Rising Inequalities of Income and Saving and Perception of Social Mobility Ewa Gucwa-Lesny1 and Barbara Liberda2, University of Warsaw, Poland Abstract The aim of the paper is to show that under the conditions of increasing income and wealth inequality in the transition countries, especially Baltic States and Poland, the mobility of households between different income and saving groups has lead to their polarization with regard to accumulation of assets and wealth. Income mobility was particularly intensive in the first years of transition and gradually diminished. The policy of minimizing the role of the state and the drive to comply as quickly as possible with the requirements of the economic efficiency resulted in less solidarity and social protection than in the old market economies of Western Europe. As public institutions perform less efficiently as a result of limited funds, the development of human capital depends more and more on the effort of the family and its accumulated wealth. The results of research on savings motives show it clearly. Subjective feelings reflect the reality. In the group of low income mobility Gini coefficient proved to be significant factor affecting satisfaction with income. The perception of the opportunities for social advancement has decreased with time and depends more on level of education attained. In the same time the feeling of inequality in access to education has increased. The research is made on the basis of data from Polish Household Budget Surveys for the years 1996-2000 and the data from Consortium of Household Panels for European Socio-Economic Research (CHER). The data from Polish General Social Survey 2002 and International Social Survey Program, Social Inequality III for the years 1992 and 1999 are also used. The paper concerns mostly Poland but some comparisons with Hungary – member of CHER and ISSP consortia – are discussed. Introduction 1 Department of Economics and Institute for Social Studies, University of Warsaw. E-mail e.gucwa-lesny@uw.edu.pl 2 Department of Economics, University of Warsaw. E-mail Barbara.Liberda@uw.edu.pl In most of the Central and East European countries undergoing transition from planned to the market economy, the process of differentiation of incomes and material and social status of households and individuals has started. The income and wealth inequalities had been increasing in the first period of the change of economic and social system, until middle of the 1990s, and then either were kept at the same level or continued to increase until now. We analyzed this process at the micro-scale i.e. income mobility of individuals or households between different income groups, on the basis of Polish nationally representative household budget surveys for the years 1994-2005 (above 30 thousand households in one year and around 100 thousand persons surveyed each year). We tried also to assess the probability of the long term occurrence of inequality using true panels of the same sample of households extracted from these surveys. True panels are rather rare and short in time span (3-5 years) in Central and East European countries. The ones, examined in this paper (1-6 thousand households; 3-5 years of duration) for Poland and Hungary were prepared for Consortium of Household Panels for European Socio-Economic Research (CHER). The perception of changes in economic and social situation was analyzed. Data originated from Polish General Social Survey 2002 as well as International Social Survey Program, Social Inequality III, for the years 1992 and 1999. 1. Overview of income inequalities in transition economies of Europe. The overall picture of changes in income inequalities in the transition economies is mixed. Figure 1 shows the Gini coefficients for household incomes in Central and East European economies3. In Lithuania, Estonia and Bulgaria the inequalities were the highest after the first transition period in 1994-1995. In Slovakia the inequalities have been rising since 1993 and in Czech Republic they are held at a level of mid-1990s. The highest income per person inequalities in 2005, as compared to previous periods, was in Latvia, Lithuania, Estonia and Poland. Inequality in these four countries was higher than in all but one members of European Union, Only in case of Portugal Gini coefficient was higher than in Baltic States (Human Development Report 2006). Other measures of inequality show similar tendencies. The ratios of incomes or expenditures of the 9th decile to the 1st decile and of the 2nd to the 8th deciles of individuals ranked by income levels are much higher in transition economies of Central and East Europe than are such ratios in richer European economies. The same concerns quintile expenditure share ratios, especially in Baltic States and in Poland. The exceptions are Czech Republic, Slovakia, Hungary and Slovenia where the quintile ratios are lower than the average quintile expenditure share ratio for European Union (25 countries). Figure 1. Income inequality in European transition economies 1998-2005 3 The exact numbers for Gini coefficients differ slightly in calculations by particular authors depending on the specific data source and breaks in data. Gini coefficients for income per person Slovenia Slovak Republic Romania Poland Lithuania 2005 Latvia 1993 1988 Hungary Estonia Czech Republic Bulgaria 0 10 20 30 40 Source: 1988, 1993 World Bank, Milanovic, 1998, p. 41; * Hungary, Poland, Slovenia 1987; Bulgaria, Romania 1989; ** Lithuania, 1994; Estonia, Latvia 1995 2005 Eurostat; calculations for Poland 2005 by Barbara Liberda; *** Bulgaria 2004. 2.Income dynamics In an egalitarian country, rising income inequality creates serious social problems. Big income dynamics creates hope for less fortunate people to improve their situation in future. According to Hirschman’s tunnel effect theory, in developing countries, the growth of income inequality causes a growth of satisfaction because people believe that someone else’s success proves that there is also a possibility for them to become richer and their satisfaction rises. Kalbarczyk (2006) studied the relation between subjective satisfaction with income and income distribution using a Polish (1994-1996) and a British (1992-2000) panel survey. According to expectations, she showed that the Hirschman’s theory can be confirmed on an individual level for Poland (a country with a very volatile economic situation) but not for England (a country with a stable income). However, the application of a new measure of dynamics, namely, the difference between the growth rates of reference income4 and real income suggested that an increase in the reference income carried positive information and increased satisfaction on individual level, both in Poland and in England. It looks like dynamics of income were essential for “tunnel effect” to occur. We observed similar effect in sociological perspective. Since the beginning of transformation average material situation of younger and middle-age group had been unfavorable comparing to others. In the same time respondents of social surveys at this age (up to 40 years 4 Education level and age as well as the region and year determined the affiliation to the same reference group. old), had tended to support socioeconomic changes (Słomczyński et al. 1996). The analysis of income dynamics showed that despite low income position of this group as a whole, within it more people advanced in their material situation than experienced degradation, so they had rational hope in going into moving line in tunnel. Figure 2 show the share of stable group - whose position on the decile income scale did not change at all or changed very little, by one decile up or down, and the share of the groups that advanced or experienced degradation by 2, 3, 4 or more deciles. Figure 2. Income mobility of individuals between deciles of income (ranked by income per person) in Poland in 1991-2000 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 1999/2000 1997/1998 1993/1994 1991/1992 0 ,=-4 -3,00 -2,00 -1,0,+1 2 3 >=4 Prepared on the basis of data from four panels for the years 1991/92, 1993/94, 1995/97 1997/2000. During most intense income mobility period (1993-1994) the ratio of stable group was only 35, 7. The groups that advanced or experienced degradation by 4 or more deciles were large in this period; their share was about 13 percent in both cases. Exceptional income mobility did not last long. Later in the 1990s more persons were moving down than moving up, leading to more inequality. The group that did not move outside of the two closed deciles was kept large, from 55% to 70% of all persons in households in Poland. Only in 1997-2000 was mobility again similar on both sides of the income scale: in each deciles group the probability of advancing and degradation was almost the same. In Hungary mobility of households during 5 years of 1992-1996 was more pronounced than in Poland. More than half of the population in the middle three quintiles changed quintile between years and moved to one of the neighboring quintiles. Measured over time, mobility has gone down. After five years under study more people stayed in the same income groups than had done so at the beginning of the period. Inequality of households’ income rose moderately (Galasi, 1998). Kolosi and Robert (2005, 51) bring data for vertical mobility by income deciles from 2001 to 2003. The report indicates that over the period the very lowest and the highest deciles saw the largest absolute increase of per capita income in relation to average growth. The ratio of the highest to the lowest deciles rose again at the end of the period in 2003. A vertical differentiation of the Hungarian society took place. The general stabilisation of relative income distribution has resulted in the lowering probability of advancement or degradation on income scale, although its dynamics is still higher in Poland and in Hungary than in old EU countries (Gorecki, 1999). Up to 1998 income mobility has been asymmetric. On the advancement side, probability to move up has been higher in lover deciles. On the degradation side, up to 1998, changes were sharper. To keep one’s position in the higher decile group was very difficult. Concerning relationship between subjective satisfaction with income and income distribution discussed above, Kalbarczyk found Gini to be significant only for the subgroup with low volatility of income. Within this group there were people who could not overcome difficult barriers to material advancement and high level of inequality deepened their frustration. 3.Saving inequality and wealth accumulation The present process of economic and social polarization concerns more wealth accumulation than earned incomes only. Investment in housing, durables, human capital in a form of education and caring for health are the attributes of wealth besides earned income. Unfortunately all these investment are relatively new and difficult to observe. Data describing wealth accumulation are heavily underreported and underestimated as well as unbalanced when aggregated across the groups of household. The macroeconomic data on financial investment of household are also often unbalanced. Household budget data have remained the most useful data to examine wealth distribution. Study on saving behavior of households at different income levels surprisingly shows that households report positive savings even if they value their income as hardly sufficient for living and if their income is really low (Liberda 2007). People with higher income in Poland save much more than is the average rate of saving. The top quintile group of households saves more than one fourth of their income, three times the average. The lowest quintile group reports negative average savings. Also a third decile had often negative saving in the past. The household average saving rates were at a level of around 6% till 2000 and only after 2001 they start growing to 9% of household income (Figure 3). Figure 3: Households’ saving rate by decile groups of disposable income in 2005 in Poland (median, in %) 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Decile -6,4 -0,8 3,6 6,5 9,3 10,6 13,6 14,8 18,6 27,8 Median 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 9,4 Source: calculations by Barbara Liberda based on Household Budget Surveys 2005, CSO, Warsaw. With such saving profiles a major part of total private households’ savings comes from the fifth top quintile income group. In 2005 households from the top quintile created 3/4 of all positive household savings. In 2000, which was a year of slow down of the economy, the saving curve was even more skewed. The top quintile accounted for more than 80% of the total household savings. Ten years earlier in 1995 the saving distribution was as skewed as in 2005. The analysis of the household mobility between different classes of households ranked by saving rates allows for estimating the long term households’ distribution with regard to saving rates. It was done by applying Markov mobility matrices to the household budget panel data of 3001 Polish households surveyed in the same month during four consecutive years 1997-2000, for which last true panel of Polish households is available (Liberda, Pęczkowski 2005). The results (Table 1) show that during four consecutive years (1997-2000) more than one third of households with very low negative saving rates had not left their class, but around one fifth jumped into the group of highest saving rates. In a class of households with highest saving rates of above 20% of the household disposable income half of the households kept these high saving rates and around one fifth of this group reported negative savings after a year. The analysis of saving mobility serves as a basis to deduce on the probability of a household to fall into one of the saving rates groups. The long term probability of falling into the lowest saving rate group was around 0.2. The highest (0.3) was the probability to get into a group that saved more than 20% of the household disposable income. Table 1 Households’ mobility matrices subject to the saving rates, 1997-2000, Poland (households ranked by saving rates) Saving rates 1998 <-20% -20% - -5% -5% - 5% 5% - 20% 20%+ Saving rates 1997 Total <-20% 37 15 11 15 23 100.0 -20% - -5% 26 16 18 20 19 100.0 -5% - 5% 23 16 16 22 22 100.0 5% - 20% 15 13 19 24 30 100.0 20%+ 12 8 10 19 51 100.0 21 13 14 20 33 100.0 Total Saving rates 1999 <-20% -20% - -5% -5% - 5% 5% - 20% 20%+ Saving rates 1998 Total <-20% 36 15 11 20 18 100.0 -20% - -5% 25 21 15 21 19 100.0 -5% - 5% 19 18 15 26 23 100.0 5% - 20% 16 10 15 27 32 100.0 20%+ 12 7 10 20 53 100.0 20 13 13 22 33 100.0 Total Saving rates 2000 <-20% -20% - -5% -5% - 5% 5% - 20% 20%+ Saving rates 1999 Total <-20% 38 14 13 17 18 100.0 -20% - -5% 26 18 15 21 19 100.0 -5% - 5% 17 17 16 27 23 100.0 5% - 20% 15 14 14 30 28 100.0 20%+ 19 9 10 23 48 100.0 20 13 13 24 31 100.0 Total Source: Liberda, Pęczkowski, 2005, based on 3001 households’ panel from Household Budget Surveys 1997-2000, CSO, Warsaw. There is then a clear tendency towards polarization of households with regard to saving rates. Such polarization indicates that the accumulation of assets by households is highly unequal. The wealth of households in transition economies will be more and more unequally distributed between individuals and households that build up their human capital and material well-being after a collapse of the central planning economy. 4. Savings and investment in human capital Building human capital on the basis of savings makes long term polarisation of wealth very important for future social mobility. Numerous public opinion research showed that precisely the changes that relate to market economy – income differences, unemployment and economization of public services - in particular education and health services are the most difficult to accept. However it is also important to note that people’s ability to adapt to the new conditions has improved from the very beginning of transition. Growing self-reliance and realism of aspirations were observed (Gucwa-Lesny 1996), as well as a more self-directed orientation (Kohn and all 1997). Building human capital with one’s own effort is a good example of the growing selfreliance mentioned above. State desertion from social policy which would be active in fields which are crucial in terms of success in the modern world leads to selective modernization, concerning only individualized areas of life, and addressed only to some segments of Polish society. Half of Polish households save voluntarily around 7 % of their disposable income. The households also invest in educating children and adults on average 2% of their disposable income and next 5 % in health care of members of the household. The profiles of spending for education display an interesting picture. The highest are expenditures for education in the young age of 20-24 years and then in 30-44 years. The first is the period of investing in the own education by heads of households. There is an educational boom at the level of tertiary education in Poland. About half of total number of students pays fees for their education, though, according to Polish constitution, the tertiary education is financed by the state. The other very common educational expenditure is for learning foreign languages and for different types of training, including the post diploma studies. Households spending for education account for one fourth of the government spending for this purpose. If not the private investment in education, Polish society would not have been well prepared for the competition within EU and on a world scale. This investment is sizable in relation to a relatively low average income of Polish households. Total spending of households for human capital is slightly higher than is the sum of savings. In one of previous research, based on the structure of expenditures for human capital and the pattern of saving function according to the level of the household income (Figure 4), Barbara Liberda (2005) claimed that investment in human capital of Polish households can be treated as a luxury good. Figure 4. The share of spendings for education and health care in household income along with household saving rate in income deciles groups 25 Percent of income for education mean 20 15 10 Percent of income for health mean 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 -5 Household income decile group 8 9 10 Saving rate median -10 -15 Spending for health care are the highest in relation to income in the lowest four income decile groups. Though they spend for health in nominal terms below the average level of household health expenditures, this investment constitutes a heavy burden for these poorer households. Often it is forced by the lack of health service for some social groups in poorer regions. At the same time 40% of richest households spend for health care more than is the household average, but in their case investment in health care is less a luxury. As spending for education is mainly voluntary, the expenditures for health care is very often forced by the limited access to the public health system (long queues, overcrowding of hospitals, sometimes low quality of service due to a shortage of qualified staff or a lower service staff). Households spending for health care are almost of the same size as the government spending for this purpose. . 5.Perception of falling social mobility Subjective opinions about rising inequality of income and wealth were analyzed on the basis of the results of International Social Survey Program, Social Inequality III, for the years 1992 and 1999. Within this period, East Europeans managed to adjust to market economy, the economy itself was stabilized, financial crises were overcome, inflation decreased to acceptable level etc. At the same time due to income and saving inequalities described in this paper, we can expect accumulation of assets by higher income households, their better adjustment to inefficient public services by replacing them privately. We anticipated growing perception of strengthening social barriers. The social mobility was studied at the beginning of transition. The results showed that Polish society became again more open than under previous social system. The tendency to “inherit” social position from parents has diminished. Current occupational status was determined by the level of education and intellectual flexibility to a greater extent in 1992 than in 1978 (Slomczynski et al. 1996). However the comparison of these beliefs with opinions expressed by respondents of Survey discussed here show reversal of this trend at the end of twentieth century. In four Eastern European Countries where International Social Survey Program was conducted in 1999 (issp@nsd.uib.no), the feeling of difficulties in overcoming social barriers has been high. It increased between 1992 and 1999 in Poland and in Hungary. In other countries Czech Republic, Slovak Republic and Slovenia, comparisons in time are impossible due to geographical and political changes which occurred in the analyzed period. Two variables were analyzed—answer to the following questions: “How important is coming from a wealthy family?” and “How important is to have connections?” Both variables were measured on the 5 point scale: 1.Very important, 2.Important, 3. Somewhat important, 4. Not important, 8. Can’t choose. As both variables are highly correlated; the principal components analysis was used to reduce them into one component (the loadings of both variables were equal) measured after normalization on a hundred (100) points scale. The scale was constructed for each country separately. Higher values indicate that chances to get ahead are available and that perceptions of an individual are independent of one’s personal and family connections; the lower values indicate that people perceive chances to get ahead as not available without these connections. The respective attitudes are shown on the figure 5. Figure 5. Mean values of scale of the availability of social advancement in 1999. (Chances to get ahead; 1- success determined by the wealth of the family and personal connections, 100 – no influence of the above factors on getting ahead) It is interesting to compare Figure 5 with Figure 1 (the value of Gini coefficients). The higher inequality in the particular country observed the lower perception on the availability for social advancement expressed by its citizens. Figure 6 presents changes in respondents status compared with her/his father in Hungary and in Poland. In both countries significant differences are observed between 1992 and 1999. Figure 6. Changes in job status. * Significant change between 1992 and 1999 at p<0.05, Source: Social Inequality III data. Please think of your present job (or your last one if you don't have one now). If you compare this job with the job your father had when you were [14/15/16], would you say that the level or status of your job is (or was)... 100% * 8* 4* 90% 80% 1* 6* 4* 18* 22* 31* 28* 70% Much low er than your father's 26* 36* 60% 40% Higher 44* 55* Much higher than your father's 38* 30% 36* 20% 10% 0% Low er About Equal 50% 18* 8 11* 7 1992 1999 HUNGARY 1992 1999 POLAND Last figure is a subjective comment to the analysis of saving and investment in education presented above. Figure 7. Opinions about commercialization of education Is it just or unjust – right or wrong – that people with higher incomes can... Buy better education for their children than people with lower incomes? 100% 26* 80% 63* Very unjust 60% 36* Somewhat unjust Neither nor 40% Somewhat just 18* 20% 13 0% 14 Very just 15* 3* 3* 9* HUNGARY POLAND * Significant change between Hungary and Poland at p<0.05 Source: Social Inequality III data. The visible difference between opinions of Hungarians and Poles are interesting because in Hungary diminishing influence of the level of education on the level of income was observed in the nineties. Different studies conducted on panel data in the years 19941997 demonstrated similar results. Maybe lower level of inequality in Hungary makes its citizens less prepared for commercialization of public services. 6. Conclusions The analysis of changes of inequality in a transition economy together with the analysis of income and savings mobility of individuals or households between different income groups leads to the following conclusions. The transformation process led to increasing income and social inequalities in all transition European countries. This process was less acute for households in Hungary, Czech and Slovakia. In Lithuania, Latvia, Estonia and Poland inequalities increased more The income and saving mobility between different classes of households (ranked by income or saving rates) allows for estimating the long term households’ distribution with regard to income or saving rates. The tendency towards polarization of households with regard to saving rates signals that accumulation of assets by households is highly unequal and the wealth of households in transition economies will be more and more unequally distributed. Half of Polish households save voluntarily around 7 % of their disposable income. The households also invest in educating children and adults on average 2% of their disposable income and next 5 % in health care of members of the household. This investment is sizable in relation to a relatively low average income of Polish households. Total spending of households for human capital is slightly higher than is the sum of savings. The analysis of the results of International Social Survey Program, Social Inequality III show subjective perception of rising barriers to social advancement. References Galasi P. (1998). Income Inequality and Mobility in Hungary 1992-96, Innocenti Occasional Papers, Economic and Social Policy Series No. 64. Górecki B., (1999). Dynamika zarobków w krajach przechodzących transformację i w krajach Unii Europejskiej, (Dynamics of Payment in Transition Countries and in EU), Ekonomista No. 5, 635-645. Gorniak, J., 2003. Poland. In: Mikhalev, V. (ed.). Inequality and Social Structure during the Transition. Oxford, UK: Palgrave Macmilan. Gucwa-Lesny, E. (1996). ‘Market Oriented Economy and the Polish Soul - Less Romantism, More Realism’. In: G. Antonides, F. van Raaij and S. Maital (eds). Advances in Economic Psychology. Chichester. UK: John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., 3-25. Hirschman, A., (1973). The Changing Tolerance for Income Inequality in the Course of Economic Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 544-566. Kalbarczyk, M., (2006). Badanie związku między subiektywna a obiektywna zamoznoscia gospodarstw domowych (Research on the Relationship between Subjective and Objective Households’ Wealth). Ekonomista,1 (75-87) Kohn, M.L., Słomczyński, K.M., Janicka, K., Khamelenko, V., Mach, B.W., Paniotto,V., Zaborowski,W., Heyman, G.R. (1997). Social Structure and personality under Conditions of Radical Social Change: A Comparative Analysis of Poland and Ukraine. American Sociological Review, 62, 614-638. Kolosi T., P. Robert (2005). Key Processes of Structural Transformation and Mobility in Hungarian Society since the Fall of Communism, in: Social Report 2004, Budapest, TARKI, 47-71. Liberda B., (2007). Income Preferences and Household Saving, Gospodarka Narodowa, No. 9; and IAREP/SABE Conference, Paris 2006. Liberda B., M. Pęczkowski, (2005). Saving Mobility of Polish Households, Proceedings of a conference on Comparative Economic Analysis of Households` Behavior (Old and New EU Members), Warsaw University, 2005, Warsaw. Liberda B., (2005). Inwestycje w kapitał ludzki a stopa oszczędzania gospodarstw domowych (Human Capital Investment versus Household Saving Rate). Ekonomista 4, 421-447. Milanovic, B., 1998. Income, Inequality and Poverty during the Transition from Planned to Market Economy, World Bank. Słomczyński K. M., Janicka K., Mach B. W., Zaborowski W. 1996. Struktura społeczna a osobowość. Psychologiczne funkcjonowanie jednostki w warunkach zmiany społecznej (Social Structure and Personality. Psychological Functioning of the Individual under Conditions of Social Change. Polish Academy of Sciences. Warsaw. Transition, the First Ten Years. 2002. World Bank.