A WORKING PAPER ON MILITARY-POLITICAL CONDITIONS AND INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC NEGOTIATIONS John S. Odell School of International Relations University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-0043 USA odell@usc.edu written for presentation at the University of Chicago Program in Political Economy Studies 29 May 1997 Please do not quote without the author’s permission. Needs work. Abstract: Present knowledge of the international negotiation process is inadequate both theoretically and empirically. For economic negotiations and possible military influences on them in particular, we need ideas formulated more precisely and consistently, as well as a less cavalier attitude toward the evidence requirements for such claims. Many conjectures have been advanced without much evidence of state leaders’ and negotiators’ beliefs--which are pivotal in many interpretations once they have been formulated carefully--or evidence on any other aspect of the negotiation process, in some cases. We might sharpen and deepen our knowledge by investing in empirical research guided by reformulated hypotheses such as the eight presented here, linking security conditions to the negotiator’s priorities, alternatives to agreement, issue linkage, and ratification. 2 Present knowledge of the international negotiation process is inadequate, both theoretically and empirically. Specifically for economic negotiations and possible military influences on them, we need general ideas formulated more precisely and consistently, as well as a less cavalier attitude toward the evidence requirements for such claims. Many conjectures have been advanced without much evidence particularly of state leaders’ and negotiators’ beliefs, which are pivotal in many hypotheses once they have been formulated carefully. We can deepen and sharpen our knowledge by investing in research on reformulated hypotheses such as the eight presented here. Few would deny that negotiation is one of the most significant processes of international affairs. Recent historical trends seem likely, if anything, to increase reliance on it. The much-noted trend toward opening nation-states to integration with regional and world markets has, among other things, opened states to new forms of friction and conflict as well. Negotiations between governments may today cover more aspects of world society than at any previous time, considering the depth and speed with which their policies penetrate societies today. This same liberalizing trend has by definition constrained governments’ ability to decree economic and political outcomes, and it has increasingly empowered actors other than governments. To the extent that commercial firms, banks, international agencies, and non-governmental organizations concerned with the environment and human rights, for example, make effective decisions over sectors of world society or have influence with governments, all these actors seem destined to be thrown together repeatedly in a multiple, overlapping processes of conflict and negotiation to achieve their objectives. Whatever structures and institutions prevail in future world affairs, negotiation will be central in determining what these structures and institutions mean in practice for states, firms, and people. Yet, to summarize the English-language literature, we do not understand these processes well enough. Although much has been written, knowledge of international negotiation as a process remains inadequate both conceptually and empirically. It remains fragmented, poorly linked to evidence, and possibly flat wrong in some respects.1 This general conclusion also applies specifically to our knowledge about possible connections between military-security conditions and international economic negotiations. These critical arguments and several positive hypotheses suggested for further scrutiny are this paper’s main offerings. It is only an exploration in problem definition and hypothesis generation, in search of honest reactions and advice that might improve a project’s future trajectory. It carves off one slice of a complex phenomenon, leaving its flanks largely undefended in many directions. “Negotiation” and “bargaining” mean a sequence of actions in which two or more parties address demands and offers to each other for the ostensible purposes of reaching an agreement 1 Other scholars are welcome to proceed on the assumption that this process makes no independent difference in the end, instead correlating variables that precede and follow it in the causal chain. This is nothing more than an assumption that has not been proven, however, and it is no more plausible than the opposite assumption, which guides my own research. 3 and changing the behavior of at least one actor from what it would have done otherwise. In some cases the actions include ostensibly unilateral moves that also send signals to other parties, and in some cases the outcome is a tacit settlement rather than an explicit agreement. Bargaining moves are not limited to compromises and concessions; they include threats and manipulation of information as well. The sequence of observed actions constitutes the outward, behavioral manifestation. The inner core of negotiation consists of a process of communicating information, unwittingly as well as deliberately. Each party sends messages or signals and attempts to influence the meanings others attach to them. My attention focuses on this process, these action sequences in particular. The subject is differentiated analytically (though not in practice) from policy making in general, which deserves equal research attention and already enjoys far more. Nor is the concept of bargaining equivalent to either “conflict” or “cooperation.” It does overlap each; in fact it forms the central theoretical bridge between the two. This study is not about all bargaining but only that which is both international and economic. "International" here means that at least one party is a national government or an agency thereof and at least one other party is based outside that country. Excluded here are negotiations in which no party directly enacts government policies for an entire nation. Economic negotiations are those in which parties’ actions refer explicitly to the production, movement or exchange of goods, services, investments, money, or information and their regulation. The parties’ actions often refer to their own and others’ national policies and to international rules designed to affect these transactions. All such episodes share a crucial property that is absent from most armistice, arms-control, or terrorism negotiations: players’ actions are normally sensitive to market conditions and reactions, since influencing markets is a key purpose (at least in a capitalist world). This market-sensitivity is found in many episodes that are diverse otherwise. These episodes are important enough for their own study and have not been viewed together in this light. At the same time, focusing on them need not require us to ignore the military-political context, nor to ignore parallels we may find with military or other bargaining. History supplies abundant examples of international economic negotiations, beginning long before the cold war of course, and many are well-known. An illustrative and unsystematic list could include those that led to the following diverse outcomes: the famous 1860 Cobden-Chevalier trade treaty; the 1936 tripartite exchange rate pact; the 1944 Bretton Woods agreements on monetary, reconstruction, and development issues; the creation of the European Coal and Steel Community; Japan’s restrictions on its own exports of textiles and apparel products to the US and European countries during the 1950s and 1960s; the 1959 deal whereby India and Exxon established a joint petroleum refinery; various GATT trade-liberalizing agreements; pacts associating newly independent African states with the EEC during the 1960s; that between Algeria and France over petroleum trade in 1983; those during the 1980s between international creditors and individual developing countries that rescheduled sovereign debts; between Japan and the US concerning semiconductor trade, 1986; over Canada-US Free Trade, 1988; and the 1993 settlement of the EC-US dispute over oilseeds. 4 Other economic negotiations have ended in impasses: for example, the 1933 London Economic Conference; Mexico and the USA over gas trade 1977; IMF members over a dollar substitution account, 1978-79; Mexico and GATT regarding Mexico’s possible accession 1979-80; and 1980s efforts by debtor countries to form a cartel. A third set of examples might include economic negotiations in process today whose outcomes are not known--such as those between China and the WTO over China’s accession; between the IMF and borrowing countries over credit terms; and between individual firms and states over investments. Note that this definition of “economic” refers to the issues that parties discuss explicitly with each other and not to the subjective goals negotiators might have in their minds. Suppose state A offered state B a trade or financial concession, and suppose one unstated objective was to make B heavily dependent on A in wartime. This would be described as a security objective or reason for carrying out an economic--not a military--negotiation. A particular negotiation could explicitly mix military with commercial or financial issues. Examples might be a negotiation over diplomatic recognition and initial establishment of relations between two states, or one between Panama or the Philippines and the United States in which the issues included military base rights and foreign aid. This study holds such mixed episodes aside in order to concentrate first on those lacking explicit military-political issues.2 Including them from the beginning and then asking whether security conditions make a difference might lead to rather obvious conclusions. It seems more sensible to try first to clarify negotiation over economic issues when the issues are in fact not mixed, as well as purely military bargaining, separately, and then with those refined ideas in hand to ask whether mixed cases require additional special analysis. WEAKNESSES IN PRESENT KNOWLEDGE Our knowledge of international negotiation in general needs improvement both theoretically and empirically. We have many impressive mathematical models of bargaining, and model building is a valuable part of the scientific process. While they might identify the right causal mechanisms, however, we simply do not know in the cases of the many conjectures that have not passed even weak tests on evidence from international history.3 Some of them may be untestable in any case. While such scholarship has its recognized place in our collective project, my own proximate goal is theory that is shown to have empirical validity. One possible way forward toward that goal--in addition to more sophisticated modeling, on which I hope others will make progress--is to divide models into basic components such that at least some elements might be made concrete and even tested. Another is to generate theoretical concepts and 2 Mixed episodes are analyzed in Thompson 1977, Stein 1993, and sources cited below, for example. 3 See Young 1975 for an earlier survey of this issue. Helpful on more recent game theory in economics are Binmore and Dasgupta 1987 and Kennan and Wilson 1993. For rare, welcome exceptions see Suzuki 1994 and, concerning military crisis bargaining, Fearon 1994. 5 relationships from field observation more directly, rather than limiting ourselves to what mathematics can express today. This study moves in both these latter directions.4 Several informal theories developed first in psychology and sociology have also been suggested for international negotiation and many of these are interesting. Again however, only a few causal propositions have been specified and confirmed even weakly with historical evidence from this field.5 Many empirically sophisticated case studies have illuminated particular events and some express theoretical payoffs.6 Despite their achievements, these case studies including my own have failed to accumulate into a consistent body of knowledge, or even into several sub-bodies each internally coherent. They begin from diverse conceptual foundations and most take few specific steps that would encourage cumulation. Some studies of international negotiations propose typologies--of components, stages, and influences upon the process--and show that these concepts can help describe multiple cases in the same language. This work too often stops short of identifying general links between causes and specific effects and conditions under which these relationships hold.7 Political science studies of international economic cooperation conducted during the last decade have generated a new school of analysis and have also achieved much,8 but this literature too suffers from at least two significant limitations. Most research has effectively restricted cooperation to regime studies, while regimes are not the only form of international cooperation. Thus less attention has been given to many bilateral instances of cooperation and possibly the most consequential ones, for both markets and politics. In fact, bilateral bargaining has been a prerequisite for, or a dominant component of, many multilateral agreements. Probably the most consequential international economic regime agreement of the twentieth century, concluded in 1944 at Bretton Woods, was actually negotiated bilaterally by the United Kingdom and the United States to a large extent, outside any international institution, before they invited other parties to join the process.9 Furthermore, beginning with the most complex multilateral negotiations makes it more difficult to isolate central causal relationships empirically. 4 For evidence that such theory might have empirical validity see Odell [ref list] 5 Sample the state of this art in Zartman 1978, Pruitt and Rubin 1986, Thompson 1990, Faure and Rubin 1993, Zartman 1994, and works cited there. 6 E.g., Wriggins 1976, Winham 1986, Haas 1992, Martin 1992, Part II, and Friedheim 1993. Other case studies are largely atheoretical, such as those in Clarke 1973, Cohn 1979, Keeley 1983, and Ravenhill 1979. 7 A good example is Sjöstedt 1993. 8 See critical reviews by Haggard and Simmons 1987 and Milner 1992. 9 Gardner 1956. 6 Second, this IPE school has generally attempted to explain regime formation and change by concentrating on the international power structure--hegemonic and otherwise--and the institutional framework itself, assuming it will govern subsequent interstate bargaining. A given power structure, however, is only the bare beginning of analysis; many different outcomes are consistent with a given structure. International institutions in fact probably have only a small influence on bargaining outcomes, relative to other influences. Little empirical research, at least, has demonstrated otherwise. One of the most popular recent theoretical ideas--that high transaction costs of operating otherwise are what drives states to cooperate via regimes--has yet to be substantiated or defended against alternatives by means of close empirical research. This cooperation school, with a few exceptions,10 effectively assumes that the bargaining process--the parties' strategy choices and the interactions between them--has no significant effects on negotiation outcomes. Consider the most seminal contribution to this school, Robert Keohane's pioneering After Hegemony. Keohane selects the multilateral negotiation of the International Energy Agency in the 1970s as the primary illustration of his theory, which effectively limits cooperation to international institution-building. Its accomplishments notwithstanding, the book itself underlines repeatedly how marginal this agency's practical effects were.11 In contrast, the book does not examine the bilateral bargaining during roughly the same period between Algeria and France, which led eventually to agreement on a higher price and movement of billions of cubic meters of gas as well as improved political relations between the two states.12 Nor does it help us understand why the parallel bilateral gas dispute during the same period between Mexico and the United States damaged that political relationship and yielded an agreement so small as to qualify as largely symbolic. Most important, the book does not report a close enough empirical investigation of the process of negotiating the IEA to show whether the main explanatory variable proposed--the desire to reduce high transaction costs of future bargaining--actually influenced any government's behavior. A full and fair evaluation will need to take account of subsequent studies and critiques, which are still unfolding.13 Institutional studies have taught us much and the tradition is certainly worthy of further investment. But most leave much to be done regarding the negotiation process. What do we know about military-political conditions and beliefs in particular as influences on economic bargaining behavior? Present research literature includes at least four types of publication--studies of decisions made in wartime; studies of peacetime economic sanctions adopted for military-political purposes; theoretical or polemical essays that assert wider 10 E.g., Young [various], Rhodes 1989, and Martin 1992. 11 Keohane 1984, pp. 224-240. 12 Zartman and Bassani 1988. 13 See Finnemore 1993; Haas, Keohane and Levy 1993; Mitchell 1994; Underdal 1992; and Young 1991 as some excellent examples. 7 positive effects in peacetime but fail to cite convincing evidence; and case studies that present copious evidence about peacetime financial and trade negotiations and find little or no effect. The effects of wars and wartime on the basic structure of international politics and on negotiators’ decisions are probably too well known to need further attention here (e.g., Gardner 1956, Gilpin 1981). Economic sanctions studies are also plentiful and well-known (e.g., Knorr 1975; Hufbauer, Schott and Elliott 1985; Baldwin 1985; Martin 1992). That research helps us understand variations in sanctions’ effectiveness when used, but often has not asked why sanctions are used in some situations and not others. [to be developed further] Others have conjectured that military conditions and motives have influenced past peacetime economic negotiations more generally but have not provided convincing evidence. For example, in his influential U.S.Power and the Multinational Corporation, Gilpin (1975, p. 154-55) asserts: In essence, after 1958, a bargain was struck between the three dominant poles of the international economy--the United States, Western Europe, and, to a lesser extent, Japan. Partially for economic reasons, but more importantly for political and strategic ones, Western Europe (primarily West Germany) and Japan agreed to finance the American balance of payments deficit. . . . Thus, after the late 1950s the United States in effect ran its foreign policy largely on credit. The willingness of Europe and, to a lesser extent, of Japan to hold dollars helped make it possible for the United States to maintain its troop commitments in Western Europe and elsewhere around the Soviet and Chinese periphery, to finance foreign aid, and of course to fight the Vietnam War. For its part, the United States, as we have already pointed out, tolerated discrimination against its exports and promoted the creation of the European Economic Community even though the success of the EEC would make it a direct and significant threat to American commercial interests. The only source cited is another broad-brush essay. No evidence is presented for the claim that the most important beliefs or objectives in states holding dollars were political and strategic ones. In fact many of those dollars were held by private European, Japanese and other banks and corporations that needed increasing quantities of dollars for doing international business. As for their governments, surely the chief reason they failed to revalue their currencies after they developed payments surpluses--which would have reduced the US deficit needing financing--was commercial, not military. They did not want to see their goods lose competitiveness at home or abroad. Aggarwal (1985), as another example, contends that the 1950s and 1960s negotiations to create international rules regulating trade in textiles and clothing were nested within a “higher level” international security system, such that states make the former conform with the latter if necessary. Unfortunately the evidence here is no more convincing. “The best evidence of the paramount importance of the bipolar struggle” in the formation of US textile trade policy, says the author (p. 78), is a quotation from a strongly protectionist US senator whose state included a 8 concentration of textile workers. The senator moaned that exporting countries complain about US measures taken to protect his constituents, and that the State Department is concerned about their protests. Protectionist representatives always voice their constituents’ complaints that Washington has done too little; this is hardly convincing as evidence that the Soviet threat or anything else did restrain US textile negotiators. In fact the textile story is one of ever-widening application of exactly this type of restriction, against more and more countries and products--during the cold war and in the face of exporters’ repeated protests. The most thorough case study of any bilateral trade negotiation ever published (Destler, Fukui, and Sato 1979) documents, in fact, that in 1971 President Nixon was willing even to threaten to use the US “Trading with the Enemy Act” to impose economic sanctions on its ally Japan in order to extract a textiles trade concession. Nixon took this remarkable step right in the midst of his strategic nuclear negotiations with the USSR--surely a moment when special restraint for the sake of allied unity would be expected if the security system really was “higher.” The authors of this study emphasize (chapter 13) that “high policy” arguments failed to keep these allied governments from engaging in a long and damaging commercial dispute. A fourth body of scholarship consists of many other thorough case studies of peacetime economic negotiations in which the parties have not acted in response to security conditions or introduced military linkages at all, as far as we know. A detailed book-length account of the GATT’s 1960s Kennedy Round, apart from noting that the parties did not include China and the USSR, makes no references at all to security conditions or linkages affecting the negotiation of this major agreement (Preeg 1970).14 The same silence, apart from peripheral references, prevails in case studies of US trade strategy between 1887 and 1939 (Lake 1988), the 1965 Canada-US automotive trade pact (Keeley), Japan’s bargaining over exchange rates 1969-1971 (Angel 1991), the 1970s New International Economic order bargaining between developing and developed countries (Rothstein 1979), Group of Five monetary negotiations at the Plaza Hotel and the Louvre (1985 through 1987, Funabashi 1988), and the GATT’s Uruguay Round (Hampson with Hart 1995). Most of these studies were written by political scientists, who should notice possible military-political influences sooner than most others, and all these studies resulted from prolonged, deep exposure to empirical evidence. Moreover, many of these negotiations took place during the cold war, and some occurred during hot wars, in fact. If we fail to find such influence then, are we likely to find it when the risk of war is lower? Is this impression of insulation due to oversight or biased selection, or does this research contain clues to valid generalizations (or both)? We do have a sound theoretical reason for expecting insulation in general--for expecting that, contrary to what north Americans hear so often from policy advocates, the two will not generally be “inextricably intertwined.” The notion of using military threats or offers to induce economic concessions, for example, assumes that such military moves would have no important consequences for the security sphere itself--a dubious assumption. Presumably security moves will be constrained substantially by security conditions, goals, and efforts by bureaucracies that embody them. Similarly on the commercial side, the proposal to bend trade or financial concessions or threats to security goals is likely to Friman 1993 (p. 404) argues that President Kennedy “played the security card” in US politics, citing the communist threat as a tactic for generating support for passage of the enabling US legislation in 1962. Preeg makes a passing reference to this domestic tactic, pp. 46-47. 14 9 meet at least some opposition from the producers, lenders and investors who would pay the price, except when the commercial moves or opportunities are insignificant economically or when these constituents believe war is imminent. (This opposition may be weaker or have less effect, though, in authoritarian polities than in democracies.) CENTRAL QUESTIONS, ASSUMPTIONS, AND CONCEPTS To summarize, what is lacking most today is theoretically-framed, comparative empirical research outside the laboratory on the international negotiation process. This paper and a planned book15 are steps in that direction. They assume that a simplified framework or theory can improve both research and actual decision-making on these complex events, and that the same framework can be useful in many countries. One central question for any comprehensive theory is what shapes negotiations’ outcomes, in the sense of the value of the agreement or settlement for each party and for the set of parties. In particular, do governments gain more or lose less in some episodes than in others, and if so, why? Why do economic disputes and negotiations turn out as they do, and by extension, can parties do better? This central question can be approached best by dividing it into several component questions. This theory concentrates on the negotiation process, rather than concentrating on the international power structure or international institutions that may be present. It begins with individuals making decisions using bounded rationality. It assumes the individual brings a set of policy values and beliefs to the current situation but lacks perfect information. The theory is partly subjective in that it assumes that information regarded as objectively valid by the observer will be relevant only to the extent that it influences the subjective beliefs of the negotiating parties. An appendix provides responses to some common academic concerns about subjective theories. This theory does not assume that individuals will necessarily strive to maximize benefits fully relative to costs. Instead the individual is assumed most likely to choose the course of action that offers the greatest subjective probability of achieving the values that seem most salient at the time. Many negotiators choose strategies at the beginning of the process, strategies that often do not specify exactly how the party will act in all conceivable future contingencies. Furthermore, the individuals of interest to us are situated in institutions, which are likely to influence both the selection of incumbents in the first place, their negotiating objectives in a given instance, and how they frame and react to information arriving during the episode. The objectives on their minds need not be limited to issues under negotiation; for example, the negotiator’s own relative political influence at home may be effectively engaged as a limiting value or explicit goal. While simplifying reality is one of any theory’s purposes, for me 15 My book in progress (progress measured on the glacial scale) is tentatively entitled Washington and the World Economy: A Theory of International Economic Negotiation. My thinking builds espeically on Walton and McKersie 1965, Raiffa 1982, Lax and Sebenius 1986, and Walton, et al 1994, among others. 10 simplicity or parsimony does not have higher priority than empirical validity. (Making precise, accurate forecasts is not a realistic aspiration for any bargaining theory today.) Given these assumptions, then, let us consider using the following conceptual building blocks, which have proven useful in interpreting the process and in conducting actual negotiations: party: an entity engaged in a negotiation, one whose actions are recognized by other entities as part of the process in question; objectives and weights: values or states of the world the negotiator wishes to achieve or preserve by means of negotiation; if more than one concern is engaged, the weights attached to each value. If weights were precise, they would sum to one hundred percent by definition. In practice they are only approximate; the concept represents any sense of priority attached to multiple objectives. Values need not be limited to those normally expressed in money terms; they may include human rights, environmental conservation, and national security. To substitute the concept “interests” for “objectives” would endow the notion with a veneer of objectivity that may or may not be valid. Rather than assuming that certain “real world” conditions will necessarily create corresponding subjective negotiating goals in leaders’ minds, we will get closer to empirically valid theory by making such assumptions explicit as hypotheses to be investigated. That way, both author and reader will find it more difficult to escape the need to seek at least indirect evidence for the subjective beliefs and weights. Thinking this way rather than in terms of “interests” also probably will save practical negotiators from inaccurate speculations by focusing them on variables that really will determine their immediate results--the subjective goals and perceptions on the other side of the table. policy belief: a proposition in the minds of a negotiator representing connections she believes obtain or will obtain between actions and reactions, or between fixed underlying conditions and the process or its outcome, or between actions and goals; issue: an agenda item or discrete matter on which parties speak or otherwise act and which constitutes an element of their requests, demands or offers; best alternative or “batna: a party’s best alternative to an agreement with the other parties in this negotiation; a course of action that, in the case of impasse, would be the best alternative to follow, as judged by the deciding party itself; resistance point (or reservation value): the value of the worst potential deal a party will accept, or the value beyond which the party would prefer no agreement in this negotiation; for a buyer, the maximum price it will pay, for a seller, its minimum; strategy: a set of actions seen as a related set and intended to advance a party toward its objectives through negotiation; (tactics: individual actions that constitute a strategy); 11 outcome: an explicit agreement between the parties covering the issues, or a de facto pattern of behavior that approximates terms of an agreement and persists for some time. A party is assumed to attach some value, positive or negative, to actual and potential outcomes. Market consequences that may flow from an official settlement are something else again, not part of the outcome in this sense. Government behavior is important enough to merit concentrated research all its own, in addition to research on markets’ behavior (“results” in American business parlance). ratification: a party’s internal decision whether to give formal effect to an agreement negotiated by an agent. This decision process, while often institutionalized, may be informal in some instances. This paper, reflecting my own research as well as the cited case studies, assumes that much of what is relevant for the present questions at least during peacetime is found elsewhere--in the markets, domestic politics, and international institutions concerned with commercial and financial issues.16 This particular working paper imagines these conditions “held constant” in order to investigate possible effects of international military-political or security conditions alone. The most basic such conditions are (a) war and defeat or victory in war; (b) in peacetime, the country’s place in the world distribution of military and general power capabilities or of war threats, and changes in these military capabilities and threats; and (c) whether the negotiating parties are also members of the same alliance (or a more limited military relationship), members of opposing alliances, or neither. This particular paper will leave aside bargaining between parties that are at war either with each other or against third parties, as well as the direct consequences of war--preferring to go beyond the relatively obvious. Surely no one would claim that World War II had nothing to do with the Bretton Woods negotiations.17 This paper does attempt to identify more precisely some of the circumstances and channels of entry through which other security conditions might enter the economic negotiating process in peacetime. (Feel free to try this yourself at home.) SOME HYPOTHESES Priorities among objectives One possible channel would be through the setting of the negotiators’ objectives. Looking back, analysts sometimes try to interpret negotiations by referring to objectives or motives. Inoguchi, for example, writes of the US demand for what became the 1986 Japan-US agreement on semiconductor trade: “It is a manifestation of deep US concerns about national 16 Possibilities neglected here are explored in Odell 1980, Odell 1985, Odell 1993, other studies in Evans et al. 1993, Odell 1995a and Odell 1995b, as well as in other works cited. Specifically the Pearl Harbor attack in fact may have triggered Treasury Secretary Henry Morgenthau’s instructions to his aide, Harry White, to begin drafting the plan that later led to the IMF, and more generally the second world war destroyed the US public’s respect for the doctrine of security by isolation--which seems to have played a role earlier in blocking US concessions on war debts, which in turn stymied earlier proposals to negotiate joint reflation and exchange rate stabilization. Odell 1988. 17 12 security, since semi-conductors are widely used in high precision, high performance weapons as well as in civilian applications.”18 Unfortunately this author supplies no evidence of any kind for this claim. What critics of actual negotiations often seem to want, even though they may not put it this way, is a change in the objectives or priorities that principals assign to their negotiators, rather than changes in how negotiating agents operate to achieve the assigned goals. Richer importing countries are chastised for demanding that poorer countries agree to limit their exports of light manufactured products, on the grounds that the importing country as a whole would be better off to enjoy the less expensive products and have money left over. Many political leaders nevertheless have directed many negotiators to achieve agreements to restrain certain imports in order to satisfy a minority of their constituents. This criticism is concerned less with how negotiators should behave once their objectives are set than with those objectives themselves. Should political leaders direct trade negotiators to aim for the greatest possible average national economic welfare, or re-election of the incumbent political party, or favorable attitudes in exporting countries, or some mixture? To take another example, in 1990 the US Congress debated the Bush Administration’s agreement with Japan to produce a military fighter aircraft jointly (a case of mixed issues). US critics complained that the President should have demanded that Japan import a purely American product instead, and thereby reduce Japan’s trade surplus with the US. Advocates responded that if Congress killed the agreement, Japan would refuse the US product and instead build its own new plane by itself, which would reduce US influence on Japanese armed forces and damage attitudes in each country toward the other.19 This debate reflected disagreement over priorities among objectives that were themselves accepted by all: how much weight US negotiators should assign to trade deficit reduction and maintaining this security relationship, to the extent that the two were rivals. In this case participants seemed to differ as well about whether the two were in fact in conflict--about what would actually happen if the US negotiator held firm in demanding that Japan’s military forces buy the off-the-shelf US plane. As a third example, today the United States debates annually whether it should maintain high tariffs against Chinese goods or grant them the much lower tariffs given to GATT members (without reciprocal Chinese trade concessions like those GATT members have made to the US). Some argue that conditioning tariff reductions on improved political rights in China would help improve those rights, while others insist this move would disadvantage US businesses in international competition and perhaps even worsen Chinese political rights by slowing the spread of capitalism in Chinese society. This debate too is partly about weights to be assigned to economic, moral, and relationship objectives in making trade policy, though it probably also reflects some disagreement about exactly what would happen if the US raised tariffs back to their pre-1979 levels. The emphasis in this study falls chiefly on the process that follows after negotiation objectives have been set initially. Setting goals is central to all policy, foreign and domestic, and 18 19 T. Inoguchi 1991, 82. Spar 1992; Ortmayer. 1992. The U.S.-Japanese FSX Fighter Agreement. Pew Case Study 350, Part A. 13 the totality of all policy making is far more than this study can hope to analyze seriously. Yet three basic ideas about priorities may help at least limit the probability distribution of a party’s future moves, and thus lead us on to other hypotheses. These ideas assume that parties will always have multiple objectives and that at least some times, increasing weight on one will be not be possible without sacrificing some of another. First, while a state is fighting in a war, its agents will increase sharply the weight placed on military-political objectives in economic negotiations with all other states and with companies. Thus offers of military assistance and threats to withhold it, for instance, probably will have substantially greater ceteris paribus effects on that negotiator’s moves than they would in peacetime. Second, the weaker the state militarily, the greater the weight its negotiator probably will place on security on average. That is, the weaker the state, the more will it sacrifice commercial for military value if there is no way to have both, other things equal. (Presumably this implies that the weakest states will regularly place greater weight on security than on economic goals when they must choose.) One reason is the principle of diminishing marginal returns. A given increment to security will be worth more to a highly vulnerable state than to the state that is already least likely to be conquered. Thus the strong power will not be willing to sacrifice other goals to the same extent to achieve that increment; it will place greater weight (than the weaker state) on achieving commercial gains when they are in conflict. Suppose strength is defined objectively first, say by a combination of actual military forces and (in the twentieth century) total industrial output, or better, by the relation between the state’s capabilities and those of its neighbors or the world as a whole. If this idea is valid, we should find that negotiators for China in the 1890s, when facing a dilemma, traded economic for security value more often or to a greater degree than did the UK. Also we should find that when a state rises dramatically in the local or world military power hierarchy over decades, its effective priorities shift away from military goals on average, while a large secular drop should produce the opposite shift. Will smaller differences in this relatively-constant “variable” also have effects that are significant in the big picture? Will major powers that are, say at one point in time, unequal but closer in military capacity also tend to assign systematically different weights? Next year will Indonesia, for example, place greater weight on military security relative to commercial advancement than China? Will China give up more commercial gain for military gain on average, when forced to choose, than Japan or Germany? Will Japan or German priorities differ predictably from those of the USA? On the one hand, yes--if marginal returns diminish, the security returns from such a trade-off should likewise be worth more to the somewhat weaker power than to the somewhat stronger, at least somewhat more so. Yet recalling that other things that are “held constant” here also strongly influence financial and trade behavior in peacetime, variations in these missing causes -- such as a trade balance shifting from surplus to deficit in one or two years -- might override this gradually-changing one when economic diplomats set priorities next year. At this time we lack sufficient evidence collected consistently from many cases to support any sound general answer to these questions. 14 Holsti (1986) proposes an idea that is related here. In the case of a weaker state tied to a dominant partner for security, the more the dependent increases its partner’s trust that the dependent’s security policy will remain loyal, the less will the partner demand that it sacrifice material goals to demonstrate its reliability. Even if relative capabilities remain highly unequal, Holsti suggests, varying trust on the partner’s part, reflecting recent experience, can ease or worsen the dilemma that forces the weaker state to choose among its goals. He cites the increasing latitude the Soviet Union allowed Finland after the 1950s, after the Soviets saw that increased Finnish trade with the West did not come at the expense of Soviet security or commercial goals. Third, if a country’s national political institutions (including political parties) systematically afford special influence to domestic groups that weight military objectives heavily, then that state will probably trade off commercial for military gains more than average when facing a dilemma, other things equal. Suppose, for example, that any government dominated by military officers will weight national military objectives more heavily than average. Then we should find that a regime change in a country should be followed by evidence of change in the subjective weights officials assign to these objectives, as well as differences between military and civilian governments in different countries that rank similarly on the economic issues at stake. Conversely, if national political institutions give special influence to groups that weight their own commercial gain strongly over national security objectives in negotiations on certain sectors, then political leaders and negotiating agents will reflect this ordering and will be willing to sacrifice the latter for commercial gain more than average when those issues are on the table. [add example] Many other things will also shape foreign policy objectives, and we must leave the rest of that large subject for others. From here forward, let us assume that the negotiating party’s objectives and priorities will be set at the outset of the process and that military security will not necessarily be ruled out, at least as a constraint on what can be accepted. Alternatives to agreement, resistance points, and distributive tactics A central proposition of negotiation theory holds that the better an alternative to agreement a seller perceives, the higher will be its bargaining resistance point and vice versa, other things equal. The better the offer a seller hears from a third party, the higher a price will it demand of the party across the table for the same item, and the worse the seller’s alternative, the lower a price will it accept. If the buyer insists on paying less than the seller’s current reservation price, the seller will prefer no deal in that bilateral negotiation. In multi-issue negotiations, a party may have separate resistance points on different issues. Typically negotiators try to keep their true reservation values secret. Figure 1 is a highly simplified depiction of resistance points in a negotiation with two parties and one issue. Points in this space represent possible outcomes and the axes measure the value of each outcome for parties A and B. Suppose the dotted vertical line at value 2 represents A’s resistance point. If B offered a deal worth less, A would prefer to reject that deal because A 15 has an alternative worth more than 2, whatever that means. All points to the right of that line represent outcomes that would make A better off than it would be in the absence of agreement with B. The horizontal dotted line at the value 10 represents B’s resistance point. Curve P is the outer limit of deals that are technically possible. In this illustration the two parties enjoy a positive zone of agreement, a set of 16 17 points at any one of which a negotiated agreement would create value for one or both parties without making either worse off. Point M is in that zone. Brazil (call it party A) participated in negotiations during the 1960s and 1970s concerning an official agreement to limit fluctuations of international coffee prices. As the leading exporter, Brazil’s alternatives to agreement with importing countries included letting the international market set the price freely, and Brasilia began seeking this agreement when prices were falling. Point M might stand for the agreement that made both Brazil and importing countries (party B) better off in 1962, when they signed the International Coffee Agreement. Market prices rose during the late 1960s, improving Brazil’s alternative to this official scheme. Now by selling to the international market it could get a better price than before. In Figure 1, let the vertical line marked 5 stand for the new Brazilian resistance point. As a result, in International Coffee Agreement negotiations over an extension of the scheme, Brazil raised its terms for agreement. In that situation, importing countries resisted and the parties deadlocked on this central issue. They completed the negotiation in 1971 with only a shell of an agreement omitting any effective ceiling-price mechanism at all.20 Seen in our diagram, Brazil’s shift to the right demanded terms that would have been worth less to its partners than their own reservation value, given the possibility curve, and so they declined. Military conditions, economic alternatives Now one channel through which the military security situation might affect a state’s economic bargaining is through an intervening variable, by first affecting the state’s market alternative to agreement. That is, the more military-political conditions worsen a state’s aggregate or sectoral market alternative to a negotiated agreement, the more its negotiator will probably ease its resistance point in those negotiations, other things equal, and the more the military situation improves its market, the more it will raise its minimum demands. Since true resistance points are difficult to observe, a derived proposition would be more usable--one relating the security situation to the negotiator’s economic bargaining tactics. The more the military-political situation worsens the market alternative to agreement, the more the state will probably soften its distributive tactics in economic bargaining, and vice versa. Concretely this change in tactics entails offering to or actually loosening any economic sanctions in place, reducing threats and demands, increasing or accelerating proposals and concessions, and taking steps to increase the credibility of promises. These terms could be defined operationally. As an illustration of this indirect effect consider West Germany in 1978 as party A and consider its aggregate balance of payments as the relevant market condition. At that time Germany was in surplus and was accumulating more dollars that it preferred. Along with other surplus countries German leaders began negotiations in the International Monetary Fund to create a dollar “substitution account,” an account at the Fund that would accept dollars in exchange for SDRs, the Fund’s money. The US resisted some features of the proposal and at the end of 1978 agreement had not been reached. This was the moment when the Khomeini revolution 20 TBA 18 overthrew the Shah of Iran, driving world oil prices up immediately. Rather quickly Germany’s and Japan’s payments surpluses disappeared. Thanks to the unpredicted military-political event in Iran, their excess dollar problem also disappeared (Gowa 1984). That revolution ironically improved the monetary status quo relative to the proposed substitution account, whose supporters then suddenly abandoned the negotiations to create it Military alternatives, potential allies Next suppose that state A, when valuing its alternative courses of action in the absence of an economic agreement with B next year, will factor in its own international military-political situation directly as one dimension of the no-deal scenario (given the assumption that even the strongest state gives some weight to security goals in economic bargaining). This broader conception of state alternatives is of course a defining distinction between states and all other parties to economic negotiations. Then the greater the risk of war or loss of influence relative to potential enemies that A’s leaders perceive, all else equal, the more A’s negotiator probably will ease its distributive tactics during economic bargaining with a potential or actual ally, as a means of cementing a relationship that could be needed for security. Conversely an improvement in A’s perception of security should lead it to harden its terms and distributive tactics with an ally. This effect might not appear, however, as long as the perception of military political danger is low, say below its long-term average. Benjamin Rowland’s interpretation of changes in Britain’s monetary bargaining behavior during 1935 and 1936 illustrates this proposition. London and Washington had taken their currencies off gold in 1931 and 1933 respectively, and the two governments were competing via efforts to push the bilateral exchange rate in opposite directions. Any thoughts of halting this conflict by agreement had been frustrated by grievances and distrust on each side. Paris continued to defend the gold franc, but its weak payments position was making this effort increasingly difficult to bring off. In 1935 a French currency crisis prompted US Treasury Secretary Henry Morgenthau to suggest to Britain that the UK and the US create limited joint gain by agreement. The two would engage France in a three-way agreement whereby London and Washington would agree to stabilize their currencies if France would agree to an acceptable limit to its devaluation, which was seeming inevitable. According to Rowland, Britain’s Ambassador in Washington did not see this proposal as acceptable on economic grounds. Then in March 1936 Hitler moved into the Rhineland and currency markets renewed their flight from the franc. Eagerness to take a strong stand against the Germans and fear that an economic crisis might drive France to embrace fascism were two potent political reasons which now joined Morgenthau’s economic calculations. After discussing the matter with Roosevelt, Morgenthau sent a message to [Chancellor of the Exchequer Neville] Chamberlain through a British intermediary. To his surprise, Chamberlain expressed himself in complete agreement. In Britain too, the overriding motive for stabilization was concern over the deteriorating political situation. But concern over the fate of France was joined by a general wariness at giving offense to the United States, since it was now clear that Britain would be dependent on the United States in the event of war. The decision to cooperate was not one that Britain reached with any great enthusiasm. It sprang, instead, 19 from a failure of alternatives. Britain had explored and would continue to explore diplomatic options by which she might contain Germany and Japan without the aid of the United States, but the Stresa Front Strategy . . . grew less and less plausible. . . . The imperial economic system . . . was itself increasingly faction-ridden (Rowland 1976, 209). Rowland’s conclusion expressed in present terms is that these events, by worsening Britain’s alternatives to agreement with Washington, defined broadly, led London to lower its resistance point for a monetary agreement slightly, to the limited actual commitment to stabilize currencies one day at a time (in Figure 1 say from 5 to 2). The result was the modest tripartite monetary pact of 1936. After its alternatives had deteriorated, London believed M offered a gain when the same agreement had meant a loss the previous year. Rowland does not describe the parties’ tactics in any detail. Unfortunately Rowland also fails to provide any evidence whatsoever for this interesting conjecture that British security beliefs influenced their monetary decision. The evidence presented does not rule out the possibility that Britain would have agreed to this modest monetary cooperation in 1936 for the economic reasons alone, even if the security move had not taken place. The Atlantic monetary conflict was proving fruitless economically, especially considering the lasting size disparity between the UK and US economies, and letting France devalue unilaterally could have hurt British producers more. Rowland concedes that these economic reasons were sufficient for Morgenthau to propose the pact in the first place. The recent collapse of the Warsaw Pact and even the USSR as a state --hardly a minor change in security for Japan and the West--failed to cause anti-Soviet allies to break off economic negotiations with each other. Indeed, Canada and the US created a new free trade area, the European Community adopted the union treaty and pledged to create a single common currency, and the Uruguay round finally produced the largest negotiated package of trade liberalization in history--after the cold war was over. Did these allies nonetheless raise their resistance points in these negotiations for this security reason and run greater risks of impasse than they would have done during the cold war? Or do states in general respond less to improving than to worsening prospects of the same magnitude? Or is this security hypothesis regarding allies simply invalid on average? Will the “partial regression coefficient,” when other things are factored in, prove insignificant? This hypothesis also implies that at a given time, A will use softer claiming tactics in a financial or commercial negotiation with an ally than with a neutral state on average, when the issues and all other conditions are the same. Relevant evidence might include, for example, whether the US did or did not agree to more favorable terms in textile negotiations with Japan and Korea than with India or Argentina on average during, say, 1965 to 1985, after correcting as much as possible for differences in economic and other likely influences. Similar tests using other parties could be imagined. Another corollary might be that at a given time, credible threats of economic sanctions conditioned on economic concessions coming from a more powerful ally will worsen A’s 20 perceived alternative to agreement, so that A probably will soften its claiming tactics slightly and slowly until the ally settles. If A were not allied to C for military security, its negotiators would probably yield less in commercial concessions. One thinks of Japan’s responses to US threats and actual sanctions regarding the yen in 1971, semiconductors in 1985-90, and autos in 1993-95. As an aside, however, this case also calls to mind the cautionary theoretical idea that the negotiation process itself can change a negotiator’s priorities (Iklé and Leites 1962), perhaps even among allies. A will probably react in the opposite direction to the extent that C’s use of hard tactics raises the subjective weight A’s negotiator places on his pride in and reputation for “saying no.” Military alternatives, potential enemies Looking at the other side of this balance-of-power coin would imply that if A perceives greater and serious military-political hostility from country C next year and other things are constant, A will probably harden its distributive tactics in economic negotiations with C, as a warning of worse measures to come and in order to limit A’s contributions to C’s economic strength. Urban (1983) reports that interwar Poland and Germany engaged in a tariff war from 1925 until November 1935, when they signed a trade treaty formally ending it. Yet trade volume did not actually recover. He reports that because Nazi Germany had begun rearming earlier that year, Polish leaders grew increasingly sensitive to the concern that greater trade with Germany would enlarge its preponderance. Hitler was sending warm signals toward his southeast but not toward Poland. Warsaw signed a loan agreement with France in 1936 and shifted its economic orientation, according to Urban, for security reasons.21 Here too the documentation of security objectives is thin. As a more extreme illustration one thinks even more readily of the US and other economic sanctions imposed against the Soviet Union and China beginning in the late 1940s and early 1950s, part of which was wartime in Korea. Issue linkage Nearly every international negotiation links different issues into a conditional package--all except those rare few that are confined to a single issue. Here the question is not when will parties link issues but when will they link economic issues to military ones? When will a party condition its agreement to an economic deal on a military-political concession by another or vice versa? (For this paper, let us jump over consideration of any issue that is both military and commercial by definition, such as weapons sales, where linkage therefore occurs by definition, in order to concentrate on the less obvious.) Earlier a general theoretical reason for expecting delinkage was introduced. Under what conditions might exceptions be made? It might seem that such linkages will be more likely within an alliance than between neutrals or enemies, because the military guarantee gives a stronger allied partner special influence over weaker ones committed to relying on it. That is, 21 Urban 1983. The last point about France is only an afterthought in this source,. 21 within an alliance, will a stronger state A probably threaten to degrade its military support unless it gets greater concessions on economic issues, the weaker the partner state B? Or is the opposite perhaps closer to the truth? Will an alliance tie adopted for security purposes constrain A as well as B even when A is stronger, so that A would be more like to link military threats and economic concessions when bargaining with weaker neutrals than with weaker allies? Empirical research could investigate some carefully selected cases for comparison. On a different tack one might imagine that state A’s negotiators will be tempted to bluff at least sometimes, underestimating their counterparts’ analytical skill or information.22 On this reasoning, A will try to convince B that A will withhold a military value unless B makes a commercial concession when A actually will not implement the threat because of its own security plans. Consider a conjecture concerning monetary negotiations between the Federal Republic of Germany and the US in 1966 and 1967. Bergsten (1975, 31-32) argues that the most important postwar step in insulating the United States from external pressure on its [gold] reserves was the explicit pledge by Germany--the most persistent [balance of payments] surplus country in the world--not to use any of its dollars to buy US gold, which was an implicit quid pro quo negotiated in 1967 for the maintenance of unchanged American troop levels in Germany. Some smaller countries, such as Korea and Taiwan, have adopted similarly (if not such explicitly) “cooperative” international monetary policies. One has to wonder why A’s own security environments and policies would not place tight limits on its willingness to carry out such a threat, inside or outside an alliance. If having US troops in Germany was valuable to the Pentagon and State Department for military-political reasons, was such a threat really credible? Granted, some members of Congress were airing the idea of pulling back troops for financial reasons, but would the Johnson administration not have fought this effort just vigorously in the absence of a German gold pledge? Did German leaders issue their gold letter for military security reasons? Did they really believe this threat? Unfortunately Bergsten, like Gilpin, stops with only assertions lacking convincing supportive evidence. We do have detailed evidence about a subsequent military-economic linkage or attempted linkage in Japan-US negotiations, but the evidence suggests this was a bluff that failed. After the occupation ended in general, the US continued its occupation of Okinawa and the other Ryukyu Islands in particular, and the Japanese people objected almost continually. The US stored nuclear weapons on Okinawa and used the island as a staging area for possible fighting against China in defense of Taiwan and actual fighting in Vietnam. Resentment in the mass public burst out into periodic demonstrations that even became violent on occasion, including the famous 1960 crisis that forced President Eisenhower to cancel his state visit. The bilateral security treaty adopted then, over these protests, was due to expire in 1970 without further negotiations, which would provide a perfect opportunity for renewed demonstrations. Late 1960s protests were even larger than those in 1960. In early 1969, the national security adviser to the new US President judged, according to his memoirs, that the US needed to make a 22 Odell 1997 provides a theoretical basis for this reasoning drawn from social psychology. 22 concession on Okinawa for national security reasons, and the issue was urgent. In November 1968 Okinawa voters in their first direct election chose a Socialist as their chief executive, and he announced immediately that he would begin to study closing the US bases gradually and returning the islands to full Japanese administration. Kissinger in March 1969 sent a memo to Nixon, supporting views shared in the State Department and the Joint Chiefs of Staff, that “our refusal to negotiate an accommodation could well lead as a practical matter to our losing the bases altogether” (Kissinger 1979, 327). First, however, Nixon meant to press Tokyo to extract a commitment to greater Japanese military spending (Buckley 1992, 122). Meanwhile Nixon was also negotiating for Japanese concessions on textile trade. In November 1969 Nixon opened a Washington summit meeting with Prime Minister Sato by telling Sato what he badly wanted to hear: that the US would finally return Okinawa to Japanese civilian administration and free of nuclear weapons in 1972 (Destler, Fukui and Sato 1979, 136). Reportedly Nixon understood Sato to agree to match this concession with Japanese concessions on textiles. Sato and his emissaries also spent time with US officials discussing the terms of a textile agreement. Upon his return, however, Sato failed to bring about Japanese implementation of this plan, and the negotiations dragged on for nearly two more years, finally ending with the “Trading with the Enemy” threat. It seems fairly clear that Nixon was attempting to get something (textiles) that he wanted (for domestic political objectives) in return for his Okinawa concession, even though the administration was going to do it anyhow for military-political reasons alone. If this is an instance of peacetime military-economic linkage, it was probably a bluff on the US side and was not reciprocated on the Japanese side. It does not seem to be strong evidence contrary to the theoretical expectation of general insulation. One of Washington’s other textile agreements of that period did include a form of true and effective linkage but not a military one. Korea and Taiwan also resisted US pressure stoutly and continuously until well into 1971. At the end of the day, when Korea saw its own no-deal alternative deteriorate when Japan’s did, Seoul also yielded but Korea alone managed to extract partial compensation. The US provided a loan and food aid beyond what was otherwise scheduled, in amounts keyed to Korea’s losses from the trade agreement (Odell 1985). Korea’s negotiators also always took American textile negotiators to visit the DMZ in person, in an attempt to convince them to exempt Korea entirely, but with little apparent effect. Ratification with a security card Finally, after a negotiation has been completed, the international deal often must clear a further hurdle in each national capital. At that stage if not before, policy advocates seeking support sometimes “play the security card.” They advance an argument that their financial or trade negotiating strategy or agreement will further their country’s security interests, or that rejection will damage those interests or relationships needed for military-political reasons. This argument is designed to cause fellow citizens to re-frame the debate in their minds from a purely commercial question to a different one. The argument introduces a new reference point for evaluating alternative courses of action--the country’s military-political objectives or “interests”--and urges the listener to attach a substantial weight to those objectives when making the decision. The speaker sometimes evokes emotions connected with patriotism. One might 23 investigate the hypothesis that when this argument is made, more constituents are likely to endorse the agreement and it is more likely to be ratified, other things equal. The locus classicus is US President Truman’s campaign to secure the support of a skeptical Congress and country for his massive Marshall Plan of foreign aid for western Europe in 1947-48 by “scaring the hell out of the country.” Less noticed, by the way, is the fact the Truman’s and Marshall’s decision to give priority to this effort came at the expense of a major political campaign to ratify the International Trade Organization charter. The ITO was intended to be the commercial counterpart of the Bretton Woods institutions and the United Nations. A large-scale ratification campaign had turned the tide against the Bretton Woods Agreements Act in the spring of 1945 (Odell 1988). The US had also initiated the ITO proposal, led those negotiations, and initialed the agreement in March 1948, but Washington abandoned it in 1950 (Odell and Eichengreen 1997). Many times US critics of hard economic bargaining with Japan and Korea have played this rhetorical card in internal politics. It is they who are often heard crying that economics and security are inextricably intertwined. Japanese and Korean advocates of concessions to such harsh tactics, or concessions to forestall US use of them, have been heard making similar pleas to their own fellow citizens. But we have done little careful research on this tactic, showing either when it is most likely to appear or when it is more and less effective.23 IN LIEU OF CONCLUSIONS How much do we know about the influence of military-political conditions on the international economic negotiation process? We know a fair amount about economic sanctions for political purposes. Additionally it is almost certainly true that wartime conditions bias economic negotiations toward military objectives, and that bargaining over any issue that is both commercial and military by definition will also reflect both sorts of influence. But beyond these important but special conditions, we don’t know much--if “knowing” means having specified the channels through which our claims enter the negotiation process, having direct or indirect evidence for these beliefs, and having ruled out prominent alternative interpretations. How hard have we tried, specifically? Not very. We have more assertions than documented conclusions, and assertions, however interesting, are notoriously sensitive to authors’ preconceptions. Can we collectively do better, via well-focused research efforts? This is only a working paper intended to elicit reactions, negative as well as positive, that might improve a continuing project’s future trajectory. Do some of these candidate ideas seem wrong or too obvious to merit investment? Would you introduce different ideas to answer the same questions, or ask different questions? What about a recursive model with reciprocal causation? Do you think careful empirical research will show any such hypothesis to be significant in general? How could one test or explore any of these relationships empirically? Thank you for any advice you may wish to give. 23 Walton and McKersie 1965, pp. 118-19, 317-19 and Friman 1993 are exceptions. 24 Here is a summary of the hypotheses discussed: 1. OBJECTIVES. Wartime: While a state is fighting in a war, its agents will increase sharply the weight placed on military-political objectives in economic negotiations with all other states and with companies and vice versa, all else equal. 2. Capabilities: In peacetime as well as wartime, the weaker the state militarily, the greater the weight its negotiator probably will place on security on average, all else equal. 3. Institutions: If a country’s national political institutions (including political parties) systematically afford special influence to domestic groups that weight military objectives heavily, then that state will probably trade off commercial for military gains more than average when facing a dilemma and vice versa, other things equal. 4. ALTERNATIVES AND DISTRIBUTIVE TACTICS: Markets: The more the military-political situation worsens the market alternative to agreement, the more the state will probably soften its distributive tactics in economic bargaining and vice versa. 5. Allies. As the subjective sense of military risk or loss increases, the state will probably soften its distributive tactics in economic bargaining with potential allies and vice versa. 6. Enemies. If A perceives greater and serious military-political hostility from country C and other things are constant, A will probably harden its distributive tactics in economic negotiations with C, as a warning of worse measures to come and to limit its contributions to C’s economic strength, and vice versa. 7. ISSUE LINKAGES Are military-economic linkages more likely or less likely within an alliance than between neutrals or enemies? 8. RATIFICATION When the “security card” argument is made, more constituents are likely to endorse the agreement and is it more likely to be ratified, other things equal. APPENDIX A partly-subjective theory sometimes stimulates questions such as how can we ever get evidence adequate for identifying what negotiators truly believe? What can be done if little or no direct evidence is available? And how can such a theory avoid becoming so complex and particular as to lose its claim to be theory? First and most important, if we believe negotiators’ subjective values and beliefs truly are part of the causal chain, then our best theory should represent what we think as accurately as possible without regard to anticipated empirical problems. Why would it be better to substitute other concepts in our very theory and thus lead 25 ourselves in the wrong direction? While omitting subjective concepts may seem a convenient way to draw attention away from the need to gather evidence for them, such thinking is woefully short-sighted. Doing so reduces our theories’ value for guiding our research, and practice for that matter. The widespread academic habit of sweeping this problem under the rug is one reason why so few practitioners use political science theories. Second, we should seek the best evidence we can get about beliefs, and the weaker the evidence the more skeptical we should be, exactly as with any other claim. No inference from evidence in social science is ever perfectly complete or beyond question, however. There is no immaculate perception. Every claim ever made--no matter how detailed the operational definitions, how large the sample size, how many variables in the regression--has failed to escape some uncertainty, some valid qualifications. All empirical methods are flawed; these are matters of degree.24 Evidence limited to published statements by a political negotiator is less complete and convincing than evidence that includes this information but also interviews separately with others who were present in private with the individual while decisions were being made, and so on. Third, if no relatively direct evidence of parties’ beliefs is available, one approximation, for the negotiator and the more distant researcher alike, is to use proxies. As an example, one analyst might assume that a political leader values her country’s trade balance in direct proportion, so that a movement in the positive direction is better and the opposite movement is worse. This analyst might take movements in that trade balance as a proxy for the weight the negotiator will place on a negotiation and on increasing exports as an objective. Naturally this is even less convincing evidence of policy beliefs than published statements alone and conclusions should be so qualified. But I believe even this type of result, if it is designed explicitly to address a subjective theory, will help move us collectively toward empirically valid theory faster over the long term than will research that misstates the theory in the first place and then tries to test the wrong idea or defend it to the death. Fourth, of course no theory is worthy of the label if it becomes infinitely complex. The solution must lie in decisions, at every step of the intellectual process, both to strain to discover or create overarching ideas and to weigh whether adding a new distinction will help more than it will sacrifice. I do not know of any general rule for making such marginal decisions, nor should we expect all readers ever to agree on how much parsimony is enough. Join in the fun. REFERENCES Aggarwal, Vinod. 1985. Liberal Protectionism: The International Politics of Organized Textile Trade. Berkeley: University of California Press. Angel, Robert C. 1991. Explaining Economic Policy Failure: Japan in the 1969-1971 International Monetary Crisis. New York: Columbia University Press. 24 See Kaplan 1964. 26 Binmore, K., and P. Dasgupta, eds., 1987. The Economics of Bargaining. Oxford: Basil Blackwell Buckley, Roger 1992. US-Japan Alliance Diplomacy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Destler, I. M., H. Fukui, and H. Sato. 1979. The Textile Wrangle: Conflict in Japanese-American Relations, 1969-1971. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Faure, G. O., and J. Z. Rubin, eds. 1993. Culture and Negotiation. Sage, 1993. Fearon, J. D. 1994. Signaling versus the Balance of Power and Interests: An Empirical Test of a Crisis Bargaining Model. Journal of Conflict Resolution 38 (2): 236-69. Finnemore, M. 1993. International Organizations as Teachers of Norms: the United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization and science policy. International Organization 47 (4): 565-98. Friman, H. Richard. 1993. Side-Payments versus Security Cards: Domestic Bargaining Tactics in International Economic Negotiations. International Organization 47: 387-410. Gardner, R. N. 1956. Sterling-Dollar Diplomacy: Anglo-American Collaboration in the Reconstruction of Multilateral Trade. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Gilpin, Robert. 1981. War and Change in World Politics. --- . 1975. US Power and the Multinational Corporation. New York: Basic Books. Gowa, Joanne. 1984. Hegemons, IOs, and Markets: The Case of the Substitution Account. International Organization 38: 661-83. Haas, P. M., R. O. Keohane, and M. A. Levy, eds., 1993. Institutions for the Earth. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Haggard, S., and B. A. Simmons. 1987. Theories of International Regimes. International Organization 41: 491-517. Hampson, Fen O. with Michael Hart. 1995. Multilateral Negotiations: Lessons from Arms Control, Trade, and the Environment. Baltimore, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Holsti, K. J. 1986. Politics in Command: Foreign Trade as National Security Policy. International Organization 40: 643-671. 27 Hufbauer, Gary, Jeffrey Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliott. 1985. Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy. Washington: Institute for International Economics. Ikenberry, G. John. 1988. Market Solutions for State Problems: The International and Domestic Politics of American Oil Decontrol. International Organization 42: 151-77. Iklé, F. C., and N. Leites. 1962. Political Negotiation as a Process of Modifying Utilities. Journal of Conflict Resolution 6: 19-28. Inoguchi, Takashi. 1991. Japan’s International Relations. London: Pinter Publishers. Kennan, J., and R. Wilson. 1993. Bargaining with Private Information. Journal of Economic Literature 31 (1): 45-104. Keeley, James F. 1983. Cast in Concrete for all Time? The Negotiation of the Auto Pact. Canadian Journal of Political Science (June). Knorr, Klaus. 1975. The Power of Nations: The Political Economy of International Relations. New York: Basic Books. Keohane, R. O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Kissinger, Henry A. 1979. White House Years. Boston: Little Brown. Lake, D. A. 1988. Power, Protection, and Free Trade: International Sources of US Commercial Strategy, 1887-1939. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press. Lax, D. A., and J. K. Sebenius. 1986. The Manager as Negotiator: Bargaining for Cooperation and Competitive Gain. New York: The Free Press. Martin, Lisa. 1992. Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Milner, H. 1992. International Theories of Cooperation among Nations: Strengths and Weaknesses. World Politics 44 (3): 466-96. Mitchell, R. B. 1994. Regime design matters: intentional oil pollution and treaty compliance. International Organization 48: 425-58. Odell, J. S. and Barry Eichengreen. Forthcoming. The United States, the ITO and the WTO: Exit Options, Agent Slack, and Presidential Leadership. In The WTO as an Organization, ed. Anne Krueger. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 28 Odell, J. S. 1997. Policy beliefs and international economic negotiations. Presented at the International Studies Association convention, Toronto. --- 1995a. Market conditions and international economic negotiation. Unpublished. January. --- 1995b. Toward a valid theory of international economic negotiation. Unpublished. April. --- 1993. International Threats and Internal Politics: Brazil, the European Community, and the United States, 1985-1987, in Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. eds. P. Evans, H. K. Jacobson, and R. D. Putnam, Berkeley: University of California Press. --- 1988. From London to Bretton Woods: sources of change in bargaining strategies. Journal of Public Policy 8: 287-316. ---. 1985. The Outcomes of International Trade Conflicts: The US and South Korea, 1960-1981. International Studies Quarterly 29:263-286. --- 1982. US international monetary policy: markets, power, and ideas as sources of change. Princeton: Princeton University Press. --- . 1980. Latin American Trade Negotiations with the United States. International Organization 34: 207- 228. Ortmayer, Louis. 1992. The US-Japanese FSX Fighter Agreement. Pew Case Study 350. Washington: Institute for the Study of Diplomacy, Georgetown University. Preeg, Ernest H. 1970. Traders and Diplomats: An Analysis of the Kennedy Round of Negotiations under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. Washington: Brookings Institution Pruitt, Dean G., and Jeffrey Z. Rubin. Social Conflict: Escalation, Stalemate and Settlement. New York: Random House, 1986. Raiffa, H. 1982. The Art and Science of Negotiation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Rhodes, C. March 1989. Reciprocity in Trade: The Utility of a Bargaining Strategy. International Organization 273-300. Rothstein, Robert L. 1979. Global Bargaining: UNCTAD and the Quest for a New International Economic Order. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Rowland, Benjamin M. 1976. Preparing the American ascendancy: the transfer of economic power from Britain to the United States, 1993-1944. In Balance of Power or Hegemony: The Interwar Monetary System, ed. Benjamin M. Rowland, pp. 195-224. New York: New York University Press. 29 Spar, Debra L. 1992. Co-developing the FSX Fighter: the domestic calculus of international co-operation. International Journal XLVII: 265-292. Stein, Janice Gross. 1993. The Political Economy of Security Agreements: The Linked Costs of Failure at Camp David. In Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press. Suzuki, M. 1994. Economic Interdependence, Relative Gains, and International Cooperation: The Case of Monetary Policy Coordination. International Studies Quarterly 38 (3): 475-499. Thompson, L. L. "Negotiation Behavior and Outcomes: Empirical Evidence and Theoretical Issues." Psychological Bulletin 108, no. 3 (1990): 515-32. Thompson, Scott. 1977. Unequal Partners: Philippine and Thai Relations with the United States, 1965-1975. Lexington, Massachusetts: Lexington Books. Underdal, A. 1992. The concept of regime effectiveness. Cooperation and Conflict 27: 227-40. Urban, Laszlo K. 1983. Once More with Feeling: German-Polish Interwar Trade Negotiations. East European Quarterly XVII (March): 89-108. Walton, R. E., and R. B. McKersie. 1965. A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations: An Analysis of a Social Interaction System. New York: McGraw-Hill. Walton, R. E., J. E. Cutcher-Gershenfeld, and R. B. McKersie. 1994. Strategic Negotiations: A Theory of Change in Labor- Management Relations. Boston, Mass: Harvard Business School Press. Young, O. R. 1991. Political Leadership and Regime Formation: On the Development of Institutions in International Society. International Organization 45 (3): 281-308. Young, O. R. 1975. Bargaining: Formal Theories of Negotiation. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. Zartman, I. W., ed. 1994. International Multilateral Negotiation: Approaches Management of Complexity. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. to the ---, ed. 1978. The Negotiation Process; Theories and Applications. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. --- and A. Bassani. 1988. The Algerian Gas Negotiations. Pew Case Studies in International Affairs, No. 103. Washington, DC: Institute for the Study of Diplomacy, Georgetown University. 30 outtakes: Choice of parties: prospective enemies No: “party” can be in a conflict as well as a cooperation Move down to tactics: Poland illustration really is on the level of beliefs could be interpreted equally as an illustration of this relationship within the frame of an ongoing negotiation between parties, rather than as a decision at the limit to begin or end talks with a party. It might be argued, in fact, that by engaging in conflict over their exchange rate, the UK and the US were already parties to a negotiation, given a definition as broad as mine. “party” can be in a conflict as well as a “cooperation.” Move down to tactics or delete: Here “security” may be understood to mean not only gross ratios of capabilities but also actions that change the odds of attack or defeat in war. These security beliefs among top leaders will influence instructions given to economic negotiators, according to this idea, even when financial and trade ministers themselves have no responsibility for military-political affairs. After the Versailles conference, relations between Weimar Germany and Poland were tense on one level. Germans wanted their Silesian territory back and Stresemann held out for territorial revisions as a condition for a lasting bilateral trade agreement. Their conflict escalated to a tariff war beginning in 1925. Meanwhile until 1934, nevertheless, these two governments also left space even then for trade to pass in sectors of concern to organized economic interests in the two countries. Poland continued to have an export surplus with Germany, the only one in eastern Europe. In November 1935 these two also signed a trade treaty that formally ended their tariff war. Yet trade volume did not recover in fact. In response to the depression, many governments had begun controling their economies much more thoroughly. In addition, Nazi Germany had begun rearming earlier that year, and Polish leaders grew increasingly sensitive to the concern that greater trade with Germany would enlarge its preponderance. Hitler was sending warm signals toward his southeast but not toward Poland. Warsaw signed a loan agreement with France in 1936 and shifted its economic orientation accordingly for security reasons.25 One thinks even more readily of Western economic sanctions against the Soviet Union and China beginning in the early 1950s. 25 31 Move down or delete: Poland illustration really is on the level of beliefs We should also resist the temptation to stretch the meaning of “security” ever more broadly. Believing as I do that preserving our natural environment and protecting women from battering in their homes are vitally important goals does not convince me that all these diverse phenomena are best analyzed using the single concept “security.” Conceptual stretching risks concealing profound differences in the causation of different phenomena, which could only delay effective remedies for concrete problems, as well as wasting even more academic time than we scholars waste anyhow. Better to introduce distinctions explicitly and observe them--thus opening the possibility of studying theoretical relationships that are specified more narrowly--without, however, completely abandoning effort to create more general formulations that could eventually encompass narrower relationships as well. More general formulations are likely to have greater value when they are built upon on accurate descriptions of real experience using carefully specified, concrete variables and relationships, both of which are sorely lacking in this area today. the Tokyo Round,26 ?Perhaps most telling of all, at least for academics, is that detailed studies even by self-described “realists”--who begin from the premise of anarchy and typically assume that military affairs dominate the economic in politics--also fail to report any military-political influences on specific economic negotiations (Krasner structural conflict,? Grieco ? HYP 2: Bergsten: Germany and Japan held $s longer; but selling could have hurt all holders financially too (see post 71) Japan failed to retaliate on trade (but also for pure economic power reason) Not comparisons with more or less powerful state [think more. Delete?: Yet in every actual case the negotiator and her principals begin ex ante with significant uncertainty about how the other party and their own society will respond to possible moves under prevailing market and domestic-political circumstances. With uncertainty one natural tendency will be to believe that the trade-off can be avoided, that the same strategy can achieve the one without sacrificing the other, at least until shown otherwise. If such evidence does come forth, normally more than one cogent interpretation can be fitted to it, as earlier examples illustrated. .........] 26