Outsourcing, Risk, and Responsibility: On the Precarious Freedoms of Disembedding for the Labor Process Craig D. Lair Gettysburg College Department of Sociology clair@gettysburg.edu Abstract There can be little doubt that outsourcing is becoming an increasingly prevalent phenomenon not only in business life, but also in the affairs of governments and in the lives and individuals and families. But what exactly is outsourcing and what consequences does it have both for those who outsource their activities and those who take them on? I will argue that such a theory can be found in seeing outsourcing as a specific form of organizational disembedding that offers entities a set of freedoms – i.e. possibilities of action and non-action - that would not be possible in the absence of this practice. However, many of these freedoms are precarious in that they involve a multitude of risks and dangers both for those outsourcing their affairs and for those who take them on. This paper highlights two such precarious freedoms – how outsourcing allows entities to contract (i.e. limit) their responsibility and to shift a number of risks onto both suppliers and workers. 1 Introduction There can be little doubt that outsourcing is becoming an increasingly prevalent phenomenon not only in business life,1 but also in the affairs of governments (e.g. the use of private prisons and private military contractors)2 and in the lives and individuals and families (e.g. the use of take-out food and cleaning services).3 In all these spheres entities are handing over an increasing array of their activities to others to perform.4 But what exactly is outsourcing and what consequences stem from this practice? Undoubtedly attempts to address these issues have come from a variety of theoretical perspectives (e.g. transaction cost economics,5 the perspective of “core” competencies/specialization,6 as creative destruction,7 etc.) but for various reasons8 these have failed to offer an adequate theoretical account of outsourcing and its nature. This, in turn, has limited the ability to explore the wide-ranging consequences that result from this phenomenon, particularly in the realm of work. As such, there is a need for a more comprehensive theory of outsourcing’s nature and consequence. I will argue that such a theory can be found in seeing outsourcing as a specific form of organizational disembedding that offers entities set of freedoms – i.e. possibilities of action and non-action - that would not be possible in 1 For various examples of this, see Klier and Rubenstein (2008) in terms of the automobile industry; Brown and Linden (2005) for semiconductors; Blackmore et al. (2005) and Lacity et al. (2009) for information technologies; Kaka (2009) for business process outsourcing; Brooks (2006) and Crouch (1997) for outsourcing in the pharmaceutical industry; and Goelman (2005) for radiological outsourcing, to name just a few examples. 2 See, for example, Light (2006) in terms of government contractors, McCoy (2009) in terms of private military contractors, Sabol and Couture (2008) in terms of private prisons, Molnar et al. (2007) for the privatization of education through education management organizations, and Sanger (2003) in terms of the outsourcing of welfare provisions. 3 See Lair (2007) for an overview of these issues. 4 See Ritzer and Lair (forthcoming) for a more comprehensive overview of this issue and the specific activities that entities are outsourcing. 5 E.g. Aubert et a., 1996, 2004; Ellram et al., 2008. 6 E.g. Prahalad and Hamel, 1990. 7 E.g. Samulevicius and Samonis 2006: 142; Greaver 1999: xiv; Singer 2004; Drezner 2005; Olsen 2006: 8-9. 8 In general, the accounts of outsourcing offered to date have suffered from at least one of the three following limitations: they have looked at outsourcing exclusively in terms of economic issues, thus overlooking its social implications; they only look at outsourcing in terms of one, and in some cases two, of the dimension of social life noted above (i.e. in terms of economic, governmental, and individual and familial activities); or they have seen outsourcing as exclusively a positive (good) or negative (bad) phenomenon. This paper, and the larger project from which it is drawn (Ritzer and Lair, forthcoming), attempts to overcome these limitations by exploring the economic and social consequences of outsourcing across all facets of social life, and by noting how the benefits of outsourcing are often inexorably intertwined with a number of negative elements. That being said, given the focus of this paper on how outsourcing is affecting the labor process in the context of responsibility and risk, it tends to concentrate on issues more relevant to work in the economic and governmental spheres. 2 the absence of this practice. However, many of these freedoms are precarious in that they involve a multitude of risks and dangers both for those outsourcing their affairs and for those who take them on. Though a number of such precarious freedoms are engendered in the outsourcing process, this paper explores two that are of particular relevance to the labor process: the contracting of reasonability (i.e. the ways in which outsourcing is used to limit and free entities from various forms of responsibility) and risk shifting (i.e. the ways in which outsourcing is allowing certain forms of risks to be pushed onto suppliers and/or workers). I will conclude by offering some general conclusions on outsourcing and its relationship to the work process. Outsourcing as Organizational Disembedding As it is normally used in the business context the term outsourcing refers to instances in which a company purchases goods or services once performed within the organizational structure of a company (i.e.” in-house”) from an outside supplier. An example of this would be an automobile manufacturer purchasing engines for its cars from an outside company instead of building this part itself. The practice of outsourcing is often characterized in terms of the “make vs. buy” decision; i.e. does a company make what it needs itself, or does it buy it from others? Though the idea, and indeed practice, of outsourcing are not new,9 it was not until the early 1970’s that business executives began to use the term “outsourcing” to describe this reliance on external suppliers and the increasing decision to “buy” instead of “make” the goods and services used in their operations.10 However, it was not until the late 1980’s and early 1990’s that this idea was widely implemented primarily in terms of manufacturing jobs. Over 9 Davis-Blake and Broschak, 2009: 322. Corbett, 2004: xiii 10 3 time, and given recent advances in information technologies (IT), white-collar and other “high-skilled” jobs have increasingly been, and are increasingly liable to be, outsourced.11 Nevertheless, despite its origins in the business context, as a practice outsourcing is not limited to the actions of businesses; the reality is that any number of non-business actors– particularly the state, individuals, and families – also engage in essentially the same type of activity by transferring tasks once performed “in-house” to suppliers located in the market. Thus, outsourcing can be generally defined as the transfer of activities conventionally performed by a certain type of entity (e.g. a business; the government; individuals or families) to an external business (or businesses) in exchange for money. Though there are a number of other important clarifications to consider in this definition and in determining exactly which transfers of activities are or are not instances of outsourcing,12 the general point to note is that outsourcing is not limited to the sphere of business activity. But what exactly is outsourcing? That is, what exactly is involved when it is said that an entity, be it a business or otherwise, has transferred some or all of its activities to an external supplier? It would seem that on the most basic level outsourcing is a form of organizational disembedding. The concept of disembedding is drawn from Anthony Giddens who defines it as “the `lifting out’ of social relations from local contexts of interaction and their restructuring across indefinite spans of timespace”.13 For Giddens disembedding is a major facet of (late) modernity and is meant to highlight how under modern conditions activities are increasingly organized on a large, and in some cases a truly transplanetary, scale. As conceived of in this manner, disembedding is a largely geographical process and closely tied to another of Giddens’ ideas - that of time-space distanciation. Giddens defines distanciation as “the conditions under which time and space are organised so as to connect presence and absence” and “the complex relations between local involvements (circumstances of co-presence) 11 Bardhan and Kroll 2003. See Lair (2007) and Ritzer and Lair (forthcoming) for a more extensive discussion of these issues. 13 Giddens, 1990: 21. 12 4 and interaction across distance (the connection between presence and absence) that are now characteristic of the modern world” (emphasis in original).14 While this geographical element of disembedding is certainly important, when it comes to the issue of outsourcing it can be seen that a more fundamental form of disembedding is involved, one that occurs at the level of organization. Indeed, what outsourcing entails is the “lifting out” of social activities from their existing organizational environment (e.g. from a business, the government, a family) and their restructuring across one or many other sources located in the market. Hasle gives a good characterization of this in his discussion of how outsourcing is changing the notion of the division of labor: “Traditionally, the division of labour has been an internal workplace manner. With the extended use of outsourcing and other supply chain arrangements, the division of labour is increasingly taking place between independent companies” (emphasis added). Though limited to the business context, this discussion highlights what is the fundamental feature of outsourcing: how outsourcing takes the activities of an entity (e.g. the internal division of labor in the quotation above), disembeds them from their organizational environment, and then restructures them across others (i.e. how the division of labor is increasingly taking place between different companies). It is in this regard that outsourcing can ultimately be seen as a process of organizational disembedding. As such, this is a process which can occur on any geographical scale, be it local (e.g. as when janitorial functions are outsourced within one specific geographical location) or global (as when call center jobs are outsourced from the U.S. to overseas locations). It is in this organizational sense that the term disembedding is used here. As will be seen below, this ability to disembed activities from one organizational environment is in fact the principal freedoms that outsourcing offers, the freedom from which all of the others discussed stem. However, it should also be noted that there is a flipside to the process of disembedding that is also of great significant to outsourcing; that of reembedding. This conception is again drawn from 14 Giddens, 1990: 64. 5 Giddens who defines it as “the reappropriation or recasting of disembedded social relations so as to pin them down (however partially or transitorily) to local conditions of time and place”.15 Like with disembedding, Giddens emphasizes the geographical dimension of remebedding by noting how disembedded activities must be reinserted into local contexts of time and place. As with disembedding, the term reembedding is used here in an organizational sense in that it is meant to highlight how outsourcing fundamentally involves the repositioning of disembedded activities into the organizational environments of outside entities located in the market independent of how much geographical distance is involved (again, this process of reembedding can occur on any geographical scale). Though the ability to lift activities out of one organizational environment and to reinsert them into another may sound like a relatively straightforward process, something quite significant is entailed within it. Taken together, the ability to disembed activities from one organizational environment and to remebed them in another offers entities possibilities of action and non-action that would not exist in the absence of outsourcing. These possibilities are the freedoms that outsourcing makes possible. However, it is also the case that mixed within these freedoms are both opportunities and risks for those who outsource their affairs and those who take them on. This insight is drawn from an exploration of disembedding in the realm of biography and how this offers individuals new freedoms of action that are precarious in nature – that is, they are mixtures of both opportunities and risk. 16 This connection between biographical disembedding and the engendering of precarious freedoms was first identified by Ulrich Beck and his individualization thesis. In short, Beck’s theory is that when biography is disembedded (i.e. freed from) from traditional social structures (be these of feudalism or first modernity) new opportunities for living a life of one’s own arise. However, such opportunities are risky in the sense that, freed from the old certainties of tradition and structure, life is now uncertain exactly to the extent that it is an open project (e.g. how following one’s own individualized life course, as 15 16 Giddens, 1990: 79-80 Beck and Beck-Gernsheim, 2002. 6 opposed to the traditional path, could result either in success or equally in failure). Though the specific opportunities and risks involved in individualization and outsourcing are quite different, the basic dynamic involved in both is the same: disembedding offers entities new forms of freedom but such freedoms contain within in them elements of risk and danger. But what exactly are the freedoms that outsourcing affords, and in what ways are they precarious? These issues are addressed in the following sections. The Freedoms of Outsourcing Though the issue of outsourcing is undoubtedly important for a number of reasons, perhaps what is most significant about this phenomenon is the constellation of freedoms (i.e. possibilities of action and non-action) that it makes possible. In other words, outsourcing allows entities to do things that would not be possible in the absence of this practice. As was noted above, the principal freedom outsourcing offers, the freedom from which all the others stem, is how outsourcing allows an entity to disembed activities from within its organizational confines. In other words, outsourcing allows entities to remove various activities from their organizational boundaries by transferring them and their performance to sources located in the market. This ability to disembed activities by outsourcing them can be seen as a type of freedom in the sense that it allows an entity to free itself of certain tasks that, for whatever reason, it does not wish to, or cannot, perform itself.17 Indeed, one of the primary benefits of outsourcing is that it allows entities to divest themselves of these types of activities. In this regard disembedding offers a negative form of freedom in that it allows entities to not do certain things. For example, the existence of firms willing to manufacture goods for others has allowed companies to not 17 This highlights a central point: it is only because there are others who can and will take on these activities that this libratory aspect of outsourcing is possible. If it were the case that these outside others were not willing or able to take on these tasks this freedom of divestment would not be possible. 7 engage in production; the existence of firms willing to take on non-war fighting military activities (e.g. base construction and maintenance) has allowed the military to free itself of these tasks; while the existence of companies willing to take over the “dirty work” of running a home (e.g. cleaning kitchens and bathrooms) has freed individuals and families from having to perform these tasks. From this it can be seen that outsourcing offers a form of liberation by divestment: by disembedding certain activities from its organizational environments and transferring them to others an entity is freed of performing them. Though this freedom to not engage in particular activities is negative in nature, there is a positive side to this process as well: by transferring certain activities to others in the market, resources (e.g. time, energy, and, in some cases at least, money) that would normally be involved in performing these activities are freed up which can, in turn, be devoted to the performance of other, perhaps more important or desired, functions. In other words, outsourcing not only gives entities a greater freedom to not perform certain functions, the resources this frees up gives it greater freedom to focus on other activities. In business theory this is talked about in terms of how the outsourcing of “peripheral” activities can liberate resources that can then be concentrated on an entity’s “core” elements.18 An example of this can be seen in how branding – the attempt to associate a product or product line with a meaning that is independent of the physical properties of what is actually being sold (e.g. how Apple has tried to frame its computers as being hip and cool as opposed to the square and stodgy PC) - is changing what it is actually ‘produced’ by many companies. In the recent past there has been a realization that what sells goods are not actual physical products but instead the meanings associated with their brand (e.g. the appeal of Apple computers being found more in the meaning attached to them as opposed to their technological capabilities). Given the values of brands and the fact that: 18 Hamel and Prahalad, 1990. 8 building a superbrand is an extraordinarily costly project, needing constant managing, tending and replenishing… [economic logics dictates that] corporations should not expend their finite resources on factories that will demand physical upkeep, on machines that will corrode or on employees who will certainly age and die. Instead, they should concentrate those resources in the virtual brick and mortar used to build their brands; that is, on sponsorships, packaging, expansion and advertising.19 Many companies have in fact followed this logic by concentrating their efforts on building their brand as opposed to actually making the things that they sell. They have done this in large part by transferring their manufacturing activities over to others. Ever since [it was realized that brands, and not products, sell], a select group of corporations has been attempting to free itself from the corporeal world of commodities, manufacturing and products to exist on another plane. Anyone can manufacture a product, they reason ... Such menial tasks, therefore, can and should be farmed out to contractors and subcontractors whose only concern is filling the order on time and under budget... Headquarters, meanwhile, is free to focus on the real business at hand - creating a corporate mythology powerful enough to infuse meaning into these raw products just by signing its name (emphasis added).20 By liberating themselves from the “peripheral” act of manufacturing these companies have been freed to concentrate on the “core” activity of brand building. One of the most famous examples of a company outsourcing their manufacturing activities in order to concentrate on what they see as their core elements is Nike. Though Nike is well known as one 19 20 Klein, 2002: 196. Klein, 2002: 21. 9 of, if not the, leading shoe and athletic apparel manufacturer in the world, it does not actually produce any of the goods and merchandise that it sells. In fact, it would be quite difficult for Nike to actually manufacture these goods since it does not own or operate any factories where this production could take place. This absence of manufacturing capacities is the result of Nike’s decision to outsource virtually all of its production to a network just fewer than 700 factories located in 52 different countries that contract with it to produce its shoes and other goods.21 Though cost is one of the main elements of why Nike outsources its production22 (an issue discussed in more detail below), the other is because this frees Nike’s employees to concentrate on its core competencies that “revolve around its understanding of athletes’ footwear needs (attained through research and development), the design competencies to meet those needs, the marketing skills to deliver the message (including endorsement and advertising skills), and the logistics systems to get the shoes delivered”.23 Thus, outsourcing allows Nike to specialize in the creation and marketing of shoes designs by leaving to others the actual production of these goods. As such, the company can claim that “[w]e grow by investing our money in design, development, marketing and sales and then contract with other companies to manufacture our products”.24 This relationship between the ability to divest certain activities in order to invest in others is one of the principal motives for why Nike and many other companies outsource their activities. However, this motive is not confined to the business sector only: both governments and individuals and families also outsource some of their activities in order to concentrate their efforts on others. For example, the military has begun to outsource more of its operations, and while there are many motivations behind this, one of the main drivers of this trend is the desire to reduce the amount of ‘peripheral’ activities that military personnel are engaged in. This is being done so that they can, in turn, concentrate on what 21 Nike, 2005-6: 25 Locke, 2002: 4 23 Greaver 1999: 95 24 Nike, cited in Locke, 2002: 4. 22 10 is ostensibly their primary core competency: war-fighting. Thus, the 2004 U.S. Budget noted that the Department of Defense “continues to pursue ways to return military members to the war-fighting ranks by increasing the ‘tooth-to-tail’ ratio through conversion of support staff to combat troops…25 [As such, the] Department is attempting to open up for competition many of the commercial services it now performs itself, such as health care activities to free up thousands of military positions for warfighting”.26 This theme has been consistently echoed in subsequent budgets. For example, the 2008 U.S. Budget announced that, to date, the DOD has “[c]onverted over 26,000 military positions to civilian positions to relieve strain on the military force and ensure all military personnel are performing ‘military essential’ activities”.27 Individuals and families are also using outsourcing as a means to concentrate on the activities that are most important to them by relieving themselves of tasks they do not have the time, energy, or desire to perform on their own. For example, Sandholtz et al. talk about a group of people they call “outsourcers” who “strive to get control of their overstuffed lives” by “farming out certain tasks and obligations (usually in their nonwork lives), then focusing more attention on the activities, relationships, and causes they care most about.”28 Similarly, in her work on the “outsourcing of domesticity” journalist Maggie Jackson29 profiles a woman who began to outsource many of her and her family’s affairs when she realized that she could not both run the business she started and do all of her housework. As a result, she hired a cleaning service, a personal organizer, two errand services, part-time personal assistants (though they help both with her business and with family errands), a lawn care service, and a personal chef. The result of all of this outsourcing is that “she’s pleased that she can take the kids to a 25 Though not all of these conversions will be to the private sector, and thus be instances of outsourcing (e.g. some tasks will be transferred to other government agencies), many will fall under this category. 26 U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003: 85 – emphasis added. 27 U.S. Government Printing Office,2007: 43. 28 Sandholtz et al., 2002: 58. 29 Jackson, 2002. 11 museum or a friend’s house on weekends, rather than doing the housework or nagging her sons to do chores.”30 On a different level, the ability to disembed activities from one context also allows a number of freedoms in terms of where these activities are moved to. In other words, outsourcing offers freedoms not just in terms of disembedding but also in terms of reembedding. In particular, this possibility of replacing where activities are performed allows entities to be liberated from the confines of their internal capabilities and resources in the sense that they can transfer their activities to sources that have different, and in most cases better, capacities than what they have themselves. All entities engage in numerous activities at any given time and it is very unlikely that they will be highly proficient in all of them. However, it is also likely that there are others who by virtue of their specific skill set (e.g. specialized knowledge and training) can perform these tasks in a highly effective and proficient manner. By outsourcing activities that one is not proficient in to others who are, one is able to gain access to capabilities that one does not internally possess. For example, although payroll is necessary for any company, unless a firm is in the payroll business this is not likely not one of its core competencies (and thus would not perform it as efficiently and effectively as an entity that specializes in it). Also, since most people do not buy one product over another because of the payroll systems used by a company, if this task were outsourced to a company that specializes in this activity they could presumably perform it in a quantitatively and/or qualitatively better manner than if it were kept in-house. In business this is normally talked about in terms of how outsourcing allows one to have access to “best-in-class” capabilities – i.e. those who are the leaders in terms of performing a specific activity.31 However, this same dynamic is evident in other spheres of life as well. For example, since the government increasingly lacks internal capabilities in certain areas, particularly in the realm of technology, it has been forced to 30 31 Jackson, 2002: 67-8. Quinn and Hilmer, 1995. 12 outsource these tasks simply because of its lack of internal resources.32 Similarly, though perhaps a more mundane example, while most people can sufficiently cook a meal in order to feed themselves, by outsourcing their food preparations to restaurants they gain access to persons with specialized skills in this area and who may be able to provide qualitatively better outcomes in terms of the food that ends up on one’s plate than if one cooked for oneself. The same situation applies to the resources that one has at one’s disposal. Though an entity may be as capable as others at performing a specific task, they may have a deficit of a specific resource (e.g. time or man-power) that can be overcome by outsourcing. For example, though a busy professional couple may be capable of cleaning their own home, and might do so in a very proficient manner, it could be the case that because of their schedule they do not have the time or energy to perform this task. However, if they outsourced this task to others they would be able to overcome this internal limitation. More generally we can see that outsourcing’s ability to move locations from one context to another offers an entity the ability to free itself of the circumstances of a particular location. The most prominent example of this can be seen in one of, if not the, main motivations for outsourcing, especially in the business context33: the desire to take advantage of labor cost differentials. Labor costs are not the same in all locations, nor are they the same in all organizational environments. By allowing entities to disembed their activities from one location and to reinsert them in another, outsourcing allows entities to take advantage of these differences in labor costs by shifting their activities to locations where these costs, and others, are lower relative to their current location. Thus, one of the reasons why so much manufacturing work has been outsourced to companies located offshore is because the average hourly compensation for manufacturing workers in many other countries is a mere fraction of 32 The National Commission on the Public Service, 2003; Soloway and Chvotkin, 2009: 210-213. Surveys of businesses and business executives have consistently found that cost reductions are the primary motivation for outsourcing their activities (e.g. The Outsourcing Institute, 2005; Ventoro, 2005: 14; Gartner cited in Krishnamurthy et al., 2009: 43; EquaTerra, 2009). However, it is also true that many other surveys have found that these expected benefits have not come to pass (e.g. Ventoro, 2005; see also Kalff, 2006: 67 for an overview of these). 33 13 what it is in the U.S.34 This can be seen in Table 1 which shows the average hourly compensation (in U.S. dollars) for production workers in select countries. Labor Cost Differentials for Manufacturing Workers in Select Countries (2007) 35 Country United States Argentina Brazil Canada Mexico Israel Japan Republic of Korea New Zealand Philippines Singapore Taiwan Czech Republic Denmark Hungary Ireland Poland Portugal Slovakia Spain United Kingdom Hourly compensation in U.S. $30.56 dollars $7.98 $7.13 $31.91 $3.91 $15.92 $23.95 $18.36 $19.19 $1.37 $15.43 $8.15 $9.67 $47.54 $10.49 $35.62 $7.69 $10.29 $8.49 $24.55 $36.66 Percent of U.S. labor cost 100% 26% 23% 104% 13% 52% 78% 60% 63% 4% 50% 27% 32% 156% 34% 117% 25% 34% 28% 80% 120% But it is not just in terms of blue-collar work that these differences in labor costs can be found; they can also be seen in white collar occupations where labor costs can be as little as one-tenth the cost 34 It is also true that cost differentials can also be found within the U.S. Thus, car manufactures may outsource their operations from the higher-cost regions of the Northeast and Midwest to the lower-cost regions of the South. However, these differences are often not as great as when foreign sources of labor are used. That thee desire to reduce cost is perennially the primary reason why businesses outsource their activities, it should not be surprising that many entities are looking to move their activities to environments where labor and other types of cost are lower (Brown and Wilson, 2005: 47). 35 Tables 1 and 2, U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, March 2009 (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/ichcc.toc.htm). 14 in low-wage nations such as India as in higher-wage nations such as the U.S.36 In the case of computer programmers, while in the U.S. the average salary is $63,000, in Japan the comparable salary is $44,000, in Indonesia this number is $12,200, in Russia it is $7,500, in the Philippines $6,500, in India $5,850, and $4,750 in China.37 Similarly, the average salary in the U.S. of call center work, including benefits and bonuses, is $46,000 per year compared to $6,000 in India and $7,300 in the Philippines.38 Salary differentials even exist for high-skilled workers. For example, while the salary of semiconductor engineers in the U.S. is $82,000, it is $60,000 in Japan, $30,000 in Taiwan, $15,000 in India, and $12,000 in China.39 Thus, in general it can be seen that outsourcing offers entities greater control over which activities they do and do not engage in which, in turn, can free up resources that can be redirected toward other activities; it can be used by entities to free themselves from internal limitations in terms of capabilities and/or resources; and it can be used by entities to free themselves from the circumstances of particular location. While these freedoms undoubtedly offer many benefits to those who outsource their activities (e.g. the ability to capitalize upon lower labor costs, the ability to concentrate on one’s core activities, the ability not to do things one does not wish to do, etc.) they are also precarious in the sense that they contain certain risks and dangers, both for those who outsource their affairs and those who take them on. Two such precarious aspects of outsourcing are highlighted below: the contracting of responsibility and risk shifting. Outsourcing and the Contracting of Responsibility 36 Baily and Farrell 2004: 1 Carmel, 2003: 6. 38 Weier, 2003. 39 National Academy of Engineering, 2008: 169. 37 15 As was seen above, outsourcing allows an entity to free itself of the performance of certain activities that it does not wish to, or cannot, perform. But outsourcing allows entities to do something else as well: to free themselves of various responsibilities that would normally be entailed if their activities were performed in-house. In other words, outsourcing allows entities to contract (i.e. limit) the responsibilities that they have. This can happen in a variety of ways. One way in which this occurs is how outsourcing allows entities to claim that they are not responsible for the actions of their contractors and/or the conditions under which their contractors perform the outsourced activities. This claim is made despite the fact that these contractors work on behalf of the entities doing the outsourcing and that the latter are often highly dependent on the former for the performance of their activities (e.g. Nike is virtually completely dependent on its contractors for the performance of its activities). The direct implication of this is that an entity is seemingly free of any responsibility regarding their contractors and the actions they do and do not take, except perhaps for those that violate the terms of the outsourcing arraignment (e.g. the cost of the goods/services being outsourced). In the business context Nike provides the classic example of how outsourcing is used to claim that one is not responsible for the actions of its contractors: when charges came to light in the 1990’s that many of Nike’s contractors were engaging in various human rights abuses such as not paying their employees adequate wages, or at all; of using child labor; and/or of forcing their employees to work extremely long hours (e.g. 60, 80, or 100 hours a week), Nike was quick to claim that these issues were not their responsibility but instead that of their contractors. As a company manager in Jakarta put it, “[t]hey are our subcontractors. It’s not within our scope to investigate [allegations of labor violations]”40 In fact, since Nike did not “know the first thing about manufacturing” given that they were merely “marketers and designers” as Nike’s Vice President for Asia claimed at that time, how could they be 40 Locke, 2002: 11, originally cited by Rosenzweig 1991 16 responsible for what went on in the production facilities of others? In essence Nike was claiming that by freeing themselves of their production functions they too were freed of any responsibility regarding what their contractors did despite the fact that they were working on Nike’s behalf. But Nike’s actions were not uncommon in this regard. Instead they mirrored the “traditional” response of companies facing accusations of human rights abuses by contractors; i.e. to “argue that they cannot realistically or financially be held responsible for the labor practices of their foreign suppliers”.41 Thus, it should not be surprising that when a Disney spokesperson was asked if Disney would be willing to accede to a call of a living wage for workers employed by a Haitian company contracting with Disney, he said "[t]he problem is, we don't own the factories; we are dealing with a licensee." Moreover, he added that this type of “request should not come to us," but to the licensee since it was they, not Disney, who directly employed these workers.42 Another example of this claim that outsourcing frees a company of responsibility regarding the actions of its contractors can be seen in the case of the toy recalls that occurred in 2007. This recall was prompted when it was discovered that a number of toys featuring characters from the Thomas the Tank children’s show were coated in lead paint. Though the British company HIT Entertainment owned the rights to these characters, the production of toys based on these characters was being outsourced to the China-based RC2 Company. When the issue of lead paint began to surface HIT’s response to the situation was simple: it was not their responsibility. As a reporter for the New York Times noted of this company’s reaction: Except for a small link on the Thomas Web site to RC2’s recall announcement, HIT has otherwise acted as if it has nothing to do with the situation. Its executives haven’t even said that they regret having been promoting toys with lead paint in them. They haven’t said anything publicly. 41 42 Spar 1998: 7 Mokhiber 1996. 17 When I suggested to the company’s public relations agency, Bender/Helper Impact, that this might not be the smartest approach, the agency e-mailed me a two-sentence unsigned statement. It said that HIT appreciated the concerns of its customers and was working with RC2 on the recall, but that the recall was “clearly RC2’s responsibility”.43 Of course, such claims could not be made if these actions took place within a company’s organizational confines. As Babb notes, “[w]hereas bureaucratic firms [i.e. ones where activities are performed in-house] can be publically criticized and sanctioned for unethical practices, to hold them accountable for the practices of their suppliers, sub-suppliers, and so on down the food chain is much more difficult.”44 The claim of non-responsibility regarding the actions of contractors can also be seen in cases of governmental outsourcing. For example, this sentiment was expressed by an officer in the Air Force when he claimed that in the midst of allegations that one of the Air Force’s contractors was engaged in sex trafficking, that “the Air Force is concerned with whether the contract is carried out, not with the behavior of individual employees”. Another example of this can be seen in an incident involving charges of human trafficking by one of the most prominent firms engaged in government contracting: Halliburton. This case centers around claims that Halliburton’s subcontractor, the Jordanian-based Daoud and Partners, lured a number of Nepalese men into working for them by promising these men jobs in hotel and restaurant kitchens in Amman Jordan. This was not to be the case and instead these workers had their passports confiscated and were going to be taken into Iraq to work at a U.S. air base. On the way to the base one of the vehicles containing the workers was stopped by insurgents and 12 43 44 Leonhardt, 2007. Babb, 2005: 215. 18 men in the car were kidnapped and subsequently executed.45 When this occurred, both Halliburton and the U.S. Army claimed they had no responsibility regarding this situation. At the time [of this incident],Halliburton said it was not responsible for the recruitment or hiring practices of its subcontractors, [while] the U.S. Army, which oversees the privatization contract, said questions about alleged misconduct "by subcontractor firms should be addressed to those firms, as these are not Army issues."46 Similarly, when allegations of prisoner abuse and torture in Abu Ghraib were first raised, Donald Rumsfeld, then Sectary of Defense, wrote to a member of Congress that any disciplining of the contractors involved in these charges was “the contractor’s responsibility”, not that of the United States Government.47 A different manifestation of this can be seen in how the casualty statistics of the war efforts in Iraq and Afghanistan commonly exclude figures on how many private contractors have been injured or killed.48 On the one hand this is official recognition that, as private contractors, these persons stand in a different category from that of military and other government personnel. On the other hand, the government often recognizes the integral role these contractors play in the conduct of these wars. This can be seen in how, beginning in 2006, the Department of Defense began to include contractors as part of its “Total Force” of operations and noting the role contractors play in constituting “its warfighting capability and capacity.”49 Whether the sacrifices made by contractors should be treated in an equivalent manner to that of military personnel and other government officials is not a question to be decided here. Nevertheless, that the sacrifices of contractors are not recorded in the same manner as 45 Mount, 2008. Simpson, 2005. 47 Brinkley, 2004. 48 Debusmann, 2009. 49 Department of Defense, 2006: 75. 46 19 that of members of military highlights how the state does not claim the same types of responsibility for the former as opposed to latter despite these two parties often performing functionally equivalent activities. A reflection of this difference can be seen in how “there is little talk of the need to bury contractors at Arlington National Cemetery or to insert them into the politically costly structures of honor and recognition” normally reserved for military personnel.50 In other words, by treating these contractors as entities outside of the State’s realm of responsibility their loss of life goes unrecorded and unaccounted for in the official annals of sacrifice. Another way in which outsourcing can be used to contract (i.e. limit) responsibility is by allowing entities to disembed activities from their existing organizational confines and to reembed them in environments where various forms of responsibility (e.g. legal, political, social) are different (and in general lower) and/or non-existent. In the economic sphere this can be seen in the outsourcing of activities to firms located in export process zones (EPZ’s).51 The International Labor Organization (ILO)52 defines EPZ’s as “industrial zones with special incentives set up to attract foreign investors, in which imported materials undergo some degree of processing before being exported again.” Milberg and Amengula offer a similar definition of EPZ’s, though, they also highlight how in these zones firms are given “special concessions on taxes, tariffs and regulations.”53 Indeed, a central reason for why these zones are so attractive to businesses is because of the concessions that are made to them in terms of such things as taxes, tariffs, and, in particular, environmental and labor regulations (e.g. exemptions from minimum wage laws54 and more “flexible” hiring and firing practices55). In fact, “low or missing social standards and environmental safeguards as well as the basic disregard of basic labor rights are 50 Taussig-Rubbo, 2009: 111. Tonkiss, 2006: 20. 52 ILO, 1998: 3. 53 Milberg and Amengula, 2008: 1. 54 Klein, 2002. 55 Perman et al., 2004: 7. 51 20 used as a completive advantage in order to attract (mostly foreign) investors” (emphasis added). 56 Thus, Milberg and Amengula note how one of the “less transparent” features of EPZ’s that is used to attract business is their “relaxed regulatory environment, including with respect to the enforcement of labour rights and standards (notably the right to unionize), foreign ownership regulations and on the leasing or purchasing of land”57. This is similar to the findings of the International Confederation of Free Trade Unions (ICFTU) which concluded that “labour standards are lower and employment rights weaker in EPZs” because of exemptions from labor law regulations, the non-enforcement of labor laws, and the fact that unions are often denied entry into EPZ’s.58 And while it is true that “[s]ome export processing zones are well-managed industrial zones where responsible firms offer good working conditions and higher wages than elsewhere in the economy”59, and that “the limited availability of detailed data” makes “an all embracing” picture of the working conditions at EPZ’s difficult, the general picture of EPZ’s seems to be one where “unacceptable working conditions” and a general disregard of national laws (e.g. in terms of labor and environmental standards) are present.60 Klein provides a good overview of EPZ’s and the working conditions found in them: [r]egardless of where the EPZs are located, the workers' stories [of them] have a certain mesmerizing sameness: the workday is long - fourteen hours in Sri Lanka, twelve hours in Indonesia, sixteen in Southern China, twelve in the Philippines. The vast majority of the workers are women, always young, always working for contractors or subcontractors from Korea, Taiwan or Hong Kong. The contractors are usually filling orders for companies based in the U.S., Britain, Japan, Germany or Canada. The management is military-style, the supervisors often abusive, the wages below subsistence and the work low-skill and tedious. As an economic model, today's 56 Zink, 2009: 19. Milberg and Amengula, 2008: 1. 58 Perman et al., 2004: 7. 59 Perman et al., 2004: 7. 60 Zink, 2009: 19. 57 21 export processing zones have more in common with fast-food franchises than sustainable developments, so removed are they from the countries that host them. These pockets of pure industry hide behind a cloak of transience: the contracts come and go with little notice; the workers are predominantly migrants, far from home and with little connection to the city or province where zones are located; the work itself-is short-term, often not renewed.61 Other examples of degraded working conditions in EPZ’s include excessive working hours (e.g. 15 hour days in peak times), overtime that is forced and/or not fully compensated for, weak or unenforced health and safety regulations (e.g. companies allowing workers few, if any, bathroom breaks while working, or companies locking their employees in the building for fear of theft, gender discrimination by paying women less than men and terminating them for becoming pregnant, and restrictions on, and repression of, unions).62 These conditions are the direct result of these places being free of many rules and regulations that companies would otherwise be responsible for if they were not located in such an environment.63 Though not an exact parallel, a similar situation of moving outsourced activities to places where various forms of responsibility are less, if not non-existent, can be seen in cases of private contractors performing military functions. This is because until recently when these activities were moved from the context of the military with its relatively clear lines of responsibility and accountability and into the hands of private contractors, they entered what was more or less a vacuum of responsibility as most of 61 Klein, 2002: 205. Perman et al, 2004: 9-13. 63 It is worth noting that while it was initially thought that EPZ’s could be used as a gateway to economic development by luring companies to a specific location with a number of economic incentives (e.g. a tax holiday for a certain number of years), what has allowed EPZ’s to be as popular as they are today is also what has made this development more illusory than real: with the ability to disembed their activities from their organizational confines and to remebed them in other places, companies are free to move their operations from that place once these incentives expire and/or any of the other conditions that made the EPZ initially attractive (e.g. the fact that it was free of unions) change and into another. Thus, “[b]y its very nature, EPZ investment is precarious, and likely to leave the country at a moment’s notice if more favorable conditions for production, including lower wage[s], are on offer elsewhere.” 62 22 the traditional means of ensuring accountability in the military are absent in cases of private contracting. As Minow describes this, [m]ilitary training, unit discipline, the Uniform Code of Military Justice, and international legal standards governing war and armed conflicts ensure accountability for the military, but not for private corporations and their employees engaged in military work. Serious questions have been raised about whether Congress can use its oversight of the military on private contractors. And difficult issues about what sources of law even applies to private contractors have rendered ambiguous the relevant enforcement mechanisms, potentially jeopardizing the success of military missions as well as domestic, military, and international norms”64 As a result of this there have been numerous cases where contractors, despite appearing to engage highly illegal, if not appalling, acts, were not held accountable for their actions because of the void of responsibility regarding their actions at the time. Two examples of this surfaced in 2000 when separate allegations were put forward charging that workers from DynCorp Inc. were engaged in prostitution and/or sexual trafficking. One case involved contractors at Camp Comanche in Bosnia, the other forced prostitution in the Balkans. In terms of the former, despite one person admitting to ‘purchasing’ a prostitute (purportedly to free her from her situation) and an Uzi machine gun in an apparent ‘package deal’, he, nor anyone else who was found to have engaged in wrongdoing (7 men in total) faced any criminal charges as a result.65 In part this was because at this time U.S. law did not apply to contractors working in a foreign country for “common crimes” while it was also unclear if 64 65 Minow, 2009: 118. Capps, 2002a; 2002b. 23 Bosnian law applied to the contractors.66 As a result of this there was a de facto form of impunity for these men: despite what they did they seemingly could not be held responsible for it in any official context with the exception of losing their jobs. In the latter case the situation was much the same, though in some senses clearer; since these contractors, while being employed by DynCorp, were working under the auspices of United Nations as part the International Police Task Force they could not be held accountable to Bosnian law as mandated by the agreement between the U.N. and Bosnia-Herzegovina. Also, since the "[t]he U.S. government has absolutely no criminal jurisdiction to prosecute civilian police officers who serve with U.N. missions abroad," this means that contractors were subject neither to the laws of their home or host country.67 As a result, they too faced a virtual form of impunity as any recognizable mechanism of responsibility was absent. In response to these situations the Military Extraterritorial Jurisdiction Act [MEJA] of 2000 was passed. In theory this act would make those American contractors working for the Department of Defense accountable to U.S. law for their actions.68 Nevertheless, despite the passage of MEJA questions of responsibility still linger.69 A more general example of this situation can be seen in the case of contractors operating in Iraq after the passage of “Order 17” by Paul Bremer, the then head of the Coalition Provisional Authority. By declaring that “[c]ontractors shall be immune from Iraqi legal process with respect to acts performed by them pursuant to the terms and conditions of a Contract or any sub-contract thereto”, this order freed contractors from any legal responsibility for their actions vis-à-vis Iraqi law. At the same time, since many of the contracts were given out through the Department of State, as opposed to the Department of Defense, there remain questions as to whether MEJA applies to these situations despite the fact that 66 Apparently it was, however, because Bosnian officials did not think this was the case and that they did not have the authority to arrest and prosecute contractors they did not pursue the matter (Capps, 2002b). 67 This quotation comes from Martina Vandenberg, a women's rights researcher for Human Rights Watch (cited in Capps, 2002b). 68 McCarron, 2008: 39. 69 Minow, 2009: 119. 24 in 2005 MEJA was expanded to include persons contracted by “any other Federal agency, or any provisional authority, to the extent such employment relates to supporting the mission of the Department of Defense overseas”. Thus, while five former employees of Blackwater have been charged with manslaughter in connection with the shooting deaths of 17 Iraqi civilians in 2007 under MEJA, they are claiming that because Blackwater’s contract was issued from the Department of State the MEJA statute is not applicable to them and therefore they cannot be charged with any crime.70 Overall situation is one where while “[c]ontractors are not longer immune from Iraqi law, as they were in the first years of the war,… avenues of legal redress remain winding.”71 Another way in which outsourcing can lead to the contracting of responsibility is through the failure to monitoring one’s contractors. In fact, it is arguable that the one distinct form of responsibly that outsourcing relationships produce is that of overseeing the activities of one’s contractors (if, for nothing else, out of self interest). This point is stressed in many works on outsourcing in the business context. For example, Kakebadse and Kakebadse warn that while “[o]rganizations may outsource infrastructure and services [they] should not allow themselves to outsource responsibility and accountability. If vigilance is not maintained, a strategy of driving costs down for an increased level of service may backfire as the supplier may not be able, or may not wish, to give the required level of attention to the host.”72 This is similar to Buffington who cautions that “the client company doing the outsourcing requires more, not less, responsibility over the third party” and that while outsourcing may lead to situations where the client has less “control responsibility” over the performance of the activity, this does not mean they are free of “leadership responsibility”; if anything, this latter form of responsibility is greater!73 However, since many businesses and government agencies are engaged in 70 McCarron, 2008: 39. The Economist, 2009. 72 Kakebadse and Kakebadse, 2006: 57. 73 Buffington, 2007: 27. 71 25 situations where the monitoring of contractors is weak and/or nonexistent, 74 when outsourcing occurs this form of responsibility is largely, if not completely, absent. As a result of this opens the door to abuses by contractors, be it in terms of the activities they are supposed to perform (e.g. they do not provide what they are supposed to), or in terms of their actions vis-à-vis labor. This can again be seen in numerous cases. One example of this can be seen in the toy recalls that occurred in 2007. Though the policy of toy makers such as Mattel was that lead-based paint not be used on their toys because of the wellknown health concerns,75 insufficient monitoring of the toy company’s contractors and the contractors’ subcontractors played a crucial role in allowing toys coated with this type of paint to reach store shelves. As one commentator put it at the time, in general “[a]s many more companies outsource their production base to China, their poor oversight there is exposing American consumers to greater safety risks…”.76 In response to this situation Mattel in particular pledged to increase the amount of monitoring and testing it undertakes to ensure that something like this is not repeated,77 a move that echoed the recommendations of those in the industry.78 But one particularly ironic aspect of this situation is that Mattel, unlike many other toy companies, keeps a significant portion (about 65%) of its manufacturing in-house, while the rest that is outsourced was to “be kept in tightly controlled [i.e. closely monitored] factories”.79 That this situation could happen to a company like Mattel with relatively high standards of monitoring its contractors speaks to the potential abuses resulting from unmonitored outsourcing relationships. More generally, in response to revelations in the 1990s that their contractors were engaged in sweatshop practices many transnational corporations (e.g. Nike, Gap, Phillips-Van Heusen, Adidas, and 74 In the business sector, see O’Rouke 2003 and Wells, 2007; in the governmental sector see Warner, 2003: 36-7. Barboza and Story, 2007. 76 Kavilanz, 2007. 77 Eckert, cited in Lyles 2008: 465. 78 For example, Sean McGowan, an analyst with Wedbush Morgan Securities, said that “[a]fter this latest episode, I think the toy industry will have to implement a level of oversight that’s never been seen before” (cited in Kavilanz, 2007). 79 Barboza and Story, 2007. 75 26 Liz Claiborne) agreed to develop standards of corporate social responsibility (CSR) mostly pertaining to labor and environmental issues. In essence, these companies agree to have the factories they outsource their production to be monitored and audited to ensure that these standards are being upheld. But notwithstanding the “evidence of improved code compliance among some first-tier suppliers, especially in respect to child labour, forced labour and health and safety…there is considerable evidence that code compliance remains weak and monitoring largely ineffective.”80 This is because at best only a fraction of suppliers are monitored81; production is often and easily shifted from one factory to another thereby making monitoring difficult82; many outsourcing arrangements involve layers of subcontractors so that only a fraction of the supply chain is being looked at (and potentially obscuring the areas where the worst abuses occur)83; monitoring is largely confined to very visible brand name retailers who make up only a small section of their industries84; and there is no real “teeth” to these standards as they are voluntary agreements that are largely unenforceable. In short, though some progress has been made as name brand companies increasingly recognize they share at least some responsibility for the conditions under which their contractors operate and have established standards which their contractors must meet, given the myriad of weaknesses in the mechanisms involved in monitoring and enforcing the compliance of these standards has left contractors free to decide if and/or how they will follow these standards. Similar situations can be seen in the area of government outsourcing. For example, despite a “general policy of not contracting for intelligence functions and services” at Abu Ghraib some interrogations of prisoners was performed by private contractors.85 And though it was realized that if such sensitive functions were to be outsourced there was a need for the Army to “maintain close 80 Wells, 2007: 65; see also Vogel, 2008: 274. For example, in 2008 the Fair Labor Association, one of the leading non-profit multi-stakeholder non-governmental organizations, auditied only 120 of the 4, 532 factories in its association. (Fair Labor Association, 2009: 7). 82 O’Rourke, 2003. 83 O’Rourke, 2003. 84 Bernstein, 2005. 85 Jones, 2004: 49. 81 27 control” over the operation, this was not the case.86 Thus, “[p]roper oversight did not occur at Abu Ghraib due to a lack of training and inadequate contract management and monitoring. Failure to assign an adequate number of [contracting office representatives]to the area of contract performance puts the Army at risk of being unable to control poor performance or become aware of possible misconduct by contractor personnel. This lack of monitoring was a contributing factor to the problems that were experienced with the performance of the contractors at Abu Ghraib” (emphasis added).87 One response to this situation has been to contract out the monitoring of contractor performance (i.e. the outsourcing of the monitoring of outsourcing) both in the operations of DOD88 and the Federal government89 more generally. One can wonder if this a legitimate means of gaining control over this problem or something more akin to putting out a fire by pouring gasoline on it. As can be seen from the above, outsourcing allows entities to contract or limit their responsibilities in a number of ways. As will be seen below, a somewhat similar situation can be found in terms of risk. Risk Shifts Another possibility that outsourcing affords entities is the ability to free themselves of certain forms of risk.90 This occurs not so much through the elimination of these risks as their transfer, intentional or not, to others. Two distinct patterns of this tend can be seen as a result of outsourcing: risks being moved to suppliers and to workers. These shifts in risk can occur in a number of different ways for each of these two groups. 86 Jones, 2004: 50. Jones, 2004: 52. 88 Government Accountability Office, 2006 (GAO-06-838R): 9. 89 Shane and Nixon, 2007. 90 This, of course, does not mean that there are not risks involved in outsourcing itself, nor that not outsourcing is a risk free activity. The point here is to simply note how outsourcing changes existing patterns of risk. 87 28 In terms of suppliers, an interesting example can be seen in terms of ownership. To own something is to make a commitment to it since it entails many costs, requirements, and responsibilities (e.g. the costs of land, the need to upkeep equipment, etc.). Today’s economic environment is, however, one characterized by high levels of dynamism and change, and one where“[b]eing stuck with outdated plants, obsolete equipment, and antiquated business systems and processes is a prescription for failure”.91 Thus, given the commitments that ownership entails and the dynamism of the economic system the result is a situation where ownership itself is an increasingly risky activity. That is, it is a gamble to make a significant commitment to something that could be rendered obsolete as a result of technological and economic developments. An example of this risk of ownership can be seen in the case of General Motors and how it was slow to shift from drum to disc brakes; GM was slow to make this move in large part because it had developed and owned the capacity to produce the former. However, given that there was a preference in the marketplace for the latter companies that outsourced their brake production and thus had no significant stake in which style they used (e.g. they did not own specific technologies nor physical facilities for break production) made this switch quickly with the consequence that they were able to get cars with disc breaks to market faster than GM and were rewarded with higher sales as a result.92 This example not only highlights the risks involved in ownership in today’s dynamic economic environment, it also shows how outsourcing allows entities to free themselves of this risk. This is because outsourcing allows entities to have their activities performed but without the risks involved in owning the means required to have these activities performed (e.g. the factories, buildings, equipment, etc. needed for this). Instead, both the ownership and the potential risks involved in it can be pushed onto one’s suppliers as they, and not the company doing the outsourcing, must take on this risk and the responsibilities ownership entails. A recent example from the automobile industry highlights this 91 92 Rifkin, 2000: 46. Chesbrough and Teece 1996: 67 29 situation well. Though outsourcing to some degree is ubiquitous in the auto industry, Porsche is distinctive in that outsources the complete production of two of its car models – the Cayman and the Boxster – to Valmet, a Finnish company. This is so much so that in 2006 Valmet produced approximately 30,000 cars for Porsche, or about one-third of its entire output.93 But with sagging sales as a result of the current economic downturn Porsche is pulling its Boxster production back in-house from Valmet so that it can keep its own plant running at capacity and thereby evade “the industry’s hoary problem of covering the fixed costs of factories and labor”.94 The result is a situation where “Valmet, rather than Porsche, is bearing much of the burden of the global auto industry’s distress”,95 since it, and not Porsche, is seeing its production orders being lost and its factories operating at less than full-capacity. Of course, if Porsche had owned both of these facilities it would have to bear the costs of an underutilized facility itself. However, since it had expanded its production capabilities through outsourcing as opposed to doing so with internal resources it was Valmet, and not Procshe, that experienced the brunt of this economic downturn.96 Another way in which this risk shifting occurs is when entities utilize outsourcing to have risky or dangerous activities conducted by others as opposed to utilizing their own internal resources for this. That is, instead of performing risky activities themselves, entities can have others perform them and let their suppliers face any potential risks involved in this. A vivid example of this comes from the outsourcing of military affairs. Though potentially negative situations and/or mistakes are always possible in military engagements, the government can shield itself from the risks of these incidents and can claim non-involvement in such situations if it outsources these activities to others outside its 93 Dougherty, 2009. Dougherty, 2009. 95 Dougherty, 2009. 96 Supporters of outsourcing in the business context realized this potential benefit of outsourcing early on. For example, in an article published in 1994 Quinn and Hilmer note how outsourcing can allow an entity to “lower its long term capital investments” and “also force many types of risks and unwanted management problems onto suppliers” (Quinn and Hilmer, 1994: 52). They then go on to list examples of companies (e.g. Apple, Nike, Gallo, and Argyle Diamonds) that have outsourced aspects of their production process in order to push the risks and responsibilities of owning the means of production onto their suppliers (e.g. how Gallo outsources grape production to suppliers so that they, and not Gallo, would have to bear the costs of any problems associated with the grape crop) (ibid.). 94 30 organizational orbit, despite the fact that these private military contractors are working on the behalf of the U.S. government. Pelton looks at this situation through the prism of fault: It is clear that beyond convenience and cost savings, relying on private contractors also makes it possible to outsource fault. Abuses are not unusual in the in the military or private sector, but the consequences are quite different. Where trigger-happy soldiers may spark an international incident and shame a nation, a contractor would simply be fired and his employer criticized. In cases where employees or contracting companies are found to have been involved in questionable activities, they simply lose their contract.97 In this regard, outsourcing offers the government a “firewall” against the risks of “unfortunate” incidents since the blame for them can be directed at the contractor, not the state. But outsourcing has allowed for a number of risks to be shifted in the direction of employees as well. The processes by which this occurs center largely around how the ability to disembed work from one organizational environment and to reembed it in another acts to undermine many of the securities of labor that characterized, in Bauman’s terms, “heavier” forms of capitalism - i.e. ones where goods, materials, information, facilities, and indeed organizations did not flow through time and space as easily as they do now.98 In situations of heavy capitalism both labor and capital were relatively immobile which fostered situations of mutual dependence and engagement. And while such forms of engagement were not without strife and conflict, they nevertheless did foster an on-going relationship with one another, one where mutual concessions were made.99 However, as capitalism has become “lighter” as a result of outsourcing and other processes, capital is increasingly free to move and can 97 Pelton, 2007: 108. Bauman, 2000. 99 Bauman, 2000. 98 31 rapidly shift its operations to new geographical and organizational environments while labor remains relatively immobile both geographically and organizationally. This asymmetry in mobility in turn undermines labor’s power and security in number of ways. First and foremost this comes about through the process of outsourcing itself: outsourcing creates new possibilities of job loss for workers simply because it opens the performance of activities to sources outside of a particular organizational environment, and with these sources comes new opportunities to move the actual performance of activities which, if acted upon, would entail job losses for workers. Thus, in this sense outsourcing poses a new risk to employment as one could lose one’s job to outsourcing, a risk that was not as prevelent when work was heavier and could not easily move organizationally or geographically. Though there are no exact numbers on the jobs that have been lost as a result of outsourcing, and while most of these estimates focus on how many American jobs have been “lost” as a result of offshore-outsourcing, the individual-level consequences that come with job loss 100 are largely the same whether one loses one’s job to a domestic or international source. One effect of this, and thus one of the ways in which labor is left in a more vulnerable position as a result of outsourcing, is how if workers make demands that capital finds excessive it can seek to relocate its operations to places where such demands are not being expressed. In other words, when capital was not as free to move as it is today, this immobility provided a sheltering force for workers who could engage it and make demands upon it. Now, as a result of outsourcing capital can move its operations if and when it feels the demands of workers are too high. A classic example of this can again be seen with Nike: In 1989 more than half of Nike's sneakers were made in South Korea, which was then ruled by an authoritarian government. As South Korea became a democracy and workers gained wage 100 Uchitelle, 2006. 32 increases and union rights, Nike shifted production to Indonesia and China. Barely 2% of Nike's sneakers are now made in South Korea. In 1996, when Indonesia was ruled by the Suharto and the only legal union was run by the government, 38% of Nike's sneakers were Indonesian-made. Since then Suharto has fallen, Indonesia has taken its first faltering steps toward democracy and workers have been able to form their own unions. In the process Indonesia's share of Nike's sport shoe production has fallen to 30% and may fall further.... The decision by Nike and other companies to reduce their investment in Indonesia has put pressure on the Indonesian government to weaken the legal protection of workers' union rights in order to prevent further capital flight. Business interests have run a concerted campaign seeking to persuade the Indonesian government to curtail workers' right to strike in order to prevent the departure of more foreign investors. 101 However, even if entities do not actually outsource jobs the simple threat of this can act to undermine the power and security that workers have. For example, with the entry of India and China into the world market, countries that were once low-cost destinations for companies looking to offshore and/or outsource their manufacturing activities have now become higher-cost destinations with the result that: [w]ith the new supply of low-wage labor [from India and China], firms that traditionally produced manufacturing goods in these [now higher-cost] countries can move or threaten to move facilities to lower-wage settings if workers in existing facilities do not grant concessions in wages or work conditions favorable to the firm. In 2004, for example, some employers in Central America told workers that they had to work extra hours without any increase in earnings 101 Connor 2003. 33 to keep business from moving to China. With wages in Central America three to four times that those in China, the threat was a valid one. 102 In this case companies were able to extract unpaid work from workers simply by threatening to outsource their operations. In other cases, the threat of moving was used to undermine unionization drives and contract negotiations.103 Both cases highlight how the threat of capital moving its operations leaves workers in a more vulnerable position and can be seen as examples of what Epstein refers to as the “threat effects” associated with the increased capital mobility. In short, with outsourcing and relatd processes capital can use the threat of its movement to undermine workers and to curtail any demands they have. A related phenomenon is how outsourcing is leading to an increased sense of economic insecurity in workers, or the psychological perception of possible economic misfortune.104 This sense of insecurity has been increasing for some time,105 and though there are many things that can induce this state of mind (e.g. a global economic downturn), outsourcing plays a significant role in this process. For example, a recent report from the Federal Bank of Saint Louis finds that workers in occupations and industries susceptible to outsourcing were approximately 30 percent more likely to believe that they would suffer a costly job loss (i.e. that they were fairly or very likely to lose their job in the next year and that it would be difficult to find another job with similar pay and benefits) than those in industries where outsourcing is less of a threat.106 This reflects a more general negative perception of outsourcing in terms of how it affects work. For example, 75 percent of those polled in the 2006 congressional elections felt that “outsourcing work overseas hurts American workers”.107 Not surprisingly, given the 102 Freeman, 2007: 30. Bronfenbrenner, 2000. 104 Hacker, 2006: 20. 105 Hacker, 2006: 19. 106 Anderson and Gascon, 2007. 107 Anderson and Gascon, 2007: 1. 103 34 prevalence of outsourcing in the US economy and this country’s relative lack of social protection mechanisms (e.g. universal health care), perceptions of income insecurity are particularly high in the United States,108 and as more and more jobs become vulnerable to outsourcing, it is likely that this perception will continue to increase. But perceptions of income insecurity are not only significant in terms of the psychological states it induces, but also because past research has found that perceptions of economic insecurity undermine workers’ bargaining powers. In situations where workers feel insecure in terms of their employment status demanding more from employers is seen as too risky an endeavor since it could lead to job loss.109 Thus, the insecurity that outsourcing fuels acts to dampen the demands that workers place upon capital thereby leaving them in a more economically vulnerable position. Another way in which outsourcing is undermining the security of labor and therefore making it a more precarious endeavor is by freeing companies to move their jobs to environments that have less economic securities built into them. In many ways this is the flipside to how entities are moving the performance of their activities to environments where various forms of responsibility are lower as many of the responsibilities that employers are trying to free themselves of are actually the bases of security for workers (e.g. union representation). Thus, when work is moved to environments where these securities are diminished, if not altogether absent, workers are left in a much more insecure, and thus riskier, situation. Export Processing Zones represent the pinnacle of this development as these are places were few, if any, labor securities exist. So too with the Nike example cited above; as worker security increased in one environment production was moved to where this was lower. But these are not the only examples of this occurring. Quinlan and Mayhew, for example, cite numerous cases where workers in outsourcing relationships face higher levels of occupational health and safety risks than workers who 108 109 Milberg and Winkler, 2009. Aaronson and Sullivan, 1998. 35 work within a company’s organizational boundaries. For example, they cite a study by Salminen et al. that finds that the risk of serious and fatal work-based injuries was one and a half times higher for contractors as opposed to regular workers.110 Quinlan and Mayhew argue that this increase in risk is the result of three factors: first, the competitive pressures of contracts that can encourage subcontractors to pursue savings by underbidding on contracts, using cheaper or ill-maintained equipment, cutting staffing and qualification levels, rushing production or working long hours, and to evade safety and other legal requirements; second, how the nature of outsourcing leads to a more fractured and complex work processes as well as a potentially diluted chain of responsibility in addition to organizational disorganization (e.g. communication problems); and lastly how the regulations and compliance programs that conventionally focused on permanent employees in larger workplaces have largely failed to address contractors. In these cases it is the nature of outsourcing relationships that is acting to expose the employees of contractors to higher levels of risk. Conclusion This paper has argued that outsourcing is a form of organizational disembedding that entails lifting the performance of activities out of one organizational environment and their reembedding in another. This, in turn, offers entities a set of freedoms – i.e. possibilities of action and non-action - that would not be possible in the absence of this practice. Though, I have attempted to chart what exactly these freedoms are, I have also tried to indicate that entailed in them are both opportunities and risks. That is, though outsourcing unquestionably has many benefits for those who engage in it, it is also the case that precarious consequences that can result from this process and that these cannot, and indeed should not, be overlooked. In particular I highlighted how the freedoms that outsourcing affords also 110 Salminen et al (1993:352). 36 allow entities to contract (limit) their responsibilities and to shift certain risks onto others, specifically suppliers and workers. In terms of the labor process, this means that workers increasingly find themselves in situations that are free of many of the securities they once could take for granted as employers can both free themselves of certain responsibilities they have regarding employees while also putting them in a riskier, and thus more insecure, position. Though it is perhaps not easy to be critical of something held so dearly as the idea of freedom, perhaps it is time to ask at what price do the freedoms that outsourcing affords come, and are they worth it? 37 References and Works Cited Aaronson, Daniel and Daniel G. Sullivan. 1998. "The Decline in Job Security in the 1990s: Displacement, Anxiety, and their Effect on Wage Growth." Economic Perspectives 22(1):17-43. Anderson, Richard G. and Charles S. Gascon. 2007. The Perils of Globalization:Offshoring and Economic Insecurity of the American Worker. Aubert, Benoit A., Suzanne Rivard and Michel Patry. 2004. "A Transaction Cost Model of IT Outsourcing." Information & Management 41(7):921-932. ------. 1996. "A Transaction Cost Approach to Outsourcing Behavior: Some Empirical Evidence." Information & Management 30(2):51-64. Babb, Sarah. 2005. "The Social Consequences of Structural Adjustment: Recent Evidence and Current Debates." Annual Review of Sociology 31:199-222. Baily, Martin and Diana Farrell. 2004. Exploding the Myths about Offshoring. McKinsey Global Institute. Barboza, David and Louise Story. 2007. "Toymaking in China, Mattel’s Way." The New York Times, July 26. Bardhan, Ashok D. and Cynthia A. Kroll. 2003. The New Wave of Outsourcing. Berkeley, CA: Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics. Bauman, Zygmunt. 2000. Liquid Modernity. Malden, MA: Polity Press. Beck, Ulrich. 2000. The Brave New World of Work. Cambridge, UK; Malden, MA: Polity Press; Blackwell. Beck, Ulrich and Elisabeth Beck-Gernsheim. 2002. Individualization. London; Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage. Bernstein, A. 2005. "A Major Swipe at Sweatshops." Business Week, pp. 98. Blackmore, D., R. De Souza, A. Young, E. Goodness and R. Silliman. 2005. Forecast: IT Outsourcing, Worldwide, 2002-2008. Brinkley, Joel. 2004. "The Struggle for Iraq: The Civilians; 9/11 Set Army Contractor on Path to Abu Ghraib." The New York Times, May, 19. Brooks, Kristin. 2009. "CRO Industry Update", http://www.contractpharma.com/articles/2009/06/cro-industry-update Retrieved February 22, 2009. Brown, Clair and Greg Linden. 2005. "Offshoring in the Semiconductor Industry: A Historical Perspective." Sloan Industry Studies Dec 14-16. 38 Brown, Douglas, Scott Wilson. 2005. The Black Book of Outsourcing. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons. Buffington, Jack. 2007. An Easy Out: Corporate America's Addiction to Outsourcing. Westport, Conn.: Praeger. Camm, Frank and Victoria Greenfield. 2005. How should the Army use Contractors on the Battlefield? Assessing the Comparative Risk in Sourcing Decisions. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation. Capps, Robert. 2002. "Crime without Punishment." Salon.Com(June, 27). ------. 2002. "Outside the Law." Salon.Com(June, 26). Carmel, Erran. 2003. "The New Software Exporting Nations: Success Factors." The Electronic Journal of Information Systems in Developing Countries 13(4):1-12. Chatterjee, Pratap. 2009. Halliburton's Army: How a Well-Connected Texas Oil Company Revolutionized the Way America Makes War New York, NY: Nation Books. Chesbrough, Henry W. and David J. Teece. 1996. "When is Virtual Virtuous? Organizing for Innovation." Harvard Business Review (January-Febuary):65-73. Columbia Accident Investigation Board.2003. Washington, DC: National Aeronautics and Space Administration and the Government Printing Office. Connor, Tim. 2003. “Globalization and Labor Rights Panel”. The Public Eye on Davos. Davos, Switzerland, January 23-27. Corbett, Michael F. and Inc ebrary. 2004. The Outsourcing Revolution. Chicago, IL: Dearborn Trade Pub. Crouch, Taylor J. 1997. "The Changing Role of CROs: The Evolution of Strategic Out-Sourcing." Clinical Research and Regulatory Affairs 14(3):205-220. Davis-Blake, Alison and Joseph P. Broschak. 2009. "Outsourcing and the Changing Nature of Work." Annual Review of Sociology 35(1):321-340. Debusmann, Bernd. 2009. "Undercounting Deaths in Iraq, Afghanistan." Reuters, September 10. http://www.reuters.com/article/idUSLA119892. Department of Defense. 2006. Quadrennial Defense Review Report. Dickinson, Laura A. 2009. "Public Values/Private Contract." Pp. 335-359 in Government by Contract: Outsourcing and American Democracy, edited by J. Freeman and M. Minow. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Dougherty, Carter. 2009. "Porsche Finds Fortune from Unlikely Outsourcing." The New York Times, April 4. 39 Ellram, Lisa M., Wendy L. Tate and Corey Billington. 2008. "Offshore Outsourcing of Professional Services: A Transaction Cost Economics Perspective." Journal of Operations Management 26(2):148-163. England, Paula and Nancy Folbre. 2000. "Capitalism and the Erosion of Care." Pp. 29-48 in Unconventional Wisdom: Perspectives on the New Economy, edited by J. Madrick. New York, NY: Century Foundation Press. EquaTerra. 2009. 2Q09 EquaTerra Advisor and Service Provider Pulse Survey Results. Fair Labor Association. 2009. Fair Labor Association 2008 Annual Report. Freeman, Richard. 2007. "The Challenge of the Growing Globalization of Labor Markets to Economics and Social Policy." Pp. 2340 in Global Capitalism Unbound: Winners and Losers from Offshore Outsourcing, edited by E. Paus. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillian. Gereffi, Gary and International Institute for Labour Studies. 2006. The New Offshoring of Jobs and Global Development. Geneva: Iils. Giddens, Anthony. 1990. The Consequences of Modernity. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Goelman, Ari. 2005. "What’s Space Got to do with it." Department of Urban Studies and Planning, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Goldsmith, Stephen and William D. Eggers. 2004. Governing by Network: The New Shape of the Public Sector. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press. Government Accountability Office. 2006. Contract Management: DOD Vulnerabilities to Contracting Fraud, Waste, and Abuse. Greaver, Maurice F. 1999. Strategic Outsourcing: A Structured Approach to Outsourcing Decisions and Initiatives. New York: American Management Association. Hacker, Jacob S. 2006. The Great Risk Shift : The Assault on American Jobs, Families, Health Care, and Retirement and how You can Fight Back. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press. Hochschild, Arlie R. 2003. "Love and Gold." Pp. 15-30 in Global Woman: Nannies, Maids, and Sex Workers in the New Economy, edited by B. Ehrenreich and A.R. Hochschild. New York: Henry Holt and Company. ------. 2000. "The Nanny Chain." The American Prospect, 01/03, pp. 32. International Labour Organization. 1998. Labour and Social Issues Relating to Export Processing Zones: Report for Discussion at the Tripartite Meeting of Export Processing Zones-Operating Countries, Geneva, 1998. Geneva: International Labor Organization. Jackson, Maggie. 2002. What's Happening to Home? Balancing Work, Life, and Refuge in the Information Age. Notre Dame, IN: Sorin Books. 40 Jones, Anthony R., LTG. 2004. Investigation of the Abu Ghraib Prison and 205th Military Intelligence Brigade. Kaka, Norish. 2009. "Strengthening India's Offshoring Industry." McKinsey Quarterly Summer(November 16):19-21. Kakabadse, Nada and Andrew Kakabadse. 2006. "Global IT Sourcing: Analysis, Developments and Best Practice Considerations." Pp. 49-64 in The Offshore Nation : Strategies for Success in Global Outsourcing and Offshoring, edited by A. Vashistha and A. Vashistha. New York: McGraw-Hill. Kalff, Donald. 2006. An Unamerican Business: The Rise of the New European Enterprise. Philadelphia, PA: Kogan Page. Kaplinsky, Raphael. 2007. Globalization, Poverty and Inequality : Between a Rock and a Hard Place. Malden, MA: Polity. Kavilanz, Parija B. 2007. "U.S. Biz Blamed for Dangerous Chinese Products." Retrieved February, 22, 2010. Klein, Naomi. 2002. No Space, no Choice, no Jobs, no Logo. Picador USA Paperback ed. New York: Picador USA. Klier, Thomas H. and James M. Rubenstein. 2008. Who really made Your Car? : Restructuring and Geographic Change in the Auto Industry. Kalamazoo, Mich.: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. Krishnamurthy, Karthik, David Jegen and Bill Brownell. 2009. "Strategic Out-Tasking: Creating “win–win” Outsourcing Partnerships." Information & Management 46(1):42-51. Lacity, Mary, Shaji Khan and Leslie Wilcocks. 2009. "A Review of the IT Outsourcing Literature: Insights for Practice." The Journal of Strategic Information Systems 18(3):130-146. Lair, Craig D. 2007. "The Outsourcing of Intimate Affiars." University of Maryland. Leonhardt, David. 2007. "A Lesson that Thomas could Teach." The New York Times, June 20. Light, Paul. 2006. The New True Size of Government. Locke, Richard. 2002. "The Promise and Perils of Globalization: The Case of Nike." MIT Working Paper IPC-02-007. Lyles, Marjorie A. 2008. "Appreciating Cultural Differences in China: An Interview with Robert A. Eckert, Chairperson of the Board and CEO of Mattel, Inc." Business Horizons 51(6):463-468. McCarron, Paula B. 2008. "Long Arm of the Law: The Military Extraterritorial Jurisdiction Act." Corrections Today Magazine 70(6):38-41. 41 McCoy, Katherine. 2009. "Uncle Sam wants them." Contexts 8(1):14-19. Milberg, William and Matthew Amengual. 2008. Economic Development and Working Conditions in Export Processing Zones: A Survey of Trends. Geneva, Switzerland: International Labor Organization. Milberg, William and Deborah Winkler. 2009. Economic Insecurity in the New Wave of Globalization. Minow, Martha. 2009. "Outsourcing Power: Privatizing Military Efforts and the Risks to Accountability, Professionalism, and Democracy." Pp. 110-127 in Government by Contract : Outsourcing and American Democracy, edited by J. Freeman and M. Minow. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Mokhiber, Russell. 1997. "The Ten Worst Corporations of 1996." Multinational Monitor's Corporate Rap Sheet 17(12). Molnar, A., David Garcia R., Gary Miron and Shannon Berry. 2007. Profiles of for-Profit Education Management, Ninth Annual Report 2006-2007. Mount, Mike. 2008. "Suit: KBR Forced Nepali Men to Work Against Will in Iraq." Cnn.com, August, 28. (http://www.cnn.com/2008/WORLD/asiapcf/08/28/kbr.nepal.workers/index.html) National Academy of Engineering. Committee on the Offshoring of Engineering. 2008. The Offshoring of Engineering: Facts, Unknowns, and Potential Implications. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press. Nike, Incorporated. 2005-6. Innovate for a Better World: Nike FY05-06 Corporate Responsibility Report. O'Rourke, Dara. 2003. "Outsourcing Regulation: Analyzing Nongovernmental Systems of Labor Standards and Monitoring." Policy Studies Journal 31(1):1. Parreänas, Rhacel S. 2001. Servants of Globalization: Women, Migration and Domestic Work. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press. Pelton, Robert Y. 2006. Licensed to Kill: Hired Guns in the War on Terror.1st ed. New York: Crown Publishers. Perman, Sarah, Laurent Duvillier, Natacha David and Eden et Samuel Grumiau, John. 2004. Behind the Brand Names: Working Conditions and Labour Rights in Export Processing Zones.International Conferderation of Free Trade Unions (ICFTU). Prahalad, C. K. and Gary Hamel. 1990. "The Core Competence of the Corporation." Harvard Business Review 68:79-93. Quinn, James B. and Frederick Hilmer. 1994. "Strategic Outsourcing." Sloan Management Review (Summer):43-55. Rifkin, Jeremy. 2000. The Age of Access: The New Culture of Hypercapitalism, Where all of Life is a Paid-for Experience. New York: J.P. Tarcher/Putnam. Ritzer, George and Craig D. Lair. 2009. "The Globalization of Nothing and the Outsourcing of Service Work." In Service Work : Critical Perspectives, edited by M. Korczynski and C.L. Macdonald. New York: Routledge. ------. 2007. "Outsourcing: Globalization and Beyond." In The Blackwell Companion to Globalization. , edited by G. Ritzer. Malden, MA ; Oxford: Blackwell Pub. 42 ------. Forthcoming. The Outsourcing of Everything: On the Precarious Freedoms of Disembedding. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Sabol, William J. and Heather Couture. 2008. Prison Inmates at Midyear 2007. Sandholtz, Kurt, Brooklyn Derr, Kathy Buckner and Dawn Carlson. 2002. Beyond Juggling: Rebalancing Your Busy Life. San Francisco, CA: Berrett-Koehler Publishers, Inc. Sanger, Mary B. 2003. The Welfare Marketplace: Privatization and Welfare Reform. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press. Sassen, Saskia. 2003. "Global Cities and Survival Networks." Pp. 254-274 in Global Woman: Nannies, Maids, and Sex Workers in the New Economy, edited by B. Ehrenreich and A.R. Hochschild. New York, NY: Metropolitan Books. Scahill, Jeremy. 2007. "The Mercenary Revolution: Flush with Profits from the Iraq War, Military Contractors See a World of Business Opportunities." The Indypendent, International (http://www.indypendent.org/2007/08/10/the-mercenaryrevolution-flush-with-profits-from-the-iraq-war-military-contractors-see-a-world-of-business-opportunities/). Shane, Scott and Ron Nixon. 2007. "In Washington, Contractors Take on Biggest Role Ever." Washington Post, February 4. Simpson, Carol. 2005. "US: Pentagon Stalls on Banning Contractors from using Forced Labor." The Chicago Tribune, December, 27. Spar, Debora L. 1998. "The Spotlight and the Bottom Line." Foreign Affairs 77(2):7-12. Standing, Guy. 2007. "Offshoring and Labor Recommodification in the Global Transformation." Pp. 41-60 in Global Capitalism Unbound: Winners and Losers from Offshore Outsourcing, edited by E. Paus. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Taussig-Rubbo, Mateo. 2009. "Outsourcing Sacrifice: The Labor of Private Military Contractors." Yale Journal of Law and the Humanities 21(1):103-169. The Economist, 2009. "The Underside of War." August, 29. (Retrieved from EBSCOhost on January 6, 2010). The National Commission of the Public Service. 2003. Urgent Business for America: Revitalizing the Federal Government for the 21st Century. The National Commission of the Public Service. The Outsourcing Institute. 2005. "8th Annual Outsourcing Index: Money Matters." Outsourcing Essentials 3(4). Tonkiss, Fran. 2006. Contemporary Economic Sociology: Globalisation, Production, Inequality. New York, N.Y.: Routledge. Uchitelle, Louis. 2007. The Disposable American: Layoffs and their Consequences.Vintage Books ed. New York: Vintage Books. U.S. Government Printing Office. 2007. Budget of the United States Government: Fiscal Year 2008. Washington, DC 20402– 0001. ------. 2003. Budget of the United States Government: Fiscal Year 2004. Washington, DC 20402–0001. 43 Ventoro. 2005. Offshore 2005 Research: Preliminary Findings and Conclusions. (http://www.ventoro.com/Offshore2005ResearchFindings.pdf). Wald, Matthew and John Schwartz. 2003. "Shuttle Inquiry Uncovers Flaws in Communication." New York Times, August, 4 (http://www.nytimes.com/2003/08/04/us/shuttle-inquiry-uncovers-flaws-in-communication.html?pagewanted=1). Weier, Mary H. 2003. "Outsourcing Call Centers Pays Off for Delta." Information Week (http://www.informationweek.com/news/services/showArticle.jhtml?articleID=10700286). Wells, D. 2007. "Too Weak for the Job: Corporate Codes of Conduct, Non-Governmental Organizations and the Regulation of International Labour Standards." Global Social Policy 7(1):51-74. Wrigley, Julia. 1999. "Hiring a Nanny: The Limits of Private Solutions to Public Problems." The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 563(1):162-174. Zink, Klaus J. 2009. "Human Factors and Ergonmics in Industrially Developing Countries: Necessity and Contribution." Pp. 15-27 in Ergonomics in Developing Regions: Needs and Applications, edited by P.A. Scott. Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press. 44