Examiners’ commentaries 2014 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 EC1002 Introduction to economics Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 2013–14. The format and structure of the examination may change in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning environment (VLE). Information about the subject guide and the Essential reading references Unless otherwise stated, all cross-references will be to the latest version of the subject guide (2011). You should always attempt to use the most recent edition of any Essential reading textbook, even if the commentary and/or online reading list and/or subject guide refer to an earlier edition. If different editions of Essential reading are listed, please check the VLE for reading supplements – if none are available, please use the contents list and index of the new edition to find the relevant section. General remarks Learning outcomes At the end of this course and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: ο· define the main concepts and describe the models and methods used in economic analysis ο· formulate problems described in everyday language in the language of economic modelling ο· apply and use the main economic models used in economic analysis to solve these problems ο· assess the potential and limitations of the models and methods used in economic analysis. What are the Examiners looking for? This year we saw the introduction of the new format examination. We replaced the compulsory short questions’ sections in previous examinations (questions 1 and 5 in Sections A and B) with a multiple-choice section which now constitutes Part I of the examination. Part II contains the long questions which, as in previous years, allow candidates to choose one out of three questions on micro- and macroeconomics. 1 EC1002 Introduction to economics Explanations for these changes can be found on the VLE; I will only say here that, while they do serve our purpose of allowing the entire syllabus to be tested in every sitting, the new structure also benefits candidates by allowing a broader scope of abilities to count towards their performance. In the previous year, the overall failure rate on this examination paper was quite high (about 43 to 48 per cent). This year, with the introduction of the new format, we noticed that the overall failure rate has fallen. This, of course, is good news but particularly because it shows that the change in format has not led to an inadvertent reduction in standards or expectations. Multiple-choice questions, although more helpful for candidates in that they trigger one’s memory through the availability of correct answers, can also be quite demanding and engage candidates’ understanding at a high level. We made sure that the type of questions that appeared in the examination papers were balanced and aimed at both a more refined demonstration of abilities and at high levels of understanding. In the multiple-choice section, candidates in Zone A scored a mean of 49.8 per cent, and 43 per cent in Zone B. This is very good and it means that, on average, Zone A candidates had already scored about 25 points, and Zone B candidates, 21.5 per cent, before they began answering questions in Section B. To remind you, Section A is mainly focused on testing what we call the ‘first level of knowledge’ (as were the compulsory sections in previous years’ examinations). This is that level at which candidates demonstrate that they have covered the material and that they understand the basic concepts and models covered in this course. Given that the questions in the Part I, Section A carry 50 per cent of the mark, you can appreciate that we think that if a candidate can demonstrate this level of knowledge across the syllabus, we believe that such a candidate should be allowed to pass. However, we cannot consider a candidate with this level of knowledge alone, as an excellent one. To achieve this level of commendation, candidates have to demonstrate that they have also acquired the second level of knowledge, which is command of the material. What we mean by this is that candidates can encounter a problem, described in normal daily language (like the problem the government faces in trying to persuade the public to increase the use of public transport in Zone A, question 1, or the problem facing the Goode family regarding the use of their garden to grow their own vegetables in Zone B, question 1, or the problems facing artistic jewellers in Zones A and B, question 2 and so on); select the right analytical framework (model) with which to deal with it; translate the specifics of the problem into a known generic framework; and then work out the implications. This level of knowledge is mainly tested in Part II of the examination. This does not mean that candidates are not awarded points for demonstrating Part II questions that they have the first level of 2 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 knowledge. That is, if a candidate chooses the right framework with which to answer a question and answers it well, even though they have not yet demonstrated their command of the material, they will already have gained some points for showing that they chose the right framework and that they know the generic form of this analytical tool. This means that if a Zone A candidate’s mean score on Part I was around 25 marks, and a Zone B candidate’s was around 21.5 marks, it should not be too difficult for the Zone A candidate to acquire the remaining 15 marks, or 18.5 marks for the Zone B candidate, by demonstrating that even if they have not mastered the second level of knowledge, they could still pass by showing in each of the long questions their command of at least the first level of knowledge. The fact of the relatively high failure rate – though lower than previous years – suggests that far too many candidates come to the examination without even the first level of knowledge (that is, knowing the concepts and the models, let alone how to use them). It is not clear to me why this should be the case. The long questions are normally based on the core topics of the syllabus. This means that it is unlikely that candidates would have failed to cover them. Just choosing the right framework in the two questions that are required to be answered, would have facilitate a pass when put together with the mean mark gained on Part I. I must therefore conclude that the relatively high failure rate is due to some level of guessing the answers to the multiplechoice questions on the part of candidates. But what the final result teaches us is that you cannot really pass this examination if you depend on guesswork. But, as in past years, I would like to move away from failure rates and say something about the majority of candidates who not only pass the examination but do well in it. The reason why we are pleased with the introduction of the multiple-choice section is mainly because it allowed for a good increase in the number of Firsts, with quite a few candidates achieving marks in the 90s! The level of achievement of the better candidates is simply remarkable, both in absolute and relative terms. The degree of command which quite a few candidates demonstrate in their ability to interpret and use the models is a sign of fantastic levels of learning. We are confident that these achievements can be replicated by a much larger group of candidates if they have the will to excel rather than the will just to pass. General advice You may want to consider your study process in stages. First, you must understand each section of the material as it is presented in the basic textbooks. Second, you must study the subject guide. If you manage to work your way through it, you are bound to have properly understood the contents of the textbook. Last, but not least, you should 3 EC1002 Introduction to economics try to independently answer questions from the self-study sections of the subject guide as well as from past examination papers, without looking at the provided answers. You should then carefully compare your answer with the provided answer in the subject guide and the Examiners’ commentaries. Always try to reproduce the full and correct answer by yourself. It was very clear in past examination papers that those who failed could not have properly gone through the first phase of the study process. At the same time, it is abundantly clear that those candidates who have done well followed all three stages of the study process. It was clear that they were familiar with the subject guide as well as with previous years’ Examiners' commentaries and that their analytical skills have been considerably enhanced in the process. Consequently, it seems that those who do well, do really well. A possible explanation for candidates’ failure to absorb the subject guide at the basic descriptive level could be the false perception of its mathematical nature. There is, in fact, very little mathematics in the subject guide and those issues, which are essential to an understanding of the subject guide’s exposition, are discussed at length in the mathematical preface. Please make sure that you read it carefully before you embark on the study of economics. There is, we are afraid, no way around it. Economics is an abstract discipline and, as such, it requires the use of logical tools. Without those tools, your ability to make sense of the vast, complex world of social interactions is considerably reduced. For the very same reason that you are required to take a quantitative paper in your first year, you must also have a reasonable command of these very basic tools, which lie at the foundation of human knowledge. This, of course, should not be misread as a call for mathematical competence. Of course, things would be easier if we all had good mathematical skills. Given that most people do not have those skills, we must be sure not to abandon mathematical tools altogether. It is important that you recognise that the subject guide’s exposition is using very basic mathematical tools, all of which are within your grasp. Instead of being stifled by fear, you should recognise that even with no mathematical background, you could meet our requirements fairly quickly. A bit more effort on this front will guarantee that at least the descriptive standards of the course will be met. You might have noticed that in recent years, the course became much more focused. This means that instead of getting acquainted with a little bit of a lot of things, we now wish you to gain some command of fewer things. The key difference here is between ‘getting acquainted’ and ‘gaining command’. For the former, one normally needs to know about economic concepts. Now, we want you to know the concepts. Essay-type or discursive writing is a method of exposition of the ‘getting acquainted’ approach. In such a format, one tends to write about things and to describe them. For 4 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 the other approach – the active-understanding approach – one would need to resort to a more analytical form of discourse. This is a form of discourse where candidates are ‘making a point’ or, to use a more traditional word, ‘rhetoric’, where one is trying to persuade. To think about writing in this way will help a great deal. It forces the candidate, first, to establish what it is that they wish to say. Once this has been established, the writer must find a way of arguing the point. To ‘make a point’, as one may put it, basically means to know the answer to the question before one starts writing. It is my impression that many candidates try to answer the question while writing. A question normally triggers a memory of something that one has read in the textbook. It somehow opens the floodgates and candidates tend to write down everything they know about the subject with little reference to what the question is actually asking. This is not what this course is all about. We want you to identify the tools of analysis which are relevant in each question; we want you to show us that you know what these tools are; and, lastly, we want you to be able to use the tools. Examination questions, in this course, are written in a ‘problem’ form which then requires that you will be able to establish which framework of analysis is more appropriate to deal with different problems. In your exposition, you are then expected to properly present this framework. Only then are you expected to ‘solve the problem’ within the framework. Although some questions may have a general appeal, we do not seek general answers. You must think of the examination as an exercise rather than a survey. Question spotting Many candidates are disappointed to find that their examination performance is poorer than they expected. This can be due to a number of different reasons and the Examiners' commentaries suggest ways of addressing common problems and improving your performance. We want to draw your attention to one particular failing – ‘question spotting’, that is, confining your examination preparation to a few question topics which have come up in past papers for the course. This can have very serious consequences. We recognise that candidates may not cover all topics in the syllabus in the same depth, but you need to be aware that Examiners are free to set questions on any aspect of the syllabus. This means that you need to study enough of the syllabus to enable you to answer the required number of examination questions. The syllabus can be found in the Course information sheet in the section of the VLE dedicated to this course. You should read the syllabus very carefully and ensure that you cover sufficient material in preparation for the examination. 5 EC1002 Introduction to economics Examiners will vary the topics and questions from year to year and may well set questions that have not appeared in past papers – every topic on the syllabus is a legitimate examination target. So although past papers can be helpful in revision, you cannot assume that topics or specific questions that have come up in past examinations will occur again. If you rely on a question spotting strategy, it is likely you will find yourself in difficulties when you sit the examination paper. We strongly advise you not to adopt this strategy. 6 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 EC1002 Introduction to economics – Zone A Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 2013–14. The format and structure of the examination may change in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning environment (VLE). Information about the subject guide and the Essential reading references Unless otherwise stated, all cross-references will be to the latest version of the subject guide (2011). You should always attempt to use the most recent edition of any Essential reading textbook, even if the commentary and/or online reading list and/or subject guide refers to an earlier edition. If different editions of Essential reading are listed, please check the VLE for reading supplements – if none are available, please use the contents list and index of the new edition to find the relevant section. Comments on specific questions PART I Section A You have 90 minutes and you should attempt to answer ALL the questions. Each question has FOUR possible answers (a–d). There is only ONE correct answer to each of the questions. Approaching the questions We will not reproduce here the multiple-choice questions with their right answers. There are enough questions on the VLE with which to practise your learning interactively. 7 EC1002 Introduction to economics PART II Section B Answer ONE question from this section. Question 1 To attract more people onto the public transport system, the government proposes to reduce the price of using the system. However, to offset the losses that would be accrued to the system, the proposal also suggests the imposition of a lump-sum tax on each individual which will ensure that on the basis of Slutsky’s definition, no real income effect will be experienced. a. Describe the initial choice the individual would make assuming the x represents the use of the public transport system and y all other goods. b. How will the proposal affect the choices which the individual makes as well as his, or her, well-being? c. Will there be income or substitution effects under the definitions of both Hicks and Slutsky? d. Would the public transport system recover all the money that had been lost due to the reduction in fares? e. Will the policy be successful? Could the government have achieved its objectives with a higher tax? Approaching the question In this question we examine candidates’ command of consumer choice theory. In our case, the government proposes a scheme to influence the choices which individuals make between the use of public transport and spending their income on other goods. The proposal is for a unit subsidy and a lump sum tax to ensure increased use of public transport without affecting the well-being of the public. a. Here candidates were expected to present the framework of analysis which they would use to deal with the problem raised in the question. We expected to find the following set-up: 8 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 y Io 0 py A y0 U0 0 px 0 py x Io 0 px x0 -use of Public transport b. We now examine the effect of the proposal on the individual. Here, there are two basic elements. First, there is the subsidy which is given through the proposed lower price (π1 π₯ < π0 π₯ ). Second, there is the lump-sum tax which will ensure that the individual stays at the same level of real income, based on Slutsky’s definition, as he/she was before the change. In other words, the government wishes to affect a pure substitution effect that will ensure that people use more public transport. The overall changes are summarised in the diagram below: y Io 0 py Io ο T 0 py y0 y1 U0 U1 A B 0 px 0 py x0 x1 1 Io 0 px px 0 py Io ο T 1 px Io 1 px use of x -Public transport The heavy black line represents the effect of the lower price (effective subsidy) which the government now charges for public transport. The red heavy line 9 EC1002 Introduction to economics represents the final new budget line when we add in the lump-sum tax which, according to Slutsky’s definition, allows people to continue buying their original choice at A. However, as the individual now faces a different price for public transport, the substitution effect under Slutsky would lead the individual to move from point A to point B. c. Here we focus on the difference between the Hicks and Slutsky definitions of real income: y Io 0 py Io ο T 0 py yc H U0 U1 A y0 C y1 B 0 px 0 py x0 xc H x1 1 Io 0 px px 0 py Io ο T 1 px Io 1 px use of x -Public transport Clearly, under the Hicksian definition of real income, we would have gone to point C. This means that the move from A to C is the pure substitution effect and, therefore, the move from C to B (which lies on the higher indifference curve) constitutes an income effect. Under Slutsky’s definition, there will be only a substitution effect as real income (consumption at point A) is unchanged. d. Candidates are now being asked about the success of the government in recapturing lost revenues. The government will achieve its objective in terms of making individuals use more public transport. However, the planned lump-sum tax will not really cover the losses that could be generated by such a move. Before the change, the individual was at point A and the following held true: πΌ0 = π0 π₯ β π₯0 + π0 π¦ β π¦0 After the change (where π1 π₯ = π0 π₯ − π ), when the new budget line goes through A, the following holds true: πΌ0 − π = (π0 π₯ − π ) β π₯0 + π0 π¦ β π¦0 10 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 which means that π = π β π₯0 so, if by offering the lower price the government’s loss of revenue will be exactly π β π₯0 and the lump sum tax covers this in full, the government will now incur extra costs because π₯1 > π₯0 . e. Could the government be more successful if it levied a higher lump sum tax? y Io 0 py Io ο T 0 py yc H U0 U1 y0 y1 A C B 0 px 0 py x0 xc H x1 1 px 0 py Io 0 px I o ο T2 I o ο T1 1 1 px px Io 1 px use of x -Public transport If the tax were higher (π1 < π2 ), then we could have moved to a point like C which would have allowed the government to achieve the same objectives, but based on the Hicksian definition of real income. In such a case, people will indeed travel more than they did but less than they would have if the lump sum tax had been lower (at point B). Question 2 The Jewellery industry is competitive and made up of two types of producers: original local artists and commercial imitators. The cost of production of jewellery is evidently higher for the local artists than it is for the commercial imitators. The consumers, however, cannot really tell the difference. However, without the local artists, commercial imitators will have nothing to imitate. a. Describe an initial set-up in which both local artists and commercial imitators supply the market. b. What will happen in the long run? c. As a result of a court case, the imitators will now have to pay a fixed fee for the right to use the local artists’ ideas. How will this affect the long run equilibrium? 11 EC1002 Introduction to economics d. If instead, the government taxed commercial imitators with a lump-sum tax, would this be, in principle, more conducive to the increase in local artists’ market share? Approaching the question In this question we examine the application of competitive market analysis. A market for jewellery is supplied by two types of producers: commercial and local artists whose costs of production are higher due to the fact that they design and make their own jewellery (i.e. not through mass production). We assume that consumers cannot really tell the difference and that the ideas of local artists are the fuel which allow commercial producers to make their own products. a. Here is the initial set-up of the industry when both types of producers are in the market (assume that there are m artists and n commercial producers): Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) k ο½1 ACi (w0 , r0 ) A A px 0 A D(ο) x i x 0 i x j x 0 x x0 j Given the difference in the technology of production and subsequently the cost of production, the initial set-up where both types of producers are in the market must be such that the commercial producers are making profits. Though we said that the ideas of the local artists are important for the commercial producers, there is no need for them to pay for these ideas as, in the competitive set-up, information is full and free. b. In the long run, the following process will develop: Local Artists Commercial MCi (w0 , r0 ) n ο«m S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) k ο½1 ACi (w0 , r0 ) A A B px 0 Sο½ n οT ο« m ο₯ MC ( w , r ) k ο½1 A k B B D(ο) x i1 x i 0 12 x i x j 1 x j 0 x j x0 x 1 x 0 0 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 The profits above normal, which commercial producers make, will allow the return above the normal market rate of return on capital which would lead to the entry of more commercial producers. This will create excess supply in the market which would lead to a fall in the equilibrium price until we get to the new price which is equal to the minimum average cost of the commercial producers (the move from A to B). Local artists will make losses and this will lead to their departure from the market. As they do so, supply will shift to the left and price will temporarily increase which, in turn, will attract more commercial producers until all local artists are pushed out and we are left with only commercial producers. c. We are now considering how the long run process will evolve if commercial producers were to pay local artists for imitating their products: Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) ACi ( w0 , r0 ) ο« A ACi ( w0 , r0 ) ο C P x ACi (w0 , r0 ) A px C k ο½1 P x 0 Sο½ A n ο«T ο« m ο«U ο₯ MC ( w , r ) k ο½1 k 0 0 C D(ο) i x1 x i 0 xi x j1 x j 0 xj x0 x x 1 We begin at A. Now the commercial producers pay a fee for the use of the local artists’ idea. This fee is a lump sum fee as it is independent of how many units they produce. It is a fixed cost for the commercial producers and equivalent to a lump sum subsidy for the local artists. As a result, the average costs of commercial producers increase while those of local artists decrease. If the fees are properly designed, the minimum of the new average costs curve would be at the same price level that would allow both types of producers to stay in the market in the long run. Relative to point A, however, both types of producers would initially make profits above the normal which would lead to an increase in their numbers. d. An alternative is considered here where a lump sum tax is levied on the commercial producers: 13 EC1002 Introduction to economics Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m A S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) k ο½1 T ACi ( w0 , r0 ) ο« x ACi (w0 , r0 ) A px 0 A D(ο) x i 0 x i x j 0 x j x0 x We begin at A where originally commercial producers made profits while local artists made no profits above the normal. If the tax is levied, it will shift the average costs of commercial producers up and will virtually eliminate all the profits which they had above the normal. In such a case, this will become the long-run equilibrium as firms will neither leave nor enter and the market share of local artists will remain unchanged. In the previous case, when commercial producers paid fees to local artists, there were still profits above the normal for both types of producers. This would have led to the entry of both commercial producers and local artists. While it is not clear what exactly will happen to their market share, their number would have increased! Question 3 Labour contracts are such that for a given level of hourly wages, one must provide at least a given number of hours. This means that workers will not be paid at all if they do not supply their contracted hours. We assume that there are no other sources of income. a. Show how this will affect the supply of labour and the well-being of workers by comparing this to a situation where payment is not conditional on a certain minimum of hours being provided. b. How would a tax on wages affect the choices of labour of those who work the required hours? c. An employer who wishes his workers to work more, offers those who work beyond the required hours a bonus but he is not sure whether to offer a lump-sum bonus or an hourly-based bonus. Which of these options will yield a better result and why? d. Would your answer to (b) be different if the worker were a workaholic (someone who would always work more than the contracted hours)? Approaching the question This is a question about the labour market and the choice of leisure. In the question we are told that labour contracts are such that, for a given level of hourly pay, individuals must provide at least a certain number of hours (say πΏΜ ). It means that a worker will 14 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 not get anything if he/she does not fulfil their part of the deal. a. To analyse the effect that this will have on the supply of labour and on workers’ well-being, we must begin with the initial set-up: x T ο ο·0 B ο·0 Le Le T If the real wage level is π0 and the contracted hours are: πΏΜ = πΜ − Μ Μ Μ πΏπ then the individual will face the above budget constraint. If the individual works less than the required number of hours, he will get no wage at all. The question is how this condition will affect the worker’s labour supply. For this we must consider the fact that there is a section of the labour supply which would not be affected but two sections which would be affected. The first one is when labour supply is upward sloping and the second is when it is backward bending. We assume that for each wage level, the contracted hours are not the same: B ο·0 A Le 0 B U1 U0 ο·0 Le A T Le L L 15 EC1002 Introduction to economics Therefore, if for the level of wages π0 the contracted hours are πΏΜ , then we will have a move from A to B. Without the minimal working hours, the individual would have chosen to work at A but, now, his utility will be maximised if he works at B. The same would apply to different wage levels with rising contracted hours. At a certain level of the wage rate, the individual would have chosen to work more hours than contracted and there will be no change in the labour supply. At the backward bending part we see the following: D C ο·1 D C U3 U2 B A U1 ο·1 Le 1 D Le B Le Le ο·0 A B U0 ο·0 0 Le T LD LB L In between there would be wages for which the choice of hours would exceed that stipulated by the contract. Had all contracts adhered to the same number of contracted hours, we would have had the following change: C ο·1 D D C B U3 A U2 U1 ο·1 1 Le 16 Le Le 0 ο·0 A B U0 ο·0 T Le L L Examiners’ commentaries 2014 where the supply of labour would have moved along the broken heavy line from the bottom and then joined the previous labour supply on the right until it moved along the red broken line again. b. There is now a tax levied on wages and the question is how this will affect those who work the required number of hours. These include those who have to do this (even though it may not have been their choice without the minimum contracted hours) and those who would have worked these hours anyway. A tax on wages means that the real wages will now fall from π0 to π0 (1 − π‘). i. In the case of those who are, as it were, made to work the hours: x T ο ο·0 A B U0 ο·0 (1 ο t ) Le ο·0 U1 T Le Initially at A, these people will still be subject to the same contract and would move to point B where they supply the same number of hours but they will become worse off. 17 EC1002 Introduction to economics ii. In the case where these hours were a choice: x T ο ο·0 A C U0 B D SE ο·0 (1 ο t ) Le U1 ο·0 T Le The substitution effect would lead the individual to point C and the income effect (in the case of leisure being a normal good) would have led him to point D. However, at D he will not be clocking enough hours according to the contract and he would therefore end up at point B. Unlike the previous case – where the individual is twice affected by the contract (his original choice as well as the choice after the tax) – this agent would only be subjected to the effects of the contract once the tax has been levied. c. The employer now wishes to entice his workers to work more than the required hours. He proposes to give them a bonus but considers two possibilities: either to pay a bonus of, say, b per every additional hour beyond the required ones, or, to pay a lump sum bonus of, say, K. Obviously, for the two proposals to be comparable we must assume that the employer spends the same amount on both occasions. 18 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 x T ο ο·0 K B T ο ο·0 ο« b( Le ο Le ) B ο½ Tο·0 ο« K C b U2 A U1 U0 ο·0 Le B Le Le T If the employer paid a bonus of b, the individual who is originally at A would choose to move to point B where he works more but is also on a higher utility level. If instead he was given a lump-sum bonus of K, which is the same as Μ Μ Μ π − πΏπ΅ π )), he would the amount spent under the bonus per hour (πΎ = π β (πΏ end up at point C where the individual will be better off than he was at A or would have been at B. From the employer’s perspective it is clearly better to offer a bonus per hour worked but from the worker’s perspective, he would rather have the lump-sum bonus. d. The question is about whether the individual would respond differently to the bonus if he was a workaholic. x T ο ο·0 ο« b( Le ο Le ) B B ο½ Tο·0 ο« K T ο ο·0 K C U2 U1 A b U0 ο·0 Le B A C Le Le L e T Le If the agent was a workaholic he would work for more than his contracted hours to begin with (point A). His response to the bonus per hour would be to work 19 EC1002 Introduction to economics even more (point B), while his response to a lump-sum bonus would be to work a bit less (point C). Like the normal agent, he too would wish to have a lump sum bonus while the employer still prefers the bonus per hour. Therefore, it is conceivable to conclude that these types of preferences do not properly represent the behaviour of a workaholics. Such individuals who find themselves at B due to the introduction of the minimum hour requirement will now move to a point like C where they will offer much more labour than before. Section C Answer ONE question from this section. Question 4 In a closed economy the marginal propensity to consume of the rich is smaller than that of the rest of the population. There is a proportional tax rate which is higher for the rich people than it is for the rest of the population. To improve equity the government decides to change the tax regulation in such a way that some of those who could escape to the lower tax rate will now be deemed higher tax rate payers. a. What will be the economy’s multiplier before the change? b. How will the change affect the economy if prices and wages are fixed? c. Will your answers to (a) and (b) be different if the government has a balanced budget policy where spending is adjusted to the level of tax revenues? d. What will be the effect of the policy if there are flexible prices and wages in the economy? What would happen to real wages, output and investment in this economy? Approaching the question In this question we have a closed economy where the marginal propensity of the rich to consume is smaller than that of the rest of the population and where the rich also pay a higher tax rate. a. To find the multiplier we need to set the scene. We assume that the share of the rich in income is given by α: c( y ) ο½ c0 ο« c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) y ο« c R1 (1 ο t H ) ο ο‘ ο y I ( y , r ) ο½ I 0 ο I 1r G ο½ G0 AE ( y , r ) ο½ [c0 ο« I 0 ο I 1r0 ο« G0 ] ο« [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c R 1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ] y ο y ο½ A( r0 ) 20 1 1 ο [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c 1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ] R ο½ A( r0 ) 1 1ο M Examiners’ commentaries 2014 b. The government has now changed the tax regulation which means that some people who were deemed to be in a lower tax bracket will not have to pay a higher rate of tax. This means that the share of income which is taxed at a higher rate will now increase. The only unclear element here is whether those who are now deemed rich will also change their behaviour in the sense that their marginal propensity to consume will fall. Both possibilities are acceptable, even though the option where people do not change their behaviour just because the government deemed them to be rich is more convincing. In the simpler case, where we assume that people who are deemed rich by the authorities will also adjust their perception of themselves, the change is simply an increase in the share of rich people in the population. Namely, it is an increase in α. In such a case, we can see that α is an argument of the multiplier alone so the effect of the change will come through the change in M: ππ = π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) − π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) < 0 ππΌ Clearly, as 1 − π‘π» < 1 − π‘πΏ and as π π 1 < π1 , the effect of the change in α is inverse. This means that an increase in α would lead to a decrease in the multiplier. If we follow the other route where we suppose that those who are deemed as rich still perceive themselves as ordinary and continue to behave as if they are not rich, the analysis will be somewhat different, though the conclusions would be similar. As income is only an argument of the consumption function, we must now write a new function where we take into consideration that a fraction of the income, say, β, has now moved from low tax bracket to a high tax bracket: πΜ (π¦) = π0 + π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ )(1 − πΌ − π½)π¦ + π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β π½π¦ + π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β πΌπ¦ Clearly, the difference between the original function and the new one is given by: ππ = −π½π¦ β π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) + π½π¦ β π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) = = π½π¦ β π1 [(1 − π‘π» ) − (1 − π‘πΏ )] < 0 And as all these variables are components of the multiplier we will have a new multiplier: 1 1 = 1 − [π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ )(1 − πΌ − π½) + π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β π½ + π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β πΌ] 1 − π′ where the difference between M’ and M is clearly: π½π1 [(1 − π‘π» ) − (1 − π‘πΏ )] < 0 As M>M’ it means that the new multiplier will be smaller whichever version of the story one would wish to tell. This means that the IS curve shifts to the left and 21 EC1002 Introduction to economics becomes steeper. r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) A r0 r1 B IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘0 ) IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘1 / ο’ ) Y1 Y Y0 Hence the equilibrium level of income will fall and the domestic interest rate will increase. c. In the case of a balanced budget the initial set up will be a bit different: c( y ) ο½ c0 ο« c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) y ο« c R1 (1 ο t H ) ο ο‘ ο y I ( y , r ) ο½ I 0 ο I 1r G ( y ) ο½ ο‘ ο y ο t H ο« (1 ο ο‘ ) y ο t L AE ( y , r ) ο½ [c0 ο« I 0 ο I1r0 ] ο« [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c R1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ο« ο‘t H ο« (1 ο ο‘ )t L ] y ο y ο½ A( r0 ) 1 1 ο½ A( r0 ) 1 ο [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c 1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ο« ο‘ ο t H ο« (1 ο ο‘ )t L ] 1ο M R With regard to sub-question (a), notice that the multiplier here will be greater than in the case without a balanced budget. Also π΄Μ < π΄ means that relative to the original position in the above diagram, the IS curve shifts to the left and becomes flatter. You have not been asked to examine where exactly the IS will lie, but this is something we encourage you to do by yourself. So how will the answer to (b) change with a balanced budget? We now follow the simple version (an increase in the share α which is accompanied by an adjustment of behaviour): ππ = π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) − π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) + π‘π» − π‘πΏ ππΌ While we know from the previous case that the first two elements produce a negative outcome, the addition is positive (π‘π» − π‘πΏ > 0). This means that, in comparison to the no-balanced budget case, the effect of the policy would lead to either a smaller fall in M or to the complete opposite: an increase in M. 22 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 In the second version of the story we will have the same change in the consumption function as before but also a change in the demand for public spending: πΊΜ (π¦) = (πΌ + π½)π¦ β π‘π» + (1 − πΌ − π½)π¦ β π‘πΏ = πΌ β π¦ β π‘π» + (1 − πΌ)π¦ β π‘πΏ + π½π¦ β (π‘π» − π‘πΏ ) which is the old G(y) + a positive number that will lead to the following new multiplier: 1 1 − [π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ )(1 − πΌ − π½) + π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β π½ + = ππ 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β πΌ + πΌ β π‘π» + (1 − πΌ) β π‘πΏ + π½ β (π‘π» − π‘πΏ )] 1 1 − π′ The difference between M’ and M is: π½ β (π‘π» − π‘πΏ ) + π½ β π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) − π½ β π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) = π½[(π‘π» − π‘πΏ ) + π1 β ((1 − π‘π» ) − (1 − π‘πΏ ))] Here, too, the answer is as ambiguous as before and the multiplier may either be positive or of a smaller negative number in absolute value. Therefore, relative to the case where there is no balanced budget, the effect will be: r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) A r0 r1 B IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘0 ) IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘1 / ο’ ) Y1 Y0 Y Namely, we will either move to the heavy blue broken line (between A and B) if the multiplier is still smaller than the one before the change or to the green dotted line (to the right of A) if the multiplier becomes bigger. d. In this section of the question you were asked to examine the effects of the change in policy when prices and wages are flexible. The following diagram should have been presented (assuming that the outcome of the policy would be to shift the IS curve to the left): 23 EC1002 Introduction to economics r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) LM ( M 0 , P1 ) A r0 r1 r2 LM ( M 0 , P2 ) B C IS (G0 , tH , tL , ο‘ ) IS (tH , tL , ο‘ , ο’ ) Y p SAS ( w0 ) p0 p1 p2 A B SAS ( w1 ) C AD (G0 , tH , tL , ο‘ , M ) AS (tH , tL , ο‘ , ο’ , M ) y1 y0 Y Clearly the fall in aggregate demand would shift IS to the left and the change in the multiplier will make IS steeper. The same will apply to the AD curve. There is now excess supply in the market which would lead to a fall in prices and, with it, an increase in the supply of real balances. In turn, this will lead to a fall in the interest rate. In the labour market real wages will increase, which will reduce the number of people employed, and the new equilibrium will be at point B. However, there is still an excess supply of labour in the labour market and this will lead to a fall in nominal wages and, subsequently, to a further fall in prices. The whole economy will then move from point B to C. Question 5 In Woodland, export is dominated by the timber industry. A discovery of a slow-spreading tree disease which reduces the quality of wood has hit the timber industry hard. In an attempt to compensate for the bad news, the Central Bank decides to allow for an increase in the amount of loans in the economy. Assume an open economy without capital mobility and a fixed exchange rate. a. Describe the initial equilibrium. b. How would the discovery of the tree disease affect the equilibrium in the short and in the long run? What will happen to domestic investment? c. Will the Central Bank’s policy be effective? d. How would your answer to (b) and (c) differ if the country had perfect capital mobility and a flexible exchange rate? 24 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 Approaching the question In this question we have an economy where timber is the main export. A slow spreading disease affects the quality of trees produced in this economy and, therefore, would lead to a fall in exports. a. We begin with the initial set-up of an open economy without capital mobility and a fixed exchange rate: NX ( r E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r0 A IS (G, t , Y0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y b. Here we are being asked to analyse the effects of the spread of the disease alone. In the terminology of the model, the spread of the disease and the decline in timber quality imply that there will be a decline in demand for exports. This means a decrease in demand for net-exports – NX – which, in turn, will reduce the demand for domestic products and shift IS to the left of the NX=0 constraint. The NX=0 constraint will shift to the left as there is a need for less income to generate the imports required to offset the new autonomous net exports component of the net-export function: 25 EC1002 Introduction to economics NX ( r E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) NX ( r1 E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 C B r0 A IS (G, t , Y1 Y2 E0 p *0 ) p0 IS (G, t , Y0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y The fall in exports would reduce the demand for net exports NX. This means that at any given interest rate there is now a smaller demand for local goods: IS shifts to the left. It also means that as initial net exports are lower, one needs a lower level of income to offset it so as to ensure that NX=0 once again. Hence, the NX=0 line also shifts to the left. Here we face the question of how far to the left should the NX=0 line should move and the answer, as always, depends on some examination of the alternative definition of equilibrium in the goods market: the investment-savings consideration. Before the change, at A, the following holds as NX=0: πΌ(π0 ) = π (π¦0 ) + π‘ β π¦0 − πΊ After the change we look at a point like B where there is equilibrium in the goods market (on IS). The following holds: πΌ(π0 ) = π (π¦2 ) + π‘ β π¦2 − πΊ − ππ As π (π¦0 ) > π (π¦2 ) and π‘ β π¦0 > π‘ β π¦2 (assuming G constant) then clearly NX<0 for the equation to hold. This means that point B must be to the right of the point where NX=0. In terms of the dynamics the following will be the sequence, in the short run and in the long run, had the central bank not intervened: 26 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 NX ( r E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M1 , P0 ) NX ( r1 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 C A r0 r2 B IS (G, t , Y1 Y2 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y0 IS (G, t , E0 p *0 ) p0 Y We will first move along LM towards the new equilibrium at point B where the goods market and liquid asset markets are in equilibrium. However, as there is a deficit in the current account, this would lead to a fall in the supply of liquid assets and a shift of LM toward point C where the final new equilibrium will be established. c. The central bank’s intervention: In our story, the central bank encourages more loans to help the industry, which suggests an increase in deposits and therefore an increase in the quantity of liquid assets. An easy way to see this is by supposing that the policy will be implemented through the relaxation of the reserve ratio: 1 πΏ = π [ − 1] πΌ where α is the reserve ratio. However, an increase in α also means that the quantity of liquid assets will increase: π = ππΆ + π 1 πΌ where PC is cash held by the public and R the total amount of reserves in commercial banks. This means that, in addition to the change in IS and in NX, there will also be a change in LM but in the opposite direction. 27 EC1002 Introduction to economics NX ( r E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M 2 , P0 ) NX ( r1 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M1 , P0 ) C A r0 r2 B IS (G, t , Y1 E0 p *0 ) p0 IS (G, t , Y0 Y2 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y The shift downwards of LM as a result of the increase in the supply of liquid assets will lead, together with the shift to the left of IS, to a move towards an equilibrium at point B (the fall in demand for exports is offset by the increase in demand for investment due to the lower interest rate). However, at B, there is a deficit in the current account (NX<0) and with a fixed exchange rate policy, this means that the central bank will sell foreign currency in return for local currency which will lead to a fall in the supply of liquid assets. The new equilibrium will have to be at point C. The bank’s policy will have no long-term effect. d. We now assume that this is an open economy with perfect capital mobility and a flexible exchange rate regime. The effects of the fall in exports without the intervention of the central bank will lead to the following situation: LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r A=C r0 ο½ r0 * r1 BOP B IS (G0 , t0 , IS (G0 , t0 , Y1 Y0 E0 p *0 ) p0 E0 p *0 E p* ) ο½ IS (G0 , t0 , 1 0 ) p0 p0 Y The fall in demand for net exports shifts IS to the left. Excess supply will lead to a fall in output and a fall in demand for liquid assets which will shift the equilibrium 28 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 from A to B. At the lower domestic interest rate there will now be an outflow of capital as the return on foreign assets is greater than that on domestic assets. The excess demand for foreign currency (which has already been created by the fall in exports) will lead to an increase in the nominal exchange rate E (a depreciation) which will increase the demand for net exports and shift IS back to its original position at A. In the case where the central bank encourages loans, the following picture will emerge: LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r LM ( M1 , P0 ) r0 ο½ r0 * A C BOP IS (G0 , t0 , r1 B IS (G0 , t0 , E p* IS (G0 , t0 , 0 0 ) p0 Y1 Y0 Y2 E1 p *0 ) p0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y As both IS and LM shift more or less simultaneously, the initial change would be to move from A to B. The fall in demand for exports is offset by an increase in demand for investment. However, the very low domestic interest rate, together with the initial fall in exports, will lead to an excess demand for foreign currency and an increase in the nominal value of E (depreciation). This will increase demand for net exports and lead to a new equilibrium at point C. The intervention of the bank is effective in more than offsetting the effects of the fall in demand for export. Question 6 The climate in Hotland is much more pleasant than that of Stormia. The two countries, however, signed an agreement which allows the free movement of non-working people between them. As a result, a great number of retired people in Stormia choose to move to warm and pleasant Hotland. Analyse the effects of this change on each of the countries individually when: a. There is a fixed exchange rate. b. There is a flexible exchange rate. 29 EC1002 Introduction to economics c. How would your answer change if Hotland had to respond to the increase in house prices by increasing the spending on public housing? Approaching the question This is a fairly straightforward question where we have two countries (which are not necessarily each other’s main trading partners) which sign a deal to allow people from the two countries to move freely between them even though they are not allowed to work in the other countries. In terms of the set-up, this is a question about an open economy with perfect capital mobility. While the question did not stipulate this explicitly, it is difficult to imagine people moving to live in another country without being able to move their assets between the two countries. The story in the question is such that people from Stormia move to live in Hotland. This means two things. First, there is an increase in demand for the exports of Hotland by the people of Sotrmia (i.e. they use their income, earned in Sotrmia, to buy goods in Hotland). Therefore, Stormia will face a fall in demand for net exports (as their demand for imports – Hotland’s exports – increases) while Hotland will face an increase in demand for netexports. Second, there will also be an increase in demand for local assets in Hotland. a. We analyse the effects on the two countries, assuming an open economy with perfect capital mobility and a fixed exchange rate policy: Stormia (A) Hotland (B) LM B (M 0 , P0 ) LM A (M1 , P0 ) A LM (M 0 , P0 ) B r1 c A r0 r1 r0 LM B (M1 , P0 ) A c B IS (ο·, B IS A (ο·, A IS (ο·, y2 A y1 A y0 A E0 p *0 ) p0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y IS B (ο·, A y0 B y1 B y2 E0 p *0 ) p0 E0 p *0 ) p0 B Y B In Stormia, the increase in demand for imports (Hotland’s goods) will lead to a fall in demand for net exports and therefore a fall in overall demand for domestic products. This will lead to a shift to the left of IS and a decline in demand for liquid assets. The economy will move from A to B. Notice that we do not assume the two countries to be each other’s main trading partners, which means that their exchange rates are not necessarily the inverse of each other. 30 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 At B, the interest rate in Stormia is lower than the international return on assets and, therefore, there will be an outflow of capital which will lead to a further increase in the demand for foreign currency on top of the one generated by the increase in the demand for imports. Therefore, as there is a fixed exchange rate policy in both countries, this will lead to a fall in the supply of liquid assets and we move to point C. In Hotland, the effect will be the exact opposite. The increase in demand for exports will lead to an increase in the demand for net exports and therefore a shift to the right of IS. At the same time, there is already an excess supply of foreign currency emanating from the purchase of assets in Hotland by residents of Stormia. Given the fixed exchange rate, this will translate into an increase in the supply of liquid assets which will be furthered by the excess supply of foreign currency coming from the current account. Hence the economy is likely to move straight from A to point C as both IS and LM shift at the same time. b. The case of a flexible exchange rate: Stormia (A) Hotland (B) LM B (M 0 , P0 ) LM A (M 0 , P0 ) B r1 A=C r0 r1 r0 A=C B IS (ο·, B IS A (ο·, E0 p *0 )ο½ p0 A A IS (ο·, y1 A y0 E0 p *0 ) p0 A ο½ IS (ο·, E1 p *0 ) p0 IS B (ο·, E0 p *0 )ο½ p0 B ο½ IS (ο·, Y A y0 B y1 E0 p *0 ) p0 E1 p *0 ) p0 B Y B In this case, the various excess supplies or demands for foreign currency would translate into a change in the nominal exchange rate (again, recall that the two countries are not necessarily each other’s main trading partner). The economies will both return to their original point as there has been no change in the supply or demand for liquid assets and, hence, the level of income for which the equilibrium will be at the level of interest rates, which would not trigger inflows or outflows of capital. c. There is an effect on house prices in Hotland, and the government decides to spend on public housing. 31 EC1002 Introduction to economics An increase in domestic house prices in Hotland would have some impact on the price level index of this country. Therefore, the real exchange of this economy will fall but so would the supply of liquid assets. In such a case, an increase in spending on public housing would increase demand and therefore shift IS to the right. It may, however, only offset the fall in demand for net exports due to the fall in the real exchange rate. However, the crucial point here is that if the increase in house prices has not been overturned by the public investment, then the new equilibrium will have to be to the left of point A below: LM B ( M 0 , P1 ) r LM B (M 0 , P0 ) B r1 r0 ο½ r0 * C A BOP B IS (ο·, B IS (ο·, y2 B y0 B y1 E1 p *0 ) p1 B IS B (ο·, E0 p *0 ) p0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y Therefore, with a flexible exchange rate, the increase in domestic price levels will lead to a recession in Hotland due to the effect of the influx of people from Stormia on domestic price levels. Had the exchange rate been fixed, the outcome would be very similar to the outcome in (a), except that point C in that diagram would be somewhere to the left of the point C in (a). 32 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 EC1002 Introduction to economics – Zone B Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 2013–14. The format and structure of the examination may change in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning environment (VLE). Information about the subject guide and the Essential reading references Unless otherwise stated, all cross-references will be to the latest version of the subject guide (2011). You should always attempt to use the most recent edition of any Essential reading textbook, even if the commentary and/or online reading list and/or subject guide refers to an earlier edition. If different editions of Essential reading are listed, please check the VLE for reading supplements – if none are available, please use the contents list and index of the new edition to find the relevant section. Comments on specific questions PART I Section A You have 90 minutes and you should attempt to answer ALL the questions. Each question has FOUR possible answers (a–d). There is only ONE correct answer to each of the questions. Approaching the questions We will not produce here the multiple choice questions with their right answers. You have enough questions on the VLE with which to practise your learning interactively. 33 EC1002 Introduction to economics PART II Section B Answer ONE question from this section. Question 1 Mr and Mrs Goode see an opportunity to use their own garden to grow as much as they can of their food consumption. The plot is such that with an overall cost of πΆ0 one can produce up to π₯Μ units of food. Assume that there are only two types of goods, x (food stuff) and y (all other goods). a. Describe the initial choice of Mr and Mrs Goode before considering whether to make use of their garden. b. Suppose that the amount of food they can grow π₯Μ is exactly the same as the quantity of x they chose to consume before deciding on growing their own food. Will they still choose to use their garden to grow food in it? On what does your answer depend? c. If they do decide to use their garden to grow food, will they also buy food from the supermarket? d. Suppose now that the whole neighborhood followed suit and there is now a local market where Mr and Mrs Goode can sell their product or buy fresh food but at a higher price than in the supermarket. Will they end up being buyers or sellers of food? Approaching the question In this question we examine candidates’ command of consumer choice theory. In our case, a couple (Mr and Mrs Goode) are considering the idea of self-sufficiency as they can grow food in their garden. At a cost of π0 they can produce up to π₯Μ units of their food consumption. a. Here candidates were expected to present the framework of analysis which you would use to deal with the problem raised in the question. We expected to find the following set-up: 34 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 y Io 0 py A y0 U0 0 px 0 py x -food stuff Io 0 px x0 b. We assume here that π₯0 = π₯Μ which means that the capacity of the garden is such that they can produce in it exactly what they are currently consuming. y Io 0 py I o ο c0 0 py I o ο c0 y ο½ 0 0 py I o ο c0 0 py B’ A B U1 C U0 0 px 0 py x0 ο½ x U2 xο« I o ο c0 0 px x -food stuff Given that the cost of producing food in the garden is π0 , there are three possible outcomes to the Goodes’ decision to grow food in their garden. In the first case (the red line or the furthest budget constraint), the level of cost is such that the couple may end up consuming at point B where the amount of food stuff they would wish to consume is greater than that which they produce themselves. This, of course, is not necessarily the outcome and much of it depends on the shape of their indifference curves. However, if food were a normal good for them, then they would find themselves at point B. Had food been an inferior good, they could find themselves at point B’ where they still make use of their entire produce from the garden. In any case, at this level of cost they will use the garden to produce food as their utility is now greater. 35 EC1002 Introduction to economics If the level of cost (π0 ) is such that they can now consume as much y as before, together with the full use of their garden, then they will stay at point A (the blue line or the middle budget constraint). In such a case, they will be indifferent between using or not using their garden. If the level of cost is such that they find themselves on the green line (the lowest budget constraint) they may move to a point like C where they make full use of their garden but their utility will be lower. In such a case, they will not use their garden to produce food stuff. c. Here we are being asked whether the Goodes would still buy food from the supermarket if they decide to grow food in their garden. There are two possibilities to be considered. In the first one, we assume, as before, that the amount of food the garden can produce is the same as the Goodes used to consume before they decided to grow food in the garden. But in such a case, for them to decide to produce food, the level of cost must be such that it corresponds to the first case in (b – the blue line or the furthest budget constraint). In the case where they are indifferent, they will definitely not buy in the supermarket as their choice would still be A (in the above diagram) so that they will just consume what they have produced. y Io 0 py I o ο c0 0 py y0 B’ B A U1 U0 0 px 0 py dx x0 ο½ x x1 U2 Io 0 px xο« I o ο c0 0 px x -food stuff In this case, we can see that if food is a normal good they would move from A to B where the amount of food they wish to consume is now greater than what they can produce. They will therefore buy dx in the market to complement their food consumption. If they treated good as an inferior good and moved from A to B’ they will not buy any more food in the supermarket. 36 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 d. The whole neighbourhood is now producing food in their gardens and a local has market developed where fresh food is sold for a higher price than the prices at which these goods could be purchased in the supermarket. The development of the local market suggests that there are local people who prefer to pay more to buy fresh produce. For them, the supermarket is not a substitute for fresh food. In other words, fresh food is a different commodity and these people spend their money only on fresh food and other products. The locals who prefer to produce their food in their gardens are of a similar persuasion. Moreover, local producers cannot sell their goods to the supermarket, which has its own cheaper sources. In other words, fresh food is now the new commodity x and its price is π1 π₯ . If all producers sold their entire produce in the market, the prices would have come down and they would have faced more or less their original budget constraint. We must now reconsider all three situations which were described in section (b) above. We shall begin with the case where the Goodes would have been indifferent between using their garden or not. This was the case in the diagram in (b) where the new budget constraint went through point A. When the local market developed and the Goodes buy (or sell) their food in the local market, they no longer shop in the supermarket: y I o ο c0 ο« px ο x 0 py 1 Io 0 py B A I o ο c0 y ο½ 0 0 py U1 U0 dx x1 x0 ο½ x 0 px 0 py 1 px 0 py xο« I o ο c0 0 px U2 Io 0 px x -food stuff Relative to their initial point they can now produce the quantity of food produce they used to consume (only now it is fresh). This means that, in principle, they could sell their produce in the local market and the new budget constraint will have to go through point A. In spite of the fact that in the previous analysis we said that they will be indifferent between using their garden and not using it, 37 EC1002 Introduction to economics when the local market develops they will clearly be better off producing food in their garden. In such a case, they will move to point B which is on a higher indifference curve and sell dx of their produce in the local market. The second case is the one where it was clear that the Goodes would want to use their garden to grow food. Here, however, we have two cases. The first is the case when food is a normal good. y Io 0 py I o ο c0 0 py C y0 B A U1 U0 U2 x0 ο½ x 0 px 0 py dx x1 xο« I o ο c0 1 px Io 0 px xο« I o ο c0 0 px x -food stuff In the absence of a local market the Goodes would have moved from A to B where they would use their garden to grow food as well as augment their consumption with food purchased in the supermarket. However, given that the emergence of the local market means that food products are now only fresh food products, the Goodes would still use their garden as well as buy products in the local market. They will therefore move from A to C. In principle, we can also say that if the Goodes did not consider fresh food as a complete alternative to supermarket food, they may have felt that B is preferred and this would have meant that they will not take part in the local market even though they would still grow food in their garden. The difference will then be purchased in the supermarket. Had they treated food as an inferior good: 38 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 y Io 0 py B I o ο c0 0 py B’ A y0 U1 U0 U2 dx 0 px 0 py x1 x0 ο½ x xο« I o ο c0 1 px Io 0 px xο« I o ο c0 0 px x -food stuff They would have opted to use the garden to grow food (point B’) but, this time, they would also join the local market where they will sell some of their products (point B). Lastly we have the case where they would not have used their garden had there not been a local market. y Io 0 py B A y0 I o ο c0 0 py U2 C U0 0 px 0 py dx x1 x0 ο½ x I οc xο« o 1 0 px xο« I o ο c0 0 px U1 Io 0 px x -food stuff Originally they were at A and with the cost of using the garden to produce food they would have found themselves at a worse position (C). However, with the option to sell the produce in the market (the heavy blue line) they may be able to move to a point like B where they would clearly prefer to use the garden for growing food and sell dx in the local market. 39 EC1002 Introduction to economics Question 2 The Jewellery industry is competitive and made up of two types of producers. Original local artists and commercial imitators. The cost of production of jewellery is evidently higher for the local artists than it is for the commercial imitators. The consumers, however, cannot really tell the difference. However, without the local artists, commercial imitators will have nothing to imitate. a. Describe an initial set-up in which both local artists and commercial imitators supply the market. b. What will happen in the long run? c. As a result of a court case, the imitators will now have to pay a fixed fee for the right to use the local artists’ ideas. How will this affect the long run equilibrium? d. If instead, the government taxed commercial imitators with a lump-sum tax, would this be, in principle, more conducive to the increase in local artists’ market share? Approaching the question In this question we examine the application of competitive market analysis. A market for jewellery is supplied by two types of producers: commercial and local artists whose costs of production are higher due to the fact that they design and make their own jewellery (i.e. not through mass production). We assume that consumers cannot really tell the difference and that the ideas of local artists are the fuel which allow commercial producers to make their own products. a. Here is the initial set-up of the industry when both types of producers are in the market (assume that there are m artists and n commercial producers): Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) k ο½1 ACi (w0 , r0 ) A A px 0 A D(ο) x i 0 x i x j 0 x j x0 x Given the difference in the technology of production and subsequently the cost of production, the initial set-up where both types of producers are in the market must be such where the commercial producers are making profits. Though we said that the ideas of the local artists are important for the commercial producers, there is no need for them to pay for these ideas as in the competitive set-up 40 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 information is full and free. b. In the long run, the following process will develop: Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) k ο½1 ACi (w0 , r0 ) A A B px n οT ο« m ο₯ MC ( w , r ) Sο½ k ο½1 A 0 k 0 0 B B D(ο) i x1 x i xi 0 j x j1 x 0 x x0 x xj 1 The profits above the normal which commercial producers make, will allow the return above the normal market rate of return on capital which would lead to the entry of more commercial producers. This will create excess supply in the market which would lead to a fall in the equilibrium price until we get to the new price which is equal to the minimum average cost of the commercial producers (the move from A to B). Local artists will make losses and this will lead to their departure from the market. As they do so, supply will shift to the left and prices will temporarily increase which, in turn, will attract more commercial producers until all local artists are pushed out and we are left with only commercial producers. c. We are now considering how the long run process will evolve if commercial producers were to pay local artists for imitating their products: Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) ACi ( w0 , r0 ) ο« A P ACi ( w0 , r0 ) ο x C A ACi (w0 , r0 ) px C k ο½1 P x 0 Sο½ A n ο«T ο« m ο«U ο₯ MC ( w , r ) k ο½1 k 0 0 C D(ο) x i1 xi 0 xi x j1 x j0 xj x0 x x 1 We begin at A. Now the commercial producers pay a fee for the use of the local artists’ idea. This fee is a lump sum fee as it is independent of how many units they produce. It is a fixed cost for the commercial producers and equivalent to a lump sum subsidy for the local artists. As a result, the average costs of commercial producers increase while those of local artists decrease. If the fees are properly designed, the minimum of the new average costs curve would be at the same price 41 EC1002 Introduction to economics level which will allow both types of producers to stay in the market in the long run. Relative to point A, however, both types of producers would initially make profits above the normal which would lead to an increase in their numbers. d. An alternative is considered here where a lump sum tax is levied on the commercial producers: Local Artists Commercial MCi ( w0 , r0 ) n ο«m A S ο½ ο₯ MCk ( w0 , r0 ) MCi ( w0 , r0 ) ACi (w0 , r0 ) k ο½1 T ACi ( w0 , r0 ) ο« x A ACi (w0 , r0 ) px 0 A D(ο) x i 0 xi x j0 xj x0 x We begin at A where originally commercial producers made profits while local artists made no profits above the normal. If the tax is levied, it will shift the average costs of commercial producers up and will virtually eliminate all the profits which they had above the normal. In such a case, this will become the long-run equilibrium as firms will neither leave nor enter and the market share of local artists will remain unchanged. In the previous case, when commercial producers paid fees to local artists, there were still profits above the norm for both types of producers. This would have led to entry of both commercial producers and local artists. While it is not clear what exactly will happen to their market share, their number would have increased! Question 3 A place of work which for technological reasons has to be located far from centres of population is, at the moment, paying a travel allowance to cover the time which workers spend commuting to work. The owner is now considering a change of policy and declares that anyone who works less than a certain number of hours per day will have to pay back their travel allowance. a. Show how workers will make their choices before the change. b. How will the proposal affect the total amount of work offered to the employer? c. If all places of work adopted such a policy what would happen to the level of wages? d. Would the amount of work offered to the employer increase if he were to offer, in addition, an extra bonus for each hour worked beyond the one for which one is entitled to a travel allowance? 42 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 Approaching the question This is a question about the labour market and the choice of leisure. In the question we are told that the place of work is located away from the centre of population which means that all workers have to spend some time to commute to work. They receive a travel allowance to pay for their time but this is a lump-sum payment which may or may not be the same as the wage they are being paid per hour multiplied by the number of hours they commute. The key point here is that they cannot choose how many hours they commute. If they do not travel to work, they will not receive the allowance. a. The first step is to establish the framework of analysis before the employer makes any changes: x TA ο TC 0 ο« (T0 ο Le ) ο ο·0 0 px A U0 ο·0 TA L0 e T0 TC T Le Suppose that the time it takes the agent to travel to work is πΜ − π0 . At first he has to pay the travel cost himself (TC) which would put him in debt and he cannot use any of the time he travels to earn any wage to offset this initial cost. Had the employer not provided any allowance, the heavy budget line where he gets a wage per hour would have had to start at that point. However, the employer pays a travel allowance (TA) which, according to the above diagram, is greater than the actual travel cost (TC). The logic of this is that the employer is also paying for the loss of earnings due to the long journey to work but this is not a significant point and it would have been just as well to have assumed that TA = TC. In our case, the individual will choose to be at point A. The number of hours he, or she, will work is therefore: πΏ0 = π0 − πΏ0 π and his, or her, income in units of x (a composite good) would be: ππ΄−ππΆ π0 π₯ + (π0 − πΏ0 π ) β π0 . 43 EC1002 Introduction to economics b. We now consider the new scheme according to which, an individual who works less than a certain number of hours, will not receive the travel allowance (i.e. they will have to pay it back). If the real wage level is π0 and the minimum hours Μ Μ Μ π then the individual will required qualifying for the travel allowance is πΏΜ = πΜ − πΏ face the following problem: x B TA ο TC 0 ο« (T0 ο Le ) ο ο·0 0 px A TA U0 U1 ο·0 TA Le 0 Le ο·0 T0 TC T Le The red (heavy) budget constraint is based on the new rule. If someone works less than the required hours, that person will not receive a travel allowance (TA). Only those who work the minimum hours required, or more, will receive the allowance in full. This means that for those agents who used to work more than the required hours (πΏπ < πΏΜ π ), there will be no change but for those who worked less (like point A), they will have to move to a point like B where more hours will be supplied. They will also become worse off. Therefore, in terms of the hours worked for the employer, the scheme will necessarily increase those hours. c. This is a question about the effect that this will have on the supply schedule and subsequently, on the equilibrium wage level: In the previous section we saw how a worker would response to the scheme given the wage he or she is earning. However, the labour supply depends on what an agent would do at all levels of wages. Given the backward bending supply of labour, it is clear that we have to consider the influence of the scheme on the individual at different levels of wages. At a lower level of wages (upward sloping supply), there will be levels of wage where the individual will not be offering enough hours to acquire the travel allowance and, as a result of the scheme, they will increase their supply of hours for a given wage level. 44 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 ο·0 B A ο·0 TA U1 U0 TA Le Le 0 TC T A Le B L L Therefore, if for the level of wages π0 the minimum qualifying hours is πΏΜ then we will have a move from A to B. Without the minimal working hours requirement, the individual would have chosen to work at A but now his utility will be maximised if he worked at B. The same would apply for different wage levels with rising contracted hours. At a certain level of wage, the individual would have chosen to work more hours than contracted and there will be no change in the labour supply. However, at the backward bending part we will see the following: ο·1 C ο·1 D D TA C ο·0 B U3 A U2 U1 ο·0 A B U0 TA 1 Le Le Le 0 TC T Le L L In between there would be wages for which the choice of hours would exceed the minimum required and will, therefore, not change the number of hours supplied at these level of wages. Therefore, if we look at the labour market as a whole, we will find that the equilibrium level of wages will fall but not necessarily the number of hours supplied: 45 EC1002 Introduction to economics ο·1 C ο·1 D D TA C ο·0 B U3 A U2 U1 ο·0 ο·2 U0 A B E TA Le 1 e L Le 0 D TC T Le L L If before the change we were at A, the new scheme will lead to an excess supply of hours which would lead to a fall in wages but an increase in the amount of hours supplied relative to the original position. d. What if the employer offered, in addition, a bonus for each hour worked beyond the minimum required to qualify for the travel allowance? For those who initially worked beyond the required hours, this is a simple case of substitution and income effect. The substitution effect will push towards an increase in the supply of hours but the income effect will push in the opposite direction as leisure is a normal good. In such a case, it is not clear whether such individuals would increase or decrease their supply of labour. But the answer is far more categorical in the case of those who used to work less than the required hours: 46 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 x T ο ο·0 C ο·0 ο« b B U1 TA U0 TA Le B Le T Le Such individuals who find themselves at B due to the introduction of the minimum hour requirement will now move to a point like C where they will offer much more labour than before. Section C Answer ONE question from this section. Question 4 In a closed economy the marginal propensity to consume of the rich is smaller than that of the rest of the population. There is a proportional tax rate which is higher for the rich people than it is for the rest of the population. To improve equity the government decides to change the tax regulation in such a way that some of those who could escape to the lower tax rate will now be deemed higher tax rate payers. a. What will be the economy’s multiplier before the change? b. How will the change affect the economy if prices and wages are fixed? c. Will your answers to (a) and (b) be different if the government has a balanced budget policy where spending are adjusted to the level of tax revenues? d. What will be the effect of the policy if there are flexible prices and wages in the economy? What would happen to real wages, output and investment in this economy? Approaching the question In this question we have a closed economy where the marginal propensity of the rich to consume is smaller than that of the rest of the population and the rich also pay a higher tax rate. 47 EC1002 Introduction to economics a. To find the multiplier we need to set the scene. We assume that the share of the rich in income is given by α: c( y ) ο½ c0 ο« c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) y ο« c R1 (1 ο t H ) ο ο‘ ο y I ( y , r ) ο½ I 0 ο I 1r G ο½ G0 AE ( y , r ) ο½ [c0 ο« I 0 ο I 1r0 ο« G0 ] ο« [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c R 1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ] y ο y ο½ A( r0 ) 1 1 ο [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c 1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ] R ο½ A( r0 ) 1 1ο M b. The government has now changed the tax regulation which meant that some people who were deemed as low tax payers will not have to pay a higher rate of tax. This means that the share of income which is taxed at higher rate will now increase. The only unclear element here is whether those who are now deemed rich will also change their behaviour in the sense that their marginal propensity to consume will fall. Both possibilities are acceptable even though the one where they do not change their behaviour just because the government deemed them as rich is more convincing. In the simpler case, where we assume that people who are deemed rich by the authorities will also adjust their perception of themselves, the change is simply an increase in the share of rich people in the population. Namely, it is an increase in α. In such a case, we can see that α is an argument of the multiplier alone so the effect of the change will come through the change in M: ππ = π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) − π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) < 0 ππΌ Clearly, as 1 − π‘π» < 1 − π‘πΏ and as π π 1 < π1 , the effect of the change in α is inverse. This means that an increase in α would lead to a decrease in the multiplier. If we follow the other route where we suppose that those who were deemed as rich still perceive themselves as ordinary and continue to behave as if they were not rich, the analysis will be somewhat different though the conclusions would be similar. As income is only an argument of the consumption function, we must now write a new function where we take into consideration that a fraction of the income, say, β, has now moved from low tax bracket to a high tax bracket: πΜ (π¦) = π0 + π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ )(1 − πΌ − π½)π¦ + π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β π½π¦ + π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β πΌπ¦ Clearly, the difference between the original function and the new one is given by: 48 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 ππ = −π½π¦ β π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) + π½π¦ β π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) = = π½π¦ β π1 [(1 − π‘π» ) − (1 − π‘πΏ )] < 0 And as all these variables are components of the multiplier we will have a new multiplier: 1 1 = π 1 − [π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ )(1 − πΌ − π½) + π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β π½ + π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β πΌ] 1 − π′ where the difference between M’ and M is clearly: π½π1 [(1 − π‘π» ) − (1 − π‘πΏ )] < 0 As M>M’ it means that the new multiplier will be smaller, whichever version of the story one would wish to tell. This means that the IS curve shifts to the left and becomes steeper. r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) A r0 r1 B IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘0 ) IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘1 / ο’ ) Y1 Y Y0 Hence the equilibrium level of income will fall and the domestic interest rate will increase. c. In the case of a balanced budget the initial set up will be a bit different: c( y ) ο½ c0 ο« c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) y ο« c R1 (1 ο t H ) ο ο‘ ο y I ( y , r ) ο½ I 0 ο I 1r G ( y ) ο½ ο‘ ο y ο t H ο« (1 ο ο‘ ) y ο t L AE ( y , r ) ο½ [c0 ο« I 0 ο I1r0 ] ο« [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c R1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ο« ο‘t H ο« (1 ο ο‘ )t L ] y ο y ο½ A( r0 ) 1 1 ο½ A( r0 ) 1 ο [c1 (1 ο t L )(1 ο ο‘ ) ο« c 1 (1 ο t H )ο‘ ο« ο‘ ο t H ο« (1 ο ο‘ )t L ] 1ο M R With regard to sub-question (a), notice that the multiplier here will be greater than in the case without a balanced budget. Also π΄Μ < π΄ and this means that relative to the original position in the above diagram, the IS curve shifts to the left and becomes flatter. You have not been asked to examine where exactly will IS lie 49 EC1002 Introduction to economics but this is something we encourage you to do by yourself. So how will the answer to (b) change with a balanced budget? We now follow the simple version (an increase in the share α which is accompanied by an adjustment of behaviour): ππ = π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) − π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) + π‘π» − π‘πΏ ππΌ While we know from the previous case that the first two elements produce a negative outcome, the addition is positive (π‘π» − π‘πΏ > 0). So it means that, in comparison to the non-balanced budget case, the effect of the policy would lead to either a smaller fall in M or to the complete opposite (an increase in M). In the second version of the story we will have the same change in the consumption function as before but also a change in the demand for public spending: πΊΜ (π¦) = (πΌ + π½)π¦ β π‘π» + (1 − πΌ − π½)π¦ β π‘πΏ = πΌ β π¦ β π‘π» + (1 − πΌ)π¦ β π‘πΏ + π½π¦ β (π‘π» − π‘πΏ ) which is the old G(y) + a positive number that will lead to the following new multiplier: 1 1 − [π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ )(1 − πΌ − π½) + π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β π½ + π π 1 β (1 − π‘π» ) β πΌ + πΌ β π‘π» + (1 − πΌ) β π‘πΏ + π½ β (π‘π» − π‘πΏ )] 1 = 1 − π′ The difference between M’ and M is: π½ β (π‘π» − π‘πΏ ) + π½ β π1 β (1 − π‘π» ) − π½ β π1 β (1 − π‘πΏ ) = π½[(π‘π» − π‘πΏ ) + π1 β ((1 − π‘π» ) − (1 − π‘πΏ ))] Here, too, the answer is as ambiguous, as before, and the multiplier may either be positive or of a smaller negative number in absolute value. Therefore, relative to the case where there is no balanced budget, the effect will be: 50 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) A r0 r1 B IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘0 ) IS (G, tL , tH , ο‘1 / ο’ ) Y1 Y Y0 Namely, we will either move to the heavy blue broken line between A and B if the multiplier is still smaller than the one before the change or to the green dotted line to the right of A if the multiplier becomes bigger. d. In this section you were asked to examine the effects of the change in policy when prices and wages are flexible. The following diagram should have been presented assuming that the outcome of the policy would be to shift the IS curve to the left: r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) LM ( M 0 , P1 ) A r0 r1 r2 LM ( M 0 , P2 ) B C IS (G0 , tH , tL , ο‘ ) IS (tH , tL , ο‘ , ο’ ) Y p SAS ( w0 ) p0 p1 p2 A B SAS ( w1 ) C AD (G0 , tH , tL , ο‘ , M ) AS (tH , tL , ο‘ , ο’ , M ) y1 y0 Y Clearly the fall in aggregate demand would shift IS to the left and the change in the multiplier will make IS steeper. The same will apply to the AD curve. There is now excess supply in the market which would lead to a fall in prices and, with it, an increase in the supply of real balances. In turn, this will lead to a fall in the interest rate. In the labour market the real wage will increase, which will reduce the number of people employed and the new equilibrium will be at point B. 51 EC1002 Introduction to economics However, there is still an excess supply of labour in the labour market and this will lead to a fall in nominal wages and, subsequently, to a further fall in prices. The whole economy will then move from point B to C. Question 5 There is a deep recession in an economy’s main trading partner. The Central Bank decides to take action to offset the potential effects of this by working towards a reduction of the interest rate. There is no capital mobility and the exchange rate is fixed. a. Describe the initial equilibrium. b. How would the recession abroad affect the equilibrium in the short and in the long run? What will happen to domestic investment? c. Will the Central Bank’s policy be effective? d. How would your answer to (b) and (c) differ if the country had perfect capital mobility and a flexible exchange rate? Approaching the question An economy’s main trading partner is in recession. Clearly, this will affect the demand for the economy’s exports. The Central Bank is taking steps to reduce the interest rate. a. We begin with the initial set-up of an open economy without capital mobility and a fixed exchange rate: NX ( r E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r0 A IS (G, t , Y0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y b. How will the recession abroad affect the economy? As we have already said, intuition suggests that this will lead to a decline in demand for this economy’s exports. In terms of the model we portrayed in (a), the only way that the main trading partner appears in the parameters of the model is in the form of foreign prices (p*), which is an argument of the real exchange rate 52 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 πΈβπ∗ ( π ). As the prices in the main trading partner are falling due to the recession (excess supply of goods), the real exchange rate will fall too. This means that there is less return on exports in real terms and imported goods are cheaper in real terms. Therefore, the demand for net exports will fall. The fall in demand for NX means both a fall in the overall demand for domestic output (IS will shift to the left) and a shift to the left of the NX=0 constraint as the fall in net exports will now require lower levels of income to offset its autonomous element: NX ( r E0 p *1 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) E p* NX ( 0 0 ) ο½ 0 p0 r1 C B r0 A IS (G, t , Y1 Y2 E0 p *1 ) p0 Y0 IS (G, t , E0 p *0 ) p0 Y The fall in exports would reduce the demand for net exports (NX). This means that at any given interest rate there is now a smaller demand for local goods: a shift to the left of IS. It also means that as the initial NX is lower, one needs a lower level of income to offset it so that NX=0. Hence, the NX=0 line also shifts to the left. Here we face the question of how far to the left the NX=0 line should move and the answer, as always, depends on some examination of the alternative definition of equilibrium in the goods market: the investment-savings consideration. Before the change, at A, the following holds as NX=0: πΌ(π0 ) = π (π¦0 ) + π‘ β π¦0 − πΊ After the change we look at a point like B where there is equilibrium in the goods market (on IS). Here the following holds: πΌ(π0 ) = π (π¦2 ) + π‘ β π¦2 − πΊ − ππ As π (π¦0 ) > π (π¦2 ) and π‘ β π¦0 > π‘ β π¦2 (assuming G is constant) then clearly NX<0 for the equation to hold. This means that point B must be to the right of the point where NX=0. 53 EC1002 Introduction to economics In terms of the dynamics the following will be the sequence, in the short run and in the long run, had the Central Bank not intervened: NX ( r E0 p *1 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M1 , P0 ) NX ( r1 LM ( M 0 , P0 ) E0 p *0 )ο½0 p0 C A r0 r2 B IS (G, t , Y1 Y2 Y0 E0 p *1 ) p0 IS (G, t , E0 p *0 ) p0 Y We will first move along the LM curve towards the new equilibrium at point B where the goods market and liquid asset markets are in equilibrium. However, as there is a deficit in the current account, this would lead to a fall in the supply of liquid assets and a shift of LM toward point C where the final new equilibrium will be established. At C, local investment will fall. c. The Central Bank’s intervention: In our story, the Central Bank proposes to take action and reduce the interest rate. As the Central Bank can influence the supply of money, the reduction in the interest rate will occur when there is an increase in the supply of real balances. Let α be the reserve ratio, and the quantity of liquid assets is: π = ππΆ + π 1 πΌ where PC is cash held by the public and R the total amount of reserves in commercial banks. A reduction in the required reserve ratio (α) will lead to an increase in the supply of liquid assets and hence, for any level of income, there will now be an equilibrium in the liquid asset market at a lower level of interest. This means that in addition to the change in IS and NX, there will also be a change in LM but in the opposite direction. 54 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 r NX ( E0 p *1 )ο½0 p0 LM ( M 2 , P0 ) LM ( M 0 , P0 ) E p* NX ( 0 0 ) ο½ 0 p0 r1 LM ( M1 , P0 ) C A r0 r2 B IS (G, t , Y1 E0 p *1 ) p0 IS (G, t , E0 p *0 ) p0 Y Y0 Y2 The shift downwards of LM as a result of the increase in the supply of liquid assets will lead, together with the shift to the left of IS, to a move towards an equilibrium at point B (the fall in demand for exports is offset by the increase in demand for investment due to the lower interest rate). However, at B, there is a deficit in the current account (NX<0) and with a fixed exchange rate policy this means that the central bank will sell foreign currency in return for local currency which will lead to a fall in the supply of liquid assets. The new equilibrium will have to be at point C. The bank’s policy will have no long-term effect. d. We now assume that this is an open economy with perfect capital mobility and a flexible exchange rate regime. The effects of the fall in exports without the intervention of the central bank will lead to the following situation: LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r A=C r0 ο½ r0 * r1 BOP B IS (G0 , t0 , IS (G0 , t0 , Y1 Y0 E0 p *1 ) p0 E0 p *0 E p* ) ο½ IS (G0 , t0 , 1 1 ) p0 p0 Y The fall in demand for NX shifts IS to the left. Excess supply will lead to a fall in output and a fall in demand for liquid assets which will shift the equilibrium from A to B. At the lower domestic interest rate there will now be an outflow of capital 55 EC1002 Introduction to economics as the return on foreign assets is greater than that on domestic assets. The excess demand for foreign currency (which has already been created by the fall in exports) will lead to an increase in the nominal exchange rate E (a depreciation) that will increase the demand for NX and shift IS back to its original position at A. In the case where the central bank increases the supply of liquid assets, the following picture will emerge: LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r LM ( M1 , P0 ) r0 ο½ r0 * A C BOP IS (G0 , t0 , r1 B IS (G0 , t0 , IS (G0 , t0 , Y1 Y0 E0 p *1 ) p0 Y2 E1 p *1 ) p0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y As both IS and LM shift more or less simultaneously, the initial change would be to move from A to B. The fall in demand for exports is offset by an increase in demand for investment. However, the very low domestic interest rate together with the initial fall in exports, will lead to an excess demand for foreign currency and an increase in the nominal value of E (depreciation). This will increase the demand for NX and lead to a new equilibrium at point C. Here, the intervention of the bank was effective in more than offsetting the effects of the fall in demand for exports. Question 6 The capital city of Gloria has become a great attraction for foreigners who wish to buy homes in it. a. Analyse the effect of this on the economy when the exchange rate is fixed. b. Analyse the effect of this on the economy when the exchange rate is flexible. c. As home prices in the city increase, the government embarks on a project of public housing. How will this affect your answers in (a) and (b)? Approaching the question In this question, there is a flow of foreigners buying local assets (homes) in a country. We assume that this is not a one off event but rather a continuous flow. It means that 56 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 there is an increase in the supply of foreign currency which emanates from the capital account. Other things being equal, this means that an excess supply of foreign currency will be formed in the market for foreign currency. In terms of choosing the framework of analysis, this is clearly the case of an open economy with perfect capital mobility. While it is true that the influx of capital to buy homes in Gloria will have an effect on local house prices and, subsequently, on the general price level, we begin the analysis assuming that this has not yet happened. a. In the first instance, you were asked to analyse the effect of an excess supply being formed in the foreign currency market on an economy with a fixed exchange rate policy. r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) LM ( M1 , P0 ) r0 ο½ r0 * A=C BOP B r1 IS (G0 , t0 , Y0 Y1 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y The gap between supply and demand for foreign currency will lead the central bank to buy the excess supply and, in so doing, increase the supply of money to the economy. As a result, there will now be an equilibrium in the liquid asset market at a lower level of the interest rate. LM, therefore, will shift downwards and the economy will be moving towards an equilibrium at point B where the lower interest rate induces an increase in the demand for investment. However, the lower interest rate also means that the return on foreign assets is greater than that of domestic assets and locals will now move to buy foreign currency denominated assets. This is on top of the increase in demand for imports which is due to the increase in income. Altogether, the demand for foreign currency will increase until the gap is plugged again. 57 EC1002 Introduction to economics b. We now consider the case of a flexible exchange rate. LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r A=C r0 ο½ r0 * r1 BOP B IS (G0 , t0 , IS (G0 , t0 , Y1 Y0 E1 p *0 ) p0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y When the exchange rate is flexible, an excess in the supply of foreign currency will translate into a fall in the nominal exchange rate E (an appreciation). This will lead to a fall in demand for NX which will reduce the overall demand for domestic output and IS will shift to the left. As the interest rate drops due to the fall in demand for liquid assets at a lower level of income, there will now be an outflow of capital as the return on foreign assets is higher than the return on local assets. As the demand for foreign currency increases, the nominal exchange rate will return to its original level at point C. c. We now consider the effects that the flow of capital into Gloria may have on domestic prices and government policy. To begin with, we shall ask what might be the indirect effect that the flow of capital into Gloria will have on the country. Naturally, as there is greater demand for accommodation, house prices in Gloria may begin to rise. This, in turn, will have an effect on the overall price level as housing is always a component of the price index. This will have the following effect in the case of fixed exchange rate: 58 Examiners’ commentaries 2014 LM ( M 0 , P1 ) r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) LM ( M1 , P0 ) r0 ο½ r0 * C A BOP B r1 IS (G0 , t0 , Y2 Y0 Y1 E0 p *0 IS (G0 , t0 , ) p1 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y The initial effect will be the same as in the story in (a). We therefore move from A to B. However, the increase in domestic prices will lead to an increase in demand for imports and a fall in demand for exports as the real exchange rate falls. This will reduce the demand for domestic products and IS shifts to the left. At the same time, the supply of real balances falls so pushing up the equilibrium level of the interest rate. As it is clear that IS will have to be to the left of the original one, we can establish that the new equilibrium will have to be at a point like C. We cannot be sure of what exactly will happen to the quantity of money M at the end of the process but we can be sure that for an equilibrium to be established, the supply of real balances must fall. If we now add government policy to embark on projects of public housing, this means an increase in public investment. IS will therefore shift to the right. If public investment is sufficiently high, this can shift IS back to its original position (and even beyond) and thus prevent the recessional effect which would have been generated by foreigners wanting to buy homes in Gloria. This means that we will end up in more or less the same situation as the one depicted in (a). In the case of a flexible exchange rate: 59 EC1002 Introduction to economics LM ( M 0 , P1 ) r LM ( M 0 , P0 ) r0 ο½ r0 * C A BOP IS (G0 , t0 , Y2 E1 p *0 IS (G0 , t0 , ) p1 Y0 E0 p *0 ) p0 Y In this case, the fall in the nominal exchange rate E together with the increase in domestic prices will lead to a decline in demand for net exports and a strong shift to the left of IS. The increase in prices will also reduce the supply of real balances and ensure that the interest rate stays the same as the international rate as demand for liquid assets is falling with income. The economy will move from A to C. However, here the effect of a policy of public investment will not be able to save the day. If, without the policy, we got to point C, an increase in public investment will cause an increase in demand and therefore shift IS to the right. But this will lead to a higher domestic interest rate and, therefore, an inflow of capital which will lead to a fall in the nominal exchange rate E until we return to point C. If the flow of capital to buy homes in Gloria has an impact on local prices, the outcome will be harmful to the economy whether or not the government follows a programme of public investment. However, if we assume that the provision of public housing will reduce prices then we may indeed be able to return to point A but we cannot be sure about this. 60