ a = ($0.0120/m2 ⋅ months)⋅(9months)⋅(1,334.7m2 ) = $144.15 4.5.5.4 GHGsequestration Low scenario (100% grass coverage) b =($28.46/ ha)⋅ a =($28.46/ ha)⋅(0.13347ha) = $3.80 High scenario (100% deciduous coverage) b =($39.11/ ha)⋅ a =($39.11/ ha)⋅(0.13347ha) = $5.22 4.5.6 Benefits Summary benefit property value (view) type value one time $2,189,385 $5,641,117 property value (accessible recreational garden) one time stormwater retention air quality GHG sequestration one time annual annual $1,922 ‐ $61,156 $88.89 ‐ $144.15 $3.80 ‐ $5.22 4.5.7 Observations Two types of property value benefits can accrue to the Louisa property: a benefit due to having an accessible recreational rooftop garden, worth $9,487,333; and a benefit resulting from close to half the units in the Louisa having a view onto the rooftop garden, worth $2,189,385. It is plausible to argue that these two benefits are additive. If the rooftop were on top of the building, affording no views from within the building itself, we would still estimate a property value of benefit of $9,487,333. The two benefits added together would thus yield a total property value benefit of $11,676,718. The stormwater management benefit is estimated to range between $1,922 and $61,156. Given that the building is located in a very dense urban environment with very high land values, low cost stormwater management 78 solutions (which are land intensive) are not an option. For this reason, the value of the benefit is likely to be at the upper end of the range in this case. The air quality benefit is estimated to be worth between $88.89 and $144.15. Given that the roof is semi-extensive, with both mixed grassy and leafy vegetation, the value of the benefit is likely to tend towards the middle of the range. The GHG sequestration benefit is estimated to be worth between $3.80 and $5.22. Given that the roof is semi-extensive, with both mixed grassy and leafy vegetation, the value of the benefit is likely to lay in the middle of the range. 79 5 Conclusions This report has provided evidence that soft benefits produce economic advantages for individual property owners, municipalities, and society at large. Despite the fact that the benefits depend on the local context, we have provided heuristic methods to estimate the economic value associated with seven soft-benefits. These are methods that can be used by property owners, developers, architects, municipal officials, and other stakeholders with information that is often readily-at-hand. The reader should keep in mind the assumptions that had to be made in order to arrive at these quick calculation methods. Some of these assumptions, along with the beneficiaries, benefiting period, and a short statement of the valuation method appear in Table 11. Table 11 ‐ Summary of Soft Benefit Valuations Section Benefit Category 3.1 Property Value Beneficiaries Assumptions Type Valuation Error! Reference source not found. view onto a green roof property owner* and/or neighbours independent of area one‐time up to 4.5% property value (portion above green roof) 3.1.1 property owner independent of area one‐time recreational garden up to 11% property value 3.1.3 productive garden property owner occupant access, independent of area one‐time up to 7% property value neighbours (adjacent) public access, independent of area one‐time up to 7% property value neighbours (150 m) public access, independent of area one‐time up to 5% property value neighbours (300 m) public access, independent of area one‐time up to 2% property value 3.2 Marketing property owner comparable to free publicity one‐time see Table 3 3.3 Food production tenants, property owner excludes labour and material costs ongoing $2‐$20/m2 per growing month 3.4 Sound attenuation property owner affects top floor only, each floor is worth an equal portion of the total property value, independent of area but assume extensive coverage one‐time 1.6% to 4.3% property value of top floor 3.5 Stormwater retention developer, municipality 42.7L/m2 retention capacity one‐time $1.44/m2 to 2 $45.82/m 80 3.6 Air quality municipality, region ongoing $521/ha to $839/ha per year 3.7 GHG sequestration municipality, region, planet ongoing $28/ha to $39/ha per year *If the green roof can be seen from at least part of the host property The case studies presented in this report show that the proposed valuation methodologies can be applied in real-life situations without requiring large (or difficult to obtain) data inputs. In general, the valuations returned by applying the methodologies seem to be of a reasonable magnitude. The observations presented at the end of each case study should help the reader interpret the results and judge how best to apply the methodologies in their own context. Among the one-time benefits proposed here, the property value benefits are by far the most significant. Properties with accessible green roofs are subject to a 11% property value premium, while those with rooftop food gardens gain 7% in property value. Neighbours of both types of green roofs also stand to benefit significantly from their presence. Buildings with views onto a green roof could gain up to 4.5% of property value (depending on how many floors have a view of the greenroof), while those adjacent to rooftop food gardens could gain from 2% to 7% (depending on distance from the building with the rooftop garden). It should be noted that the sum of the all the property value gains accruing to neighbouring properties could be considerably larger than the value of the benefit accruing to the host property. Sound attenuation offers one-time benefits on a similar order of magnitude, ranging from a 1.6% to a 4.3% property value premium on the value of the top floor. However, this benefit only arises if there is a significant source of overhead noise, such as air traffic or an elevated train nearby. As for the marketing benefit, also a one-time benefit, the experience of the 401 Richmond building in Toronto (Case Study 3, Section 4.3) suggests that it is relatively small – 0.6% of property value in this case. The value of the stormwater management benefit varies considerably when viewed as a fraction of property value. In the 401 Richmond case, for example, it is estimated to be worth between 0.01% and 0.28% of property value, whereas in the case of the True Nature Foods Victory Garden, it is estimated to be worth 0.2% to 6.9% of the property value. This benefit is not tied to property value but rather to the area of the green roof; True Nature Foods has low property value but a relatively large roof and the stormwater benefit is therefore much larger relative to property value. Where ongoing benefits are concerned, the food production benefit is much more valuable than the air quality and GHG sequestering benefits, according to our methods of estimation. We propose that the value of the food produced on a rooftop garden is worth $2 to $20 per square metre per month in the growing season. As most of the North American population lives in places where the growing season is 81 at least 6 months long, the benefit is therefore worth at the very least $12/m2 of rooftop growing area per year. In places with a year-round growing season, such as in the southern coastal states, the benefit could be worth up to $240/m2 per year. In contrast, the air quality benefit is worth between $0.0521/m2 to $0.0839/m2 per year and the GHG sequestration benefit is worth $0.0028/m2 to $0.0039/m2 per year. The difference between food production and air quality/GHG benefits is well illustrated by the two case studies that feature rooftop food production (Case Studies 2 and 4). In Case Study 2, on the Fairmont Waterfront Hotel herb garden, food production is estimated to be worth $3,121 to $31,210 per year, while air quality improvement is worth $11.54-$18.73 per year and GHG sequestration is worth a mere $0.56-$0.76 per year. In Case Study 4, on the True Nature Foods Rooftop Victory Garden, food production is estimated to be worth $2,289 to $22,890 per year, while air quality improvement is worth $8.47-$13.73 per year and GHG sequestration is worth a mere $0.47-$0.64 per year. Given how small the air quality and GHG sequestration benefits are, it is almost meaningless to include them in an assessment of the benefit values for individual green roofs. Both of these benefits would be more meaningful if calculated for numerous green roofs covering a substantial portion of a neighbourhood or city. For example, as reported above, Bating et al (2005) calculated that if all flat rooftops across the City of Toronto were extensively greened, the annual cost savings attributable to reduction in air pollution would amount to US$1,970,000 (C$2,700,000 in 2008). Readers are reminded that the methodologies offered here are heuristic in nature; they are rough estimations based on a number of assumptions that are reasonable in most cases but may not be applicable in specific contexts. Changes in the assumptions will of course lead to a different evaluation of benefits. Also, the report provides calculation methods for a range of greenroof conditions. These are meant to serve as benchmarks only and of course do not cover all potential situations. The user is asked to use their own best judgment as to whether and how the assumptions made and range of conditions covered in this report can be usefully applied or adapted to their own unique situation. It is also important to keep in mind when using the calculation methodologies presented in this report that we did not account for any of the costs involved in producing the benefits. Most importantly, we did not account for the extra costs involved in creating a green roof compared to a conventional roof. Nor did we include the higher property taxes that might accrue to buildings whose property values have been increased due to the presence of a green roof. Finally, we did not account for direct inputs such as the cost of materials and labour that go into food production. 82 As already noted, the goal of this report was to allow users to make rough calculations of benefits without undertaking a major research effort. For the most part, this has been achieved: the equations require data that is usually readily available such as property value, building height, roof area, and so on. The sole exception is the marketing benefit, which requires detailed information on publicity gained due to the green roof. Our experience with the case studies suggests that most green roof property owners do not have precise information on media coverage, if they track it at all. Future research might address this by tracking media coverage across many green roof projects and generating a more generic formula for estimating the value of the marketing benefit. To our knowledge, this is the first attempt in the growing literature on green roofs to offer a means for calculating the value of a range of soft benefits associated with the use of the technology. Clearly, however, it is not the last word. Future research may not only allow us to refine the approaches offered here but to expand the range of soft benefits covered to include, for example, habitat creation and community building. If this report has helped put us on this path, then it has served its purpose. 83 Interviewees Michelle Bates-Benetua Lettuce Link Program Manager Solid Ground michelleb@solid-ground.org 206-694-6754 Martine Desbois Coordinator of Sustainability Initiatives Dockside Green mdesbois@docksidegreen.com 250-360-1100 x 227 Neil Jamieson Executive Sous Chef Fairmont Waterfront neil.jamieson@fairmont.com 604-691-1991 x1611 Emily Lake Director of Urban Agriculture Urban Habitat Chicago emilyhlake@gmail.com Robert Lotz Advertising Sales Representative 103.9 PROUD-FM robertlotz@hotmail.com 416-948-7944 Erin MacKeen Communications Director Urbanspace erin@urbanspace.org 416-595-5900 x 25 Rich McDonald P-Patch Program Manager Department of Neighborhoods City of Seattle 84 rich.macdonald@seattle.gov 206-386-0088 Sky Seeley Sales Coordinator Dockside Green sky@docksidegreen.ca 250-380-7278 85 Bibliography Akbari, H. & Konopacki, S. (2003). Streamlinedenergy‐savingscalculationsforheat‐ islandreductionstrategies. Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory: Berkeley, CA. LBNL Paper #47307. Banting, D., Doshi, H., Li, J., Missios, P., Au, A., Currie, B.A., & Verrati, M. (2005). ReportontheEnvironmentalBenefitsandCostsofGreenRoofTechnologyfortheCity ofToronto. Report prepared for the City of Toronto and Ontario Centres of Excellence – Earth and Environmental Technologies (OCE-ETech) (http://www.toronto.ca/greenroofs/pdf/fullreport103105.pdf). Barrs, R. (2002). SoutheastFalseCreekUrbanAgricultureStrategy. Holland-Barrs Planning Group in Association with Lees + Associates. Bateman, I., Day, B., Lake, I., & Lovett, A. (2000). TheEffectofRoadTrafficon ResidentialPropertyValues:ALiteratureReviewandHedonicPricingStudy. Edinburgh: Scottish Office, Development Department. Bay Localize (2008). BayLocalizeWebGallery–TrueNatureFoodsRooftopVictory Garden. Webpage (http://www.baylocalize.org/webgallery/thumbnails.php?album=48&page=2). Brown, K. (2002). UrbanAgricultureandCommunityFoodSecurityintheUnited States:FarmingfromtheCityCentertotheUrbanFringe. Community Food Security Coalition. Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation (CMHC) (2003). FairmontWaterfront HotelGreenRoofHerbGardenCaseStudy,Vancouver,BritishColumbia. From the CMHC Innovative Buildings series (http://www.cmhcschl.gc.ca/en/inpr/bude/himu/inbu/upload/Fairmont-Waterfront-Hotel.pdf). Canadian Automobile Association (2008). DrivingCosts,2008Edition. Retrieved from: http://www.caa.ca/documents/DrivingCostsBrochure-2008-eng-web.pdf. Carter, T. & Keeler, A. (2008). Life-cycle cost–benefit analysis of extensive vegetated roof systems. JournalofEnvironmentalManagement 87, 350-363. Champ, P., Boyle, K., & Brown, T. (2003). APrimeronNon‐marketValuation. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers. City of Victoria (2005). DocksideDevelopment,MasterDevelopmentAgreement. Retrieved from: http://www.victoria.ca/cityhall/currentprojects_dockside.shtml. 86 City of Waterloo (2005). GreenRoofFeasibilityStudyandCityWideImplementation Plan. Public document (http://www.city.waterloo.on.ca/Portals/57ad7180-c5e749f5-b282c6475cdb7ee7/LIBRARY_Plans_documents/GRReport2005Complete.pdf). Clark, C. (2005). Optimization of Green Roofs for Air Pollution Mitigation. In ProceedingsfromGreeningRooftopsforSustainableCommunitiesConference2005, WashingtonDC. Clark, C., Adrieans, P. & Talbot, F.B. (2008). Green Roof Valuation: A probabilistic economic analysis of environmental benefits. EnvironmentalScienceTechnology 42(6), 2155-2161 (http://pubs.acs.org/cgibin/abstract.cgi/esthag/2008/42/i06/abs/es0706652.html). Connelly, M. & Hodgson, M. (2008). Sound Transmission Loss of Extensive Green Roofs - Field Test Results. AcousticsWeekinCanada,October6‐8,2008. Vancouver, BC: Canadian Acoustical Association. Costanza, R., d'Arge, R., de Groot, R., Farber, S., Grasso, M., Hannon, B., et al. (1998). The value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Ecological Economics, 25(1), 3-15. Crompton, J. (2005). The Impact of Parks on Property Values: Empirical Evidence from the Past two Decades in the United States. ManagingLeisure 10(4), 203-21. Cunnigham, N. (2001). RethinkingtheUrbanEpidermis:astudyoftheviabilityof extensivegreenroofsystemsintheManitobacapitalwithanemphasisonregional casestudiesandstormwatermanagement. Master’s thesis dissertation, Department of Landscape Architecture, University of Manitoba, Winnipeg, Manitoba. Curran, D. (2001). EconomicBenefitsofNaturalGreenSpaceProtection. The POLIS Project on Ecological Governance and Smart Growth BC. Currie, B.A. (2005). AirPollutionMitigationwithGreenRoofsUsingtheUFOREModel. Unpublished Master’s Thesis, Ryerson University, Toronto. Currie, B.A. & Bass, B. (2008). Estimates of air pollution mitigation with green plants and green roofs using the UFORE model. UrbanEcosystems11, 409-422. David Suzuki Foundation (2008). Ontario’sWealth,Canada’sFuture:Appreciating theValueoftheGreenbelt’sEco‐Services. Public document (http://www.davidsuzuki.org/files/Conservation/DSF-Greenbelt-web.pdf). De Groot, R. S. (1992). Functions of nature: Evaluation of nature in environmental planning. In Groningen, Netherlands: Wolters-Noordhoff. 87 Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (DEFRA). (2007). An IntroductoryGuidetoValuingEcosystemServices. Economic and Planning Systems, Inc. (2000). QuantifyingourQualityofLife:An EconomicAnalysisoftheEastBay'sUniqueEnvironment. Eisenberg, Olivieri, & Associates, Inc. (EOA) (2007). DevelopmentsProtectingWater Quality:AGuidebookofSiteDesignExamples. Report produced for the Santa Clara Valley Urban Runoff Pollution Prevention Program (http://www.scvurpppw2k.com/pdfs/0607/SC_Site_Design_Manual_Final_0207.pdf). Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) (1998). RegulatoryImpactAnalysisforthe NOx SIPCall,FIP,andSection126Petitions. Report EPA-452/R-98–003A. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) (1999). Preliminarydatasummaryofurban stormwaterbestmanagementpractices. Report EPA 821-R-99-012. Edwards, K. (2007). DoParksMakeCents?:AnAnalysisoftheEconomicValueof ParksinSanFrancisco. UC Berkeley, Richard and Rhoda School of Public Policy. Fankhauser, S. (1994). The social costs of greenhouse gas emissions: an expected value approach. TheEnergyJournal 15(2), 157–184. Goodman Williams Group and URS Corporation. (2005). MillenniumPark:Economic ImpactStudy. Grover, R. (2006). Are DVRs killing network TV? BusinessWeek, May 11 (http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/may2006/nf20060511_7450_db 011.htm?campaign_id=rss_daily). Hendricks, J. (2005). Zeroing on the Decision-Makers: Knowing the Potential Green Roof Client. GreeningRooftopforSustainableCommunities. Washington, DC. Hidano, N. (2002). TheEconomicValuationoftheEnvironmentandPublicPolicy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) (2007). Summary for Policymakers. In ClimateChange2007:Impacts,AdaptationandVulnerability. ContributionofWorkingGroupIItotheFourthAssessmentReportofthe IntergovernmentalPanelonClimateChange. M.L Parry, O.F. Canziani, J.P. Palutikof, P.J. van der Linden and C.E. Hanson, Eds. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 7-22. Jamieson, N. (2008). RoofTopHerbGarden. Media factsheet prepared by the Executive Sous Chef of the Fairmont Waterfront Hotel restaurant. 88 King, A., & Lenox, M. (2001). Does It Really Pay to Be Green?: An Empirical Study of Firm Environmental and Financial Performance. JournalofIndustrialEcology, 5(1), 105-116. Kowal, C. (2008). Measuring Urban Green. TheNewPlanner, Winter (http://www.planning.org/thenewplanner/2008/win/measuringurbangreen.htm) Miller, A. R. (2001). Valuingopenspace:Landeconomicsandneighborhoodparks. Cambridge, MA, MIT Center for Real Estate (http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/8754). Morikawa, H., Takahasi, M., and Kawamura, Y. (1998). More than a 600-fold variation in nitrogen dioxide assimilation among 217 plant taxa. Plant,Cell& Environment 21, 180–190. Navrud, S. (2002). TheState‐Of‐The‐ArtonEconomicValuationofNoise. Final Report to European Commission DG Environment. Nowak, D., & Crane, D. (1998). The Urban Forest Effects (UFORE) model: quantifying urban forest structure and functions. IntegratedToolsProceedings, Idaho, 16-20 (http://www.nrs.fs.fed.us/pubs/gtr/gtr_nc212/gtr_nc212_714.pdf). Nowak, D., & Crane, D. (2002). Carbon storage and sequestration by urban trees in the United States. EnvironmentalPollution116, 381-389. Ontario Medical Association (OMA) (2000). TheIllnessCostsofAirPollutionin Ontario. Public report (http://www.oma.org/phealth/icap.htm). Patel, I. (1991). Gardening's Socioeconomic Impacts: Community Gardening in an Urban Setting. JournalofExtension ,29 (4), 7-9. Peck, S. (2008). AwardWinningGreenRoofDesigns. Toronto: Green Roofs for Healthy Cities. Peck, S., & Callaghan, C. (1999). GreenbacksFromGreenRoofs:ForgingaNew IndustryInCanada. Peck and Associates. Reed, J., Frazão, E., Itskowitz, R. (2004). HowmuchdoAmericansPayforFruitand Vegetables?. United Sates Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service. September, A., & Peck, S. InnovativeBuildings:FairmontWaterfrontHotel. Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation. South Coast Air Quality Management District (SCAQMD) (2007). AnnualRECLAIM AuditReportforthe2005ComplianceYear. Public report (http://www.aqmd.gov/hb/2007/March/070334a.html#_ftn1). Statistics Canada (2007). Householdsize,byprovinceandterritory(2006Census). Web page (http://www40.statcan.gc.ca/l01/cst01/famil53b-eng.htm). 89 Trust for Public Land (2008 a). HowMuchValueDoestheCityofPhiladelphiaReceive fromitsParkandRecreationSystem? Report for the Philadelphia Parks Alliance. Trust for Public Land (2008 b). QuantifyingtheGreenhouseGasBenefitsofUrban Parks. August 2008 White Paper prepared by IFC International. Urban Habitat Chicago (2008). Rooftop‐integratedfoodproductionFAQ. Webpage (http://www.urbanhabitatchicago.org/blog/rooftopintegrated-food-productionfaq/). Urban Habitat Chicago (undated). TrueNatureFoods. Webpage (http://www.urbanhabitatchicago.org/projects/true-nature-foods/). Urbanspace Property Group (2007a). IntensiveRoofGarden. Poster prepared for Doors Open Toronto 2007 (http://www.401richmond.net/gardens/401%20Roof%20Garden%20Posters.pdf). Urbanspace Property Group (2007b). ExtensiveRoofGarden. Poster prepared for Doors Open Toronto 2007 (http://www.401richmond.net/gardens/401%20Roof%20Garden%20Posters.pdf). Urbanspace Property Group (2008). 401Richmond:Building. Webpage (http://www.401richmond.net/building/). US Census Bureau (2006). 2006AmericanCommunitySurveyDataProfileHighlights. Web page (http://factfinder.census.gov/servlet/ACSSAFFFacts?_event=&geo_id=01000US&_g eoContext=01000US&_street=&_county=&_cityTown=&_state=&_zip=&_lang=en&_s se=on&ActiveGeoDiv=&_useEV=&pctxt=fph&pgsl=010&_submenuId=factsheet_1&d s_name=DEC_2000_SAFF&_ci_nbr=null&qr_name=null&reg=&_keyword=&_industry =). Voicu, I. & Been, V. (2008). The Effect of Community Gardens on Neighboring Property Values. RealEstateEconomics36(2), 281-243. Wachter, S. (2004). TheDeterminantsofNeighborhoodTransformationsin Philadelphia‐IdentificationandAnalysis:TheNewKensingtonPilotStudy. University of Pennsylvania, The Wharton School. Yang, J., Yu, Q., & Gong, P. (2008). Quantifying air pollution removal by green roofs in Chicago. AtmosphericEnvironment 42, 7266-7273. 90