INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS Instructor: Filip Vesely 22 U-Shaped Curves Why the average total cost curve (ATC) is U-shaped Average total cost, ATC, is the sum of average fixed cost, AFC, and average variable cost, AVC. The shape of the ATC curve combines the shapes of the AFC and AVC curves. The U shape of the average total cost curve arises from the influence of two opposing forces: •Spreading total fixed cost over a larger output •Decreasing marginal returns The marginal cost curve (MC) is also U-shaped and intersects the average variable cost curve and the average total cost curve at their minimum points. Cost Curves and Product Curves The technology that a firm uses determines its costs. At low levels of employment and output, as the firm hires more labor, marginal product and average product rise, and marginal cost and average variable cost fall. Then, at the point of maximum marginal product, marginal cost is a minimum. As the firm hires more labor, marginal product decreases and marginal cost increases. But average product continues to rises, and average variable cost continues to fall. Then, at the point of maximum average product, average variable cost is a minimum. As the firm hires even more labor, average product decreases and average variable cost increases. Cost Curves and Product Curves A firm’s average variable cost curve is linked to its average product curve. If average product rises, average variable cost falls. If average product is a maximum, average variable cost is a minimum. At low outputs, MP and AP rise and MC and AVC fall. At intermediate outputs, MP falls and MC rises; and AP rises and AVC falls. At high outputs, MP and AP fall and MC and AVC rise. Shifts in Cost Curves Technology A technological change that increases productivity shifts the total product curve upward. It also shifts the marginal product curve and the average product curve upward. With a better technology, the same inputs can produce more output, so an advance in technology lowers the average and marginal costs and shifts the short-run cost curves downward. Prices of Factors of Production An increase in the price of a factor of production increases costs and shifts the cost curves. • A change in rent or some other component of fixed cost shifts the fixed cost curves (TFC and AFC) upward and shifts the total cost curve (TC) upward but leaves the variable cost curves (AVC and TVC) and the marginal cost curve (MC) unchanged. • A change in wage rates or some other component of variable cost shifts the variable curves (TVC and AVC) and the marginal cost curve (MC) upward but leaves the fixed cost curves (AFC and TFC) unchanged. LONG-RUN COST Plant Size and Cost When a firm changes its plant size, its cost of producing a given output changes. Will the average total cost of producing a gallon of smoothie fall, rise, or remain the same? Each of these three outcomes arise because when a firm changes the size of its plant, it might experience: • Economies of scale • Diseconomies of scale • Constant returns to scale Economies of scale exist if when a firm increases its plant size and labor employed by the same percentage, its output increases by a larger percentage and average total cost decreases. The main source of economies of scale is greater specialization of both labor and capital. Diseconomies of scale exist if when a firm increases its plant size and labor employed by the same percentage, its output increases by a smaller percentage and average total cost increases. They arise from the difficulty of coordinating and controlling a large enterprise. Eventually, management complexity brings rising average total cost. Constant returns to scale exist if when a firm increases its plant size and labor employed by the same percentage, its output increases by the same percentage and average total cost remains constant. Constant returns to scale occur when a firm is able to replicate its existing production facility including its management system. The short-run average cost curve shows the lowest average cost at which it is possible to produce each output with a given plant size. SRAC The long-run average cost curve shows the lowest average cost at which it is possible to produce each output when the firm has had sufficient time to change both its plant size and labor employed. Minimum efficient scale is the smallest quantity of output at which the long-run average cost reaches its lowest level. Constant returns to scale Economies of scale SRAC1 SRAC2 SRAC3 LRAC Diseconomies of scale CHAPTER 11 – PERFECT COMPETITION Explain how price and output are determined in perfect competition Explain why firms sometimes shut down temporarily and lay off workers Explain why firms enter and leave the industry Predict the effects of a change in demand and of a technological advance Explain why perfect competition is efficient Competition Perfect competition is an industry in which: Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions to entry into the industry. Established firms have no advantages over new ones. Sellers and buyers are well informed about prices. Perfect competition arises: When firm’s minimum efficient scale is small relative to market demand so there is room for many firms in the industry. And when each firm is perceived to produce a good or service that has no unique characteristics, so consumers don’t care which firm they buy from. Competition Price Takers In perfect competition, each firm is a price taker. A price taker is a firm that cannot influence the price of a good or service. (No single firm can influence the price—it must “take” the equilibrium market price.) Each firm’s output is a perfect substitute for the output of the other firms, so the demand for each firm’s output is perfectly elastic. Economic Profit and Revenue The goal of each firm is to maximize economic profit, which equals total revenue minus total cost. (Total cost is the opportunity cost of production, which includes normal profit.) A firm’s total revenue equals price, P, multiplied by quantity sold, Q, equals P × Q. A firm’s marginal revenue is the change in total revenue that results from a one-unit increase in the quantity sold. In perfect competition MR = P. Firm’s Revenue in Perfect Competition Market demand and supply determine the price that the firm must take. Firm’s total revenue curve is given by Price x Q. Because in perfect competition the price remains the same as the quantity sold changes, firms marginal revenue equals price. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm faces two constraints: A market constraint summarized by the market price and the firm’s revenue curves A technology constraint summarized by firm’s product curves and cost curves The perfectly competitive firm makes two decisions in the short run: Whether to produce or to shut down. If the decision is to produce, what quantity to produce. The perfectly competitive firm makes two decisions in the long-run: Whether to stay in the industry or leave it. If the decision is to stay, whether to increase or decrease its plant size. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition Profit-Maximizing Output A perfectly competitive firm chooses the output that maximizes its economic profit. One way to find the profit maximizing output is to look at the firm’s the total revenue and total cost curves. Next figure looks at these curves along with the firm’s total profit curve. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition Part (a) shows the total revenue, TR, curve and the total cost curve, TC. Total revenue minus total cost is profit (or loss), shown in part (b). The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition Part (a) shows the total revenue, TR, curve and the total cost curve, TC. Total revenue minus total cost is profit (or loss), shown in part (b). Profit is maximized when the firm produces 9 sweaters a day. At low output levels, the firm incurs an economic loss—it can’t cover its fixed costs. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition Part (a) shows the total revenue, TR, curve and the total cost curve, TC. Total revenue minus total cost is profit (or loss), shown in part (b). Profit is maximized when the firm produces 9 sweaters a day. At low output levels, the firm incurs an economic loss—it can’t cover its fixed costs. At intermediate output levels, the firm earns an economic profit. At high output levels, the firm again incurs an economic loss—now it faces steeply rising costs because of diminishing returns. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition The firm can use marginal analysis to determine the profit-maximizing output. Because marginal revenue is constant and marginal cost eventually increases as output increases, profit is maximized by producing the output at which marginal revenue, MR, equals marginal cost, MC. If MR > MC, economic profit increases if output increases. If MR < MC, economic profit decreases if output increases. If MR = MC, economic profit decreases if output changes in either direction, so economic profit is maximized. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition Profits and Losses in the Short Run Maximum profit is not always a positive economic profit. To determine whether a firm is earning an economic profit or incurring an economic loss, we compare the firm’s average total cost, ATC, at the profit maximizing output with the market price. The Firm’s Decisions in Perfect Competition If price equals ATC then the firm earns zero economic profit (that is normal profit only). If price exceeds ATC then the firm earns a positive economic profit. If price is less than ATC then the firm incurs an economic loss—economic profit is negative and the firm does not even earn normal profit. RECALL THAT IN PERFECT COMPETITION P = MR