13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 135 DAMAGES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT FOR SALE OF GOODS Introduction In this article, the writer seeks to examine some common issues in the assessment of damages where there is a breach of a contract for the sale of goods. Together with the general law on the sale of goods, the law relating to damages in such contracts has been codified in the Sale of Goods Act1 . Sections 50, 51, 53 and 54 which contain the relevant law form the starting point in considering damages for various types of breach, but since the statute consists of a codification of the common law, the bulk of the material remains case law. However, in so far as the guidance offered by precedents is concerned, the following observations by Warren LH Khoo J, in delivering the judgment of the Singapore Court of Appeal in Hong Fok Realty Pte Ltd v Bima Investment Pte Ltd 2 should be noted: “It must be borne in mind ... that the ascertainment of damages is an exercise to establish a question of fact, that is, what loss and damage have been suffered by the plaintiff in the particular case before the court, and to award him damages ascertained according to these principles. Decided cases are useful more for the principles they enunciate, than for the result of the application of the principles.” Remoteness of Damages and Measure of Damages As Andrew Phang said in his book3: “In the ultimate analysis a claim for damages raises two distinct questions. ... These emerge from the fundamental principle that the remoteness of the damage for which compensation is claimed must be distinguished from the monetary assessment of that compensation. The first is: for what kind of damages is the plaintiff entitled to recover compensation? ... To this end Hadley v Baxendale4 defined the kind of damage that is the appropriate subject of compensation, and excluded all other kinds as being too remote. The decision was concerned solely with what 1 2 3 4 Cap. 393, 1994 Ed (which is in pari materia with the U.K. Sale of Goods Act 1979). [1993] 1 SLR 73, at 80. Entitled Cheshire, Fifoot and Furmston’s Law of Contract, Singapore & Malaysian Edition, Butterworths, 1994 at 848, 849. (1854) 9 Ex 341. 136 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) is correctly called remoteness of damage, and it will conduce to clarity if this expression is reserved for cases where the defendant denies liability for certain of the consequences that have flowed from his breach. The second question, which must be kept quite distinct from the first, concerns the principles upon which damage must be evaluated or quantified in terms of money. This may appropriately be called the question of the measure of damages. The principle adopted by the courts in many cases dating back to at least 1848 is that of restitutio in integrum. If the plaintiff has suffered damage that is not too remote, he must be restored to the position he would have been in had that particular damage not occurred.” Alderson B stated the rule that governs remoteness of damage as follows in delivering the judgment of the Court of Exchequer in Hadley v Baxendale5: “Where two parties have made a contract which one of them has broken, the damages which the other party ought to receive in respect of such breach of contract should be such as may fairly and reasonably be considered either arising naturally, that is, according to the usual course of things, from such breach of contract itself, or such as may reasonably be supposed to have been in the contemplation of both parties, at the time they made the contract, as the probable result of the breach of it.” In this case, the plaintiffs were the millers of a mill and had entered into a contract of carriage with the defendant, a common carrier. The defendant was to deliver the plaintiffs’ broken crank shaft to the makers as a pattern for a new one. The plaintiffs claimed damages for loss of profit caused by a delay by the defendant. Alderson B demonstrated that, in accordance with the principle he had just expressed, there were only two possible grounds upon which the plaintiffs could sustain their claim. Firstly, that in the usual cause of things the work of the mill would cease altogether for the want of the shaft. This, he said, would not be the normal occurrence, for, to take only one reasonable possibility, the plaintiffs might well have had a spare shaft in reserve. Secondly, that the special circumstances were so fully disclosed that the inevitable loss of profit was made apparent to the defendant. This however was not the case since the only communication proved was that the article to be carried was the shaft of a mill and that the plaintiffs were the owners of the mill. The words “either” and “or” used in the formulation of the rule as explained by Alderson B show that it contains two branches. The first 5 Ibid, at 354. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 137 deals with the normal damage that occurs in the usual course of things; the second with abnormal damage that arises because of special or exceptional circumstances.6 Asquith LJ in what is generally regarded as a classic exposition of the law reformulated the test of remoteness of damage laid down by Alderson B in Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd v Newman Industries Ltd7 . He summarised the substance of the test in the following three propositions:“In cases of breach of contract, the aggrieved party is only entitled to recover such part of the loss actually resulting as was at the time of the contract reasonably foreseeable as liable to result from the breach. What was at that time reasonably so foreseeable depends on the knowledge then possessed by the parties or, at all events, by the party who later commits the breach. For this purpose, knowledge ‘possessed’ is of two kinds; one imputed, the other actual. Everyone, as a reasonable person, is taken to know the ‘ordinary course of things’ and consequently what loss is liable to result from a breach of contract in that ordinary course. This is the subject matter of the ‘first rule’ in Hadley v Baxendale. But to this knowledge, which a contract-breaker is assumed to possess whether he actually possesses it or not, there may have to be added in a particular case knowledge which he actually possesses of special circumstances outside the ‘ordinary course of things’, of such a kind that a breach in those special circumstances would be liable to cause more loss. Such a case attracts the operation of the ‘second rule’ so as to make additional loss also recoverable.”8 In this case the facts were as follows: The plaintiffs, launderers and dyers, decided to extend their business. For this purpose and for the purpose of obtaining certain dyeing contracts of an exceptionally profitable character, they required a larger boiler. The defendants, an engineering firm, contracted to sell and deliver to the plaintiffs on 5 June a certain boiler of the required capacity. This however was damaged in the course of removal and was not delivered until 8 November. The defendants were aware of the nature of the plaintiffs’ business and they were informed in more than one letter before the conclusion of the contract that the plaintiffs were “most anxious” to put the boiler into use “in the shortest possible time.” 6 7 8 This sentence was cited with approval in the Singapore High Court decision of Fazlur Rahman v Bombay Trading Co (Pte) Ltd [1993] 1 SLR 440, at 447. [1949] 2 KB 528. Ibid, at 539. 138 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) In an action for breach of contract, the plaintiffs claimed (a) damages for the loss of profit, assessed by them at sixteen pounds a week, that they would have earned through the extension of their business but for the delay in delivery of the boiler, and (b) damages, assessed at two hundred and sixty two pounds a week, for the loss of the exceptional profits that they would similarly have earned on the highly lucrative dyeing contracts. In the opinion of the Court of Appeal, the defendants, with their engineering experience and with the knowledge of the facts possessed by them, could not reasonably contend that the likelihood of some loss of business was beyond their prevision. They were indeed ignorant that the plaintiffs had in prospect the “highly lucrative” dyeing contracts and so could not be liable specifically for the “highly lucrative” profits that the plaintiffs had hoped to make. However the plaintiffs were not precluded from recovering a general sum which might represent the normal profit to be expected from the completion of the dyeing contracts. In The Heron II9, however, the House of Lords differed from the judgment of Asquith LJ with regard to the criterion by which to determine the remoteness of damage arising from a breach of contract. They stated that the question is not as Asquith LJ said, whether the damage should have been foreseen by the defendant but whether the probability of its occurrence should have been within the reasonable contemplation of both parties at the time when the contract was made, having regard to their knowledge at that time. What is the degree of probability required and how is it to be defined? Asquith LJ said: “In order to make the contract-breaker liable under [Hadley v Baxendale] it is not necessary that he should have actually asked himself what loss is liable to result from a breach. ... It suffices that if he had considered the question he would as a reasonable man have concluded that the loss in question was liable to result ... Nor ... to make a particular loss recoverable, need it be proved that upon a given state of knowledge the defendant could, as a reasonable man, foresee that a breach must necessarily result in that loss. It is enough if he could foresee it was likely so to result. It is indeed enough ... if the loss (or some factor without which it would not have occurred) is a ‘serious possibility’ or a ‘real danger.’ For short we have used the word ‘liable’ to result. Possibly the colloquialism ‘on the cards’ indicates the shade of meaning with some approach to accuracy.”10 9 [1969] 1 AC 350. 10 [1949] 2 KB at 540. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 139 In The Heron II11 their Lordships unanimously rejected the use of the phrase “on the cards.” However they could not agree upon a suitable substitute. Lord Reid distrusted the expression “liable to result” and preferred “not unlikely” or “quite likely” to happen. Lord Hodson disapproved of “likely to result” and preferred “liable to result” the phrase which Asquith LJ had suggested. Lord Upjohn was content to adopt the phrases “a real danger” or “a serious possibility.” If indeed a single phrase, must be chosen, “liable to result” seems to have secured the most general assent. It is questionable whether this exercise in semantics is of any great value. As Lord Upjohn said in the House of Lords, “the assessment of damages is not an exact science,”12 and it may be added that the search of such an elusive quantity as a person’s assumed contemplation can scarcely be governed by any particular formula. This is an unsatisfactory case. Foreseeability is certainly important because prices are fixed on the basis of a foreseeable outcome; it would therefore generally be unjust to impose liability for unforeseen consequences. But it does not follow that it is always just to impose liability for foreseeable consequences. Whether this is just may well depend to some degree on the nature of the contract and on whether the price of the goods in question is likely to be affected by the foreseeable consequences of breach. In a contract for sale of goods, the price of the goods will normally reflect the scarcity value of those goods. In the Victoria Laundry case the sellers were selling a boiler for laundry use at a time when laundries were in great demand; plainly this fact would have affected the price at which the boiler was sold; and it was therefore reasonable to treat the seller as liable for the lost profits arising from his delay in delivering the boiler. But in The Heron II the defendants were shipowners and the service they were selling was that of carriage of goods. Freight charges for the carriage of goods would not normally be affected by the value or scarcity of the goods being carried because these facts do not affect supply and demand of shipping space. Therefore a shipowner would not increase his freight charges to cover the additional risk of lost profits arising from fluctuations of market price in the goods which he carries. Nor does it seem desirable that he should be required to do so, because he does not have or profess the knowledge of relevant market conditions to enable him to gauge this additional risk accurately; nor would it be economically efficient for a shipowner to adjust his freight charges to the particular market conditions of the goods he carries. The Heron II is an illustration of serious deficiencies in the sophistication of common-law courts in dealing with what are, at least, partly economic issues. 11 Supra, n 9. 12 Ibid, at 425. 140 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) Another case takes this principle to what are surely unacceptable extremes. In H Parsons (Livestock) v Uttley Ingham & Co Ltd13 the defendants supplied and installed a large hopper for holding animal foodstuffs for the plaintiff, a pig farmer. The defendants unfortunately left closed a ventilator at the top of the hopper (which could not be seen from the ground) with the result that some of the food became mouldy. The pigs became ill and later a much more serious pig disease was triggered off by this first disease and many of the pigs died. The farmer recovered substantial damages for all his lost and deceased pigs on the basis that they were foreseeable results. There does seem to be an air of unreality about the foreseability test in cases of this nature. In one sense everything that happens (except perhaps for voluntary human action) occurs according to the laws of the physical universe and in so far as these are known, virtually any result is foreseeable as possible from a base which supposes knowledge of the initial breach of contact. Thus the only consequences that come to be regarded as unforeseeable are those where the train of events has been interrupted by conscious human interventions. This seems to go much too far. It would be more sensible in a case of this nature to ask whether losses from pig disease ought to be treated as part of the risks of farming, or of the manufacture and sale of animal food hoppers. This case shows the difficulties in this field have not been laid to rest. Lord Denning MR thought that as Hadley v Baxendale, the Victoria Laundry case and The Heron II all dealt with loss of profits, they could be regarded as laying down a principle applicable only where breach of contract led to economic loss and that where it led to physical loss, the same test as in tort, i.e. that of foreseeability should apply. The distinction between economic and physical loss is itself difficult to apply. Scarman LJ rejected this distinction and found for the plaintiffs on the ground that it was within the party’s contemplation that the pigs would have upset stomachs as a result of eating mouldy nuts and that what happened was simply a more extensive example of a contemplatable loss. Scarman LJ’s view places a heavy burden on the distinction between type and extent of loss. None of the judgments explain why, if any illness to feed the pigs were contemplatable, the plaintiffs were not at fault in continuing to feed the nuts to the pigs. In spite of all the difficulties highlighted above it is submitted that the two branches of Hadley v Baxendale provide the basic principle to the question: for what kind of damage is the plaintiff entitled to recover compensation or the question of remoteness of damage. It is impossible to answer the question in general for just as contracts vary infinitely in character so also do the types of loss that their non-performance normally causes. The nature of the damage that ensues in the usual course of things from a breach varies with the circumstances of each contract. 13 [1978] QB 791. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 141 We turn now to the measure of damages. The principle here is to effect a restitutio in integrum so far as the actionable damage is concerned. 1. Non-delivery The measure of damages for non-delivery of goods sold is prescribed by Section 51 of the Sale of Goods Act. Section 51(2) provides that “the measure of damages is the estimated loss directly and naturally resulting, in the ordinary course of events, from the seller’s breach of contract.” Section 51(3) provides that “where there is an available market for the goods in question, the measure of damages is prima facie to be ascertained by the difference between the contract price and the market or current price of the goods at the time or times when they ought to have been delivered, or, if no time was fixed, then at the time of the refusal to deliver.” To this, Section 54 adds that nothing in the Act shall affect the buyer’s right to recover interest or special damages where by law recoverable. Section 51(2) is framed in terms of the first rule in Hadley v Baxendale, excluding the element of the defendant’s knowledge of special circumstances; section 51(3) states the normal measure of damages under the first rule; section 54 brings in the second rule in Hadley v Baxendale and will in appropriate cases displace section 51(2) and (3) and allow increased damages. The normal measure of damages as stated in section 51(3), thereby incorporating the common law as stated in Barrow v Arnaud 14 , is the market price of the goods at the contractual time for delivery less the contract price, since this represents the amount that the buyer must obtain to put himself in the position he would have been in had the contract been carried out. For to put himself in such a position he must go into the market and buy equivalent goods; even if he does not choose to rebuy in the market his loss will remain the same. If therefore there is no difference between the contract and the market prices, the buyer will have lost nothing and the damages will be nominal. In Bulsing Ltd v Joon Seng & Co15 Chua J elaborated upon Section 50, subsections (2) and (3) (dealing with damages for non-acceptance of goods) which are similar to Section 51, subsections (2) and (3): “In my opinion the general rule in the case of breach of contract is that the plaintiff by way of damages, is entitled to be put in the same position as he would have been in if the contract had been completed. Subsections (2) and (3) ... give the measure of general damages and the measure of damages laid down in subsection (3) is 14 [1846] 8 QB 595, at 609-610. 15 [1972] 2 MLJ 43, at 45. 142 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) not to be applied in cases where it is not appropriate to achieve the result required by subsection (2), for example, in the case where the plaintiff is a dealer in the particular goods sold. In such a case, what ensues from the breach in the usual course of things is that the plaintiff loses the profit that he would have made had the sale to that particular buyer been completed and he is entitled to be recompensated (sic) for that loss. It is no answer to say that he has sold, or may readily sell the goods to another person, for even if he has been successful the fact remains that he has profited from one sale instead of two.” 2. Delayed Delivery No rule is prescribed by the Sale of Goods Act for the measure of damages where the goods sold are delayed and ultimately accepted by the buyer after the delay. The consequential losses are much the same as in non-delivery but the normal measure of damages is necessarily quite different and is indeed more in line with the normal measure for breach of warranty. The normal measure of damages is the market value at the contractual time for delivery less the market value at the time of actual delivery since this represents the amount that will put the buyer into the position he would have been in had the contract been carried out. The price at which the buyer has resold the goods to a third party may be taken as evidence of their value at the time of actual delivery where this is difficult to assess; authority can be sought in the equivalent breach of warranty cases. If the resale price is lower than the market value at delivery it cannot be relied on by the buyer to augment his damages. Yet in the converse situation where the resale price was higher than the market value at delivery, it was held to control in Wertheim v Chicoutimi Pulp Co.16 This was a case where the seller made late delivery of a quantity of wood pulp bought by the buyer at 25s a ton. The market price of the pulp was 70s a ton at the port of delivery on the date fixed for delivery (that was September/November), but by the time of the actual delivery in the following June, the market price had fallen to 42s 6d a ton. Under various sub-sales the buyer was able to fulfil these sub-contracts and when he sued the original seller for damages for late delivery, the Privy Council assessed them as the difference between (a) the market value at the port of delivery at the due date for delivery and (b) the actual price obtained on their resale. The Privy Council held that the sellers could rely on the sub-sales to reduce the damages. 16 [1911] AC 301. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 143 Lord Atkinson said:“The market value [that is, at the time of actual delivery] is taken because it is presumed to be the true value of the goods to the purchaser ... but if in fact the purchaser, when he obtains possession of the goods, sells them at a price greatly in advance of the then market value, that presumption is rebutted and the real value of the goods to him is proved by the very fact of this resale to be more than market value, and the loss he sustains must be measured by that price, unless he is, against all justice, to be permitted to make a profit by the breach of the contract, be compensated for a loss he never suffered, and be put, as far as money can do it, not in the same position in which he would have been if the contract had been performed, but in a much better position.”17 This argument has been criticised by Scrutton LJ in Slater & Anor v. Hoyle & Smith18 where the learned judge pointed out that:“The buyer was under no obligation to deliver the contract goods on the sub-contract. If he had bought other goods and used them for the sub-contract, he would have been left with goods delivered at a time when the market price was 42s 6d instead of when it was 70s, and would have recovered 27s 6d. Lord Atkinson says that in the case of non-delivery the price at which the purchaser might in anticipation of delivery have resold the goods is properly treated, where no question of loss of profit arises, as an entirely irrelevant matter. It is always so treated, as I understand the law, unless the buyer can affect the seller with such notice of the sub-contract as makes him liable for loss by its non-fulfillment... I respectfully think that all the English decisions show that a plaintiff cannot measure the real value of what he has lost by reference to a contract peculiar to himself, for which the defendant is not responsible, and that his loss therefore is not measured by that price.” Here the argument of Scrutton LJ is that the buyer was under no obligation to deliver the contract goods on the sub-contract, and that if he had bought other goods and used them for the sub-contract he would have been left with the original goods on his hands so that their market price at actual delivery would have been the relevant figure in measuring the damages. It is submitted that in the latter scenario, a different scenario from that in Slater’s case, the difference in value of the goods as they are when delivered and as they ought to have been would mark his real loss and thus the measure of damages. 17 Ibid, at 307-308. 18 [1920] 2 KB 11, at 23-24. 144 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) Scrutton LJ was of the view that whether the resale price is higher or lower than the market price at the date of actual delivery, the buyer’s damages should be calculated exclusively by reference to the market price at the due date and at the actual date, since the buyer could have bought other goods to fulfil his obligations under the sub-contract and the market price of the goods delivered late by the seller would then be relevant to those goods left on his hands at that date. Another writer, G.H. Treitel19 said:“To allow the buyers to recover 27s 6d would, it was said, enable them to make a profit out of the breach. But this is hard to fit in with the principles normally governing the assessment of damages. Two possibilities exist in cases of this kind. First, the buyer has resold the very goods comprised in the main contract. If so he has admittedly not lost 27s 6d per ton but it is difficult to see that he lost anything at all; he would not have been free to sell the pulp in the market at 70s per ton as he was bound to deliver it to his sub-buyer. Secondly, the buyer has resold an equivalent quantity. If so, the subsale should be disregarded. Had the pulp been delivered in September/November, it could have then been sold to a third party and the sub-buyer could still have been satisfied with an equivalent quantity bought in June at 42s 6d per ton. It is improbable that the buyer would have kept the pulp throughout this period on a falling market. On the other hand, if (in view of the delay), the buyer had bought other goods and used them for the sub-contract he would have been left with the goods delivered at the time when the market price was 42s 6d instead of when it was 70s. Nor is it right to say that the buyer would make a profit out of the breach of contract if he were awarded 27s 6d a ton. He would make a profit out of the advantageous subsale.” Further, as stated in Chitty on Contracts20 :“But the buyer was not bound to fulfil the subcontracts by delivering the specific goods which he received under the original contract.... It is submitted that the choice of the buyer not to repurchase in the market on the date of the breach should not benefit the defaulting seller any more than it should harm him by increasing the damages payable by him if the resale price is below the market price at that date.” 19 In the book entitled “The Law of Contract” (9th Ed, Sweet & Maxwell Ltd) at 857. 20 27th Ed, 1994 (Sweet & Maxwell Ltd) in paragraph 41-300 at 1280 at footnote 91. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 145 For as stated below, Scrutton LJ has said that if the buyer is lucky enough, for reasons with which the seller has nothing to do, to get his goods through on the sub-sale without a claim against him, this on principle cannot affect his claim against the seller any more than the fact that he had to pay very large damages on his sub-contract would affect his original seller. It is submitted that Wertheim’s case was rightly decided based on the principle that the plaintiff is to be put in the position he would have been in if the contract had been performed but not to put him in a better position. 3. Breach of Warranty The measure of damages for breach of warranty generally is prescribed by Section 53 of the Sale of Goods Act. Section 53(2) provides that in the case of breach of warranty of quality such loss is prima facie the difference between the value of the goods at the time of delivery to the buyer and the value they would have had if they had answered to the warranty. To this, Section 54 adds that nothing in the Act shall affect the buyer’s right to recover interest or special damages where by law recoverable. Section 53(3) is framed in terms of the first rule in Hadley v Baxendale excluding the element of the defendant’s knowledge of special circumstances; Section 53(3) states the normal measure of damages under the first rule in the case of breach of warranty of quality, but it would appear to be equally the normal measure for other breaches of warranty, such as those in relation to description and fitness; Section 54 brings in the second rule in Hadley v Baxendale, and in appropriate cases will displace Section 53(2) and (3) and allow increased damages. The normal measure of damages as stated in Section 53(3) is the value of the goods as warranted less their value as they are, both values being taken at the contractual time for delivery since this represents the amount that will put the buyer into the position he would have been in had the warranty been satisfied. If the value at actual delivery is nil then the market value of the goods as warranted forms the measure of damages. Here an interesting question is whether the subsale would be relevant in assessing the measure of damages that the seller is liable to pay to the buyer. In Slater & Anor v Hoyle & Smith21 , the court answered the above question in the negative. In this case, the buyer bought cotton from the seller in order to fulfil another contract that the buyer had already made with a sub-buyer. The seller delivered cloth that was not up to the contractual quality but the buyer was able to perform the sub-contract 21 Supra n 18. 146 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) by delivering the same cloth. The sub-buyer paid the full price under the sub-contract and then the buyer sued the seller for damages. The seller submitted, firstly, that the resale price should be taken instead of the market value of the cloth at the time it was delivered, and secondly, that the buyer had not in fact suffered any loss because he received the same resale price as he would have received if the seller had not been in breach. The Court of Appeal, however, awarded the buyer damages assessed at the normal measure, that is, the difference between (a) the market price at the time and place of delivery of cloth up to the contractual quality, and (b) the market price at the time and place of delivery of the cloth actually delivered. Scrutton LJ said that:“If the buyer is lucky enough, for reasons with which the seller has nothing to do, to get his goods through on the sub-contract without a claim against him, this on principle cannot affect his claim against the seller any more than the fact that he had to pay very large damages on his sub-contract would affect his original seller.”22 The Court of Appeal in Bence Graphics International Ltd v Fasson UK Ltd23 refused to follow Slater’s case. In the former case, the sellers supplied cast vinyl film to the buyer who used it to manufacture decals that were used in the shipping industry to identify bulk containers. It was a term of the contract that the film would survive for at least 5 years but the film degraded prematurely and rendered many of the decals illegible. The Court of Appeal held that at the time of making their contract the parties were aware of facts that indicated to both that the loss, in the event of a breach, would not be the difference between the value of the goods delivered and the market value and accordingly that measure of damages ceased to be appropriate. The Court of Appeal held that both parties contemplated (a) that the buyer would, after manufacturing the goods into another product, sell the latter to others; and (b) that the measure of damages for defects in the goods should be the extent of the buyer’s liability (if any) to those others resulting from the defect. In Bence’s case the court accepted that its approach was contrary to Slater’s case and was of the view that the latter case should be “reconsidered.” Auld LJ said that in the latter case, the court wrongly overlooked the basic rule in Section 53(2) of the English Sale of Goods Act 1979 (which is in pari materia with the Singapore Sale of Goods Act 22 Ibid, at 23. 23 [1997] 1 All E R 979. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 147 (Cap 393), 1994 Ed) as to what would have been in the ordinary and natural contemplation of the parties in a commercial contract, namely, that the buyer could well be prejudiced in his onward dealing with the goods if they were defective. Otton LJ distinguished Slater’s case on the grounds that the sub-sale was of the same goods although after bleaching and the seller did not know of the contemplated sub-sale. In Bence’s case the goods were substantially converted or processed by the buyer and the sellers were aware of the precise use to which the film was to be put at the time the contract was made. Auld LJ on the other hand did not think that Slater’s case was materially distinguishable from Bence’s case on the two grounds given by Otton LJ. Auld LJ said that as to the seller’s knowledge of the buyer’s intended use of the goods, “the report in Slater’s case states that the seller did not know of the buyer’s onward sale contracts. However, that must simply mean that he did not know of the specific contracts; for there can be no doubt that, in contracting to sell 3,000 pieces of unbleached cloth of a certain quality, the seller knew that he was dealing with a commercial buyer who could sell them on either unprocessed or processed to some degree, and must be taken to have contemplated that loss could result from such onward sales if the cloth was not of the required quality. The fact that the seller in this case had more detailed knowledge of the use to which the buyer would put the film is not a material distinction in determining the measure of damages as distinct from their precise calculation.”24 It is possible to distinguish Slater’s case on the ground that on the facts, the parties did not contemplate that if the goods were defective, the extent of the buyer’s liability towards his sub-buyer should be the measure of damages payable by the seller. The issue was stated in Bence’s case to be what was within the contemplation of the parties, which issue is a question of fact dependent on the facts of each case. However it is submitted that this is not really a good ground of distinguishing the two cases for in Slater’s case the sellers would have known that the cloth would be the subject of onward dealing. Auld LJ convincingly substantiated his ruling that Slater’s case and those who supported it were wrong and had wrongly: (1) overlooked the basic rule in Section 53(2) as to what been in the ordinary and natural contemplation of the commercial contract such as it was, namely, that the well be prejudiced in his onward dealing with the goods defective; 24 Ibid, at 992. would have parties in a buyer could if they were 148 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2001) (2) disregarded the reasoning of the Privy Council in Wertheim’s case that where there has been delivery in a mercantile contract and it can be seen what the buyer has done with the goods, it is possible to and proper to measure his actual loss by reference to that outcome; (3) had too much regard to practicality at the expense of principle in relying on possible difficulties of establishing causation and of assessment where the goods sold have been subjected to some process or where the terms of the contract and sub-contract may for that or some other reason be different; and (4) were seemingly content to award a buyer more than the evidence clearly showed he had lost. Section 53(2) of the English Sale of Goods Act 1979 provides that “the measure of damages for breach of warranty is the estimated loss directly and naturally resulting in the ordinary course of events, from the breach of warranty.” Looking at Section 53(2) of the Act, Auld LJ seems to be right in saying that one has to look at “what would have been in the ordinary and natural contemplation of the parties in a commercial contract such as it was, namely, that the buyer could well be prejudiced in his onward dealing with the goods if they were defective.”25 If one were to apply this test of what is in the ordinary and natural contemplation of the parties to Slater’s case one would have to come to the same conclusion as in Bence’s case, that is, that the plaintiffs were only entitled to recover damages for losses under or arising from a breach of contract for onward sale. Conclusion The assessment of damages that a defendant is liable for in breaching a contract is not an exact science and it is hardly possible to pin down the requisite degree of foreseeability with mathematical precision. However this does not mean that no damages are to be given just because it is difficult to quantify the damages. Damages of the most unusual nature may ensue from a breach of contract but on practical grounds, the law takes the view that a line must be drawn somewhere and that certain kinds of loss, though caused as a direct result of the defendant’s conduct, shall not qualify for compensation. To this end, Hadley v Baxendale defined the kind of damage t h a t is the appropriate subject of compensation and excluded others as being too remote. 25 Ibid, at 994. 13 S.Ac.L.J. Damages for Breach of Contract for Sale of Goods 149 As regards the question of the measure of damages, the principle is that of restitutio in integrum. The plaintiff must be restored to the position he would have been in had that particular damage not occurred but he must not be put in a better position. LEOW CHYE SIAN* * LLB (Sing), LLM (Cantab), Associate Professor, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore.