Monetary Review Monetary Review 1st Quarter 04 1 Danmarks Nationalbank Telephone +45 33 63 63 63 www.nationalbanken.dk MON1_04.indd 1 Havnegade 5 DK-1093 Copenhagen K Fax +45 33 63 71 25 E-mail: info@nationalbanken.dk 2004 Danmarks Nationalbank Danmarks Nationalbank D A N M A R K S N A T I O N A L B A N K 2 0 0 4 1 03-02-2004, 10:28:58 The small picture on the front cover is a section of the national coat of arms as redesigned in 2003 as the motif on the reverse of the 20-krone. Text may be copied from this publication provided that Danmarks Nationalbank is specifically stated as the source. Changes to or misrepresentation of the content are not permitted. The Monetary Review is published by Danmarks Nationalbank and is issued quarterly. Managing Editor: Jens Thomsen Editor: Anders Møller Christensen The Monetary Review can be ordered from: Danmarks Nationalbank, Information Desk, Havnegade 5, DK-1093 Copenhagen K. Telephone +45 33 63 70 00 (direct) or +45 33 63 63 63. E-mail: info@nationalbanken.dk www.nationalbanken.dk SCHULTZ GRAFISK A/S ISSN 0011-6149 (Online) ISSN 1398-3865 17-02-2004 11:23 Antal sider: 1 Rev. nr. kolofon Oprettet af Alice Colombo Contents Recent Economic and Monetary Trends ............................................. 1 The Development in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing.......... 19 Erik Haller Pedersen, Economics Adjusted for general price trends, owning a home is not more expensive today than it was previously, but there are large regional differences. In the metropolitan area, the costs of living in owner-occupied housing are at a historically high level. It is believed that the introduction of adjustable-rate loans has had a small positive effect on cash prices, as will the introduction of deferred-amortisation loans. Developments in the Danish Bond Market since 1970 ....................... 35 Ulrik Knudsen and Michael Sand, Market Operations This article outlines the development in the Danish bond market since 1970, focusing on mortgage-credit and government bonds. Previously callable annuity bonds dominated the market, but now there is a more equal distribution of these bonds and uncallable bullet loans. The development in the total krone duration has been reduced since mid-1999. The US Current-Account Deficit and the Dollar .................................. 47 Niels C. Beier, Economics This article provides a general overview of the developments in the US current account and the dollar in recent years. The development is outlined in the light of the macroeconomic development as well as the underlying capital flows. Finally, an account is given of the future sustainability of the deficit. Quarterly Financial Accounts for Denmark ......................................... 63 Jan Overgaard Olesen and Jens Jakob Svanholt, Statistics In April, Danmarks Nationalbank will start publishing regular quarterly financial accounts for Denmark. This article presents the new statistics, which provide an overview of the financial assets and liabilities of the main sectors in the economy. In addition, some possible applications of the statistics are outlined. 24-03-2004 08:53 Antal sider: 2 Rev. nr. 4 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Indholdsfortegnelse_en.doc Oprettet af Alice Colombo The EU's Financial Services Action Plan ................................................. 83 Dorte Kurek, Financial Markets The European Commission's Financial Services Action Plan is aimed at removing the remaining legislative and regulatory barriers to a single financial market in the EU. This article describes the Action Plan, the Lamfalussy procedure and the future work towards financial integration. Press Releases ........................................................................................ 93 Tables and Graphs Section Vol. XLIII, No. 1 24-03-2004 08:53 Antal sider: 2 Rev. nr. 4 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Indholdsfortegnelse_en.doc Oprettet af Alice Colombo 1 Recent Economic and Monetary Trends This review covers the period from the middle of November 2003 to the middle of February 2004 INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL MARKETS There is uncertainty as to how robust the emerging international upswing is, and particularly as to whether Europe will stumble in the initial phase. The economic cycle is driven by the USA, but also Japan is making progress after a prolonged period of stagnation. The euro area economy is weaker, and forward-looking indicators are ambiguous. In spite of improvements in the US economy, the dollar continued to weaken vis-à-vis the euro into 2004. From the beginning of 2002 to midJanuary 2004 the dollar weakened by more than 30 per cent against the euro to a rate of 1.28 dollars per euro, which was also the exchange rate in mid-February. When the euro was introduced on 1 January 1999 the exchange rate was 1.17 dollars per euro. The weakening of the dollar seems to be related to concerns about the financing of the large and growing current-account deficit in the USA, as well as the long-term sustainability of the public finances. In a longer perspective, the current 1 rate of the dollar vis-à-vis the euro is not particularly low, cf. Chart 1. The weakening of the dollar has been less pronounced in relation to a number of other currencies, among them many Asian ones. The Bank of Japan has sought to keep down the exchange rate of the yen via massive interventions during 2003 and in the current year. The effective exchange rate of the dollar, i.e. measured against a broad basket of currencies, has weakened by approximately 10 per cent since the beginning of 2002. The economic upturn the 2nd half of 2003 has not resulted in higher long-term interest rates. The US and the German 10-year governmentbond yields have both declined since the turn of the year and were approximately 4.1 per cent in mid-February, the same level as six months earlier. The Japanese 10-year yield was 1.3 per cent. The fact that longterm interest rates have not risen as a result of the upturn, particularly in the USA, could indicate widespread confidence in the market that inflation will remain modest, even in the medium term. This should be 1 Before 1 January 1999 the dollar rate vis-à-vis the D-mark is applied. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 2 Chart 1 US DOLLAR VIS-À-VIS EURO US dollars per euro 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 1990 1991 1992 1993 US dollars per euro 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Average 1990-2004 Note: Before 1 January 1999 the exchange rate of the dollar vis-à-vis the D-mark is applied. The latest observation is from calendar week 7, 2004. seen in the light of, inter alia, low and falling core inflation and moderate wage increases in the USA. Monetary-policy interest rates in the USA, Japan and the euro area have remained unchanged since June 2003. Chart 2 PRICE OF CRUDE OIL (BRENT) Price per barrel 33 30 27 24 21 18 Jan 2002 Apr Dollars per barrel Jul Oct Jan 2003 Apr Jul Oct Jan 2004 Euro per barrel Note: The latest observation is from calendar week 7. Source: EcoWin. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 3 The improved outlook for the US economy in particular has influenced stock prices. In mid-February the S&P 500 index was more than 15 per cent above the level in the summer. The European Stoxx 50 index has risen correspondingly, while the increase in the Japanese Nikkei index has been a little weaker. Commodity prices in dollars continued their rising trend in the 4th quarter and into 2004. Industrial metals, which are especially cyclically sensitive, have increased even more – by almost 30 per cent since October. In euro terms the development has been more moderate. The price increases are attributable to the improved growth prospects in the major industrialised countries, as well as strong underlying growth in demand from emerging market economies, notably China. The oil price (Brent) in dollars has shown a rising trend since May 2003 and was just under 30 dollars per barrel in mid-February, only slightly lower than the level up to the war in Iraq at the beginning of 2003. In euro, however, the price has been more or less constant throughout the period, cf. Chart 2. THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY USA In the 4th quarter of 2003, GDP at constant prices increased by 1.0 per cent over the 3rd quarter. Although this was only half the very high growth rate seen in the 3rd quarter, it was significantly higher than the rate of increase in the 1st half of the year, and presumably on the high side of the potential output growth in the longer term. Growth was broadly based with increases in private consumption, investments and especially exports, which benefited from the low dollar rate. Growth in the USA has been stimulated by highly expansionary fiscal and monetary policy. Monetary policy has been expansionary worldwide, whereas fiscal policy has been expansionary primarily in the USA. The budget deficit was thus 4.9 per cent of GDP in 2003 and is expected to rise further in 2004. The deficit reflects a strong reversal of the US economy from a surplus of 1.4 per cent of GDP in 2000, cf. Chart 3, to a deficit that is among the highest in the industrialised world. Only a marginal proportion of the deterioration is attributable to economic developments, while the rest is a result of tax cuts and higher expenditure. The consolidation achieved during the 1990s has thus been undone in a very short time. At approximately 50 per cent of GDP, government debt is still lower than in the euro area and particularly Japan, but higher than the UK level. The question is whether the economic upswing will be self-sustaining and thus continue when the expansionary effects of economic policy 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 4 Chart 3 GOVERNMENT BUDGET BALANCE IN THE USA Per cent of GDP 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 -7 1 2 3 Budget balance 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Structural balance Note: The structural balance shows the cyclically adjusted government budget balance. Source: OECD, Economic Outlook no. 74. subside. The increases in consumption and investments in the 2nd half of 2003 were stimulated by e.g. an extensive tax package including general reductions of income tax, tax relief for families with children and increased deduction options for business enterprises. Some of these measures are, however, temporary. The President has proposed that they be made permanent, which would worsen the outlook for the public finances. The sustainability of the upswing will also depend on the development in the labour market. There are several approaches to calculation of US employment, and they indicate different recent trends, cf. Chart 4. One measure shows that employment has risen, while another indicates that it has fallen. However, the upswing only seems to have had a relatively small impact on employment thus far. "Jobless recovery" is a buzzword. Positive elements include a strong housing market, which supports private consumption, and the stimulus to exports from the falling dollar. Overall the prospects of continued substantial growth in the US economy in 2004 are good, and business confidence has also grown considerably, cf. Chart 5. A risk which could jeopardise the upswing in the slightly longer term, is the sustained large imbalances in the US economy. In addition to the budget deficit there is a large current-account deficit, in 2003 approximately 5 per cent of GDP, cf. the article on the US current-account deficit and the dollar, p. 47ff. The deficit was previously to a large extent 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 5 Chart 4 EMPLOYMENT IN THE USA ACCORDING TO TWO SOURCES Million persons 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 1970 1975 1980 Household survey 1985 1990 1995 2000 Establishment survey Note: The household survey asks a sample of US households whether they are employed, while the establishment survey asks a sample of business enterprises about their employment situation. One of the differences between the two is that the establishment survey does not include the self-employed, agricultural employees and unpaid family members. In addition, the establishment survey does not capture employment in new enterprises as fast as the household survey. On the other hand, the establishment survey operates with considerably larger samples than the household survey. Source: EcoWin. Chart 5 BUSINESS CONFIDENCE AND INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION IN THE USA Percentage balances 70 Per cent, year-on-year 8 60 6 50 4 40 2 30 0 20 -2 10 -4 0 -6 1998 1999 2000 2001 Industrial production, 3-month moving average (right-hand axis) 2002 2003 ISM, manufacturing Note: The ISM index shows the development in business confidence in the US manufacturing sector. The latest observation is from January 2004. Source: EcoWin. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 6 financed by non-residents' purchases of US stocks, whereas in recent years a significant percentage of financing has been attributable to the purchase of US government bonds by Asian central banks – particularly those of Japan and China. The foreign-exchange reserves of many Asian countries are now larger than ever before. Inflation, in terms of the consumer-price index, was 1.9 per cent in December. Consumer-price inflation excluding food and energy was 1.1 per cent. Core inflation has been falling in recent years. The weaker dollar exerts upward pressure on prices owing to higher import prices, but the effect on consumer prices is limited since foreign trade does not constitute a large proportion of the US economy. Industrial wages are rising at a rate of around 2.5 per cent per annum so typical industrial workers have seen a positive development in real wages. The Federal Reserve has maintained an unchanged Fed funds target rate since June last year, when it was lowered by 0.25 per cent to 1 per cent. In the assessment of the Federal Reserve, the risks concerning growth and inflation, respectively, more or less balance, and consequently, "with inflation quite low and resource use slack, the Committee 1 believes that it can be patient in removing its policy accommodation" . Japan The Japanese economy has grown considerably over the past year, with quarterly growth of 1.7 per cent in the 4th quarter. Growth was driven by exports and business investments, while private consumption was weak. The growth in Japanese exports is mainly attributable to the demand for Japanese products in Asia, while the performance of sales in the USA and EU was weaker. For several years Japan has seen deflation, i.e. a fall in the general price level. However, the deflationary trend has been weakening during the past year, and towards the end of 2003 annual price increases, measured by the consumer-price index, were only marginally negative. This development is partly a result of temporary factors so there are no immediate prospects of sustained positive inflation. The rate of wage increase is close to zero. In the long term, the weakening of the dollar and many Asian currencies pegged to the dollar may constitute a problem to the exportdriven Japanese economy. The Bank of Japan has therefore attempted to contain the strengthening of the yen via massive purchases of dollars for yen in the foreign-exchange market. The banks' liquidity has in- 1 Press release, Federal Reserve, 28 January 2004. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 7 creased, and combined with a monetary-policy interest rate close to zero this means that monetary policy in Japan is highly expansionary. The euro area Unlike the USA and Japan, the euro area saw fairly weak growth in the 2nd half of 2003, at 0.4 per cent and 0.3 per cent, respectively in the 3rd and 4th quarters over the preceding quarters. Growth in the 2nd half was, however, stronger than in the 1st half. Early signs of an upswing are mainly found in the confidence indicators. Business confidence in the manufacturing sector was thus increasing towards the end of the year, but flattened out in December and January, cf. Chart 6. The positive development in exports is threatened by the significant strengthening of the euro. It is doubtful whether the increased sales opportunities in the export markets will fully compensate for the loss of competitiveness. Sustained growth in the euro area economy will therefore to a large extent depend on the course of domestic demand, which has remained more or less unchanged since 2001. However, the strengthening of the euro increases real income in the euro area member states. With a continued weak labour market and ample spare capacity in the business enterprises, the prospects of growth in domestic demand are, however, only moderately positive. The February consensus estimate for euro area growth in 2004 is 1.8 per cent. BUSINESS CONFIDENCE AND INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION IN THE EURO AREA Percentage balances 65 Chart 6 2000 = 100 105 60 102 55 99 50 96 45 93 40 90 1998 1999 PMI, manufacturing 2000 2001 2002 2003 Industrial production (right-hand axis) Note: The PMI index shows the development in business confidence in the euro area manufacturing sector. Source: EcoWin. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 8 Chart 7 DEVELOPMENT IN REAL GDP IN SELECTED EU MEMBER STATES 1st quarter 1995 = 100 130 125 120 115 110 105 100 95 1995 UK 1996 France 1997 1998 EU15 1999 Italy 2000 2001 Germany 2002 2003 Denmark Source: EcoWin. Unemployment in the euro area has stabilised in recent months and was 8.8 per cent in December, equivalent to more than 12 million unemployed. Initially, a moderate economic upswing will scarcely be sufficient to reduce unemployment significantly since the business enterprises' capacity utilisation is low, cf. above. In 2003 the budget deficits of both Germany and France exceeded the limit of 3.0 per cent of GDP stipulated in the EU Treaty for the second year running. The deficits were just over 4 per cent of GDP, and the two member states are also expected to exceed the limit this year, as is Portugal, cf. the European Commission's autumn forecast 2003. However, in November the Council of Ministers of Economic Affairs and Finance, the Ecofin Council, decided to suspend the excessive deficits procedure for Germany and France so that no immediate sanctions will be imposed on the two member states by the EU. The Commission has decided to challenge in the European Court of Justice the legal status and validity of certain elements of the Council conclusions. In terms of HICP, inflation in the euro area has fluctuated around 2.0 per cent in the last six months and thus been close to the ECB's target of a rate of price increase below, but close to, 2 per cent in the medium term. The considerable spare capacity helps to curb price rises, as does the appreciation of the euro. On the other hand, higher price-increase rates for food, inter alia as a result of the drought in Southern Europe in the summer, have contributed a little to inflation. Looking ahead, higher indirect 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 9 STRUCTURAL REFORMS IN GERMANY Box 1 The German economy has for some time been characterised by relatively low growth and high unemployment. Many experts, including the OECD and the IMF, have pointed out that significant contributory factors are inappropriate structures, particularly in the labour market, and the way the social system works. In other words, structural reforms are called for rather than ordinary economic policy if Germany is to find a sustainable way out of the present low growth. The social-security schemes, i.e. health, unemployment, pension, care and accident insurance, are key to the German social system. These schemes are to a large extent financed via social taxes that act as a tax on work and thus contribute to placing German hourly costs among the highest in the OECD. At the same time, the working hours are among the shortest. In addition, the labour market is relatively inflexible compared to many other countries e.g. in terms of the companies' access to dismiss superfluous labour and the limited options for flexible work planning. On the costs side the demographic development, i.e. an ageing population, and relatively high benefits, e.g. pensions, which almost entirely lie within the public sector, contribute to increasing public expenditure. Previous reform measures have been limited and cautious, but in the spring of 2003 the German government launched a reform package, Agenda 2010, which was translated into a series of new measures during the year. Among the most important labour-market reforms were reductions in unemployment benefits, tougher requirements for the long-term unemployed to accept job offers, and easier access for firms with 5-10 employees to dismiss superfluous labour (the very small firms already had this option). Outside the labour market, the criteria for receiving social benefits were tightened. Some economists, including the Germany economic advisors and the head of the Ifo Institute for Economic Research, have expressed concerns as to whether the measures adopted are sufficiently extensive and radical to solve the problems within the German economy. The reason is that the structural problems have been allowed to grow considerably over the years. Experts point to the necessity to reduce the very high hourly wage costs in the Germany manufacturing sector, as well as the necessity of breaking down the very rigid wage structures, i.e. to achieve a more decentralised wage-determination procedure. Both require the acceptance of the social partners. Finally, it would be desirable to increase the incentives for low earners to seek work. taxes on e.g. tobacco in Germany and France will also exert upward pressure on prices. Inflation excluding food, energy, alcohol and tobacco was 1.6 per cent in January and has been stable at this level for some time. The ECB has not changed its interest rate since it was lowered by 0.5 per cent to 2.0 per cent in June 2003. Growth in Germany was negative in 2003 and overall growth during the past three years has been practically zero. The unemployment rate and budget deficit have both been increasing. Since the mid-1990s, Germany has seen lower growth than the other EU member states, cf. Chart 7. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 10 The German government is now seeking to kick-start the economy by bringing forward tax cuts from 2005 to 2004 so that the total reduction in 2004 will be approximately 15 billion euro, i.e. twice as large as originally planned. This makes it even more difficult to reduce the budget deficit. At the same time, there is increasing acknowledgement that a sustainable solution of Germany's economic problems cannot be obtained via fiscal-policy instruments alone. Structural labour-market reforms are also required. In 2003 a number of measures were adopted, cf. Box 1. German economic advisors, among others, believe that these measures are a step in the right direction, albeit insufficient. UK In the 2nd half of 2003, growth in the UK economy was more positive than expected, and for the full year real GDP increased by 2.1 per cent, driven by domestic demand. Fiscal policy is expansionary and the government's original target for the budget balance in 2003 was exceeded. In comparison with the preceding year the budget deficit increased from 1.5 per cent to 2.8 per cent of GDP, and it is expected to deteriorate further in 2004. This development is primarily attributable to higher public expenditure for e.g. healthcare and education. Cash prices for owner-occupied housing have doubled since 1999, and the rate of annual increase has been around 20 per cent in the last few quarters. The ratio of average house prices to the households' disposable income is now at the same high level as in the late 1980s, and now as then households borrow extensively against the higher mortgageable value resulting from the increasing house prices. However, the level of interest rates is somewhat lower now than then, which makes it easier for the households to service higher debt with a given disposable income. The Bank of England raised its interest rate by 0.25 per cent to 4.0 per cent at the beginning of February. In the last six months the pound has followed the euro's strengthening vis-à-vis the dollar. In December 2003 the Bank of England's inflation target was changed by the Treasury, cf. Box 2. Sweden In terms of GDP growth the Swedish economy has fared relatively well through the global recession. Increasing household wealth as a result of rising house prices and recently also stock prices have buoyed up private consumption, which has been robust in spite of a weak labour market. Unemployment has been rising, e.g. as a result of fewer people in activation schemes, and towards the end of the year it exceeded 5 per cent. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 11 CHANGE IN THE UK INFLATION TARGET Box 2 The Treasury has determined that the future UK monetary policy should be conducted with the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices, HICP, as the target variable. The target, which is symmetrical, is an inflation rate of 2 per cent +/- 1 per cent, i.e. practically the same as the ECB's target, which is, however, asymmetrical with 2 per cent as the maximum. Thus far the inflation target has been linked to the RPIX index. The difference between this index and HICP is firstly that the price of living in owner-occupied housing is included in RPIX, but not in HICP, and secondly differences in the technical calculation methods. Since the mid-1990s inflation in terms HICP has been around 1 per cent lower than RPIX inflation. Approximately half the difference is attributable to the calculation methods, while the rest is a result of the different compositions. The new inflation target of 2 per cent is 0.5 per cent lower than the previous RPIXbased target, equivalent to the difference attributable to the different calculation methods. The Bank of England finds that the change of target variable has not changed the monetary-policy stance. Whether this will also apply in the future will depend on the development in housing prices. The increases in HICP and RPIX were 1.4 per cent and 2.4 per cent, respectively, in January 2004 compared with January 2003. Inflationary pressure is low. On the basis of the volatile energy prices, Sveriges Riksbank has decided to attach importance to the price index UND1X excluding energy. This index rose by 1.1 per cent in January. In early February, Sveriges Riksbank lowered its interest rate by 0.25 per cent to 2.5 per cent. Norway Unemployment in Norway has been growing in recent years and reached 4.6 per cent of the labour force by the end of 2003. This is a high level by Norwegian standards. At the same time, inflationary pressure is low. Core inflation, measured by the KPI-JAE index, was 0.4 per cent in December and 0.1 per cent in January, e.g. as a result of considerable decreases in the shoes and clothing subindex. The rate of price increase is thus far below the monetary-policy inflation target of 2.5 per cent. Against that background Norges Bank lowered its interest rate by a further 0.25 per cent in mid-December, and also in late January, to 2.0 per cent now. The rate of interest has thus been lowered by 5.0 per cent since December 2002, to the lowest level since World War II. This is expected to boost the economy in mainland Norway, and there are indications to this effect. From the beginning of 2003 until mid-February 2004 the Norwegian krone weakened by approximately 20 per cent vis-à-vis the euro and thus also the Danish krone. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 12 Hungary The autumn saw renewed unrest in the financial markets in Hungary. At the end of November the forint weakened significantly against the euro within a few days. At an extraordinary meeting of the Monetary-Policy Committee on 28 November the central bank decided to raise its interest rate from 9.5 per cent to 12.5 per cent to counter the weakening trend. The subsequent development has been highly volatile, and in midFebruary the forint was approximately 4 per cent weaker than immediately prior to the onset of the currency unrest. The forint remains within the official fluctuation band vis-à-vis the euro of +/- 15 per cent around the central rate of 282.36 forint per euro. The currency unrest in Hungary has not affected the Polish and Czech currencies. The Hungarian central bank operates with targets for both inflation and exchange rate. Since the monetary-policy authorities have only one instrument at their disposal – the rate of interest on the banks' accounts with the central bank – the development in Hungary demonstrates the risk that the targets might in principle clash when political priorities are unclear. THE DEVELOPMENT IN THE DANISH FINANCIAL MARKETS Since October the krone has weakened marginally against the euro, and the exchange rate in mid-February was kr. 7.45 per euro, i.e. slightly stronger than the central rate of kr. 7.46038 per euro. In January Danmarks Nationalbank sold foreign exchange for almost kr. 10 billion net with a view to keeping the krone stable. The sale of foreign exchange continued in February. The net sales were to a large extent attributable to pension companies requiring foreign exchange to purchase foreign securities. At end-January the foreign-exchange reserve was kr. 215 billion. Danmarks Nationalbank has not changed its interest rates since June 2003, when the lending rate was lowered to 2.15 per cent. The currentaccount rate and discount rate are 2.0 per cent. Danish long-term yields have shown the same pattern as the European ones, and the 10-year government-bond differential to Germany has been unchanged at approximately 20 basis points. Recent monetary trends, illustrated by the financial statistics, support the expectations of a cyclical reversal during 2004. Growth in lending by banks and mortgage-credit institutes has been robust in spite of the sluggish development in investments and private consumption in the first three quarters of 2003. Lending to households was 8.1 per cent higher in December than in the same month of the preceding year. Loans have e.g. been raised to finance residential investments, but the figures indicate 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 13 Chart 8 LENDING BY BANKS AND MORTGAGE-CREDIT INSTITUTES Per cent, year-on-year 25 20 15 10 5 0 -5 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Lending by banks to households Business lending by banks Lending by mortgage-credit institutes to households Business lending by mortgage-credit institutes Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. that some of the loan proceeds have been invested in financial assets, which may be used to finance increased consumption in the future. However, pension savings accounted for some of the placements. Growth in lending to the business sector has been somewhat slower over the past year and was around 2.5 per cent higher in December 2003 than in 2002. Growth in lending by mortgage-credit institutes to households has been considerably higher than growth in lending by banks to households in recent years. This pattern has changed over the last few months so that the rates of increase were almost identical in December, cf. Chart 8. In absolute terms, lending by mortgage-credit institutes to households is approximately four times as high as lending by banks. New statistics for the deferred-amortisation loans that have been available to private borrowers since 1 October 2003 show that deferredamortisation loans for kr. 44 billion were granted in the 4th quarter of 2003, equivalent to 57 per cent of total gross new lending. Of the kr. 44 billion in deferred-amortisation loans, kr. 42 billion were adjustable-rate loans, mainly with an initial fixation period of up to one year. THE DANISH ECONOMY The first release of national accounts showed reasonable growth in the Danish economy throughout 2002, with a somewhat receding trend in 2003. After the latest revision this picture has, however, changed signifi- 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 14 cantly so that the development in Denmark is more in line with that of the euro area, i.e. a flatter course with weak growth in both years. The preliminary quarterly national accounts for the 3rd quarter of 2003 show a fall in GDP in volume terms by 0.2 per cent for the second quarter running. A decline in stocks, as well as a higher increase in imports than in exports, contributed to the negative growth. On the other hand, private consumption grew by 0.5 per cent from the 2nd to the 3rd quarter, inter alia as a result of an increase in new car purchases, which had long shown a falling trend. Investments increased by 4.4 per cent, redressing the fall in the two preceding quarters. Particularly machinery investments developed positively. Residential construction showed zero growth. The higher private consumption and investments explain a large proportion of the increase in imports. It is also worth noting that growth in public consumption has been curbed in the last few quarters, and in the 3rd quarter of 2003 it fell by 0.5 per cent. Looking ahead, there are concerns as to whether the prospects of a change in the local and regional government structure in Denmark might lead to an inexpedient transitional increase in localgovernment expenditure, particularly in the construction area. Against this background the government has imposed a duty on the local governments to report planned investment measures. This does not imply an approval process, however. Manufactured exports rose in the 2nd half of 2003 after a significant fall in the 2nd quarter, but the level was still lower than in the same period of the preceding year. The value of agricultural exports decreased in 2003. Exports are impeded by the rising effective krone rate, but in the long term they will benefit from the expanding international export markets. Imports also declined marginally in 2003 compared with the year before. Towards the end of the year imports to businesses and households had, however, picked up again. The monthly seasonally adjusted trade surplus was kr. 5-6 billion throughout 2003. The current account of the balance of payments improved during 2003 and the full-year surplus was almost kr. 40 billion, compared to kr. 28 billion in 2002. The surplus is thus back at the high level seen in 2001. This development is mainly a result of improvements on the balance of services. In the last three months of the year, the seasonally adjusted volume of retail sales was 2.6 per cent higher than in the 3rd quarter, cf. Chart 9. Car sales in the 4th quarter were higher than in the other quarters of 2003 and continued to rise in January 2004. Consumer confidence in January, as in the preceding months, was positive, chiefly owing to an 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 15 Chart 9 INDICATORS OF PRIVATE CONSUMPTION 2000 = 100 Percentage balances 130 10 120 8 110 6 100 4 90 2 80 0 70 -2 60 -4 50 -6 -8 40 2000 2001 Consumer expectations (right-hand axis) 2002 New passenger car registrations 2003 Retail sales index Source: Statistics Denmark. optimistic view of the household's own financial situation. The increase in sales and imports of machinery, etc. indicates continued growth in business investments, while the high housing prices will boost housing construction. Stocks fell in both the 2nd and 3rd quarters. Overall economic growth in the 4th quarter is estimated to have been moderately positive. Seasonally adjusted employment has declined by approximately 50,000 in the past 18 months or so, primarily in the private sector. Unemployment continued to rise for the rest of the year and reached 6.6 per cent in December. The uncertain labour-market conditions may help to curb growth in consumption. The domestic preconditions for an upswing in 2004 seem to be present. Disposable income is still rising since the rate of wage increase exceeds the rate of price increase and income taxes have been lowered. In addition, the housing market is still strong. Deferred-amortisation loans, which already enjoy great popularity, are also expected to contribute moderately to growth in consumption. There is, however, much uncertainty as to when and how fast the positive factors will be reflected in private consumption. Moreover, there is much uncertainty concerning the outlook for the European, and particularly the German, economy. The combination of a strong krone and wage increases that have long exceeded those of Denmark's competitors has pushed up the real effective krone rate, which is an indicator of competitiveness, to a high level, 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 16 Chart 10 COMPETITIVENESS AND THE KRONE RATE 1990 = 100 115 110 105 100 95 90 90 91 92 93 94 95 Real effective krone rate, consumer prices Nominal effective krone rate 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 Real effective krone rate, hourly wages Source: Own calculations. cf. Chart 10. On the basis of the current account of the balance of payments, and to some extent the rate of unemployment, competitiveness is still deemed to be good. Nevertheless, it has deteriorated. A more subdued wage development would contribute to reversing the declining trend in employment and would also be consistent with a sustainable increase in real wages. After reconciliation, a proposal has been submitted for a new collective agreement for e.g. the industrial sector. The collective agreement, which will run for three years, comprises an increase in the pension contribution from 9 per cent to 10.8 per cent, a longer period with full wages entitlement during maternity leave, and an increase in the minimum hourly wages by kr. 2.25 in each of the three years, to kr. 95.15. In addition, the agreement includes improvements for wage-earners in a number of other areas, e.g. higher inconvenience bonuses, higher public-holiday payments and higher wages for apprentices. The agreement gives employers increased scope for varying the working hours at local level in cooperation with the employees. The relevant organisations will now take a ballot on the proposal. The social partners believe that the centrally negotiated collective agreements increase costs to business enterprises by just under 1.0 per cent per annum. This agreement could indicate some dampening of the relatively high rate of wage increase that has persisted in Denmark for a number of years, cf. Box 3, but the ultimate development in costs will depend on the local negotiations in the individual enterprise. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 17 PRODUCTIVITY IN DENMARK AND THE EURO AREA Box 3 For some time, Danish wages have been increasing at a faster rate than in most of Denmark's competitor countries, including the euro area member states. At a given exchange rate, an excess wage-increase rate in Denmark will tend to weaken Denmark's competitiveness, unless it is offset by an equivalent higher increase in productivity. In the 2nd half of the 1990s the development in productivity was weaker in Denmark than in the euro area as a whole, while Danish wages in the private sector rose at a higher pace. The result was a significant loss of competitiveness. From mid-2000 the situation changed. Danish wage increases still exceeded those of the euro area, but there was an almost equivalent higher increase in productivity in Denmark, cf. Chart 11. However, in recent years the latter mainly reflects a poorer development in employment (the denominator) rather than higher GDP growth (the numerator) and thus indicates considerable streamlining of Danish business enterprises. Higher employment would presumably require that the rate of wage increase in Denmark is brought more in line with that of Denmark's competitors. Productivity is difficult to calculate correctly. The Chart applies a productivity measure for the whole economy, i.e. growth in real GDP per person employed. However, the pattern is more or less the same if we only look at productivity development in the sector of the economy exposed to competition. Chart 11 WAGES AND PRODUCTIVITY IN DENMARK AND THE EURO AREA Per cent, year-on-year 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 1995 1996 1997 Excess wage increase in Denmark 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Excess productivity increase in Denmark Prices In January the consumer-price index was 1.1 per cent higher than in January 2003. This is the lowest monthly rate of price increase for 10 years, reflecting e.g. the lowering of indirect taxes on alcohol and cigarettes in October 2003. The subindex for alcohol and tobacco, with a 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 18 weighting of almost 5 per cent in the consumer-price index, has thus decreased by more than 6 per cent over the last year. The index of net retail prices, which is not affected by the lowering of indirect taxes, rose by 1.5 per cent in January. The contribution to inflation from imports and energy has also declined, inter alia as a result of the higher effective krone rate, which makes imported goods cheaper in Danish kroner, as well as the high oil price at the beginning of 2003. The rate of price increase is also expected to be very low in the months to come. Domestic market-determined inflation (IMI) was 1.9 per cent in January. The declining import prices have not passed fully through to consumer prices. Typically a change in import prices is not fully reflected in consumer prices in the short term so that profit margins move in the opposite direction, acting as a shock absorber in consumer prices. Danish inflation is still lower than inflation in the euro area, partly as a result of the reduced indirect taxes. However, if energy and food, including alcohol and tobacco, are excluded, core inflation is higher in Denmark than in the euro area and has been so for a while. 24-03-2004 09:20 Antal sider: 18 Rev. nr. 5 I:\WEBpublikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\SØMU_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 19 The Development in Cash Prices of OwnerOccupied Housing Erik Haller Pedersen, Economics CONCLUSIONS After a sustained increase over many years, the prices of owner-occupied housing – be it single-family houses, row houses, summer cottages or owner-occupied flats – are at a historical high, cf. Chart 1. However, the rate of increase has been declining in recent years. Notwithstanding the high level, the increase in real-property prices is by and large attributable to the underlying pattern of the households' disposable incomes, interest rates, and supply factors. Unless the Danish economy is hit by a prolonged recession with rapidly rising unemployment or significantly REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN REAL CASH PRICES FOR OWNER-OCCUPIED HOUSING Chart 1 1980 = 100 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 Region 1 Region 2 Region 3 Regions 6 and 7 Region 8 Average 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Regions 4 and 5 Note: Regions 1 to 3 comprise the broadly-defined metropolitan area (Greater Copenhagen plus the Counties of Frederiksborg and Roskilde). Regions 4 to 8 comprise the rest of Denmark on an increasingly rural scale. See Appendix 1 for details. The consumption deflator has been applied. Source: Told og Skat, Ejendomssalg (Customs and Tax, Property sales). 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 20 higher interest rates, there is little likelihood of major downward adjustments of cash prices, although price increases can be expected to be more moderate in future. As the Chart illustrates, the concept of one housing market is scarcely valid any more. Up through the 1990s and in recent years the housing market has shown an increasingly clear tendency to split, with considerably stronger price dynamics in the metropolitan area than in the rest of Denmark. The same tendency, albeit weaker, was observed during the upswing from 1982 to 1986. This price gap is not likely to narrow significantly in the near future. It is believed that the introduction of adjustable-rate loans in 1996, viewed in isolation, had a small positive effect on cash prices, raising them by approximately 4 per cent. The introduction of deferredamortisation loans will scarcely have any major impact on cash prices, but could have a marginally expansionary effect in the short term. DEMAND FOR OWNER-OCCUPIED HOUSING From a theoretical point of view, the major factors affecting the cash prices of owner-occupied housing are: the households' real disposable incomes, interest rates, construction costs, and the expectations of future increases in house prices. The ratio of the households' real disposable incomes to the stock of houses has been increasing since the early 1990s, cf. Chart 2. The volume and quality of owner-occupied housing have thus not increased at the same rate as real income after tax. This factor alone could explain the rising trend in cash prices in that the demand for housing traditionally increases at more or less the same rate as incomes. Chart 2 includes real first-year instalments. These include interest expenditure after tax, redemptions and property taxes, but not utilities. The first-year instalment, shown for financing at a short- and long-term interest rate, respectively, is close to the net instalments typically shown on the estate agents' sheets of information. The first-year instalment gives an idea of the liquidity burden for a first-time buyer and thereby illustrates how difficult it is to enter the market for owner-occupied housing. Real first-year instalments rose from 1993 to 2000, but have subsequently levelled off. The first-year instalment comprises redemptions on loans for financing the home and thus represents both actual financing costs and savings invested in the home. Since redemptions are part of the first-year instalment, the latter becomes sensitive to the rules for mortgage-credit lending, e.g. in terms of maturity, loan type, etc. The newly introduced 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 21 Chart 2 FACTORS DETERMINING THE COSTS OF HOME OWNERSHIP 1980 = 100 Per cent 140 18 120 16 100 14 80 12 60 10 40 8 20 6 4 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Real disposable income / stock of houses First-year instalment, short-term interest rate First-year instalment, long-term interest rate User cost excluding expected capital gains (right-hand axis) Note: The first-year instalment comprises financing costs after tax and redemptions, as well as property taxes. The real first-year instalment for the short-term interest rate is calculated using adjustable-rate loans for the period from 1996 onwards deflated by consumer prices. The user cost excluding expected capital gains shows interest after tax plus property taxes plus depreciation, cf. Appendix 2. Source: Realkredit Danmark and Mona's data bank. mortgage-credit loans with deferred amortisation for up to 10 years will immediately lower the first-year instalment considerably for buyers opting for such loans. In theory, capital costs, also known as the user cost, are a better and more adequate expression of the costs of owning and occupying a home over a number of years, see Appendix 2. The user cost is not effected by changes in the redemption profile of loans, but purely by the development in interest after tax, property taxes, the depreciation rate, and the expected future price increases. Houses and flats are durable goods, and in a forward-looking perspective the real costs of owning one's home depend on the development in its price. This is in line with the general perception that a good time to invest in housing is when significant increases in housing prices are expected. Expectations of higher cash prices and thus capital gains thereby have a downward impact on the real costs of owning and occupying a home. Chart 2 shows the development in the part of the user cost that comprises interest after tax, property taxes and depreciation, but excludes expected capital gains. Taxation of housing generally has a dampening effect on fluctuations in market prices of owner-occupied housing since increases in cash prices as a result of higher demand are less pronounced 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 22 Chart 3 THE REAL "RENT" PAYABLE BY OWNER-OCCUPIERS 1980 = 100 225 200 175 150 125 100 75 50 25 0 1980 1982 1984 Copenhagen 1986 1988 Rural areas 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Average Note: "Rent" has been calculated as the user cost including expected capital gains multiplied by the index of real cash prices, cf. Appendix 2. Source: Told og Skat (Customs and Tax) and Mona's data bank. when taxes also rise. Likewise, price falls are moderated. Taxation of housing is one of the reasons why the user cost did not fall as much as interest rates during the 1990s. To obtain the level of real costs, the user cost including expected capital gains is multiplied by the real cash price of owner-occupied housing. The expected capital gains, shown in Chart 7, attempt to capture the households' expectations of future increases in the price of the home since these must be included in a theoretically correct cost measure, cf. above. The product of total user cost and the real cash price shows the real "rent" that the owner pays to live in his or her home. In 2003 the real "rent" for the housing market taken as one was close to its historical average, cf. Chart 3. Adjusted for general price trends, owning a home is therefore not more expensive today than it was previously, but there are large regional differences. In the metropolitan area, real "rent" is at a high level. The drop in the calculated "rent" in the mid-1980s reflects expectations at the time that cash prices would continue to rise significantly, which had a downward effect on the user cost – including expectations of capital gains – cf. above. These expectations were not met, and the user cost increased again in the latter half of the decade. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 23 SUPPLY OF OWNER-OCCUPIED HOUSING 1 While interest rates and – to some extent – taxation are the same throughout Denmark, the development in incomes may differ from region to region. However, the supply of owner-occupied housing is the clearest indicator of the regional differences between the metropolitan area and the rest of the country. In the short term the supply of housing is constant, and changes in demand are thus directly reflected in cash prices. Fluctuations in housing prices are therefore a natural element of the housing market and do not necessarily reflect price bubbles or the like. If housing prices continue to rise, the cash price of owner-occupied housing will at some point exceed the costs of building a new home. If there are vacant building plots and spare capacity in the construction sector, this will boost new building, thus exerting downward pressure on housing prices. If there are vacant plots, cash prices will in the long term increase in line with the increase in construction costs and thus follow 2 the general level of prices . In that case there will not be any real capital gains on housing. The situation is fundamentally different if the number of vacant building plots is insufficient, e.g. because the region has been fully built-up, or because no more land has been zoned for residential purposes. If so, the price of land and property could continue to rise as long as demand is increasing, and homeowners will see real capital gains. Housing prices will also become more volatile over time. This scenario resembles the situation in the metropolitan area in the last 10 years, although this area has also seen some construction activity. Underlying factors include demographic shifts between regions (urbanisation), changing living patterns (e.g. more singles) and differences in economic growth. The split housing market is clearly illustrated in Chart 4, showing residential investments at constant prices and the relative cash price, i.e. the ratio of the price of existing housing to the price of new building. The rise 3 in housing prices since 1993 has boosted residential investments . There can be no doubt that cash prices have reached a level where it often pays to build a new home. 1 2 3 The progression in property-value tax mainly affects the metropolitan area. On the other hand, this area derives the greatest benefits from the tax freeze in the housing sector. Land tax also varies from municipality to municipality. This presumes that productivity development in the construction sector does not systematically deviate from the general course of productivity in the economy. Residential investments are affected by reparation of damage caused by the hurricane in December 1999. This explains the uneven trend towards the end of the period. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 24 Chart 4 RELATIVE CASH PRICE (TOBIN'S Q) AND RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENTS 1980 = 100 150 Billion 1995-kroner 70 120 60 90 50 60 40 30 30 0 20 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 Region 2 Whole country 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Regions 6 and 7 Residential investments (right-hand axis) Note: Relative cash price calculated as the ratio of the cash price to the deflator for residential investments. The size shows the ratio of prices for existing housing to new building. Region 2 is the County of Copenhagen, while regions 6 and 7 cover smaller municipalities and provincial towns, but not decidedly rural municipalities, cf. Appendix 1. Source: Told og Skat (Customs and Tax) and the Mona data bank. Chart 5 NEW BUILDING OF OWNER-OCCUPIED HOUSING 1,000 2,500 m2 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 Metropolitan area 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Rest of Denmark Note: Estimates for 2003. Source: Statistics Denmark, National accounts. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 25 Residential investments comprise both new building and improvements to and maintenance of existing housing, including urban renewal. The national accounts for new building by region show that growth in new building is clearly strongest outside the metropolitan area, cf. Chart 5, although the gap between the price of existing housing and the price of 1 new building is widest in the metropolitan area. As stated above, this reflects the shortage of building plots. Land prices in Denmark have 2 increased at a higher rate than cash prices during the last 20 years . It is therefore hardly likely that the price gap between the metropolitan area and the rest of Denmark will narrow significantly in the near future. In many ways it is more relevant to compare prices in the metropolitan area with prices in other cities such as Stockholm, Helsinki or Hamburg rather that comparing with rural areas in Denmark, and in an international perspective Copenhagen is not particularly dear. A similar pattern, i.e. a housing market split between the metropolitan region and the rest 3 of the country, is seen in many other European countries . THE DEVELOPMENT IN CASH PRICES The preceding pages describe the key factors determining the development in house prices. Danmarks Nationalbank's economic model, Mona, captures these factors in a house-price relation where housing prices are a function of income, user cost and the stock of owner-occupied housing, cf. Appendix 3. Unemployment, which is often said to determine the course of property prices, is not directly included in this house-price equation, but is reflected indirectly via incomes. The supply is included via a relation for residential investments. A house-price relation of the above nature is not fully able to explain the increases in cash prices in recent years. This is illustrated by positive residuals since 1998, cf. Chart 6. On a quarterly basis, the residuals show the difference between the actual price development and the development predicted by the house-price equation. This may have several causes. Firstly, there are indications of a structural break in housing demand in the late 1990s after the adoption of the 1998 Whitsun Package of Economic Measures, which made it less attractive to invest in e.g. capital pensions. This may have stimulated the demand for housing in general and summer cottages in particular as alternative investments. 1 2 3 Investments in urban renewal, façade renovation and the like are not included in the new-building figures. Traditionally most of these investments have been made in the metropolitan area. See Told og Skat, Ejendomssalg (Customs and Tax, Property sales). See Structural Factors In The EU Housing Markets, European Central Bank (2003). 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 26 Chart 6 ACTUAL AND ESTIMATED CASH PRICES 1980 = 100 Per cent, quarter-on-quarter 6 350 300 4 250 2 200 0 150 -2 100 -4 50 -6 1980 1982 1984 1986 Nominal cash prices 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Residuals, long-term rate (right-hand axis) 2000 2002 Residuals, short- and long-term rates (right-hand axis) Note: The residuals show the difference between the actual and estimated cash prices. Positive residuals thus indicate that the cash-price equation has not been fully able to explain the price increases. If the interest-rate series from the Association of Danish Mortgage Banks are applied instead of the long-term rate alone, cf. Appendix 3, the residuals are reduced. Source: The Association of Danish Mortgage Banks and own calculations using the Mona model's cash-price relation. Secondly, the house-price relation estimates the average price development and thus does not fully take into account that some areas, such as the metropolitan area, may be particularly price sensitive owing to supply. EFFECT OF ADJUSTABLE-RATE LOANS ON CASH PRICES Box 1 Chart 6 shows the result of estimating and projecting the house-price relation using respectively a long-term mortgage-credit rate and an interest rate taking account of adjustable-rate loans. As can be seen, a house-price relation in which adjustable-rate loans are taken into account in the user cost is better at explaining the development (i.e. lower average residuals and lower standard deviation on these) than if only a long-term rate is applied. Differences in residuals can be translated into a cash-price level, which gives an estimate of the effect of adjustable-rate loans on cash prices. Calculated in this way, the figures show that the extensive use of adjustable-rate loans, viewed in isolation, has pushed cash prices for owner-occupied housing upward by approximately 4 per cent. This calculation does not consider the circumstance that short-term interest rates are typically lower than long-term interest rates, but also entail a higher risk. One interpretation of the result might be that buyers opting for adjustable-rate loans have not fully taken into account the increased risk, possibly because the Danish market has not seen any period of significantly increasing interest rates since the introduction of this loan type. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 27 A third factor is the introduction of adjustable-rate loans in 1996, which made it possible to finance housing at short-term interest rates via mortgage-credit institutes. Calculations show that adjustable-rate loans, viewed in isolation, have boosted cash prices for owner-occupied housing a little, cf. Box 1 and Appendix 3. THE SIGNIFICANCE OF THE INSTITUTIONAL AND LEGAL FRAMEWORK In addition to the above factors, property prices are affected by the institutional and legal framework for home financing. The framework for mortgage-credit activities has undergone significant changes over the past 20 years, thanks to extensive liberalisation. One result of the liberalisation measures has been a large increase in the number of mortgage-credit products offered. Today a borrower may choose between fixed- and adjustable-rate loans, between bond, cash and index-linked loans, between euro- and krone-denominated loans, between loans with different redemption profiles and maturities, etc. Danmarks Nationalbank has supported the gradual liberalisation process and welcomed product development. At the same time, the need to advise the borrower on the ever more complex choice of product has been emphasised to ensure that borrowers are aware of the risks incurred. The legal framework within which mortgage-credit institutes operate may in itself affect property prices, cf. above on the possible effects of adjustable-rate loans and deferred-amortisation loans. The liberalisation measures have, however, been introduced gradually to give the market an opportunity to adapt. The above development with a still wider product range is not a purely Danish phenomenon, but can also be found in a number of other countries with other traditions and institutions for home financing. The Danish mortgage-credit system ensures that even small loans can be raised on financial-market terms with a low interest-rate margin. Consequently the Danish mortgage-credit system has attracted increasing interest from abroad in recent years. The gilt-edged status of mortgage-credit bonds is founded on a number of key legislative elements which impose certain restrictions on the activities of mortgage-credit institutes, but which are also prerequisites of the 1 soundness of the system. This is particularly true of the balance principle , which ensures a high degree of coherence between the terms and conditions for loans and the underlying bonds. The balance principle, which has been central to Danish mortgage-credit legislation since the mid-19th 1 Danmarks Nationalbank supported the adjustments of the balance principle which took place in 1989 and 2001, respectively. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 28 century, is actually a simple type of risk management within mortgagecredit institutes and has helped to steer them safely through periods with significant fluctuations in interest rates and prices. The mortgageable limit of 80 per cent of the market value and the maximum maturity of 30 years for mortgage-credit loans are other important elements. DEFERRED-AMORTISATION LOANS On 1 October 2003, deferred-amortisation mortgage-credit loans were introduced in the Danish market. Amortisation can be deferred for up to 10 years, but subsequently the loan can be refinanced via a new deferred-amortisation loan. The 10-year rule thus primarily ensures that the collateral, i.e. the property, is reassessed if the borrower wants to raise a new loan. The new product is already available in several versions – as fixed- or adjustable-rate loans, and with the deferred-amortisation period placed in the first 10 years of the loan term (which can be up to 30 years) or an "opt-in" model under which deferred amortisation can be selected and deselected as required. The range of mortgage-credit products has thereby been expanded further. The impact of the new type of loans on the housing market and the economy in general will to a large extent depend on the behaviour of borrowers. If borrowers take a holistic approach to their finances, the deferred-amortisation loans are in principle not revolutionary. During the last 10 years there has been general access to supplementary mortgage credit, and various reversed mortgage products are already available in the market. Consequently, nobody has involuntarily had to accumulate large savings in the home. At most, the deferredamortisation loans make it a little easier and cheaper not to accumulate free mortgageable value in one's home in excess of the value accrued as a result of rising cash prices. However, if borrowers take a very narrow approach to their finances, mainly focusing on the first-year instalment after tax, the deferredamortisation loans may have an impact on savings and cash prices. The first-year instalment after tax can be considerably lower for a deferredamortisation loan than for a traditional loan. As described above, the user cost is not affected by the redemption profile of the loan. In general, the majority of borrowers must be presumed to consider their overall financial situation when deciding whether to raise a deferred-amortisation loan, but there will be a tendency for the deferred-amortisation loans to support cash prices. Initially the new loans have mainly appealed to middle-aged people in owner-occupied housing with a high free mortgageable value. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 29 OTHER EFFECTS OF THE INCREASE IN CASH PRICES Housing prices are important in a number of contexts outside the housing market. Above all, housing prices determine the value of the stock of houses, which in turn constitutes a significant part of the households' wealth, which – together with incomes – determines private consumption. Traditionally capital gains are reflected in higher consumption for a while. However, the increase in wealth since 1998 has had a surprisingly small effect on private consumption in Denmark. This is in contrast to the development in certain other countries, including the UK. The reasons why the increase in the households' wealth has not had a more significant impact on private consumption may be a considerable reduction of the tax value of interest deductibility in this period, as well as wider acknowledgement than previously of the need to save up for one's pension. It is assessed that the introduction of deferred-amortisation loans will not in itself entail a significant change in the propensity of households to save. Housing prices also have an, albeit indirect, impact on inflation, on credit expansion and thus financial stability, and on the distribution of wealth in the Danish society. These issues will not be considered further here. For a more detailed analysis of the impact of housing prices on financial stability, see Financial Stability, Danmarks Nationalbank (2002). 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 30 APPENDIX 1 Municipal grouping of owner-occupied housing applied by Customs and Tax: Group 1: The Cities of Copenhagen and Frederiksberg. Group 2: All municipalities in the County of Copenhagen. Group 3: All municipalities in the Counties of Frederiksborg and Roskilde. Group 4: Other municipalities with more than 50,000 inhabitants in the largest urban area. Group 5: Other municipalities with 20-50,000 inhabitants in the largest urban area. Group 6: Other municipalities with 10-20,000 inhabitants in the largest urban area. Group 7: Other municipalities with 5-10,000 inhabitants in the largest urban area. Group 8: Other municipalities with up to 5,000 inhabitants in the largest urban area. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 31 APPENDIX 2 A model calculation of the costs of home ownership (user cost) typically includes the following elements: user cost = interest after tax + housing tax as a percentage of property value + depreciation rate – expected capital gains A falling level of interest rates makes dwelling cheaper, while lower interest deductibility and higher property taxes make it dearer. The development in these two factors and the rate of depreciation are shown in Chart 2. Lower inflation expectations increase the user cost since the expected capital gains on the home purchased are lower. The perception that a housing purchase will result in capital gains thus helps to reduce the real housing costs. The first part of the expression is standard, whereas the expected capital gains can be calculated in several ways, particularly when it comes to modelling the expectations. Inflation expectations may be created extrapolatively or regressively, depending on the degree to which historical series are included. In practical modelling it is a question of whether, and to which degree, price series should be smoothed (on regressive formation of expectations). For regressive expectations, a large increase in cash prices will lead to expectations of a future fall, while there will be expectations of further increases and thus possibly a price bubble in the extrapolative case. In practice, an assessment of the expected price increase in the housing market may include several elements. For instance, more than one price development may be considered. The most obvious candidates are consumer prices, construction costs and the cash prices themselves. The expected development in house prices cannot be measured directly, so any estimations must be indirect. In Danmarks Nationalbank's Mona model, on which this Appendix is based, expected capital gains are estimated as an integral part of the cash-price relation. Specifically, consumer prices, primarily filtered consumer prices, and house prices are included in the determination of expected capital gains in Mona's house-price 1 relation . Filtering smoothes consumer prices and removes the impact of individual shocks to prices. This leaves a softer underlying tendency in the price index and its rate of increase. 1 For a more detailed description of this, see MONA – a quarterly model of the Danish economy, Danmarks Nationalbank (2003). 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 32 In the estimation of the house-price relation, the coefficients for the rates of increase in consumer and house prices add up to the coefficient for the nominal rate of interest. The weighed rates of increase can thus be seen as the rate of increase for a real interest rate. The expected price increase thereby determined is more subdued than the actual year-on-year increase in cash prices. However, a pass-through from the actual development in the prices of owner-occupied housing can be observed. For instance, the expected price increase declined around 1980 when growth in cash prices subsided, but picked up again around the mid-1980s when cash prices increased after the fall in interest rates, cf. Chart 7 showing the expectations part of Mona's user-cost expression. Since the mid-1990s the series of expected capital gains has been at a level of around 2½ per cent. Inflation expectations have generally been declining over time and are now close to the expected increase in cash prices in the long term, outside the metropolitan area at any rate. The Chart also shows the expected price deflator for residential investments as defined in the Adam model. This is an indication of the development in cash prices in the long term. The real "rent" for an owner-occupier is calculated as the user cost as described above multiplied by an index of the real cash price, i.e. real "rent" = user cost*cash price/consumption deflator, cf. Chart 3. Chart 7 INFLATION PART OF THE USER COST AND INCREASE IN CASH PRICES Per cent 25 20 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 75 77 79 81 83 85 Inflation adjustment (Mona defginition) Increase in cash prices, year-on-year 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 Deflator for residential investments Source: Mona databank and Adam databank (the rpibhe variable). 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 33 APPENDIX 3 For the purposes of this article, the cash-price relation in the Mona model has been reestimated applying a long-term mortgage rate up to 1996, and a weighted average of the Association of Danish Mortgage Banks' series for long- and short-term mortgage rates, respectively, from 1997 onwards. The weight of the short-term rate is calculated as the percentage of adjustable-rate loans in new lending by mortgage-credit institutes, cf. the MFI statistics. At present this percentage is approximately 50. The result of the reestimation is shown below. The estimated equation, cf. Table 1, has subsequently been projected using the long-term mortgage rate and the weighted rate, respectively, and the two projections have been compared to the actual development. This gives two sets of residuals calculated as the actual development less the estimated development. As Chart 6 shows, we get closer to an explanation of the development in cash prices if we include adjustable-rate loans. The differences in the residuals are then "translated" into a cash-price level by dividing the average difference in the residuals, i.e. 0.32 per cent, by the coefficient for the lagged real cash price in the reestimated equation (0.0907). Thus an estimate is achieved of the impact of adjustable-rate loans on cash prices. CASH-PRICE EQUATION Table 1 Variable Name Coefficient t value House price ∆log(kp) Consumption deflator ∆log(pcp) User-cost change ∆(rente + ssats ) Lagged user-cost change ∆(rente-1 + ssats-1 ) User cost rente-1 + ssats-1 + 0,01 Expected change in consumption dpcpe-1 deflator Expected change in house price dkpe-1 Real house price log(kp-1/pcp-1) Real income/stock of houses log((ydp-1 - ipv-1)/pcp-1) - log(fwh-1) Constant 0.2531 -3.7589 -0.7370 -0.8505 1.3 9.0 1.7 2.8 0.8666 0.1706 -0.0907 0.0569 0.0706 2.5 2.7 3.6 2.1 3.9 T = 1974:2 – 1999:4 R2 = 0.6767 Se Note: DW JB = = 1.695 0.803 AR(1) = 2.499 AR(4) = 6.388 = 0.0166 The relation is estimated by restricted OLS. The restriction equals the sum of price-increase coefficients for the interest-rate coefficient. Furthermore, income elasticity in housing demand is restricted to 1. 24-03-2004 11:49 Antal sider: 15 Rev. nr. 9 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Dev in Cash Prices of Owner-Occupied Housing_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Erik Haller Pedersen 35 Developments in the Danish Bond Market since 1970 Ulrik Knudsen and Michael Sand, Market Operations INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY The Danish bond market has changed radically since 1970. At that time it almost exclusively comprised mortgage-credit bonds. Today mortgage-credit bonds and government securities make up 2/3 and 1/3, respectively, of the total bond market in Denmark. Until the mid-1970s callable annuity bonds dominated the Danish bond market. This pattern changed with the renewed issue of serial-loan bonds by the central government. In 1983 the central government introduced bullet issues, and since then the percentage of bullet loans has been increasing. This trend reflects the central-government borrowing strategy, as well as the popularity of adjustable-rate loans from the late 1990s. Today the circulating volume of bonds comprises callable annuity bonds and uncallable bullet issues, with an overweight of the latter. The total krone duration in the Danish bond market has declined since mid-1999. This is attributable to the changed composition of the circulating volume of mortgage-credit bonds, in that the proportion of adjustable-rate bonds has increased, and to the development in interest rates, which has reduced the krone duration of the callable mortgagecredit bonds. ISSUING AND BORROWING ACTIVITY IN THE BOND MARKET The central government and the mortgage-credit institutes are the prin1 cipal issuers of Danish bonds. The first domestic Danish government 2 bond loan was raised in 1785. In the following years the issue of government bonds increased, and the growing turnover resulted in regular bond quotations on Københavns børs (the Copenhagen exchange) in 1 2 Special institutions (including KommuneKredit and Danish Ship Finance), government-guaranteed entities (e.g. A/S Storebælt) and private enterprises are also significant issuers of bonds. The first Danish government-bond loan was raised in Amsterdam in 1757, cf. Statistics Denmark, Statistical Reports no. 24 – Credit-Market Statistics (in Danish), 1969. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 36 1810. Some 10 years after the issue of the first domestic Danish government bond, the first mortgage-credit loan was arranged in Denmark. After the fire of Copenhagen in 1795 there was a need to reconstruct a large number of the destroyed buildings. Consequently, the first Danish mortgage-credit institute, Kreditkassen for Husejere i Kjøbenhavn (the Credit Fund for Houseowners in Copenhagen), was established in 1797. With the Constitution of 1849 freedom of association became a statu1 tory right, and in 1850 the first Danish mortgage-credit act was passed. The framework for the mortgage-credit market has changed radically over the years, partly as a result of increased legislative liberalisation, partly as an element of economic policy, e.g. as an instrument of adjustment. Among other things, this has entailed a much higher degree of concentration, so that there are now only 7 Danish mortgage-credit issuers left, compared to 25 in the early 1970s. Box 1 outlines the development in the Danish bond market. The Appendix includes definitions of a number of bond-market concepts. The Danish bond market as a percentage of GDP grew strongly up to the mid-1980s and then stabilised, cf. Chart 1. Until the late 1970s the Danish bond market almost exclusively comprised mortgage-credit bonds. Subsequently, the issue of government securities increased significantly, and these two groups now dominate the bond market in Denmark, accounting for around 2/3 and 1/3, respectively, of the outstanding volume of bonds. The shift is mainly attributable to the considerable government deficits in the late 1970s and up until the mid-1980s, which entailed an equivalent central-government borrowing requirement. The circulating volume of government securities therefore increased significantly in this period. In 1989-97 the government balance was negative once again, resulting in growth in the volume of government securities. The circulating volume of mortgage-credit bonds has increased steadily since 1970. Among other things, this reflects a higher pledgeable value. In addition, amendments to mortgage-credit legislation have had a major impact on the issuance activity, cf. Box 1. Liberalisations have thus been a significant factor contributing to the households' increased borrowing from mortgage-credit institutes, to some extent at the cost of bank loans. In the latter half of the 1990s adjustable-rate loans were reintroduced in the Danish mortgage-credit market. Unlike traditional callable annuity loans, adjustable-rate loans are financed via uncallable bullet bonds 1 See Michael Møller and Niels Chr. Nielsen, 200 Years of Mortgage Credit in Denmark (in Danish), 1997. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 37 THE STRUCTURE OF THE DANISH BOND MARKET SINCE 1970 Box 1 1970: Mortgage-credit reform: The maximum term to maturity for mortgage-credit loans is reduced to 30 years, whereby 30-year fixed-rate callable annuity bonds become the dominant financing option1; one-tier mortgaging is introduced, entailing a higher degree of concentration among mortgage-credit institutes. 1975: The central government resumes the issue of fixed-rate serial-loan bonds.2 1976: The central government resumes the issue of fixed-rate Treasury notes (redeemed as bullet loans); in connection with special mortgage credit for new owner-occupied housing, mortgage-credit institutes may offer adjustable-rate loans financed via 1- to 5-year uncallable bonds amortised as bullet loans. 1980: Mortgage-credit reform: General option to raise cash loans (repealed in 1985), including adjustable-rate loans; the quota for mortgage-credit loans for residential properties is repealed. 1982: Financing of mortgage-credit loans via index-linked bonds is introduced (mainly uncallable bonds redeemed according to the serial-loan principle). 1983: The central government introduces fixed-rate bullet government-bond loans. 1984: The central government introduces variable-rate bullet government-bond loans (issuing ceases in 1990). 1986: Mixed loans a requirement in connection with e.g. change of ownership and construction of new owner-occupied housing (part of the Potato Package of Economic Measures). Loans are thus financed via a combination of callable annuity and serial-loan bonds. 1988: Serial-loan bonds are no longer included in the central government's on-therun issues. 1989: Mortgage-credit reform: Freedom to establish new mortgage-credit institutes. 1990: The central government introduces Treasury bills as zero-coupon bonds. 1992: Access to free mortgaging within 80 per cent of the value for owner-occupied housing via mixed loans with maturities of up to 30 years. 1993: 30-year annuity loans for owner-occupied housing are reintroduced. 1996: The mortgage-credit institutes reintroduce adjustable-rate loans, primarily financed via the issue of uncallable fixed-rate bullet bonds with maturities of 1 to 11 years (adjustable-rate bonds). 2003: Introduction of mortgage-credit loans with deferred amortisation for up to 10 years, financed via traditional fixed-rate callable bonds or adjustable-rate bonds. Note: For acts of Parliament, the year is the year of adoption, not the year of implementation. Source: Various editions of annual reports from the Association of Danish Mortgage Banks, the Mortgage-Credit Act, Danish Government Borrowing, Danish Government Borrowing and Debt, and Report and Accounts, Danmarks Nationalbank. 1 In the period analysed, uncallable annuity bonds constitute a limited percentage of the total Danish bond market. 2 Government securities (government bonds, Treasury notes and Treasury bills) are uncallable. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 38 Chart 1 DEVELOPMENT IN THE BOND MARKET Kr. billion 2,500 Per cent of GDP 180 2,250 160 2,000 140 1,750 120 1,500 100 1,250 80 1,000 60 750 40 500 20 250 0 0 1970 1973 1976 1979 Government securities 1982 1985 1988 Mortgage-credit bonds – other 1991 1994 Other bonds 1997 2000 2003 Mortgage credit – adjustable-rate loans The bond market as a percentage of GDP (right-hand axis) Note: Nominal values at the end of January, April, July and October (to avoid an impact from the refinancing activities in December). Index-linked bonds are stated at the indexed value. Government securities comprise government bonds, Treasury notes and Treasury bills. Government bonds denominated in foreign exchange have been excluded. ”Other bonds” comprise e.g. issues by special institutions, government-guaranteed entities and private enterprises. Data for adjustable-rate loans are available from January 1999 onwards. The observations for January and April 1994 illustrate a massive wave of conversions. Source: Statistics Denmark and Danmarks Nationalbank. 1 with short maturities, known as adjustable-rate bonds. At end-2003 the volume of adjustable-rate loans was kr. 498 billion, of which kr. 85 billion was denominated in euro, equivalent to around 1/3 of total mortgage-credit lending. The surge in the volume of adjustable-rate loans since 2000 is mainly attributable to an increasing positive spread between long-term and shortterm interest rates, which initially makes adjustable-rate loans cheap. In 2 addition, the economic situation is generally perceived to be stable. Since October 2003 mortgage-credit institutes have been able to offer loans with deferred amortisation for up to 10 years. Statistics from the Association of Danish Mortgage Banks show that deferred-amortisation loans constituted almost 57 per cent of gross lending for owner-occupied housing and summer cottages in the 4th quarter of 2003. Practically all 3 deferred-amortisation loans are financed via adjustable-rate bonds. 1 2 3 2000 saw the introduction of adjustable-rate loans as bond loans based on uncallable variable-rate annuity bonds with a typical maturity of 4-5 years. A general discussion of these topics can be found in Anders Møller Christensen and Kristian Kjeldsen, Adjustable-Rate Mortgages, Danmarks Nationalbank, Monetary Review, 2nd Quarter 2002. Record lending in 2003 – mortgage-credit lending exceeds half a trillion! (in Danish), the Association of Danish Mortgage Banks, press release, 27 January 2004. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 39 Owing to the new loan types, the proportion of adjustable-rate bonds in the Danish bond market is rising at the cost of conventional callable mortgage-credit bonds with long maturities. This means that the financial structure of the Danish real-property market now resembles that of the euro area to a higher degree than previously. In Europe the Danish mortgage-credit market is only exceeded by the German one in absolute volume terms. In GDP terms the Danish mortgage-credit market is among the largest in the world. The bond market by selected types The Danish bond market was previously dominated by callable annuity bonds, whereas the present circulating volume of government and mortgage-credit bonds primarily comprises callable annuity bonds and uncallable bullet loans, with an overweight of the latter, cf. Chart 2. From 1975 until the beginning of the 1980s most government bonds were issued as fixed-rate serial loans. In 1983 bullet government bonds were introduced. In the following years serial loans were phased out in favour of bullet loans, and from 1988 the former ceased to be part of the central government's on-the-run issues. Until the mid-1980s the Danish mortgage-credit market was dominated by fixed-rate annuity loans with long maturities. However, with the GOVERNMENT SECURITIES AND MORTGAGE-CREDIT BONDS BY SELECTED LOAN TYPES Chart 2 Kr. billion Per cent 2,500 100 2,250 90 2,000 80 1,750 70 1,500 60 1,250 50 1,000 40 750 30 500 20 250 10 0 0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 Annuity Bullet Percentage callable (right-hand axis) 1995 2000 Serial Index-linked – mortgage credit Note: Estimated nominal values at end-October. "Percentage callable" is estimated on the basis of loan types, excluding index-linked bonds. Index-linked bonds are stated at the indexed value. Government bonds denominated in foreign exchange have been excluded. Source: Copenhagen Stock Exchange, Nordea Analytics and Danmarks Nationalbank. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 40 Chart 3 DOMESTIC GOVERNMENT DEBT BY SECURITY TYPES Per cent 100 Kr. billion 800 90 750 80 700 70 650 60 600 50 550 40 500 30 450 20 400 10 350 300 0 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 Fixed-rate bullet government-bond loans 1996 1998 Serial loans Variable-rate bullet government-bond loans Treasury notes Treasury bills Other 2000 2002 Total domestic government debt (right-hand axis) Note: Nominal value at end-December. Foreign-exchange swaps in 2001-02 totalling kr. 21 billion have been excluded. "Other" comprises e.g. premium bonds. In 1984, 5- and 10-year variable-rate bullet government-bond loans with quarterly interest adjustment were introduced. Issues of these bonds ceased in 1990, and today all variable-rate government-bond loans have been redeemed. Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. Potato Package of Economic Measures in 1986 mixed loans became compulsory, leading to issues of serial loans in the mortgage-credit market. In 1993 it once again became possible for mortgage-credit institutes to provide loans solely based on annuity bonds. The ratio of callable to uncallable bonds has also changed since 1970. Owing to the issuance activity in government securities and, more recently, the emergence of adjustable-rate bonds, callable bonds as a percentage of the total market for government securities and mortgagecredit bonds has declined significantly in this period, cf. Chart 2. In Denmark, government bonds are issued in the 5- and 10-year maturity 1 segments, whereas Treasury notes are issued with a maturity of 2 years. These maturity segments are also the internationally most important 2 ones. These securities, along with Treasury bills , which are issued with maturities of up to 12 months, make up the central government's onthe-run issues. In line with the government borrowing structure in many 1 2 Since considerable government deficits were envisaged, the sale of Treasury notes was resumed in 1976. In 1990 zero-coupon Treasury bills were introduced (i.e. the yield is the difference between issue below par and redemption at par). 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 41 other countries, the Danish domestic central-government debt today practically only comprises fixed-rate bullet loans (government bonds and Treasury notes) and Treasury bills, cf. Chart 3. The government borrowing structure has thus gradually been simplified. By building up large liquid series the central government seeks to 1 achieve a liquidity premium and thus lower borrowing costs. The central-government borrowing strategy helps to make government securities attractive to both domestic and foreign investors. DEVELOPMENT IN THE TOTAL KRONE DURATION SINCE 1999 A major consideration for bond investors is the interest-rate risk of the bond portfolio. The interest-rate risk of a bond can be expressed as the 2 krone duration, cf. the Appendix. The value of the krone duration of an individual bond series depends on the characteristics of the bond, including term to maturity, coupon and amortisation, but also on the yield curve and the development in the volume of the series. For callable mortgage-credit bonds the borrower's right of conversion must also be taken into account. If the callable mortgage-credit bonds are traded at or above par, the krone duration is typically very low. The pattern of the total krone duration in the Danish bond market is affected by the structural change in the composition of the circulating volume of mortgage-credit bonds, i.e. a higher percentage of adjustable-rate bonds and a lower krone duration for the callable mortgagecredit bonds as a result of the course of interest rates, cf. Chart 4. In the period 1999-2003 the total krone duration fell from kr. 100 3 billion to kr. 83 billion. In mid-1999 the krone duration for callable mortgage-credit bonds accounted for just over half the total krone duration. Four years later this percentage had decreased to just over one third. Even though adjustable-rate bonds constituted almost a third of the circulating volume of mortgage-credit bonds in 2003, they only contributed 8 per cent of the total krone duration. Typically these bonds have a maturity of only 1 year and thus a relatively low krone duration. A large proportion of the krone duration for the callable mortgage4 credit bonds is related to 30-year issues within the last 10 years. The 1 2 3 4 For a more detailed description, see Danmarks Nationalbank, Danish Government Borrowing and Debt 2002, 2003. For a detailed review of bond risks etc. see Danmarks Nationalbank, Financial Management at Danmarks Nationalbank, 2004. The total krone duration at end-December 2003 was calculated at kr. 88 billion. This development is primarily attributable to an influx of 30-year mortgage-credit bonds with a coupon of 5 per cent maturing in 2035. During the past 10 years, 30-year callable mortgage-credit bonds have been issued with coupons of 5, 6, 7 or 8 per cent. Depending on the time of issue, these securities mature in 2026, 2029, 2032 or 2035. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 42 TOTAL KRONE DURATION BY BOND TYPES, AND THE 10-YEAR GOVERNMENT-BOND YIELD Chart 4 Kr. billion Per cent 100 7.0 90 6.5 80 6.0 70 5.5 60 5.0 50 4.5 40 4.0 30 3.5 20 3.0 10 2.5 0 2.0 1999 2000 Government securities 2001 2002 Other bonds Mortgage-credit bonds – callable 2003 Mortgage-credit bonds – adjustable-rate 10-year government-bond yield (right-hand axis) Note: The krone duration is stated at end-June. The 10-year government-bond yield is shown on a monthly basis. "Other bonds" comprise e.g. index-linked bonds issued by mortgage-credit institutes and issues from special institutions, government-guaranteed entities and private enterprises. The krone duration for index-linked bonds is stated on the basis of the indexed value. Source: Nordea Analytics, Danmarks Nationalbank and own calculations. krone duration for these issues has fallen by just over a third, from kr. 36 billion to kr. 23 billion, and most of the krone duration is now related to 30-year mortgage-credit bonds with a coupon of 5 per cent, cf. Chart 5. From mid-1999 to mid-2002 mortgage-credit bonds with a coupon of 6 per cent maturing in 2026 and 2029 contributed most of the total krone duration. In this period, the extensive waves of conversions – in the form 1 of bond purchases in the market – in these securities led to a significant reduction in the circulating volume of bonds. This development contributed to the decline in the krone duration for 30-year securities in this period. Throughout the period shown most 30-year mortgage-credit bonds with a coupon of 7 or 8 per cent were traded above par as interest rates declined (depending on coupon and maturity). This led to extraordinary redemptions. By mid-2003 this was also the case for 30-year bonds with a coupon of 6 per cent. As a result, the total krone duration has decreased. On the other hand, recent years' issuance of 5-per-cent bonds 1 Cf. Ulrik Knudsen, Conversions of 30-Year Mortgage-Credit Bonds During the Last 10 Years, Danmarks Nationalbank, Monetary Review, 2nd Quarter 2003. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 43 THE KRONE DURATION OF 30-YEAR MORTGAGE-CREDIT BONDS BY COUPON, AND THE 10-YEAR GOVERNMENT-BOND YIELD Chart 5 Kr. billion 40 Per cent 6.5 35 6.0 30 5.5 25 5.0 20 4.5 15 4.0 10 3.5 5 3.0 0 2.5 2.0 -5 1999 2000 2002 2001 2003 8 per cent 7 per cent 6 per cent 5 per cent 10-year government-bond yield (right-hand axis) Note: The krone duration is stated at end-June. The 10-year government-bond yield is shown on a monthly basis. A mortgage-credit model is used to determine the krone duration. Consequently the determination of the krone duration entails model uncertainty since the calculations are dependent on assumptions of e.g. the borrower's conversion behaviour. The value of the krone duration may therefore vary from model to model, depending on the model assumptions. Source: Nordea Analytics, Danmarks Nationalbank and own calculations. 1 maturing in 2035 has increased the krone duration. When a borrower converts high-yield callable loans into callable loans with a lower yield, this has a positive effect on the krone duration. However, if the new loans are adjustable-rate loans, the impact on the krone duration is limited. The total krone duration is sensitive to changes in interest rates. For example, an increase in the level of interest rates by 0.5-1.0 percentage points would mean that 30-year mortgage-credit bonds with a coupon of 6 per cent were traded below par, depending on their maturity. This would reduce the risk of conversion and thus increase the krone duration. 1 In the period shown the circulating volume of 30-year bonds increased by almost kr. 62 billion to kr. 627 billion. This increase comprised a reduction by kr. 128 billion in 30-year mortgage-credit bonds with a coupon of 6 per cent or more. On the other hand, the volume of 30-year bonds with a coupon of 5 per cent increased by kr. 190 billion, including growth of kr. 166 billion in bonds with a coupon of 5 per cent maturing in 2035 since the autumn of 2002. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 44 APPENDIX Bond-market concepts Amortisation: Annuity loan: Constant payments at regular intervals (higher instalments and lower interest payments over time). Serial loan: Constant instalments at regular intervals (lower payments over time). Bullet loan: Only interest is paid during the term of the loan - the principal falls due on the maturity date. Mixed loans: Typically 60 per cent annuity loan and 40 per cent serial loan. Callable: A loan is callable when it can be redeemed prematurely at par, in addition to purchases in the market of the callable bonds on which the mortgage-credit loan is based. Uncallable: A loan is uncallable when it can only be redeemed prematurely by purchasing the bonds on which the mortgage-credit loan is based. Bond loan: The borrower's principal is equal to the nominal value of the bonds on which the loan is based. The borrower's proceeds thus depend on the market value of the bonds at issue. Cash loan: The borrower's principal is equal to the market value of the bonds issued. The capital loss to the mortgage-credit institute when selling the bonds is included in the cash-loan interest and is thus taxdeductible for private borrowers. In connection with premature redemption the borrower is tax liable for any capital gain. Interest: Fixed-rate loan: The rate of interest is unchanged throughout the term of the loan. Adjustable-rate loan: Current adaptation of the rate of interest at fixed intervals. Refinancing: The outstanding debt is fully or partially replaced by sale of new bonds. Index-linked loan: The principal and the outstanding debt, and thus the payments, are regularly adjusted in accordance with the development in an agreed price index. Granted as a cash loan. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 45 Nominal loan: Generic term for loans that are not index-linked. This is by far the most common – and the traditional – type of loan. Krone duration: Expresses how much the market value of a bond holding marginally changes in kroner at a 1-percentage-point change in the yield curve. 24-03-2004 08:46 Antal sider: 11 folder\tiltryk\Udviklingstendenser Rev. nr. 46 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 på obligationsmarked_32_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af msd det danske 47 The US Current-Account Deficit and the Dollar Niels C. Beier, Economics The US current-account deficit is around 5 per cent of GDP and has been increasing, cf. Chart 1. A deficit of that size usually triggers a weakening of the currency and lower growth. The USA is an economic superpower and lower US growth as well as a weaker dollar will automatically have global effects – especially if the dollar falls abruptly, creating turbulence in the global financial markets. Against this background the US currentaccount deficit has been subject to numerous analyses (e.g. Bergsten and Williamson, 2003; BIS, 2003; Greenspan, 2003; Mann, 1999, 2002; Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000). This article provides a general overview of the developments in the US current account and the dollar in recent years. First, the pattern from the mid-1990s until today is outlined in the light of the macroeconomic development. The underlying capital flows are then analysed and finally, an account is given of the future sustainability of the deficit and possible adjustments. Chart 1 THE US CURRENT ACCOUNT 1995-2003 Per cent of GDP 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Current account as a percentage of GDP Note: The 2003 figure represents the OECD autumn 2003 estimate. Source: OECD, Economic Outlook 74. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 48 Some of the article's conclusions are: the increasing current-account deficit during the second half of the 1990s was driven by private-sector investments and savings in response to the "new economy". The deficit in 2001-03 was generated by the public sector's savings deficit and by the households' continued low propensity to save. It reflects the expansionary economic policy following the reversal of the stock prices and the economy in 2000-01. The present combination of a budget deficit and the households' low propensity to save makes the current-account deficit less sustainable than previously, and the weakening of the dollar since 2002 should be seen in that light. THE CURRENT ACCOUNT, THE DOLLAR AND THE MACROECONOMY The current account A current-account deficit is not bad by definition or necessarily undesirable. On the contrary, the deficit may reflect a country's borrowing abroad to finance productive investments for the benefit of future out1 put. The US current-account deficit in the second half of the 1990s can be interpreted as a deficit of this type. The US economy was affected by a favourable productivity shock (the "new economy"), which inter alia resulted in increased investments in order to benefit from new technology. The result was a number of golden years of high growth in output, 2 investments and consumption as well as rapidly rising stock prices. In 2000 the economy started to slow down, and stock prices declined sharply. Since then the private sector – seen as a whole – has consolidated while economic policy has been expansionary in order to support the economy. The monetary-policy interest rate was lowered from 6.5 per cent in 2001 to 1 per cent in 2003. Fiscal policy has been eased considerably through tax cuts adopted in both 2001 and 2003. As a result, the federal budget surplus of approximately 2½ per cent of GDP in 2000 3 has been transformed to a deficit of 3½ per cent in 2003. The counterpart of the current-account deficit has thus shifted from a private to a public savings deficit. This is illustrated in Chart 2 which shows the current-account deficit's counterparts on the private and public savings balances. It also appears that the present situation is somewhat reminiscent of the 1980s when the situation with concurrent external and government deficits was termed the Twin Deficits. 1 2 3 See Pedersen (2003) for a general introduction to the balance of payments and the specific development in Denmark. See also Sørensen (1999) as well as IMF (2002) and Vastrup (1999) for different views on the importance of the balance of payments as a policy objective. The rapidly rising stock prices and the high investment level indicate that the latter part of the period may have been characterised by overoptimistic expectations of the economy and overinvestment, cf. the subsequent falls in stock prices and low capacity utilisation. The figures refer to the fiscal years of 2000 and 2003, cf. the Congressional Budget Office. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 49 Chart 2 US FINANCIAL BALANCES 1980-2003 Per cent of GDP 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 1980 1982 1984 1986 Public svaings balance 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Private savings balance Current account as a percentage of GDP Note: The public savings balance comprises the federal savings balance as well as local authorities' savings balance. The observations for 2003 represent the OECD autumn 2003 estimate. Source: OECD, Economic Outlook 74. The term twin deficits is, however, a simplification of the present situation, as the overall consolidation of the private sector conceals sectoral differences. The business enterprises have improved their savings balance the most, while the households' savings are still at a low level. The ratio of households' savings to disposable income is by and large unchanged compared to 1999. The difference between the behaviour of business enterprises and households was obvious in the two relatively slack years of 2001 and 2002 when private investments declined while private consumption increased, strongly stimulated by the falling interest rates and the considerable personal-tax cuts. The dollar The dollar strengthened in step with the favourable economic development at the end of the 1990s, cf. Chart 3 which shows the real effective exchange rate. The dollar has weakened since the beginning of 2002, but has not yet reached the level of the mid-1990s. The question is: why has the dollar run this course? Exchange rates are notoriously difficult to explain and predict and generally show significant and protracted fluctuations (e.g. Dornbusch, 1976; Meese and Rogoff, 1983; Rogoff, 1996). The exchange rate is determined by the expected future return in different currencies, typically with the expected real-economic development and interest-rate differ- 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 50 CURRENT ACCOUNTBALANCE OF PAYMENTS AND REAL DOLLAR RATE Per cent of GDP 1 Chart 3 Index, January 1980 = 100 150 0 140 -1 130 -2 120 -3 110 -4 100 -5 90 -6 1980 80 1985 Current account 1990 1995 Real effective dollar rate (right-hand axis) 2000 Note: The real effective dollar rate is the Federal Reserve's broad measure of the real effective exchange rate, i.e. a trade-weighted average of a large number of bilateral exchange rates adjusted for differences in national price developments. The latest observation for the real dollar rate is January 2004. Source: EcoWin and OECD, Economic Outlook 74. entials as the dominating factors. However, any exchange-rate development can be interpreted in different ways (Bacchetta and Wincoop, 2004). One possible view of the dollar's pattern since the mid-1990s uses the macroeconomic developments during the period as its pivotal point. Considering the positive economic growth and the "new economy", the strengthening of the dollar was foreseeable. The favourable investment opportunities in the USA naturally required foreign capital, the dollar strengthened and the balance of payments deteriorated. The strengthening of the dollar occurred in two stages, from 1996 to the 1 beginning of 1998 and then again in the period 2000-01, cf. Chart 3. In that light, the weakening of the dollar from the beginning of 2002 until today may be related to the favourable investment opportunities being exhausted and to concerns as to the sustainability of the currentaccount deficit. The shift from a private savings deficit with a high level of investments to a public savings deficit, which can be attributed partly to increased security and defence financing as well as tax cuts ceteris paribus makes the present deficit less sustainable. 1 Thus, the dollar also strengthened in 2001 when the economy was in recession, investments and stock prices fell and the Federal Reserve lowered the interest rate drastically during the year. The development in 2001 only illustrates the point that exchange rates are not always in accordance with all explanatory elements at the same time, and that the precise timing of exchange-rate changes is extremely difficult to predict. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 51 Chart 4 CAPITAL INFLOWS TO THE USA 1997-2003 Billion dollars 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 -100 1997 Total 1998 1999 Public 2000 2001 2002 2003 Private Note: Total of four quarters. Net capital inflows. The latest observation is the 3rd quarter of 2003. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis and US Treasury. FINANCING OF THE CURRENT ACCOUNT AND THE DOLLAR The increasing current-account deficit from the mid-1990s has extensively been financed by higher private capital inflows. Recently the inflow of private capital has stagnated, however, whereas public capital 1 inflows have risen, cf. Chart 4. This is due to foreign central banks' interventions to prevent their currencies from strengthening vis-à-vis the dollar. Federal Reserve (2003) substantiates this by pointing out that in 2002 public capital inflows were largest in the 2nd and 4th quarters exactly when the pressure on the dollar was most intense. A closer look at the private capital flows reveals divergence at the start of the 2000s compared to the second half of the 1990s. First and foremost, the composition of private capital inflows has changed. From 1997 to 2000 there was a large influx of private funds to Corporate America, i.e. stocks, corporate bonds and direct investments, but from 2000-01 the relative significance of these assets has declined. For example, foreign direct investments in the USA decreased by more than 200 billion dollars from the 1st quarter of 2001 to the 3rd quarter 2 of 2003. The private capital inflows can now to a larger extent be attributed to private investors' purchases of US government bonds. 1 2 The public capital flows include primarily foreign central banks' purchases and sales of US assets – typically government bonds. Sum of four quarters. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 52 DISTRIBUTION BY COUNTRY OF PRIVATE CAPITAL INFLOWS TO THE USA Chart 5 Billion dollars 500 400 300 200 100 0 -100 1997 Euro area 1998 1999 UK 2000 Japan 2001 2002 2003 Other Note: The Chart illustrates inflows of direct investments and portfolio investments. Net capital inflows. Sum of four quarters. The latest observation is the 3rd quarter of 2003. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis and US Treasury. Secondly, the flat course of total private capital inflows in the period 1 2001-03 reflects diverging individual developments. Foreign purchases of US securities and direct investments in the USA have fallen, but this has been offset by a decrease in US purchases of foreign securities and direct investments in other countries. Finally, the composition of countries has changed, cf. Chart 5. In the period 1997-2000 the euro area accounted for a significant part of the USA's private capital imports, but in recent years, the private sources of finance have come from especially the UK and Japan while private net capital flows from the euro area to the USA have ceased. Overall, it may be concluded that in the second half of the 1990s the deteriorating current-account deficit was increasingly financed by acquisitions of US business enterprises, corporate bonds or stocks, whereas the present deficit is to a larger extent financed by foreign purchases of government securities – especially purchases by Asian central banks. The current account and the dollar: a financing view Foreign investors' willingness to finance the US current-account deficit plays an important role in terms of the dollar rate and the size of the current-account deficit. If foreign investors do not wish to acquire US 1 Or more precisely net purchases – the difference between purchases and sales. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 53 GLOBAL FOREIGN-EXCHANGE RESERVES DISTRIBUTED BY COUNTRY AND REGION Chart 6 Billion SDR 1,800 1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 1997 North America 1998 1999 Europe 2000 Japan 2001 Non-Japan Asia 2002 Rest Note: The reserves are compiled in SDR (Special Drawing Rights) and are exclusive of gold. Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics. securities and other US assets at a given exchange rate, the dollar rate will recede and a weaker dollar will – ceteris paribus – improve the 1 current account and vice versa. During the boom in the second half of the 1990s demand for US business enterprises, stocks and corporate bonds among private investors was substantial. The dollar strengthened. The pattern from the peak of the boom until now shows that foreign private investors' demand for US assets has declined. One possible explanation is that private investors have become concerned about the sustainability of the current-account deficit in the light of the concurrent government deficit. A reversal of a current-account deficit will typically involve a weakening of the currency, cf. below, which will – ceteris paribus – make it less attractive for foreigners to invest in the USA since the value of the investments decreases in the investors' currency. The dollar has weakened concurrently with the decline in private foreign capital flows. The dollar's general tendency to weaken has caused a number of Asian countries to intervene in the foreign-exchange markets to prevent their currencies from strengthening vis-à-vis the dollar. This applies not only to China that actively pursues a fixed-exchange-rate policy against the USA, but also to other countries with more flexible exchange-rate 1 The current account is improved via enhanced competiveness as a result of the weakening of the dollar. The improvement typically occurs with a certain lag (J-curve). 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 54 THE COUNTERPARTS OF THE US CURRENT-ACCOUNT DEFICIT Box 1 In theory, the global current account sum is zero, i.e. the US deficit is offset by other countries' surpluses. However, in practice a significant global deviation exists, as the sum of deficits exceeds the sum of surpluses. In 2001 the deviation was around 150 billion dollars. This deviation can be attributed to several factors (see IMF, 2002), probably including the fact that the tax systems give an incentive to capture all allowances in income. The global deviation generates uncertainty as to the actual size of the US current-account deficit which is nevertheless large. The Chart illustrates the US current account and some of its important counterparts, including the global deviation. As can be seen, the Japanese and euro area surpluses more than offset the US deficit in the mid-1990s. The Japanese and European surpluses have been fairly stable thus the present large US deficit is offset by other countries' increased surpluses. The Chart shows that Emerging Asia has seen a growing surplus from 1996 to 2002 and is increasingly a counterpart of the US deficit. The largest country in the category Emerging Asia is China which overall has a small current-account surplus. On the other hand, China has a large surplus if trade with the USA is viewed in isolation. CURRENT ACCOUNTS FOR SELECTED REGIONS AND COUNTRIES, 1980-2002 Billion dollars 200 100 0 -100 -200 -300 -400 -500 -600 1980 1982 USA 1984 1986 Euro area 1988 Japan 1990 1992 1994 Emerging Asia 1996 1998 2000 2002 Global deviation Note: In the Chart Emerging Asia comprises the Philippines, India, Indonesia, China, Malaysia, Singapore, South Korea and Thailand. The global deviation is (minus) the global balance of payments as stated by the IMF. The latest observation for the global deviation is 2001. Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics and OECD, Economic Outlook 72 and 74. regimes. Japan intervened strongly in 2002 and 2003. The Asian interventions can be illustrated by the significant increases in the countries' 1 foreign-exchange reserves in recent years, cf. Chart 6. The countries typically have a trade surplus vis-à-vis the USA and overall they have a current-account surplus, cf. Box 1. 1 IMF (2003) argues that several Asian countries have built up larger reserves than warranted by the economic fundamentals. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 55 Chart 7 DOLLAR RATES, SELECTED COUNTRIES Index, January 2002 = 100 105 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65 Jan 2002 Apr Jul Oct Effective dollar rate Jan 2003 Japan Apr Jul Oct Euro area UK Apr Oct Jan 2004 Index, January 2002 = 100 105 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65 Jan 2002 Apr Jul Oct Effective dollar rate Jan 2003 Canada China Jul Jan 2004 South Korea Index, January 2002 = 100 105 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65 Jan 2002 Apr Jul Oct Effective dollar rate Jan 2003 Thailand Apr Taiwan Jul Oct Jan 2004 Hong Kong Note: Nominal exchange rates. The effective dollar rate is the nominal effective dollar rate. A decline in the Chart reflects a weakening of the dollar. The latest observation is January 2004. Source: EcoWin. In general the extent and duration of the effects of interventions in the foreign-exchange markets are an open question. However, overall the Asian currencies have indeed strengthened less than the flexible currencies, e.g. the euro, the pound sterling and the Canadian dollar, vis-à-vis the dollar, cf. Chart 7. The strengthening of the pound sterling, the Canadian dollar and the Japanese yen has been on the same scale, while the euro has accounted for the most significant strengthening. Table 1 indicates different countries' weights in the trade-weighted effective exchange rate of the dollar. The total weight of the Asian currencies is not insignificant. A change in the countries' foreign-exchange policies may thus impact considerably on the effective dollar rate. THE CURRENT ACCOUNT AND THE DOLLAR IN FUTURE History shows that on average countries with an external deficit of 4-5 per cent of GDP have their current accounts restored (BIS, 2003; Freund, 2000; IMF, 2002). However, some countries have a larger deficit prior to the adjustment, and naturally the "threshold value" for the USA is unknown. In any case the current-account deficit means that the US net 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 56 WEIGHTS IN THE EFFECTIVE DOLLAR RATE IN 2004 Country Table 1 Weight (per cent) Euro area .................................................................. Canada ..................................................................... Japan ........................................................................ Mexico ...................................................................... China ........................................................................ UK.............................................................................. South Korea ............................................................. Taiwan ...................................................................... Malaysia ................................................................... Singapore ................................................................. Hong Kong ............................................................... Brazil ......................................................................... Thailand ................................................................... Switzerland .............................................................. Australia ................................................................... 19 17 11 11 10 5 4 3 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 Note: The weights are rounded. Only the 15 countries and regions with the largest weights have been included. Source: Federal Reserve. external debt increases, cf. Chart 8. An increasing proportion of the US output must thus be "handed over" to abroad by way of interest and dividend. Due to the low level of interest rates this consequence has not been clearly felt until now, but the debt cannot rise infinitely. On the other hand, the USA enjoys special status due to its size and the dollar's role as a global reserve currency. Considering the role of the dollar there will always be demand for US securities among countries and investors. Another reason is that the US financial markets and the US economy are the largest in the world and a diversified portfolio should – ceteris paribus – include an appropriate amount of US assets. Furthermore, non-residents have historically achieved lower returns on their investments in the USA than residents have achieved on investments abroad. This appears from the fact that even though the USA's net international investment position had been negative for some time, it was not until 2002 that the USA's receipts of interest and dividend were lower than its payments of interest and dividend. Also, a large part of the US debt is issued in dollars (Mann, 2002), whereby a weakening of the dollar entails a capital loss for foreign investors, not the other way round. All these factors imply a higher "threshold value" and better sustainability of a given deficit. The present deficit has become less sustainable as it reflects a low savings level rather than a high investment level. Contrary to low savings increased investments imply higher output in the future and thus more future resources to service the debt – i.e. better sustainability of a given deficit. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 57 Chart 8 THE USA's NET FOREIGN ASSETS 1980-2002 Per cent of GDP 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 -20 -25 -30 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Net assets as a percentage of GDP Note: Net international investment position. Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics and OECD, Economic Outlook 74. How will an adjustment take place? According to history (BIS, 2003; Freund, 2000; IMF, 2002) a currentaccount deficit is adjusted via two channels: a weakening of the cur1 rency and lower economic growth. If the dollar's decline in the last few years is interpreted as the beginning of an adjustment of the US currentaccount deficit, it is remarkable that in the same period the USA has seen and is still seeing strong growth compared to e.g. the euro area and Japan. This should be viewed in the context of the expansionary economic policy that has buoyed up the economy. An adjustment of the US current-account deficit via lower future growth in the USA is plausible as both the public sector and the households need to increase their savings. Primarily, consolidation of public finances seems to be necessary in the medium term, i.e. tighter fiscal policy in the future. Significant government deficits and indebtedness 2 are envisaged during the next decade , if the fiscal policy adopted thus far is implemented without changes. Like many other countries the USA is also faced with increasing pressure on the expenditure side in the coming years as the large post-war generations retire from the labour 1 2 Freund's (2000) analysis shows that lower growth and a weakening of the currency typically occur over a period of 3-4 years around the time the current-account deficit reaches its peak. The Congressional Budget Office's most recent estimate up to 2014 for the federal finances dates from January 2004 and is available at www.cbo.gov. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 58 1 market. The households' savings ratio has reached a historical low and 2 indebtedness has shown an increasing trend. The boost in consumption in the second half of the 1990s can be attributed to expectations of future income increases and wealth gains in relation to the "new economy", whereas in recent years consumption has to a large extent been stimulated by economic policy, especially fiscal policy. The households cannot accumulate debt infinitely either. In addition, asymmetrical trade elasticity between the USA and the rest of the world means that relative growth in the USA must decline if the current-account deficit is to be reversed. Empirical studies (cf. Mann, 1999) show that following a 1-per-cent increase in income both in the USA and the rest of the world the US current account will – ceteris paribus – deteriorate. US imports will increase more rapidly than imports in the rest of the world. This asymmetry is not explained in full but supports the view that an adjustment will imply lower relative US growth. Chart 9 illustrates that exports must grow significantly more than imports in order to close the gap between the two series. A weakening of the dollar alone is probably not enough. What does an adjustment entail for the rest of the world? Basically an adjustment of the US deficit is desirable if the deficit is unsustainable. A significant uncertainty is whether the adjustment is gradual or abrupt. An abrupt adjustment, e.g. through a sudden and very strong weakening of the dollar, may lead to turbulence in the global financial markets. This turbulence may spread to the rest of the world economy, and this is one of the reasons for the strong focus on the US current account. Finally, there may be a tendency for the financial markets to overreact, so that a dollar movement becomes unnecessarily strong and distorts the adjustment. The dollar has declined significantly since its peak at the start of 2002, but the weakening has not led to turbulence, as it has been gradual. This was also the case for the weakening of the dollar in the 1980s, cf. Chart 3. Even if a weakening of the dollar is gradual it will still have an effect. In the countries with strengthened currencies the competitiveness of the business enterprises will deteriorate, but the countries will at the same time experience improved terms of trade, contributing to higher real incomes. In global economic models the net effect on GDP growth is 1 2 For an overview of the problems of the US public finances reference is made to the contributions in Mühleisen and Towe (2004) and the references therein. The question is, of course, what is the "equilibrium savings ratio"? In general, the savings ratio has been declining in the USA since the mid-1980s. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 59 Chart 9 US EXPORTS AND IMPORTS 1990-2002 Billion dollars 1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 1990 1991 1992 Export 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Imports Note: Goods and services. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. typically negative. On the other hand, US goods become cheaper abroad – US competitiveness improves – and this will have a positive impact on the current account in the USA. If an adjustment takes place via lower growth in the US economy, global growth can only be maintained if activity increases in other areas. The adjustment of the US deficit in the 1980s occurred at a time of strong demand in Japan and Germany. In the present situation growth in these two countries has been low for a number of years – although Japan saw positive trends in 2003. Thus, reforms to stimulate private demand in the two countries are called for – not only from a domestic perspective but also from a global perspective in relation to an adjustment of the USA's external deficit. Another aspect is the distribution of the weakening of the dollar. Thus far it has been most significant vis-à-vis the euro. If the dollar continues to weaken and the Asian countries continue to intervene the flexible currencies will carry the largest "burden". In this connection it should be borne in mind that the flexible currencies only carry the burden now because they reaped the "gain" during the period when the dollar strengthened. In that period the countries that followed the dollar most closely carried the burden. The problem seems to arise precisely because domestic demand in e.g. the euro area is as low as it is. In addition, several studies indicate that the euro is presently close to its equilibrium exchange rate (see ECB, 2002 for an overview). 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 60 CONCLUSION The present current-account deficit in the USA reflects low savings, and it is doubtful whether the deficit is sustainable. Consolidation is required both in the public sector and in the households. The gradual weakening of the dollar in recent years that has coincided with decreasing private foreign capital inflows to the USA can be seen as the start of an adjustment. Viewed in isolation, a declining dollar will improve the US current account but in a more forward-looking perspective, lower US growth for a while seems to be a precondition for reversing the deficit. In that light the question is whether it would have been more expedient to adjust demand in the USA at an earlier stage but to a lesser extent. It has been argued that the Federal Reserve ought to have reacted 1 earlier based on the soaring stock prices (e.g. Cecchetti, 2002) that contributed to the imbalances. The Federal Reserve rejects the criticism (Greenspan, 2004) and finds that no other response to the stock-price development was possible based on two arguments. It was impossible to determine firstly whether the stock-price rises were unfounded (bubble), and secondly the required increase in interest rates should have been excessively large and would have harmed the economy more than the result of declining stock prices at a later stage. The Federal Reserve finds that the major problem in relation to the current-account situation is that – combined with weak employment growth – it gives rise to opposition against free trade due to short-term considerations to protect US jobs (Greenspan, 2003). 1 The problem can also be seen as a question of how monetary policy should respond to a productivity shock. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 61 LITERATURE Bacchetta, Philippe and Eric van Wincoop, 2004. A Scapegoat Model of Exchange Rate Fluctuations. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 10245. Bergsten, C. Fred and John Williamson (editors), 2003. Dollar Overvaluation and the World Economy. Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics. BIS, 2003. 73rd Annual Report. Cecchetti, Stephen G., 2002. Central Bankers and Asset Price Misalignments. Financial Times, 9 May. Dornbusch, Rudiger, 1976. Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84, pp.1161-1176. ECB, 2002. Economic Fundamentals and the Exchange Rate of the Euro. Monthly Bulletin, January, pp. 41-54. Federal Reserve, 2003. U.S. International Transactions in 2002. Federal Reserve Bulletin, May, pp. 191-203. Freund, Caroline L., 2000. Current Account Adjustments in Industrialized Countries. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers, Number 692. Greenspan, Alan, 2003. Current Account. Speech at the 21st Annual Monetary Conference, Washington D.C., 20 November. Greenspan, Alan, 2004. Risks and Uncertainty in Monetary Policy. Speech at the American Economic Association's meeting on 3 January, San Diego. IMF, 2002. Essays on Trade and Finance. World Economic Outlook. Chapter II, September. IMF, 2003. Three Current Policy Issues in Developing Countries. World Economic Outlook. Chapter II, September. Mann, Catherine L., 1999. Is the U.S. Trade Deficit Sustainable? Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 62 Mann, Catherine L., 2002. Perspectives on the U.S. Current Account Deficit and Sustainability. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 16 Number 3, pp. 131-152. Meese, Richard A. and Kenneth Rogoff, 1983. Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Seventies: Do They Fit Out of Sample? Journal of International Economics 14, pp. 3-24. Mühleisen, Martin and Christopher Towe (editors), 2004. U.S. Fiscal Policies and Priorities for Long-Run Sustainability. IMF, Occasional Paper 227. Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2000. Perspectives on OECD Economic Integration: Implications for U.S. Current Account Adjustment. In Global Economic Integration: Opportunities and Challenges. A Symposium Sponsored by The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Pedersen, Erik H., 2003. The Balance of Payments – from Sustained Deficit to Sound Surplus. Danmarks Nationalbank, Monetary Review, 2nd Quarter, pp. 25-44. Rogoff, Kenneth S., 1996. The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature 34, pp. 647-688. Sørensen, Peter B., 1999. The Current-Account Target – a Commentary, (in Danish) Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift 137, pp. 360-387. Vastrup, Claus, 1999. Does the Current Account Present a Problem? (in Danish). Published in Lotte Langhoff-Roos (editor), Socialøkonomisk Debat Gennem 25 År. Jurist- og Økonomforbundets Forlag. 26-03-2004 10:56 Antal sider: 16 Rev. nr. 10 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\USAs betalingsbalanceunderskud og dollaren_en1_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Niels C. Beier - 6587 63 Quarterly Financial Accounts for Denmark Jan Overgaard Olesen and Jens Jakob Svanholt, Statistics INTRODUCTION In recent years Danmarks Nationalbank has extended its financial statistics for Denmark, inter alia on the basis of statistical requirements from the European Central Bank, ECB. In April 2004 Danmarks Nationalbank will therefore publish its first quarterly financial accounts for Denmark, and subsequently these statistics will be published regularly with a time lag of 15 weeks. Financial accounts include a financial balance sheet and a statement of the financial flows for all main sectors of the economy. They are not statistics in the traditional sense, but derived statistics generated by processing and compiling existing primary sources. Quarterly financial accounts have not previously been published for Denmark, but Statistics Denmark has compiled annual financial accounts since 2001. The purpose of Danmarks Nationalbank's statistics is to illustrate the development in financial wealth on a quarterly basis with the shortest possible time lag. From the outset, the statistics will include information on the financial balance sheets, while financial flows are expected to be incorporated during 2005. Quarterly financial accounts are well-known in other countries. The statistics derive from the USA, where quarterly financial accounts have 1 been prepared according to the "Flow-of-Funds" principle since 1959. Quarterly financial accounts are also published in e.g. the UK, Norway and Sweden, with the two latter countries focusing primarily on household information. This article initially describes the background to the compilation of financial accounts and provides an overview of the contents of the statistics. Subsequently a preliminary extract of the quarterly financial accounts for Denmark is presented in the form of the financial balance sheets for households and non-financial corporations. Finally, some of the possible applications are outlined, based on e.g. the ECB's use of financial accounts. 1 Financial accounts prepared according to the "Flow-of-Funds" principle include information on the counterparties to all financial transactions. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 64 BACKGROUND With the establishment of Economic and Monetary Union, significant extension of the financial statistics was initiated at the European level, inter alia with a view to improving the basis for planning the single 1 monetary policy. Among the new statistics are quarterly financial accounts for the euro area (Monetary Union Financial Accounts, or MUFA), which have been compiled and published by the ECB since May 2001. The statistics currently cover the most important financial assets and liabilities for selected main sectors. In the longer term the ECB intends to extend the statistics to a full set of financial accounts. MUFA are published in a separate press release 4½ months after the end of a quarter and are regularly included in the description of monetary and financial 2 development in the euro area. The statistics are compiled on the basis of available primary statistics for the euro area (e.g. the ECB's balancesheet and flow statistics for monetary financial institutions), as well as supplementary national information reported to the ECB by the individual member states on a quarterly basis. The latter comprises e.g. information on the households' pension savings and selected sectors' 3 securities holdings. The project to compile quarterly financial accounts for Denmark is based on the ECB's initiatives for the euro area member states since it is Danmarks Nationalbank's objective that the Danish financial statistics should be in line with international requirements and standards. Quarterly financial accounts also have a number of applications which make the statistics interesting in an economic-policy context, cf. the section on applications. Financial accounts for Denmark are the joint responsibility of Danmarks Nationalbank and Statistics Denmark. Basically, Statistics Denmark is responsible for preparing annual financial accounts, while Danmarks 4 Nationalbank is responsible for the quarterly financial accounts. In specific subareas this pattern is, however, deviated from if practical considerations such as data availability justify it. This is the case for general government (where Statistics Denmark also prepares the quarterly 1 2 3 4 Cf. ECB (2000), which outlines the ECB's present and planned future requirements of statistical coverage. MUFA are published as Financing and Financial Investment in the Euro Area, and are also included in the statistics appendix in the ECB's Monthly Bulletin. For an introduction to the statistics, see ECB (2001). The ECB's need for supplementary national information was formalised in 2002, cf. the Guideline of the European Central Bank of 21 November 2002 on the statistical reporting requirements of the European Central Bank in the field of quarterly financial accounts (ECB/2002/7). The distribution of responsibilities between Danmarks Nationalbank and Statistics Denmark reflects the international distribution where the ECB compiles quarterly financial accounts for the euro area, while Eurostat (the Statistical Office of the European Communities) is responsible for the annual financial accounts. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 65 accounts). In the same way, Danmarks Nationalbank is responsible for compiling information for the annual financial accounts for the rest of the world, which are then processed and published by Statistics Denmark. Since 2001, Statistics Denmark has published annual financial ac1 counts with a time lag of 13 months. With Danmarks Nationalbank's releases from April, quarterly financial accounts will also be available in future, albeit only for the financial balance sheets in the first instance. The two sets of statistics basically serve different purposes in that the primary purpose of the annual accounts is to provide a relatively detailed picture of the financial structures in the economy, while the quarterly accounts are short-term statistics to illustrate the development in the financial conditions with the shortest possible time lag. The quarterly accounts can thus be used for ongoing analyses of e.g. economic prospects and issues relating to financial stability, cf. the application section. There will be numerical discrepancies between the quarterly and annual statistics, partly as a result of the use of different primary statistics or calculation methods. Furthermore, the frequency of revision varies. Revisions of the primary statistics are incorporated in the quarterly financial accounts on a quarterly basis, but in the annual accounts on an annual basis. For this reason alone the two sets of figures can be expected to differ. It is not possible to say which statistics generally give the truest picture. The differences can thus been seen as an expression of the uncertainty associated with compiling financial accounts on the basis of incomplete statistical coverage. Statistics Denmark and Danmarks Nationalbank are working together to ensure that the need for and possibilities of harmonising the statistics are considered on an ongoing basis. CONTENTS OF FINANCIAL ACCOUNTS Financial accounts are part of the national accounts and comply with the guidelines of the European System of National Accounts (ESA 1995). The statistics are compiled for a number of different sectors that together cover the whole economy, including households and non-financial cor2 porations . For each sector, the financial accounts include a financial balance sheet showing the holdings of financial assets and liabilities. As a main 1 2 Cf. Statistics Denmark (2001) for the first release. Statistics Denmark has published quarterly financial accounts for general government since 2002, cf. Statistics Denmark (2002a). The statistics from Statistics Denmark include both financial balance sheets and financial flows. Non-financial corporations comprise e.g. manufacturing and service enterprises. The sectors are described in Appendix 1. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 66 rule, all holdings are stated at market value. In corporate accounts, assets and liabilities balance. However, this is not the case for financial accounts since they only include information on the financial part of 1 the balance sheet. The value of non-financial assets such as housing, vehicles and the enterprises' capital stock is thus omitted by definition. The difference between the holdings of financial assets and liabilities indicates the sector's net financial assets, which are included as part of 2 the sector's total net worth. In addition to the financial balance sheets, the financial accounts include statements of financial flows comprising transactions and other changes (including revaluations). The information on the financial flows illustrates the degree to which changes in the balance sheet are attributable to e.g. trading in a financial asset (a transaction) or changes in the price of an asset (revaluation). The flows will not initially be included in the quarterly financial accounts for Denmark published by Danmarks Nationalbank, but are expected to be added within the next year. The financial assets and liabilities are split into a number of main instrument groups: • Monetary gold and special drawing rights • Currency and deposits • Securities other than shares • Loans • Shares and other equity • Insurance technical reserves • Other accounts receivable/payable The financial instruments are classified according to type or characteristics. This makes it possible to identify each sector's financial risk or exposure to e.g. the stock or bond market. The above groups are subdivided, e.g. by degree of liquidity. This can be relevant in connection 3 with monetary analysis. For compilation of quarterly financial accounts a wide range of primary statistics are used, comprising both direct and indirect sources. The direct sources are used for compiling financial accounts for a specific sector and include e.g. Danmarks Nationalbank's International Investment Position (IIP) statistics, statistics on the balance sheets and flows of the MFI sector, and Statistics Denmark's quarterly financial accounts for general government. The indirect sources provide supplementary in1 2 3 In addition, valuation at market value may affect the ratio of assets to liabilities. For instance, the market value of issued shares and other equity is included instead of the book value of equity on the liabilities side. Cf. also the description of the households' and non-financial corporations' net worth below. Appendix 2 includes a review of the instruments, including the subinstruments. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 67 formation about the sectors for which no direct sources are available, or where the direct sources are not exhaustive. Examples of indirect sources are Danmarks Nationalbank's securities statistics (illustrating issues and holdings of securities across sectors) and counterpart information from 1 the direct sources. In addition, calculations or estimations are performed in the areas where no primary statistics are available or where the coverage is incomplete. This is the case if a source is only available on an annual basis (e.g. annual accounts). A more exhaustive description of sources and methods will be prepared in connection with the first release. A key element in the compilation of financial accounts is the reconciliation of different primary statistics. The need for reconciliation arises where there are two (or more) primary sources of the same balances. For example, there are two independent sources of the MFI sector's holdings of Danish bonds, viz. the balance-sheet statistics for the MFI sector and the securities statistics. The purpose of reconciliation is to ensure that any discrepancies between the sources can be identified, explained and corrected if required. Since financial accounts are a complete system covering the assets and liabilities of all sectors in a given financial instrument (e.g. quoted shares), the reconciliation is also aimed at ensuring internal consistency so that the total assets correspond to the total liabilities for the instrument. In this way the reconciliation process contributes to ongoing quality assurance, not only of the quarterly financial accounts, but also of the basic primary statistics compiled by Danmarks Nationalbank. QUARTERLY FINANCIAL ACCOUNTS FOR DENMARK 2 This section outlines the financial balance sheets of households and non-financial corporations. These sectors are often focused on in connection with compilation of quarterly financial accounts, partly because of their significance to e.g. financial stability and economic cycles, partly because the total net financial asset position of the sectors is not compiled in other statistics. The data sources comprise primarily indirect sources such as securities statistics, counterpart information from the MFI statistics and the IIP statistics as regards the sectors' external accounts. 3 The financial balances shown have been stated on a non-consolidated basis and cover the period from the 4th quarter of 1998 to the 2nd quar1 2 3 For example, the statistics on the balance sheets and flows of the MFI sector may include (counterpart) information on lending to non-financial corporations, which is included in the compilation of total borrowing by non-financial corporations. In the following households include non-profit institutions serving households (cf. Appendix 1). Accounts between institutional units within the same sector are included in the statistics. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 68 Chart 1 HOUSEHOLDS – FINANCIAL ASSETS Kr. billion 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 4 1998 1 2 1999 3 4 1 2 2000 3 4 1 2 2001 3 4 1 2 2002 3 4 1 2 2003 Currency and deposits Securities other than shares Shares and other equity Insurance technical reserves (pension savings) Note: Other accounts payable/receivable have been omitted since they amount to less than kr.10 billion over the entire period. Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. ter of 2003. The figures are preliminary since an ongoing revision of the sources of Danmarks Nationalbank's IIP statistics may affect the balance sheets. In addition, work is underway to extend the coverage for un1 quoted shares and other equity in the quarterly financial accounts. The households' total financial assets amounted to just over kr. 2,000 billion as at mid-2003, cf. Chart 1. The largest item by far is insurance technical reserves, primarily comprising the households' pension savings 2 with pension funds and life-insurance companies. Insurance technical reserves represent commitments by pension funds and life-insurance companies vis-à-vis policyholders, among others, and comprise the total insurance provisions made by the companies to meet future requirements for pension disbursements and life-insurance claims. Around a third of the households' financial assets are currency and deposits, chiefly bank deposits. The households also have large holdings of shares and other equity, more than half of which are mutual funds shares. The households' total financial assets have to a large extent mirrored the development in the stock markets. Their direct ownership of shares is limited, but indirectly households have a considerable amount of as1 2 For instance, the information on the households' holdings of unquoted shares and other equity issued by non-financial corporations is not comprehensive at present. Pension savings account for the largest part by far of the insurance technical reserves. The rest comprises e.g. prepaid insurance premiums, cf. Appendix 2. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 69 sets placed in shares via pension schemes with pension funds and lifeinsurance companies and – to a lesser degree – via mutual funds investing in shares. If the shares held by pension funds, life-insurance companies and mutual funds are included, the households' total (direct and indirect) ownership of shares as at mid-2003 was almost 20 per cent of the total financial assets. Only about a third of this volume is owned directly by the households. The total percentage of shares is lower than previously, inter alia as a result of pension funds and life-insurance companies having reduced the holdings of shares (and increased the holdings of bonds) in recent years. This has reduced the households' indirect ownership of shares. The value of the financial assets in non-financial corporations is lower than that of the households and was almost kr. 1,300 billion as at mid2003, cf. Chart 2. The financial assets primarily comprise shares and other equity, most of which is equity in other non-financial corporations or in foreign companies. The relatively large holdings of shares, etc. are to some extent attributable to the fact that non-financial holding companies belong to this sector so that their ownership interests in subsidiaries are included. For this reason, non-financial corporations are more exposed to the stock market than households and larger fluctuations are seen in the financial assets of non-financial corporations. As at mid-2003 the total financial liabilities of the households amounted to almost kr. 1,400 billion. The liabilities primarily comprise loans, and throughout the period the households' borrowing has been steadily rising. From end-1998 to mid-2003 the households' total borrowing increased by approximately kr. 350 billion. Around three quarters of the households' borrowing constitutes mortgage-credit loans, and the increase should therefore be seen against the background of the rising trend in house prices in recent years and the resulting increased mortgaging options. The rest of the households' loans are primarily raised from banks, while borrowing via e.g. consumer credit is relatively limited. Non-financial corporations mainly finance their operations via loans and issues of shares and other equity, cf. Chart 3. Total borrowing was on the rise up to 2001, after which is has stabilised at the high level, but throughout the period there have been significant fluctuations in the value of the shares, etc. issued, reflecting, inter alia, the general development in the stock markets. Most loans to non-financial corporations (approximately 60 per cent as at mid-2003) are provided by Danish credit institutions, primarily banks and mortgage-credit institutes, each accounting for just under half of the lending by credit institutions. However, the corporations also have a significant proportion of foreign loans 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 70 Chart 2 NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATIONS – FINANCIAL ASSETS Kr. billion 1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 4 1998 1 2 1999 3 4 1 2 2000 3 4 1 2 2001 3 4 1 2 2002 3 4 Currency, deposits and loans Securities other than shares Shares and other equity Other accounts receivable/payable 1 2 2003 Note: Insurance technical reserves (prepaid premiums, etc.) have been omitted since they amount to less than kr. 10 billion over the entire period. Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. (almost 30 percent), while the remaining borrowing is attributable to e.g. financial leasing provided by Danish financing companies. Nonfinancial corporations only to a limited extent finance their activities by issuing securities other than shares (typically bonds). Since a relatively Chart 3 NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATIONS – FINANCIAL LIABILITIES Kr. billion 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 4 1998 1 2 3 4 1999 1 2 3 2000 4 1 2 3 4 2001 1 2002 Loans Securities other than shares Shares and other equity Other accounts receivable/payable 2 3 4 1 2 2003 Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 71 Chart 4 NET FINANCIAL ASSETS Kr. billion 900 Kr. billion -700 850 -750 800 -800 750 -850 700 -900 650 -950 600 -1,000 550 -1,050 -1,100 500 4 1 2 3 4 1 2 3 2000 1998 1999 Households 4 1 2 3 2001 4 1 2 2002 3 4 1 2 2003 Non-financial corporations (right-hand axis) Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. large proportion of loans are raised from mortgage-credit institutes, which are required under the balance principle to finance lending via bond issues, a significant proportion of the capital base of non-financial corporations is, however, indirectly attributable to issues of securities other than shares. The households' net financial assets have been positive throughout the period and were approximately kr. 650 billion as at mid-2003, cf. Chart 4. Total net assets have declined since the 3rd quarter of 2000, partly as a result of the households' increased borrowing, partly due to the development in the value of the share holdings, including the value of shares owned indirectly via pension funds and life-insurance companies, as well as mutual funds. The households' net financial assets in Chart 4 are calculated including the value of insurance technical reserves (pension savings). Since this asset cannot be immediately realised, from an economic perspective it can also be relevant to consider the net financial assets excluding insurance technical reserves. This measure of the households' net financial assets is generally negative, and in mid-2003 net financial debt was approximately kr. 300 billion. Net assets excluding insurance technical reserves are not to the same extent affected by fluctuations in stock prices and therefore show a more stable trend. An assessment of the households' total financial position should take into account the fact that the households also hold considerable non- 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 72 financial assets. The value of the housing stock and the households' fleet of vehicles can, viewed in isolation, be calculated at around kr. 1,350 bil1 lion at the beginning of 2002 so that total net (financial and nonfinancial) assets can be estimated to lie somewhere around kr. 2,000 billion. Overall the households are therefore relatively well-consolidated. The decrease in net financial assets in recent years should be seen against the background of the increase in housing prices, and thus the value of the housing stock, in the same period. For non-financial corporations net financial assets are negative, cf. Chart 4. The reason is that much of the capital base of these corpora2 tions is placed in non-financial assets (tangible assets and goodwill). Since non-financial corporations have a negative net position in shares (i.e. the value of the issued shares on the liabilities side exceeds the holdings of shares on the asset side), net assets will typically move in the opposite direction of the stock markets. This explains why e.g. rising stock prices up to the 3rd quarter of 2000 led to lower net assets. The development in stock prices also explains some of the large fluctuations in net assets seen at times. The tendency for the net assets of nonfinancial corporations to fall more or less throughout the period is attributable to increased borrowing, among other things. ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS Quarterly financial accounts provide a detailed picture of the financial structures of the whole economy and also make it possible to calculate net financial assets by sectors. This makes the statistics applicable for e.g. economic analyses and forecasts, analyses of financial-stability issues, and analyses of monetary-policy issues, cf. e.g. Mink (2002) and ECB (2000) for a general description of the ECB's use of quarterly financial accounts for the euro area. In connection with economic analyses and forecasts, quarterly financial accounts may provide information on the current savings of the private sector, as well as input for projections of e.g. private consumption and business investments where wealth (the net worth or subitems on the balance sheet) may be a relevant factor. In economic models it is customary to include a measure of the households' wealth in an explanation of the development in private consumption, cf. e.g. MONA, Danmarks Na3 tionalbank's quarterly model of the Danish economy. In this case, quar1 2 3 Cf. Statistics Denmark (2002b) and Statistics Denmark (2003). The housing stock includes the value of business buildings owned by households. At the beginning of 2002, the value of the capital stock was kr. 1,950 billion, cf. Statistics Denmark (2002b). See Danmarks Nationalbank (2003a). 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 73 terly financial accounts provide a current statement of the financial part of the net worth, and the information on balance-sheet composition may be used for assessing whether and to which extent a given development in the financial markets affects the sectors' net worth. Viewed in isolation, borrowing by households and non-financial corporations may also be interesting in connection with an assessment of economic prospects, although the effects on real-economic activity are ambiguous. On the one hand, increased debt may be a sign of increased loan-financed demand. On the other hand, increased debt will – all other things being equal – lower the creditworthiness of borrowers, which could lead to lower demand as a consequence of higher loan costs or even credit rationing. 1 Financial accounts can also be used for analyses of financial stability. 2 The statistics are used for compiling "Macro-prudential indicators" , which, inter alia, comprise a measure of the non-financial sectors' indebtedness defined as debt (loans raised plus the value of issued securities other than shares) as a ratio of GDP. Higher debt for these sectors might affect financial stability since the consequence may be a larger volume of bad loans, which could entail losses to banks, among others. In Denmark, the indebtedness of non-financial corporations and households has been increasing over the period as a whole, cf. Chart 5. The level of household indebtedness in Denmark is among the highest 3 in the EU , presumably as a result of the Danish mortgage-credit system, which provides good opportunity for borrowing against real property as collateral. For instance, it is possible to borrow against the non-mortgaged value of the properties in Denmark, a practice which is 4 not so widespread in other EU member states . The indebtedness of non-financial corporations in Denmark is in line with that of the euro area member states. However, indebtedness cannot be viewed in isolation in terms of financial stability. Higher debt may thus be a result of an increase in the value of the non-financial assets since increased indebtedness among households could be supported by greater housing wealth. Likewise, it is relevant to include financial assets in an assessment of the sectors' wealth. For Danish households, the growing indebtedness since 1998 has gone hand in hand with an equivalent increase in the value of the fi- 1 2 3 4 Cf. Danmarks Nationalbank (2003b) for the latest edition of Danmarks Nationalbank's annual report on financial stability in Denmark. See Mink and Silva (2003) for a review of Macro-prudential indicators. The IMF operates with a number of similar key indicators, called Financial Soundness Indicators, see Sundararajan et al. (2002). See ECB (2002). See ECB (2003). 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 74 Chart 5 INDEBTEDNESS IN DENMARK AS A PERCENTAGE OF GDP Per cent 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 4 1 2 3 4 1998 1999 1 2 3 2000 Non-financial corporations 4 1 2 3 2001 4 1 2002 2 3 4 1 2 2003 Households Source: Danmarks Nationalbank. nancial assets. As at mid-2003 the net financial assets were thus at the same level as at the start of the period, cf. Chart 4. Financial accounts may also be used in connection with analyses of monetary-policy issues, including analyses of the economic impacts of a change in monetary-policy interest rates (analyses of the monetarypolicy transmission mechanism). Among other things, these impacts depend on the composition of the financial balance sheets of non-financial corporations and households since this may affect the sectors' reactions to changes in e.g. prices in the financial markets, as well as the credit 1 institutions' lending and deposit rates. Compared with the euro area, Danish households have a larger proportion of insurance technical reserves in their financial assets and consequently a lower proportion of shares and other equity, cf. Chart 6. The holdings of unquoted shares among Danish households may, however, be slightly underestimated since complete statistics are not currently available for the households' ownership share of non-financial corporations. Overall, it is clear that Danish households have placed a larger proportion of their assets with pension funds and life-insurance companies and thus to a larger extent own securities indirectly. This may affect the impact on household behaviour of movements in the financial 1 See ECB (2002). For a review of the impact of financial structures on the credit channel in the monetary-policy transmission mechanism, see Pedersen (2003). 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 75 Chart 6 THE HOUSEHOLDS' FINANCIAL ASSETS, END-2001 Euro area Denmark Deposits, ect. Securities other than Shares and other Insurance technical reserves (pension savings) Note: Deposits, etc. also include loans and the holdings of banknotes and coins. Other accounts receivable/payable have been omitted since they constitute less than 2 per cent of total assets. Source: Danmarks Nationalbank and Eurostat. markets since insurance technical reserves are not normally a visible part of the households' wealth. The households' reactions to changes in financial prices may therefore be more subdued than if the securities had been owned directly. Moreover, Denmark differs from the euro area in that almost three quarters of household savings are funnelled into financial corporations (in the form of deposits and insurance technical reserves), which is somewhat higher than the level in the euro area. In relation to the euro area, non-financial corporations in Denmark make less use of share issues, but rather tend to raise loans, cf. Chart 7. Access to and the costs of raising loans, including loans from Danish credit institutions, are therefore of greater significance to the financing base of Danish corporations, whereas non-financial corporations in the euro area are more dependent on liquidity and prices in the stock mar- NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATIONS' FINANCIAL LIABILITIES, END-2001 Euro area Loans, etc. Securities other than shares Chart 7 Denmark Shares and other equity Other Note: Loans, etc. also include deposits. Other comprises the instruments insurance technical reserves and other accounts receivable/payable. Source: Danmarks Nationalbank and Eurostat. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 76 1 kets. This could indicate that credit extension via credit institutions plays a larger role in monetary-policy transmission in Denmark. The special credit extension by mortgage-credit institutes and its significance to the financing of non-financial corporations should also be included in a more detailed analysis of the transmission mechanism in Denmark, cf. Pedersen (2003). CONCLUSION In April, Danmarks Nationalbank will begin to regularly publish quarterly financial accounts for Denmark. The statistics will initially include information on the financial balance sheets for the main sectors of the economy since end-1998. For illustration purposes, this article presents a preliminary extract in the form of financial balance sheets for households and non-financial corporations. Next year the quarterly financial accounts published will be extended to include financial flows. The development of quarterly financial accounts for Denmark is a consequence of similar measures at the European level. This article outlines some of the possible applications, including the ECB's use of quarterly financial accounts for the euro area. Likewise, the Federal Reserve applies very extensive "Flow-of-Funds" statistics as an element of its decision-making concerning monetary policy in the USA. For a description of the application in the USA, reference is made to Teplin (2001). 1 There are, however, major differences in the composition of the non-financial corporations' liabilities in the individual euro area member states. Share issues constitute a relatively large proportion of financing in e.g. Spain, France and Italy, while loans play a fairly significant role in e.g. Germany and Austria, cf. ECB (2002). 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 77 LITERATURE Danmarks Nationalbank (2003a), MONA – a quarterly model of the Danish economy. Danmarks Nationalbank (2003b), Financial Stability. Statistics Denmark (2001), Financial Accounts 1995-1999, Statistical Reports (in Danish), National Accounts and Balance of Payments, No. 2001:5. Statistics Denmark (2002a), Financial Accounts for General Government Q1 2002, Statistical Reports (in Danish), Public Finance, No. 2002:20. Statistics Denmark (2002b), Fixed Real Capital 2002, Statistical Reports (in Danish), National Accounts and Balance of Payments, No. 2002:14. Statistics Denmark (2003), Value of Consumers' Vehicles, etc. 1993- 2002, Statistical Reports (in Danish), National Accounts and Balance of Payments 2003:14. ECB (2000), Statistical Information Collected and Compiled by the European System of Central Banks. ECB (2001), Financing and financial investment of the non-financial sectors in the euro area, Monthly Bulletin, May. ECB (2002), Report on financial structures. ECB (2003), Structural Factors in the EU Housing Markets. Mink, Reimund (2002), Quarterly Monetary Union Financial Accounts for ECB Monetary Policy Analysis, IFC Bulletin No. 12. Mink, Reimund and Nuno Silva (2003), The Use of Financial Accounts in Assessing Financial Stability (paper presented at a meeting of the OECD Working Party on Financial Statistics on 6-7 October 2003). Pedersen, Anders Mølgaard (2003), The Credit Channel in MonetaryPolicy Analyses, Danmarks Nationalbank, Monetary Review, 4th Quarter. Sundararajan V., et al. (2002), Financial Soundness Indicators: Analytical Aspects and Country Practices, IMF Occasional Paper 212. Teplin, Albert M. (2001), The US Flow of Funds Accounts and Their Uses, Federal Reserve Bulletin, July. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 78 APPENDIX 1 – SECTORS IN FINANCIAL ACCOUNTS Under ESA 1995, a distinction is made between a number of domestic sectors and the rest of the world, where the domestic part is generally broken down according to economic activity by the sectors households, 1 etc. , financial corporations, non-financial corporations and general government. Financial corporations include corporations which are principally engaged in financial intermediation, i.e. channelling financial assets from persons or enterprises with savings surpluses to persons or enterprises with savings deficits. ESA 1995 divides this sector into five subsectors (cf. sectors S.121-S.125 below), where the enterprises are grouped by type of financial intermediation. This provides for a more detailed analysis of the financial structure of the economy. The sectors in financial accounts are as follows (with the ESA 1995 codes in brackets): • Non-financial corporations (S.11) This sector includes enterprises whose principal activity is the production of goods and non-financial services. Examples include manufacturing enterprises and service enterprises. • Danmarks Nationalbank (S.121) The national central bank, which has been listed as a separate unit under the main sector monetary financial institutions (comprising S.121 and S.122). • Other monetary financial institutions (S.122) This sector consists of all corporations which are principally engaged in financial intermediation and whose business is to receive deposits and/or close substitutes from the general public. The sector comprises banks, mortgage-credit institutes, other credit institutions and moneymarket funds and corresponds to the reporting population for Danmarks Nationalbank's statistics on the balance sheets and flows of the MFI sector. • Other financial intermediaries (S.123) This sector can be seen as a residual group of financial corporations since it comprises corporations that are financial intermediaries, but which do not fit into the other financial subsectors, e.g. mutual funds, financial 1 Including non-profit institutions serving households. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 79 holding companies, leasing companies, investment companies and companies providing consumer credit (e.g. via charge cards). • Financial auxiliaries (S.124) The corporations in this sector are principally engaged in auxiliary financial activities, e.g. in connection with financial transactions. Among others, the sector comprises stockbrokers, insurance brokers, the Copenhagen Stock Exchange and VP Securities Services. • Insurance corporations and pension funds (S.125) Basically, this sector consists of all insurance companies and pension funds. However, the sector does not comprise public pension schemes to which certain population groups must by law make contributions (e.g. the Labour Market Supplementary Pension Fund – ATP). • General government (S.13) Includes all authorities and institutions whose principal function is to supply (non-market) public services to citizens and/or to redistribute income and wealth. In Denmark, this sector can be divided into three subsectors: central government, local government, and social security funds, the latter primarily the Labour Market Supplementary Pension Fund (ATP). • Households (S.14) The households sector covers all consumers and sole proprietorships and partnerships without independent legal status. • Non-profit institutions serving households (S.15) This sector consists of non-profit institutions supplying goods and services to households, e.g. trade unions and charities. • Rest of the world (S.2) This sector comprises Danish residents' financial accounts with nonresidents, i.e. households, enterprises, etc. domiciled abroad. In the quarterly financial accounts published for Denmark, the sectoral breakdown will be simplified in relation to the above in that the sectors financial auxiliaries and non-profit institutions serving households (whose balance-sheet totals are relatively modest) will be included under other financial intermediaries and households, respectively. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 80 APPENDIX 2 – INSTRUMENTS IN FINANCIAL ACCOUNTS In the financial accounts, the following principal instruments will be included under both assets and liabilities for the individual sectors (with the equivalent ESA 1995 codes in brackets): • Monetary gold and special drawing rights (AF.1) This instrument is only relevant for central banks and comprises the foreign-exchange-reserve assets monetary gold (AF.11) and special draw1 ing rights (AF.12). • Currency and deposits (AF.2) Comprises banknotes and coins in circulation (AF.21), transferable deposits (AF.22), i.e. typically sight deposits, and other types of deposits (AF.29), including time deposits and deposits at notice. • Securities other than shares (AF.3) Comprises negotiable securities which do not give the holder ownership rights in relation to the issuer. This instrument is divided into short-term securities (AF.331), long-term securities (AF.332) and financial derivatives (AF.34). Classification as long- or short-term securities, respectively, refers to whether the original maturity (i.e. the term to maturity at issue) was more or less than 1 year. Short-term securities include e.g. Treasury bills and certificates of deposit, while long-term securities include e.g. government and mortgage-credit bonds. • Loans (AF.4) Loans are divided into short-term loans (AF.41), i.e. loans with an original maturity of 1 year or less, and long-term loans (AF.42) with an original maturity of more than 1 year. • Shares and other equity (AF.5) This instrument comprises quoted shares (AF.511), unquoted shares (AF.512) and the residual group other equity (AF.513), comprising e.g. ownership interests in cooperative societies, limited partnerships, etc. The principal instrument also includes mutual fund shares (AF.52). • Insurance technical reserves (AF.6) This instrument comprises insurance companies' and pension funds' provisions to cover obligations vis-à-vis policyholders and beneficiaries. The 1 Special drawing rights comprise SDR deposits, where SDRs are international reserve assets created by the IMF and allocated to its members as a supplement to the existing reserve assets. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 81 instrument can be subdivided into net equity of households in life insurance reserves (AF.611), comprising the insurance companies' provisions for life insurance, and net equity of households in pension fund reserves (AF.612), comprising the pension funds' reserves for pension disbursements to households. The instrument also includes prepayments of insurance premiums and reserves for outstanding claims (AF.62), comprising e.g. amounts due to policyholders in the form of prepaid premiums, as well as the companies' provisions to cover actual incidents for which damages have not yet been paid. Most insurance technical reserves belong to the households in that they relate to their pension savings. • Other accounts receivable/payable (AF.7) This instrument comprises trade credits and advances (AF.71) and other accounts receivable/payable, except trade credits and advances (AF.79), including e.g. tax payable and social benefits receivable. In the quarterly financial accounts published the distribution by instruments will be simplified in relation to the above since it is not possible to separate all instruments on the basis of the existing data. For instance, unquoted shares and other equity will be stated under one, and other accounts receivable/payable will not be subdivided. 24-03-2004 12:08 Antal sider: 19 Rev. nr. 28 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Kvartalsvise finansielle konti for Danmark_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Jens Jakob Svanholt 83 The EU's Financial Services Action Plan Dorte Kurek, Financial Markets INTRODUCTION The work to establish a single market for financial services in the EU was initiated in the 1970s but only really gathered momentum in connection with the capital liberalisation and the 2nd generation directives in the late 1980s. The introduction of the euro as the single currency has strengthened this process. The European Commission's Financial Services Action Plan was introduced in 1999 and includes 47 proposals aimed at removing the remaining legislative and regulatory barriers to a single financial market in the EU. The proposals must be adopted at the latest by April 2004 and implemented by the member states by 2005. Presently 36 proposals have been finally adopted. In 2001 a new decision-making procedure, the Lamfalussy process, was introduced in order to make the regulation process for securities markets more efficient. This article takes stock of the work of creating a framework for financial integration in the EU, focusing on the following three areas: the key measures in the Financial Services Action Plan, the Lamfalussy process and future work. FINANCIAL INTEGRATION Financial integration implies that previously separate national financial markets start functioning as one integrated market. An integrated financial market, as in the USA, offers a number of advantages. The first is more liquid financial markets and a wider product range. This enables investors to diversify their investments. Furthermore, competition is intensified within the group of banks and other financial intermediaries, resulting in a wider range of financial products and lower prices. Finally, with the improved diversification possibilities, the supply of risk capital increases. A study by London Economics, PricewaterhouseCoopers and Oxford Economic Forecasting at the request of the European Commission concludes that due to lower funding costs in banks and on the fi- 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 84 nancial markets, financial integration will in the longer term lead to an 1 increase in the EU-wide real GDP by 1.1 per cent. The EU creates the overall legislative and regulatory framework for an integrated financial market. Subsequently the degree of financial integration is primarily determined by the market participants' behaviour. Barriers in the form of language and cultural differences, high nonrecurring costs when entering a new market, insufficient knowledge of markets and business enterprises in other countries and the need for personal contacts may lead to a low degree of financial integration even though the legislative framework is in place. Thus wholesale markets are generally more integrated than retail markets because the retail markets are characterised by cultural and language differences across countries and by a greater need for personal contacts. Furthermore retail markets may be more influenced by national consumer legislation, tax rules, etc. The study by London Economics and others estimates that the financial integration in the EU has increased significantly during recent years as a result of the work of establishing a single financial market in the EU, the introduction of the euro, technological advances and globalisation. This has led to inter alia the development of more financial products and a gradual shift in business enterprises' sources of financing from traditional bank-based financing and towards an increasingly market-based approach to raising capital. Another effect is that households have become increasingly active in the stock markets. The financial integration in the EU has not yet reached the level in the USA, however. STATUS OF THE FINANCIAL SERVICES ACTION PLAN Since the work of establishing an internal financial market started in the 1970s a large number of measures has been implemented in order to create secure and uniform conditions with regard to supervision and regulation to enable financial institutions to trade across national borders. The introduction of the euro has accelerated the integration process and increased the authorities' and market participants' focus on removing the remaining barriers. At the European Council in Cardiff in 1998 it was decided to request that the European Commission table an 1 London Economics in association with PricewaterhouseCoopers and Oxford Economic Forecasting, Quantification of the Macro-Economic Impact of Integration of EU Financial Markets, November 2002. Other similar studies include Friedrich Heinemann, Mathias Jopp, The Benefits of a Working Retail Market for Financial Services, Report to the European Financial Services Round Table, 2002, as well as Paolo Cecchini, The European Challenge 1992. The Benefits of a Single Market, 1988. 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 85 action plan which could bring the EU to completion of a single financial market. In 1999 the European Commission launched the Financial Services Action Plan. The Action Plan prioritises the work of implementing the single financial market and aims to remove legislative and regulatory barriers that prevent the establishment of secure and integrated financial markets within the EU. The Action Plan contains 42 original and 5 supplementary proposals to be implemented by 2005. A key element is to refine and expand the common rules for providers of financial services, the "European passport" for financial services. The European passport enables financial providers who are approved in one EU member state to provide the same financial products in another EU member state without a new approval. The Action Plan seeks to ensure financial stability in a world of integrated financial markets and with financial providers operating across industries and national borders. This includes clear and uniform supervision rules and very close cooperation between supervisory authorities across national borders. The contents and status of the key measures are described in Box 1. Presently 36 of the 47 proposals in the Action Plan have been 1 adopted . The European Council has decided that all proposals must be adopted by April 2004 at the latest. This gives the member states at least 18 months until the implementation deadline in 2005, taking account of the elections to the European Parliament in the summer of 2004. Initially, proposals regarding the securities market should have been implemented in 2003, but some proposals are expected to be adopted only in 2004. The IAS Regulation, the Financial Conglomerates Directive and the directive on insider dealing and market manipulation were adopted during the Danish EU Presidency, and political agreement was reached on the Prospectus Directive. THE LAMFALUSSY PROCESS The Lamfalussy process is a decision-making procedure introduced on securities markets in 2001. In 2002 it was proposed that the process be extended to the entire financial area (credit institutions, insurance and pensions, and securities). The introduction of the Lamfalussy process aimed at ensuring more efficient regulation on securities markets in order to keep up with the rapid development and to provide for implementation of the extensive financial services action plan within the time limit. Previously, the legislative process tended to be slow and the 1 European Commission, Progress on the Financial Services Action Plan, Annex, 25 November 2003. 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 86 CONTENTS AND STATUS OF KEY MEASURES Box 1 In the following the contents of the key measuress are summarised, and the status of the individual measures appears from the Table. The financial markets Directive on insider dealing and market manipulation contains common rules to combat market abuse in the EU. The directive updates the existing EU rules on insider dealing, which are 10 years old, so that new financial products are included. Common rules on regulation of market manipulation have been added as well. Directive on takeover bids aims at harmonising rules for cross-border acquisitions of listed companies in the EU. The purpose is to strengthen the legal certainty of crossborder takeover bids and to ensure protection for the minority shareholders. The IAS Regulation stipulates that listed companies prepare their consolidated accounts in accordance with the international accounting standards. The provisions will enter into force on 1 January 2005. The regulation, among other things, contributes to removing barriers to cross-border securities trading as the companies' financial information becomes more transparent and comparable. The Investment Services Directive should promote the creation of transparent, efficient and integrated financial markets by requirements of increased transparency on the markets and harmonisation of the rules concerning the various types of marketplace1. Furthermore the protection of investors in the EU member states is sought enhanced through harmonising the conduct of business rules and ensuring the best execution of a securities deal for the client. The directive replaces the current directive from 1993 which is out of date in areas such as investor protection, types of investment services on the market and the market structure. The Prospectus Directive is to create better and more uniform conditions for investing and raising capital in the EU. This implies e.g. that a prospectus which has been approved in one member state can freely be listed and offered in all other member states and thus obtain a European passport for prospectuses. Another objective is to enhance consumer protection for investing in securities. The directive thus contains a number of provisions on the contents of prospectuses to make them more uniform. The objective of the Transparency Directive is to lay down minimum requirements to harmonise the information to be published by issuers of securities listed in a regulated market, e.g. a stock exchange. The information on the issuers of the securities should contribute to better investment decisions. The UCITS directives include provisions on e.g. authorisation, supervision, investment policy and transparency requirements for investment funds (UCITS) and management companies. An important element is to enable the management companies to achieve a European passport that gives access to operate in other member states. In addition, the directives adjust the current UCITS directive to the market development as regards the included products. Financial supervision The Capital Adequacy Directive comprises capital-adequacy provisions for banks, other credit institutions and investment undertakings and is to a large extent based on the standards of the Basel Committee, Basel II2. The existing capital-adequacy rules, the Basel I Accord, from 1988 have contributed to ensuring a level playing field for banks 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 87 CONTINUED Box 1 with cross-border activities. However, new financial products and more sophisticated risk management in the credit institutions have called for more up-to-date rules. The objective of the new Basel II Accord is for the capital requirement to reflect more clearly the risks incurred by the individual credit institution. The Financial Conglomerates Directive aims at ensuring a level playing field for different types of financial groups by imposing a number of obligations that transcend sector divides and national borders. Furthermore, coordination of supervision across borders is stated. The directive seeks to take account of a number of group risks, including ensuring that capital is solely used to meet capital requirements in one company within the group; that group structures are transparent; that intra-group transactions take place on market terms; and that risks in one company do not contaminate other entities of the group. STATUS OF MEASURES IN THE FINANCIAL SERVICES ACTION PLAN Pending proposals Reinsurance Supervision Directive 3rd Money Laundering Directive ........................................ Directive on risk-based capital (capital adequacy) ............ Legal framework for payments .......................................... 14th Company Law Directive .............................................. Directive on insurance solvency II (capital adequacy) ....... Plan for proposal 1st quarter 2004 2nd quarter 2004 2nd quarter 2004 2nd quarter 2004 3rd quarter 2004 2005 Presented proposals which are not adopted Directive on Take Over Bids ............................................... 10th Company Law Directive .............................................. Transparency Directive ........................................................ Investment Services Directive.............................................. Plan for adoption 1st quarter 2004 1st quarter 2004 1st quarter 2004 2nd quarter 2004 Table Adopted proposals which are not implemented Implementation deadline Directives on UCITS (amendments) .................................... 1st quarter 2004 Directive on fair value accounting...................................... 1st quarter 2004 Directive on the taxation of savings income ...................... 1st quarter 2004 Directive on winding-up of credit institutions ................... 2nd quarter 2005 Financial Conglomerates Directive ..................................... 3rd quarter 2004 Directive on distance marketing of consumer financial 4th quarter 2004 services................................................................................. European Company Statute ................................................ 4th quarter 2004 Directive on insider dealing and market manipulation ..... 4th quarter 2004 Regulation on international accounting standards ........... 1st quarter 2005 Directive on modernising of the accounting provisions..... 1st quarter 2005 Directive on insurance mediation ....................................... 1st quarter 2005 Directive on prospectuses.................................................... 2nd quarter 2005 Directive on institutions for occupational retirement 3rd quarter 2005 provision ............................................................................. Source: European Commission, Progress on the Financial Services Action Plan, Annex, 25 November 2003 and European Commission, The FSAP enters the Home Straight, Ninth progress report, 25 November 2003. 1 2 The Investment Services Directive is described in Birgitte Bundgaard and Anne Reinhold Pedersen, The Investment Services Directive – a New Basis for Securities Trading in Europe, Danmarks Nationalbank, Monetary Review, 4th Quarter 2003. The Basel Committee's proposal for new standards is described in Lisbeth Borup and Morten Lykke, New Capital-Adequacy Rules for Credit Institutions, Danmarks Nationalbank, Monetary Review, 3rd Quarter 2003. 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 88 THE LAMFALUSSY PROCESS Box 2 The Lamfalussy process was established at the recommendation of the Committee of Wise Men on the Regulation of European securities markets chaired by Professor Alexandre Lamfalussy, former President of the European Monetary Institute. The Committee of Wise Men was set up by the Ecofin Council in July 2000 with a view to making regulation in the securities markets more efficient. The Lamfalussy process in the securities area was adopted by the European Council in Stockholm in March 2001 and includes: • Level 1: The European Commission presents proposals for legislation based on advice from a number of committees, cf. below. The proposals lay down the key general principles and are adopted in co-decision by the Ecofin Council and the European Parliament. • Level 2: The technical details laid down within the framework of level 1 are considered under the comitology procedure. Here the European Securities Committee (ESC) together with the European Commission lay down the rules following advice by the Committee of European Securities Regulators (CESR). • Level 3: The CESR proposes consistent implementation of specified rules. The CESR can provide voluntary guidelines and common standards. The supervisory authorities also cooperate in the CESR. • Level 4: The European Commission supervises that the member states comply with the provisions. If necessary, the European Commission can bring action against the member states at the European Court of Justice. In December 2002 the Ecofin Council decided to extend the Lamfalussy process to the remaining financial area (credit institutions, insurance and pensions). In connection with the extension a number of new committees are established with a view to advising the European Commission under level 1, participating in the comitology procedure under level 2 and ensuring uniform implementation of the provisions (supervision) under level 3 in the new areas as regards the Lamfalussy process. The proposed committee structure for the entire financial service sector is summarised in the Chart and the Table overleaf. The advisory and comitology committees are composed of high-level representatives from the relevant national ministries, while the supervisory committees are composed of high-level representatives from the national supervisory authorities. Central banks without supervisory responsibilities are also represented in the Committee of result could reflect some legal uncertainty, e.g. due to political disagreement which gave room for national interpretation. Under the Lamfalussy process the Ecofin Council and the European Parliament adopt the legal framework that lays down key principles in the area in question (level 1). The technical measures are adopted under the so-called comitology procedure whereby the European Commission, assisted by senior representatives from the relevant national ministries, prepares detailed rules within the given framework (level 2). Further- 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 89 CONTINUED Box 2 European Banking Supervisors (CEBS). The directive on insurance solvency II is considered under CEIOPS as the first directive in this structure. PROPOSED FINANCIAL SERVICES COMMITTEE STRUCTURE European Commission • Proposal for a directive • Comitology Level 1 Ecofin Council ESC European Parliament EBC EIOPC Key Principles Level 2 Details and technical measures Level 3 CESR CEBS CEIOPC PROPOSED FINANCIAL SERVICES COMMITTEE STRUCTURE Banking Supervision Table Insurance and pensions Securities Advisory function for level 1, Comitology function under level 2 The European Banking Committee (EBC) The European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Committee (EIOPC) The European Securities Committee (ESC) Supervisory function under level 3 The Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS) The Committee of European Insurance and Occupational Pensions 1 Supervisors (CEIOPS) The Committee of European Securities Regulators (CESR) Source: The Commission of the European Communities, Proposal for a directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Council Directives 73/239/EEC, 85/611/EEC, 91/675/EEC, 93/6/EEC and 94/19/EC and Directives 2000/12/EC, 2002/83/EC and 2002/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, in order to establish a new financial services committee organisational structure. 1 Henrik Bjerre-Nielsen, Director General, Danish Financial Supervisory Authority, is the chairman of CEIOPS. more, a number of supervisory committees have been appointed in order to e.g. advise the European Commission and the regulatory committees on supervision issues and ensure uniform implementation of the rules (level 3). In many ways the process is similar to the Danish legislative process in the financial area where the Folketing (Parliament) promulgates acts with the overall framework, while the Danish Financial Supervisory Authority lays down the technical rules in executive orders. The Lamfalussy process is described in detail in Box 2. 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 90 A special committee, the Financial Services Committee, FSC, has been appointed. The committee consists of senior officials from the national ministries of finance and economic affairs. FSC advises the Ecofin Council and the European Commission on financial integration issues. The tasks of the FSC include supervision of implementation of the Action Plan, clearing and settlement as well as corporate governance in relation to financial markets. The FSC also advises on coordination and cooperation between national authorities in the areas of crisis management and financial stability. Experience with the Lamfalussy process The Lamfalussy process distinguishes between political legal framework principles (level 1) and technical measures (level 2) in order to make the legislative process more efficient. It is important to strike the right balance between the two levels. The legal framework under level 1 must be of a general nature to give the European Commission and the national officials room to develop the technical details. At the same time the legal framework should settle the most important political differences so that these are not left for the European Commission and the officials to resolve. The initial measures in connection with the Lamfalussy process are the directive on insider dealing and market manipulation, the Prospectus Directive, the Investment Services Directive and the Transparency Directive. A group appointed by the European Commission, the Ecofin Council and the European Parliament assesses that generally the process is faster and more 1 efficient than the previous practice . For example, it took less than one year to adopt the second Investment Services Directive, whereas it took six years to adopt the first one in 1993. However, experience also shows that it has been difficult to strike the right balance between level 1 and level 2 in the legislative process. There are incidences of too detailed framework 2 principles that leave insufficient room for the comitology procedure , and incidences where political differences were not resolved satisfactorily under level 1. Finally, it is generally agreed that the national implementation of the directives is not always uniform. FUTURE WORK TOWARDS FINANCIAL INTEGRATION The legislative part of the Action Plan is now in its final phase. As the last proposals are adopted focus will shift towards timely and uniform 1 2 Inter-Institutional Monitoring Group, Second Interim Report Monitoring the Lamfalussy Process, December 2003. ECB, Monthly Bulletin, October 2003, The integration of Europe's financial markets. 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 91 implementation of the directives in the individual member states, including the acceding countries, and adjustment of legislation in line with the development in the financial markets. Also, the dialogue on regulation of the financial markets with authorities outside the EU, e.g. in the USA, will be enhanced. The European Commission has set up four expert groups within the areas of banking, insurance, securities and asset management to assess the effectiveness of the measures in the Action Plan and the status of financial integration in the EU. The expert groups' reports will be published for consultation during the summer of 2004. There are strong indications that the decision-making process within the financial area will be changed with the new constitutional Treaty for the EU. Negotiations on the draft Treaty Establishing a Constitution for Europe broke down at the EU Summit in Brussels in December 2003, so the development is still uncertain. The draft Treaty presented at the EU Summit in Brussels in December 2003 suggests a decision-making process similar to the Lamfalussy process. However, the essential difference is that the proposed decision-making process does not contain a comitology procedure in which national experts are consulted. On the other hand, it is acknowledged that the comitology procedure can be maintained as a voluntary consultation procedure. The Irish Presidency has not yet indicated how negotiations on the constitutional Treaty will be continued. FURTHER INFORMATION ON THE FINANCIAL SERVICES ACTION PLAN Further information on the EU's Financial Services Action Plan can be found using the following links: • The European Commission: http://europa.eu.int/comm/internal_market/finances_en.htm • The European Parliament, the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs: www.europarl.eu.int/committees/econ_home.htm • The Committee of European Securities Regulators (CESR): www.europefesco.org • Federation of European Securities Exchanges (FESE): www.fese.be/initiatives/european_representation/index.htm 24-03-2004 08:50 Antal sider: 9 Rev. nr. 11 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\FSAP KVO_en_final_bowne.doc Oprettet af Dorte Kurek 93 Press releases 10 DECEMBER 2003: ELECTION TO THE COMMITTEE OF DIRECTORS OF DANMARKS NATIONALBANK Ms. Pernille Blach Hansen, MP, has withdrawn from the Committee of Directors. The Board of Directors has elected Ms. Pia Gjellerup, MP, as new member of the Committee of Directors for the remainder of the term ending on 31 March 2004. 13 JANUARY 2004: FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT AT DANMARKS NATIONALBANK Today Danmarks Nationalbank publishes the book Financial Management at Danmarks Nationalbank. The book provides a description of the principles and methodologies used in connection with management of the foreign-exchange reserve and other portfolios. Danmarks Nationalbank considers it important to provide a comprehensive description of the principles for financial management and to ensure that the principles are available to the general public. Danmarks Nationalbank is one of the first central banks to publish a full description of the management of the foreign-exchange reserve. The description covers considerations related to the decision-making process and distribution of responsibility as well as risk management and performance measurement. The composition of Danmarks Nationalbank's balance sheet and the financial result is also described. The cornerstone of financial management is the fixed-exchange-rate policy, although good returns are also an objective to Danmarks Nationalbank. The choice of risk level is characterised by prudence. Management of the individual types of risk reflects that Danmarks Nationalbank seeks to avoid major losses as a result of changes in interest-rate risk and currency risk, and the aim is to completely avoid losses as a consequence of counterparty failure. The book is available in Danish and English. 19 JANUARY 2004: NEW FAROESE 200-KRONE BANKNOTE Today a Faroese 200-krone banknote is issued. This is a new denomination in the Faroese banknote series. 24-03-2004 08:52 Antal sider: 3 Rev. nr. 13 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Press releases.doc Oprettet af Josephine Rasmussen 94 The motif on the face of the 200-krone banknote is a Ghost Moth, Hepialus humuli, printed in intaglio. The Ghost Moth, which spreads its wings across the banknote, is found all over the Faroe Islands. The background is reproduced from a watercolour with blades of grass. The motif of Tindhólmur near Vágar on the reverse of the banknote is also reproduced from a watercolour. The watercolours are by Zacha-rias Heinesen. The 200-krone banknote measures 145 x 72 mm and its primary col-our is dusty violet. 200 kroner – a new denomination The introduction of this new denomination in the Faroese banknote series is a natural consequence of the Act on Faroese Banknotes etc., which e.g. states that Faroese banknotes shall have the same sizes and denominations as Danish banknotes. The wish to be able to settle payments using as few banknotes and coins as possible was the background to introducing the Danish 200-krone banknote. Security features Like the 100-krone banknote, the 200-krone banknote has a holo-gram. With the other security features –such as the watermark and the security thread with colour change –it makes Faroese banknotes difficult to counterfeit. The new banknote series The remaining two banknotes in the new series are expected to be issued within 1½ years. Further information A folder on the new banknote will be distributed to Faroese house-holds from 20 January 2004. For further information, visit: www.nationalbanken.dk, Notes and coins. 11 FEBRUARY 2004: COMMEMORATIVE COIN TO MARK THE WEDDING OF HRH CROWN PRINCE FREDERIK AND MISS MARY DONALDSON ON 14 MAY 2004 A commemorative coin will be issued to mark thewedding of His Royal Highness Crown Prince Frederik and Miss Mary Donaldson. This is in line with the tradition to issue commemorative coins in connection with special events in the Royal Family. The coin will be issued in a 20-krone and a 200-krone version. The 20krone coin will be of the same size and alloy as the ordinary 20-krone 24-03-2004 08:52 Antal sider: 3 Rev. nr. 13 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Press releases.doc Oprettet af Josephine Rasmussen 95 coin in circulation. It will be minted in an edition of 1.2 million coins. The 200-krone coin will be 38 mm in diameter and will be minted in fine silver in an edition of 125,000 coins. The motif on the obverse of the coin is a profile of the Queen, identical to the one used on the most recent 10- and 20-krone coins. The reverse features a twin portrait of His Royal Highness Crown Prince Frederik and Miss Mary Donaldson. The wedding portrait was designed by the sculptor Karin Lorentzen. Both commemorative coins will be available from banks and coin dealers from 10 May 2004. 24-03-2004 08:52 Antal sider: 3 Rev. nr. 13 I:\WEB-publikationer\MON1_04 folder\tiltryk\Press releases.doc Oprettet af Josephine Rasmussen Tables Interest rates and share-price index ......................................................... 1 Selected items from the Nationalbank's balance sheet .......................... 2 Factors affecting the banks' and the mortgage-credit institutes' net position with the Nationalbank........................................ 3 Selected items from the consolidated balance sheet of the MFI sector and the money stock.................................................................................. 4 The banks' lending..................................................................................... 5 Selected items from the balance sheet of the mortgage-credit institutes .................................................................. 6 Principal items of the balance of payments (net revenues).................... 7 External financial payments (net payments from abroad) ..................... 8 Denmark's international investment position ......................................... 9 GDP by type of expenditure...................................................................... 10 Development in consumer prices and net retail prices ........................... 11 Selected monthly economic indicators ..................................................... 12 Selected quarterly economic indicators ................................................... 13 Exchange rates .......................................................................................... 14 Danmarks Nationalbank's Statistical Publications Symbols and Sources 0 Magnitude nil or less than one half of unit employed. … Data not available or of negligible interest. Some of the most recent statistics may be provisional. Due to roundingoff there may be small differences between the sum of the individual figures and the totals stated. Date of going to press: 26 March 2004. The Tables section of this publication is thus based on more recent information than the equivalent section of the Danish edition. Danmarks Nationalbank is the source for Tables 1-6, 8-9 and 14, while the Copenhagen Stock Exchange is the source for series of bond yields and the share-price index in Table 1. Statistics Denmark is the source for Tables 7 and 10-13. The calculations in Table 11 have been made by Danmarks Nationalbank. INTEREST RATES AND SHARE-PRICE INDEX Table 1 The Nationalbank's The ECB's minimum interest rates bid rate (in the main Lending refinancand ing certifiDiscount cates of operations) deposit rate Effective end-of-year/ from 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 ............... ............... ............... ............... ............... Per cent per annum The Copenhagen Stock 30-year Exchange sharemortprice gageindex credit KFX bond Bond yields Inter-bank interest 10-year rate, central3-months governuncollatment eralized bond End of period Per cent per annum 3.7.89 =100 3.00 4.75 3.25 2.75 2.00 3.30 5.40 3.60 2.95 2.15 3.00 4.75 3.25 2.75 2.00 1999 ............. 2000 ............. 2001 ............. 2002 ............. 2003 ............. 3.57 5.33 3.54 3.00 2.16 5.64 5.20 5.15 4.45 4.46 7.45 7.30 6.55 5.47 5.45 255.69 313.90 272.45 199.49 244.35 2002 6 Dec. ... 2.75 2.95 2.75 2003 Feb ..... 2.65 4.17 5.32 178.03 2003 7 Mar. .. 2.50 23 May.... 2.50 6 Jun. .... 2.00 2.70 2.65 2.15 2.50 2.50 2.00 Sep ..... Oct ..... Nov .... Dec..... 2.13 2.16 2.19 2.16 4.22 4.51 4.62 4.46 5.43 5.58 5.61 5.45 238.19 258.01 242.72 244.35 2004 26 Mar. .. 2.00 2.15 2.00 2004 Jan ..... Feb ..... 2.16 2.11 4.41 4.22 5.39 5.23 261.83 275.94 SELECTED ITEMS FROM THE NATIONALBANK'S BALANCE SHEET Table 2 The banks' and the mortgage-credit The institutes' net position with the central Nationalbank governThe ment's foreign- Notes and account exchange coin in with the Certifi- Deposits reserve circula- National- cates of (current Total net tion (net) Loans position deposit account) bank End of period 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Kr. billion ............................... ............................... ............................... ............................... ............................... 165.3 117.5 148.4 193.2 224.2 46.4 44.8 47.3 47.7 49.7 39.7 37.7 43.5 50.3 44.0 99.9 51.9 113.6 160.7 157.3 6.5 8.1 3.7 10.1 12.9 33.1 25.3 63.4 81.2 48.0 73.3 34.6 53.9 89.6 122.2 2003 Feb ......................... 196.9 44.7 76.1 133.0 3.6 72.2 64.4 Sep ......................... Oct ......................... Nov......................... Dec ......................... 227.8 228.5 228.2 224.0 46.3 46.5 47.1 49.7 89.4 84.3 52.7 40.9 132.8 142.7 150.6 157.3 13.0 3.9 6.9 12.9 63.5 59.4 42.1 48.0 82.3 87.2 115.4 122.1 2004 Jan.......................... Feb ......................... 214.6 206.4 47.2 46.7 56.9 54.5 131.1 139.0 4.7 3.3 39.4 51.7 96.5 90.7 FACTORS AFFECTING THE BANKS' AND THE MORTGAGE-CREDIT INSTITUTES' NET POSITION WITH THE NATIONALBANK Table 3 The banks' and the mortgage-credit institutes' net position with the Nationalbank Central-government finance Net purchase The of Sales of foreign NationalDomestic domestic exchange bank's gross centralnet by the financing governChange in Other End of Liquidity National- bond requirenet ment bank purchases factors position period ment securities effect Kr. billion 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 67.9 62.3 81.2 115.5 99.7 68.8 65.7 87.7 121.9 94.1 -0.9 -3.4 -6.5 -6.4 5.6 62.7 -37.7 28.4 45.4 31.0 1.9 2.1 1.0 -0.9 -0.1 -7.9 0.4 -3.6 -2.4 -4.0 55.7 -38.7 19.3 35.7 32.5 73.3 34.6 53.9 89.6 122.2 2003 Feb ............ -4.8 5.9 -10.7 2.3 0.2 -0.1 -8.4 64.4 Sep ............ Oct............. Nov............ Dec ............ 8.5 13.4 23.6 11.7 9.4 8.3 -8.1 4.5 -1.0 5.1 31.6 7.3 0.0 0.7 -0.3 0.3 1.0 -0.2 -1.3 0.3 0.6 -0.7 -1.8 -1.2 0.6 4.9 28.2 6.7 82.3 87.2 115.4 122.1 2004 Jan............. Feb ............ 0.6 2.5 16.6 1.0 -16.0 1.5 -9.6 -7.3 -2.0 0.0 1.9 0.0 -25.7 -5.8 96.5 90.7 SELECTED ITEMS FROM THE CONSOLIDATED BALANCE SHEET OF THE MFI SECTOR AND THE MONEY STOCK Table 4 of which: Domestic lending of which: Total balance Total Households End of period 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Holdings of domestic securities Nonfinancial other than shares companies Foreign assets, 1 net Money stock (M3) Kr. billion .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 2,612.8 2,806.8 2,932.1 3,201.5 3,358.9 1,578.2 1,758.7 1,925.9 2,024.5 2,151.6 1,001.8 1,076.8 1,168.6 1,249.3 1,351.7 420.0 499.2 573.2 578.3 607.5 125.8 114.2 133.1 142.8 123.3 163.7 49.6 -46.9 -63.9 -53.7 523.2 506.4 546.4 604.7 690.8 2003 Feb ............ 3,311.9 2,044.9 1,261.0 587.4 154.0 -47.0 670.4 Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 3,445.3 3,383.6 3,312.2 3,358.9 2,125.9 2,120.5 2,129.7 2,151.6 1,327.5 1,328.9 1,333.7 1,351.7 602.0 594.0 598.2 607.5 157.5 151.8 122.1 123.3 -26.4 -55.6 -64.8 -53.7 687.2 729.2 729.8 690.8 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 3,347.1 3,369.3 2,159.7 2,165.6 1,355.2 1,358.2 602.5 608.7 126.5 124.1 -55.6 -68.4 769.2 701.4 Change compared with previous year, per cent 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 8.5 7.4 4.5 9.2 4.9 5.8 11.4 9.5 5.1 6.3 7.8 7.5 8.5 6.8 8.2 2.9 18.9 14.8 0.9 5.1 -17.9 -9.2 16.5 7.3 -13.7 … … … … … 0.0 -3.2 7.9 10.7 14.2 2003 Feb ............ 9.1 5.6 7.8 1.5 7.5 … 21.0 Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 6.6 5.2 3.2 4.9 5.8 5.7 5.7 6.3 7.6 7.5 7.9 8.2 3.5 3.6 3.0 5.1 -3.4 -0.5 -12.5 -13.7 … … … … 16.2 20.6 20.7 14.2 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 1.9 1.7 6.3 5.9 8.5 7.7 3.1 3.6 -15.6 -19.4 … … 17.1 4.6 Note: The MFI sector includes Danish Monetary Financial Institutions, i.e. banks and mortgage-credit institutes, other credit institutions, money-market funds and Danmarks Nationalbank. 1 The net foreign assets of the MFI sector has been compiled as the difference between all assets and liabilities vis-a-vis non-residents. THE BANKS LENDING Table 5 From Danish owned banks abroad From banks in Denmark of which: To Danish residents total Households NonTo nonfinancial Danish companies residents End of period 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 of which: Total To Danish residents To nonDanish residents Total lending Kr. billion .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 399.8 526.2 588.0 599.2 662.9 203.4 239.0 253.3 253.5 271.5 117.2 186.4 228.8 231.3 285.7 105.0 104.7 112.7 124.5 129.4 345.4 312.5 288.1 298.3 323.1 123.2 66.2 34.6 32.6 30.2 222.1 246.3 253.5 265.7 292.9 850.2 943.4 988.8 1,022.0 1,115.4 2003 Feb ............ 640.4 244.3 279.6 152.0 … … … … Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 656.8 645.1 647.3 662.9 261.3 258.2 256.8 271.5 282.8 273.1 277.1 285.7 137.5 124.2 118.9 129.4 326.8 … … 323.1 30.0 … … 30.2 296.8 … … 292.9 1,121.1 … … 1,115.4 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 661.5 657.6 265.3 266.2 279.8 280.0 132.9 129.7 … … … … … … … … Change compared with previous year, per cent 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 5.5 31.6 11.7 1.9 10.6 4.5 17.6 6.0 0.1 7.0 4.2 59.0 22.7 1.1 23.5 40.4 -0.3 7.6 10.5 3.9 39.2 -9.5 -7.8 3.5 8.3 27.8 -46.3 -47.7 -5.8 -7.4 46.4 10.9 2.9 4.8 10.2 21.1 11.0 4.8 3.4 9.1 2003 Feb ............ 9.5 -0.4 20.9 17.9 … … … … Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 9.8 9.5 9.8 10.6 2.4 2.8 5.5 7.0 22.5 22.4 20.2 23.5 -1.3 -15.3 -6.5 3.9 15.2 … … 8.3 -2.6 … … -7.4 17.4 … … 10.2 9.8 … … 9.1 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 2.5 2.7 8.0 8.9 -0.4 0.2 -9.7 -14.7 … … … … … … … … Note: As from 2003 the banks' lending is affected by the inclusion of an institution previously belonging to the category "Other Credit Institutions". Lending to households includes lending to self-employed individuals. SELECTED ITEMS FROM THE BALANCE SHEET OF THE MORTGAGE-CREDIT INSTITUTES Table 6 of which: 1 Domestic lending Total balance Total End of period 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 of which: Lending to house2 holds of which: Interest adjusted lending of which: Lending in foreign currency Debt securities issued Kr. billion .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 1,222.9 1,341.1 1,579.5 1,721.8 1,863.8 1,050.9 1,095.4 1,191.8 1,284.6 1,393.5 785.8 830.2 907.6 988.0 1,072.1 59.7 99.8 245.7 365.0 499.1 9.6 15.5 54.5 82.5 85.7 1,116.2 1,212.9 1,421.3 1,584.2 1,729.0 2003 Feb ............ 1,564.8 1,311.0 1,009.0 385.5 84.8 1,482.1 Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 1,642.3 1,579.0 1,606.4 1,863.8 1,374.3 1,380.5 1,388.2 1,393.5 1,058.9 1,063.3 1,069.5 1,072.1 452.3 462.9 476.1 499.1 90.3 89.1 88.9 85.7 1,533.2 1,467.5 1,491.2 1,729.0 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 1,571.2 1,599.5 1,402.1 1,412.3 1,081.8 1,084.0 516.9 532.0 85.4 85.3 1,488.3 1,520.2 Change compared with previous year, per cent 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 4.3 9.7 17.8 9.0 8.2 6.4 4.2 8.8 7.8 8.5 7.5 5.7 9.3 8.9 8.5 … 67.2 146.2 48.6 36.7 … 61.5 251.6 51.4 3.9 -0.6 8.7 17.2 11.5 9.1 2003 Feb ............ 14.1 9.0 10.1 38.5 27.3 17.5 Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 11.7 8.5 7.6 8.2 8.4 8.2 8.0 8.5 8.9 8.6 8.4 8.5 35.4 35.0 35.4 36.7 12.6 9.9 8.5 3.9 11.9 7.1 6.5 9.1 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 4.5 2.2 8.2 7.7 8.6 7.4 37.9 38.0 1.9 0.6 4.4 2.6 1 2 The distribution of lending to households, interest adjusted lending and lending in foreign currency may coincide. Therefore, some lending has been included in more than more than one of the above categories. Lending to households includes lending to self-employed individuals. PRINCIPAL ITEMS OF THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS (NET REVENUES) Goods (fob) Services Goods and services Wages and property income Table 7 Current transfers Total current account Kr. billion 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 ............................... ............................... ............................... ............................... ............................... 46.7 54.1 61.7 60.1 67.7 11.1 22.1 23.8 16.8 24.0 57.8 76.2 85.5 76.9 91.7 -17.4 -32.8 -24.8 -27.2 -25.3 -19.3 -24.8 -20.3 -22.1 -24.2 21.2 18.6 40.5 27.6 42.3 Feb 02 - Jan 03 ................ 59.9 16.0 75.8 -26.9 -22.2 26.7 Feb 03 - Jan 04 ................ 66.6 25.1 91.6 -25.0 -23.9 42.7 2003 Jan.......................... 4.0 -0.1 4.0 -2.6 1.6 2.9 Aug ........................ Sep ......................... Oct.......................... Nov......................... Dec ......................... 6.1 9.1 5.0 5.2 3.9 2.7 2.5 3.5 2.3 3.1 8.8 11.6 8.5 7.5 7.0 -1.5 -1.2 -2.3 -4.6 -2.9 -2.2 -2.4 -2.4 -1.7 -2.4 5.2 8.0 3.7 1.2 1.7 2004 Jan.......................... 2.9 0.9 3.8 -2.4 1.9 3.3 EXTERNAL FINANCIAL PAYMENTS (NET PAYMENTS FROM ABROAD) Table 8 Financial payments of which: Direct investments Current Capital payments transfers Total Foreign in Denmark Danish abroad Danish kroneErrors denomiand nated bonds omissions Increase in the foreignexchange reserve Kr. billion 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 21.2 18.6 40.5 27.6 42.3 0.9 -0.1 -0.2 0.7 -0.3 61.4 -18.0 -44.5 29.0 -37.4 116.9 266.9 92.5 52.4 17.9 -118.6 -202.7 -107.9 -44.6 -8.6 15.3 -21.3 -17.7 8.5 -32.7 -19.3 -43.6 31.7 -11.8 26.1 64.2 -43.0 27.5 45.4 30.8 Mar 02 - Feb 03.. 28.6 0.6 -8.7 48.7 -46.1 26.1 5.8 26.4 Mar 03 - Feb 04.. … -0.4 -72.4 19.1 -1.6 -64.2 … 9.4 2003 Feb ............ 4.4 -0.2 -8.2 0.8 -7.8 8.0 5.6 1.7 Sep ............ Oct ............ Nov............ Dec ............ 8.0 3.7 1.2 1.7 0.0 0.1 0.1 -0.2 -4.3 -15.3 -4.7 -6.6 1.3 -0.7 0.9 1.0 0.5 0.1 2.2 2.0 17.3 -35.5 -16.6 17.0 -5.9 12.3 3.2 0.8 -2.2 0.7 -0.3 -4.3 2004 Jan ............ Feb ............ 3.3 … -0.3 -0.1 -30.3 -24.3 6.2 -1.3 0.1 -3.1 -2.9 -17.8 17.8 … -9.4 -8.2 DENMARK'S INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT POSITION Direct investment Portfolio investment In Shares, Abroad Denmark etc. Bonds, etc. Table 9 Other investment Loans, currency and Trade credits deposits Other The foreign exchange reserve Total Kr. billion End of period Assets 1999 .............. 2000 ............... 2001 .............. 2002 .............. 2003 .............. 358 557 624 571 581 22 29 35 30 30 387 454 403 254 301 151 229 317 359 454 48 51 57 57 57 457 472 417 451 519 98 143 124 249 181 225 121 152 197 228 1,747 2,056 2,131 2,167 2,350 2003 Q1 ........ Q2 ........ Q3 ........ Q4 ........ 578 584 584 581 30 30 30 30 226 246 273 301 414 431 414 454 57 57 57 57 549 570 519 519 222 267 268 181 202 240 234 228 2,278 2,425 2,380 2,350 1999 .............. 2000 ............... 2001 .............. 2002 .............. 2003 .............. 19 26 33 33 33 333 564 601 551 575 160 218 201 146 189 611 646 754 763 777 24 24 30 30 30 621 672 631 668 814 73 120 106 214 139 58 3 4 4 3 1,899 2,274 2,359 2,408 2,560 2003 Q1 ........ Q2 ........ Q3 ........ Q4 ........ 33 33 33 33 553 567 572 575 144 164 180 189 821 828 830 777 30 30 30 30 772 823 761 814 181 225 229 139 1 3 3 3 2,535 2,672 2,636 2,560 1999 .............. 2000 ............... 2001 .............. 2002 .............. 2003 .............. 338 531 591 538 548 -311 -535 -567 -521 -545 227 236 203 107 112 -459 -418 -436 -404 -323 25 27 27 27 27 -164 -199 -214 -217 -295 25 23 19 36 42 167 117 148 193 224 -152 -218 -229 -241 -210 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 546 551 552 548 -522 -537 -542 -545 82 82 93 112 -407 -397 -416 -323 27 27 27 27 -223 -253 -242 -295 41 42 40 42 202 237 231 224 -257 -247 -256 -210 Liabilities Net assets ........ ........ ........ ........ Note: As a key principle, the market value has been used for the compilation. GDP BY TYPE OF EXPENDITURE Table 10 Final domestic demand GDP GeneralgovernGross fixed Change in ment Private inventconsump- consump- capital tion formation ories tion Total Exports Imports of goods of goods and and services services Kr. billion 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 1,207.7 1,279.0 1,325.5 1,360.7 1,391.0 599.5 610.5 624.5 641.9 661.0 312.1 323.4 343.3 358.5 370.9 240.9 258.1 271.0 282.7 271.5 -2.6 10.9 1.3 0.7 -1.2 1,149.9 1,202.8 1,240.0 1,283.8 1,302.3 459.6 563.4 591.5 602.7 606.5 401.8 487.2 506.0 525.8 517.8 2002 Q4 ............ 354.3 167.6 92.2 73.4 -2.0 331.2 156.2 133.0 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 336.3 347.4 343.7 363.6 162.4 163.7 161.7 173.3 89.7 93.0 92.8 95.5 64.2 67.2 66.2 73.9 1.6 2.0 -3.0 -1.8 317.9 325.9 317.6 340.9 149.6 147.0 152.4 157.5 131.1 125.5 126.3 134.8 ............ ............ ............ ............ Real growth compared with previous year, per cent 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 .................. .................. .................. .................. .................. 2.6 2.8 1.6 1.0 0.0 0.7 -0.7 -0.2 0.6 1.1 2.0 0.9 2.7 2.1 1.2 1.5 6.9 4.9 4.5 -2.9 … … … … … 0.1 2.4 1.0 1.9 0.1 12.3 13.5 4.4 4.8 0.1 5.5 13.5 3.5 7.3 0.4 2002 Q4 ............ 0.4 1.7 1.6 0.5 … 0.7 4.5 1.4 -1.2 -0.4 0.3 0.5 0.3 1.3 2.4 2.8 1.3 0.1 0.7 -2.7 -7.1 -1.9 0.1 … … … … 1.3 -1.5 -0.8 1.5 4.2 -2.3 -1.2 -0.1 5.7 4.3 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 ............ ............ ............ ............ -3.1 -2.1 2.5 Real growth compared with previous quarter (seasonally adjusted), per cent 2002 Q4 ............ -0.3 1.3 -0.1 -0.4 … -0.5 -0.8 -1.9 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 0.5 -0.5 -0.1 0.3 -0.3 0.0 0.6 1.8 0.6 0.2 -0.5 0.5 -3.8 -0.7 4.0 0.6 … … … … 0.5 -0.5 0.2 1.2 0.4 -0.6 -0.3 0.6 0.6 -1.7 0.8 3.0 ............ ............ ............ ............ DEVELOPMENT IN CONSUMER PRICES AND NET RETAIL PRICES Index of net Consumer-price retail prices Energy Imports Total index Table 11 Domestic prices Food stuffs Rent Public services IMI 0.232 0.034 0.370 Weights HICP CPI 1.000 0.080 0.157 0.764 0.128 Year-on-year growth, per cent 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 ................... ................... ................... ................... ................... 2.1 2.7 2.3 2.4 2.0 2.5 2.9 2.4 2.4 2.1 2.1 3.1 2.4 2.5 2.3 2.1 19.5 -0.9 0.9 1.6 -0.3 4.3 2.4 0.4 0.4 2.5 1.7 2.7 3.0 2.6 0.6 2.4 3.4 2.0 1.8 2.7 3.1 3.0 2.9 2.7 3.5 3.7 3.3 4.5 7.9 2.9 0.1 2.1 3.2 2.2 2001 Q1 .............. Q2 .............. Q3 .............. Q4 .............. 2.3 2.5 2.3 2.0 2.4 2.6 2.4 2.1 2.5 2.7 2.4 2.0 2.2 2.4 -1.3 -6.5 4.6 2.8 1.9 0.6 2.2 2.8 2.9 3.1 2.8 4.0 3.7 3.1 2.9 3.0 3.0 3.0 3.3 2.4 3.5 3.8 1.2 2.1 2.2 2.9 2002 Q1 .............. Q2 .............. Q3 .............. Q4 .............. 2.5 2.1 2.4 2.7 2.5 2.3 2.3 2.6 2.7 2.3 2.5 2.6 -0.7 -0.3 -0.2 5.1 0.1 0.5 0.5 0.8 3.4 2.8 3.0 2.7 3.4 1.6 1.4 1.5 3.1 3.1 2.8 2.6 3.9 4.5 4.2 5.1 3.6 2.9 3.6 2.9 2003 Q1 .............. Q2 .............. Q3 .............. Q4 .............. 2.8 2.2 1.6 1.3 2.8 2.3 1.8 1.5 2.8 2.4 2.0 1.9 10.6 -0.4 -1.0 -2.4 1.3 0.8 0.0 -0.6 2.4 2.9 2.5 2.7 1.6 1.7 1.8 2.2 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 8.1 8.6 8.3 6.8 1.8 2.7 1.9 2.3 Note: Weighting basis of December 2002. The index of net retail prices is the consumer price index adjusted for indirect taxes, duties and subsidies for general price reductions. "IMI" is a measure of domestic market-determined inflation. "IMI" is normally larger than the increase in the index of net retail prices due to an overweight of services, for which the price development is typically stronger than for other commodities. HICP is the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices. SELECTED MONTHLY ECONOMIC INDICATORS Table 12 Quantitative index for sales in sectors of Composite cyclical indicator for Extraction of ConNew raw Unempassen- sumer Building Forced ployment materials configer car and sales of and Bank- registra- dence construcreal manufac- Retail property ruptcies tions indicator Industry tion Per cent turing trade of labour force 2000=100 2000=100 Number Balance per cent 1999 ............... 2000 ............... 2001................ 2002 ............... 2003 ............... 5.7 5.4 5.2 5.2 6.1 95 100 102 103 102 99.3 100.0 100.6 103.9 107.8 2,397 2,584 2,682 3,041 3,039 1,636 144,259 1,771 113,634 2,329 96,114 2,469 111,598 2,506 96,501 -2 2 0 1 1 -11 5 -3 -4 -6 -8 -1 -11 -14 -18 Seasonally adjusted 2003 Feb ........ 5.7 105 107.4 213 205 8,048 -2 -5 -21 Sep ........ Oct ........ Nov........ Dec ........ 6.3 6.4 6.5 6.6 103 103 102 99 106.8 110.1 109.0 107.6 282 288 259 210 194 228 213 234 8,391 8,398 9,169 8,897 -2 3 3 2 -5 -4 8 1 -16 -15 -13 -15 2004 Jan......... Feb ........ 6.5 … 102 … … … 240 238 204 210 9,246 8,194 3 2 1 5 -15 -13 SELECTED QUARTERLY ECONOMIC INDICATORS Table 13 Employment Total Private 1,000 persons 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 ........................ ........................ ........................ ........................ ........................ 2,716 2,734 2,750 2,740 2,705 1,896 1,912 1,920 1,901 1,866 Hourly earnings in manufacturing industry Real effective krone rate based on hourly earnings Feb. 1996 =100 1980=100 114.4 118.4 123.5 128.5 133.8 Property prices (purchase sum, one-family dwellings) As a percentage of property value 1995 102.7 98.6 101.2 103.3 108.2 143.7 153.0 162.0 168.1 … Seasonally adjusted 2002 Q4 ................ 2,729 1,892 130.7 104.6 169.3 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 2,709 2,704 2,699 2,705 1,867 1,866 1,861 1,866 132.2 132.8 134.4 135.9 106.5 108.1 108.7 109.4 169.9 173.3 174.7 … ................ ................ ................ ................ Change compared with previous year, per cent 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 ........................ ........................ ........................ ........................ ........................ 1.3 0.7 0.6 -0.4 -1.3 1.5 0.9 0.4 -1.0 -1.8 4.1 3.5 4.3 4.0 4.2 -0.4 -4.0 2.6 2.0 4.7 6.9 6.5 5.9 3.8 … 2002 Q4 ................ -0.9 -1.4 4.3 2.3 4.2 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 -1.3 -1.7 -1.3 -0.9 -1.8 -2.4 -1.8 -1.4 4.4 4.0 4.3 4.0 4.4 5.3 4.6 4.6 3.0 3.0 3.2 … ................ ................ ................ ................ EXCHANGE RATES Table 14 EUR USD GBP SEK Kroner per 100 units Effective krone rate Real effective krone rate based on consumer prices 1980=100 Average .............. .............. .............. .............. .............. 743.56 745.37 745.21 743.04 743.07 698.34 809.03 831.88 788.12 658.99 1,129.49 1,223.33 1,197.74 1,182.10 1,074.99 84.46 88.26 80.58 81.12 81.45 99.6 95.6 96.9 97.7 101.2 104.3 100.6 101.8 103.5 107.5 2003 Feb ......... 743.17 689.86 1,109.81 81.26 100.1 106.4 Sep ......... Oct ......... Nov......... Dec ......... 742.73 743.01 743.70 744.17 662.17 635.51 635.69 607.03 1,065.77 1,065.15 1,073.59 1,060.36 81.91 82.46 82.69 82.54 101.2 101.5 101.4 102.2 107.6 107.5 107.6 108.2 2004 Jan.......... Feb ......... 744.81 745.11 590.55 589.25 1,076.15 1,100.85 81.52 81.20 102.6 102.6 108.4 … 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Danmarks Nationalbank's Statistical Publications Periodical publications (electronic publications) Upon compilation of financial statistics, Danmarks Nationalbank releases these to the public in electronic publications. The publication of new statistics on a specific topic comprises 3 elements: ♦ E-mail with a brief summary, including selected key figures and links to the below-mentioned publications on the Nationalbank's website. ♦ "Nyt" (News) with text and charts to illustrate key development trends, as well as a 1-2 page tables section. The contents of the "Nyt" publications will also include in-depth commentary in order to give users greater scope to interpret and apply the statistics. ♦ Tabeltillæg (Tables Supplement) containing tables with detailed specifications and descriptions of the sources and methodologies applied in the compilation of the statistics. The text of all tables and charts as well as the descriptions of the sources and methodologies are translated into English. Statistical database A statistical database supplements the above statistical publications, and in time the database will comprise all time series included in the financial statistics. When a topic is published the corresponding time series are updated, and they include data as far back in time as possible. Special Reports In Special Reports are published statistics of a thematic character that are not prepared on a regular basis. Release calendar A release calendar for the statistical publications, covering the current month and the following quarter, is shown on the website.