74 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 In search of the social forces of post-Soviet Russia’s transformation, this paper traces their origins back to the critical period of 1989-1993. From 1989 onwards, competitive elections became the stimulus to the mobilizing force in society. Liberalization in the form of social pluralism had expanded the scope of the civil society, while democratization through the mechanism of contested elections had turned it into a political society. 1 The institutional empowerment of the RSFSR Congress of People’s Deputies and the Russian Presidency not only precipitated the collapse of the Soviet Union but also complicated the state-building process in post-Soviet Russia. In contrast to a regime-initiated civil society as the political ally of “perestroyka from above,” this paper focuses on the society-mobilized civil society which was the driving force of “reform from below.” 2 In this critical juncture, 1989-1993, I classify two types or functions of social forces in the development of a society-mobilized civil society in two different political contexts: first, 1989-91, an elections-stimulated and anti-regime civil society (the politics of liberation); and second, 1991-93, a pro-reform and anti-restorationist civil society (the politics of state-building). The political contexts of the disintegrating Soviet Union and the subsequent Russian state-building triggered the corresponding opportunities for political mobilization. The representative cases of a society-mobilized civil society during this transition period were the miners’ movement and Democratic Russia (DemRossiya). Miners’ strikes endangered the legitimacy of the Communist regime. The social movement DemRossiya used mass rallies and electoral mobilization to topple the Soviet nomenklatura, as well as mobilized support for Yeltsin’s administration in its struggle against the post-Soviet 1 Unlike its democratic counterparts in the anti-Communist movements in Eastern Europe, such as Solidarity in Poland, Civic Forum in Czechoslovakia, and the Union of Democratic Forces in Bulgaria, which were able to offer themselves as the alternatives to the outgoing Communist regimes, Russia’s democratic movement represented by Democratic Russia (DemRossiya) never came to power, that is, Russian civil society did not turn itself into a state. Lilia Shevtsova, Yeltsin’s Russia: Myths and Reality (Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1999), 31. 2 This chapter focuses only on democratically reform-oriented organizations of civil society. For conservative nationalist or statist groups, as well as the nationalist-communist alliance during this period, see John B. Dunlop, The Rise of Russia and the Fall of the Soviet Empire (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993), chap. 4; Gordon M. Hahn, “Opposition Politics in Russia,” Europe-Asia Studies 46, no. 2 (1994): 305-35; and Yitzhak M. Brudny, Reinventing Russia: Russian Nationalism and the Soviet State, 1953-1991 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998). 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 75 anti-reform parliament. 3 This paper mainly focuses on three sets of institutional arrangements which were central to the changing relations between state and society: elections, social partnership, and executive-legislative relations. The Politics of Liberation: An Elections-Stimulated and Anti-Regime Civil Society The roots of popular mobilization lay in the broadened political opportunity structure initiated by Gorbachev. As transition theorists maintain: “Reformist political leaders contribute to the potential for mobilization by adopting controversial policies by reaching out to formerly marginalized constituencies for support in the ensuing battles among the political elites.”4 Regime-initiated grassroots activism became a support for Gorbachev and constituted an important alliance against the conservative mid-level bureaucracy of the Communist Party. Public opinion and citizen participation became increasingly significant in this transition period. The elections of 1989 and 1990 further enlarged the opportunity structure for political mobilization. Newly empowered democratic institutions served as pro-reform counterweights to the entrenched conservative bureaucracies. Informal groups also provided training grounds for political elites and created the organizational groundwork of electoral mobilization. 5 Various voters’ clubs and electoral blocs were created by grassroots activists to support opposition candidates. 3 On a few occasions, according to Yitzhak M. Brudny, DemRossiya did not lose its impressive mobilizational ability after the collapse of Communist regime “because of a distinctive feature of the Russian democratization process: the emergence of the Gorbachev-era parliament (the Congress of People’s Deputies and its Supreme Soviet) as an institution that has threatened to reverse the democratization process in the post-communist period. This has sustained DR’s [DemRossiya] capacity as a movement for anti-restorationist mobilization.” Yitzhak M. Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’, 1990-1993” Post-Soviet Affairs 9, no. 2 (1993): 142. 4 Sidney Tarrow, “Aiming at a Moving Target: Social Science and the Recent Rebellions in Eastern Europe,” PS: Political Science and Politics (March 1991): 15. 5 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 142-43. With the exception of the Democratic Union, most informal groups viewed the elections for the USSR Congress of People’s Deputies, the Russian Congress of People’s Deputies, and the local and district soviets as opportunities to promote reform from within the system. Democratic Union did not participate in the elections and advocated the overthrow of the entire Soviet system. See Michael McFaul and Sergei Markov, The Troubled Birth of Russian Democracy: Parties, Personalities, and Programs (Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, 1993), 3 and 7. 76 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 The introduction of competitive elections for the new parliaments created unity among ideologically diverse elites and interregional electoral alliances across the country and provided the most important stimulus for the formation of DemRossiya. 6 Opposition forces under the broad umbrella of DemRossiya were poised to challenge the Communist Party for control of the state. The elections directly promoted Russia’s independent democrats into government, thus establishing a base of opposition within the Soviet state itself. The miners’ unrest, which undermined the authority of Gorbachev’s leadership and provided an opportunity for the further encroachment of the newly autonomous republic-level governments on the center, contributed to the dissolution of the central government and state structures. 7 The organizational structure, common value system, and mobilizational ability of informal groups, DemRossiya, and labor movement, in conjunction with the regime’s response, are critical elements in understanding the changing political opportunity structure as well as the development of civil society. Elections March 1989 A new election law was approved in December 1988, which provided for a choice of candidates in the coming national-level and local legislative elections. Despite the unprecedented use of contested elections for the USSR Congress of People’s Deputies, one third of the 2,250 deputies were reserved seats for the Communist Party, the Komsomol, the official trade unions and other officially-sponsored public organizations. 8 Sergey Stankevich, a leader of the Moscow Popular Front, was the only informal groups’ candidate to be elected to the 6 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 142-43. For an interview which focused on the history of informal movements leading up to the creation of DemRossiya, see the interview with Mikhail Schneider, one of the original members of the organisational committee for DemRossiya, in McFaul and Markov, The Troubled Birth of Russian Democracy, 141-53. 7 Linda J. Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed: Welfare Policy and Workers’ Politics from Brezhnev to Yeltsin (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1993), 193-96. 8 The major exception to the “rubber-stamp elections” in the 39 official public organizations authorized to select deputies occurred in the Academy of Sciences, where a widespread mutiny forced a second round of nominations and elections resulting in the winning of seats by several distinguished scientists and scholars such as Andrey Sakharov, Dmitriy Likhachev, Roald Sagdeev, and Nikolay Shmelev. See Michael Urban, Vyacheslav Igrunov, and Sergei Mitrokhin, The Rebirth of Politics in Russia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 348; and Michael Urban, More Power to the Soviets: the Democratic Revolution in the USSR (Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar, 1990), 93-7. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 77 new legislature. 9 Nevertheless, independent voters’ associations and popular fronts did help elect progressive candidates in popular elections and in elections held in public organizations as well, including Yuriy Afanas’ev, Il’ya Zaslavsky, Andrey Sakharov, Telman Gdlyan, Boris Yeltsin, and Arkadiy Murashev. Informal groups also conducted negative campaigns against conservative senior figures from the CPSU hierarchy. 10 Even though the intention of the elections was to make sure of CPSU’s “leading role” in society, which was still enshrined in the Soviet Constitution, the elections also served as “a surrogate party purge, with popular rejection at the polls providing added leverage to oust certain officials not identified with the reform leadership.” 11 The 1989 elections represented a watershed event in the course of Russia’s political development, fundamentally redefining the relations between state and society. 12 At this juncture, the Congress of People’s Deputies became an important 9 McFaul and Markov, The Troubled Birth of Russian Democracy, 143. Due to the resistance of the local apparatus, Moscow Popular Front only managed to field candidates in two electoral districts rather than in the nineteen districts of its original plan. Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 132. 10 As a result, several senior CPSU members lost in the election campaign. For example, Yuriy Solovev, the first secretary of the Leningrad oblast, ran unopposed but lost by not receiving the required 50 percent. Aleksei Bol’shakov, the deputy chairman of the Leningrad Party committee, and Anatoly Gerasimov, the first secretary of Leningrad City Party Committee, also lost. A total number of 31 regional first secretaries (the obkom and kraikom first secretaries) of the CPSU suffered defeat at the polls. For details, see V. A. Kolosov, N. V. Petrov, L. V. Smirnyagin, eds., Vesna 89: geographiya parliamentskikh vyborov (Moscow: Progress, 1990). 11 Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 120. Unable to win a seat in the electoral competition, 74 members and 36 candidate-members of the Central Committee accepted early retirement in the immediate aftermath of the elections. Ibid. 121. 12 Despite the recognition of the limitations of the USSR Congress of People’s Deputies as a representative institution, the Moscow Popular Front members still actively participated in the elections because of their conviction that “change in a reformed Soviet political society, however limited, was the only way to create the social basis for political influence when the party and state controlled all instruments of coercion and still dominated resources essential for the mobilization of independent activity.” They concluded that participating in the elections rather than conducting extrasystemic confrontation against the Communist party was the only option for increasing public awareness and activating citizens’ political consciousness. Marcia A. Weigle, Russia’s Liberal Project: State-Society Relations in the Transition from Communism (University Park: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 2000), 148-49. 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 78 institution for further democratic mobilization throughout 1989. During the May-June first Congress, millions of people followed the daily proceedings of the Congress through live television and radio. 13 Memorial and the Moscow Popular Front alternated as hosts to the daily mass rally held at the parade grounds next to the Luzhniki sports stadium, which served as a meeting place between deputies and electorate. 14 Over 100,000 people showed up to endorse the principal slogans: “All Power to the Soviets!,” “For a Radical Perestroika!,” and “For a Union of Really Free and Sovereign People!.” 15 At the end of congressional proceedings, progressive deputies, such as Afanas’ev, Yeltsin, Gavriil Popov, Stankevich, and Sakharov, arrived at Luzhniki and gave their personal reports to the rally on that day’s events at the Congress. The idea of the Moscow Association of Voters (MOI, in its Russian acronym), a coalition of voters’ clubs that had coalesced around democratic candidates during the March 1989 elections, was born at these rallies. 16 The backbone of MOI was the Moscow Popular Front groups in every borough and the teams that had acted as deputies’ campaign staffs. 17 Aiming at the upcoming Russian elections scheduled for March 1990, MOI decided to seek maximum inclusiveness by avoiding potentially divisive issues such as formulating a program (none was adopted) or choosing a leader (a fifteen-person Coordinating Council was elected). 18 Within the Congress, a liberal bloc called the Interregional Group of Deputies (hereafter: IGD) was organized by the progressive deputies. It was officially founded in July 1989 by some 388 deputies. Five co-chairmen were elected, including Yeltsin, Afanas’ev, Popov, Sakharov, and Viktor Palm. A Coordinating Council of twenty-five 13 Sakharov commented on this effect that, “the televised debates attracted enormous attention and served further to politicize the populace.” Literaturnaya gazeta, 21 June 1989. Cited in Dunlop, The Rise of Russia and the Fall of the Soviet Empire, 80. 14 The other sponsored informal groups were Moscow Tribune, Democratic Perestroika, Civic Dignity, and Voters’ Club of Moscow. See Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 156. 15 16 Ibid. “Interview with Mikhail Schneider,” in McFaul and Markov, The Troubled Birth of Russian Democracy, 148. 17 Ibid. 18 Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 165. MOI held its founding conference on 27 July 1989. According to MOI’s charter, MOI was “a union of clubs and committees devoted to promoting civil society and democracy whose efforts would be coordinated, but in no way directed, by MOI itself. The functions envisaged for MOI were confined to publicity and electioneering: organization of public discussions, publication of information bulletins, service on electoral commissions, nomination of candidates, conducting election campaigns and contributing to the legislative process by drafting bills.” Ibid., 360. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 79 persons was selected. In the political sphere, the platform adopted at the founding congress advocated “revoking the CPSU’s monopoly on power, the granting of full power to the soviets, the right of citizens freely to form political, professional, and other organizations, and the responsibility of power before society.” 19 Despite its organizational weakness, the appearance of IGD as an opposition faction in the legislature, around which grassroots informal groups and voters’ clubs began to unite, represented a breakthrough for the democratic movement in terms of communication. 20 In addition to regular attendance of IGD’s members at meetings held by informal groups, the Coordinating Council of IGD also invited representatives of informal groups to its conferences in December 1989 to cement close relations with the democratic movement. 21 IGD’s changing political identity throughout 1989 could be described as follows: “If its leading intellectual figures from Moscow Tribune had defined their role in early 1989 as progressive counsel to the authorities and by mid-year as a loyal--albeit reluctant--opposition, then by year’s end they were prepared to acknowledge that theirs was indeed an opposition aimed not at reforming the Communist system but at liquidating it.” 22 In January 1990, the Democratic Platform reform faction within the CPSU was founded in Moscow by 455 delegates representing 175 party clubs and organizations and 55,000 Communists from 102 cities and 13 union republics, to demand “rapid democratization of the Communist party.” 23 On 2 February 1990 a democratic demonstration attended by an estimated 500,000 people, the largest one held in Moscow in decades, called for the revoking of Article Six of the Constitution. 24 Miners’ Strikes The most significant worker activism by way of the massive strikes in 1989 resulted from Gorbachev’s political reforms. 25 The abrupt change in the political 19 Russkaya mysl’, 4 August 1989. Cited in Dunlop, The Rise of Russia and the Fall of the Soviet Empire, 83. 20 Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 164. 21 Ibid., 168 and 361. 22 Ibid., 168. 23 Dunlop, The Rise of Russia and the Fall of the Soviet Empire, 92. 24 Ibid., 93. 25 In the pre-Gorbachev period, according to Victor Zaslavsky, the lack of solidarity and collective action among Soviet workers resulted from the credible threat of repression and from bureaucratic 80 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 climate, which occurred in the wake of the 1989 election campaign and the live broadcasts of the first Congress, stimulated the process of politicization of miners’ demands in the major coal mining regions such as the Kuzbass, Vorkuta and the Donbass. 26 This wave of coal miners’ strikes was not related to ethnic disputes as was the previous mass strikes in the Caucasus and the Baltic republics in 1988, but to political mobilization of sections of the Soviet working class. 27 Thanks to glasnost’, the miners’ strikes of July 1989 received unprecedented publicity which set off a demonstration effect throughout the USSR. 28 The coal miners’ strategic position in industry gave them the potential for collective action that could have damaged or paralyzed the economy. Demanding better wages and improved working conditions, over half a million miners were on manipulation of workers. An atomized and depoliticized working class resulted in the workers’ political quiescence. See Victor Zaslavsky, The Neo-Stalinist State: Class, Ethnicity, and Consensus in Soviet Society (Armonk: M. E. Sharpe, 1982). Glasnost’ and the loosening of political control contributed significantly to the emergence of labor activism and unrest. In the autumn of 1987, the Soviet press began reporting Soviet workers’ protests, work stoppages, and strikes. In addition, during the years 1986 through 1988, the consequences of a number of reform policies, such as an economic modernization plan calling for large-scale reductions in the use of manual labor, and the Law on the State Enterprises mandating both self-financing and self-management, provided the context for the growth of workers’ discontent and activism. Appealing through established, official channels, workers’ protests against layoffs and pay cuts remained politically innocuous and were confined to individual grievances, to the factories and to production relations. The patterns of workers’ strikes of 1987 and 1988 were spontaneous, uncoordinated, disconnected, and localized. Even from the perspective of the social contract thesis which constrained the Gorbachev regime from pursuing its original reform strategy, “before mid-1989, workers’ protests were neither large nor well organized enough to force policy retreat.” See Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 152-56, and 207. 26 Russell Bova, “Worker Activism: the Role of the State,” in Perestroika from Below: Social Movements in the Soviet Union, eds. J. B. Sedaitis and J. Butterfield (Boulder: Westview, 1991), 33-4. 27 Peter Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” in Milestones in Glasnost and Perestroyka: Politics and People, eds. Ed A. Hewett and Victor H. Winston (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1991), 290. According to Rutland, the worker unrest of 1989 had two distinctive features: first, the plethora of demands, ranging from constitutional changes to minor aspects of wage policy; and second, the extreme fragmentation of the movement--both over the tactics to be followed, and over the general goals to be pursued. Ibid., 288. 28 Elizabeth Teague, “Perestroika and the Soviet Worker,” Government and Opposition 25, no. 2 (1990), 197. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 81 strike between 10 and 22 July 1989, the first time since the 1920s. 29 From July to November 1989, the time lost through strikes amounted to 5.5 million man-days, that is, an average of nearly 50,000 workers were on strike each day. 30 The miners’ strikes bypassed the official trade unions and local authorities, demonstrating the latter’s irrelevance to the miners’ needs. As a result, to co-ordinate activities and to negotiate on their behalf with the authorities, the miners set up their own strike committees which formulated their demands. 31 Strike committees later transformed themselves into permanent workers’ committees to monitor the implementation of the strike agreements. The role of the miners was pivotal in accelerating “perestroyka from below,” and in discrediting further the central planning system and the local party-state apparatus. 32 The miners’ demands escalated from material necessities to political ones. The first explicitly political demands came from the Arctic city of Vorkuta 29 Judith Devlin, The Rise of the Russian Democrats: The Causes and Consequences of the Elite Revolution (Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar, 1995), 230. 30 Izvestiya, 14 December 1989. 31 Miners’ discontents and grievances focused on living conditions, work regime, the slow pace of reform, the effects of reform, management, and environmental pollution. A typical list of demands included improved pay, pensions, and holidays; better provision of food and industrial goods; more housing construction; consumer, municipal, and medical services; more investment in modernization of the mines; cuts in the administrative apparatus; and more rights for labor collectives. In general, the miners supported the industrial reforms, that is, enterprise autonomy and self-financing. For details, see Izvestiya, 19 July 1989, p. 6; and Trud, 12 July 1989, p. 1. 32 The experience of Poland’s Solidarity in 1980 was not relevant for the case of Soviet workers’ unrest in the year of 1989. As Elizabeth Teague pointed out, three aspects revealed the difference. First, the main aim of the Polish workers was to set up an independent trade union movement, while Soviet workers just tried to reform the system from within. Secondly, Polish dissident intellectuals played a major role in the development of the workers’ movement, while the communication between Soviet workers and intellectuals was at that time almost non-existent. Thirdly and most importantly, the Polish society was ethnically homogeneous and united by its Catholic faith, while the Soviet Union was a multinational empire which led to the fragmentation of workers’ movements. Teague, “Perestroika and the Soviet Worker,” 204-5. Rutland also pointed out that the links between the Soviet regions in the course of strikes were rather tenuous, that is, the links were through an interregional demonstration effect rather than through a network of truckers ferrying messages between the regional centers which Poland’s Solidarity did in 1980. The Soviet strikes of 1989 did not succeed in generating a broadly based workers’ movement along the lines of Poland’s Solidarity to topple the Soviet system. See Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” 292, 304 and 307-8. 82 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 during the July 1989 strikes which coincided with the televised meetings of the opening session of the Supreme Soviet. 33 Vladimir Lushnikov, a miner deputy elected from Vorkuta, spelled out the political demands of the miners in a nationally televised speech before the USSR Supreme Soviet: the removal of Article 6 from the Constitution; direct election of the chairmen of soviets at all levels; and the abolition of the guaranteed seats in the soviets for the officially-sponsored public organizations. 34 The government developed ad hoc procedures, sending high-level commissions to negotiate with the strike committees, and providing multiple institutional guarantors including the Council of Ministers and the All-Union Central Council of Trade Unions to the strike agreements. The miners’ strikes were defused only through the signed agreements which were formalized as Council of Ministers Resolution No. 608 that assured miners’ grievances and demands would be met in full. 35 The government also tried to establish a legal framework for industrial conflicts. On October 9 1989 the Supreme Soviet adopted the resolution “On Procedures for Settling Collective Labor Disputes,” which both established and limited Soviet workers’ right to strike. 36 The issue of the legality of strikes politicized the continuing workers’ unrest and left miners outraged and intransigent. 37 Apart from the coal mining areas, strike activity in other key sectors of the economy tried to emulate the miners’ success but failed to generate a network of new organizations capable of articulating and defending workers’ interests. 38 The March 33 Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” 301. 34 Krasnaya znamya, 25 July 1989, p. 1. Cited in Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” 301. 35 Polozheniye, “O gosudarstvenno-obshchestvennoy komissii po kontrol’yu za vypolneniyem postanovleniya SM SSSR ot 3 Avgusta 1989 no. 608,” Moscow, 24 November 1989. See Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” 302-4. 36 For the text of this resolution, see Pravda, 14 October 1989, pp. 1-2. 37 Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 170-71. 38 Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” 314-15. The coal miners represent only one sector of the industrial labor force. In the words of Linda J. Cook, “a sector clearly distinguished by three features of the mining socioeconomy which are critical to an understanding of the strikes’ patterns and program: 1. the concentration of miners in workers’ settlements where they do hard and dangerous work, which contributed to their solidarity and militance; 2. the low profitability of the coal industry caused by state price control; 3. international demand for coal, which can potentially be sold for hard currency on international markets.” Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 157. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 83 1990 elections for republic and local soviets provided an opportunity for strike activists to participate in high politics. For example, five Kuzbass leaders were elected to the Russian parliament, and 30 candidates who were endorsed by Kuzbass’s electoral campaign were elected to the 250-seat Kemerovo oblast soviet. 39 The miners’ committees continued to raise grievances about the government’s fulfillment of the strike accord, Resolution No. 608. In July 1990, the Regional Council of Strike Committees called a twenty-four-hour political strike to demand the resignation of Ryzhkov’s government, the end of party control of enterprises and central institutions, and the nationalization of the property of the Communist Party and All-Union Central Council of Trade Unions. 40 In the absence of both institutionalized mechanisms and competence for bargaining with organized workers, as Linda J. Cook wrote, “Ryzhkov’s government typically responded to labor unrest with easy concessions followed by poor delivery, setting a pattern which led repeatedly to protracted disputes with mobilized sectors of the labor force, and which further undermined the state’s authority.” 41 In the hope of creating a new, independent national trade union federation, the Confederation of Labor was formed in May 1990 in Novokuznetsk by 270 representatives of small independent unions from around the country. 42 This organisation was weak and could not represent the whole workers’ movement because workers from other industries, except those from the Kuzbass coal mining districts, failed to join it in significant numbers. Attempts by party conservatives to co-opt the workers’ movement through the compliant United Workers’ Front also failed to attract the miners. 43 Due to their declining living standards and the government’s failure to implement Resolution No. 608, particularly regarding the miners’ economic autonomy, the coal miners went on strike again in March 1991. With a lack of unified leadership, the 39 V. Pribylovskiy, Slovar’ novykh politicheskikh partii i organizatsii Rossii (Moscow: Panorama, 1991), 83. 40 Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 193. 41 Ibid., 194 and 206. 42 Rutland, “Labor Unrest and Movements in 1989 and 1990,” 310; and V. N. Berezovskiy, N. I. Krotov and V. V. Chervyakov, Rossiya: partii, assotsiatsii, soyuzy, kluby, vol. 1 (Moscow: Rau-Press, 1991), 56-7. 43 On the formation of the United Workers’ Front, see FBIS:SU, 25 August 1989, p. 82, and FBIS:SU, 20 October 1989, pp, 71-73. 84 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 strikers displayed less organisation and unity than in the summer of 1989. 44 The April 1991 price reform further politicized labors’ movement. In the first quarter of 1991, Russia lost 573,000 man-days through strikes. 45 Because the miners no longer trusted the central government to deliver on its promises, they began to look to republic-level governments, which became the alternative bargaining partners, for satisfaction of their demands. With the republic governments promising the miners economic independence, together they formed an alliance against the center and found common ground in demanding the transfer of the mines from central to republic jurisdiction. The Soviet regime-labor relations during Gorbachev’s period can be summarized in Cook’s words, [T]he democratizing Soviet state was weak and vulnerable in the face of grass-roots challenges from labor. No longer willing to repress workers’ grievances in the mode of its authoritarian predecessor, it also lacked the established democratic state’s legal and institutional framework for labor negotiation. Moreover, its hurried efforts to create rules for dealing with industrial conflicts failed; miners and others rejected the legislation, and its application served only to politicize the labor movement. 46 The March 1990 RSFSR Elections With minor modifications, Russian legislative structure was built on the model of the USSR Congress of People’s Deputies: Congress, Supreme Soviet, and Presidium of the Supreme Soviet. Russian Congress had 1,068 deputies, 900 of them elected in equally sized popular districts, and 168 of them elected in national-territorial districts. There were no seats reserved for public organizations. The major difference between the Russian and the USSR legislatures stemmed from the electoral laws that defined 44 The three organizations which initiated the strike, the Council of Kuzbass Workers’ Committees, the Regional Council of Donbass Strike Committees, and the Independent Trade Union of Coal Miners, shortly set up the Interregional Coordinating Council in Moscow. Despite their varied demands, the two central demands were: “wage increase of 100 to 150 percent with improved pension benefits, and the resignation of Gorbachev and his government.” Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 194. 45 Ekonomika i zhizn’, no., 17, 1991, p. 16. 46 Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 171. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 85 the way the candidates were nominated. 47 Russian electoral law, which was passed by the old Russian Supreme Soviet in October 1989, abolished the pre-electoral district meetings, the “filters” in the March 1989 elections, which kept many independent candidates off the ballot, and enabled many more types of collectives the right to nominate candidates. 48 MOI made concerted efforts to get some of its members elected to the district electoral commissions, since the latter had arbitrarily denied the registrations of thousands of candidates in the previous elections. 49 The 1990 elections for the RSFSR Congress of People’s Deputies as well as local and district soviets reinvigorated grassroots political activism. To get a better chance of winning a seat, emerging political groups were inclined to become a serious political force through the establishment of an electoral bloc. 50 Groups like Moscow Popular Front and MOI became professional campaign organizations by means of organizing mass demonstrations, disseminating leaflets, and mobilizing support networks for democratically-minded candidates endorsed by the newly-established electoral bloc DemRossiya. 51 Thus, opposition to the election candidates associated with the Communist party apparatus and their nomenklatura allies in the state bureaucracy and in state enterprises was organized by DemRossiya. DemRossiya was supporting more than 5,000 candidates for the various soviets by 20 February 1990. 52 Radical majorities were elected to the city councils of Moscow, Leningrad, Kiev, and several large cities in the Urals, Siberia, and the Far East. 47 Jerry F. Hough, Democratization and Revolution in the USSR, 1985-1991 (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1997), 282-3. The more democratic electoral rules led to a more democratic nomination process. According to Hough, “More candidates were nominated in the 1,068 districts in the 1990 Russian election than in the 1,500 districts in the 1989 USSR election--8,254 or 7.7 per district as compared with 7,351 or 4.9 per district in 1989. More important, the screening process had drastically reduced the number of candidates from 4.9 to 1.9 per district in 1989, but only from 7.7 to 6.3 in 1990. The decrease in 1990 seems to have resulted almost totally from the voluntary withdrawal of candidates, rules violations, or candidates being nominated in more than one district.” Ibid., 283-4. 48 For the text of the 1990 Russian electoral law, see Izvestiya, 28 October 1989. 49 Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 176. 50 I. N. Barygin, ed., Politicheskie partii, dvizheniya i organizatsii sovremennoy Rossii na rubezhe vekov. 1999 g. Analiticheskiy spravochnik (St Petersburg: Izdatel’stvo Mikhaylova V. A., 1999), 35. 51 In addition to MOI and the Moscow Popular Front, the other important organizational predecessors of DemRossiya were the Memorial, the Interclub Party Group, the nationwide network of voters’ clubs, and the Interregional Group of Deputies. Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 143. 52 Argumenty i fakty, no. 8, (24 February-2 March 1990), p. 8. 86 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 After February 1990 new political parties had formed as a result of the repeal of the Communist Party’s monopoly enshrined in Article Six of the Constitution. 53 However, the March 1990 elections were not multi-party elections both because the Constitutional amendment was enacted too late (the official removal of Article 6 from the Soviet Constitution was carried out on 13 March 1990 by the Third Congress of People’s Deputies) to affect the formalities of the balloting 54 and because new political parties had organized themselves too late to participate in the elections.55 The Law on Public Associations which was adopted in October 1990 established the legal mechanism whereby registered political parties and other civic organizations could gain the status of juridical persons, thereby enabling them legally to engage in their essential activities, such as opening of bank accounts, possession of foreign currency, rental of premises, conclusion of contracts with printing houses, acquisition of copying equipment, and operation of their own newspapers. 56 53 Article Six of the 1977 Soviet Constitution (which declared the Communist Party to be “the leading and guiding force of Soviet society and the nucleus of its political system”) was replaced by a provision which legalized the principle of a multi-party system: “The Communist Party of the Soviet Union, other political parties, as well as trade union, youth, and other public organizations and mass movements participate in shaping the policies of the Soviet state and in running state and public affairs through their representatives elected to the soviets of people’s deputies and in other ways.” Pravda, 16 March 1990. Cited in Stephen White, Graeme Gill, and Darrell Slider, The Politics of Transition: Shaping a Post-Soviet Future (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), 155. 54 Timothy J. Colton, “The Moscow Election of 1990,” in Hewett and Winston, eds., Milestones in Glasnost and Perestroyka, 334-5. 55 Even though Democratic Union, the self-proclaimed political party, had been founded in May 1988, it boycotted both the 1989 and 1990 elections. On the formation of political parties, Urban, Igrunov, and Mitrokhin, specified two axes of conflict that structured party formation from the emergence of a national movement opposed to the Soviet regime in late 1989 to that regime’s overthrow in August 1991: the first axis was a single social-political movement as opposition to the Communist order; and the second axis was conflict over sovereignty, Russia versus the USSR, after the 1990 elections. They identified three types of political parties that formed in correspondence to three stages of CPSU disintegration within the above time-frame: Stage 1: identity-based parties, such as the Social Democratic Party of Russia, the Russian Christian Democratic Movement, and the Constitutional Democratic Party; Stage 2: programmatic factions in the CPSU, including the Marxist Platform, the Democratic Platform, and the Movement of Communist Initiative; and Stage 3: the anti-Communist party, such as the Democratic Party of Russia. See Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 201-20. 56 White, Gill, and Slider, The Politics of Transition, 155-56. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 87 The concept of civil society was officially welcomed at the 28th Congress of CPSU in 1990 when an entire section of the official document “Toward a Humane Democratic Socialism” was devoted to “civil society and the legal state.” Among the formulations to be found there are the following: “the formation of a civil society in which no person exists for the sake of the state, but the state exists for the sake of the person;” and “all social groups and communities have a guaranteed legal right and actual possibility to express and build their interests,” which would be protected by the “strengthening of a legal state, which excludes the dictatorship of any class, party, grouping, or administrative bureaucracy.” 57 A new Central Committee Department for Work with Socio-Political Organizations was created to facilitate contacts with public organizations. However, public associations also faced resistance from conservative Communist officials who used the power they possessed over registration and access to facilities such as premises and printing equipment to obstruct the former activities. 58 They also tried to hinder the development of the emerging public organizations by such dirty tricks as infiltration of existing organizations, fostering alternative groups to oppose those they perceived to be a challenge, attacks in the media, and the forcible break-up of meetings. 59 In order to gain the status of a legal entity DemRossiya decided to register its organizing committee with the Moscow City Council. 60 DemRossiya held its founding congress in Moscow on 20-21 October 1990 and defined itself as a movement consisting of its parliamentary bloc, political parties, civic organizations, and individuals. 61 It was a loosely organized and collectively led social movement 57 Materialy XXVIII S’ezda KPSS, pp. 88-89. Cited in Mary Buckley, Redefining Russian Society and Polity (Boulder: Westview Press, 1993), 202. For emphasizing the importance of civil society and a legal state for the development of human civilization, see the article published in the journal Communist, Viktor Zotov, “Grazhdanskoe obshchestvo i pravovoe gosudarstvo: pokazateli tsivilizovannosti,” Kommunist 17 (November 1990): 20-30. 58 White, Gill, and Slider, The Politics of Transition, 160. 59 Ibid. 60 “Interview with Mikhail Schneider,” 151. 61 According to Brudny, the founding congress of DemRossiya “was the most representative gathering of democratic forces ever assembled in Russia: 1,273 delegates representing 10 main political parties and 31 democratic organizations, the Interregional Group of Deputies, the DR [DemRossiya] parliamentary bloc, and regionally-elected delegates from Moscow, Leningrad, and seventy regions of Russia.” DemRossiya’s intention of coordinating all existing democratic organizations “represented a 88 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 rather than a well-disciplined and vertically-structured political party. 62 Its goals were the “coordination of democratic forces opposing the state-political monopoly of the CPSU, the carrying out of joint electoral campaigns, the coordination of parliamentary activity, and other concrete actions promoting the creation of a civil society.” 63 In the absence of identifiable social interests or social differentiation structured by property relations and manifest as associations pursuing specific interests, the only mandate that DemRossiya could have sought in the elections was a political mandate to undo the Communist order. 64 As an anti-Communist movement, DemRossiya organized a series of demonstrations in major cities throughout Russia to topple the old order: a protest over the invasions of Lithuania and Latvia in January 1991; a successfully mobilized support for Yeltsin in March 1991 when the conservative members of the Russian Congress of People’s Deputies had launched a campaign to relieve Yeltsin of his chairmanship; the landslide election of Yeltsin as Russia’s first President in June 1991; and the banning of the Communist Party following the August 1991 putsch. June 1991 Russian Presidential Election and the August 1991 Coup By the spring of 1991 DemRossiya had emerged as a force to be reckoned with: by April 1991 it boasted a membership of 1.3 million in a thousand cities and towns across Russia; a significant presence in the Russian parliament (about 35 per cent of the seats); majorities of seats in the city soviets of Moscow and Leningrad; and its clear departure from the East European model of a social movement which envisioned only individual membership.” Cited in Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 149 and 148, respectively. 62 Ibid., 148. DemRossiya’s governing bodies consisted of a 48-member Coordinating Council and a 138-member Council of Regional Representatives. The movement’s first elected co-chairmen were Yuriy Afanas’ev, Viktor Dmitriyev, Arkadiy Murashov, Lev Ponomaryov, and Gavriil Popov. Ibid., 150. 63 Ibid., 150. According to the Declaration of the Congress of the DemRossiya, DemRossiya is founded on the following principles: 1. Priority of the rights and interests of the individual over the rights and interests of the State, parties, social and ethnic groups; 2. Implementation of the right to self-determination, while observing the rights of the ethnic, religious and other minorities of the non-native population; 3. Creation of a social market economy through privatization; 4. Social security and charity as essential elements of the civil society; and 5. Intellectual and confessional tolerance, while fighting totalitarian parties and structures which aspire to a political monopoly. Cited in Devlin, The Rise of the Russian Democrats, 216. 64 Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 199, 220, and 371. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 89 mobilizational ability for demonstrations in the capital and other large cities. 65 Despite DemRossiya’s disappointment with Yeltsin’s refusal to accommodate its request to call on Russians to vote against the Union in the March 1991 referendum, the establishment of the Russian presidency endorsed by the referendum provided a new opportunity for DemRossiya to mobilize democratic forces to campaign for Yeltsin. DemRossiya’s National Initiative Group was officially registered with Moscow City Soviet in May 1991 for the purpose of placing Yeltsin’s name on the ballot through the petition option requiring 100,000 signatures. 66 Activists of DemRossiya played a key role in the work of the electoral headquarters in Moscow and in the regional headquarters in provincial cities as well. 67 Emphasizing the image of a statesman standing above the political fray, Yeltsin, even as a symbolic leader of DemRossiya, did not establish any formal connections with DemRossiya or any other organisation. 68 Soon after the elections, Yeltsin further distanced himself from DemRossiya. 69 Regardless of DemRossiya’s rejection of the draft of the Union Treaty, Yeltsin’s decision to sign the treaty jeopardized their alliance. 70 The August 1991 coup defused their potential confrontation and provided DemRossiya another opportunity to mobilize social forces in support of Yeltsin through three mass demonstrations in Moscow and pro-democracy rallies in major provincial cities. 71 The unprecedented civic unity and mobilization, particularly in Moscow, raised the political costs of repression enormously and contributed substantially to the failure of the coup which ended in just a few days. The Politics of State-Building: A Pro-Reform and Anti-Restorationist Civil Society 65 Michael E. Urban, “Boris El’tsin, Democratic Russia and the Campaign for the Russian Presidency,” Soviet Studies 44, no. 2 (1992): 191. 66 Ibid., 204. 67 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 152. 68 Yeltsin eschewed establishing any direct relationship with DemRossiya which secured his nomination and conducted his election campaign. For example, Yeltsin failed to consult DemRossiya on such major issues as the “nine-plus-one” agreement, his choice of Aleksander Rutskoi for his running mate, and the composition of his post-election government. Urban, “Boris El’tsin, Democratic Russia and the Campaign for the Russian Presidency,” 194. 69 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 152. 70 Ibid., 152-53. 71 Ibid. 90 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 The major root of the political crisis in post-Communist Russia was the widening gap between a weak and unconsolidated regime and a gradually demobilized society. The sources of the power struggle lay more within the emerging political system than outside of it. 72 In the words of Afanas’ev, one leading member of DemRossiya, “The confrontational character of the relations between the government and the society has changed little since Communism’s collapse....Russian society is excluded from the decision-making process.” 73 Few of the institutional, legal, cultural, or behavioral supports essential for an institutionalized civil society were in place. The domination of political structure over civil society continued due to the rudimentary and amorphous situation of post-Soviet civil society. 74 Accordingly, the confrontation between the executive and the legislative branches took place in the context of growing passivity on the part of society and increasing weakness of the democratic movement. 75 In this section, the social bases of the construction of post-Soviet Russia’s state are addressed in an analysis of corporatist forms of interest representation and the adapting role of DemRossiya in support of Yeltsin’s administration. The Failure of Social Partnership 76 72 Lilia Shevtsova, “Parliament and the Political Crisis in Russia, 1991-1993,” in Democratization in Russia: The Development of Legislative Institutions, ed. Jeffrey W. Hahn (Armonk: M. E. Sharpe, 1996), 41. 73 Literaturnaya gazeta, February 19, 1992. Cited in Shevtsova, Yeltsin’s Russia, 33. 74 A. Galkin and Yu. Krasin, Grazhdanskoe obshchestvo: put’ k politicheskoy stabil’nosti (Moscow: Fond sotsial’no-politicheskikh issledovaniy, 1992), 7. 75 Shevtsova, “Parliament and the Political Crisis in Russia, 1991-1993,” 37-39. 76 It should be noted that by the autumn of 1990, both the central and republic-level governments had actually begun holding regular consultations with the reformed official trade unions over employment, income, and other labor and social policies. In October 1990, Ryzhkov declared his government ready for a social partnership with the newly-established General Confederation of Trade Unions (the reformed successor of the old All-Union Central Council of Trade Unions). A general agreement between the union and the Council of Ministers, which gave organized labor privileged status and influence in economic and social policy-making, was approved in April 1991. According to Cook, there were three problems with this social partnership (corporatist) approach to Soviet state-labor relations. First, there was no significant, independent entrepreneurial or managerial group. Secondly, the Soviet economy, with the exception of the embryonic cooperative sector, had no market features; the state largely controlled and bore responsibility for wages, prices, and production. Finally, the General Confederation of Trade Unions could not represent the interests of labor as a whole because of 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 91 To defuse industrial unrest and maintain social stability, Yeltsin’s government created an institutional framework of social partnership (also known as neocorporatism or tripartism) within which workplace conflicts might be mediated during market reforms. 77 On 26 October 1991, two days before informing the parliament of his intention to launch economic reform, Yeltsin signed a presidential decree “On Guaranteeing the Rights of Trade Unions during Transition to a Market Economy,” according to which the government would consult with both Russian official trade unions (the Federation of Independent Trade Unions of Russia, the successor to the old official RSFSR branch of Soviet trade unions) and other republican trade union associations before adopting any major legislation on social or economic issues. On 15 November 1991, Yeltsin signed a decree “On Social Partnership and the Resolution of Labor Disputes,” which pledged that the Russian government would reach an annual agreement on social and economic questions with representatives of republican trade union associations and employers. Aiming to review and set general and sectoral wage rates, monitor working conditions, and mediate industrial disputes, a tripartite commission under the co-ordination of Gennadii Burbulis, the then State Secretary, was created and composed of representatives of the Russian government, the official and unofficial trade unions, and Russia’s fledgling employers’ associations. 78 The Russian Tripartite Commission on the Regulation of Social and Labor its lack of authority among rank-and-file workers. See Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 191-92. 77 See Elizabeth Teague, “Russian Government Seeks ‘Social Partnership’,” RFE/RL Research Report 1, no., 25 (19 June 1992): 16-23. Corporatism is defined by Philippe C. Schmitter as “a system of interest representation in which the constituent units are organized into a limited number of singular, compulsory, noncompetitive, hierarchically ordered and functionally differentiated categories, recognized or licensed (if not created) by the state and granted a deliberate representational monopoly within their respective categories in exchange for observing certain controls on their selection of leaders and articulation of demands and support.” Philippe C. Schmitter, “Still the Century of Corporatism?” in The New Corporatism, eds. Fredrick B. Pike and Thomas Stritch (Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press, 1974), 93-94. 78 Organized management and organized labor were the most coherent and resource-rich interests in post-Soviet civil society, mainly because of their critical positions in the economy and due to labors’ broad membership organisation. Without their cooperation, Yeltsin would be governing in a near vacuum because he had no firm organized links to major societal interests. See Cook, The Soviet Social Contract and Why It Failed, 212. 92 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 Relations came into official existence on 2 January 1992. The staff of government ministries represented the government subgroup. A number of employers’ organizations including the Russian Union of Industrialists and Entrepreneurs and the Congress of Russian Business Circles served on the employers’ subgroup. Fourteen members of official and unofficial trade unions represented the trade union subgroup: nine representatives from the Council of the Federation of Independent Trade Unions of Russia; three from the Union of Socialist Trade Unions; and one each from the Independent Miners’ Union and the independent union of civil aviation pilots. 79 On 25 March 1992, a General Agreement for 1992 was signed by representatives of the above three subgroups. 80 In reality, the settlements of labor disputes were reached outside the tripartite framework. The government managed to reduce strikes by giving in to strikers’ demands and granting wage increases at the expense of the economic reform program. 81 The desire of the government to find compliant trade-union partners proved in vain, because such unions would not be able to win the workers’ trust. 82 The social partnership program was inadequate in shaping interest representations and in promoting a social basis of support for state power, and thus it failed to establish a corporatist arrangement for state-labor-management relations. 83 79 Teague, “Russian Government Seeks ‘Social Partnership’,” 20. 80 Under the terms of the General Agreement, “the government made various promises concerning the provision of social safety nets (retraining programs, job creation schemes, unemployment benefits, and so on) during the reform process. In return, the trade unions and the employers’ associations (including those representing major state-owned enterprises) assented to the government’s plans to liberalize prices, privatize property, and create what the General Agreement called ‘a socially oriented market economy.’ The employers’ promised to refrain from mass layoffs and plant closures, and the unions promised that, as long as the government and the employers observed their pledges, they would not call their members out on strike.” Ibid., 20-21. For the text of the General Agreement, see Ekonomika i zhizn’, no., 17, 1992, p. 20. 81 Teague, “Russian Government Seeks ‘Social Partnership’,” 22. 82 Igor Iurgens, “Chto tolky razgovarivat’ s zerkalom?” Trud, 9 October 1992, p. 3. The Federation of Independent Trade Unions, as Simon Clarke has noted, seemed to represent not the interests of workers but, along with managers, the interests of their production branch. See Simon Clarke, Peter Fairbrother, and Vadim Borisov, The Workers’ Movement in Russia (Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar, 1995), 407. 83 Corporatism failed to establish an organizational model for post-Communist Russian state-society relations. As Weigle pointed out, “The fledgling state had neither the institutional coherence nor the financial resources to promote a state-dominated corporatism; Russian society did not have the prerequisites, such as clearly defined property relations, an established market, or coherent sets of interests represented in established organizations, to produce a society-instigated corporatism. Neither business nor labor interests were developed enough to engage the state in meaningful discussion 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 93 The Constraint of Executive-Legislative Conflict The state-building period between 1992 and 1993 can be characterized as a period of “dual power,” the fighting for supreme authority in Russia between the president and the parliament. 84 Former Communists and right-wing nationalists played an active and significant role in the Russian parliament and the majority of local soviets, which became the bastion of institutional opposition to Yeltsin’s radical economic reforms. The confrontation between the executive authority and the legislature reflected the paradox of Russian political reality in this period. As Lilia Shevtsova pointed out, “On the one hand, the preservation of the old institutions that had been formed in the communist era (mainly the legislature) contributed to stability of the situation in the postcommunist period. On the other hand, attempts to use the old structures for the implementation of new goals provoked conflicts and increased the political crisis; the demands of short-term stability contradicted the demands of long-term stability.” 85 The constitutional crisis was generated by two main factors: elites’ strategic choices and the peculiar institutional arrangements. 86 Since the collapse of leading to feasible agreements on state-labor-management relations.” Weigle, Russia’s Liberal Project, 234. 84 During 1990-91, as Lilia Shevtsova observed, there were no serious conflicts between the Russian executive branch and the legislature. Their consensus was mainly based on that of the struggle with Gorbachev’s center. The disappearance of the common enemy, that is, the collapse of the Soviet Union in December 1991, stimulated a process of polarization between these two former allies. Shevtsova, “Parliament and the Political Crisis in Russia, 1991-1993,” 30. For an examination of three commonly cited explanations for the deputies’ change from support to opposition towards Yeltsin and his reform policies, i.e., (1) Faithful delegates: the deputies were representing the will of the nation in opposing Yeltsin and Gaidar; (2) Design flaws: the innate flaws of the peculiar organisation of the Soviet legislative system; and (3) Conservative deputies: the make up of the deputy corps in terms of social background, see Thomas F. Remington, “Ménage a Trois: The End of Soviet Parliamentarism,” in Democratization in Russia, 107-17. On this period as one of dual power, see Archie Brown, “Political Leadership in Post-Communist Russia,” in Russia in Search of its Future, eds. Amin Saikal and William Maley (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), 28-47. 85 86 Shevtsova, “Parliament and the Political Crisis in Russia, 1991-1993,” 38. See Yitzhak M. Brudny, “Ruslan Khasbulatov, Aleksandr Rutskoi, and Intraelite Conflict in Postcommunist Russia, 1991-1994,” in Patterns in Post-Soviet Leadership, eds. Timothy J. Colton and Robert C. Tucker (Boulder: Westview Press, 1995): 75-101. 94 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 Communism, political elites were responding to institutional opportunities to better their positions in the post-Communist Russian state. It was a power struggle within the original anti-Gorbachev alliance involving Yeltsin, on the one hand, and Ruslan Khasbulatov and Aleksandr Rutskoy, on the other. By January 1992, the Yeltsin-Khasbulatov-Rutskoy coalition had collapsed because the primary goals uniting its participants--to remove Gorbachev, destroy the CPSU, and abolish the Union structure--were fulfilled, and a consensus on economic reform and the new constitution failed to be reached. 87 The creation of the Russian presidency had destructive effects on the balance of power between conservative and democratic deputies. 88 The position of the democratic forces within the parliament was weakened as many deputies gave up their deputy mandate upon assuming an executive branch job. 89 Yeltsin tended to free executive decision making from legislative oversight rather than to build his base of support within the Congress. 90 The confrontation between the president and parliament at the top was mirrored below. The local institutions created by Yeltsin’s decree in 1991-92, the appointed presidential representatives and heads of administration, caused polarized gridlock between governors who looked to Yeltsin for support and provincial soviets which aligned themselves with Khasbulatov’s parliament. 91 The deputies had little party identification and few organizational means to 87 Ibid., 81 and 84. 88 See Remington, “Ménage a Trois: The End of Soviet Parliamentarism,” 117-32. 89 Ibid., 118-19. 90 Ibid., 126. According to Remington, the bipolar distribution of political positions along the left-right cleavage produced at the elections of 1990 had eroded by the sixth Congress (6-21 April 1992). Resisting Gaidar’s program of economic shock therapy, the Communist conservatives consolidated their power within the Congress through 1992. The left-right dimension was supplemented by a new one over presidential power. By the summer of 1993, deputies of the anti-Yeltsin opposition had assumed nearly all the leadership positions in the parliament. Ibid., 124-32. 91 Jeffrey W. Hahn, “Studying the Russian Experience: Lessons for Legislative Studies (and for Russia),” in Hahn, ed., Democratization in Russia, 244. According to Hahn, power at the local level was wielded by elites because of the institutional weakness. “In the absence of established process, local Russian politics remains highly personalistic.” Jeffrey W. Hahn, “Conclusions: Common Features of Post-Soviet Local Politics,” in Local Power and Post-Soviet Politics, eds. Theodore H. Friedgut and Jeffrey W. Hahn (Armonk: M. E. Sharpe, 1994), 277. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 95 mobilize voter support because the elections of 1990 were not multi-party elections.92 The decision not to hold founding elections in late 1991 had a destructive effect on political parties and led to a delay in the formation of representative links with the electorate. 93 Due to the weakness of alternative sources of support, the deputies subordinated themselves to the patronage power wielded by the executive and legislative leaderships. 94 The problem of the absence of strong linkages between deputies and Russian citizens helped to explain why legislative factions failed to evolve into real electoral parties. 95 Yeltsin’s refusal to associate himself with any political party further excluded party politics from regular channels of interaction with the state. The lack of a genuine multi-party system to intermediate competing social interests reinforced the conflicts at the top echelon of power. 96 The Eighth Congress of People’s Deputies on March 12, 1993 terminated all the extraordinary powers that had been accorded to Yeltsin by the Fifth Congress in October 1991: the powers to issue decrees with the force of law, to appoint local 92 The first multi-party elections came in December 1993. None of the three sets of contested elections in 1989, 1990, and 1991 fulfilled the criteria of multi-party elections. See Archie Brown, The Gorbachev Factor (Oxford: University of Oxford Press, 1996), 188. 93 See Grigoriy V. Golosov, “Formaty partiinykh sistem v novykh demokratiiakh: institutsional’nye faktory neustoichivosti i fragmentatsii,” Polis, no. 1 (1998): 106-29. According to Urban, there were three missed opportunities to provide structure to political society: (1) in January 1990 the Democratic Platform decided to remain in the CPSU; (2) in the 1991 presidential election Yeltsin avoided responsibility to his base, and the latter were reluctant to demand it; and (3) the failure to call new elections after the collapse of the Soviet Union. Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 213, 243 and 265. 94 Remington, “Ménage a Trois: The End of Soviet Parliamentarism,” 118-23. A well-defined social structure necessary to anchor a political party system did not develop, given the absence of private property or established social interests. Party development after the coup did not depend on establishing a social base of support or forming stable coalitions, due to the absence of new elections. In terms of consolidating a multi-party system, the tasks of developing a mass base, organizational coherence, and stable links with state institutions were complicated by the post-Communist conditions of social disarray, economic reforms, and state construction. Weigle, Russia’s Liberal Project, 146, 180, and 194. 95 Hahn, “Studying the Russian Experience,” 246-49. 96 Shevtsova, Yeltsin’s Russia, 89. 96 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 administrative chiefs, and to name ministers without the approval of the parliament. 97 On September 21, 1993, Yeltsin issued decree No. 1400, “On the Stages of Constitutional Reform in the Russian Federation,” to dissolve the parliament. On October 4, 1993, Yeltsin declared a state of emergency in the city of Moscow and bombarded the parliament. The Constitutional Court was also disbanded in the autumn of 1993. 98 Russia remained without such a judicial body until 1995. After his victory over parliament, Yeltsin quickly set a date of December 1993 for the new parliamentary elections and a referendum on the presidential constitution. His draft constitution which liberated the president from all constraints was approved by the national referendum. 99 The results of the new parliamentary elections were a clear vote of no confidence in the pro-presidential radical liberals represented by Gaydar’s Russia’s Choice. 100 After the elections, Yeltsin began to distance himself even further from his liberal associates. The growing role of the Prime Minister Viktor Chernomyrdin reflected the triumph of the interest groups of natural resources and agrarian lobbies, the enterprise-director elites, and the federal bureaucracy. 101 The Adapting Role of DemRossiya 97 These extraordinary powers should have expired by the end of December 1992, but they had been extended by the compromise reached at the Seventh Congress of People’s Deputies in December 1992. See Shevtsova, Yeltsin’s Russia, 69-70. 98 The Constitutional Court, which was established in 1991, proved incapable of clarifying constitutional prerogatives of state institutions. Between 1991 and 1993, with no stable state structure, the court’s role was as politicized as the policy processes occurring in the executive and the legislature. Weigle, Russia’s Liberal Project, 218. For the analysis of the Russian Constitutional Court and its function during the first Russian Republic, see Robert Sharlet, “The Russian Constitutional Court: The First Term,” Post-Soviet Affairs 9, no. 1 (January-March 1993): 1-39; and idem, “Russian Constitutional Crisis: Law and Politics under Yeltsin,” Post-Soviet Affairs 9, no. 4 (October-December 1993): 314-36. 99 Unlike its predecessor, the 1993 Constitution makes it nearly impossible for impeachment to be used, gives the president an effective veto over legislation, and is difficult to amend. The combination of veto and decree authority was crucial to Yeltsin’s ability to legislate by decree. For an argument of “the nature and extent of presidential decree authority and the political and institutional context in which it was exercised varied considerably between the two post-Soviet Russian republics,” see Scott Parrish, “Presidential Decree and Authority in Russia, 1991-95,” in Executive Decree Authority, eds. John M. Carey and Matthew Soberg Shugart (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), 62-103. 100 Shevtsova, Yeltsin’s Russia, 97. 101 Ibid., 97-103. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 97 Civil society as a whole in Soviet Russia was characterized by a common anti-regime sentiment rather than by a special program of change. This enabled the formation of an all-inclusive strategic alliance at the expense of crafting a coherent and constructive organisation. 102 In the wake of their August 1991 triumph, the divisions between Yeltsin and DemRossiya--and within DemRossiya itself--had sharpened even more. Yeltsin’s contingent strategy of enhancing his personal authority to the neglect of institutional building was achieved at the expense of his own long-term organizational base. A loose electoral bloc whose primary plank was opposition to the ruling apparatus was well suited to accomplishing the purpose of mobilizing a mass electorate during the election campaign, but what was an asset in the campaign, however, would become a liability for the elected democrats after the elections when the problem of governing had to be addressed. Focusing on the wider constituency as a whole and maintaining freedom of political maneuver, elected democratic politicians like Russia’s President Yeltsin, Moscow’s Mayor Popov, and Leningrad’s Mayor Sobchak felt that high office and membership of a political organisation were incompatible and therefore refrained from assuming leadership of DemRossiya. 103 As with other anti-Communist social movements in the post-Communist era, DemRossiya after the August 1991 coup was plagued by organizational splits and secessions, leadership infighting, an inability to define new goals and a shortage of opportunities for political mobilization, lack of funding, and the need to adjust to a long period of forced inactivity. 104 It was hard to keep the divergent groups together when the common goal of destroying the Communist regime had been achieved. For example, its composite center-right parties like Travkin’s Democratic Party, Viktor Aksyuchits’s Christian Democrats, and Mikhail Astaf’ev’s branch of the Kadets (Constitutional Democrats) did not share the majority view of DemRossiya’s members on the issue of Russian sovereignty and the need to reform the Soviet Union. 102 For example, due to the character of informal groups or voters’ associations unconcerned with programs and internal leadership structures, the efforts to form a nationwide league, such as the Popular Front of the RSFSR, or an all-union coalition of voters’ associations, such as the All-Union Association of Voters, tended to fail as in the former case, or if established, soon disappeared, as in the latter. See Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 165-67. 103 Devlin, The Rise of the Russian Democrats, 218-23. In seeking to extract the Communist Party from the state, the RSFSR Congress of People’s Deputies passed a law in June 1990 which stipulated that high-ranking members in a party could not simultaneously hold ministerial posts, or be chairmen of councils or on committees with the Supreme Soviet. 104 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 141 and 168. 98 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 This split the Moscow branch of DemRossiya and resulted in an open breach in the movement in October 1991 when Travkin, Aksyuchits, and Astaf’ev withdrew from it. 105 The infighting within, and splits of, DemRossiya’s leadership seemed inevitable. As Michael Urban, Vyacheslav Igrunov, and Sergei Mitrokhin have noted, DemRossiya’s organizational forms were shaped by the state socialist context from which it emerged and against which it defined itself. On the one hand, the absence of a civil society structured by the institution of property meant that it, too, would consist of an ensemble of personalized relations analogous to those characteristic of the party-state that it opposed......On the other hand, although it appeared as a national movement, its corpus was not a coalition of social interests expressing themselves as voluntary associations--say, trade unions or professional associations--but overlapping networks of personal acquaintances among its leaders, organizers and activists developed as far back as the dissident period and extending through the informal movement, the 1989 election campaigns, work in the I-RDG [Interregional Group of Deputies], voters’ associations and the 1990 campaign itself. 106 From the very beginning, the relationship between Yeltsin and DemRossiya was “mutually-parasitic.” 107 For DemRossiya, the lack of opportunities for electoral mobilization caused both a decline in the number of energetic activists and a trend to disintegration in local chapters. The worsening economic situation compelled DemRossiya to seek subsidies from the government to survive. 108 For Yeltsin, a growing opposition in parliament against his economic reforms forced him to seek support from DemRossiya. In December 1991, these mutual interests led to the establishment of the Public Committees of Russian Reforms based on DemRossiya’s regional branches in support of the government’s economic program. This decision caused splits between the majority pro-government wing and the minority radical opposition wing of DemRossiya’s leadership. 109 105 Devlin, The Rise of the Russian Democrats, 218. 106 Urban, et al., The Rebirth of Politics in Russia, 192. 107 Ibid., 183-84. 108 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 156. 109 According to Brudny, the radicals headed by Afanas’ev and Sal’ye condemned Yeltsin for his betrayal of the cause of democratization by preserving the political and economic power of the old nomenklatura and argued that “dependency on governmental support would transform DR [DemRossiya] into an organization completely subservient to executive authority.” Ibid., 156-59. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 99 On July 4 1992, in order to broaden the political base of support for Yeltsin, DemRossiya, several associations of private entrepreneurs, a few democratic factions in the parliament and other organizations participated in a conference entitled Forum of Supporters of Reform. On the urging of high-ranking officials, including Burbulis, Gaydar, and Anatoliy Chubays, in the autumn of 1992 this forum led to the formation of Democratic Choice, an alliance in defense of democracy and radical economic reforms, which was accompanied by the founding of its parliamentary wing of some 150 Yeltsin-supporting deputies--Parliamentary Coalition for Reforms. 110 The defeat of DemRossiya’s radical members and the creation of the pro-Yeltsin Democratic Choice alliance brought to an end DemRossiya’s year-long period of splits among its leadership, as well as the search for the resources and the new goals to maintain its raison d’etre. 111 Facing a wave of anti-reform demonstrations staged by the Communist-nationalist alliance and a growing anti-Yeltsin parliament, DemRossiya’s revitalized political mission was to rally Russians to defend Yeltsin for the sake of radical economic reform and constitutional reform, one consistent with its experience in oppositional political mobilization. 112 In sharp contrast to its demobilized democratic counterparts in Eastern Europe and the Baltic states in the post-Communist era, DemRossiya did not lose its impressive mobilizational ability, demonstrating its support for Yeltsin in the cases of the March 1993 impeachment and the April 1993 referendum. 113 However, the 110 Ibid., 160-61. In sharp contrast to the rapid privatization program of Democratic Choice, the Civic Union, a center-right coalition between Arkadiy Volskiy’s Russian Union of Industrialists and Entrepreneurs, Travkin’s Democratic Party, and Rutskoi’s People’s Party of Free Russia, was formed earlier in June 1992, representing the particular interests of the industrialists and state enterprise managers. For arguments that a passive Russian state was under the control of the economic interests of the management, see A. A. Ignat’ev and B. V. Mikhailov, “Grazhdanskoe obshchestvo i perspektivy demokratii v Rossii,” in Grazhdanskoe obshchestvo i perspektivy demokratii v Rossii, ed., B. V. Mikhailov (Moscow: Rossiiskii nauchnyi fond, 1994). 111 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 161. 112 Ibid., 157-61. 113 DemRossiya mobilized 100,000 demonstrators, the largest political rally since the August 1991 coup, on Red Square to express their support for Yeltsin on 28 March 1993, the day the Congress was voting on the motion to impeach the Russian president. DemRossiya also made a greater contribution to Yeltsin’s victory in the referendum than its contribution to his 1991 presidential victory. DemRossiya succeeded in mobilizing the presumably indifferent electorate through its Public Committees in Support of the Referendum in every region. A total of 64.2 percent of the registered voters cast their ballots, while 58.7 and 53 percent, respectively, expressed their support for Yeltsin and 100 俄羅斯學報 第三期 民國 92 年 3 月 development of the social movement DemRossiya was ultimately dependent on Yeltsin’s willingness to adopt a populist political strategy as a contingent alternative to his preferred intra-elite compromise: Yeltsin’s confrontation with his opponents energized DemRossiya; Yeltsin’s compromise with his opponents relegated DemRossiya to irrelevance. 114 Conclusion A gradual widening of the boundaries of legitimate social initiatives promoted a society-mobilized civil society to define its own reform agendas that challenged the authority and legitimacy of the Communist regime. The introduction of contested elections in the USSR Congress of People’s Deputies of 1989 and the following year’s republic and local elections changed the incentives for popular mobilization by lowering the risks of persecution and opening channels for citizens to participate and influence the policy-making process. It was an unprecedented event in Soviet history that deputies were chosen by popular mandate. Political actors thus responded to institutional opportunities for high politics via civil society organizations. DemRossiya and the miners’ movement represented the major social forces of demanding from below. In the hope of political liberation, a combination of anti-Communist ideology and an inclusive form of organisation inclining to zero-sum conflict-oriented resolution (we against them) proved useful for solidarity and collective action, but such a strategy was incapable of articulating and adjusting conflicting social claims of quotidian politics when the common enemy had been destroyed. Post-Soviet Russian civil society had to adjust to the new political reality of state construction. Political elites’ strategic choices and peculiar institutional arrangements triggered the constitutional crisis. The conflict between the executive and the legislature dominated state-society relations. Social forces were mobilized in support of or in opposition to Yeltsin’s economic reforms. The Social Partnership program failed to resolve workers’ problems. The social movement DemRossiya adapted its the government’s economic program. Brudny, Ibid., 167-68. From the perspective of Yeltsin’s populist strategy, as Hahn wrote, “The longer-term effect of the referendum, however, was to strengthen Yeltsin’s conviction that he enjoyed a popular mandate and that the Russian people would back him in a confrontation with parliament.” Hahn, “Introduction: Analyzing Parliamentary Development in Russia,” 20. 114 Brudny, “The Dynamics of ‘Democratic Russia’,” 141-70. 俄羅斯轉型的社會力量探源 101 anti-regime role to support Yeltsin’s government at the expense of its own political autonomy. After the dissolution of the parliament and the adoption of a presidential constitution, a superpresidency established by Yeltsin became the paramount power. A wider gap between the state and society was doomed to be inevitable.