Dynamic Macroeconomics Chapter 9: Imperfectly flexible prices University of Siegen University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 1 / 12 Overview 1 Introduction and motivation 2 Price-setting under imperfect competition University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 2 / 12 Introduction and motivation Introduction and motivation • Effects of a monetary impulse in an economy with flexible prices: −4 2 Responses to a money growth shock x 10 output employment 0 −2 −4 −6 −8 0 5 10 15 20 25 2 real int. rate nominal interest rate inflation 1.5 1 0.5 0 −0.5 0 5 10 15 20 25 =⇒ Monetary decisions have almost no real effects. University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 3 / 12 Introduction and motivation Introduction and motivation • Evidence suggests that nominal prices are sticky in the short run: • Bils and Klenow (2004): Prices in the United States are changed on average every six months. • Alvarez et al. (2006): Prices in the euro area are changed on average every ten to twelve months. =⇒ Monetary policy has influence on real variables in the short run. =⇒ Ben Bernanke (Interview, June 2004): The second issue is that these models [RBC models] abstract from sticky wages and prices and hence from the possibility of short-run deviations of output from full employment. They don’t have any substantial role for stabilization policies. I believe that we live in a world where stabilization policy - stabilization of inflation as well as output - is sometimes needed. University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 4 / 12 Introduction and motivation Introduction and motivation • Effect of a monetary shock (Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans, 1997) Fed Funds Model with M1 NBR Model with M1 MP Shock => Y NBR/TR Model with M1 MP Shock => Y 0.2 0.1 MP Shock => Y 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 -0.0 -0.0 -0.0 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.3 -0.5 -0.6 -0.4 -0.4 0 3 6 9 12 15 -0.5 0 MP Shock => Price 3 6 9 12 15 0 MP Shock => Price 3 6 9 12 15 MP Shock => Price =⇒ Monetary shocks have relatively sizeable and persistent real effects. 0.2 0.14 0.1 0.18 0.09 0.07 -0.0 0.00 -0.1 -0.07 -0.2 -0.14 -0.3 -0.21 -0.4 -0.28 -0.5 -0.35 -0.6 -0.42 0 3 6 9 12 15 -0.00 -0.09 -0.18 -0.27 -0.36 -0.45 -0.54 -0.63 0 MP Shock => Pcom 3 6 9 12 15 0.15 6 9 12 15 12 15 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.05 -0.00 -0.00 -0.05 -0.05 -0.05 -0.10 -0.10 -0.10 -0.15 -0.15 -0.20 -0.25 -0.15 -0.20 0 3 6 9 12 15 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 -0.0 University of Siegen -0.20 0 MP Shock => FF -0.4 3 MP Shock => Pcom 0.10 0.10 -0.00 -0.2 0 MP Shock => Pcom 3 6 9 12 15 0 MP Shock => FF 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.8 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.4 -0.0 -0.1 -0.2 Dynamic Macroeconomics 3 6 9 MP Shock => FF 0.6 0.2 0.0 -0.2 5 / 12 Introduction and motivation Introduction and motivation • To model price-setting in macro models several approaches have been developed. • Leading examples are: • Calvo pricing (Calvo, 1983) • Staggered wage setting (Taylor, 1979) • Quadratic adjustment costs (Rotemberg, 1982) • Menu-cost models (Akerlof and Yellen, 1985) =⇒ Most popular: Calvo pricing (and - increasingly - menu-cost models). University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 6 / 12 Price-setting under imperfect competition Price-setting under imperfect competition • We consider the supply side of the economy. • There is one representative firm. • This firm has monopolistic power. • The firm produces good Q using input factors X1 , X2 , ..., Xn . • To produce the good the firm has access to a production function: Q = F (X1 , X2 , . . . , Xn ) , F 0 > 0, F 00 < 0 (1) • The cost of production, C , are given by: n C= ∑ Wi Xi (2) i =1 where Wi denotes the price of input factor Xi . University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 7 / 12 Price-setting under imperfect competition Price-setting under imperfect competition • The price of input factor Xi increases with Xi , i.e. we have: Wi = W (Xi ), W 0 (Xi ) > 0 (3) • The firm faces a downward-sloping demand for its product: P = P (Q ) , P 0 (Q ) < 0 (4) • The firm’s maximization problem is given by: max Q,X1 ,X2 ,...,Xn s.t. PQ − C P = P (Q ) (5) (6) n C= ∑ Wi Xi (7) i =1 Q = F (X1 , X2 , . . . , Xn ) University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics (8) 8 / 12 Price-setting under imperfect competition Price-setting under imperfect competition • The associated Lagrange function is given by: n L = P (Q )Q − ∑ W (Xi )Xi + λ [F (X1 , X2 , . . . , Xn ) − Q ] (9) i =1 • The first-order conditions are: ∂L = P + P 0 (Q )Q − λ = 0 ∂Q ∂L = −Wi − W 0 (Xi )Xi + λFi0 = 0 ∂Xi • Combining the two first-order conditions yields: λ = P + P 0 (Q )Q = MR = Wi + W 0 (Xi )Xi MCi = = MC 0 MPi Fi (10) (11) (12) with MC total marginal cost, MR marginal revenue University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 9 / 12 Price-setting under imperfect competition Price-setting under imperfect competition • MPi is the marginal productivity and MCi is the marginal cost of the i-th factor. • So formally we have ∂C ∂C ∂Xi = ∂Q ∂Xi ∂Q (13) ∂C = W (Xi ) + W 0 (Xi )Xi ∂Xi (14) ∂Q = Fi0 ∂Xi (15) MC = MCi = MPi = University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 10 / 12 Price-setting under imperfect competition Price-setting under imperfect competition • For the price P we obtain: ∂P Q P = MC ⇐⇒ P + P 0 (Q )Q = MC ⇐⇒ P + ∂Q P ∂P Q 1 MC P 1+ = MC ⇐⇒ P = ∂Q P 1− 1 (16) εD • with εD = − ∂Q P ∂P Q (17) =⇒ Interpretation? University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 11 / 12 Price-setting under imperfect competition Price-setting under imperfect competition • Substituting ε Xi = ∂Xi W ∂W Xi (18) • we get 1 + ε1X Wi i P= 1 1 − ε D Fi0 (19) • So the price P depends upon the unit cost of the factors of production Wi , their marginal productivities MPi , the elasticity of their supply ε Xi and the elasticity of the demand for the good ε D . University of Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 12 / 12