P2JW183000-0-A01300-1--------XA CMYK Composite CL,CN,CX,DL,DM,DX,EE,EU,FL,HO,KC,MW,NC,NE,NY,PH,PN,RM,SA,SC,SL,SW,TU,WB,WE BG,BM,BP,CC,CH,CK,CP,CT,DN,DR,FW,HL,HW,KS,LA,LG,LK,MI,ML,NM,PA,PI,PV,TD,TS,UT,WO THE WALL STREET JOURNAL. Wednesday, July 2, 2014 | A13 OPINION C an something good come from a U.S. splurge of climate pork that, in itself, would have no discernible effect on global climate or atmospheric carbon dioxide? A probable answer is no. It would actually end up making our putative carbon challenge worse. But Paul Krugman and others say a carbon tax is politically impossible, and that we should settle for President Obama’s “second-best” approach. The problem with subsidies and mandates is that they create vested interests in inefficient renewable energy. Warren Buffett BUSINESS already is colWORLD lecting millions By Holman W. for what he adJenkins, Jr. mits is hopelessly cost-ineffective solar energy in California. State mandates for renewables favor in-state providers, discouraging competition that would lower costs. Lobbies that form around such favors are quietly unfriendly to interstate power lines that would force expensive local energy to compete with cheaper renewables elsewhere. In Germany, where vast subsidies flow to wind and solar, coal has become the fuel of choice for utilities struggling to provide backup power. Result: German carbon-dioxide output is growing not shrinking. Most glaring is the renewable lobby’s opposition to fracking— never mind that fracking, by displacing coal, has done more to reduce carbon output than renewables have. As for cap-and-trade, check out the Senate testimony two weeks ago by Joseph Mason, of LSU and the Wharton School, Getty Images Birth of a Climate Mafia A wind farm on Pellworm island off the North Sea coast of Germany. on how easily such schemes have succumbed to fraud and corruption. A straight-up, revenue-neutral carbon tax clearly is our first-best policy, rewarding an infinite and unpredictable variety of innovations by which humans would satisfy their energy needs while releasing less carbon into the atmosphere. Failing that, our second-best policy might well be to do nothing, skip the green pork bonanza, and hope that new energy technologies emerge out of the already-ample natural incentives to do so. Why? One thing that can be safely predicted is that renewable energy that becomes addicted to subsidies in order to survive will not meaningfully replace fossil energy that remains cheaper in real terms. Now the new entrants in the climate policy derby: Robert Rubin and Henry Paulson. Impressive is the fanfare greeting the former Treasury secretaries and their splashy, economically focused climate lobby, the “Risky Business Project.” Unfortunately, they trod a well-worn path by trying to scare the American people into compliance. Their emphasis on “extreme weather” is an especially tired piece of foolishness. Whatever the human impact on climate, the overwhelming reason storms are becoming more destructive is the simple fact that more people and property stand in their way. Their unnaturally specific forecasts of rising sea levels and heat waves are based on the same speculative climate models that do such a poor job of explaining even the present and recent past—and whose limits the report doesn’t even mention in a footnote. The principals clearly want their assertions about the future to be taken as facts, not as extrapolations from simulations whose credibility they are wholly unprepared to defend. Their assertion that the U.S. can shame China and India into giving up carbon energy is no more plausible in their mouths than in anybody else’s. But Mr. Paulson’s policy heart is in the right place—a carbon tax. He has explicitly rejected the climate cronyism of BOOKSHELF | By Ben Downing the Krugman-Obama school. Sadly he and the passel of worthies behind his group (including Michael Bloomberg and hedge-fund impresario Tom Steyer) colossally fumble their 15 minutes by adopting the hectoring, frighten-the-public approach that Al Gore, Bill McKibben and James Hansen have so reliably demonstrated leads nowhere, produces no results and ultimately discredits the cause. They should have focused on tax reform first—on hope, growth and opportunity. Tax reform already has quietly been climbing the nation’s agenda—even President Obama has paid lip service. A tax reform that restored dynamism to the U.S. economy is an example that other countries could adopt out of self-interest, not because they are shamed into doing so by the overpowering moral gigantism of Al Gore. The one impeccable finding of climate science is a 40% increase in atmospheric carbon, even if our ability to detect its impact on climate is hampered by extraordinarily noisy weather data and the inadequacies of climate modeling. That’s reason enough many voters might accept a modest carbon tax that would be offset by reduced payroll and income taxes. And if a technologically superior answer to our energy needs is in the cards, tax reform is a better way to help elicit it than anything else government might do. By the way, if we had to bet, our bet (not preference) would be that humanity will not organize a coherent and meaningful carbon policy. The worst-case climate scenarios will prove overdrawn. Fossil energy will be outmoded over some period by cheaper alternatives. To boot, the world will discover that climate change is not the greatest challenge facing it after all. An Innovation Slowdown at the Tech Giants By Michael S. Malone F or more than a half-century, big technology companies have led the way in inventing revolutionary products and services, from calculators to smartphones. Startups, meanwhile, have built upon those creations with innovations like peripheral devices and software applications. This was as true for the IBM 360 computer as it was for the Apple iPhone. But something fundamental has shifted in Silicon Valley. The emblematic event was Facebook’s February acquisition of the mobile messaging startup WhatsApp for an astounding $19 billion. WhatsApp was barely five years old and had 55 employees. The question from one end of Silicon Valley to the other was: What possessed Facebook to spend that kind of money? Surely there must be a method to Facebook CEO Mark Zuckerberg’s apparent madness. In fact, a strategy is emerging: In 2012, the social media giant bought Instagram for $1 billion. The number of Facebook users grew less than 4% last year, but the number of Instagram users jumped 23%. Millennials are getting bored with the website and abandoning the platform in far greater numbers than their Seen anything new and big lately from Cisco, Yahoo or even Twitter? Valley and it’s hard to find established companies still devising their next products in-house. Seen anything new and big lately from Cisco, Yahoo or even Twitter? Even Apple, tech’s most innovative company under Steve Jobs, now seems to have slowed down with Tim Cook as CEO. During Jobs’s tenure, the company produced three landmark products— the iPod, iPhone and iPad—in little more than eight years. Now, after four years, customers are growing impatient waiting for the rumored iWatch, which, if real, won’t appear until at least autumn. Meanwhile, Apple has purchased nearly 30 companies. Google, though it requires employees to spend part of their time inventing, has acquired more than 150 companies in its history, including drones and Boston Dynamics’s robot cheetahs. Even Intel has been slogging along for the past few years. On the other hand, even if they are short on new ideas, most of these companies are long on cash, with some of the biggest war chests in American industrial history. Apple is sitting on $160 billion—enough to buy the entire next generation of tech startups. We’ve seen this strategy elsewhere. It defines the pharmaceutical industry, where young biotech companies develop new drugs, shepherd them through the Food and Drug Administration approval cycle and if, against great odds, they succeed are quickly snapped up by pharmaceutical companies for a handsome payday. Those that don’t get FDA approval quickly die. Is that the future of Silicon Valley and the tech industry? It’s what Oracle CEO Larry Ellison has been doing at his software companies for decades: buying the latest enterprise software companies, firing their employees, and adding their products to Oracle’s portfolio. No one else is that ruthless yet, but Mr. Ellison has a history of being ahead of his time. Why are large tech companies losing the ability to innovate? Entrepreneur and author Salim Ismail studies the new generation of “exponential corporations,” enterprises that grow 10 times faster than the average rate. He believes that established companies simply aren’t structured for this kind of speed. So their only choice is to buy those companies that can still innovate rapidly. If Mr. Ismail is correct—and the current dynamic in Silicon Valley suggests that he may be—we’re on the brink of a major restructuring of business strategy, venture capital and almost every part of the high-tech world. It may be time to stop waiting for famous tech companies to roll out the hottest new product and start investing in startups that can sell their innovations to big companies. Tech appears to be evolving into a different kind of field: one that is, paradoxically, more static at the top but also more dependent on entrepreneurship than ever before. Mr. Malone’s new book, “The Intel Trinity: How Robert Noyce, Gordon Moore, and Andy Grove Built the World’s Most Important Company” (HarperBusiness), will be published in July. Restive Republicans Target the Ex-Im Bank was understandable that Mr. Cantor’s defeat would be taken to spell the end of hopes for immigration reform in this Congress, and perhaps the next as well. Less predictably, it has also jeopardized the reauthorization of the Export-Import Bank, a venerable if modest institution whose mission is to promote U.S. exports by providing financing for transactions in which the private sector declines to participate. The majority leader’s successful challenger castigated him for being too close to Wall Street and for encouraging what populists of the left and right call “crony capitalism.” The Export-Import Bank, which Rep. Cantor supported, has become the poster child for this allegedly corrupt, self-dealing relationship between government and the private sector. Kevin McCarthy, the favorite to replace Mr. Cantor, was also an advocate for the bank. But Bloomberg reports that on June 18, the day before Republicans were to vote on a new majority leader, a group of populist members met with Mr. McCarthy and told him that the Ex-Im Bank must go. Three days after winning the election, he went on national television to announce that he had withdrawn his support from the bank, sparking panic in the ranks of business groups who had long relied on the House Republican leadership’s steadfast defense of the bank against its critics. Most of these critics are restive rank-and-file members. But not all. At the beginning of a hearing convened in June 2013 to Composite ouse Majority Leader Eric Cantor’s shocking primary loss has exposed the divide between establishment and populist conservatives over economic fundamentals. The most recent survey from the Pew Research center sheds light on the core differences between these two groups, who together account for 70% of the Republicans who pay close attention to politics and vote in nearly every election. The survey shows that 71% of populist conservatives bePOLITICS lieve that too & IDEAS much power is concentrated in By William large companies, A. Galston versus only 35% of the establishment conservatives. Among the establishment, 74% think that Wall Street helps the economy more than it hurts; only 49% of populists agree. These differences shape stances on particular issues. The survey finds that 68% of establishment conservatives believe that free-trade agreements benefit the U.S., compared with only 39% of populists. On immigration, 64% of the establishment thinks that immigrants strengthen our country, a view shared by only 17% of the populists. And by a margin of two to one, populists reject any and all reductions in Social Security benefits, while a plurality of the establishment believe that such reductions need to be considered. In light of these differences, it assess Ex-Im’s progress reforming its risk-management policies, House Committee on Financial Services Chairman Jeb Hensarling (R., Texas) noted that President Obama had once described the bank as “little more than a fund for corporate welfare,” adding that “I could not agree more.” (Mr. Obama made his statement during the 2008 campaign. As president, he has supported expanding ExIm’s financing authority.) Former vice-presidential candidate Paul The populist crowd is going after the wrong ‘crony capitalism’ target. Ryan is also opposed to reauthorizing the bank. As always, the real issues are more complex than the public debate. In fiscal 2013, Ex-Im supported the exports of more than 3,400 small businesses that probably could not have obtained commercial financing, for reasons unrelated to the creditworthiness of the prospective borrowers or to the quality of their proposed transactions. (Transaction costs and unfamiliarity with foreign businesses are two often-cited reasons for this commercial lending gap.) The relationship between ExIm and big business raises murkier issues. Of the roughly $12 billion in long-term loan guarantees the bank extended in fiscal 2013, the top 10 beneficiaries received 97% of the total. Boeing alone received nearly $8 billion— about two-thirds of the total. At first glance, this looks indefensible. But the manufacture and sale of commercial aircraft is far from a free market. Boeing’s major competitor—Airbus—receives massive export subsidies from a European consortium. In the best case, Europe and the U.S. would negotiate the mutual elimination of subsidies. But until that happens, say Ex-Im’s supporters, it would be self-destructive for the U.S. to stand down unilaterally. They have a point. Still, large corporate beneficiaries of Ex-Im financing should be required to prove that they could not compete profitably in overseas markets without this assistance. We should not be asked to take Boeing’s word for it—all the more so because the bank is working with our tax dollars. Although Ex-Im boasts that it returns money to the Treasury each year, a former bank president told me that if it were subject to standard capital adequacy requirements and accounting standards, it would not be reporting a profit. After everything that has happened since 2007, taxpayers deserve to know the real subsidies they are paying and risks they are running. “Crony capitalism” may be a populist rallying cry, but it is too blunt for the complex reality of market failure and government subsidies in today’s cutthroat competition for global exports. Populists should train their fire instead on the epicenter of crony capitalism—our corporate tax code. The Owl Who Liked Sitting on Caesar By Martin Windrow (Farrar, Straus & Giroux, 302 pages, $26) I n the annals of publishing, there may be a precedent or two for a venerable military historian setting aside his generals and artillery to evoke the love affair that consumed him as a younger man, but it’s probably safe to say that in none of these memoirs is the object of adoration feathered, 10 inches tall and given to maniacally attacking the historian’s shoelaces. Such is the case with Martin Windrow’s “The Owl Who Liked Sitting on Caesar.” If the above description makes the book sound funny, touching and divertingly novel, so it is. But there’s more to it than that. In relaxed yet lapidary prose, Mr. Windrow—best known for “The Last Valley,” his 2004 account of the Battle of Dien Bien Phu— has produced an homage to both a creature and its species that is almost Leonardo-like in its precision and spirit of curiosity. The result is nothing less than a small masterpiece of animal literature. In the late 1970s, having grown fond of an owl that lived with his brother in rural Kent, Mr. Windrow decided to get his own, despite living in a London highrise. After a disastrous experiment with a Little Owl that rejected him utterly, he obtained a month-old Tawny Owl. At their first meeting, he encountered a life form “shaped rather like a plump toy penguin with a nose-job. It appeared to be wearing a one-piece knitted jumpsuit of pale grey fluff with brown stitching, complete with an attached balaclava helmet. From the face-hole of the fuzzy balaclava, two big, shiny black eyes gazed up at me trustfully. ‘Kweep,’ it said quietly. . . . It blinked its furry grey eyelids, then jumped very deliberately up onto my right shoulder. It felt like a big, warm dandelion head against my cheek, and it smelt like a milky new kitten. ‘Kweep,’ it repeated, very softly.” He was a goner. Mumble, as he named her, had a cage on the balcony yet was often given the run of the flat. At times she would “roost happily” atop either a door or the author’s bust of Germanicus. At others she would indulge in “boisterous hunting games,” insist on riding the carriage of his typewriter as he wrote, and freely heed the call of nature. (Owls, he sighs, are “impossible to housetrain.”) Decidedly a “one-man bird,” she was highly affectionate with him but a territorial menace to others; whenever he had a visitor, he would issue them one of his many “old military helmets,” since Mumble was bound to “fly for their scalp.” A military historian and an owl make a home together in a London high-rise. Visitors are issued vintage helmets for protection. “Her job, her hobby, her passion was watching things,” Mr. Windrow writes of Mumble, and his own passion was watching her. His observations—many of them quoted from the journals he kept—are a joy to read, in part because of his gift for metaphor and association. “While Mumble was patrolling around the living-room floor,” one passage begins, “her vainglorious strut suddenly reminded me of a character in a Japanese samurai film. Like some warrior played by Toshiro Mifune, she had the touchy air of someone who is ready, at an instant, to take furious offence over some imagined slight.” He distinguishes and names Mumble’s various poses—“giant moth” and “cottage loaf,” to mention only two—and lists “six basic types of call,” including a “sort of ‘whistling kettle coming to the boil’ as she pumps herself up in indignation, e.g., when she notices a pigeon lurking around. This starts with a crouch, a puff of the feathery throat, and an interrogation that quickly turns dangerous: ‘skwer? . . . skwer? . . . SKWER! . . . SKWERKK!” Riveted by Mumble, Mr. Windrow began reading up on the Tawny Owl and owls in general. He presents the fruits of his research in a series of interlarded chapters on the behavior, anatomy, place in the British ecosystem and folkloric reputation of owls. (“In Yorkshire, owl soup was supposed to cure whooping-cough.”) But he also light-handedly dramatizes the way in which his growing expertise, together with his prior knowledge of aviation and military hardware, put him ever more in awe of Mumble as “a supremely elegant example of functional design.” He was especially dazzled by her telescoping neck, which he compares to the gyroscopic stabilizers used in tank turrets. Realizing that she could, while perched on his hand, keep her head fixed in place even as her body is raised and lowered, he succumbed to “the mischievous temptation to play ‘owl yo-yo’. . . . I did this several times, giggling foolishly, until Mumble got fed up with this childish game and took off.” In 1981 he decided to move to a small town in Sussex. For Mumble he built an outdoor aviary, where she thrived. Then one day in 1993, just before her 15th birthday, he found her dead, probably of a heart attack. Though tersely expressed, his devastation is clear. Like J.R. Ackerley, whose classic “My Dog Tulip” documents a relationship of almost exactly the same length, Mr. Windrow was a bachelor heavily invested in his pet. At the time he got Mumble, he was “chewing over the cold cud of some fairly discouraging insights into my own character and the probable future shape of my life.” Yet he found it “impossible to sustain a mood of self-centered depression while an indignant ball of fluff was doing squeaking pratfalls all over the place.” Mumble became his mate-equivalent, and he hers. With the restraint typical of an educated Englishman of his generation, he does not dilate on what she meant to him, but we feel it the more keenly for his reticence. A paradoxical pitfall of animal literature is that it achieves its effects too easily: Consider how quick we are to laugh when a writer so much as mentions a monkey. The good stuff, however, stands out for its refusal to push buttons or indulge in glib anthropomorphism. In this perfect book, Mr. Windrow may compare Mumble to a samurai and think of her as hurling at pigeons the owlish equivalent of a certain Anglo-Saxon expletive, but he never loses sight of what she is: Strix aluco, a beautiful alien. Mr. Downing is the author of “Queen Bee of Tuscany: The Redoubtable Janet Ross.” P2JW183000-0-A01300-1--------XA H parents—the kiss of death—are joining. So Mr. Zuckerberg has two options: radically transform his current product (no small matter with the drag of 1.3 billion users), or buy the Next Big Thing. And the next one. Then the one after that. It may prove a brilliant strategy. But it also means that Facebook, one of the most innovative companies of the past decade, now depends on purchasing the inventiveness of others. The company isn’t alone. Look around Silicon Full Feather Jacket MAGENTA BLACK CYAN YELLOW