Perceptions of External Accounting Transfers under Entity and Proprietary Theory Author(s): Francis A. Bird, Lewis F. Davidson, Charles H. Smith Reviewed work(s): Source: The Accounting Review, Vol. 49, No. 2 (Apr., 1974), pp. 233-244 Published by: American Accounting Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/245098 . Accessed: 17/11/2011 22:09 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. American Accounting Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Accounting Review. http://www.jstor.org Perceptions of External Accounting ransfers Under Entity and Proprietary Theory Francis A. Bird, Lewis F. Davidson, and CharlesH. Smith and Flaherty' (S & F hereafter) have used a liquidity hypothesis to describe "the method of assigning values at the event of the exchange under the historical cost system." Their finding in general is that, in an exchange (a "twoway flow of goods . . . an acquisition accompanied by a sacrifice"), the more liquid good is independently valued, and the less liquid good is dependently valued. They found, however, that their operational guidelines are inappropriate for numerous exchanges of nonmonetary goods. Nichols and Parker2 (N & P hereafter) subsequently took the liquidity hypothesis to task by offering the objectivity hypothesis as an alternative: they found that it "leads to practices recommended by the majority view of the literature." The objective of this paper is to demonstrate that accountants need to reach unanimity on the fundamental question of the nature of external accounting exchanges before guidelines can be completed for the valuation of the "two-way flow of goods." It is, in essence, our contention that writers will continue to be at odds on the issue of the method for attaching values to the exchanges until agreement is reached on the question of the nature of the exchanges. The writers agree that a valuation scheme is not complete unless STERLING developed for both internal exchanges, e.g., recording of depreciation, and external exchanges, e.g., recording of purchase of an automobile. However, it seems reasonable to conclude that most internal exchanges are mere reclassifications of prior external exchanges, and that it is therefore fundamentally more important to have an appropriate understanding of external exchanges. The paper covers aspects of the overall valuation problem, but it does not seek to argue for or against the hypotheses of The research for and writing of this paper were completed while Mr. Davidson was Assistant Professor of Accounting at The University of Texas at Austin. The Financial Accounting Standards Board, as a matter of policy, disclaims responsibility for any publication or speech by any of its individual members or staff. Accordingly, the views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Standards Board. I Robert R. Sterling and Richard E. Flaherty, "The Role of Liquidity in Exchange Valuation," THE AcCOUNTING REVIEW (July 1971), pp. 441-56. Donald R. Nichols and James E. Parker, "An Alternative to Liquidity as a Basis for Exchange Valuation," Abacus (June 1972), pp. 68-74. 2 Francis A. Bird is Professor of A ccounting at The University of Richmond, Lewis F. Davidson is Research A ssociate with the Financial A ccounting Standards Board, and Charles H. Smith is A ssociate Professor of Accounting at The University of Texas at A ustin. 233 2T4 S & F and N & P. That debate is not entered into. The paper suggests, instead, that the debate cannot be continued until agreement is reached as to the nature of the external exchanges entered into between the accounting entity and other entities, i.e., including legal owners. Although the authors cited above use the term "exchange," and although some writers' appear to agree that, under the conventional (historical cost) model, accountants admit exchange transactions as the reportable input to the financial accounting system, for purposes of this paper the term "transfer" is used to facilitate description of exchange. The term "transfer" is more general, lends itself to subclassification and these subclassifications can be used appropriately to describe the nature of the more specific transfer known as an exchange. More specifically, the discussion of this paper regarding the nature of external exchanges is undertaken with reference to the Accounting Principles Board's (APB) categorization of external transfers. In Statement No. 44 the APB used external transfer to describe the basic input to the financial accounting system, identified some of them as nonreciprocal (nonexchange or one-way flow) in nature, and was therefore forced to seek a more general description. The basic approach of this paper is to illustrate the difference between the entity and proprietary theories. The very fundamental question of what it is that accountants record cannot be answered until agreement is reached as to for whom the recording is to be made. This implies a need to settle the issue (pedestrian and prosaic as it might seem) of entity vs. proprietary theory. The ultimate development by accountants of a scheme for classifying and recording external transfers is a function of a viewpoint adopted, i.e., transfers of resources or obligations between independent accounting entities (external trans- The Accounting Review, April 1974 fers) may be perceived in accordance with either the proprietary or the entity theory of accounting.5 Different classification schemes can result from such differences in perception, and these can, in turn, lead to different recordings. The methodology of the paper will also include an identification of the theory (entity or proprietary) embraced by practitioners, and illustration of the fact that current practices are often internally inconsistent, i.e., practice is based partially on entity and partially on proprietary theory. This will strengthen our basic argument that the S & F search for a set of valuation guidelines will forever be frustrated until settlement of the entity vs. proprietary issue is reached. ENTITY AND PROPRIETARY THEORIES CONTRASTED The critical difference between the two theories, at least insofar as external transfers are concerned, lies in the manner in which owners' equity is perceived. Under the entity theory, owners' equity is gen3 John J. Willingham, Entity: A (July 1964), pp. 543-52; William J. Schrader, "An Inductive Conceptual Model," THE "The Accounting ACCOUNTING REVIEW Approach to Accounting Theory," THE ACCOUNTING (October 1962), pp. 645-9; and W. A. Paton and A. C. Littleton, An Introduction to Corporate Accounting Standards (American Accounting Association, 1940). 4 Statement of the Accounting Principles Board No. 4, Basic Concepts and Accounting Principles Underlying Financial Statemnents of Business Enterprises (AICPA, 1970). C. Littleton, Structure of Accounting Theory 5 A. (American Accounting Association, 1953), p. 25. Although argument can be made for a need to discuss others, this paper is limited to issues under the two dominant theories underlying financial statements, i.e., the proprietary and entity theories. The fund theory has not generally been well received by accountants seeking solutions to the problem of net income determination since it is not income oriented. The enterprise theory is not at all well defined in scope and application. Furthermore, the enterprise theory is value oriented and therefore not applicable under the constraints of historical costs. Under the residual equity theory the residual equity is simply viewed" . . . as one of several types of equity under the entity theory." Eldon S. Hendriksen, A ccounting Theory (Richard D. Irwin, 1970), p. 501. REVIEW Bird, Davidson and Smith: External Transfers erally acknowledged to be an obligation or a liability of the enterprise to its owners, albeit, "elastic and residual" rather than "fixed and contractual" to use the distinction made by Paton in his Accounting Theory.6 It is granted that the preceding statement may be open to debate since, as pointed out by Lorig, "some writers (on entity theory) seem to want to maintain a distinction between creditors and owners." "However," Lorig goes on to say, "others regard proprietors as creditors and the widespread use of 'Liabilities' as a heading for the whole credit side of the balance sheet indicates that this is the commonly held opinion."' In conformity with the line of reasoning which treats owners as creditors, the relevant accounting equation for the entity theory is Assets= Liabilities.8 It is true that this equation has evolved into the more familiar entity theory equation, and this fact has been Assets=Equities, commented upon by Gilman. As early as 1917, Paton suggested replacing the word "liabilities" with the word "equities." The preference for the word "equities" seems a somewhat euphemistic attempt to avoid legalistic 235 viewpoint and in criticism of entity theory, Sprague maintains that inclusion of proprietorship among the liabilities is improper since: The entity does not stand in the same relation to its proprietors or its capitalists as to its "other" liabilities. It would seem more appropriate to say that it is "owned by" rather than "owes" the proprietors."2 Elsewhere, Under the proprietary approach, the enterprise The accountant who bases his reasoning upon the entity convention may, and frequently does, conceal that element of his working philosophy which baldly asserts that an artificial entity owes money to a proprietor for his investment and accumulated profits. But this may be due to no lack of faith. Rather, it may be prompted by the desire to avoid legal arguments.'0 In contrast to entity theory, proprietary theory disavows that owners' equity is in any sense a liability or an obligation of an enterprise to its owners. Therefore, the Assets= Liabilities equation is replaced by one which treats owners' equity as a separate element, namely, Assets-Liabilities = Owners' Equity." In defense of this is viewed as an agent of the owners and the records as an accounting by the proprietors for their own property. The owners are not considered outside parties. This is in contrast with the entity viewpoint which is concerned with the examination of the operations of the entity separate and apart from the suppliers of funds. PERCEPTIONAND CLASSIFICATIONOF EXTERNAL TRANSFERS UNDER PROPRIETARYTHEORY reproach....9 Gilman himself supports the idea of treating owners' equity as a type of liability. he states: Thus the right-hand side of the balance sheet is entirely composed of claims against or rights over the left-hand side. "Is it not then true," it will be asked, "that the right-hand side is entirely composed of liabilities?" The answer to this is that the rights of others, or the liabilities, differ materially from the rights of the proprietors In describing external transfers in StatementNo. 4, the position taken by the APB is unquestionably "proprietary" since owners' equity is denied any status whatsoever as a liability or obligation of the enterprise to its owners. For example, in 6 William A. Paton, Accounting Theory (Chicago: Accounting Studies Press Ltd., 1962), chapters 2 and 3, and Stephen Gilman, Accounting Concepts of Profit (Ronald Press, 1939), p. 58. 7 Arthur N. Lorig, "Some Basic Concepts of Accounting and Their Implications," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW (July 1964), pp. 566-73. 8 Stephen Gilman, Accounting Concepts of Profit (Ronald Press, 1939), p. 57. 9 Ibid., p. 58. 10 Ibid., p. 64. 1' Hendriksen, p. 31. 12 Charles E. Sprague, The Philosophy of A ccounts (Ronald Press, 1913), p. 49. 13 Ibid., p. 46. 236 The Accounting Review, April 1974 discussing the situation in which the enterprise receives resources from owners, it is stated that "the enterprise . . . incurs no obligation in exchange for owners' investments." Also, throughout the Statement, reliance is placed upon the proprietary equation, Assets-Liabilities=Owners' Equity, with assets being defined as "economic resources," liabilities as "economic obligations," and owners' equity as "residual interest." Residual interest is further defined as "the interest in the economic resources of an enterprise after deducting economic obligations." With respect to external transfers, Statement No. 4 identifies three types: (1) Exchanges or reciprocal transfers, (2) nonreciprocal transfers between an enterprise and its owners, and (3) nonreciprocal transfers between an enterprise and entities other than owners. It is not possible to supply an answer to those concerned about the chicken and the egg issue. It is safe to conclude though that the APB's definition of the credit side of the balance sheet and its categorization of external transfers are interrelated, i.e., embracement of either the definition or categorization as a starting point dictates acceptance of the other. Whether or not this same classification scheme for external transfers would have emerged had reliance been placed on entity theory is the question to which attention is now directed. PERCEPTION AND CLASSIFICATION OF EXTERNAL TRANSFERS: ENTITY THEORY VS. PROPRIETARY THEORY The discussion of this section will be undertaken on the basis of the external transfer categorization of proprietary theory, i.e., as developed in Statement No. 4. Exchanges or Reciprocal Transfers Exchanges are defined in the Statement as "reciprocal transfers between the enterprise and other entities that involve obtaining resources or satisfying obligations by giving up other resources or incurring other obligations." There is no disparity between this definition and the entity concept of exchanges. Both envision the situation shown in Figure 1. Nonreciprocal Transfers Between an Enterprise and Its Owners It is in the area of nonreciprocal transfers that the proprietary-entity cleavage occurs. Nonreciprocal transfers are defined in Statement No. 4 as "transfers in one direction of resources or obligations, either from the enterprise to other entities or from other entities to the enterprise." In discussing "nonreciprocal transfers between the enterprise and its owners," the Statement goes on to say: These are events in which the enterprise receives resources from the owners and the enterprise acknowledges an increased ownership interest, or the enterprise transfers resources to owners and their interest decreases. These transfers are not exchanges from the point of view of the enterprise. The enterprise sacrifices none of its resources and incurs no obligations in exchange for owners' investments, and it receives nothing of value to itself in exchange for the resources it distributes. The foregoing quote in effect states that an enterprise cannot enter into an exchange with its owners because it cannot obligate itself to the owners. Concomi- Resource or Release from Obligation Received Enterprise ^ Resource or Obligation Given FIGURE 1 PROPRIETARY AND ENTITY THEORY ~~~~~~~~~~~Another Entity 237 Bird, Davidson and Smith: External Transfers tantly, when the enterprise distributes resources to the owners, it cannot receive a release from any obligation to them. This reasoning is in accord with proprietary theory. However, entity theory would hold that the enterprise can indeed obligate itself to its owners and receive releases from these obligations. Such entity reasoning would then lead to the conclusion that "nonreciprocal transfers between an enterprise and its owners" are exchanges no different in concept from exchanges with creditors. For clarification, graphic depiction of the two viewpoints is presented in Figures 2 and 3. Figure 3 (entity theory) covers both cases of Figure 2, and because entity theory views the owners as separate from the enterprise, the transfers consist of a two-way rather than a one-way flow. As specific examples of nonreciprocal CaseI Resources Received Enterprise Owners Onr Resources Given Enter- Owners praise _' Onr FIGURE 2 PROPRIETARY THEORY: NONRECIPROCAL TRANSFERS WITH OWNERS CaseII Resource or Release from Obligation Received Enterprise Resource or Obligation Given Owners FIGURE 3 ENTITY THEORY: EXCHANGES WITH OWNERS transfers with owners, Statement No. 4 cites investments of resources by owners, declaration of cash or property dividends, acquisition of treasury stock, and conversion of convertible debt. Under the entity theory, all of these would be considered exchanges since, in each case, the reciprocity needed to qualify the transfer as an exchange would be achieved by acknowledging either an obligation to owners or a release therefrom. It should be noted at this point that adherence to the proprietary viewpoint negates the idea that the rules of debit and credit14 as applied to enterprise external transfers can be succinctly stated as "debit what is received" and "credit what is given." Such a rule cannot be applied if, as shown in Figure 2 above, the enterprise can be involved in nonreciprocal transfers in which it receives but does not give, or gives but does not receive. Nonreciprocal Transfers Between the Enterprise and Entities Other Than Owners With respect to "nonreciprocal transfers between the enterprise and entities other than owners," Statement No. 4 indicates: "In these transfers one of the two entities is often passive, a mere beneficiary or victim of the other's actions. Examples are gifts, dividends received, taxes, loss of a negligence lawsuit, imposition of fines, and theft." Under proprietary theory such transfers are perceived as depicted in Figure 4 which differs from Figure 2 only with respect to the description of the transfer, i.e., the transfer correctly covers obligations because entities other than owners are involved. Statement No. 4 cites the receipt of gifts and dividends as examples of Case 1. Gifts given, taxes, lawsuit losses, fines, and thefts are cited as examples of Case II. In contrast, entity theory, which acknowl14 Schrader, p. 648. 238 The Accounting Review, April 1974 Case I Resource or Release from Obligation Received Enterprise ,I1Owners Case II R r or Resource Given _ Enterprise _ An Entity Other Than An Entitv Other Than ~~~~~~~~~~~Owners FIGURE 4 PROPRIETARY THEORY edges obligations to owners and releases therefrom, might explain all of these examples (except perhaps dividends received and taxes, discussed later in this paper) in the manner shown in Figures 5 and 6. Gifts to and from the enterprise can be used to provide examples of Figures 5 and 6. A gift which is received by the enterprise from an entity other than owners would be counterbalanced by the enterprise giving a commitment or obligation to its owners. (Entity theory advocates would argue that a maturity date is not essential for the creation of a liability, and that the nature of this particular commitment is very simply a promise to make available and/or pay over to owners the proceeds of the gift upon realization.) Correspondingly, a gift given by the enterprise to an entity other than owners would be counterbalanced by the enterprise receiving a release from its outstanding commitment or obligation to its owners. Similar reasoning can be applied to lawsuit losses, fines and thefts. Summary What is being suggested at this point is that entity theory easily accommodates an expanded concept of exchanges, namely, one involving three parties with the enterprise acting as receiver from one party and < ) <&t1 X & vAn FIGURE A 7 5 GIFT TO THE ENTERPRISE Received Releaseobligation Enpise Resouce Given FIGURE A Entit 6 GIFT FROM THE ENTERPRISE Ower Bird, Davidson and Smith: External Transfers giver to another. Thus, under entity theory, two types of exchanges'5 could be identified: (1) those involving the enterprise and one other party (bilateral) as shown in Figures 1 and 3, and (2) those involving the enterprise and two other parties (trilateral) as shown in Figures 5 and 6. In trilateral exchanges, just as in bilateral, the previously mentioned observation that debit and credit equate to receiving and giving, respectively, would still be valid. If the reasoning above is accepted, all the examples of "nonreciprocal transfers between the enterprise and entities other than owners" given in Statement No. 4, and cited in the preceding paragraph, would be designated trilateral exchanges under entity theory except perhaps for the two examples of taxes and dividends received. Both of these examples could be construed as bilateral exchanges. In the case of taxes, it could be contended that the enterprise gives a resource or obligation to the government in return for the receipt of government services. With respect to dividends received, the reciprocal element given could be said to be entrepreneurial services furnished to the entity paying the dividend. To summarize, external transfers as perceived under proprietary and entity reasoning can be contrasted as shown below. Proprietary 1. Reciprocal transfers or exchanges 2. Nonreciprocal transfers between an enterprise and owners 3. Nonreciprocal transfers between an enterprise and entities other than owners Entity 1. Bilateral exchanges itsI 2. Trilateral exchanges IMPLICATIONS OF THE DIVERGENT PERCEPTIONS As perceived under the entity theory, all external transfers are exchanges involving simultaneous reciprocal flows of consideration to and from the enterprise. Under the proprietary theory such is not 239 the case because nonreciprocal transfers are identified which involve a one-way flow only, either to or from the enterprise. This basic difference in perception may have significant implications for accounting thought. Rules of Debit and Credit At a very fundamental level, the basic rules of debit and credit can be stated differently depending upon the way in which external transfers are perceived. As indicated previously, the rule for external transfers under entity theory can be stated very concisely as "debit what the entity receives" and "credit what it gives." A proprietary theorist would find this rule unacceptable because it does not accommodate nonreciprocal transfers. His debit-credit rules would be the familiar ones which stress increases or decreases in the three components of the proprietary balance sheet equation, as expanded so as to include income statement accounts as subelements. Examples: Differences in Perception Only As a logical extension of different thinking at the debit-credit level, further divergences in accounting thought may result at higher levels. For example, with respect to the concept of revenue, Hendriksen states: Two approaches to the concept of revenue can be found in the literature, one focusing on the inflow of assets resulting from the operational activities of the firm and the other focusing on the creation of goods and services by the enterprise and the transfer of these to consumers or other producers. That is, revenue is considered to be either an inflow of net assets or an outflow of goods and services.16 As a matter of conjecture, it would seem that an entity theorist, emphasizing the 15 It is clear from the above discussion that transfers under entity theory are all exchanges. This latter term is therefore used rather than the more general term, transfer. 16 Hendriksen, p. 160. 240 reciprocal flows which to him are always present in external transfers, would identify revenue as an outflow of goods and services. On the other hand, a proprietary theorist, conditioned as he is to think of external transfers more in terms of their ultimate effects on the balance sheet, might reason that revenue is an inflow of net assets which is counterbalanced, ultimately, by an increase in owners' equity. As in the case of revenue, the concept of cost may be open to different interpretations. Just as it would seem reasonable for an entity theorist to define an outflow of goods and services as revenue or revenue realization, it would also appear reasonable for him to define its counterpart, an inflow of goods or services, as cost or cost incurrence. It is doubtful, however, whether a proprietary theorist would define cost as an inflow of goods or services. It is more likely that his perception of cost would be in accord with the following statement made by Hendriksen: What is meant by cost and what should be included in the term? Basically, cost is measured by the current value of the economic resources given up in obtaining the goods and services to be used in operations.'7 (Emphasis added) Turning to the more practical implications of the divergent perceptions of external transfers, one becomes aware of an important difference in thinking between entity and proprietary adherents in connection with the recording process. Since the "entity accountant" perceives all external transfers as exchanges, he must identify each of two reciprocal flows (received and given) in order to confirm that a recordable external transfer does, in fact, exist. On the other hand, the "proprietary accountant," because of the existence of nonreciprocal transfers in his frame of reference, need only identify one flow. Consider, for example, the case of taxes which is cited in Statement No. 4 as an example of a "nonreciprocal transfer between an en- The Accounting Review, April 1974 terprise and entities other than owners." In this case, Statement No. 4 acknowledges only that a resource or an obligation is given by the enterprise. Therefore, the question of exactly what the debit to tax expense represents is left unanswered. However, an entity adherent, because his thought process is centered on reciprocity, would strive to identify both the "received" and "given" elements and, as a matter of conjecture, it would seem likely that he would identify the debit to tax expense as "government services received." Based on the foregoing observations, the following generalization will now be advanced: The proprietary accountant, because he is not constrained by the necessity to identify reciprocity in external transfers, might admit on occasion to the accounting record data which would not be recorded by his entity-thinking counterpart. As one example, consider the recording of a receipt of stock subscriptions counterbalanced by a credit to capital stock subscribed. To the entity accountant, this would be an exchange of reciprocal obligations and, therefore, executory in nature and generally nonrecordable under present-day accounting conventions. However, to the proprietary accountant such an entry might be acceptable since it could be thought of as a nonreciprocal transfer involving the receipt of a resource by the enterprise. In other words, the fact that proprietary theory holds that an enterprise cannot obligate itself to its owners (presumably either current or prospective) removes the stock subscription entry from the "reciprocal obligation" category and places it in the nonreciprocal category. Reasoning parallel to the above can be applied in other areas such as the recording of a stock option at the date of grant when the option is given for future services. It is also possible that the proprietary 17 Ibid., p. 181. Bird, Davidson and Smith: External Transfers accountant might record some "external transfers" which would be considered fictional by his entity-thinking counterpart. For example, a common practice in connection with warranty guarantees is to record the sale and then to make a complementary entry charging warranty expense and crediting an estimated liability for future warranty service. A proprietary accountant might accept this treatment as correct since he could view the sale as a reciprocal transfer and the expense entry as a nonreciprocal transfer. However, an entity accountant probably would reason that the nonreciprocal transfer is fictional since the debit to expense represents nothing received. To his way of thinking, proper reciprocity would be shown if the expense debit of the second entry were netted against the original sales credit and the two entries compressed into one exchange entry. This exchange entry would reflect a resource received offset by two elements given, goods (sales) and a promise to provide future services (liability). Consider further the unresolved problem of the proper treatment of payments for the use of capital. This problem has long been a thorn in the side of accounting theorists. The controversy which raged during the 1920's was perhaps one of the most intense in accounting history with some 234 references in the Accountant's Index during the period of 1900-1926. The problem centers on the question as to whether interest is a cost or a distribution of income somewhat akin to dividends. If it is a cost, should it be subjected to the internal reclassification in the same manner as other costs such as labor, materials, or overhead? That is, does interest cost become a bona fide component of inventory cost or constructed assets? To include interest cost on only debt capital, whether general or specific debt, is to permit the capital structure and management discretion on identification of funds to influ- 241 ence asset cost unless interest is imputed to owner's capital. Since for the proprietary theorist the credit for such an imputed charge would necessarily be to interest income, it would violate the realization principle to the extent that the charge was deferred in the balance sheet. The issue was temporarily resolved by requiring treatment of interest as a period charge in the case of debt capital concerning operations. However, interest on constructed assets remains a much debated issue, with current practice being generally to capitalize interest on specific debt on the constructed asset (with the implicit assumption that such identification is possible). Public utilities continue to capitalize all interest including that on owner's capital, with the credit being to interest income. The problem of interest can be perceived quite differently from the entity point of view which recognizes obligations to owners and creditors alike. To the entity theorist there is no question to the fact that payment for the use of capital is a cost since a service (use of money) has been received in exchange for obligations to the suppliers of capital, whether it be creditors (liabilities) or to owners (equity). From the entity theory viewpoint there is a bona fide exchange which permits the recognition of interest cost both for debt capital and equity capital. Moreover, the credit for the imputed interest charge on owner's capital is an obligation to owners, i.e., a credit to equity, and not to interest income. Note that revenue or income is defined as an outflow of goods or services rendered by the entity. Such is not the case with this credit; it is merely the recognition of an obligation analogous to interest payable for debt capital. The payment of actual interest is cash given in exchange for release from obligation. Analogously, the payment of dividends is not a distribution of income but is cash given in exchange for release from obligations. 242 Examples: Recording Differences Although the previous sections reveal that proprietary and entity theories perceive external transfers differently, it is clear from the section immediately preceding that such differences in viewpoint do not necessarily have serious results, i.e., the net effect of recordings can be similar irrespective of viewpoint. This is, unfortunately, not always the case. It is the differences in the net effect of recording that force the writers to the conclusion of this paper, i.e., that unanimity needs to be reached on the fundamental question of the nature of external transfers (and therefore settlement of the proprietary vs. entity theory issue) before valuation guidelines can be set for the recording process. Because the assets of an enterprise are perceived under proprietary theory as belonging to owners, Hendriksen correctly states that "proprietorship is considered to be the net value of the business to the owners."18 Proprietary theory is therefore a wealth concept. One could conclude therefore that proprietary theory leads to a need for current value accounting. It is extremely doubtful that an entity accountant, indoctrinated as he is with the concept of exchange reciprocity, would be agreeable to the idea of current value accounting.'9 To his way of thinking, no reciprocal giving and receiving has occurred at the current market level, and therefore admission of market value to the accounting record is unjustified. The proprietary accountant, however, may be more receptive to the idea since he is already conditioned to the recording of what he perceives to be nonexchange or nonreciprocal data. On the other hand, and somewhat paradoxically, the entity accountant, while he would not agree to market value as a proper basis for carrying securities, might agree to the equity basis for investments in common stock of less than majority-owned The Accounting Review, April 1974 companies. To elaborate on this statement, an increase in the investment in stock account would represent an additional commitment or obligation received from the owned company and the offsetting credit to income would be reflective of entrepreneurial services given to that company. There is logical parallelism here since, if the entity accountant were to consider entries made on the books of the owned company, he would think of the entry which transfers net income to retained earnings as a debit to services received from owners and a credit to commitment or obligation given to owners. However, the proprietary-thinking accountant, because he does not acknowledge that'an enterprise can obligate itself to its owners, would not accept this line of reasoning. His acceptance of the equity method, if indeed he accepted it, would probably be based on either the concept of current value or partial consolidation. Convertible debt provides another useful example of an unsettled issue. The two basic theories lead to different recordings, and both are to be found in practice today. The proprietary theorist, reflecting concern for the affairs of the owners, would in all likelihood support the recording of a gain or loss at the time of conversion. The entity theorist would probably argue that an additional exchange in form only has occurred at the time of conversion (the liability before and after conversion is unchanged), and the only change of substance that is required is that of account descriptions, i.e., use of the so-called book value method which does not reflect a gain or loss. Ibid., p. 496. 19Price level adjustments could conceivably be acceptable to the entity accountant, but not current exchange (entry or exit) values. The former adjust for a change in the value of the measuring unit, but not that of the resources or obligations involved in the original exchange. 18 Bird, Davidson and Smith: External Transfers THE INTERNALINCONSISTENCIES OF CURRENTPRACTICE This paper argues that valuation guidelines under the historical cost model cannot be developed until a decision is made to embrace either proprietary or entity theory. It also argues that the development of such guidelines is not possible on the basis of "an observation of practice" because current practice reflects use of both proprietary and entity theories. Embracement of two fundamentally different underlying theories is bound to lead to a mixed set of guidelines. In listing and describing the generally accepted accounting principles contained in Statement No. 4, the APB indicated that "The description of generally accepted accounting principles is based primarily on observation of accounting practice." Statement No. 4 is, then, a summary of what accountants were doing as recently as 1970. If Statement No. 4 represents a description of current practice, it is clear (from the discussion of Statement No. 4, and from observation and analysis of numerous current practices) that the very foundations of current practice are internally inconsistent, and that guidelines for practice are developed on the basis of both proprietary and entity theories. Earlier in this paper it was observed that Statement No. 4's position is proprietary in nature in that owners' equity is denied any status as a liability of the enterprise to its owners. And yet the principles section of Statement No. 420 evidences implied acceptance of entity theory because of the reliance upon historical cost as a valuation method. The Statement adopts a proprietary theory perception of the transfers in the concepts section, but entity theory's valuation method is dominant in the principles section. In the previous section of this paper it was indicated that proprietary theory leads logically to different bases for asset valuation 243 in order to value more accurately the wealth of owners. It is not unjustified therefore to ask those who purport to embrace proprietary theory why the main basis for asset valuation continues to be historical cost.21 The latter is logically acceptable under entity theory. It is also necessary to ask those who purport to embrace proprietary theory how they are able to justify use of the equity method and 100% elimination of intercompany profits in consolidations, both of which are entity theory phenomena. Entity theory suggests that, for the profits made by a subsidiary, an exchange has occurred between the parent and the subsidiary (the parent has received a promise from the subsidiary for payment of profits made, and this promise is made in return for use of the parent's funds and for assumption of risk on the part of the parent), and therefore use of the equity method is justified. Use of the equity method cannot logically be argued under proprietary theory because this theory does not recognize a promise, commitment, or obligation to the parent (stockholder) with respect to the subsidiary's profits. With respect to consolidations two principal alternatives exist for the elimination of intercompany profits, namely, the fractional and 100% elimination methods. The fractional method draws a sharp distinction between classes of equityholders (the majority and minority interests) since only the proprietary (majority) share of the intercompany profit is eliminated. The minority interests' share of this profit is recognized as a liability. On the other 20 Statement No. 4 is made up of a concepts section (chapters 3-5), and a description of current principles section (chapters 6-8). 21 One should hasten to observe what could be interpreted as a slight trend in practice in the direction of current value accounting. The use of the Equity Method (APB Opinion No. 18) and proposal of the APB to value marketable securities at current values, are examples. 244 The Accounting Review, April 1974 hand, the 100% elimination method requires that no distinction be made between these two groups. Under this method no intercompany profits are recognized as accruing to either the majority or minority interests. Despite the fact that Statement No. 4 embraces proprietary theory (with which the fractional method is consistent), the prevailing practice of 100% elimination is based upon entity theory. Practice also employs different recordings for the retirement of similar financing obligations. The first case to be looked at is that of a gain upon the retirement of debt which finds its way into the income statement as proprietary theory would dictate. However, a gain on the retirement of preferred stock is credited to a separate owners' equity account as is dictated by entity theory. The latter would, of course, accord to debt the same treatment as that accorded to preferred stock because the difference, or gain, in both cases constitutes a direct change in owners' equity (increase in the obligation to residual equity holders) rather than income to stockholders." The second case of relevance under this heading of financing obligations is that of the retirement of convertible debt which was discussed in the previous section. The book value and market value methods are acceptable in practice, and yet the former is dictated by entity and the latter by proprietary theory. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION The findings of this paper are that: 1. Adoption of proprietary theory results in a different perception and classification scheme of external transfers than does adoption of entity theory. 2. Proprietary theory views certain external transfers as being nonreciprocal in nature, whereas entity theory views all external transfers as exchanges between entities. 3. While the differences in perception do not often lead to differences in the net effect of recordings, there are a number of situations where recordings are different in terms of effect on the financial statements. 4. Practitioners purport to embrace proprietary theory, but examination of current practice leads to the conclusion that recordings are sometimes based on proprietary and sometimes on entity theory. Two specific conclusions appear to follow from the findings: a. If accountants could reach unanimity on the very fundamental question of the nature of external accounting transfers, it would lead to acceptance of either proprietary or entity theory as a major underlying concept. The result of this choice would be the development of accounting thought and practice which would be internally consistent. Differences in such thought and practice would therefore be narrowed. b. It is incorrect to describe the conventional (historical cost) model on the basis of an examination of current practice. Attempts such as those of S & F and N & P to develop valuation guidelines therefore will forever be frustrated until the proprietary vs. entity choice has been made. 22 Under the entity concept, despite the fact that they rank differently from a legal point of view, shareholders and debtholders are viewed equally as providers of enterprise capital. For this reason, under the entity concept, income to all investors includes interest on debt, dividends on preferred stock, dividends on common stock, and all the undistributed remainder. The 1957 Statement of the American Accounting Association, in explaining the entity concept, stated that, ". . . interest charges, income taxes, and true profitsharing distributions are not determinants of enterprise net income" See, Committee on Accounting Concepts and Standards, "Accounting and Reporting Standards for Corporate Financial Statements" (Columbus, Ohio: American Accounting Association, 1957), p. 5. The implication of all this is, of course, that income can exist under entity theory only if one imposes a particular viewpoint upon the entity, e.g., all stockholders versus all equity holders versus residual claimants.