Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 1 Chapter 4: The objective of international harmonisation: value relevance or accountability? Introduction Many scholars take it for granted that the objective of international harmonisation is to improve the informational efficiency of foreign stock markets. As Hopwood said, in most international accounting research, The user perspective is taken to be one of such obviousness that it requires no appeal to conventionally accepted evidence (1994, p.249). By user-perspective Hopwood means the decision-relevance or informational perspective which, as we saw in chapter three, says that the aim of accounting is to help investors value companies. In this chapter we appeal to conventionally accepted evidence to ask, why do the capital markets want harmonised accounting? It is not sufficient to simply assume that this is the aim of international accounting, any more than we can just assume that domestic investors want valuerelevant accounting information. As Holthausen and Watts say, standard-setting inferences based on a theory that assumes standard setters consider a high association with stock values a desirable attribute for accounting earnings are not likely to be useful if the evidence suggests standard setters do not consider stock valuation association an important attribute. Simple assertions by authors that standard setters should consider that attribute desirable are not sufficient for scientific research (2001, p.4). While there are important differences in international financial reporting, their significance for users in share valuation is debatable. Many observers believe accounting differences create a Tower of Babel . However, there is extensive evidence that the capital markets of developed economies are informationally efficient (e.g., Choi and Levich, 1990, pp.23-25; Alford, 1993, pp.184, 196). In other words, accounting differences have not caused domestic investors any insurmountable problems in valuing shares sufficiently accurately to prevent abnormal transfers of wealth from trading on past prices (weak-form efficiency), publicly available accounting information (semi-strong), or even inside information (strong-form). NonAnglo Saxon capital markets have lower liquidity and public disclosure standards, but we must remember that poor public disclosure does not necessarily impede the flow of information into stock prices, since the information flow can occur instead via the trading of informed insiders (Ball, Kothari and Robin, 2000, p.48). US investors behave as though they believe foreign stock markets are efficient. As Lochner, a SEC commissioner, pointed out, the failure of most non-US companies to use US GAAP has not deterred U.S. investors from purchasing foreign securities (1991, p.108). The problem for those who allege that IAS are a pre-requisite to a well-developed global securities market is that a well-developed capital market exists already. It has evolved without uniform accounting standards (Goeltz, 1991, p.86). To explain the objective of international harmonisation we must distinguish between informational efficiency and allocational efficiency, that is, between the fair price for a financial security and its maximum value. A securities market is efficient if Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 2 information is widely and cheaply available to investors and all relevant and ascertainable information is already reflected in security prices (Brealey and Myers, 1984, p.266). The chapter argues that the problem for international investors is not whether the market price for foreign securities is fair, but whether the expected returns are as high as possible. As Choi and Levich point out, the international capital market efficiency of interest to policy makers includes not just confidence in the accuracy of relative share values, but the confidence to form fully diversified global portfolios: Not withstanding this rosy appraisal of international capital markets, two questions are of concern to policy makers. First, would a common, harmonized accounting system provide more useful information to market participants than the diverse systems now in place? Second, even though financial markets may appear efficient, do diverse accounting systems act as a nontariff barrier, affecting the capital market decisions of investors and issuers? (Choi and Levich, 1990, p.34). The fundamental question is whether, based on their analyses, foreign investors are confident enough to participate in international markets to the extent required to hold well-diversified portfolios (Choi and Levich, 1990, p.22). Even though there is clear evidence that market prices reflect available information [this] does not address the question of how costly it is for investors to process diverse accounting information (Choi and Levich, 1990, p.22). We saw in chapter 1 that international diversification by US and UK investors is below its apparently optimal level. This is consistent with the hypothesis that without IAS international investors do not expect the returns from additional investment in foreign securities to cover the increased information processing costs they would incur to hold foreign management accountable for the rate of return on capital. If the international capital markets are informationally efficient, accounting is useful to investors only as a means of holding management accountable. Only if investors have confidence that the accounts objectively measure management s performance are there no accounting barriers to investors allocating their capital to those firms delivering the highest rates of returns on capital. In this sense, we can agree with Saudagaran and Meek that The primary economic rationale in favor of harmonization is that major differences in accounting practices act as a barrier to capital flowing to the most efficient uses. Investors are more likely to direct their capital to the most efficient and productive companies globally if they are able to understand their accounting numbers (and so, presumably, their economic reality) (1997, p.137). The most efficient and productive companies are those with the highest rates of return on capital. This, we shall argue, is the economic reality of concern to international investors. By contrast, the information efficiency objective assumes harmonising accounting around the Anglo-Saxon model will give investors more value-relevant information, Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 3 that is, information with more predictive ability , to increase capital market efficiency.1 As we saw in chapter 3, the basis of the IASC[ s] conceptual framework is the value relevance of financial reports (Ali and Hwang, 2000, p.3). The dominant view is that the objective is to improve the efficiency with which the markets operate by reducing the diversity that exists among the bases on which financial accounts are prepared in various countries (Bayless, 1996, p.76; see also, Zarzeski, 1996, p.18). As Arthur Wyatt, former director of the IASC, put it, Comparable financial information assists in the quality of the financial analysis and thereby should increase the efficiency of capital markets. . One can build a strong case that financial data, presented on a comparable basis across countries - with the same degree of credibility as local data possesses will increase the efficiency of investment analysis (1991, p.13.9). To prove that informational efficiency is the real aim of harmonisation, its advocates must show us, first, that the primary function of accounting in the Anglo-Saxon capital markets is to help investors value securities.2 In other words, they would have to show us that Anglo-Saxon accounting plays a major role in security valuation by providing investors with information having significant predictive-ability or valuerelevance . Second, they would have to show us that restating foreign accounts using Anglo-Saxon methods improves their value-relevance. We first show that extensive research has established neither proposition. Then we look at the evidence supporting the accountability objective of harmonisation. The value-relevance of accounting During the 1970s and 1980s scholars attempted to verify the decision-usefulness view of accounting by establishing a statistical link between economic returns and accounting earnings, usually called the information content or value-relevance of accounting. Initially they had little success. Early studies of the information content of earnings usually found only weak links between earnings and returns, with R2 statistics typically ranging from 2 per cent to 10 per cent (Pope and Rees, 1992, p.337). Stimulated by Ohlson s work the inclusion of the book value of equity in the regression equations increased these embarrassingly low R2 statistics (Strong and Walker, 1993, p.385). Nevertheless, we will see this research has not established value-relevance as the primary function of accounting, and we conclude, therefore, that it provides no support for the market efficiency objective of harmonisation. Value relevance research starts from the tautology that the market value of a firm s equity is the sum of the book value3 of its net assets plus the present value of its expected residual income . Residual income is the excess earnings over the required return on its net assets. The economic value of expected residual earnings is what accountants call internal goodwill. Value-relevance research exploits this tautology 1 Note that market efficiency does not mean that the market has perfect forecasting ability, only that prices reflect all available information (Brealey and Myers, 1984, p.271). 2 We saw in chapter 3 that the IASC s Framework for the Preparation and Presentation of Financial Statements assumes this is the aim of accounting. 3 From the traditional perspective, book value is replacement cost. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 4 to re-write the dividend valuation model using accounting numbers. The dividend valuation model is: Pt = R- Et[dt+ ] =1 Pt = share price at time t. R = 1 + required return on equity. dt+ = the dividend to be paid at year-end t + . Et[.] = expectations at year-end t. To re-write this equation with accounting numbers, we define earnings as the annual clean surplus . This means earnings equals all changes in the book value of equity (other than capital injections and distributions) including all movements of reserves (e.g., foreign currency translation differences, asset revaluations, goodwill write-offs): xt = yt - yt-1 + dt xt = earnings in the year end t. yt = book value of equity capital at year-end t. yt-1 = book value of equity capital at year-end t-1. dt = the dividend paid at year-end t. We define residual income for year t as earnings for year t less a capital charge based on the opening book value of equity: xta = xt - (R - 1) yt-1 xta = yt + dt - Ryt-1 dt = Ryt-1 + xta - yt All this says is that dividends equals the normal increase in equity (i.e., normal income) plus the abnormal or residual income less the closing equity. Substituting this expression for dividends in the dividend valuation model produces: Pt = yt + Et[xat+ ]R=1 This says the market value of a firm is the sum of the book value of its equity and the present value of expected clean surplus residual income. Thus, if the market knows the book value of equity and can forecast expected earnings and, therefore, the clean surplus residual income, it can deduce the expected dividends and value the firm whatever methods of accounting management uses. Consider the following example:4 A company raises £1m cash in equity at the end of t = 0. The company immediately communicates to the market the expectation that this £1m will all be used to buy inventory during year 1: 4 From Rees (1995, pp.230-231). Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 5 The company will sell half of the inventory in year 1 for £0.6m; The company will sell half of the inventory in year 2 for £0.6m It will earn no other income and pay no taxes. It will distribute all cash balances at the year end. Assuming a cost of capital of 10%, according to the dividend capitalisation model the value of the firm at t0 is: P0 = £0.6m/1.1 + £0.6m/[1.1]2 = £1.0413m. We can derive this valuation from the forecast accounts based on the forecast events regardless of the methods used. Consider the following three accounting bases: 1. Historical cost accounting where the closing stock at the end of year 1 = £0.5m. 2. Valuing closing stock at zero at the end of year 1. 3. Valuing closing stock at £2m at the end of year 1. 1. Stock @ t=1 = £0.5m: Cash Inventory Equity -----------------------------------------------------------------£m £m £m Initial capital +1.0 -1.0 Purchases -1.0 +1.0 Sales +0.6 -0.6 Cost of sales -0.5 +0.5 Profit/Dividends -0.1 +0.1 Dividends/cash -0.5 +0.5 -----------------------------------------------------------------BS end 1 0.0 0.5 0.5 ================================================================== Sales +0.6 -0.6 Cost of sales -0.5 +0.5 Profit/Dividends -0.1 +0.1 Dividends/cash -0.5 +0.5 -----------------------------------------------------------------BS end 2 0.0 0.0 0.0 ================================================================== According to the accounting valuation model: Et[xat+ ]R- P t = yt + =1 £0.1m - [£1m x 0.1] £0.1m - [£0.5m x 0.1] = £1m + ------------------- + --------------------1.1 1.12 = £1.0413. 2. Stock @ t=1 = £0.0m: Cash Inventory Equity ------------------------------------------------------------------£m £m £m Initial capital +1.0 -1.0 Purchases -1.0 +1.0 Sales +0.6 -0.6 Cost of sales -1.0 +1.0 Dividends -0.6 +0.6 ------------------------------------------------------------------BS end 1 0.0 0.0 0.0 =================================================================== Sales +0.6 -0.6 Cost of sales 0.0 +0.0 Profit/Dividends -0.6 +0.6 ------------------------------------------------------------------- Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 6 BS end 2 0.0 0.0 0.0 ==================================================================== -£0.4m - [£1m x 0.1] £1m + ------------------- + 1.1 £0.6m - [£0.0m x 0.1] --------------------1.12 = £1.0413. 3. Stock @ t=1 = £2.0m: Cash Inventory Equity -------------------------------------------------------------------£m £m £m Initial capital +1.0 -1.0 Purchases -1.0 +1.0 Sales +0.6 -0.6 Revaluation +1.0 -1.0 Dividends -0.6 +0.6 -------------------------------------------------------------------BS end 1 0.0 +2.0 -2.0 ==================================================================== Sales +0.6 -0.6 Cost of sales 2.0 +2.0 Profit/Dividends -0.6 +0.6 -------------------------------------------------------------------BS end 2 0.0 0.0 0.0 ==================================================================== £1.6m - [£1m x 0.1] -£1.4m - [£2.0m x 0.1] £1m + ------------------- + ---------------------1.1 1.12 = £1.0413. Many researchers have estimated Ohlson s model in the following forms to assess the value relevance of accounting : Either, Pt = a0 + a1bj,t + a2xj,t + ,jt Or, a statistically more valid formulation (Brown et al. 1999),5 as xj,t xj,t Rj,t = a0 + a1 ------- + a2 ------- + ,jt pj,t-1 pj,t-1 Where: Pt = share price at time t. a0 = the intercept. a1, a2 = regression coefficients. bj,t = the book value of the equity of firm j at time t. xj,t = reported earnings of firm j at time t. xj,t = the change in the reported earnings of firm j from time t-1 to t. ,jt = an error term. 5 Regressions of the levels of prices against levels of the book value of equity and earnings can lead to spuriously high R-squares because companies with large nominal share values tend also to have large values for the book values of equity and earnings per share. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 7 Researchers usually take the regression R2 as a measure of the value relevance of the accounting numbers. On this basis, research in the US and Europe shows that this relation is weak, suggesting that reported earnings do not provide good summary measures of the value-relevant events that have been incorporated in stock prices during the reporting period [as] R-squares are relatively low (Dumontier and Raffournier, 2002, p.131), usually in the range 20% to 30% for US and non-US companies (e.g., Ali and Hwang, 2000, Table 3, p.12). However, even these correlations do not prove that the release of accounting numbers themselves causes any changes in forecast earnings and hence share prices. As accounting numbers reflect real world events, correlations between accounting and share prices could reflect the correlation between share prices and the underlying real world events which accounting reports reflect. But, if (as in our example) the market can forecast the real world events underlying its forecast of the accounts, including the dividend, why would it bother to use the accounts to value the firm as it could do so directly? As Walker concludes, Potentially the most destructive criticism of the Ohlson approach is that it does not explain why firms bother to report earnings and book values in the first place. Ever since Beaver and Demski s (1979) seminal paper, this line of criticism has dogged all approaches to financial accounting based on notions of income measurement. In particular, [that] neo-classical economics has failed to develop a theory of income measurement in which there is an endogenous demand for some form of income measurement (1997, pp.352, 342). Beaver and Demski restated the well-known fact that income measurement only has an unambiguous interpretation as an increment to economic value in a wholly unrealistic certain world with perfect and complete markets. In the real world of uncertainty and imperfect and incomplete markets the case for accrual accounting to improve the predictive abilities of investors is unclear. In the real world, to forecast dividends and value shares investors need information about the real world, in particular management s state-contingent production plans . They must combine their knowledge of management s plans with other information to form beliefs about future states of the world and their implications for the dividends expected from particular firms. It is unclear whether, or if so how, accrual accounting provides this information (Beaver and Demski, 1979, pp.43-45). Although Ohlson claims to integrate the income measurement approach that assumes that investors use accounting information to value companies with the information perspective that says that accounting provides data about the real world that investors use for valuation, in fact, as Walker says, The Ohlson models assume that accounting numbers reflect an underlying reality that is directly observed by the market (1997, p.352). As Dumontier and Raffornier say, association studies do not infer any causal connection between accounting figures and stock prices. They do not even presume that market participants use accounting data in their valuation process. They only posit that if accounting data are good summary measures of the events incorporated in Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 8 security prices, they are value-relevant because their use might provide a value of the firm that is close to its market value (2002, p.128). In short, Ohlson s model tells us nothing about the role of accounting in the real world, only that it is to some extent correlated with share prices. Not surprisingly, the huge value-relevant literature has made virtually no contribution to setting accounting standards. Holthausen and Watts are scathing in their criticism of this literature: Barth et al summarize what the have learned from the research on the value relevance of fair value as the basis of accounting. They conclude that various fair value estimates of pension assets and liabilities and fair values of debt securities, equity securities, bank loans, derivatives, non-financial intangible assets (R&D, capitalized software, advertising, brands, patents and goodwill) and tangible long-lived assets are value relevant. They also conclude that some estimates are not value relevant. These conclusions amount to the finding that the literature has documented that the listed items are correlated with equity values than other items. However, it is difficult to derive standard-setting inferences from these findings without descriptive theories of accounting and standard setting to interpret them (2001, p.65).6 To write helpful standards we must understand accounting and its role. As Walker concludes, what we really want to know is why do we have financial reporting systems that supply measures of income (earnings) and value (book value)? Perhaps one cannot hope to explain the basic features of the financial reporting unless one starts from the proposition that that capitalist owners value measures of return on capital (Walker, 1997, p.352). In traditional accounting, capitalist owners value the accounting rate of return because it provides an objective basis for holding management accountable for the rate of return on capital. As we shall see, research on the usefulness of accounting to the international capital markets is consistent with the accountability hypothesis. First, however, we show that although there is some evidence that Anglo-Saxon accounting has more value-relevance within Anglo-Saxon capital markets than foreign GAAP has in foreign capital markets (Ali and Hwang, 2000), there is little evidence that the value relevance of their accounts to Anglo-Saxon investors would increase if foreign firms used Anglo-Saxon GAAP. This undermines the hypothesis that investors demand international harmonisation to improve the value relevance of non-Anglo Saxon GAAP and thereby increase the informational efficiency of the international capital markets (hereafter, the efficiency hypothesis ). The value-relevance of non-Anglo-Saxon GAAP 6 Barth et al (2001) is a reply to Watts in the same issue of the journal. They admit that Because usefulness is not a well-defined concept in accounting research, value relevance studies typically do not and are not designed to assess the usefulness of accounting amounts , and that Academic researchers are the intended consumers of value relevance research (pp.78-79)! Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 9 If Anglo-Saxon GAAP has predictive-ability we should expect the accounts of foreign firms that report using non-Anglo Saxon GAAP would consistently have significantly less value-relevance than Anglo-Saxon restatements. The SEC s 20-F requirement that to have their shares traded in the US foreign firms must restate their accounts to US GAAP provides a test of the likely value-relevance of internationally harmonised accounts. Several studies have investigated whether US GAAP restatement releases have value-relevance. Saudagaran and Meek summarise the results: (1) non-US GAAP accounting information has value relevance; (2) restatement information seems to have some (though not overwhelming) value relevance, but evidence on the general direction of relevance is mixed; (3) such value relevance as exists seems to vary by country of domicile, or perhaps system of accounting. In other words, the restatement may be more important for some countries than it is for others (1997, p.152). Bhusan and Lessard (1992) surveyed the opinions of US and UK international investment fund managers. They found that while professional investors thought international harmonisation useful , it was not essential as they relied on local accounts and local valuation. Meek (1993) examined 26 firms from five countries. He found no significant relationship between the equivalent 20-F earnings and security prices. He concluded the market had already impounded the information contained in the 20-F reconciliation before the company released them (usually three months after the foreign earning announcement). Amir et al (1993) studied 101 firms from 20 countries. They observed that 20-F earnings and shareholders equity reconciliations were not value relevant even for specific items (e.g., goodwill, asset revaluations, and taxes). Amir et al question the relevance of 20-F reconciliations as they argue a careful investigator could reconstruct US GAAP for themselves. Consistent with this, McQueen s (1993) analysis suggests that levels of both [foreign] reported earnings and foreign earnings reconciled to a US GAAP basis are significantly associated with securities returns (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.15), but the relationships were small and not robust (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, p.266). Alford, et al (1993) compared the information content and timeliness of accounting earnings in 17 countries using the US as the benchmark. They do find differences, but some of them are inconsistent with the market efficiency hypothesis. Their finding that the information content and timeliness of accounts to the capital markets in Denmark, Germany, Italy, Singapore and Sweden, was either less timely or less value relevant than US GAAP earnings is consistent with the efficiency hypothesis. However, they also find that accounts in Australia, France, Netherlands, and the UK are more informative and timely accounts than US companies, which is highly unlikely. Given the size, liquidity, extensive requirements for timely disclosures effectively policed by the SEC this result would puzzle many US observers (at least), and is not explained by the authors . In addition, data questions, such as whether earnings is defined consistently across sample countries, also obscure the results. Cautious interpretations are in order (1997, p.149). Significantly, the results for Belgium, Canada, Hong Kong, Ireland, Norway, South Africa and Switzerland are not conclusive (Alford, et al, 1993, p.213). That is, it was not possible to conclude Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 10 that these countries systems of accounting were or were not more or less value relevant than US GAAP. Harris, Lang and Moller (1994) compared the correlations between accounting earnings and stockholders equity to share prices and returns using Ohlson s approach for German and US companies on their home stock exchanges. These researchers find the explanatory power (R2) of earnings for stock market returns is similar for both German and US companies (around 10%). Harris, Lang and Moller conclude, contrary to the notion that accounting data are essentially meaningless for German corporations that these data are associated with stock price levels and returns. Further, the explanatory power of earnings for returns in Germany is comparable to that in the United States, which suggests that German earnings are not as garbled as is often perceived. However, the explanatory power of shareholder s equity for price is significantly lower in German than in the United States (1994, p.207). The conclusion that German stockholders equity is significantly less correlated with returns than US stockholders equity is consistent with the efficient markets objective. However, they also found that the market valued German earnings at a higher multiple than US earnings, as an efficient capital market should given the conservative nature of German accounting. Saudagaran and Meek conclude: Arguably, the most surprising aspect of these results is that German GAAP earnings are just as value relevant as U.S. GAAP earnings. Differences between the two countries in the importance of capital markets as a source of finance, the fundamental purpose of accounting, and particularly German income smoothing practices would lead one to expect lower explanatory power for German companies (1997, p.149). In other words, this finding is inconsistent with the efficient markets objective. Also inconsistent is the finding of Joos and Lang (1994) who found that while UK accounting is more investor-oriented than France or Germany their R-squares were higher than those for the UK. Also inconsistent with the efficient market objective is the conclusion of Hall, Hamao and Harris (1994) that over the period they studied (1980s) there is little evidence of any relation between market returns and accounting earnings in Japan, even though the Japanese capital markets were informationally efficient over this period. Clearly, as they conclude, investors in Japanese capital markets relied heavily on other , non-accounting, information in valuing Japanese securities. However, first, it is not clear that investors elsewhere rely on accounting information most of which the market anticipates, or they are reacting to the real world data they reflect. Second, investors in all capital markets rely heavily on nonaccounting data (Dumontier and Raffournier, 2002, pp.137-139). Understanding the role of accounting in market valuation in any country depends crucially on that nation s institutional framework, involving the purpose and practice of accounting and the capital market microstructure (Saudagaran and Meek, 1997, p.149). In other words, it is necessary to understand how the market makers obtain the information they use to value shares. As these sources differ across countries, not surprisingly the associations between market returns and accounting, its value relevance, differ systematically across countries according to institutional differences, particularly the differences between the market or shareholder-focused economies Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 11 and the Continental or code-law or bank-dominated economies (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, p.272; Ali and Hwang, 2000). In market systems, with numerous investors with no direct access to value relevant information, investors rely heavily on financial accounting disclosures. In bank-oriented systems, by contrast, banks are insiders with direct access to value relevant information (e.g., Berglof, 1990). Not surprisingly, therefore, Ali and Hwang find, Using financial accounting data from manufacturing firms in 16 countries for 1986-1995, that the value relevance of financial reports is lower for countries where the financial systems are bank oriented rather than market oriented; where accounting practices follow the Continental model as opposed to the British-American model; where tax rules have a greater influence on financial accounting measures; and where spending on auditing services is relatively low (2000, p.20).7 Thus, even the remarkable case of Japan provides no grounds for harmonisation in the name of improving capital market efficiency. Studies have repeatedly found the Japanese capital market is efficient. Bandyopadhyay et al (1994) study 20-F reconciliations from a sample of Canadian firms. They found no evidence that the reconciliations were value relevant in the US. Harris, a leading researcher in value-relevance, admitted in an open forum discussion of allowing foreign access to US capital markets on the basis of IAS, the evidence was inconclusive. [W]e have not been able to isolate a market reaction on an aggregate basis to the release of the 20F disclosures given that other accounting information exists (Bayless, 1996, p.91). For example, Frost and Pownall s study of Smithkline Beecham plc (SK) found that U.S. investors do not appear to be confused by U.S./U.K. GAAP differences, and in fact use information about U.K. GAAP earnings in their valuations of SK (1996, p.38). Chan and Seow (1996) studied 45 firms 20-F adjustments and found better associations between foreign GAAP and market returns than US GAAP. In contrast, Barth and Clinch s (1996) find a negative relationship with market returns, for Canadian reconciliations, and a positive relationship for changes in reconciliations. Their results differ year by year. Gornik-Tomaszewski and Rozen conclude U.S. capital market participants are able to interpret foreign GAAP earnings and promptly infer from them U.S. GAAP earnings (1999, p.550). This, as they say, may be interpreted as empirical evidence of semi-strong efficiency of capital markets in an international context. [M]arket participants have apparently developed a coping mechanism in dealing with accounting diversity. They seem to utilize other sources of information, such as previous years reconciliations and interim reports (Gornik-Tomaszewski and Rozen, 1999, pp.550-551). 7 Ali and Hwang find that these factors are all closely related, with only one underlying construct, but they were unable to label the construct (2000, p.2). In chapter five we label the underlying construct capital market orientation , the extent to which the capital markets dominate industrial and commercial enterprise. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 12 Davis-Friday and Rivera (2000) assess the relationship between market prices and Mexican and US GAAP earnings and equity. They find no significant relationship between the [Mexican] ADR price and net income and equity reconciliations from Mexican to US GAAP. [Their] results call into question once again the validity and usefulness of the SEC s required reconciliations to US GAAP (Davis-Friday and Rivera, 2000, p.113). Their results also call into question the efficient market objective. Conclusions There is no case for harmonisation around the Anglo-Saxon model if the purpose is to improve the informational efficiency of the capital markets. As Choi and Levich conclude, the conventional wisdom behind the quest for a harmonized set of international accounting standards appears to be twofold (1997, p.6.23). First, that mandatory accounting standards are necessary, and second, that harmonisation is a necessary part of developing large, well-functioning international financial markets (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.23). There is, as they say, empirical evidence that contradicts both , and at best the capital markets case for harmonization remains an empirical issue (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.23). The best we can say after extensive empirical research is that The results are mixed, with coefficient estimates and Rsquares varying across empirical specifications, years and sample firms domiciles (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, p.266). Certainly, as Pownall and Schipper conclude, the Form 20-F reconciliation literature provides some evidence that for non-U.S. firms that list in the U.S., both U.S. and non-U.S. GAAP accounting measures are value-relevant for U.S. (and other) investors (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, p.268). Therefore, if the objective is value relevance, full harmonisation is not necessarily a good idea. As Pownall and Schipper put it, the academic research literature poses the following question for securities commissioners and standard setters worldwide: What is the best way to trade off the comparability benefits and benefits from economies of oversight and enforcement, obtainable from using a single set of financial statements worldwide, against the potential noncomparability costs of inappropriately imposing worldwide standards on events and transactions that are inherently noncomparable because of cross-jurisdictional institutional differences? Faced with this cost-benefit trade-off, some regulators and standard setters may find it preferable to maintain (at least some) countryspecific reporting differences that capture qualitative, institution-driven differences in similar-seeming events and transactions, coupled with reconciliations for firms wishing to report in several jurisdictions (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, pp.278-279). In other words, recent levels of diversity in international accounting are consistent with an efficient international capital market. How is this possible? From the traditional perspective the purpose of accounting is to hold management accountable for the capital they control, not to provide investors with data for economic valuation. Accounts merely provide investors with a steady state model of the realised surplus for the period and the capital recoverable. While accounts do contain data that may be more or less useful in valuing shares, for valuation investors must interpret this data in the light of their beliefs and the vast amount of additional and alternative Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 13 information available. From this point of view, the existence of capital market efficiency implies that most differences in international accounts are insignificant for the purpose of share valuation. That is, international differences in accounting are either irrelevant, or sophisticated investors can see through them or compensate by using alternative information to produce share values. It certain appears to be true that, In shareholder-focused economies (common-law countries), earnings [or information correlated with earnings] are used by shareholders to determine share value and compensate managers, while in stakeholder-focused economies (code-based countries), earnings are used more for determining current payouts to government (via taxation), to shareholders (via dividends), and to managers and employees (via wages and bonuses) (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, p.273). However, it does not follow that code-country stock markets would be more efficient if its companies used IAS or US GAAP and investors relied more on these accounts and less on their current sources of value-relevant information. The fact that investors in shareholder-focused economies make more use of accounts or information correlated with accounting information to value shares than investors in code-based economies does not mean share valuation is the purpose of harmonisation. If we cannot justify the international harmonisation of accounting in the name of value-relevance, why are the world s leading stock markets and the IASB determined it will happen? In what follows we argue the evidence supports the accountability objective. Accountability to the international capital markets? From the accountability perspective the purpose of accounts, whether national or international, is to motivate management to take decisions in the interests of the providers of equity.8 As Lowenstein puts it, The financial disclosure system, while intended to permit investors and creditors to make rational decisions, and so to make markets fair and efficient, in fact it has the quite independent effect of forcing managers to confront disagreeable realities in detail and early on, even when those disclosures may have no immediate market consequences. [G]ood disclosure has been a most efficient and effective mechanism for inducing managers to manage better. Alas, it is an insight that is lost on most financial economists, who instead rely on stock prices as the measure of corporate performance (1996, pp.1335-1336; 1342-1343). This independent effect , management s accountability for the capital it controls and the profits or losses it makes, appears to explain the superior statistical performance of Ohlson s book value model over the earnings models. In traditional accounting net assets represents the capital estimated to be recoverable. Implicit, therefore, in the inclusion of an asset on the balance sheet, is the verified estimate that management 8 We assume the providers of credit either share the same interests as equity or are able to look after their interests where they differ. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 14 will recover the capital and expects to earn at least the required return from its ordinary operations. This is consistent with Walker s view that The key to understanding why accounting book values might yield superior explanatory performance turns on the fact that reported book values reflect the rational investment choices of firms, and assessments by the firm (and its accountants) of capital expenditures that can be booked as assets. A fundamental feature of accruals accounting is that it classifies expenditures into revenues and capital. To the extent that the currently booked capital expenditures have positive net present a truncated equation based on earnings and book values will tend to produce a better statistical fit than the truncated dividend series. In other words, accounting numbers provide a better association with market values because, somehow, managers have been motivated to adopt investments with value (1997, p.346). Ohlson s value-relevance approach assumes management makes maximum NPV investments. Traditional accounting explains why management maximizes NPV. It assumes accountability for the rate of return on capital is the purpose of financial reporting - that is, accountability for the maximum sustainable residual income. If management maximizes NPV it will maximize sustainable residual income, and vice versa. Thus, the accountability perspective explains the statistical results of Ohlson s value relevance approach. It explains why we find reasonably high correlations between accounting numbers and share prices. The traditional accountability perspective is also consistent with the findings of other research on international capital markets and financial reporting. In particular, with research seeking to explain (a) voluntary disclosure to the international capital markets, (b) listing behaviour, (c) management s behavioural responses to international diversity in accounting, (d) differences in apparent income smoothing in different accounting jurisdictions, and (e) emerging evidence of a governance premium . (a) Voluntary disclosure: The importance of accountability to the international capital markets could explain why those European and Japanese companies who came to these markets to raise capital in the 1960s and 1970s voluntarily disclosed substantial additional information. For example, in 1969 Most found that when comparing financial statements of listed U.S. and European chemical companies, a skilled analyst could compare their accounts. In 1973 Choi showed that companies that sought to borrow on the eurobond market adapted their financial reports to best international practice. Choi rationalised this finding by claiming that Increased firm disclosure tends to improve the subjective probability distributions of a security s expected return streams in the mind of an individual investor by reducing the uncertainty , that increased disclosure had value-relevance. However, it is also consistent with the demand from the international capital markets for increased accountability. In 1976 Barrett examined both the extent of financial statement disclosures, and the comprehensiveness of the net income figure, for 103 companies in the US, Japan, UK, France, Germany, Sweden and Holland, in 1963 and 1972. The companies chosen Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 15 had the largest market capitalisations in their domestic stock markets in 1972. Barratt studied their English-Language accounts to view the financial reporting practices of the sample companies through the eyes of an internationally-oriented investor (Barrett, 1976, p.11). The results were as follows: Disclosure: Barrett constructed a weighted scoring index for the disclosure of 17 items of information (covering financial history, segments, capital expenditure, depreciation, funds flow, stocks, price-level, marketable securities, currency translation, tax, margins): US UK Japan Sweden Holland Germany France All Companies Average Disclosure Indices 1963 1972 53 72 48 73 41 56 29 58 43 57 40 52 24 44 41 59 Source: Barrett (1976), p.15. Barrett s work showed that US companies were better on operating details and UK companies were better on segmental data and capital expenditure plans.9 Comprehensiveness: Barrett measured this as (a) the extent of consolidation and (b) the comprehensiveness of income statement for 1963 and 1972: % Companies Consolidating All Significant Subsidiaries 1963 1972 US 67 87 UK 100 100 Japan 42 64 Sweden 71 93 Holland 88 100 Germany 20 86 France 0 50 All Companies 54 83 Source: Barrett (1976), p.17. In 1972 only US companies made significant use of equity accounting, although the average percentage of companies reporting equity in associates had increased from 9% in 1963 to 34% in 1972 (Barrett, 1976, p.18). Inclusiveness of Net Income: In 1963 53% of companies passed all noncapital items (e.g., accrued liabilities, extraordinary items) through the income statement. In 1972 61% did. Only the US had 100% in both years, and the UK provided sufficient supplementary data to achieve similar results. When supplementary disclosures were included, 62% of companies provided a comprehensive net income figure in 1963, and 66% in 1972. 9 Note that the authors did not consider alternative sources of information (e.g. the detailed individual French company accounts produced according to the Plan Comptable) in scoring the disclosures. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 16 Barrett concluded: While the overall level of financial disclosure steadily improved throughout the 1963 to 1973 period, there was still a wide variance between the overall level of disclosure of American and British firms on the one hand, and the firms from the other five countries. In addition,...the American and British firm s financial statements were considerably more comprehensive.... These results were certainly consistent with the general belief that there is a link between the quality of financial reporting practice and the degree of efficiency of national equity markets (1976, p.24). These results are also consistent with the hypothesis that while all these national equity markets were efficient , whereas the American and British firms were fully accountable to their capital markets, the firms of the other countries were not. Meek and Gray (1989) studied 28 Continental European firms listed on the London Stock Exchange, who exceeded its disclosure requirements through a wide range of voluntary disclosures. Choi and Levich say, These results suggest that firms have found it in their interest to provide additional accounting disclosures in the hope of improving their share prices, reducing the cost of their funds, and competing with other firms for capital in the international market (1997, p.6.14). However, it does not automatically follow that these benefits to firms accrue from the improved valuerelevance of their accounts. While not probed by these researchers, this evidence is also consistent with the hypothesis that the benefits from additional disclosure arise from the increased accountability they signal to the market. As Saudagaran and Meek say, an unresearched question is, for example, whether, and if so how, restatement disclosures affect the way companies are managed. For example, there is anecdotal evidence that Daimler-Benz changed its management practices in response to reporting U.S. GAAP earnings (Saudagaran and Meek, 1997, p.153). (b) Listing behaviour: The research of Biddle and Saudagaran (1991), Saudagaran and Biddle (1992, 1995) on the listing choices of 450 firms from eight countries provides further evidence consistent with the accountability objective. Their evidence is consistent with the explanation that over the 1980s and early 1990s the required levels of disclosure of foreign stock exchanges compared to their domestic disclosures strongly influenced firms who choose to obtain a listing on a foreign stock exchange. These studies found that, after taking other factors into account, companies were indifferent across exchanges with levels of disclosure that were less than domestic levels.10 However, companies were progressively less likely to list on exchanges with higher disclosure levels.11 Scholars usually rationalise this behaviour as an aversion by some firms to the large expenses required in foreign listings requiring greater disclosures. 10 Firm size, foreign sales, foreign investment, and foreign employees, industry, geographic location, exports, importance of domestic stock market as a proportion of GDP. 11 While Gray and Roberts (1997) study of listing decisions into London in 1994 questions the generality of this finding, their companies were not typical of all foreign companies. Those listing tended to be large, came from countries with relatively important stock markets and had high needs for capital as measured by the level of domestic investment over the country of origin s GNP. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 However, it is also consistent with the hypothesis that the major management is the increased accountability entailed. 17 cost for For example, as Saudagaran and Biddle note, Managements in certain countries such as Germany and Japan strongly oppose quarterly reporting on philosophical grounds, arguing that it adversely affects their ability to take actions that are in the long term interests of their firms (1992, p.373). These countries have therefore largely avoided listing in the US. From the accountability perspective, management should take decisions in the long-term interests of investors, to produce the maximum sustainable return on capital, not in the interests of their firms! Glaum and Mandler (1996) give us evidence consistent with the accountability view in their survey of the opinions of the senior management of top listed German companies and German university professors about the desirability of adopting 13 accounting US regulations. In general these US regulations would have shifted German accounting towards traditional Anglo-Saxon accounting. Glaum and Mandler found: almost every single US-GAAP regulation was opposed by the corporate managers. The professors assessment were more differentiated . A second, related, observation is equally striking: all suggestions for the adaptation of German accounting to current US-practices were judged less favorably by the managers than by the professors (1996, p.226). Their explanation for this difference is consistent with German managers not wanting to face increased accountability to shareholders: One purpose of financial accounting is to oblige management to render an account at regular intervals to the owners of the company with regard to the financial results of their decision-making. [C]urrent German accounting rules leave management wide discretion for accounting policy and, in particular, for the smoothing of profits. The differing attitudes of managers and professors may be explained, at least partly, by the managers negative attitude towards closer scrutiny of their decision-making by the capital markets (Glaum and Mandler, 1996, p.226). Not surprisingly, many major firms did not wish to list in the US under SEC rules. Also consistent with the accountability objective is Saudagaran and Biddle s finding that Japanese managements were unhappy about the segment reporting a US listing would have required. Japanese companies complain that these disclosures put them at a competitive disadvantage relative to other Japanese companies that are not listed in the U.S. (Saudagaran and Biddle, 1992, p.373). Competition is essential for accountability to holders of diversified portfolios. To produce the maximum sustainable residual income from all companies requires management teams to compete with other firms to earn abnormal returns. To hold management accountable for the performance of its segments requires objective and comparable accounting information relative to its competitors. Clearly, disclosure of segment results could intensify competition in Japan, could make the management of US listed Japanese Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 18 companies more accountable to the product market, but it would certainly make them more accountable to investors.12 In countries such as Germany and Japan, the law currently sanctions if not encourages conservative accounting. The statutory audits of Germany and Japan only attest to conformity with the law. Thus, German and Japanese managers may not have sought a listing in the US or UK because they require auditors to attest whether the statements are either fair according to US GAAP or are true and fair according to UK GAAP. Consistent with the accountability objective is the view of Robert Bayless, chief accountant of the Division of Corporate Finance for the US Securities and Exchange Commission, who argued for retaining the requirement to translate foreign accounts to US GAAP or to equivalent IAS. In his view, A particular danger to an efficient market and to investor confidence in that market could arise if one of the competing accounting and reporting systems is of lower quality than the other because it is more susceptible to management s discretionary selection of the methods and its disclosure rules are less rigorous than the other system (Bayless, et al, 1996, p.88). This is the real problem with conservative accounting - the discretion it gives management to manipulate the accounts and thereby become unaccountable to investors for their performance as accounts are not comparable. As Jim Leisenring said, This debate is about how much flexibility is acceptable (Bayless, et al, 1996, p.90). (c) Management behaviour and accounting diversity: Choi and Levich (1991, 1996) use the results of opinion surveys to discuss the effects of accounting diversity on the behaviour of major categories of participants in the international capital market. Choi and Levich find accounting diversity does have effects on behaviour. They conducted an opinion survey during 1988 and 1989 of 52 institutional investors, companies, underwriters, regulators, and debt raters. They found that international accounting diversity was seen as having a detrimental effect on the ability of participants in the international capital markets to reach their classic financial objectives - earning the highest risk-adjusted rate of return on their investments and incurring the lowest cost of capital conditional on the risks of their strategies (Choi and Levich, 1991, p.7.2). Half of their respondents thought international diversity affected their capital market decisions . Only 24% of investors claimed to be able to fully understand international accounting principles and practices, and said diversity had no effects on their capital market decisions. More than 50% of them said they had difficulty in comparing international accounts.13 While most attempted to standardise accounts, this did not eliminate the problem of diversity. Some imposed a higher risk premium, simply avoided international investment, or avoided accounting data in their investment decisions placing more weight on non-accounting information. Those investors with problems saw international accounting standards as the solution - those in favour thought it 12 Another suggestive example is the frequently cited influence of the U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, requiring the disclosure of bribes [?], as a reason for not listing in the US. Many foreign firms believe that these regulations adversely affect their global competitiveness and contradict established business practice (Saudagaran and Biddle, 1992, p.114). Not having to report bribes allows management discretion to consume some of all of these expenses themselves. 13 International security underwriters (who often bring new companies to the international markets) also found diversity troublesome. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 19 would not only make life easier for analysts, but would enlarge investor interests in international markets (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.18). Choi and Levich repeated their survey in 1996, tailoring it to European investors and companies. While a much smaller number cited accounting differences and the quality of financial reporting as significant barriers to pan-European investments, over half said a change in European accounting reports would make them more likely to consider pan-European investments (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.19)! How can we explain this apparent contradiction? Choi and Levich offer two comments from their investor respondents that are for them very different interpretation[s] of why accounting changes might matter for investors (1997, p.6.20): All analysts recognize that earnings figures are manipulated, so they will conduct their fundamental analysis on a relative basis. Either relative to earlier years, or relative to other firms in the same country. The desire for accounting standardization is computer driven growing from a desire to mechanise the analysis of firms (Choi and Levich, 1997, pp.6.1920). Again, [the impact of accounting harmonization] depends on the firm. If Nestle decides to issue in US GAAP, it will not affect us, since we feel we already know a great deal about Nestle and the outlook for the firm. On the other hand, if a smaller firm (he mentions one) makes an accounting change, it could be a signal of a cultural change within the firm. For small and mid cap firms, this accounting change could be important as a signal (Choi and Levich, 1997, pp.6.20). From the accountability perspective we can resolve the apparent contradiction. We resolve the problem if diversity of accounting was not a critical problem for valuing European companies and therefore was not a barrier to investment, but, as many European companies were not accountable to their investors their rate of return on capital did not justify investing in them. Both comments are consistent with this interpretation. The desire to mechanise the comparison of accounts is consistent with the critical role this plays in holding management accountable for financial performance. Similarly, the change in culture signalled by the change to AngloSaxon accounting is the improved accountability it affords. As Choi and Levich comment, whether firms are managed for shareholders or debt holders, whether firms are managed for profit maximization and wealth maximization or some other less transparent target (1997, p.6.20), such as balancing stakeholder interests. The managers of such European companies may well want to change their accounts to signal their acceptance of primary accountability to shareholders. This could, as Choi and Levich imply, be costly to these firms as firms cannot alter their accounting reporting practices for free (1997, p.6.20). The costs of accountability to shareholders they identify could be high, they imply, even though they are unquantifiable political costs: For many European firms, there is not a tradition of external, or financial reporting versus tax reporting. A second set of accounting reports could add a layer of confusion. And some may value secrecy and hold allegiance to debt holders (1997, p.6.20). As we shall see in the following chapters, one stakeholder group in particular, the workforce, may well feel confused . That is, may focus on the higher profits in international accounts described as fair and ignore the lower, more conservative, profits reported in domestic accounts, the traditional focus of wage negotiations in these countries. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 20 Choi and Lee (1991) and Lee and Choi (1992) find that UK, German and Japanese companies pay more on average for US acquisitions. They also find a relationship with these countries more flexible treatments of purchased goodwill compared to the US where management must capitalise and amortise it over not more than 40 years. This is particularly the British option of writing off purchased goodwill against reserves. This allowed British companies to report higher earnings than under US GAAP (Weetman and Gray, 1990), and a higher rate of return on capital (Bryer, 1995). As Choi and Levich say, while there are no economically substantive differences arising from the British treatment of goodwill, Conventional wisdom says that differences in accounting treatment for goodwill provide an incentive for British companies to offer more than U.S. acquirors for a U.S. target because future earnings need not be reduced by the higher price paid (1997, p.6.15). Conventional wisdom , the views of most non-academic commentators, was right, and fully consistent with the accountability perspective. From the traditional viewpoint the absence of the US requirement to amortise goodwill did give the managers of British companies a competitive advantage . That is, British managers could pay more for their US acquisitions because they were not accountable for the cost whereas US managers were. Choi and Lee s analysis showed that the differing goodwill accounting treatments does explain the larger British merger premia; that British managers with the most flexibility, paid the most: higher premiums paid by UK acquirors do appear to be associated with not having to amortize goodwill to earnings . As they conclude, consistent with the accountability perspective, This finding suggests that national differences in accounting do impact managerial behaviour in the market for corporate control (1997, p.6,16). Choi and Lee repeat their analysis for German and Japanese companies, also active acquirors of US companies. Goodwill is deductible from taxable income in Germany and Japan (unlike the US and UK). For these countries they also found higher merger premia compared with those paid by US acquirors. Although relative tax benefits partly accounted for the results, Regression analysis again showed that goodwill accounting does explain merger premiums (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.16). Germany allowed the most favourable accounting treatment and these companies paid higher premia than Japanese acquirors.14 (d) Smoothing earnings As Pownall and Schipper say, a consistent result is earnings of firms in some countries are smoother than are earnings of firms in other countries (1999, p.276). They reference evidence showing, for example, that For three-quarters of th[eir] variables, Australian firms standard deviations are the highest of the seven countries [studied], and Japanese firms standard deviations are the lowest . Another study finds evidence consistent with both German and French firms managing their earnings to a greater degree than do U.S. firms (Pownall and Schipper, 1999, p.277). Other work is consistent with greater earnings management in the UK compared to the US. These differences are consistent with different levels of accountability demanded by different accounting systems. Whether the differences result from differences in rules or differences in the way management operationalises them is, as 14 Dunne and Rollins (1992) and Dunne and Ndubiza (1995) report similar results. See, however, the criticisms of Nobes and Norton (1997) which are cutting but not fundamental. See the reply in Lee and Choi (1997). Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 21 Pownall and Schipper say, a fruitful area of academic inquiry (1999, p.279). We look in some detail and differences in rules in following chapters. (e) The governance premium If investors do not get objective accounts, we might expect them to nevertheless pay more for companies that guarantee their accountability to shareholders in other ways. According to research by McKinsey, the consulting firm, the World Bank and the Institutional Investor magazine, just such a governance premium exists: Investors will pay large premiums for companies with effective boards of directors, particularly in countries where financial reporting is poor. [For example, I]nvestors were prepared to pay premiums of up to 30 per cent for companies that had a majority of independent outside directors (Financial Times, June 20 2000). Investors also favoured companies where directors held significant shareholdings, paid themselves in share options, and subjected themselves to formal evaluation. While in the US and UK investors will pay around 18 per cent more than the average for well governed companies, in Asia and Latin America they will pay much more. In Indonesia, Venezuela and Colombia they will pay 27 more, and in Thailand and Malaysia 25 per cent more. As Mr Coombs of McKinsey said: In Asia and Latin America, where financial reporting is both limited and of poor quality, investors prefer not to put their trust in figures alone. They believe their investments will be better protected by well-governed companies that respect shareholder rights. In Europe and the US, where accounting standards are higher, the relative performance of corporate governance is lower (Financial Times June 20 2000). Consistent with the accountability hypothesis, Classen et al (2002) find that concentrated control in East Asia diminishes firm value indicating low levels of accountability, whereas in wealthy Western countries, La Porta et al (2002) find that firm s with higher concentrations of ownership by controlling owners increased value. With less accountability, high concentrations of ownership is dangerous to minorities because management can divert wealth to the owners; with effective accountability, high concentrations of ownership means the controlling owner s incentive to increase wealth also benefits the minority. Conclusions The evidence available suggests the international harmonisation of accounting is unnecessary to improve the efficiency of the international capital markets. That is, to provide international investors with more useful information for investment decisionmaking. Choi and Levich say we can safely assume that most managements have favorable intentions toward shareholders and wealth maximization (1997, p.6.20). If we can assume this, as firms can choose to provide additional disclosure and translations to Anglo-Saxon GAAP, it follows that firms that do this have weighed the Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 22 additional costs and benefits to investors and that in their particular environments an optimal level of financial reporting currently exists: Given that corporate issuers have a natural incentive to provide accounting information that attracts foreign investors and that both issuers and investors have developed a variety of mechanisms to facilitate communication, the burden to issuers in having to comply with yet another layer of mandated accounting and reporting requirements is likely to outweigh the benefits to the wider market (Choi and Levich, 1997, p.6.24). However, if the favourable intentions of continental European and Japanese managements towards shareholders cannot be assumed - the starting point of the accountability perspective - then it cannot be assumed that the potential costs of international harmonisation outweigh the potential benefits to international investors. This, at least, provides a coherent explanation for the unswerving drive of the international capital markets, the accounting profession and the IASB for IAS. We argued in this chapter that the evidence is consistent with the accountability hypothesis. That is, that the purpose of international harmonisation is to improve the accountability of the managements of firms from countries that allow or promote conservative accounting - to abolish or significantly reduce the income-smoothing it currently allows their managements. In chapter 5 we reinforce this conclusion with evidence that the cause of this difference in international accounting is different systems of corporate governance . Many argue that the cause of differences in corporate governance is differences in culture . However, we argue different systems of corporate governance are the product of differences in the historical development of the capital markets that create different systems of accountability. References Alford, A., Jones, J., Leftwich, R. and Zmijewski, M., The Relative Informativeness of Accounting Disclosures in Different Countries, Journal of Accounting Research (Vol.31, Supplement 1993), pp. Ali, A. and Hwang, L.S., Country-Specific Factors Related to Financial Reporting and the Value Relevance of Accounting Data, Journal of Accounting Research (Vol.38, No.1, Spring, 2000), pp.1-21. Amir, E., Harris, T. and Venuit, E., A comparison of the value relevant of US versus non-US GAAP accounting measures using 20-F reconciliations, Journal of Accounting Research (Supplement, 1993), pp.230-264. Ball, R., Kothari, S.P. and Robin, A., The effect of international institutional factors on properties of accounting earnings, Journal of Accounting & Economics (Vol.29, 2000), pp.1-51. Bandyopadhyay, S., Hanna, J. and Richardson, G., Capital market effects of USCanadian GAAP differences, Journal of Accounting Research (Vol.32, 1994), pp.262-277. Barth, M. and Clinch, G., International accounting differences and their relation to share prices: Evidence from UK, Australian, and Canadian firms, Contemporary Accounting Research (Vol.13, No.1, 1996), pp.135-170. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 23 Barth, M.E., Beaver, W.H. and Landsman, W.R., The relevance of the value relevance literature for financial accounting standard setting: another view, Journal of Accounting & Economics (Vol. 31, September 2001), pp.77-104. Bayless, R., Cochrane, J., Harris, T., Leisenring, J., McLaughlin, J. and Wirtz, J.P., Commentary: International Access to US. Capital Markets - An AAA Forum on Accounting Policy, Accounting Horizons (Vol.10, No.1, March 1996), pp.76-94. Beaver, W.H. and Demski, J.S., The Nature of Income Measurement, The Accounting Review (Vol.LIV, No.1, January 1979), pp.38-45. Bhusan, , R. and Lessard, D.R., Coping with international accounting diversity: Fund managers views on disclosure, reconciliation and harmonisation, Accounting Horizons (September, 1991), pp.69-80. Brown, S., Lo, K. and Lys, T., Use of R2 in accounting research: measuring changes in value over the last four decades, Journal of Accounting and Economics (Vol.28, 1999), pp.83-115. Biddle, G.C. and Saudagaran, S.M., Foreign stock listings: Benefits, costs and accounting policy dilemma, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Summer, 1992), pp.106-148. Chan, C. and Seow, G., The association between stock returns and foreign GAAP earnings vs. earnings adjusted to US GAAP, Journal of Accounting and Economics (Vol.21, February, 1996), pp.139-158. Choi, F.D.S. and Levich, R.M., The Capital Market Effects of International Accounting Diversity (Homewood, Ill.: Dow Jones-Irwin, 1990). Choi, F.D.S. and Levich, R.M., International Accounting Diversity and Capital Market Decisions, in Choi, F.D.S., (ed) Handbook of International Accounting (New York: John Wiley and Sons Inc., 1991). Choi, F.D.S. and Levich, R.M., International Accounting Diversity and Capital Market Decisions, in Choi, F.D.S., (ed) Handbook of International Accounting, second edition (New York: John Wiley and Sons Inc., 1997). Choi, F.D.S. and Lee, C., Merger premia and national accounting differences in accounting for goodwill, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Vol.3, No.3, 1991). Claessens, S., Djanckov, S. and Lang, L.H.P., Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings, Journal of Finance Choi, F.D.S. and Lee, C., Merger premia: a Reply, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Vol.8, No.2, 1997), pp.142-143. Davis-Friday, P.Y. and Rivera, J.M., Inflation Accounting and 20-F Disclosures: Evidence from Mexico, Accounting Horizons (Vol.14, No.2, 2000), pp.113135. Dumontier, P. and Raffournier, B., Accounting and capital markets: a survey of the European evidence, The European Accounting Review (Vol.11, No.1, 2002, pp.119-151. Dunne, K. M. and Rollins, T.P., Accounting for goodwill: an analysis of the US, UK and Japan, Journal of International Accounting and Taxation (Vol.1, No.2, 1992), pp.191-207. Dunne, K. M. and Ndubiza, G., International acquisition accounting method and corporate multinationalism: Evidence from foreign acquisitions, Journal of International Business Studies (Second quarter, 199), pp.361-378. Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 24 Dunne, K. M. and Ndubiza, G., The effects of international differences in the tax treatment of goodwill: a reply, Journal of International Business Studies (Vol.27, No.3, 1996), pp.593-596. Frost, C.A. and Pownall, G., Interdependencies in the Global Markets for Capital and Information: The Case of Smithkline Beecham plc, Accounting Horizons (Vol.10, No.1, 1996), pp.38-57). Glaum, M, and Mandler, U., Global Accounting Harmonization from a German Perspective: Bridging the GAAP, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Vol.7, No.3, 1996), pp.215-242. Goeltz, R.K., International Accounting Harmonization: The Impossible (and Unnecessary?) Dream, Accounting Horizons (Vol.5, No.1, 1991), pp.85-88. Gornik-Tomaszewski, S. and Rozen, E.S., Pricing of Foreign GAAP Earnings in U.S. Capital Market Prior to the SEC Required Reconciliation Disclosure, The International Journal of Accounting (Vol.34, No.4, 1999), pp.550-551. Gray, S.J. and Roberts, C.B., East-West Accounting Issues: A New Agenda, Accounting Horizons (Vol.5, No.1, March 1991), pp.42-50. Gray, S.J. and Roberts, C.B., Foreign company listings on the London Stock Exchange: Listing patterns and influential factors, in Cooke, T.E. and Nobes, C.W. (eds) The Development of Accounting in an International Context (London: Routledge, 1997). Hall, C., Hamao, Y. and Harris, T.S., A comparison of relations between security market prices, returns and accounting measures in Japan and the United States, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Vol.5, No.1, 1994), pp.47-73. Harris, T.S., Lang, M, and Moller Hans P., The Value Relevance of German Accounting Measures: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Accounting Research (Vol.32, No.2, Autumn 1994), pp.187-209. Holthausen, R.W. and Watts, R.L., The relevance of the value-relevance literature for financial accounting standard setting, Journal of Accounting & Economics (Vol. 31, September 2001), pp.3-75. Hopwood, A.G., Some reflections on The harmonization of accounting within the EU , The European Accounting Review (Vol.3, No.2, 1994), pp.241-253. Joos, P. and Lang, M., The effects of accounting diversity: evidence from the European Union, Journal of Accounting Research (Supplement, 1994), pp.141-168. Lee, C. and Choi, F.D.S., Effects of alternative goodwill treatment on merger premia: Further empirical evidence, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Autumn, 1992), pp.220-236. Lochner, P.R. Jnr., The Role of U.S. Standard Setters in International Harmonization of Accounting Standards, Journal of Accountancy (September 1991), pp.108109. Lowenstein, L., Financial Transparency and Corporate Governance: You Manage What You Measure, Columbia Law Review (Vol.96, June 1996), pp. 13351362. Meek, G.R., US Securities Market Responses to Alternate Earnings Disclosures of Non-US Multinational Corporations, The Accounting Review (April 1983), pp.394-402. Meek, G.R. and Gray, S.J., Globalization of stock markets and foreign listing requirements: voluntary disclosures by continental European companies listed Ludwig Erhard Lectures 2004 25 on the London Stock Exchange, Journal of International Business Studies (Summer 1989), pp.315-316. Most, K.S., How Bad Are European Accounts? in Berg, K.B., Mueller, G.G. and Walker, L.M., (eds), Readings in International Accounting (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1969). Nobes, C and Norton, J., Effects of Alternative Goodwill Treatments on Merger Premia: a Comment, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Vol.8, No.2, 1997), pp.137-141. Ohlson, J., Accounting earnings, book value and dividends: the theory of the clean surplus equation (Part 1), in Brief, R.P. and Peasnell, K.V. (eds), Clean Surplus: A Link Between Accounting and Finance (New York: Garland Publishing, 1996), pp.165-227. Pownall, G. and Schipper, K., Implications of Accounting Research for the SEC s Consideration of International Accounting Standards for U.S. Securities Offerings, Accounting Horizons (Vol.13, No.3, September 1999), pp.259-280. Rees, W., Financial Analysis, second edition (Hemel Hempstead: Prentice-Hall International, 1995). Saudagaran, S.M. and Meek, G.K., A Review of Research on the Relationship Between International Capital Markets and Financial Reporting by Multinational Firms, Journal of Accounting Literature (Vol.16, 1997), pp.127159. Saudagaran, S.M. and Biddle, G.C., Financial disclosure levels and foreign exchange listing decisions, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting (Summer, 1992), pp.106-148. Saudagaran, S.M. and Biddle, G.C., Foreign listing location: A study of MNC s and stock exchanges in eight countries, Journal of International Business Studies (Vol.26, No.2, 1995), pp.319-341. Strong, N. and Walker, M., The Explanatory Power of Earnings for Stock Returns, The Accounting Review (Vol.66, No.2, 1993), pp.385-399. Walker, M., Clean Surplus Accounting Models and Market-based Accounting Research: A Review, Accounting and Business Research (Vol.27, No.4, Autumn 1997), pp.341-355. Wyatt, A.R., International Accounting Standards and Organizations: Quo Vadis? in Choi, F.D.S., (ed) Handbook of International Accounting (New York: John Wiley and Sons Inc., 1991). Zarzeski, M.T., Spontaneous Harmonization Effects of Culture and Market Forces on Accounting Disclosure Practices, Accounting Horizons (Vol.10, No.1, March 1996), pp.18-37.