The Dual Economy 1. Introduction 2. Classical Approach 2.1 Lewis—Fei—Ranis models 2.1.1 Traditional activities sector 2.1.2 Modern activities sector 2.1.3 Interplay 2.2 Comments and Criticism 3. Neoclassical Approach 3.1 Jorgenson model 3.1.1 Agriculture sector 3.1.2 Manufacturing sector 3.1.3 Development 3.2 Comments and Criticism 4. Neoclassical Approach: An Extension 4.1 Amano model 4.1.1 Agriculture sector 4.1.2 Industrial sector 4.1.3 Development 5. Conclusion. Appendix A: Agricultural Surplus 1 Introduction A distinctive feature of most less developed economies is the predominance of an agricultural sector characterized by widespread underemployment and high rates of population growth, side by side with a small but hopefully growing industrial sector. In such a dualistic (two sector) setting the heart of the development effort may be said to lie in the gradual shifting of the center of gravity of the economy from the agricultural to the industrial sector. Such a process can be gauged in terms of the reallocation of the population between the two sectors in order to promote a gradual expansion of industrial employment and output. A complete understanding of the growth process in such a dualistic economy obviously requires a careful analysis of both sectors and their interdependence. Fortunately, there is no shortage of dual economy models. In this chapter we will examine the key models of the dual economy. For each model we will examine the structural characteristics prevailing in the two sectors taken individually and then proceed to examine in general outline the nature and extent of the interdependence between the two sectors in the context of a continuous process of labor reallocation and growth. 1 This chapter is organized as follows: in this introduction we will first attempt to provide a general definition of a dual economy. Next, we will try to motivate the reader by asking: “What can we hope to achieve by imagining an economy composed of dual sectors?” Finally, we will briefly outline some controversial issues arising from the dual economy models, and identify two strands or approaches of the dual economy. In section 2 we will examine the first of two approaches to the dual economy: the classical approach. In section 3, we will examine the other approach: the neoclassical approach. In the following section, 4, we will extend the neoclassical approach and conclude this chapter in section 5. We now proceed with an introduction to this chapter. Let us begin by describing a dual economy. There are two aspects to the definition of a dual economy. The first is that when we speak of a dual economy we are talking about a theoretical model, and not a real dualistic economy. Of course, we must hope that a theoretical model of a dual economy approximates a real dual economy. The difference between a theoretical and practical dual economy is that a theoretical model must, by nature, be more general and abstract than a real dual economy, such as those of most less developed economies. This means that a theoretical construct may include many features and characteristics not shared by all real dual economies. So we have to be careful— we are not making statements about reality when looking at an economy through a dual economy lens. Rather we hope to highlight dualistic aspects of less developed ‘real’ dual economies, which are dominated by an agricultural sector. Secondly, the possibility of theoretical models of the dual economy precludes a single definition. This is because that mysterious entity, theory, allows for very many diverse models of dual economies. To make matters more complex, these various models can be identified with numerous strands which differ fundamentally. Clearly then, the dual economy, as a theoretical concept is difficult to define.1 Despite these difficulties, we’ll try to define the dual economy anyway: the dual economy consists of two sectors which can be characterized in a number of ways, each having suggestive advantages and each carrying with it the possibilities of error as well. For example, some dual economy models deal with the rural and urban parts of the economy as if they were conterminous with agriculture and industry, or with modern and traditional activities. We can clearly supply examples of rural activities that are modern and industrial, or urban firms that are traditional in substance and spirit. So given the fact that the two sectors in a dual economy can be referred to in many ways, we are forced to adopt some labels for now: let us label the two sectors “agriculture” and “industry”. We will relax these ‘temporary’ labels and use the correct references when a particular model or approach requires so. With convenient nomenclature in hand, we are ready to provide a general definition of the dual economy. The agricultural and industrial sectors (or equivalently, any two sectors in a 1 Of course it is not too difficult to define, identify, or categorize a real dual economy. See the pioneering work of Kuznets and see Syrquin and Chenery’s paper in the Handbook of Development Economics, Volume I. 2 dual economy) are asymmetrical, and thus dualistic, in terms of organizational and production characteristics. The organizational asymmetry stems from the different initial endowments conditions of the two sectors, their spatial characteristics, as well as their differential potential deployment of technology. The production asymmetry arises because agriculture disposes over something approaching “fixed” inputs of land, very little capital, with large pre-existing inputs of labor. On the other hand, industry requires virtually no land, while capital can be accumulated and labor absorbed as needed. Together the production and organizational asymmetries imply that the two sectors will develop in markedly different ways. In other words, there is static and, to a certain extent, dynamic asymmetry between sectors of a dual economy. We now question the utility of a dual economy: “Why do we need it and where does it take us?” In this respect we note that economic development in a dual economy can be characterized by essentially one way flows of labor and resources from agriculture to industry, resulting in a shifting of the economy’s center of gravity from agriculture to industry. This shift is known in the literature as “structural change”. All dual economy models seek to explain or describe structural changes in an economy— this obviously warrants a further examination of structural change. This we do below. The concept of structural change has many uses and abuses2 and requires clarification. We use ‘structure’ in the sense of the relative importance of the sectors in an economy, where the relative importance is measured in terms of production and factor use. Casual observation tells us that the agricultural sector dominates the total economy of a less developed country. This is true in terms of production (where agricultural production is often between 50%-70% of total GDP) and factor use, since typically about three-quarters of the population of a less developed economy is in agriculture. Now, structural change is said to occur during a transition from a low income agrarian rural economy to an industrial urban economy, with substantially higher capita incomes. Note that structural change includes structural sequences such as: (i) labor flows from agriculture to industry concomitant to enlargement of the industrial sector and corresponding to a dimunition of agriculture, (ii) the rationalization of agricultural production, (iii) capital accumulation in agriculture and industry, (iv) increase in total factor productivity, and (v) rise in savings rates. This list of structural sequences is in no way comprehensive, but it serves to highlight the salient aspects of structural change. It is important to note that structural change has been historically uniformly ubiquitous, and it can therefore be said to have been at the center of economic development. Kuznets, for example says: “Some structural changes, not only in economic but also in social institutions and beliefs, are required, without which modern economic growth would be impossible”. Elsewhere, Abramovitz adds: “Sectoral redistribution of output and employment is both a necessary condition and a concomitant of productivity growth”.3 Clearly, structural change is and 2 See Machlup (1963). see Syrquin (1988), Syrquin & Chenery (1986). 3 Also 3 must be an integral part of any comprehensive model of development. It is in this respect that the dual economy is important: it is formulated because of a need to explain, describe and analyze one of the most fundamental aspects of development— structural change. In looking at or characterizing a less developed economy as ‘dual’, the many models of the dual economy attempt to explain and describe structural change. Thus, when studying the models of a dual economy, we seek to gain an understanding of the various aspects and dynamics of structural change. But lest we expect a complete explanation, we should note that the dual economy models treat structural change, and thus structural sequences, as stylized facts.4 Models of dual economies simulate or describe economic development based on these facts. Thus, like any theoretical model, it cannot and does not tell us what is actually going on, but how a transition from agriculture to industry might occur if “things went smoothly”. It is a model of ‘idealized development’. That the dual economy is a model of idealized development has escaped the attention and cognizance of many economists, and we hope that the reader does not commit the same error. Overlooking the fact that models of dual economies are theoretical treatments has over the course of the last four decades resulted in massive economic and social costs when policy makers have attempted to duplicate structural change simply because they think that such ‘interventionist’ policies are called for and implied by models of the dual economy. This is incorrect and we must be extremely cautious not to make the same error. To illustrate what we mean, let us focus on one particular aspect of structural change: the enlargement of the industrial sector with a corresponding decline in agriculture’s size. Many economists believe that because structural change has been ubiquitous, it must be replicated, no matter what the means or cost. These economists believe that agriculture does not require resources or a favorable policy environment because its relative share of the economy declines. Hence, many less developed countries have wildly pursued industrialization policies without regard to agriculture, or to the fact that there have always been increases in productivity and rationalization of production in agriculture before any development has taken place— we will see more on this in section 2.2. Instead, economists in the past have completely overlooked the need for rapid agricultural growth. As a result, many economies are now cursed with economic stagnation, and will continue to do so until agricultural sectors see more growth. All in all, economists forget that the agricultural sector is important because it provides food— one cannot assume that food production will always be forthcoming. Policies designed to increase food production, rationalize production, increase agrarian productivity and growth have been in scarce supply— we hope you take note of the serious catastrophic consequences of taking the lessons of structural change and the dual economy literally. We hope that the discussion in this chapter will convince you of agriculture’s importance. One additional point though. It is easy to say agriculture has been neglected simply because 4 Studies of structural change are in a sense descriptions of real dual economies, while dual economy models are theoretical treatments of the stylized facts thrown up by structural changes studies. 4 economists were in a hurry to replicate the process of development experienced by the now developed world, i.e., structural change in the sense that the center of gravity shifted from agriculture to industry. Instead, it is important to realize that when government planners intercede, they do so within a framework of objectives and constraints, which is ultimately conditioned by the prevailing academic understanding of how economic growth proceeds. And the dominant paradigm of development for the last four decades has been the dual economy. It still is one of the most flexible models around, used for understanding and designing policies for migration, (un)employment, taxation, and food supplies. Therefore, to begin understanding why economists have been prone to think that agriculture can and should be squeezed on behalf of industry, we should start with an examination of the dual economy and its various models. This will also serve our concern with the agricultural sector, especially its role and position in the models of the dual economy. Additionally, it serves our preoccupation with agriculture— the dominant theme in this book. We now briefly identify two major strands of the dual economy models. The literature on the dual economy has had two strands. The first strand has been called the classical model or approach. The classical approach includes the Lewis (1954) and Fei-Ranis (1961) models. The second strand is referred to as the neoclassical model or approach and includes the work of Jorgenson (1961) and Amano (1980). A partial synthesis of the two approaches can be found in Dixit (1970). In this chapter we will be analyzing these two approaches. But before we begin with the classical approach in section 2, it would serve us well if we briefly describe what differentiates the classical from the neoclassical approach. The classical and neoclassical models differ in their conception of: (a) Production conditions in the agricultural sector, and (b) Dynamic of the system. Examining (a) first, we note that the classical approach postulates a production function, f (L), of the type depicted in Figure 1.1. In the introduction to the classical approach we will explain why f (L) has the shape that it does. In contrast, the neoclassical agricultural production function, g(L), shown in Figure 1.2, differs markedly— the reasons for which will be explained in the introduction to section 3. Let us further differentiate between the two approaches. From Figure 1 we can see that production conditions in the agricultural sector differ for each model. Clearly, we cannot talk in terms of an agricultural sector when it involves different specifications in the two approaches. Therefore, to make matters easier, we label the ‘agricultural sector’ in the classical approach the traditional sector, while the neoclassical agricultural sector retains its label. We have labelled the classical agricultural sector the traditional sector because it is traditional, as will be explained further in section 2. For now, let us just say that the initial conditions of the traditional sector imply that there exist traditional activities in the classical agricultural sector. For example, the initial condition of abundant labor on fixed land in the presence of no technical progress leads to diminishing returns to labor and high man/land ratios— a 5 Figure 1: Production Conditions in the Classical and Neoclassical Agriculture Sectors characteristic typical of traditional activities such as peasant farming and pastorialism. This of course means that the classical approach differentiates between the dual sectors on the basis of the kind of activity (i.e., traditional or modern), while the neoclassical approach, as we’ll shortly see, differentiates on the basis of the kind of product, i.e., agriculture and industry. That traditional activities are characterized by diminishing returns to labor is expressed in Figure 1.1. The total product curve in the traditional sector is completely flat for a proportion of labor. We should emphasize that the classical approach often segues the concepts of labor measured in terms of number of workers and hours of labor— we will clear up this confusion in chapter 2, but you must be aware of this aspect of the classical approach to the dual economy. Coming back to the discussion we see that a flat total product curve is equivalent to a zero marginal product of labor (M P L = 0), implying that there is redundant, or surplus, labor in the sense that labor may be withdrawn from the traditional sector without a loss in output. Thus, this surplus labor can be reallocated to the “modern” sector (this being the classical version of the industrial sector) where it may be used to expand this sector, all without a loss in the traditional sector output. In a sense therefore, development in the classical model is “costless”.5 On the other hand, the neoclassical approach characterizes its dual sectors 5 Costless at least to a certain extent because as is evident from Figure 1.1, when that much labor has been withdrawn from the traditional sector that we are at the positively sloped portion of the total product curve, then there will be a decline in traditional output as labor is reallocated from the traditional to the modern sector. 6 on the basis of product, and in the context of less developed economies the natural choice is agriculture and industry. The reason why the neoclassical approach does not characterize the dual sectors on the basis of activity is because it assumes that no matter what the man/land ratio, economic activities will always be characterized by M P L > 0. Thus, the neoclassical approach does not assume the existence of excess labor in the sense used above. Hence, when labor is reallocated from the agriculture to the manufacturing sector, there will be a loss in agricultural output. Clearly, in contrast to the classical model, there is no such thing as a ‘costless’ development in the neoclassical model. Instead, the neoclassical model relies on changes in the parameters of the economy, such as population, technical progress, capital accumulation to effect development. Thus, we see that axiomatic differences in the traditional sector and the agriculture sector leads to markedly different growth patterns and dynamics in the two models— this captures point (b). Coming back to point (a) above, we note that not only are there differences in the production conditions of the (classical) traditional and (neoclassical) agriculture sector, but the two models differ in their characterization of organization in these sectors as well.6 This once again implies that development will proceed very differently in the classical and neoclassical approaches. In the coming sections, we urge the reader to beware of these differences in production conditions and organizational structures in the traditional and agricultural sectors, and particularly how these lead to orthogonal development paths in the two approaches. We now proceed to the classical model. 2 2.1 The Classical Model Lewis-Fei-Ranis Model In this section we will study two dual economy models belonging to the classical approach. These are the Lewis (1954) and Fei-Ranis (1961) models. As its name suggests, the classical approach borrows many of its assumptions from classical economics. So, before we plunge into a detailed discussion of the Lewis and Fei-Ranis models, it will serve us to examine those assumptions borrowed from classical economics. While we cannot hope to treat this matter comprehensively, an attempt will be made to lend the reader with some sort of a classical conceptual framework— we hope this enables you to think like a classical economist. We begin with an examination of the assumptions and concerns present in the classical approach to the dual economy. The classicals were primarily concerned with the distribution of income and how this affected the growth process in an economy. For a detailed discussion see book on classical economics.7 6 The sharp reader will note that within the classical (neoclassical) model, the traditional (agriculture) sector is asymmetrical not only in the inter-model sense— i.e., the (classical) traditional and (neoclassical) agricultural sector differ— but also in the intra-model sense, that is, the traditional/modern sectors and the agriculture/industrial sectors, both in the production and organizational characteristics. 7 See in particular, Lipsey, R., An Introduction To Positive Economics. 7 Having said this, let us examine some of the most fundamental assumptions of classical economics. To begin with, classical economics assumed that the agricultural sector any economy was characterized by: (C1) The absence of technical progress; (C2) A large and growing population; (C3) Land is “fixed”. A couple of comments are necessary here. First, why did the classicals assume (C1)-(C3) for any economy? The reason is that at the time classical economics was formulated, many economists, particularly those belonging to the Malthusian school, thought that all economies were characterized by the assumptions above. Assumptions (C1) and (C2) seem to be quite harmless in the sense that it isn’t too difficult to understand where they come from— after all, most classical economists functioned in the nineteenth century, hardly a time for technical progress in the agricultural sector and times when population growth rates were very high, although the pessimism of population rates outstripping agricultural production growth rates contains a strong dosage of Malthusian doctrines. Assumption (C3) may seem a bit perplexing. To see the logic behind this note, in typical classical fashion, that (1) land, unlike other factors of production, is not reproducible— it is not a produced means of production and is therefore fixed in quantity, and (2) increases through extensive cultivation (that is, increasing cultivable land through bringing in marginally inferior land, or just simply, cultivating new land) and intensive cultivation (in which yield per unit land is raised through technological progress) is not feasible because population pressures has already pushed cultivable land to its limit. Besides intensive cultivation has been already ruled out by virtue of assumption (C1). Now, (C1)-(C3) taken together simply imply that agriculture is, or soon will be, characterized by the presence of a large population relative to fixed land— i.e., the existence of very high man/land ratios which in turn implies that there are diminishing returns to labor. We have depicted this situation in Figure 2. In Figure 2.1 we have the production contour lines M, M . These production contours represent the production function in the agricultural sector with various inputs of land and labor. The two ridge lines Ou∗ and Ov ∗ mark off the region of factor substitutability. For example, below Ov ∗ the production contours become perfectly horizontal indicating that, with land held constant, any further increases in labor render that factor redundant, as output can no longer be raised. The counter case— where the production contours become perfectly vertical indicating that with labor held constant, any further increases in land either through intensive or extensive cultivation will not be possible— does not interest us because we have made the assumption that population is large and growing. So, we return to the first case where production contours are flat because of the fixity of land. When an economy is endowed with say Ot units of land, we can see that OG units of labor can be absorbed in agricultural production without becoming redundant.8 . But in the case of an overpopulated economy, in which agricultural 8 This is tantamount to the case of a low man-land ratio, 8 L T population is say OP ,9 we see that GP units of labor is redundant. We see therefore how a high TL leads to diminishing returns to labor— so low in fact that a major proportion of the agrarian population becomes unproductive to the point of being redundant, a quality which we label as surplus labor. That this is so is underscored in panels 1 and 3. In Figure 2.2 the total product of labor curve (T P L) becomes completely flat after OG units of labor. Whether you choose to measure labor in number or hours does not really matter. But for simplicity, let’s say labor is measured in terms of number of workers. This flat portion N M reflects that output can no longer be raised with additional units of workers. Correspondingly, the M P L curve in Figure 2.3 reflects the same result: after OG units of labor the M P L curve becomes completely flat and equal to zero. Clearly, any additional units of labor after OG will not raise output since M P L = 0. This property, or rather, economic implication of M P L = 0 was adopted by Rosentein-Rodan (1943) and Nurkse (1951) in the middle of this century. More specifically, they realized that the classical assumption of agriculture sectors characterized by high man-land ratios offers a way for development, or accounts for one way that a structural change may proceed: the presence of redundant labor in the agricultural sector brought about by high TL means that surplus labor or this parasitic population— so called because it does not contribute anything to output— can be transferred out of the agricultural sector with no loss in agricultural output. Surplus labor is therefore a supply of labor which, given the preponderence of the agricultural sector in less developed economies, is likely to be of major quantitative importance in the development process of overpopulated less developed economies. This is the classical tradition which Lewis inherited. His model of the dual economy contained two analytical advantages over his predecessors. The first was his logical account of how development would proceed in a dual economy characterized by classical conditions. This is a point which will anyway be impressed upon you repeatedly in the discussion to follow, so we will not pay much attention it here. The second advantage was that the sources of surplus labor (available for costless development) in the Lewis model were not only in the agricultural sector but all those sections of the economy where resources were so scarce relative to an economy with a large population (a situation also known as a labor surplus economy, which is not to be confused with surplus labor, which is simply redundant labor) that marginal product of labor was forced down to zero. We want to emphasize that it is the abundance of labor relative to a scarce resource (land) which enabled the agricultural sector to be a source of labor offering the possibility of costless development in the Rosentein-Rodan framework. Lewis, on the other hand, asked a very obvious question: “Are there other sections of an economy which may be sources of surplus labor?” Put another way, this question becomes: “Are there other sections with high man/some-resource ratios which cause labor to be unproductive to the extent of M P L = 0, i.e., 9 Corresponding to a high L T 9 Figure 2: Classical Production 10 Conditions in Agriculture surplus labor?” Before we answer this question, a slight digression is necessary. It might appear that Ex Ante it makes no difference whether the agriculture sector is the sole source of surplus labor or whether there are other sources of surplus labor. We dispute this assertion, but we first note that Ex Post it certainly pays to know whether surplus labor originates strictly in agriculture. Look: if agriculture is the single source of surplus labor then the planner should have focused on policies designed to tap this surplus labor in agriculture. On the other hand, if there are sources of surplus labor other than agriculture, then the scope of the model widens. Compared to the earlier case when agriculture was the single source of labor the pace and extent of the development process will be markedly different. Had the planner known this Ex Ante she could have designed policies to take advantage of this situation. Moreover, if agriculture is not the only source of surplus labor, then Ex Ante knowledge of a comprehensive supply of surplus labor should not be taken to mean that policies designed to reallocate labor from these ‘other’ sources of surplus labor are equally applicable to agriculture. Another way to make the same point is to note that when there are sources of surplus labor other than agriculture, we may tend to think of agriculture as ‘just another source of labor’ and neglect its importance as a supplier of food. This is an important point and we will return to it later in section 2.2. Returning to our earlier query of whether agriculture is the single source of surplus labor, we see that if we try to answer in the context of less developed economies, the answer must be that there are indeed sources of surplus labor other than the agricultural sector. Why? Casual observation tells us that overpopulated less developed economies have not only a shortage of land compared to a large and growing population, but a shortage of all other resources, especially capital. Labor surplus economies are therefore characterized not only by high man/land ratios but also high man/capital ratios. Thus, sections of L an economy which are characterized by high K are also a source of surplus labor, which form a labor supply to the growing sections of the economy. In this context, Lewis says: “In those countries where population is so large relatively to capital and natural resources ... there are large sectors of the economy where the marginal productivity of labor is negligible, zero, or even negative”.10 Those sections of the economy which are sources of surplus labor are collectively labelled the traditional sector.11 The traditional sector is so called because economic activities tend to be what one may typically what one might 10 W. A. Lewis, ‘Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor, in Agarwala & Singh, The Economics of Underdevelopment, p. 402. 11 Clearly, it is a monumental error— which has been made before and will undoubtedly be made again— to equate the traditional sector with agriculture. True, agricultural activities in most less developed economies may be traditional but the reverse does not hold true, as will be clear from the examples of traditional activities in section 2.1. 11 label traditional— i.e., unproductive, uncommercialized, production units which are frequently coincident with household units. The principal reason for traditional activities to be traditional is simply because of M P L = 0. It must be pointed out that once we depart from ascribing M P L = 0 to high man-land ratios and simply recognize that a more deeper cause is high man-capital ratios, we get a better idea of why activities in surplus labor sections of an economy tend to be traditional— these activities are not fructified by capital, which incidentally is another classical assumption invoked heavily in the classical approach to the dual economy: (C5) Capital fructifies labor’s efforts. We can therefore approach the issue of traditional activities from the other side. Using (C5) it is clear that those sections of the economy, where high man-capital ratios persist, will be characterized by activities “unfructified” by capital and thus resulting L in M P L = 0. A high K in the absence of technical progress gives rise to highly unproductive activities characterized by primitive technology and uncommercialized small-scale production units with surplus labor (again, in the sense that additional labor will not affect output), and production units which frequently coincide with households. We can now see that the traditional sector as a source of labor supply, when contrasted with the formulation where the agriculture sector was the single source of labor, has an obvious analytical advantage: since the (theoretical) supply of surplus labor in the Lewis dual economy is more comprehensive, development in this model can proceed costlessly to a greater extent. Having introduced the traditional sector, let us quickly describe the “modern” sector. The modern sector is by a matter of difference what the traditional sector is not. It is characterized by high capital/man ratios, commercialized production, productive economic activities characterized by M P L > 0, and production units which do not coincide with household units. We assume that the modern sector, at the beginning of the development process in the Lewis dual economy, is small compared to the traditional sector. But while it is presumed to be small it is assumed to be a growing sector. The Lewis model does not explain, nor does it care, how or why the modern sector may begin growing.12 Instead, it assumes that for whatever reason and source, there has been an investment in the modern sector permitting its creation and viability for future growth. Having emphasized the initial conditions— and therefore the assumptions— of the classical approach, we now discuss each sector, describing its structural characteristics and then move on to a discussion of the development process in the classical dual economy. Let us begin with the traditional sector. We choose to discuss the Lewis and Fei-Ranis model collectively because the difference between the two is the degree of exposition. They share the same assumptions. though they label some concepts differently. We will point out these differences whenever necessary. 12 In this respect see Hussain, Sayed Mushtaq, (1968) 12 2.1.1 Traditional activities sector We now examine some examples of traditional activities in less developed countries. The first and most prominent example is of course agriculture. Typically, agricultural family holdings are so small that if some members of the family obtained other employment the remaining members could cultivate the holding just as well. Now, a slight digression: one can imagine this “constant output” as a consequence of surplus labor in two ways: (1) that there are so many workers on a piece of land that the departure of some makes no difference to output, because overcrowding was previously so chronic that the removal of some workers does not affect output. One can imagine, for example, 500 people squeezed on 1 acre of land— clearly, if one worker departs and 499 remain, production is very likely to remain at previous levels— surplus labor is then said to exist. (2) One can imagine that all that really matters to keep output constant is that the total labor hours worked before and after the migration of a (or some) workers remains the same. Under this scenario, we assume that the remaining workers put in more labor hours, just sufficient to maintain total labor hours worked, and hence output, at previous levels— again, surplus labor is said to exist. The first scenario is compatible with sheer overcrowding— to such an extent that the withdrawal of a worker makes no difference to output. The second scenario is compatible with leisure satiation— there is so much leisure that the remaining workers are glad to work harder. This second aspect is a distinctly classical concept, for neoclassical economics as you know treats leisure as a superior good. The issue of what surplus labor is will be taken up in the next chapter. For now, it must be reiterated that the Lewis model does not distinguish clearly between which of the two scenarios of surplus labor is relevant. Lewis mentions briefly the possibility of the remaining workers working harder but does not develop the conditions for this, and seems to also suggest the first scenario at various points. For the discussion of development in the Lewis model, it does not really matter which scenario is more relevant, but the issue will become important in chapter 2. Let’s resume our discussion of the traditional sector: other examples of traditional activities are those in the so-called ‘informal’ sector: casual jobs such as dock workers, coolies, jobbing gardeners, rickshaw pullers, lottery sellers and petty retailing. All of these are characterized by high man/capital ratios, redundant13 labor and an organizational structure where family holdings typically are the production units; thus the family, or part of it, participates in production and earning— we will return to this point shortly. Clearly, while the traditional sector consists of markedly different activities, it is the fact that all these activities are characterized by M P L = 0 that allows us to speak in terms of a 13 Lewis notes: “.. These occupations usually have a multiple of the number they need, each of them earning very small sums from occasional employment; frequently their number could be halved without reducing output in this sector” 13 traditional sector. We now discuss M P L = 0. Firstly, we must emphasize that M P L = 0 arises not because of a lack of effective demand but because of a technology and resource constraint. Secondly, Lewis does not claim that the entire labor force in the traditional sector is characterized by M P L = 0; only that a substantial portion of it is producing with M P L = 0. The reason for this is straightforward. There are some traditional activities which may well be productive. But the point remains that a major proportion of activities will be unproductive. Most traditional activities in less developed economies have small holdings, whether these are land or capital in the form of tools for example. Furthermore, most agricultural traditional production units, and thus households, are spatially dispersed, creating a market with massive transportation costs and slow dissipation of information. All this means that most traditional activities (of which the major portion in less developed economies is the agricultural sector) will be unproductive in the sense of M P L = 0. Thirdly, note that M P L = 0 is used to convey the spirit of unproductive activity in the traditional sector. It is not an empirical statement nor is it, Lewis claims, essential to the classical model. For example, Lewis notes that if we ignore the question, “Which sections of the economy are characterized by M P L = 0?”, and simply ask, “Which sections of the economy are a potential source of surplus labor?”, the answer would include women. In Lewis’ opinion, the point of M P L = 0 is to simply underscore the existence of a comprehensive, massive source of labor supply to the modern sector. The economic activities of women, Lewis emphasizes, are characterized by M P L > 0. As such M P L = 0 is used for convenience- to demonstrate the point that initial conditions of the traditional sector give rise to unproductive or traditional activities, the agents of which are a potential source of labor supply for the expansion of the modern sector. Fourthly, the existence of M P L = 0 in the traditional sector raises the issue of compensation. From the point of marginal productivity calculus, it seems curious that a worker could be working at M P L = 0 and yet earn a positive wage. That workers must earn a positive wage is obvious. For if not, then in an overpopulated economy with scarce food supplies forced by high manland ratios, starvation will prevail. Clearly some arrangement must exist in the traditional sector by which workers earn a positive real wage despite M P L = 0. This arrangement is best explained through the organizational characteristics of the traditional sector. Given the large number of spatially dispersed workers with M P L = 0, the frequent coincidence of households and production units, the real wage in the traditional sector must be based on some institutional sharing arrangement rather than on the marginal productivity calculus. Now a slight digression. Note that sharing arrangements pose no logical problems in the case of selfemployed workers. Consider for example the case of a family cultivating a plot of land. Here the members of a family simply share in the work and the income. Notice that this is only possible because the household is coincident with the production unit, i.e., the farm. But the work and income sharing explanation 14 is not so simple when we consider cases where labor is employed, i.e., labor is engaged in traditional activities for wages. Why would an employer pay a positive wage when his workers are producing with M P L = 0? Lewis explained that this was because in an overpopulated country: The code of ethical behaviour so shapes itself that it becomes good form for each person to offer as much employment as he can.. Social prestige requires people to have servants.. This is found not only in domestic service, but in every sector of employment.14 Notice that this notion of an institutional wage does not require that some of the traditional labor force must be redundant in the sense that it can be removed without affecting output adversely— only that some proportion of the traditional population receive a food allocation, or earnings, in excess of its marginal product. It is in this sense that organizational dualism is an important feature of the labor market. Given the abundance of labor and relative scarcity of cooperating factors, mainly land and capital, this is what is meant by the phenomenon of underemployment: a situation in which productive employment opportunities are limited not because of a lack of effective demand but because of technological and resource constraints. The initially heavy endowment of labor relative to land and capital means that a substantial portion of the labor force faces a M P L = 0 condition which requires, especially in the context of less developed economies, a wage well above the neoclassical marginal product to be agreed upon by the community, the family, the commune or whatever organizational structure exists. Such a wage in excess of the marginal product may be set equal to the average product or— in order to leave a surplus, say for the head of the family— at some percentage of the average product. The LFR model assumes that real wage in the traditional sector equals the average product of labor. Nor do we need to assume that this institutional or bargain wage is constant over time. Such determination is likely to persist as long as the supply of traditional labor remains disguisedly unemployed in the sense that there are too many people relative to scarce resources to permit a sharing nexus to be replaced by competitive rules.15 The existence of an institutional wage in the traditional sector should thus not be confused either with assertions about M P L = 0, used for convenience in formal modeling, or equated in general to the average product, again a matter of sheer convenience. Instead, the basic assertion is that wages in the traditional sector contain a strong dosage of output “sharing”, largely a function of the fact that people cannot be readily be dismissed when household and production units coincide and/or when decisions are made on a collective basis. We should also note that by its definition, the traditional institutional wage cannot be scientifically measured, but in the context of overpopulated less de14 Ibid., p. 403. then is the definition of disguisedly unemployed: that portion of the traditional sector which earns an institutional wage higher than its marginal product. Note that surplus labor is not the same as disguised unemployment, though one can expect the two to go together. 15 This 15 Figure 3: Total and Marginal Product in the Traditional Sector 16 veloped economies, the real wage is likely to be related to the consumption standard as a floor.16 LFR, in the classical tradition, assume that the institutional wage is so low that it equals the subsistence consumption wage. Hence the real wage in the traditional sector is a small but positive quantity. In Figure 3 we have summarized the production and organizational characteristics of the traditional sector. Here we see in panel 1 that if the total population in the traditional sector is OP then the surplus labor is equal to GP . We also see that AP L is equal to MP OP , which is the slope of the line OM . We assume that the wage w persists in the traditional sector as long as there is disguised unemployment in this sector. Thus, in Figure 3.2 it is clear that the surplus labor (GP ) and part of the M P L > 0 portion of the population (OG), earns a real wage w which is above M P L.17 To reiterate, workers in the tradiQ tional sector whose wage, w = AP L = MP OP = L , is above their M P L are called 18 disguisedly unemployed, and w persists in the traditional sector as long as there is disguised unemployment. Another way to say this is that competitive wage determination according to marginal product calculus will come in effect only after the supply of the disguisedly unemployed, SP , is allocated out of the traditional and into the modern sector. Our repeated statements that sharing arrangements persist as long as disguised unemployment exists, serves to underscore the essence of the classical model, and how this manifests itself in the LFR model. Indeed, the classical scenario of family enterprises, characterized by work and income sharing, as well as subsistence wages is captured through the concept of disguised unemployment— that portion of the labor force which consumes in excess of its earnings. If you have been perceptive enough, you will notice that we have not said anything about a connection between surplus labor and sharing arrangements. That is because, there is no unambiguous relationship between surplus labor and work and income sharing. Indeed, surplus labor, as will be demonstrated in chapter 2, can exist even if M P L > 0— a point which serves to illustrate that surplus labor is not unique to M P L = 0— a condition one can expect to hold with high probability in a sharing nexus. Moreover, it is clear that the real wage in the traditional sector obviously sets the floor to modern sector wages: if the modern sector is to attract labor from the traditional sector, it must at the very least offer a wage equal or higher than the real wage in the traditional sector. And here is where the possibility of rapid and extensive growth exists: because w in overpopulated economy with 16 Institutional explanations of the greater than marginal product real wage in the traditional sector has not been satisfactory to modern economists. Consequently many attempts have been made to link up the determination of the institutional real wage to peculiarities of rural organization, tenure arrangements, linked market failures etc. See Binswanger & Rosenzweig (1984). The empirical reality of a gently upward-sloping supply curve has been demonstrated in the case of the agricultural sector by Sen (1966) 17 i.e., The disguisedly unemployed in this sector is the portion SP . 18 We note here that Lewis labels the portion GP as surplus labor while SP is labelled disguised unemployment. In contrast, Fei-Ranis label surplus labor as redundant labor while the disguisedly unemployed are also known as surplus labor in their model. Clearly, there is enormous scope for confusion, and to keep matters tractable, we stick with Lewis’ usage: i.e., surplus labor is the portion GP (which coincides with Fei-Ranis’ redundant labor force), while the portion SP is the disguisedly unemployed portion of the labor force. 17 scarce resources will be close to subsistence level, the modern sector need only pay a slightly higher wage (just how much higher we will see in the next section) to execute a transfer of labor from the traditional to the modern sector. The subsistence wage in the traditional sector permits the expansion of old industries and the creation of new ones without limit at the existing wage; or, to put it another way, shortage of labor does not constrain the modern sector’s growth. We now analyze the modern sector before moving on to the interplay between the two sectors. 2.1.2 Modern activities sector As mentioned earlier, the LFR model assumes that a less developed, labor surplus economy,19 consists of a traditional sector coexisting with a modern sector. We now describe the modern sector. The modern sector is by definition what the traditional sector is not. By difference, modern activities are productive, i.e., M P L > 0 (recall (C5), uses modern techniques and has specialized production. Accordingly, its’ initial conditions are simply that there exist low man/land ratios as well as high K L . Therefore, labor will not be unproductive and redundant. Instead, M P L > 0, and wages will be determined according to neoclassical marginal product calculus. This is an important point, for if wages are determined according to marginal product and not some institutional sharing arrangements, then it means that the organization of production units in the modern sector approaches that of commercialized organization. Unlike her traditional counterpart, the modern capitalist is “more commercially minded, and more conscious of efficiency, cost and profitability”.20 Figure 4 depicts the production and organization conditions in the modern sector. Notice the production and organizational asymmetries between the modern and traditional sectors. Panel 1 depicts the various production contours in the modern sector. The absence of any factor in abundance relative to another factor ensures that the expansion path OE is continually upward sloping, and that the production contours do not become vertical or horizontal at the extremes, as was the case in the traditional sector. Hence, assuming constant returns to scale, the modern sector production function, g(L), can be depicted in panel 2. Corresponding to this T P L curve we have the modern sector M P L, which is always positive, indicating that no factor saturates the production process. Formally, we may express g(L) as: Q = g(L), g (L) < 0, and limL→∞ g (L) = 0. We note that the modern sector encompasses the modern sections of an economy. What we have is not one island of expanding modern employment, but rather a number of such tiny islands. This is very typical of countries in their early stages of development.21 We find a few industries highly capitalized, 19 i.e., an economy with a large population compared to scarce resources, such that high man-resource ratios persist. 20 Lewis, W. A., ‘Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor, in Agarwala & Singh, The Economics of Underdevelopment, p. 407. 21 This is a Lewisian assumption: that a great number of islands of expanding modern 18 19 Figure 4: Production Conditions in the Modern Sector such as mining or electric power, side by side with the most primitive techniques; a few high class shops, surrounded by masses of old style traders; a few highly capitalized plantations, surrounded by a sea of peasants. Though the modern sector can be subdivided into islands, it remains a single sector because of the effect of competition in tending to equalize the earnings on capital. The competitive principle does not demand that the same amount of capital per person be employed on each ‘island’, or that average profit per unit of capital be the same, but only that the marginal profit be the same. Having described the basic characteristics of the modern sector we turn to the most important aspect of the model: how does growth, and greater employment, occur in the modern sector? The answer to this is, again, a classical assumption: the LFR model assumes that the modern sector grows through capital accumulation. Capital accumulation is the continued investment of capitalists surplus which is simply the profit left after payment of the total costs. Thus, to calculate the size of the capitalists surplus, we need to first compute the total costs— let us concentrate on total variable costs of labor first. To calculate the wage bill we will have to first address the issue of labor demand and supply in the modern sector. Addressing labor supply first we see that as long as there is surplus labor in the traditional sector (and we assume that there is) the labor supply curve ww to the modern sector will be flat, indicating that any amount of labor can be hired at the prevailing wage w. We have shown ww in Figure 4.3. On the issue of labor demand we see that since neoclassical marginal product calculus is in effect, the M P L curve is the labor demand curve. Thus, the equilibrium in the labor market, where the quantity of labor demanded is equal to the quantity supplied, will occur where the labor demand and supply curves intersect. Hence, it might appear that the total wage bill is simply the quantity of labor hired in equilibrium L2 multiplied by the prevailing wage, which in this case is w. This is an essentially correct statement, except for one point. In practice, modern sector wages have to be higher than w. Lewis estimated that the difference in modern sector real wages, W , and the traditional sector real wages, w, would have to be about 30% or more. This difference arises because of several reasons. Firstly, some of this difference is illusory because of the higher costs of the modern sectors. Again this has to do with the organizational characteristics of the modern sector since it tends to be highly concentrated and urbanized. Therefore, congestion and transport costs are higher. Secondly, the decision for a labor in the traditional sector to migrate to the modern sector involves a psychological cost. As Lewis put it: “[There is a] psychological cost of transferring from the easy going way of life of the [traditional] sector to the more regimented and urbanized environment of the [modern] sector”.22 employment exist in the early stages of a developing economy— the key here is employment. Recent experience suggests that modern activities may be many in number and may even be expanding, but not necessarily creating employment in the modern sections. See the point regarding choice of techniques in section 2.2. 22 Ibid., p. 410 20 Finally, the gap in modern and traditional real wages may simply recognize: “that even the unskilled worker is of more use to the [modern] sector after he has been there for some time than is the raw recruit from the [traditional sector]”.23 That modern real wages have to be higher than traditional real wages is reflected in Figure 4.3 where we depict a now higher labor supply curve W W reflecting the additional wage which the modern sector must pay the traditional sector to extract labor out of that sector. The amount of labor demanded, L1 can be read off from the intersection of the labor demand curve, ABC and the labor supply curve, W W . From this, we can calculate the total wage bill which is simply equal to L1 W or the rectangle OW B L1 . Having calculated the total wage bill we can now turn our attention back to how capital accumulation takes place, which as we have mentioned earlier takes place through capitalist surplus, which can be calculated with the help of the total wage bill. Recall that capitalist surplus is defined as the portion of the total product left over after total costs have been paid. This capitalists surplus is an investment fund for the modern sector, but surely, agricultural surplus too can be a source of funds for investment in the modern sector? However, Lewis assumed that the traditional sector, given the initial conditions, would be unable to generate an agricultural surplus. This view however is not shared by Fei-Ranis, who assume that it is through capitalist and agricultural surplus that capital accumulates. In our present discussion we will stick to capitalist surplus as investment funds in the modern sector. We take up the issue of agricultural surplus as an investment fund in Appendix A to this chapter. Coming back to our discussion, we now calculate the capitalists surplus. If we examine Figure 5.3 we see that initially the labor demand curve ABC (corresponding to T P L0 in figure 5.2) and the labor supply curve W W intersect at B and yield the equilibrium quantity of labor L1 . Here the total wage bill is represented by the rectangle OW BL1 while the profit to the modern sector, or the capitalist surplus, is W AB. Now, Lewis, like his classical predecessors, assumes that this capitalist surplus will be invested. This investment will raise the capital stock from K1 to K2 , as can be seen in Figure 5.1. This new capital stock results in a new total product curve T P L1 which in turn means that the M P L curve will shift out from M P L0 to M P L1 , or from ABC to A B C resulting in a new equilibrium. At B more labor L2 is demanded and supplied from the traditional sector. And yet again another capital surplus W A B is obtained. This capital surplus will again be invested and the process will continue as long as capitalist surplus exists. But there is an obvious objection to the preceding analysis. The discussion assumes that capital surplus will be reinvested and not hoarded. Is this a reasonable assumption? In this respect Lewis adopts the classical explanation: Why should the capitalists produce more capital to produce a larger surplus which could only be used for producing still more capital 23 Ibid., p.410-411 21 22 Figure 5: Capital Accumulation in the Modern Sector and so on ad infinitum? To this Marx supplied one answer: capitalists have a passion for accumulating capital. Ricardo supplied another: if they don’t want to accumulate, they will consume instead of saving; provided there is no propensity to hoard, there will be no glut. Malthus ... raised another question; suppose that the capitalists do save and invest without hoarding, surely the fact that capital is growing more rapidly than consumption must so lower the profit on capital that there comes a point when they decide that it is not worth while to invest? This Ricardo replied, is impossible; since the supply of labor is unlimited, you can always find employment for any amount of capital.24 In fact we will see that Lewis and other classical economists were mistaken when they assumed that capitalist surplus will be invested.25 But now we now proceed to a discussion of development in a dualistic economy. For this we consider the interplay between the traditional and modern sectors. 2.1.3 Interplay The previous two sectors described the structural characteristics of each sector in the LFR model. We have set the stage for the interplay. Now the action begins. We bring the traditional and modern sectors together in Figure 6. Let us quickly explain a few items about Figure 6. Examining Figure 6.1 we represent the production conditions in the modern sector. We have shown two M P L curves df , and d f . We assume initially that the modern sector is very small relative to the economy. Therefore, we assume that the entire population almost lives and works in the traditional sector. So, to begin our analysis of development in the classical model we turn to the traditional sector. Panels 2 and 3 show the production conditions in the traditional sector. Examining figure 6.3 first we have the traditional sector production function or total product curve OCF M — only that it has been reflected on the y = −x line.26 Hence, population in the traditional sector is read from right to left while output is read from top to bottom. The T P L curve contains a flat region CM indicating the existence of surplus labor, DP . This fact is also represented in panel 2 where we have drawn the M P L curve of the traditional sector P DU . Again, labor is read from right to left but the marginal and average products 24 Lewis, W. A., ‘Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor, in Agarwala & Singh, The Economics of Underdevelopment, p. 407. 25 Strictly speaking, Lewis was right if he was granted two conditions: (a) that capitalists did not hoard their capitalists surplus, and (b) that the economy was closed. We can see that of these two conditions, condition (b) is the more problematic one in these times: because capital can move across international borders, it becomes difficult to assume that capitalists surplus will be invested at home, and not in another country where the returns to capital are higher. Since this book assumes a closed economy, we will not pursue this matter further, but the point ought to be kept in mind. 26 Or alternatively, it has been reflected on the x-axis and reflected again on the y-axis. 23 Figure 6: Interplay in the Classical Dual Economy 24 are read bottom to top. We see that the M P L curve is flat for the region of surplus labor DP . In accordance with the LFR model, the institutional wage in the traditional sector: (1) Is equal to the average product of labor. As a first approximation, assuming that our analysis begins with a full population OP in the traditional sector, the real wage in the traditional sector, w, is simply w = AP L = MP OP . (2) Persists for as long as there is disguised unemployment in this sector. Thus, by definition of disguised unemployment, in Figure 6.2 we have shown the real wage w = AP L extending all the way till it meets the M P L curve at U . From points (1) and (2) above we have a new definition: we define AP workers as the disguisedly unemployed labor force since all traditional workers until this point are producing producing less than they consume, i.e., M P L < w = AP L.27 Of course, when the supply of disguisedly unemployed workers, AP , is exhausted, the average product of labor becomes less than the marginal product. This is seen to happen at point U in Figure 6.2. On the left of U an institutional wage persists. On the right of U competitive wage determination comes into effect and marginal product calculus is ushered in. At U any worker withdrawn out of the traditional and into the modern sector will be paid her marginal product. We are now ready to discuss the interplay between the two sectors. We will describe three stages in the development of the LFR model. (1) Stage I is the range for which M P L = 0 in the traditional sector, i.e., this phase marks off the surplus labor force DP in the traditional sector. (2) Stage II is the range for which a positive M P L in the traditional sector is less than the institutional real wage w. Stages I and II together mark off the end of the disguisedly unemployed labor force. (3) Stage III is the range for which the M P L in the traditional sector is greater than the institutional real wage w. We now begin our analysis of each stage. STAGE I: Assume that for some reason there is an initial investment in the modern sector. As mentioned earlier, the Lewis-Fei-Ranis model is silent on the source of this investment. But what is critical here is that for the modern sector to grow, this investment must be sufficient to generate a capitalist surplus at the prevailing real wage in the modern sector which, in turn, implies the notion of a ‘minimum critical effort’. Now, we represent this initial investment in Figure 6.1 by the M P L curve df . This is the demand curve for labor in the modern sector. The supply of labor in Stage I is represented by the flat curve w = SS . This curve is partially flat for the portion of the labor force for whom the institutional wage prevails and is rising when workers are paid according to their marginal product. Now at the initial wage of w and labor demand curve df we see that the labor market will be in equilibrium. In this equilibrium the capitalist surplus 27 Do note that surplus labor is a technological phenomenon brought on by resource and technological constraints, whereas disguised unemployment is an economic concept- it depends upon the production function, the institutional wage, and the size of the traditional population. 25 will be equal to W dt which when reinvested will result in a new capital stock which shifts out the initial M P L curve, df , to another M P L curve, d f . More labor is demanded and an equal number supplied by the traditional sector. This process continues until we reach the end of Stage I at point t on the labor supply curve in Figure 6.1. Let’s make a few comments about Stage I. Firstly, we can see that as the workers are reallocated from the traditional to the modern sector in Stage I, output in the traditional sector remains unchanged. Thus, unproductive surplus, or redundant, workers are being transferred to the modern sector where they will be more productive, without a loss in traditional sector output. In a sense then, development process in Stage I is “costless”. Secondly, the traditional sector, we have noted earlier, includes the agricultural sector. Hence, when workers transfer out of the traditional sector, it is very likely that some of these will be agricultural workers. In that case, the question of food transfers enters the picture. Workers cannot move out of the agricultural sector without the existence of some mechanism which simultaneously transfers the consumption per head with each transferred worker. If we assume that transferred workers consume the same amount of food in the modern sector as they did in the traditional sector, then we can set out some conditions for this costless development to occur. To do this we must define some concepts, which is done immediately below. Assume that the traditional sector is the agricultural sector. (This is only an assumption and should not be taken to mean that the traditional and agricultural sectors are actually the same). Now, as workers are transferred out of the agricultural and into the modern sector we see that a surplus of agricultural goods begins to appear. That portion of the total agricultural output (read off the traditional T P L curve, OCM ) in excess of the consumption requirements of the agricultural labor force at the institutional wage is defined as the Total Agricultural Surplus (T AS). The amount T AS can be seen to be a function of the amount of labor reallocated at each stage. For example, if GP agricultural workers are withdrawn in Stage I and re-allocated, then JG is required to feed the remaining agricultural workers and a T AS of size JF results. The T AS at each stage is represented by the distance between the T P L curve in the traditional sector and the straight line OM . From the T AS we can define the Average Agricultural Surplus, AAS, as the total agricultural surplus available per head of allocated modern sector workers. The AAS curve is represented by the curve wY Z in Figure 6.2. In Stage I as T AS increases linearly with the allocation of surplus labor from P to D we can picture each allocated worker as carrying her own subsistence bundle along with her. The AAS curve for Stage I thus coincides with the institutional wage curve wY U in Figure 6.2. It is only when the AAS is constant, that development in the classical model will be costless. The following conditions must be satisfied for a constant AAS: (a) The remaining workers in the traditional sector continue to consume the same amount. (b) The transferred workers consumes the same amount. (c) There are no transport costs. 26 (d) If with each transferred worker, AP L units of food are transported. If the conditions above are met, then development in Stage I of the classical approach will be costless. For example, if the conditions above are not met, (say) the remaining workers do consume more than before, then it means that food supplies per head for the transferred workers will be reduced, putting a stop to the development process in Stage I. So, some way must be found to prevent the remaining workers from consuming more than before. Clearly, in some way, the emergent T AS must be removed from the traditional sector, which raises the issue of how the T AS will be transferred out of the agricultural sector as workers are reallocated to the modern sector. One can imagine that it is (i) siphoned off to the modern sector through the investment activities of landlords in a process whereby the agricultural surplus is converted into a wage fund, or (ii) the extra food surplus resulting with every transferred worker will have to be taxed by the government— a taxation scheme due to Nurkse. Either (i) or (ii) will be enough to prevent the remaining workers from consuming more than before. We will return to this point later since the issue of transferring the T AS becomes more obvious in Stage II. STAGE II: We left off the development process in Stage I with the M P L curve in the modern sector congruent with the curve df . As before, the M P L curve is moving outwards towards d f through the process of investment and further capital accumulation. But there is a hidden problem. We can see from Figure 6.2 that the institutional wage w is assumed to persist throughout Stage II. This stems from our assumption that w persists as long as there are disguisedly unemployed workers in the traditional sector. Since the supply of the disguisedly unemployed workers has not been exhausted in Stage II, the labor supply curve to the modern sector can expected to remain flat throughout Stage II. But a glance at Figure 6.2 tells us this is not the case; instead of the supply curve being flat in Stage II it is upward sloping. What is going on? The explanation lies in the issue of total and average food surplus we discussed in stage I. Notice that in Stage II, since the the M P L of the now allocated workers is positive28 , total output begins to fall which means there is insufficient agricultural surplus output to feed all the new modern sector arrivals at the institutional wage level. This occurs, because while T AS is increasing in Stage II— because the distance between the curve M CRO and the straight line OM in Figure 6.3 begins increasing— AAS begins to fall as the number of workers allocated to the modern sector begins to rise— the falling AAS is illustrated as Y Z in Figure 6.2. This scenario, where despite rising T AS, the AAS begins falling occurs due to a worsening of the modern sector terms of trade.29 The “worsening of the 28 That is, the portion DU in Figure 6.2 and CRO in Figure 6.3. note that in order to talk about terms of trade we need to assume that the two sectors are producing different products. Now we already have an agricultural sector, but there still remains the modern sector producing ‘modern goods’, which defies easy classification. Hence, to talk in terms of a terms of trade story let us think of the modern sector as the industrial sector. We want to emphasize that we are doing this to discuss terms of trade problems and 29 Do 27 terms of trade” for the industrial sector occurs as the result of a relative shortage of agricultural commodities seeking exchange for industrial goods in the market. Accordingly, we label the point Y (or equivalently, point D) in Figure 6.2, which is at the border of Stages I and II, the shortage point. After Y , there is a tendency for the industrial supply curve to turn up as Stage II is entered because this is the time when there begins to appear a shortage of agricultural goods measured in terms of AAS. This in turn causes a deterioration of the terms of trade of the industrial sector and a rise in the industrial real wage measured in terms of industrial goods since there is now an excess demand relative to supply of food. We thus see that the disappearance of surplus labor in the agricultural sector marks the ‘turning point’ shown as point t in Figure 6.1. As far as development is concerned, capital accumulation is continually reinvested but at a slower pace and to a lesser extent. We can see that because of the rising supply curve, brought on by the worsening terms of trade for the industrial sector, capitalists surplus in the industrial sector declines, which reduces the investment fund meaning that less investment will take place. The pace of development will also slow down because the costless phase is over. Old industries and new industries can no longer be created or expanded without limit— the previous advantage of a constant subsistence level institutional wage in the agricultural sector no longer holds. The M P L curve in the industrial sector keeps shifting outwards until we reach the end of Stage II. The entire disguisedly unemployed labor force has been transferred out of the agricultural and into the industrial sector. This brings us to the end of Stage II. STAGE III: We have now reached Stage III which constitutes a major landmark in the developmental process. With the completion of the transfer of the disguisedly unemployed, there will occur a switch, forced by circumstance, in employer behavior. Stage III heralds the advent of a fully commercialized agricultural sector. The system of institutional wage determination is abandoned and competitive market forces yield the commonly accepted equilibrium conditions. The advent of Stage III signals the end of the take off process for the agricultural sector, which has now ceased to be the dominant sector. The center of gravity has shifted in favor of the industrial sector and the agricultural sector has now become commercialized, following neoclassical marginal product wage determination. Indeed, a structural change, in the relative sizes of the sectors, the production conditions and organizational characteristics has occurred. For this reason we call the points X, U , and R in Figures 6.1, 6.2 and 6.3 respectively, the Commercialization Point. We should note that the labor supply curve at the commercialization point in Figure 6.1 is accentuated. The reason is that since agriculture has become fully commercialized in Stage III, it must now bid with the industrial sector for its workers. This leads to an increase in the industrial real wage level if this should not mean that the modern sector is the industrial sector nor that the traditional sector is the agricultural sector. 28 the industrial employer is to compete successfully with the landlord for the use of the, by now, “limited” supply of labor. It can, moreover, be readily seen that during Stage III, AAS and T AS declines even more rapidly as the now commercialized wage in agriculture becomes operative. This is seen in Figure 6.2 where the AAS curve dips even further at the edge of Stages II and III, i.e., at point Z in Figure 6.2. In addition, this declining AAS is also reflected in Figure 6.3 where the straight line OM has an inward curve QO. With this, our description of the interplay between the traditional (agriculture) sector and the modern (industrial) sector is complete. We have seen how the classical characteristics of the dual economy, in particular the high man-resources ratios which resulted in M P L = 0, an income sharing setup and subsistence wages, contributed to the development effort in this model. We now criticize and comment on this model. 2.2 Comments and Criticisms Firstly, is it possible to achieve costless development with sources of labor other than surplus labor? Lewis talks of potential sources of labor supply which, although not surplus labor, does form an elastic labor supply at a given wage rate. These potential sources includes women. Hence, it is inevitable that sooner or later, women will begin to enter the labor force, for employment in the modern sector— this accounts for another well known structural sequence. That women provide the possibility of costless or near costless growth, underscores the point, made by Lewis, that M P L = 0 is not fundamental to his model. But this is not entirely correct. When new workers, such as women, are employed, what are they going to do with their wages? For one thing, they will certainly buy food. But whether this food will be forthcoming or not is a valid question, and is clearly tied up with M P L = 0 phenomenon. Take, for example, the case of a worker who is openly unemployed in agriculture or industry. How much does she consume, relative to when she is employed? It can be argued that there is a huge difference between the food consumption, or even in food needs, of the chronically unemployed, and the food consumption, or needs, of the employed. If this is so, the question of where the food is going to come from is all-important. An economic development which proceeds by absorbing the openly unemployed generates larger food requirements than that implied by economic development which soaks up the disguisedly unemployed. Let’s try to calculate the food demand set up. That is, the extra food that must be produced if one extra worker is to be employed. If the worker was openly unemployed, the extra food requirement is given by: R ≡ Food needs when employed — food needs when unemployed In the case of the disguisedly unemployed worker, we have to account for two factors: one, the total food output will fall when this worker finds employment and is transferred out of the agriculture sector. The fall in total output is therefore f (L). Two, the departure of this worker raises the income of the 29 remaining workers which will in turn raise their food consumption because of this higher income. Let the increase in consumption of food be Θ when the per d( f (L) ) L . Note that f (L) capita income of the remaining workers goes up by dL L is the AP L of the departed worker. Then adding these two factors gives us the extra food requirements when a disguisedly unemployed worker finds employment: R̂ ≡ f (L) + Θ| d( f (L) L ) | dL f (L) − Lf (L) | L2 Now, we recall from the previous section that in Stage I, because f (L) is flat, we have f (L) = 0 and that since we may siphon off the extra surplus by taxation, we have: ⇒ R̂ ≡ f (L) + Θ| d( f (L) L ) |=0 R̂ ≡ f (L) + Θ| , 1 , dL 1 =0 =0 ⇒ R̂ = 0 Thus R̂ = 0. However, R can be expected to be significantly positive. The extent to which additional food production is required will depend on the distribution of the unemployed between the disguisedly and openly unemployed. Second, our discussion of labor flows from the traditional (agricultural) sector to the modern (industrial) sector has not specified what will actually cause labor to migrate and food to be marketed. This is a controversial issue which will be taken up throughout this book. Third, what should be the pattern of labor removal from the traditional sector? Should incentives be structured so that individuals from each family farm migrate, or should entire families migrate? Let us begin to consider this issue by asking what happens to the emergent land once some workers or an entire family migrate. If individuals from each family migrate, then we see that the assumptions of M P L = 0 on the aggregate makes sense and the question of (emergent) land marketability becomes unimportant, since members of the family remain on the land. If, however, entire families migrate there is the important question of where the land goes. Is land sold on departure? If so, to whom? Moreover, from the perspective of equity, if, as likely in the agricultural sector, rich farmers buy the emergent land, the distribution of land-ownership is likely to worsen— what consequences does that have? In addition, depending on the pattern of labor removal, traditional output may or may not fall. Thus, the pattern of labor removal is tied with whether M P L = 0 in the traditional sector or not. We will now show that if a worker from each family is removed, there will no loss in output, and therefore M P L = 30 0. But if an entire family is removed, then output will fall, and we can no longer claim that M P L = 0 in the traditional sector. Consider the following simple hypothetical situation. Let us consider an agricultural sector characterized by traditional production and organizational conditions. Let all family sizes and land sizes be identical. Each family has L laborers and T units of land. Suppose there are N families (N ≥ L). Suppose that L workers are to be withdrawn from agriculture. This can be done in two ways: (i) One worker from L family farms migrates, or (ii) An entire family migrates. Let the agricultural production function be given by f (l, t), and suppose that fl (t, l), evaluated at (T, L) equals zero. We deal with each case, starting with case (i). (i) If a worker is removed from each of the L family farms then each farm’s output falls by fL (T, L). Thus, the total output falls by LfL (T, L). But from our assumption of fl (t, l)|(T,L) = 0 we have a net loss of zero. Of course, we have to assume that the removal of each worker does not affect the M P L, and, more importantly, that each worker puts in an equal amount of work. (ii) Say the ith family (consisting of L workers) is removed. The output of this ith farm falls by f (T, L). If we assume that this land is bought by (say) the j th family, then the j th family’s land holdings double. Thus, the j th family’s output will increase by f (2T, L) − f (T, L). The net loss in output is therefore: f (T, L) − [f (2T, L) − f (T, L)] Assuming f is strictly concave and homogeneous to a degree ≤ 1, the net loss in this case is: 2f (T, L) − f (2T, L). Clearly, if there is at most constant returns to T , then there can be no net gain. In all likelihood, there will be some diminishing returns, and so a net loss in output will occur. We see that: 2f (T, L) − f (2T, L) ≥ f (2T, 2L) − f (2T, L) > Lfl (2T, 2L) = Lfl (T, L) Thus, the net loss in case (ii), with some diminishing returns, is greater than in case (i). We note that if the land given up by the ith family could be parceled out equally to all families, the loss would be reduced, but there are problems with this since land is not a shiftable input. We now consider an example to illustrate the discussion above: example: Suppose the production function in the agricultural sector is: f (t, l) = min(t, l) where f is a Leontief production function. Now, let each family have 2 units of land and 3 workers. Then f (T, L) = min f (2, 3) = 2. Suppose the total number of farms is N = 3 and that 3 workers are to be reallocated to the modern or industrial sector. Now, from case (i) above, if we remove one worker from each family, the net d2 loss in output will be 0. This is from the fact that 3fL (2, 3) = 3 dL = 0. In case 31 (ii) if we remove one family we see that the loss in output from this family is 2. If this land is transferred out to another family then this (j th ) family’s production function becomes: f (2T, L) = min(4, 3) = 3 Thus, the net loss is 1 unit of output. But if the land is equally divided then each remaining family’s output will be: f (3, 3) + f (3, 3) = min(3, 3) + min(3, 3) = 6 which exactly equals the output before the reallocation. Thus, the net loss in output, when land is divided equally amongst remaining families is less than when land is parceled out to just one family. This example is obviously artificial but conveys the sense of what we are trying to say. Fourth, we have seen that the essence of the LFR model lies in the existence of an abundant supply of cheap labor available for use as inputs in the modern sector. But what sort of workers are these? In the context of overpopulated less developed economies we see that there is an abundance of unskilled labor, and so a major portion of the labor supply to the modern sector will consist of unskilled workers. The flip side of this is obviously that there is a shortage of skilled labor. How severe is this bottleneck? Obviously, if the modern sector expands by adopting sophisticated techniques which require skilled workers then our development story is in trouble. Lewis assumed that the bottleneck of skilled labor can be overcome by government intervention. In practice though this is unlikely. The recognition that there is a shortage of skilled labor but an abundance of unskilled labor in turn introduces the issue of the choice of techniques: obviously, labor-intensive, or labor-using, techniques are in order here. We will have more to say about this below. Fifth, the issue of labor-using techniques raises another question. Because there is an abundance of labor, especially unskilled labor in most labor surplus less developed economies, it makes sense for investment in labor-using techniques. But it is possible that the capitalist surplus may be well be invested in labor-saving, or capital-intensive, techniques. In such a case the employment generated would be less than if the modern sector had invested in labor intensive techniques of production. Consequently, the shifting of the center of gravity from traditional (agriculture) sector to modern (industrial) sector would be delayed. We can illustrate this point below in Figure 7. Figure 7.1 illustrates the effect on employment when the modern sector invests in labor-using techniques. In Figure 7.2 we have the modern sector investing in capital-intensive techniques. Clearly, the effect on employment is marginal when compared to Figure 7.1. Finally, Figure 7.3 illustrates the effect on employment when the modern sector invests in completely labor-displacing technology. Additional employment is simply nil. Experience from less developed economies indicates that capitalist surplus is indeed invested in labor-saving or labor-displacing techniques. Thus, policies 32 Figure 7: Choice of Techniques and Effect on Employment designed to speed up structural change by heavy investment in industry paradoxically slow the process down. Even worse, some countries are cursed not from heavy investment in capital intensive techniques but from capital flight, where capitalists surplus instead of being invested, is spirited off to foreign lands. Six, we have seen that the rate at which labor is transferred from the traditional to the modern sector is proportional to the pace of capital accumulation in the modern sector. But the possibility of capital acummulating faster than population certainly does exist. The effect of this situation is to increase real wages so high that capitalists’ profits may decline to such an extent that these may be consumed instead of being saved. Hence, net investment may be nil. The logic here is simple: if capital is accumulating faster than the population, then the pace at which labor is transferred to the modern sector is faster than the rate at which it can be replaced through population growth30 This raises the average product per labor in that sector not because production conditions have changed but simply because fewer workers remain behind to share the output. The effect of a higher average product is transmitted to the modern sector which must now pay a higher real wage to transfer labor from the traditional sector. This in turn implies a smaller capitalist surplus which progressively becomes smaller and may result in direct consumption or hoarding of this surplus. Development may, therefore, come to a stop sooner. Seventh, In Stage I, if w was originally at minimum subsistence levels then the development process comes to a stop in Stage II. We can see this by going back to our explanation of why the labor supply curve begins to turn upwards 30 We are of course talking about net population growth. That is, the excess of births over deaths. 33 in Stage II, even though the institutional wage w continues to prevail. The explanation was that since the AAS declines in stage II, the terms of trade must turn against the modern sector, thus raising the labor supply curve upwards. This is because as the modern sector expands, its demand for food increases, and since, simultaneously, the agricultural output begins to fall, the price of food in terms of modern products rises. The higher food prices in turn raise the modern wages, turning the terms of trade against it. But this scenario only makes sense if the original per head consumption was above basic subsistence. For if not, then no rise in modern wages can compensate for the decline in the AAS. In effect, the supply curve to the modern sector will become vertical after stage I. It should be obvious then that a dynamic model, incorporating population growth, capital accumulation, and technical progress is necessary if we are to have continued growth in the economy. This is done, to a limited extent, in the neoclassical model. Finally, in retrospective, we see the terms of trade issue in Stage II reduces both the pace and extent of development in the dual economy. Since the institutional wage is assumed to extend into Stage II, we see that, ideally, the economy can take advantage of this constant wage and expand without limit. But the worsening of the modern (industrial) terms of trade thwarts this “ideal” possibility. Is there some way that we can bypass the terms of trade problem? There certainly is, if we are willing to relax the assumption of no technical progress, which is done in the Fei-Ranis model but not the Lewis model. If agricultural productivity through technical progress were to increase, then stage II would be shortened. And if this productivity increase was high enough (just how high we will see shortly), then Stage II can be eliminated altogether. We analyze this possibility below. We begin by assuming that technical progress is exogenous and neutral. An increase in the agricultural labor productivity can be described by upward shifts of the T P L curves. We can see this in Figure 8.3 below: productivity increases are depicted by a sequence of T P L curves marked I, II, III, .., among which the I-curve is the initial T P L curve and II, III represent the T P L curves after successive increases in agricultural productivity. Let us make the assumption that as agricultural productivity increases the institutional wage remains unchanged, i.e., w in Figure 8.2 equals the slope of OM in figure 8.3 as determined by the initial T P L curve. In Figure 8.2 we may now plot the sequence of M P L curves marked I, II, III .. Each M P L curve contains a flat portion representing surplus labor in the traditional labor force. In figure 8.2, surplus labor is the portion P S1 . In Figure 8.2 we have also drawn the sequence of AP L curves I, II, III.. corresponding to the T P L curves I, II, III .. in Figure 8.3. According to the method already indicated, we can now determine the three stages for each level of productivity, i.e., the sequence of shortage points, S1 , S2 , S3 .. and the sequence of commercialization points, R1 , R2 , R3 .. Reference to these points will facilitate our analysis of the effects of an increase in agricultural productivity on the supply curve of agricultural labor and on the AAS curve. As depicted in Figure 8.2, for every amount of labor employed in the agri34 cultural sector, an increase in agricultural productivity shifts the M P L curves upward. As a consequence, the agricultural labor supply price curve is transformed from wt1 t1 to wt2 t2 , wt3 t3 .. etc.. with a shortening of its horizontal portion (i.e., stage II arrives earlier) as the sequence of commercialization points R1 , R2 , R3 .. gradually shifts from right to left. On the other hand, the sequence of shortage points S1 , S2 , S3 .. etc. gradually moves from left to right. This is due to the fact that, for each amount of labor allocated to the modern (industrial) sector, the AAS increases with the increase in T P L; the amount of food consumed by agricultural labor remains unchanged, leaving more T AS and hence AAS for the industrial workers. Thus the effect of our increase in agricultural productivity is an upward shift of the AAS curve to positions marked I, II, III, ... Sooner or later, the shortage point and the commercialization point coincide, and the distance S1 R1 , S2 R2 , S3 R3 ... vanishes and stage II is eliminated. In Figure 8.2 such a point of coincidence is described by R3 = S3 . We shall call this point the Turning point. There exists one level of agricultural productivity which, if achieved, will bring about this turning point. In figure 8.3 this level of agricultural productivity is described by T P L curve III. Let us now investigate the impact of an increase in agricultural productivity on the industrial supply curve L1 depicted in Figure 8.1. On the one hand, the upward shift of the AAS curve will shift the industrial supply curve downward before the turning point. This is due to the fact that an increase of AAS will depress the terms of trade for the agricultural sector and, with the same institutional wage (in terms of agricultural goods) paid to the industrial workers, the industrial wage (in terms of industrial goods) must decline. On the other hand, the upward shift of the M P L curve which is accompanied by a higher real wage in the agricultural sector after the turning point raises the industrial supply curve after that point. Thus we see, for example, that the L2 curve crosses the L1 curve from below, indicating that ultimately the “terms-of-trade effect” (due to an increasing of AAS) has been overcome by the “real-wage effect” (due to an increase in M P L). For purposes of this chapter, we are, however, not concerned with stage III which lies beyond the turning point. Let us now examine more closely the relative positions of the industrial supply curves before stage III is reached. Let the horizontal portion L1 P1 of the initial industrial supply curve L1 be extended up to P3 , the turning point, and let us call this horizontal line segment L1 P3 the balanced-growth path. We may then claim that all industrial supply curves between L1 and L3 cross the balanced-growth path at the respective shortage points. This is due to the fact that at the shortage point for each case (for example f2 in Figure 8.2 for the case of the industrial supply curve L2 in Figure 8.1) the subsistence wage rate and the AAS take on the same value as that prevailing in Stage I before any increase in agricultural productivity has been recorded. Hence the same real wage, in terms of industrial goods, must prevail at the shortage point as prevailed previously. In short, before the turning point, the industrial labor supply curve lies above (below) the balanced growth path when the AAS curve lies below (above) the horizontal line ww, causing a deterioration (improvement) 35 36 Figure 8: Labor productivity in the agriculture sector of the industrial sector’s terms of trade. The economic significance of the equality between our turning point and the (final) shortage point is that, before the turning point, the economy moves along its balanced-growth path while exploiting (or making the best of) its under-employed agricultural labor force by means of an increase in agricultural productivity. The economic significance of the equality between our turning point and the commercialization point is that, after the turning point, the industrial supply curve of labor finally rises as we enter a world in which the agricultural sector is no longer dominated by nonmarket institutional forces but assumes the characteristics of a commercialized capitalistic system. With this, our discussion of the classical approach ends. We now move on to the neoclassical approach. 37 QUESTIONS 1. Consider the Lewis dual economy. Discuss various situations in which the supply curve of labor to the industrial sector might be upward-sloping, even in the first stage of development. Relate the upward slope, in particular, to the ability of the planner to impose confiscatory taxes on agriculture, and to the extent that the initial average output of foodgrain is close to minimum subsistence. 2. Finally, briefly discuss which factors could determine (a) the pattern of migration that may actually occur in a given situation, and (b) the extent of land redistribution that is likely to take place, if entire families migrate. READINGS Lewis, W.A. (1954) ‘Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor’, Manchester School, 22:139-191. also in Agarwala & Singh (eds.), The economics of underdevelopment. Fei, J.C.H & Ranis, G. (1961) ‘A theory of economic development’, American Economic Review, 51:533-565. also in Eicher & Witt (eds.), Agriculture in economic development. 3 3.1 The Neoclassical Model Jorgenson Model Once again, as in the case of the classical approach, we feel compelled to provide you with the basis of the neoclassical approach. By now, you are pretty much steeped in the neoclassical tradition, so there is no need to go into a detailed introduction. Instead, what we will do here is to motivate the dicussion by highlighting the principal differences between the classical and neoclassical approaches. We seek to do this first, and then tell you a bit about the logic and intuition of the foremost example of the neoclassical approach to the dual economy: the Jorgenson model. Let us begin by comparing and contrasting the classical and neoclassical approaches. We have done this to a certain extent in the introduction to this chapter, but here, having dealt with the classical approach, a compare and contrast discussion will be more fruitful. As far as a comparison of the two approaches go, we can only say that they seek to describe and explain a ubiquitous aspect of economic development: structural change. The classical model managed to do quite a good job of it. It developed upon the reasonable assumption that most less developed economies, or strictly speaking, pre-structural change economies, are likely to be characterized by high man-resources ratios which gives rise to diminishing returns to labor, to the extent that M P L = 0. The pressures of population on scarce resource forces a situation where work and income sharing arrangements dominate the traditional sector of an economy. Workers in such a sharing nexus are paid 38 a shared wage which is close to subsistence levels. These low wages, and the presence of a supposedly unproductive labor force (i.e., surplus labor and the disguisedly unemployed) permits the modern sector to pay a wage marginally above subsistence levels and expand without limit (to a certain extent at least). Included in this scenario are not only differences in production conditions between the two sectors (i.e., traditional, unproductive activities contrasted with modern, productive activities) but also organizational asymmetries, i.e., uncommercialized family enterprises contrasted with highly commercialized, rationalized production units. This is a very powerful scenario which provides a pretty accurate picture of most labor surplus economies. Also included in the classical model were structural sequences such as higher savings rate (i.e., capitalists surplus which is reinvested) and the entry of women into the labor force. So, the classical approach paints a pretty grand and comprehensive picture. But it is curiously silent on one point, which was raised in section 2.2. And that is: what happens when the food production is inadequate to permit development? Suppose, food production is so low, that when workers move out of the traditional or agricultural sector, that they cannot be fed. Clearly, development must cease. It is at this point that the neoclassical approach comes in. Let us understand the reasons for why the neoclassical approach is so concerned with the viability conditions for growth, especially with regards to adequate food production. The neoclassical approach, it was stressed, looks at the dual sectors of an economy in a very different way when contrasted with the classical approach. The neoclassical approach is not founded on assumptions of large and growing populations, nor is it interested in pessimistic scenarios of zero marginal products and most of all, it does not regard leisure as either a free or inferior good.31 Neoclassical economics treats leisure as a superior good, which implies that no matter what the circumstances, M P L will always be > 0. That the two approaches differ in this fundamental aspect requires development in the neoclassical approach to proceed along very different paths. The neoclassical approach must rely on changes in the parameters of the dual economy, such as population, technical progress and capital accumulation, to spur growth. It moreover, recognizes that there is no such thing as a given assumption that modern sectors can grow on its own volition or through exogenous investment, without regard to adequacy of food supplies. Hence, the first thing a neoclassical approach does is to explore the conditions for the emergence of a food surplus. This is simply done by postulating that population growth rates increase, but only until a physiological limit. A population which grows at less than its physiological limit, is a population which is not meeting its food requirements. Hence, the viability condition is very simply that food production be sufficient to permit the population to grow at its physiological limit. Once this physiological limit is reached, the neoclassical approach assumes that the population maintains a constant consumption of food per capita, which is sufficient to maintain the population growth rates at its 31 Recall, that one interpretation of M P L = 0 was that there was leisure satiation. 39 physiological maximum. Thus, any food production per capita in excess of per capita consumption of food sufficient to maintain population growth rates at the physiological maximum, results in a food surplus which permits the release of labor for work in the manufacturing sector. Hence, the neoclassical approach in this section will first derive the viability condition for the emergence of a food surplus which allows the existence of a dual economy, and permits the release of labor from the agricultural sector for work in the manufacturing sector. Thereafter, the model, in the neoclassical tradition, derives the growth rates of population, agricultural labor force, manufacturing labor force, agricultural and manufacturing wages, agricultural and manufacturing output (total and per capita), and the terms of trade. All this is done through traditional price theory. Now, before we plunge into a detailed discussion of the neoclassical approach, we set out the basic assumptions of the model. We assume that technical progress in the neoclassical model is neutral. By this we mean that if output is held constant, then the marginal rate of technical substitution between factors of production remains constant before and after technical change. Moreover, we have not allowed for capital accumulation in the agricultural sector, a weakness which is corrected by extensions of the neoclassical approach, as will be seen in section 4. But an obvious question is, “How is technical progress in the agricultural sector possible if there is no capital accumulation?” The answer is that technical progress occurs in intensive cultivation, such as the timely sowing of seed, or being extra careful not to trample planted areas etc... Having sketched out the general framework of the neoclassical dual economy, let us chart our course through this section. We will begin with an examination of the agriculture sector. Here, we will first explore the case of the single sector agricultural economy. From this we will explore the viability condition and show that when this viability condition is met, the single-sector backward economy transforms into a dual economy with sustained growth. Our analysis of the agriculture sector will then have to be adapted to fit the dual model. Having dealt with the agricultural sector we will move onto a discussion of the manufacturing sector. Here we will investigate, among other things, the behavior of the manufacturing sector population and capital accumulation. Finally, we will bring the two sectors together and discuss development in a neoclassical dual economy. When discussing each sector and development in the dual economy we will be primarily interested in two measures of the parameters in a neoclassical dual economy. The first is the level of the parameter: what does it depend upon and how is its behavior characterized? Secondly, we will be interested in the growth rates of these parameters. What are the patterns of growth and what do these depend upon? We want to emphasize that by the rate of growth of a variable ln x x we mean xẋ = dx/dt or simply d dt , where t is time. Now, enough has been x said here. Let us move on to the Jorgenson model. 40 3.1.1 Agriculture Sector We begin our description of the agricultural sector by assuming that it is the only sector in the economy. From this we will derive the viability condition for the emergence of a dual economy. This is the same as saying that if food productions are not sufficient to enable population to grow at its physiological maximum, the economy will fail to emerge as a dual economy. Hence, the viability condition for adequate food production (defined according to the requirement that population grows at its physiological maximum) is becomes the same as the viability condition for the emergence of a dual economy from a single-sector agricultural economy. Since we are beginning with the case of a backward, single-sector, economy, the natural implication is that the entire population P lives and works in the agricultural sector. Let Y denote the agricultural output. We assume that land in the agricultural sector L is fixed in supply, in the sense of being fixed with regard to extensive cultivation. Furthermore, we assume that the agricultural production function has a Cobb-Douglas form: Y = eαt Lβ P 1−β (1) From the properties of Cobb-Douglas functions, we see that the agricultural production function exhibits constant returns to scale. In equation [1], eαt represents technical progress, assumed to take place at a constant rate, α. The constant β indicates the elasticity of agricultural output with respect to an increase in the supply of land. In the Cobb-Douglas production function, β also represents the share of landlords in total output. If we assume that the supply of land is fixed, then the landlord’s share will take the form of rent which is defined as: the unimputed residual remaining after the share of labor in the agricultural product, 1 − β, has been paid to the agricultural labor force. Now, since land is assumed fixed, we may choose our origin for measuring time so that the agricultural production function becomes: Y = eαt P 1−β (2) This is the production function that we will be working with in this section. Now, if we divide both sides of equation [2] by P , the total population (or equivalently the total agricultural force), we obtain y, the agricultural output per person: y = eαt P −β (3) We are now interested in obtaining the growth rate of y. As we pointed out above, the growth rate of y is simply ẏy . Thus, to obtain the rate of growth we differentiate equation [3] with respect to time and obtain: ẏ = αeαt P −β − eαt βP −1−β Ṗ Dividing the expression above by y we obtain: 41 Ṗ ẏ =α−β y P (4) Equation [4] gives the growth rate of agricultural output per capita. But to complete the expression above we need to say something about the function which governs the growth of population, Ṗ P. We assume that if there is no agricultural production, then reproduction rate literally falls to zero. Moreover, we assume that the mortality rate is constant and equal to δ. Thus, when y = 0 then there are no births and the population declines at a constant rate δ. In the event that there is agricultural production, we assume that the rate of gross reproduction is an increasing function of the agricultural output per head, y. It is simplest to assume that the rate of increase in the gross reproduction rate is constant as per capita income increases. Let the constant factor be γ. Of course, we cannot assume that the rate of gross reproduction increases without bound as agricultural output per head increases. We assume that the rate of gross reproduction is an increasing function of agricultural output per head up to some physiological maximum, say + δ. Thus Ṗ the net reproduction rate P may simply be described by the model in equation [5]: Ṗ = min(γy − δ, ) (5) P where γ is the rate of increase in the gross reproduction rate with respect to an increase in the output of food per person. Here, note that the net reproduction Ṗ , is equal to the gross reproduction rate minus the mortality rate, δ. rate, P Next, we see from equation [5] that the net reproduction rate is the minimum of the two rates determined by the physiologically maximum rate of reproduction and the rate determined by the output of food per head. Now, we have begun our analysis by assuming that a backward, single-sector, agricultural economy exists. By our discussion in the previous section, we see that if the backward economy exists then the population must grow at a rate less than its physiological maximum. Thus, looking at equation [5] we see that Ṗ P = γy − δ. In this case equations [4] and [5] may be combined to give: ẏ = α − β(γy − δ) = α + βδ − βγy y (6) Multiplying both sides by y we obtain the fundamental differential equation for the theory of development of the agricultural sector (or equivalently, the single-sector, backward economy): ẏ = (α + βδ)y − βγy 2 (7) Note that equation [7] fully describes the path of agricultural output. From this we can derive the viability condition of the economy. This is done as follows: if the viability condition, which is assumed to exist, is not met, then sustained 42 development will not occur. Development here means that ẏ is increasing. Thus, if ẏ = 0, the economy is not growing and will remain a backward economy. From equation [7] we can find out that value of y for which ẏ = 0 and let us call this value of y the solution to the fundamental differential equation [7]. Now, if we are interested in deriving the viability condition, then we have to find out if the solution to [7] is a stationary solution or not: that is, for any initial value y(0) we are interested in finding out the conditions under which y will continue to grow without ever settling into an equilibrium. Alternatively, we want to know the conditions under which ẏ will not grow: that is, are there any values of y (stationary solutions) which once established will maintain themselves? We may find all stationary solutions to equation [7] by setting it equal to zero. We therefore set the rate of change in per capita income equal to zero: (α + βδ)y − βγy 2 = 0 ⇒ y[(α + βδ) − βγy] = 0 We can see that there are two solutions: y1 = 0, y2 = (α + βδ) βγ The first solution, y1 , doesn’t particularly interest us because by our previous assumption, if y is zero then the population will fall off at a negative rate given by the force of mortality, −δ.32 Thus, the population dies off exponentially and we do not devote any further attention to this case. The second solution, y2 = (α+βδ) βγ , is necessarily positive. For this value of y we have ẏ = 0. One slight point here: note that ẏ = 0 does not imply that agricultural output or population are not increasing. Instead, both output and population are increasing, but at the same rate which keeps agricultural output per capita constant. We can see this from: Ṗ (α + βγ) α = γ[ ]−δ = >0 P βγ β Substituting this in equation [4] we see that: Ṗ α ẏ =α−β =α−β =0 y P β Thus, population and output are increasing at the rate of α β, forcing ẏ = 0.33 32 Recall, that gross reproduction is zero by assumption; therefore, net reproduction rate is simply equal to the mortality rate, which is negative and equal to δ. 33 One can show that output is also increasing at the rate α . First, from Ṗ = α , we have β P β by integrating both sides: 8 1 dP = P 43 8 α dt β Now, under what conditions is y2 stable? To reiterate, we want to know the conditions under which y2 will be an equilibrium; conditions, which if met, will mean that y2 will be approached and maintained no matter what the initial value of y is. Let us begin by defining y + the minimum level of income at which pṗ attains its physiological maximum, . Define y + : We may find y + y + = min(y : γy − δ ≥ ) (8) from the population model in equation [5]: ṗ = γy + − δ = p Hence: y+ = +δ βγ This is the value of y at which the population attains is maximum growth rate. We can now derive our viability conditions by considering two conditions: CONDITION 1 y2 < y + CONDITION 2 y2 > y + We will consider these two conditions and argue that if condition (1) is true then the economy will reach a stationary point and remain there in equilibrium. On the other hand, if condition (2) is true then the economy will grow without bound— i.e., there will be no stationary solution. Before going on we wish to point out that condition (1) is equivalent to: y2 < y + ⇒ +δ α + βδ > γ βγ where the expression above is obtained simply by substituting for the values for y2 and y + in condition (1). Since γ > 0, the expression above becomes: α−β <0 (9) α−β >0 (10) Thus, y2 < y + is equivalent to α − β < 0. On the other hand, by the same method above, it is evident that condition (2) is equivalent to: From which we have: ln P = α t. β Substituting this in equation [1] yields: αt Y = eαt P 1−β = eαt [e β ]1−β from which it follows that Ẏ = α . β 44 Now, assuming that the solution y2 exists we will show that the condition for y2 to be an equilibrium is equivalent to α − β < 0, or y2 < y + (CONDITION 1). Alternatively, we will show that if α − β > 0 (CONDITION 2), then a long-run sustained growth in per capita output will be achieved from any initial output. First, let us solve the fundamental differential equation. We have: ẏ = (α + βδ)y − βγy 2 Let us have a change in variables. We define a new variable u: y = y2 − 1 u u̇ u2 We substitute this in the fundamental differential equation and obtain: ⇒ ẏ = 1 1 2 u̇ = (α + βδ)(y − − ) − βγ(y ) 2 2 u2 u u Multiplying and dividing the first term on the right hand side by βγ, we obtain: u̇ (α + βδ) 1 1 2 = βγ − − (y ) − βγ(y ) 2 2 u2 βγ u u Notice that the term (α+βδ) on the right hand side is equal to y2 by definition βγ so the expression above reduces to: u̇ 1 1 2 = βγy (y − − ) − βγ(y ) 2 2 2 u2 u u ⇒ u̇ 1 1 1 1 = βγ(y2 − )[y2 − (y2 − )] = βγ(y2 − )( ) 2 u u u u u We eliminate y2 by setting y2 = (α+βδ) βγ obtaining: βγ α + βδ u̇ 1 = [ − ] u2 u βδ u ⇒ βγ u(α + βδ) − βγ u̇ (α + βδ) βδ = [ ]= − 2 u2 u uβδ u u Multiplying throughout by u2 we obtain the fundamental differential equation completely expressed in terms of u: u̇ = (α + βδ)u − βδ We can now solve this differential equation: du = −βδ + (α + βδ)u dt 45 (11) by setting βδ = A and (α + βδ) = B. Then equation [11] becomes: du = −A + Bu dt Multiplying both sides by dt and dividing both sides by (−A + Bu) we obtain: du = dt (12) −A + Bu Before we integrate both sides though we need to specify an initial condition. Notice that since this is a first order differential equation, we need specify only one initial condition. Let this initial condition by y(0) at t = 0. Now we express the initial condition in terms of u. We have y = y2 − u1 and substituting y(0) into y we have: y(0) = y2 − Therefore, u(0) = 1 y2 −y(0) . 1 u(0) The differential equation is therefore: 8 8 du = dt 1 −A + Bu 0 y −y(0) 2 Integrating this, we have: 1 = |t|t0 | ln(−A + Bu)|u 1 y2 −y(0) B Which further expanded is simply: Or: 1 B 1 ln (−A + Bu) − ln (−A + )=t−0 B B y2 − y(0) 1 −A + Bu )=t ln( B −A + B C where C = y2 − y(0). Taking anti-logs of both sides we have: −A + Bu = eβt −A + B C Which solved for u gives: eBt B A [−A + ] + B C B Substituting the expressions for A, B, and C, we have the final solution for u(t): u(t) = u(t) = e(α+βδ)t [ 1 βγ βγ − ]+ y2 − y(0) α + βδ α + βδ But remembering that y(t) = y2 − 1 u(t) , we have the final solution for y(t): 46 y(t) = y2 + βγ e(α+βδ)t [ α+βδ 1 1 + y(0)−y ]− 2 (13) βγ α+βδ where equation [13] is valid for y(0) = y2 . We will now show: (1) That y2 is a stationary equilibrium when y2 < y + . Recall from above that this is equivalent to α − β < 0, or CONDITION 1. (2) That y2 will not be a stationary equilibrium when y2 > y + , which is equivalent to α − β > 0, or CONDITION 2. In other words, when this condition holds, there will be sustained growth in the economy. Let us now deal with one condition at a time. CONDITION 1: In essence, we want to show that no matter what the initial output per head, the economy in the long run (i.e., for a time T , where T >> t) will settle down to a level y2 . This per capita agricultural output will maintain itself once established. Now, there are three possibilities for y(0): Case (a) 0 < y2 < y + ≤ y(0) Case (b) 0 < y2 < y(0) < y + Case (c) 0 < y(0) < y2 < y + Let us first deal with cases (a) and (b) together. In both these cases, it is sufficient to show that (i) the difference y(t)−y2 is always ≥ 0, and (ii) that this difference is declining to zero from above as t → ∞. Let us begin by showing that (i) and (ii) holds for cases (a) and (b). Examining the expression below we see that if y(0) > y2 , i.e., cases (a) 1 and (b), then the fraction y(0)−y must be positive and therefore the entire 2 denominator of the expression below is positive. This shows that y(t) − y2 ≥ 0, which completes (i) for cases (a) and (b). We now show that (ii) holds for these two cases: that is, we show that this difference approaches 0 from above as t → ∞. To see this, examine the term e(α+βδ)t in the denominator of the following expression. Clearly, as t → ∞, e(α+βδ)t approaches a very large number which means that the right hand side of the expression below, and hence y(t) − y2 , must approach zero from above: y(t) − y2 = 1 βγ 1 e(α+βδ)t [ α+βδ + y(0)−y ]− 2 βγ α+βδ We can summarize these cases in figures 9.1 and 9.2. For case (c), let us show that (i) the difference y(t) − y2 is always ≤ 0, and (ii) that this differences approaches zero from below, as t → ∞. Handling (i) 1 first, we see that the fraction y(0)−y is negative. Moreover, it can be easily 2 shown that by virtue of this, the denominator on the RHS of the expression above is negative.34 Therefore, the right hand side of the expression above is negative when 0 < y(0) < y2 < y + . This proves (i). Now, we show that (ii) is true. Notice that as t → ∞, the denominator decreases, thereby raising 34 All you have to do is to expand the denominator and substitute y = 2 algebra, the result follows. 47 α+βδ . βγ With a little Figure 9: y2 as a stationary solution in CONDITION 1, Cases (a) and (b) Figure 10: y2 as a Stationary Solution in CONDITION 1, case (c) the (negative) fraction as a whole. Therefore, the difference y(t) − y2 becomes smaller as t → ∞, and approaches 0 from below. This is shown in figure 10. Together, cases (a)-(c) prove that CONDITION 1 corresponds to a stable stationary solution to the fundamental differential equation. Now it remains to prove that CONDITION 2 corresponds to a continuous growth situation— i.e., y2 will not be approached in the limit. Equivalently, this condition will be seen to be the viability condition for the single-sector agricultural economy to emerge as a dual economy. CONDITION 2: This condition corresponds to y2 > y + , which, as we have shown above, is equivalent to α − β > 0. There are three cases which are possible in CONDITION 2: Case (a) 0 < y + < y2 < y(0) Case (b) 0 < y + < y(0) < y2 Case (c) 0 < y(0) < y + < y2 With regards to cases (a) and (b) it is clear that y2 by definition is that stationary level assuming that the population growth has not reached its maximum. But if y(0) is already greater than y + , then population cannot grow any faster than the physiological maximum. Thus, the stationary level, y2 , will not be reached and instead the economy will be characterized by continuous growth. This is shown below in figure 11. In case (c), when 0 < y(0) < y + < y2 , the general solution has the form: y(t) − y2 = 1 1 e(α+βδ)t [ y12 + y(0)−y ]− 2 48 1 y2 Figure 11: Sustained Growth in CONDITION 2, Cases (a) and (b) 1 1 We see that the fraction y(0)−y is negative. Since, y12 < (y2 −y(0)) < 0, the 2 right hand side remains negative and approached zero from below. But y(T ) = y + < y2 for T >> t, since y(t) approaches y + from below and cannot surpass it for, once again, it would require population growth at a rate greater than the physiological maximum. Hence the growth path is stable. It is clear from the discussion above that depending upon the conditions of production and the net reproduction rate, the system is characterized either by a low-level equilibrium, in which output per head is constant, or by a steady growth equilibrium, in which output per head is rising and population is growing at its physiologically maximum rate. This has some important implications for policy making, which we discuss below. First of all note that any change in social policy affects some parameter of the system. Now, if an economy is in a low-equilibrium trap, i.e., y2 is a stationary solution and thus ẏ = 0, and if β is assumed constant, then the planner can only affect two parameters: α, the rate of technical progress, and , the maximum net rate of reproduction. We can conceive of a situation where α can be increased (without changing β) such that the sign of α − β changes from negative to positive, or equivalently, the economy experiences sustained growth (CONDITION 2) instead of a low-level equilibrium (CONDITION 1). In the case of sustained growth there will be a steady increase in the output of food per capita. Alternatively, an improvement in medical technique will increase , which will also decrease δ, thereby worsening the test criterion. On the other hand, if is decreased this may result in a lowering of y + to a level that it falls below y2 , at which point, sustained growth becomes possible. Thus, in this model, to escape the low-level equilibrium trap, changes in the rate of introduction of new techniques or measures of birth control are required— the resulting situation will mean sustained growth in the economy which in turn means there will be steady increases in the output of food per capita. This model further assumes that when sustained growth commences, the population continues to consume an amount of food equal to y + per capita, since this is sufficient to enable the population to grow at its maximum rate of reproduction, . In this case, since output per head y is increasing but consumption per head y + is constant, a steadily increasing agricultural surplus, 49 s, will emerge, where agricultural surplus s is defined as: y − y+ = s (14) We see that s is defined as the amount of food in excess of what the population requires to maintain its maximum net reproduction rate. Thus, when the agricultural output per head, y, exceeds y + — the level of output necessary to bring about the maximum rate of increase in the population— an agricultural surplus, s, is generated which implies that part of the labor force may be released from agricultural production. The released labor will produce industrial goods, and because y − y + > 0, the rate of growth of the total labor force will not be affected. Since our model has a food surplus which has permitted labor to be released for use in the manufacturing sector, we may now begin to talk in terms of a dual economy. We assume that our viability condition has been met, and therefore there is sustained growth in output and a growing manufacturing sector. We will now formulate a model of a dual economy with an agricultural and a manufacturing sector. First, let us denote manufacturing population by M , and the agricultural population by A. Thus, the total population becomes: P =A+M Now, how does the theory of population change for a dual economy with an agricultural and manufacturing sector? The net reproduction rate is the minimum of the physiologically maximum rate and the gross reproduction rate corresponding to the output of food per capita for the total population, less δ the mortality rate. For the latter we note that the total agricultural output— recalling that y is the agricultural output per head— is equal to Ay. Thus, the A output of food per capita for the total population will be y P . Our population model is therefore: Ṗ A = min( , γy − δ) P P Clearly, when A = P the population model above reduces to that where the entire labor force is engaged in agricultural activities. Now, as we have mentioned earlier, if an agricultural surplus exists in the dual economy, then labor from the agricultural sector may be released to the manufacturing sector. We assume that the rate at which labor may be freed from the land is such that it is just sufficient to absorb the agricultural surplus. If, as it may well happen, the growth of the manufacturing sector is not sufficiently rapid, then some of the excess labor force will remain on the land and part or all of the surplus may be consumed in the form of increased leisure for agricultural workers. Such an event will lead to the destruction of manufacturing activity or the importation of food by increased manufactured goods. To simplify matters, we assume that there is a balance between the expansion of the manufacturing labor force and the production of food. We say that the proportion of the 50 total labor force engaged in agriculture, A, is the ratio of the subsistence level of agricultural production to the actual agricultural output per man in the agricultural population: y+ A = y P What this says is simply this: if there is no agricultural surplus, then y = y + and the entire population will be engaged in agriculture. But if y > y + then an agricultural surplus exists and some of the agricultural labor force may be released for manufacturing activities. Assuming that s exists, the rate at which A agricultural labor force can be released for manufacturing is simply P , because the total food production is Ay while the total food consumption is P y + — for there to be a balance we thus require that the expression above hold true. Note that the relationship above holds only when y > y + ; hence, we restate the relationship of the distribution of labor between agriculture and industry as: A y+ = min(1, ) P y (15) From equation [15] we can see that at the very least, the entire population is engaged in agricultural activities (corresponding to the case: y = y + ), or, A/P = 1). Otherwise, in the event y > y + , some of the agricultural labor force is released into manufacturing activities, in which case the proportion of + population engaged in agriculture is simply = yy . We have so far described the agricultural sector and the distribution of the labor force between manufacturing and agriculture. We now move onto a fuller discussion of the manufacturing sector. 3.1.2 Manufacturing Sector We denote the manufacturing labor force by M and the capital stock by K. We assume that the level of manufactured output, X, is a function of M and K. Since we can expect technical progress to be quite rapid in the manufacturing sector we have a third argument in the manufacturing sector production function: technical progress. This is represented by the time t at which manufacturing takes place: X = F (K, M, t) (16) We assume that F exhibits constant returns to scale which is equivalent to the assumption that the manufacturing output is exhausted by factor payments to labor and the owners of capital. Let us now suppose that the relative share of labor in the manufacturing output is constant and equal to 1−σ. Further assume that technical change is neutral and represented by some function of time, A(t). Then the production function, F , can be represented in a Cobb-Douglas form as: 51 X = A(t)M 1−σ K σ (17) Let us suppose that the rate of growth, A, is constant, say: Ȧ =λ A Then cross multiplying by A and setting Ȧ = dA/A we have the following differential equation: dA = λdt A Let us impose the initial condition that at t = 0 we have A = A(0). Thus, our differential equation becomes: 8 8 dA = λdt A(0) A 0 Which is simply: | ln A|A(0) = |λt|0 ⇒ ln A − ln A(0) = λt ⇒ ln A = λt A(0) Taking anti-logs of both sides and multiplying throughout by A(0) gives us: A = A(0)eλt (18) Inserting this into equation [17] gives us another form of the production function: X = eλt A(0)M 1−σ K σ (19) Now, just as in the case of the agricultural production function, we can obtain the output per man in the manufacturing sector by dividing the equation above by M . Letting x be the output per man and k, the capital per man, we have: X M 1−σ σ = A(0)eλt K M M ⇒ x = eλt A(0)( K σ ) M ⇒ x = eλt A(0)k σ Let us further choose our units of X such that A(0) = 1. We therefore have the final version of the production function: x = eλt kσ 52 (20) If we differentiate the equation above with respect to time and then divide by x, we obtain the growth rate of manufacturing output per capita: eλt kσ−1 k̇ eλt kσ ẋ = λ λt σ + σ λt σ x e k e k This gives us an expression describing the net growth of manufacturing output per capita: ẋ k̇ =λ+σ (21) x k Our model is almost complete: we have described the growth rates of agricultural and manufacturing output per capita. However, a glance at the previous equation tells us that we still need an expression for the rate of capital accumulation, kk̇ . We will now solve this problem. One way to solve for kk̇ is to use the Ex Post identity that consumption plus investment in the manufacturing sector must equal output in the same sector. If we assume that industrial workers do not save (that is, they consume their entire income) and that property owners do not consume (that is, they save, or equivalently, invest all their income), then the consumption of manufactured goods, in the manufacturing and agricultural sectors, is simply equal to the share of labor in the product of the manufacturing sector. Now, in the manufacturing sector, the industrial wage-rate, w, must, by neoclassical marginal product calculus, be equal to the marginal productivity of labor, or:35 ∂X = (1 − σ)x = w ∂M The first equality above, which states that the marginal product of labor in the manufacturing sector, or the industrial wage-rate, is equal to the share of labor in the manufacturing product can be simply derived by taking the partial derivative of equation [19] with respect to the manufacturing labor force, M . Letting A(0) = 1 as before, we differentiate equation [19] to obtain: σ ∂X Kσ = (1 − σ) eλt σ ∂M M1 , K σ But M σ = k , and thus the underbracketed terms in the righthand side are equal to x by virtue of equation [20]. We therefore obtain: ∂X = (1 − σ)x ∂M where, as before, x is the output per person in the manufacturing sector and 1 − σ is the share of manufacturing labor in the product of the same sector. The condition that the industrial wage-rate is equal to the marginal product is 35 Note that the following expression is written incorrectly in Jorgenson (1961). Instead of ∂X writing ∂M he has written ∂M . Please note this error. See p. 322 of Jorgenson (1961). ∂X 53 a necessary condition for profit maximization. That manufacturing firms seek to maximize profits is quite a reasonable assumption; however, the case is quite different for the agricultural sector. Here, we can assume that there is a difference in the wage rates between the manufacturing and the agricultural sector. This is a reasonable assumption because we can assume that whereas the wage in the manufacturing sector is determined according to marginal product calculus, no such neoclassical determination takes place in the agricultural sector. In fact, assuming, as we have, that agricultural production is carried out on traditional lines, we can expect wage determination in the agricultural sector to defy marginal product calculus. However, despite the fact that we assume a difference in manufacturing and agricultural marginal products (which is transmitted to a difference in wage rates between the two sectors) neoclassical analysis does not postulate the existence nor the possibility of zero marginal product. A difference in manufacturing and agricultural marginal products exists because of different techniques of production and organization; but, agricultural marginal product is never zero— always positive. This is, as we have emphasized repeatedly, the fundamental difference between the classical and neoclassical approaches. For this reason, the analytics of the development process are markedly different in the two models. We have postulated that there exists a wage differential between the manufacturing and agricultural sectors of the dual economy. Now, what is the direction of this wage differential? Quite clearly, in a dualistic setting, where (a) manufacturing activity is more productive than agricultural activities, and where (b) the economy is assumed to grow through labor movements from the agricultural to the manufacturing sector, we can see that agricultural workers will respond to wage differential between manufacturing and agriculture only if the industrial wage-rate is greater than agricultural income (which includes agricultural wage and rent). Let us then assume that the wage-differential is proportional to the industrial wage rate. Let µ, where 0 < µ < 1, denote the ratio between agricultural income y per capita, y, and the industrial wage-rate, w. Thus, µ = w . Then the total wage-bill for the entire economy is simply equal to: wM + µwA = (1 − σ)X + qY (22) where wM is the industrial wage bill and µwA is the total agricultural income, expressed in terms of manufactured goods. On the right hand side of equation [22] we have (1−σ)X which is the consumption of manufactured goods by workers in both sectors and qY is the value of agricultural output measured in terms of manufactured goods. Thus, q is the terms of trade between agricultural and industry. Note that equation [22] assumes that the entire agricultural output is consumed. This is a natural consequence of an agricultural sector where production is not fully rationalized— were it not so, then equation [23] would have to be modified to reflect the fact that marginal products in the two sectors will be equal in the long-run. However, as mentioned earlier, we assume that agricultural organization is traditional, ensuring that marginal products will differ 54 between the two sectors. The assumption that agricultural production is traditional in nature and spirit— the consequence of which, again, is that land-owners will consume their income— has an immediate implication: investment in the manufacturing sector is completely and totally financed out of the incomes of the property holders in that sector.36 Therefore, it is clear that once the share of labor in the manufacturing product is distributed to workers in the form of food and consumption goods, and agricultural workers have received the proportion of manufacturing output which must be traded for food, the remainder of manufacturing output is available for capital accumulation, i.e., investment. Here, capital accumulation is defined as investment less depreciation, where depreciation is a constant fraction of the capital stock. Thus, the net capital accumulation, K̇, is the total investment I minus the capital depreciation, ηK: K̇ = I − ηK (23) where η is the constant proportion of capital depreciation. Then by definition that total industrial output equals total consumption plus total investment, we have: X = (1 − σ)X + I which implies the following relation between output and capital stock: X = (1 − σ)X + K̇ + ηK (24) Equation [24] closes the system. We have fully described the growth of output in the agricultural and manufacturing sectors. We now study some important results of development in a neoclassical dual economy. 3.1.3 Development In the previous two sections we have developed some very important results. The first, and major, result is to note that a dual economy may grow only if there exists an agricultural surplus. The existence of an agricultural sector permits the emergence and, subsequently, the growth of the manufacturing sector by releasing labor from the agriculture to the manufacturing sector. That an agricultural surplus is necessary for the dual economy to grow is equivalent to α − β > 0. We shall assume in the forthcoming analysis that this condition holds. For if not, that is, α − β < 0, then the economy remains in an undeveloped state for the simple reason that no agricultural surplus exists, which means no agricultural labor can be released for the emergence and growth of a manufacturing sector. Thus the undeveloped, stagnant economy in which output of food per capita remains constant and population grows at 36 Do recall that we do not have the income of manufacturing labor force as a source of investment in that sector because we have assumed that the entire wage bill in the manufacturing sector is consumed by the workers. 55 less than its physiological maximum, will produce only food and other products of the traditional sector. For this reason, we are, obviously, not concerned or particularly excited with the case when α − β < 0; for in such a situation, the theory of a dual economy reduces to that of a backward, single sector economy. Clearly, the more interesting case is when an agricultural surplus does exist, or α − β > 0. Here, we will add to the analysis of the preceding sections by detailing the dynamics (i.e., level and growth) of the agricultural and manufacturing labor force, population, capital, terms of trade and manufacturing and agricultural wages. Let us the begin our analysis at that stage when an agricultural surplus comes into being, which occurs when y = y + . When this happens, two events follow immediately; one, an industrial labor force comes into being and, second, agricultural output has attained that minimum level at which population may grow at its maximum rate of net reproduction . Thus, at time t = 0 when y = y + , the path of population level, P (t), may be expressed through the equation: P (t) = e t P (0) (25) where P (0) is the population at time t = 0. Now, note that population is growing at a constant rate and if we assume that consumption per capita is also constant, then food output and population must grow at the same rate: Y (26) = y+ P Here the left hand side is the per capita food consumption, which by our assumption must equal y + once y equals y + . Thus the growth rate of Y can be calculated by: Y = P y + = P (0)e t y + (27) Given the equation above we can calculate the required rate of growth in the agricultural labor force necessary to maintain the growth of the agricultural surplus. First, from equation [2] note that Y = eαt P 1−β . But in a dual economy setting, where the agricultural sector ceases to be the sole sector, we must denote the agricultural labor in equation [2] by the variable A, and not by the variable P which previously stood for the agricultural labor force, but now denotes the total population in the economy. Hence, setting equations [2] = [27] equal to each other, we have: Y = eαt A1−β = P (0)e t y + Dividing both sides by eαt we have: A1−β = P (0)y + e[ Taking the 1 th 1−β −α]t root of the expression above, we have: 56 −α 1 A = [P (0)y + ] 1−β e[ 1−β ]t (28) Now, let us recall from equation [3] that y = eαt P −β . But now see that we have chosen our present origin of time when y = y + . Then, substituting t = 0, y = y + and P = P (0) in equation [3] we have: y + = eα0 P (0)−β ⇒ y + = P (0)−β We substitute this in equation [28] and obtain: −α 1 A = [P (0)P (0)−β ] 1−β e[ 1−β ]t −α 1 ⇒ A = [P (0)1−β ] 1−β e[ 1−β ]t −α ⇒ A = P (0)e[ 1−β ]t But note that at t = 0, P (0) = A(0). Therefore, our final expression for agricultural labor force is: −α A = A(0)e[ 1−β ]t (29) It is clear from equation [29] that A may either grow, decline or remain constant depending only on the relative magnitude of the two parameters α and .37 Also, from equation [29] we can immediately deduce an expression for the manufacturing labor force. First, we have the total population P as the aggregate of the manufacturing and agricultural labor force, or P = A + M . Thus, subtracting equation [29] from P we have: M (t) = P (t) − A(t) −α ⇒ M = e t P (0) − P (0)e[ 1−β ]t Which gives us the final expression for the manufacturing labor force: −α M = P (0)(e t − e[ 1−β ]t ) (30) Do note that when t = 0, M = 0.38 This is in accordance of our earlier statement that until the economy generates a positive food surplus, a dual economy cannot emerge. Ṁ Examining equation [30] we are led to ask, if M will grow faster, slower or the same rate as the population, which grows at . To answer this we must check 37 Recall 38 This 0. that we have β fixed. is clearly obvious from simple substitution: M = P (0)(e 0 −e 57 −α [ 1−β ]0 ) = P (0)[1−1] = −α the relative magnitude of and [ 1−β ]. From the fact that we require α − β > 0, we can add to each side and obtain: < +α−β ⇒ − α < (1 − β) which yields: >[ −α ] 1−β (31) From equation [31] it is immediately obvious that the manufacturing labor force will grow at a rate much more rapid than the population growth rate.39 Finally, in the long-run the growth rate of the manufacturing labor force will approach, in the limit, the rate of growth of population, . We can show this result in yet another way. Consider the expression for M : −α M = P (0)[e t − e[ 1−β ]t ] −α To make matters simpler let us denote [ 1−β ] as v. Differentiating the expression above we have: Ṁ = P (0)( e t − vevt ) We can now obtain Ṁ M by simple division of the two expressions above: Ṁ ( e t − vevt ) = M (e t − evt ) We can easily see that over the interval (0, ∞), Ṁ M declines from ∞ to . Having examined the dynamics of the growth of the manufacturing labor force we now turn our attention to capital accumulation. To study the dynamics of capital accumulation we require three important relations. First we have the expression for the size of the manufacturing labor force; reproducing equation [30] we have: −α M = P (0)[e t − e[ 1−β ]t ] (32) In addition, from equation [19] we have the production function for the manufacturing sector:40 39 Yet another way to see this result is to note that the result in equation [32] indicates by virtue of equation [30], that the agricultural labor force will grow less rapidly compared to the population growth rates. This is in turn implies that the manufacturing labor force will have to grow more rapidly than the population growth rates, since the rate of growth of population is simply the weighted average of the rates of growth of each of its two components. 40 Notice that compared to equation [19] the following equation has chosen the units of X such that A(0) = 1. 58 X = eλt K σ M 1−σ (33) And finally, we reproduce from equation [24] the identity of industrial output equal to consumption and investment: X = (1 − σ)X + K̇ + ηK (34) Equation [34] can also be expressed as: σX = K̇ + ηK ,1 , 1 (35) K̇ + ηK = σeλt K σ M 1−σ (36) A B where A is savings and B is investment. Now, we can substitute equation [33] into equation [35] and obtain: All that remains for us is to substitute the expression for M (from equation [32]) into the expression above, thereby obtaining: −α K̇ + ηK = σeλt K σ [P (0)(e t − e( 1−β )t )]1−σ (37) The expression above simplifies to the fundamental differential equation for the development of a dual economy: −α K̇ = σeλt K σ P (0)1−σ [e t − e( 1−β )t ]1−σ − ηK (38) The solution to the differential equation above is much too long for us to consider here. Instead, we will discuss some major aspects of the solution to equation [39].41 Firstly, we note that no stationary situation is possible for an economy in which capital accumulation is possible. This is equivalent to the statement that there is no stationary situation in an economy with an agricultural surplus, i.e., α − β > 0. Indeed, once the economy has begun to grow (which occurs when y = y + ) it must continue to grow. But what will be the pattern of the growth of the dual economy? That depends on two initial conditions: (1) The size of the population when growth begins, i.e., P (0), and (2) The initial capital stock, K(0).42 Of these two, only (1) has an effect on the long-run growth of the economy. The influence of (2), the initial capital stock, dies out very quickly; indeed, the greater the rate of depreciation η and the larger the share of labor in the manufacturing product, (1 − σ), the more rapidly will the effects of the initial capital stock disappear. Secondly, there is no “critical” level of an initial capital stock. In contrast to the classical model, where there is a critical level of initial capital stock required for sustained growth in that dual economy, the neoclassical dual economy 41 The interested reader can see Jorgenson, D., (1961) p. 331 for solution to equation [38]. again, we have chosen t = 0 as that stage when growth begins, or when y = y + . 42 Once 59 experiences sustained growth given any level of initial capital stock. The combination of a positive and growing agricultural surplus s combined with a small positive capital endowment will give rise to a rapid rate of growth, akin to the “take-off” stage discussed in Rostow’s model. Thirdly, if sustained growth occurs, then in the long-run capital and output must grow at the same rate, even if there is no technical change. Let us show this result starting with the case of no technical change. If there is no technical change, then capital, output and population will grow at the same rate . If, on the other hand, there is technical change, then population will grow at its maximum rate of while capital and output will grow at a more rapid rate of λ 1−σ + , where, λ is the rate of technical progress and 1 − σ is the share of labor in the manufacturing product. Fourthly, growth in the manufacturing output is more rapid the greater the rate of growth of the labor force or the more rapid the rate of technical progress, λ; the rate of growth of manufacturing will be less rapid the greater the share of labor in output or the smaller the savings ratio. We can show the results above by decomposing the rate of growth of manufacturing into the rate of technical progress, the rate of growth of the industrial labor force and the rate of capital accumulation. First, we have the production function in the manufacturing sector: X = eλt A(0)M 1−σ K σ Differentiating this, we have: Ẋ = λeλt A(0)M 1−σ K σ + eλt A(0)(1 − σ)M −σ Ṁ + eλt A(0)M 1−σ σK σ−1 K̇ Dividing the expression above by X we have the rate of growth of manufacturing output: K̇ Ẋ Ṁ +σ = λ + (1 − σ) X M K ,1 ,1 A (39) B So that the rate of growth of output in the industrial sector is equal to the rate of technological progress plus a weighted average of the rates of growth of the manufacturing labor force (A) and the rate of growth of the capital stock (B). Now, since the capital stock always grows at some positive rate and the growth of the manufacturing labor force begins at an extremely high rate and declines to the rate of population growth, the initial rate of growth of manufacturing output must be extremely high, declining gradually and approaching its equilibrium value. This result has an interesting policy implication: if one considers the experience of the now developed countries, we observe a “big-push”. Many economists have attributed this big-push to high levels of capital stock, arguing, therefore, that the same big-push can be replicated in the now less developed countries by massive infusion of capital. It is clear from the discussion above 60 that such an infusion is unnecessary for development leading to sustainable growth. We have so far described the dynamics of the population, manufacturing labor force, capital accumulation and manufacturing output. We now discuss some final aspects of the neoclassical dual economy— we will discuss the development of wages and the terms of trade between the advanced manufacturing sector and the backward agricultural sector. First, recall that wages per person, w, must be equal to the share of labor, (1 − σ), multiplied by the output per person, x: w = (1 − σ)x To inspect the development of wages we differentiate the expression with respect to t obtaining: ẇ = (1 − σ)ẋ Dividing throughout by w to obtain the rate of growth of wages we obtain: ẇ (1 − σ)ẋ = w w But w = (1 − σ)x and therefore: ẇ (1 − σ)ẋ ẋ = = w (1 − σ)x x But ẋ x = Ẋ X − Ṁ M by definition. Hence, the expression above becomes: ẋ Ẋ Ṁ λ ẇ = = − =[ + ]− w x X M 1−σ λ + by virtue of the fact that the rate of growth of output in the long-run is 1−σ ẇ while that of the manufacturing labor force is simply . Thus, w can be expressed as: ẇ λ = (40) w 1−σ Clearly, if there is no technological progress in the manufacturing sector, real wages will reach some constant level. If, on the other hand, there is technical progress, real wages rise more rapidly, the more rapid the rate of technical change and the higher the savings ratio. Another way to state this is, the higher the share of labor in the manufacturing output, the less rapid the rise of real wages. Having dealt with the dynamics of real wages, let us now turn to the dynamics of the terms of trade between the manufacturing and agricultural sectors. Let us first reproduce the fundamental relation of the terms of trade q. From equation [22] we have: 61 a c b d 1, 1 , 1 , 1, wM + µwA = (1 − σ)X + qY , 1 , 1 W C Let’s examine the expression above, which is really equation [22] once again. a is the manufacturing sector wage bill while b is the total agricultural income. Thus, a + b is the total wage bill of the economy W , which, with the assumption that workers do not save, must equal total consumption in the economy C, consisting of the consumption of manufactured goods c and agricultural goods d. Since a ≡ c, we can cancel these out and obtain: µwA = qY All that remains now is to insert the appropriate expressions for A and Y . Recall −α from equation [29] that A = P (0)e( 1−β )t and Y = P (0)e t y + . Substituting these into the expression above we have:43 −α µwP (0)e( 1−β )t = qP (0)e t y + Canceling out P (0) from both sides and taking q on one side we have: −α µwe( 1−β − q= y+ )t (41) Now, to obtain the rate of growth of q, qq̇ , we require q̇. Accordingly, we differentiate the equation above with respect to t and obtain: q̇ = [ −α −α µ − ]w + e[ 1−β − 1−β y ]t + −α u [ 1−β − ]t e ẇ + y We can now obtain an expression for the rate of growth of q by dividing the expression above by q: −α −α [ 1−β − ]w yµ+ e( 1−β − q̇ = −α − )t ( q µwe 1−β )t + −α u ( 1−β − )t ẇ y+ e ( µwe y+ −α − )t 1−β y+ And we therefore obtain the final expression for the rate of growth of q: ẇ −α q̇ =[ − ]+ q 1−β w , 1 ,1 A (42) B Two items of interest are immediately apparent from the equation above. One, notice that the underbracketed terms A are negative, by virtue of equation [31]. On the other hand, from equation [40] we can see that ẇ w is positive 43 Note that Jorgenson has made an error in the following expression. He has P (0) only on the left hand side, not on both sides, which is the case actually. See p. 330 of Jorgenson (1961). 62 λ and equal to 1−σ . We now see that if technical progress in the manufacturing sector declines to zero then the terms of trade for agriculture must decline. Alternatively, the more rapid the technical progress in the manufacturing sector, the less rapidly the terms of trade for agriculture deteriorate; if terms of trade is sufficiently rapid, the terms of trade for agriculture may even improve. The reverse holds true for technical progress in the agriculture sector— the more rapid technical progress in that sector, the more rapidly must the terms of trade deteriorate. Secondly, note that the more rapid the growth of population the less rapidly will the terms of trade decline. With this, our dicussion of the Jorgenson model is complete and we now criticize and comment on the model. 3.2 Comments and Criticism In this section we will first criticise Jorgenson’s neoclassical model and then compare the classical and neoclassical models of the dual economy. We begin with a criticism of the Jorgenson model. Firstly, the model suffers from the fact that it relies on a Cobb-Douglas production function. The model, as proposed by Jorgenson, does not apply to all forms of the production function. This drawback has been corrected by later neoclassical models of the dual economy, in particular Amano (1980), whose model is the subject of the next section. Secondly, recall that even though the neoclassical approach allows for technical progress in the agricultural sector, it does not account for the possibility of capital accumulation in this sector. This is a serious drawback, that is tackled, once again, in Amano’s model. Thirdly, it seems somewhat curious that, once population grows at the physiologically maximum growth rates, everyone in the economy continues to consume at y + . The model does not allow for the food consumption per capita to rise above y + as output of food per capita, y, increases. Another way to say this is that the agricultural surplus is not dented by the increased consumption of the remaining workers. This is, admittedly, somewhat of a copout— after all, one of the strongest criticisms of the classical model was precisely that one could not expect the remaining workers in the traditional sector to maintain consumption at previous levels. Thus, to thwart the possibility of increased consumption by the remaining workers in that model, a taxation scheme, such that it siphoned off the extra surplus was devised. Such a scheme is also admittedly very hard to formulate and implement. So it seems that this problem has been tackled in Jorgenson’s model by assuming that everyone continues to consume the same amount, for y ≥ y + . This defect is also addressed and overcome by Amano (1980). Finally, It will be interesting to compare the results of the two approaches. Such a comparison was undertaken by Dixit (1970), whose results we now discuss. Dixit’s discussion begins with a discussion of a 1967 paper by Jorgenson. In that paper, Jorgenson claimed the following points when he contrasted the 63 classical and neoclassical approaches: (1) The classical model implies a fall in the industrial capital/output ratio as the economy develops. The ratio is asymptotically constant under Jorgenson’s neoclassical model. (2) The rate of growth of capital increases over time in the classical model, but is asymptotically constant in the neoclassical model. (3) In the classical model, output and employment in manufacturing grow at the same rate so that productivity is constant, while it rises in the neoclassical model. (4) There must be an absolute decline in the agricultural labor force before the surplus labor phase ends in the classical model; this is not a necessary consequence of the neoclassical approach. We are going to see that the differences between the classical and neoclassical approaches are less striking than made out in the four points above. We begin by restating some fundamental aspects of Jorgenson’ model. We assume that we are at time t = 0 when the viability condition has just been satisfied. That is, y = y + and the manufacturing sector has come into being. In this case, from equation [30] we see that the manufacturing sector labor force is given by: v 1 , −α [ ]t t 1 M = P (0)(e − e − β ) −α We simplify the expression above by employing v to denote [ 1−β ] Now, we will attempt to find an expression for the rate of growth of M , i.e., by differentiating the expression above: Ṁ M. We begin Ṁ = P (0)( e t − vevt ) Therefore: Ṁ ( e t − vevt ) = M (e t − evt ) (43) Ṁ declines from ∞ to . Having done this, Clearly, over the interval (0, ∞), M let us find the rate of growth of manufacturing output and then the rate of growth of capital accumulation. The rate of growth of X is given by equation [39] and is reproduced below: Ẋ K̇ Ṁ = λ + σ + (1 − σ) (44) X K M Now if we neglect depreciation, since it makes no difference to the results below, we can then see from equation [35], substituting η = 0, that: K̇ = σX 64 (45) From this we can calculate the rate of growth of capital sides of the equation above by K: X K̇ =r=σ K K Now, we take the logs of both sides and differentiate: K̇ K by dividing both (46) ln r = ln σ + ln X − ln K ṙ Ẋ K̇ = − ln r X K Substituting equation [44] above we have: ⇒ λ+σ K̇ K̇ + (1 − σ) K K Which yields: ṙ Ṁ K̇ = λ + (1 − σ)[ − ] r M K Noting from equation [46] that r = obtain: K̇ K (47) we substitute in the equation above and K̇ ṙ = λ + (1 − σ)[ − r] r K ⇒ ṙ = λr + (1 − σ)r ⇒ ṙ = (1 − σ)r[ Ṁ − (1 − σ)r2 M λ Ṁ −r+ ] (1 − σ) M λ , where µ is the rate of industrial technical progress in laborWriting µ = (1−σ) augmenting form, and substituting this in the expression above we obtain:44 Ṁ + µ − r) (48) M We are now ready to discuss points 1 through 4 above. First of all, we have Ṁ will decline from ∞ to over the interval noted from equation [43] that M Ṁ (0, ∞). Therefore, it is obvious that M + µ will decline from ∞ to + µ over the same interval (0, ∞). Now, from equation [46] we can see that with M = 0 at t = 0, we have r = 0 at that instant. But if we take all the proper limits of equation [48] we see that ṙ = (1 − σ)r( 65 Figure 12: Growth Rates of Ṁ M + µ, r ṙ is infinite.45 This means that both r and ṙ become positive and the path of r can be proved to be of the form shown in figure 12. We can see that r rises monotonically to + µ, passes this value, equals Ṁ + µ at some time t∗ , and then declines thereon to its asymptotic level + µ. M Clearly, during the first phase of development, r is rising. Correspondingly, X from equation [46] we see that K is rising or that K X is falling. This conclusion is exactly the same that Jorgenson found for the classical model. Thus, we see that point 1 above is not as striking as it first seemed. We can also see from the analysis so far that point 2 arises from the simple fact that Jorgenson is contrasting the asymptotic results of his model with those of the surplus-labor phase in the classical model. Indeed, if we limit ourselves to a finite time period, we see that the classical and the neoclassical yield the exact same result: initially, the rate of growth of capital increases. It is only asymptotically that the neoclassical rate of growth of capital approaches a limit and settles there. With regard to point 3 above, see that constant real wage in the classical model implies a constant marginal product of labor. Clearly, if the production function is of the Cobb-Douglas form, the average product is a constant multiple of this, and hence, it too remains constant. This is the justification which Jorgenson offers for his claim that productivity remains constant in the classical model. But obviously, we see that the classical result need not be the case 44 Be 45 See careful: the µ here is different from that used in Jorgenson’s model. Dixit (1970), p. 234-235 for proof. 66 when we consider other forms of production functions.46 Moreover, productivity change can also be explained by allowing for changes in the industrial real wage, either because of technical progress in the agriculture sector or because of a shift in the terms of trade. For the neoclassical model we have already calculated the rate of change of industrial productivity. By definition, change in industrial productivity, ẋx (= ẇ w) is simply: Ẋ Ṁ − X M From equation [44], we have: Ẋ Ṁ K̇ Ṁ Ṁ K̇ − =λ+σ −σ = λ − σ[ − ] X M K M M K λ = µ. Thus, λ = µ(1 − σ). Also, But note that by definition (1−σ) Substituting above, we have: K̇ K = r. Ẋ Ṁ Ṁ Ṁ − = µ(1 − σ) − σ[ − r] = µ − µσ − σ + rσ X M M M Which gives the final expression for the rate of change of industrial productivity: Ṁ Ṁ Ẋ − = µ − σ( + µ − r) (49) X M M What is the sign of the equation above? Clearly, the answer is ambiguous. Initially, the gap [ Ṁ M +µ]−r is quite large and hence the rate of change of industrial productivity is negative. But as time increases, this rate turns from negative to positive at time t , which is indicated in the diagram above. We can therefore see that point 3 above was overstated. In fact, the possibility of productivity changing does exist in the classical model and contrary to Jorgenson’s claims, neoclassical productivity is actually negative in the beginning of the growth process. With regards to the final point above, we can see that the absolute decline in the agricultural labor force depends on the assumption in Fei-Ranis’ classical model and Jorgenson’s neoclassical model, that technical progress in the agriculture sector is exogenous and neutral, and that there is no capital accumulation in that sector. This implies that the level of employment, L∗ at which M P L = 0, is constant over time. But clearly, if there is surplus labor, then one effect of technical progress in the agricultural sector is to render that labor productive, which directly implies that the level L∗ changes. The same thing will happen with capital accumulation in agriculture. Thus, it is possible that through technical change the surplus labor phase may be overtaken by letting 46 See Marglin, S. A., Comment on Jorgenson, in Adelman and Thornbecke (eds.), The Theory and Design of Economic Development, pp. 60-66. 67 L∗ overtake the agricultural labor force. This discussion indicates that the exogeneity and neutrality of technical progress are rather poor assumptions in the context of a labor surplus model. This completes our discussion of point 4. READINGS Jorgenson, D. (1961) ‘The Development of a Dual Economy’, Economic Journal, June 1961, pp. 309-334. Dixit, A. (1970) ‘Growth Patterns in a Dual Economy’, Oxford Economic Papers, 1970. << We are not yet done with Amano’s discussion. >> 68