Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? For anyone playing the wildly popular online role-playing game Diablo 3 back in May, the effects of an expansion of the monetary base on the price level were evident. For the uninitiated, some background detail would be helpful. Each player controls one character in a world also populated by the characters of other players. The game proves interesting study for economists due to the way in which scarce in-game items are allocated; through an auction house, where players bid for items being sold by other players. By doing this the auction house essentially creates a market for each item in the game, with price being determined by the interaction of supply and demand. In May, a bug in the game allowed players to quickly add massive amounts of gold, the in-game currency, to their account in a very short period of time. The result: prices for most goods in the auction house shot up. For example the radiant star ruby, which had been hovering just above 20 million gold for the previous 6 months, shot up to 85 million in one day. However the most interesting price change to note was in the price of gold itself. Players can buy in-game gold using real money; this is one of the ways the producers profit from the game. The price of 10 million gold had been dead stable at $2.50 for the previous 3 months, before falling to 39 cents in one day, reflecting the reduced purchasing power of gold in-game. While the events of Diablo 3 are perhaps the most recent, history abounds with such examples. Liberal printing of money led to hyperinflation in Zimbabwe in 2008 and in the 1920s Weimar Republic. Even further back than that, when the value of coins was linked to the precious metal contained within them, prices in Europe quadrupled during the 16th Century when gold and silver began flowing into Europe from the newlydiscovered Americas, driving down the value of the precious metals contained in each coin. When looking to explain these effects of a changing monetary base, we could first look at the work of Irving Fisher, an American economist prominent in the early 20th Century. He noticed that the amount of money in the economy, multiplied by the number of times money changes hands in a given time period (the velocity of money), must be equal to total expenditure in the economy over that time period. Similarly, the total expenditure in the economy in a given time period must be equal to the general price level multiplied by the goods sold during that time. Combining these two statements gives the identity: MV=PQ (Fisher’s equation of exchange) This identity underpins the quantity theory of money. When it is assumed that the velocity of money and the quantity of goods produced is constant, it becomes clear that there is a constant ratio between the monetary base and the price level; a change in the monetary base will lead to a proportional change in the price level. This theory directly implies another, the neutrality of money. First proposed by Friedrich Hayek in 1931; the idea behind the theory is that money can only influence nominal variables in the economy, such as price, with no effect on real variables, such as inflation-adjusted GDP, as 1 Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? any increase in the monetary base will be completely offset by the proportional rise in prices. So with this knowledge of the link between the monetary base and the price level, we should be able to answer the question as to whether quantitative easing (QE) must always end in inflation. QE was first implemented by the Bank of Japan in 2001 as an attempt to use monetary policy to stimulate a stagnant economy while interest rates were down against the zero lower bound, a situation nowadays referred to as a liquidity trap. QE entails the government electronically creating funds and using these funds to buy various securities from banks. When people deposit savings into a bank, the banks loans out some of the money in order to make a profit, but it has to keep some of the deposit within the bank, so it isn’t overextended and can pay out money to people who want to withdraw their savings. This is known as fractional reserve banking. The requirement for reserves has increased as a result of the international Basel III agreement. If banks are liquidity constrained, they will be unable to lend money, which is where QE comes in. Buying assets from banks floods them with liquidity, which will hopefully enable and encourage private lending, by giving banks reserves well above the levels they need, leaving them with little risk of a liquidity shortage. In the case of Japan, the assets the central bank bought up were mainly long term government bonds. More recently the US Federal Reserve has conducted QE via buying up mortgage backed securities and carrying out liquidity swaps with other central banks. Since then, the Fed has also begun to buy up government securities. The reason we may expect QE to lead to inflation is that in electronically creating funds to buy securities the government expands the monetary base. So by the quantity theory of money we would expect an increase in the price level proportionate to the increase in the monetary base. Looking at recent economic data from Japan and the USA … Index (Jan 2008 =100) The Monetary Base and the CPI in the USA since 2008 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2008 CPI Monetary Base 2010 2012 2014 Year 2 Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? The Monetary Base and the CPI in Japan since 2001 Index (Jan 2001 = 100) 250 200 150 CPI 100 Monetary Base 50 0 2001 2006 2011 2016 Year … we don’t see that relationship at all. We would expect proportionality to be clearly visible when using indices as the lines would more or less follow the same path, yet here this is evidently not the case. In the example of Japan, we actually have deflation accompanying a quantitative easing program that is massively increasing the monetary base. There are other factors at work here though, which have influenced the price level. In Japan, an ageing and contracting population is reducing demand for goods. At the same time, fear of bank insolvency has encouraged many Japanese to buy treasury bonds as opposed to saving their money in a bank account, meaning there has been no money available for lending, again reducing demand for goods. Deflation itself is selfexacerbating, as the Yen strengthens reducing the cost of imports and people hold out on buying goods in case of further price drops. Nonetheless we would expect such a huge change in the monetary base to override these factors, meaning that we can still conclude that there is no significant relationship between the monetary base and the price level in these situations. So, do these results invalidate Fisher’s equation of exchange? Not quite! This equation is an identity – it holds in all situations. We should look instead at the assumptions that the velocity of money and the quantity of goods remain constant. The cases of Japan and the USA suggest that at least one of these is incorrect. First we’ll examine the assumption that the velocity of money stays constant. This assumption was challenged by John Maynard Keynes, a British economist who lived through the years of the Great Depression and is arguably the father of modern economic thought. He argued that money is used not just as a medium of exchange while buying and selling goods, but also as a store of value, in that it can be saved today to be spent later. 3 Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? Keynes argued that money’s use as a store of value is determined by the interest rate. Using money as a store of value has an opportunity cost, which is the assets that could be bought with that amount of money. You might hold assets instead of cash, as assets have the advantage of earning interest over time. This idea is referred to as liquidity preference theory. The advantage of holding money is that it can be used at will, whereas with assets, converting into hard cash can be more difficult. When interest rates are high, assets yield higher returns, so people are inclined to hold assets. In our current situation, where interest rates are near-zero as a result of measures taken to stimulate the stagnating economy, there is next to no opportunity cost to holding money; individuals and corporations will forgo what little profit they may receive on assets in order to have cash on hand. The effect is compounded, as individuals are particularly wary of bonds in zero interest rate situations, as interest rates cannot fall any further. Once the economy has recovered and interest rates rise again, the price of bonds will fall. The significance of liquidity preference theory for QE is that when money is being held as a store of value at the margin, the money banks receive from QE is primarily padding out their cash reserves, without it ever really entering the economy. Think back to the Fisher equation of exchange and separate the new money created by QE and the money that already existed. MV + M1V1 = PQ If the new money created simply sits in a bank’s reserves, its velocity will be zero, and hence there will be no change in the value PQ. Now we’ll look at the assumption that the quantity of goods produced by the economy remains constant following a change in the monetary base. Consider when Milton Friedman remarked that the USA could fight price deflation by printing money and dropping it from a helicopter. Although it was mentioned by Ben Bernanke, now the Chairman of the Federal Reserve, back in 2002, it seems like an absurd policy. However, you could consider a £1,000 fixed tax break financed by the central bank purchasing government bonds equivalent to a helicopter drop. Clearly this is simply expansionary fiscal policy financed by QE, which sounds like a more plausible policy option, although lacking the drama of money falling from the skies. Aggregate demand would inevitably increase, as families now have more disposable income they can spend on goods. When thinking about the effects of QE on aggregate demand, we should also think about the impact QE has on long term interest rates. When the central bank decides to buy bonds and other securities, the price of the bonds increases due to the increase in demand. The yield on these securities, which is usually a fixed nominal value for the term of the bond, decreases as a percentage of its value, and this decrease in percentage yield should trickle through the economy to rates on loans, credit cards and mortgages. With interest rates lowered, aggregate demand will increase as it is cheaper to borrow money. Investment in particular should pick up as most investment is financed through 4 Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? borrowing. Usually this would lead to an increase in the price level; in fact this would be a typical case of demand-pull inflation. However this may not occur under some circumstances. The recession has caused a lack of demand in the economy – that much is clear. When UK house prices fell in 2007, people and corporations began slashing their spending in an attempt to reduce debt. This fall in aggregate demand creates an output gap, where a country produces fewer goods than its capabilities allow it to. In 2009, the UK was estimated to have had an output gap of roughly 4% of GDP, which shows just how significant the effects of the recession have been. Clearly the output gap means that there is unemployed capital in the economy. Keynes told us that prices are sticky. Hence with a large amount of unemployed capital, when demand increases firms are willing to increase output without increasing prices. This leads to the conclusion that the aggregate supply curve is fully elastic when there are large amounts of unemployed resources. The importance of the above is that an increase in aggregate demand, caused by both reduced long term interest rates and the potential for some new money to leak into the economy, would not have to be inflationary if it put unemployed resources to use. And yet, the above cases only concern the short run. Friedman, Keynes and Hayek, arguably the three titans of 20th century economics, all told us that in the long run money is neutral, so surely inflation must occur eventually? When the economy recovers, banks will start to lend their reserves and the velocity of money will increase back towards ‘normal’ levels. Aggregate demand will recover to the point where it intersects on the upwards sloping section of the aggregate supply curve, and the price level will be higher than it would otherwise have been without the increase in the monetary base. This is the case, which is why the central bank will start contracting the monetary base once the economy starts to recover, thus never allowing inflation to be realised. There are numerous ways a central bank can do this, known as ‘exit strategies’. 5 Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? Essentially, if the central bank has bought up lots of assets, it can start selling them, destroying the money it receives from sales. The central bank can also raise interest rates, which will encourage people to switch away from holding money, reducing inflationary pressure. Sadly however, the solution is unlikely to be as simple as dumping assets and hiking interest rates. If this happens too abruptly, before the economy is ready, then the green-shoots of recovery could be trodden underfoot, as was the case following the rise in interest rates in Japan in 2006. Furthermore, instantly calling a halt to QE could lead to a spike in bond yields, which would be potentially problematic. In order to give itself more flexibility with regard to the timing of monetary tightening, the central bank could pay interest on cash reserves stored there, as the Federal Reserve has just been given permission to do. This would delay bank reserves flooding into the economy, as banks would not lend them out at rates less than the rate earned for storing reserves risk-free at the central bank. Another tool the central bank could use is reverse repurchase agreements, where the central bank sells assets and promises to buy them back later for a higher price. In fact, these stall strategies could allow the central bank to let its assets mature, as opposed to selling them and risking hefty losses. In summary, a look at the effects of QE and the possible exit strategies seems to provide the answer to the question posed. Quantitative easing, in the short run, need not be inflationary – and even in the long run it doesn’t have to end in inflation, as it is a temporary and fully reversible measure. Getting the exit right, however, may be more complex than patching a video game. 2433 words excluding bibliography 6 Must ‘quantitative easing’ end in inflation? Bibliography Diablo 3 Price Tracker - http://www.diablohub.com/auction-house/ US Department of Labour Statistics – CPI - ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.txt Federal Reserve - Aggregate Reserves of Depository Institutions and the Monetary Base http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/default.htm Official Statistics of Japan – 2010 base Consumer Price Index http://www.e-stat.go.jp/SG1/estat/ListE.do?bid=000001033702&cycode=0 Bank of Japan Statistics – Monetary Base – www.boj.or.jp/en/statistics/boj/other/mb/mblong.zip DK – The Economics Book – Pages 30-33 – Money Causes Inflation Alan S. Blinder – Quantitative Easing: Entrance and Exit Strategies http://www.princeton.edu/ceps/workingpapers/204blinder.pdf Simon Wren-Lewis - Mainly Macro – Money and Inflation – 21st December 2011 http://mainlymacro.blogspot.co.uk/2011/12/money-and-inflation.html Simon Wren-Lewis – Mainly Macro – What do people mean by helicopter money? – 12th October 2012 http://mainlymacro.blogspot.co.uk/2012/10/what-do-people-mean-by-helicoptermoney.html Paul Krugman – Conscience of a Liberal – Monetary Policy in a Liquidity Trap – April 11th 2013 http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/11/monetary-policy-in-a-liquidity-trap/?_r=0 The Economist – The President Speaks – June 4th 2009 http://www.economist.com/node/13768746 Ben Bernanke – The Fed’s Exit Strategy – The Wall Street Journal – July 21st 2009 http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203946904574300050657897992.html Nouriel Roubini and David Backus – Lectures in Macroeconomics – The IS/LM Model http://people.stern.nyu.edu/nroubini/NOTES/CHAP9.HTM#topic6 Stephanie Flanders – Should Bank start the helicopter? – BBC – 12th October 2012 http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-19925013 Kenji Nishizaki, Toshitaka Sekine, Yoichi Ueno – Chronic Deflation in Japan http://www.boj.or.jp/en/research/wps_rev/wps_2012/data/wp12e06.pdf Tom Pybus – Office for Budget Responsibility – Estimating the UK’s historical output gap http://cdn.budgetresponsibility.independent.gov.uk/WorkingPaperNo1-Estimating-the-UKshistorical-output-gap.pdf 7