INTRODUCTION One of the more recently developed fields of political science is public administration. This relatively late-developing, highly theoretical offshoot of political science was almost an afterthought in the United States. Even though it developed in the 1880s with the work of Woodrow Wilson, its relations to older parts of political science have been awkward and uneasy. Strangely, public administration tends to develop in spurts, which allows for improvement, but this improvement rarely incorporates older theory. The 1980s and 1990s were marked by administrative reform in western industrial democracies.1 Some of this is attributable to the nature of public administration development in the United States. Rather than adopting the rigid European model of administration, Americans chose to “chink in” an administrative structure, adding functions as merited by need.2 Even so, the development process often ran years behind cited needs. In addition, it was often common to have two or more agencies performing essentially the same task since new methods of administration often disregarded current mechanisms in favor of obtaining independence for the newly-established agency. Of course, a highly theoretical discipline like American public administration would be susceptible to such disorder. The answer to such a quandary lies within developing a single coherent method that describes how public administration really works. Once this framework is established, a single frame of reference can link troublesome pieces in the public administration puzzle, and the level of understanding will permit in-depth investigation of individual variables. This paper will explain how the different theories of public administration can be used in Patricia W. Ingraham, “Play it Again Sam; It’s Still Not Right: Searching for the Right Notes in Administrative Reform.” Public Administration Review, Vol. 57 (July/Aug. 1997), 325-331. Accessed from http://firstsearch.org 19 February 2000. 1 2 Richard J. Stillman II, Preface to Public Administration: A Search for Themes and Direction (Burke, VA: Chatelaine, 1999), 57. 2 tandem to develop a more effective and elusive “grand theory” of public administration. For this purpose, this paper will use the writing of David Rosenbloom to explain how his theories can serve as the backbone for a composite theory. This paper will take Rosenbloom’s predecessors and critics one by one, and attempt to explain how Rosenbloom’s writing is strengthened by their arguments and how Rosenbloom’s reasoning can serve as the framework for understanding other theories of public administration. Indeed, Rosenbloom’s argument was groundbreaking; it advanced a new theory of how the separation of powers interfered with effective bureaucracy. BIOGRAPHY OF DAVID ROSENBLOOM David H. Rosenbloom is a professor of Public Administration at American University in Washington, DC. Dr. Rosenbloom received the 1992 Distinguished Research Award and the 1993 Charles Levine Award for Excellence in Public Administration from the American Society for Public Administration and National Association of Schools of Public Policy and Administration. He serves on the board of a dozen leading public administration journals and his focus areas for research include constitutional and administrative law, administrative history, and theory. ROSENBLOOM’S ARGUMENT Public Administration Theory and the Separation of Powers: A Simple Explanation Rosenbloom’s best known and most cited theory was advanced in his 1983 article, “Public Administration Theory and the Separation of Powers.”3 In this article, Rosenbloom argues that three interrelated approaches to public administration make it difficult for government to perform effectively. Specifically, he cites the legal approach, which relates to the judicial system; the managerial approach, which relates to the executive branch; and the political approach, which David H. Rosenbloom, “Public Administration Theory and the Separation of Powers.” In Jay M. Shafritz, Classics of Public Administration (New York: Harcourt Brace, 1997). 3 3 relates to the legislative branch. Tendencies associated with these three approaches make it extremely difficult for government to identify a problem, decide on a solution, and implement that solution. The legal approach is primarily concerned with defending basic constitutional rights of individuals, safeguarding procedural due process, and its core values are equity and fairness. The organizational structure involves using impartial examiners and the adversarial model, where two sides attempt to fight and clarify their positions, under the basic assumption that the truth is somewhere in the middle. The legal approach views individuals as unique people operating under unique circumstances. Each case has its own particular merits. An example of how Rosenbloom would argue that the legal approach limits the effectiveness of individuals would be in fighting crime. Although crime could be nearly eliminated if police officers arrested every single person walking after midnight, this runs contrary to the system of our system of constitutionally guaranteed freedoms. In the United States, there is a consensus that agrees that individual rights supersede society’s right to take such arbitrary action. Procedural due process, in other words, prevents government from dealing with crime and other goals of administration in the cheapest and easiest way. The managerial approach preaches the values of efficiency, effectiveness, and economy. Organizational structure is designed to emphasize specialization, with the upper echelon of management working as coordinators and facilitators. Civil service jobs, according to this model, should be divided up into the proper agencies; these agencies should then clarify these jobs and classify them. Next, these jobs, the duties of which should be codified, are filled on a merit basis by politically neutral, qualified applicants. This model takes the stance that the individual is not distinct; only position in the hierarchy matters when determining net worth. 4 The classic example of this would be the role of public health epidemiologists during a disease outbreak. Members of this group would plan their attack without input from elected officials or the citizens, and the orders of the President would be obeyed without question. Most complex agencies have a proficient and valuable command structure. Rosenbloom’s third approach is the political approach. This view values representativeness, responsiveness, and accountability. Examples of the trend toward accountability include the proliferation of so-called “sunshine laws,” which require that government meetings be open to the public; and “sunset laws,” which impose definite limits on the duration of programs. To continue a program after the specified, predetermined length of time it is given in a law, the legislature must reenact the program. Not surprisingly, the organizational structure under this model is pluralistic and includes the rights of citizens to access public information. The Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) allows interested citizens to obtain copies of certain documents and records of proceedings so they can conduct their own inquiries. The political approach embraces the view of the employee or civil servant as the member of a group, and the public as a clientele of that group. This approach is very consumer-friendly and responsive to citizens. Rosenbloom’s triple approach can be extrapolated in various ways to relate to many other works of public administration. No matter which aspect of public administration is being studied, Rosenbloom’s approach can be used to analyze that procedure, giving researchers a baseline for developing a comprehensive theory of public administration. In succeeding sections, this paper will explain the implications of Rosenbloom’s argument on the main points of contention within the discipline. It will first define “public administration,” explain the role of the executive, and then discuss how resulting perspectives of public administration ultimately revolve around at least one of Rosenbloom’s three approaches to public administration. 5 Rosenbloom’s approaches are amazingly helpful in reconciling administrative theories. DEFINITION: “PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION” It is proper to begin by defining exactly what constitutes “public administration.” James Skok defines public administration as “the carrying out of policies established by the political (or policy making) elements of the government.”4 For the purposes of this paper, this definition will be used. The implications of using this definition include a sharpening of the politicsadministration dichotomy and accepting the assumption that public administration itself does not influence the policy-making process, an issue this paper will deal with in detail later. The politics-administration dichotomy represents the idea that politics and administration are two separate entities that should be mixed as little as possible. The major benefit of using this definition are its broad base and its emphasis on implementation as a key factor. The chief criticism of this approach lies in the idea that it oversimplifies the dichotomy itself. The logical place to begin the application of Rosenbloom is with the executive branch. GULICK AND THE ROLE OF THE EXECUTIVE One of the earliest to focus on the executive was Luther Gulick, in his 1937 work “Notes on the Theory of Organization.”5 Gulick’s work contained several important connotations for public administration. First, Gulick argues that men differ in nature, capacity, and skill, and therefore a division of work is not only prudent, but mandatory.6 Coordination of work, therefore, requires a capable executive with a written mandate. Gulick coined the word James E. Skok, “Policy Issue Networks and the Public Policy Cycle: A Structural-Functional Framework for Public Administration.” Public Administration Review, V. 55 (July/Aug. 1995), 325-332. Accessed form http://firstsearch.oclc.org. Accessed 19 February 2000. 4 Luther Gulick, “Notes on the Theory of Organization.” In Luther Gulick and L. Urwick, Papers on the Science of Administration (New York: Institute of Public Administration, 1937). 5 6 Gulick, 6. 6 “POSDCORB” to explain the functions of the executive, namely planning, organizing, staffing, directing, coordinating, and budgeting.7 More importantly, Gulick maintained that “A man cannot serve two masters.”8 This “unity of command” allows workers to be more methodical, efficient, and responsible.9 This focus on upper-level management is useful for its structure. Gulick avoided taking a stance on the question of “top-down” or “bottom-up” organization in favor of promoting both. Gulick found that this approach was useful in reorganizing New York City’s sixty departments. Because the number of city departments subject to mayoral oversight could not be brought down to a manageable number without creating serious intra-departmental conflicts and confusion, the City Charter Commission of 1934 recommended a smaller-scale downsizing to twenty-five departments, along with the appointment of three or four assistant mayors.10 This trend has continued into the present era, as “super agencies” have been crated at all levels of government to streamline management control.11 Rosenbloom’s theory corresponds favorably with Gulick’s theory and model in New York City. According to Rosenbloom, public administration’s managerial approach is dependent on a structure arranged hierarchically. “Programs and functions are to be clearly assigned to organizational units. Overlap is to be minimized.”12 Gulick had admitted that a major concern of the New York City project had been the possibility that the new assistant mayors would usurp powers instead of being the eyes and ears of the mayor, who would exercise broad administrative 7 Gulick, 13. 8 Gulick, 9. 9 Gulick, 9. 10 Gulick, 12. 11 Philip E. Present, People and Public Administration (Pacific Palisades, CA: Palisades, 1979), 99. 12 Rosenbloom in Shafritz, 433. 7 power and ultimate decision-making authority power.13 Rosenbloom’s theory argues that it is precisely this view of the individual bureaucrat as a “‘cog’ in an organizational machine over which he/she has virtually no control” that is characteristic of the managerial approach.14 The values emphasized by such an approach become obvious. The organization reigns supreme over the individual, and administration is to determine what government can do, and do achieve these goals with the least possible expenditure of time, energy, or money. In New York City, this was demonstrated by the stress placed on the need to preserve the principle of homogeneity, which was solved by requiring the new assistant mayors to remove themselves from the “technology of the services and devote themselves to the broad aspects of administration and co-ordination.”15 While what Gulick supported fit with Rosenbloom’s managerial approach, Gulick’s problem was that he did not balance it out with a political and legal perspective. IMPLEMENTATION At its core, the study of public administration is a study of implementation; it is an evaluation of whether policy can be put into practice. The chief architects of theories concerning implementation of bureautically-derived policies are Jeffrey Pressman and Aaron Wildavsky.16 Wildavsky defines implementation by the dictionary definition, “to carry out, accomplish, fulfill, produce, complete.”17 Writing in the 1970s, the two used the federal government intervention in Oakland as a classic example of how policy enacted in Washington frequently fails to affect the 13 Gulick, 12. 14 Rosenbloom in Shafritz, 433. 15 Gulick, 12. 16 Jeffrey L. Pressman and Aaron B. Wildavsky, Implementation (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1974). 17 Pressman and Wildavsky, xiii. 8 individual on the street. In 1966, the newly-created Economic Development Administration (EDA) was seeking a target destination for its endowment of $23 million dollars. The EDA was under the Department of Commerce, and until the mid 1960s, the agency had concentrated its aid in rural areas, which was its jurisdiction.18 Its authorizing act was the Public Works and Economic Development Act, passed into law on August 26, 1965. This legislation was created to stimulate economic development and aid recovery in areas of the country which were suffering through depletion of a natural resource, like gold or timber, or an area that was shifting from reliance on one natural resource to another.19 Suddenly, the agency did an about-face and selected Oakland, California as the first site where it would try to rebuild cities, eliminate poverty, and quell racial tensions by redressing unemployment. The agency ignored its original directive and chose to implement its own policy. Douglas Murray McGregor claims that “noncompliance tends to appear in the presence of perceived threat.”20 Herbert Kaufman concurs, and argues that “people who calculate that they will be worse off under the proposed changes than they would be under the status quo often will not cooperate with them.”21 This indeed seems to have been the case here. The political process often results in a serious misallocation of resources. Logically, other cities like Chicago, Los Angeles, or New York, which already had suffered riots, would be first in line to receive funds. Still, Eugene Foley, the Assistant Secretary of Commerce and the head of EDA, choose to spend the EDA’s funds in Oakland rather than another large city because it 18 Pressman and Wildavsky, 1. 19 Pressman and Wildavsky, 7. 20 Douglas Murray McGregor, The Professional Manager (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967), 118. 21 Herbert Kaufman, Time, Change, and Organizations: Natural selection in a Perilous Environment (Chatham, NJ: Chatham House, 1985), 53. 9 had a Republican administration, and if there had been quarrels with a mayor in the city chosen, Foley “did not want some Democratic mayor—like Daley—to be able to pick up the phone and call President Johnson.”22 Even more appalling, the agency had too much free rein in determining which business enterprises were eligible for funds. Because of a tight time schedule, and the pressure imposed by the Watts riot in Los Angeles, the EDA’s hands were tied. Tension and foreboding were combined with stringent budgetary requirements. Funds were available in the 1965 budget, but if they were not used within four months, the money would be lost.23 The end result was that, three years later, only $3 million had been spent, and most of that was spent on one highway overpass and architect’s fees.24 Jobs created were largely temporary, and very small in number. Rosenbloom’s discussion of implementation is found indirectly within his legal and political approaches. The view of the individual emphasizes procedural and substantive due process, placing the interests of the individual above society. Organizations under the legal approach focus on individuals, who are guaranteed basic rights, which include certain rights of obstruction. Public administration under the political approach values responsiveness, representativeness, and accountability. Clearly, the political approach led to the selection of Oakland as a beneficiary of EDA funds. EDA directors, alarmed by the riots that had been taking place in the inner cities, thought they could make a contribution by diverting their funds to a city with the right preconditions for a riot. Oakland was an obvious target. The fact that Oakland city government was viewed as non-hostile led to the realization that a plan to hire minorities would promote political pluralism, another key concept embedded in the political 22 Pressman and Wildavsky, 14-15. 23 Pressman and Wildavsky, 138. 24 Pressman and Wildavsky, xi. 10 approach of Rosenbloom. Not surprisingly, Rosenbloom claims that this approach has been widely denounced as making government “unmanageable, costly, and inefficient.”25 Therefore, McGregor’s idea that managerial strategies can induce commitment may actually be dangerous in circumstances such as these.26 Instead, should one desire to change policy, it is wiser to approach the problem by using no coercive techniques to push the bureaucrat down the desired road. Leonard White lists several, including educational campaigns and compliance through publicity.27 Kenneth Meier takes a more extreme view.28 He remarks that “zero-base budgeting, management by objectives, reform in the civil service structure, reinventing government, and planned programmed budgeting systems are “efforts to convince us that bureaucracy is the problem with governance in the United States.”29 The real problem, according to Meier, is that good policy can be political suicide in the short run. For example, because the government has a limited supply of funds, Congress deals with the Social Security system by creating an “intergenerational transfer of wealth,” which creates intergenerational conflict that Congress failed to address.30 Congress, in essence, has failed as a deliberative body, and gridlock is the major reason American public administration is worse off than its European counterpart.31 To 25 Rosenbloom in Shafritz, 435. 26 Douglas Murray McGregor, The Professional Manager, 129. 27 Leonard White, Introduction to the Study of Public Administration (New York: Macmillan, 1946), 469-477. Kenneth J. Meier, “Bureaucracy and Democracy: The Case for More Bureaucracy and Less Democracy.” Public Administration Review, V. 57 (May/June 1997), 193-199. Accessed from http://firstsearch.org 19 February 2000. 28 29 Quoted in Meier. 30 Meier. 31 Meier. 11 resolve this problem, which is the exact problem Rosenbloom cites as his “political approach,” Meier advocates redesigning the political system to eliminate some checks and balances, making United States government more like British or Canadian government.32 Tacitly, this admits that the Rosenbloom approach is correct, based on Meier’s willingness to scrap the monkey wrenches in the system cited by Rosenbloom. Next, Meier wants to lengthen the time frame for public policy making and manipulate the system to favor a long-term, rather than a short-term policy approach, through the use of longer terms for elected officials.33 Conceivably, this would allow executives to be better managers, as they would not need to be quite as responsive to the whims of a changeable electorate. In fact, Meier fails to recognize one other aspect of this point. The European bureaucracies he champions all have elected executives with terms longer than that of the United States President. In Great Britain, the Prime Minister serves a term up to five years, and in France, the President serves a seven year term. Both are re-electable at least once, and in Britain, the shorter term is compensated for by a greatly shortened election process compared to the United States. Executives in these Western European democracies can concentrate on longterm contingency planning, without fear of upsetting the electorate or engaging in reelection campaigns that in the United States seem to begin shortly after inauguration. Since it is unlikely that we will adopt the British model, Rosenbloom is helpful in clarifying how the United States system combines political and legal insights in the pursuit of efficiency. So, we see that Rosenbloom combines with other works to achieve innovative and pragmatic solutions. BUDGETING Meier hinted that intimately related to the troubles of implementation is the problem of 32 Meier. 33 Meier. 12 budgeting. A budget is “a document, containing words and figures, which proposes expenditures for certain items and purposes.”34 At best, budgets can be a tool to help achieve the objectives of an organization. At worst, budgets create unfair expectations, obstruct the process by dictating how money will be spent, and create resentment that leads an agency to backlash and devote itself to causes other than its original mission, as we have seen occurred in Oakland with EDA. Budgets are measured both quantitatively and qualitatively. James Q. Wilson points out, “bureaucracies are often prepared to accept less money with greater control than more money with less control.”35 Wilson provides the example of Robert McNamara, the Secretary of Defense under Presidents Kennedy and Johnson, whose budget was considerably higher than his predecessors and successors, including Melvin Laird, who despite having a smaller budget, was a far more popular secretary of defense among the military services.36 The reason for this discrepancy is that McNamara embraced a PPBS, or planned, programmed budgeting system. McNamara saw the budget as a tool to achieve goals, whereas Laird, when he took office, slashed the budget but allowed the individual services to determine where the savings would come from. Laird cut the budget twenty-eight percent during his tenure, resulting in the loss of army divisions, ships, and total personnel.37 Still, each service continued its own pt projects; the Navy was free to continue developing its high-performance, pricey F-14 fleet defense fighter, and the army was permitted to continue research into technological communications breakthroughs. 34 Aaron Wildavsky, The Politics of the Budgetary Process (Boston: Little, Brown, 1974), 1. 35 James Q. Wilson, Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It (New York: Harper Collins, 1989), 179. 36 Wilson, 179. 37 Wilson, 179. 13 This is an example of the coordination of Rosenbloom’s managerial and political principals. The amount of leverage given to individual agencies is a managerial question typical of what Frederick Mosher labels the “political challenge.”38 The product of egalitarianism, knowledge expansion, and management, the political challenge represents the fact that politics is the enemy of career systems, and that many systems, including the military, actually grew up in opposition to politics.39 Knowing that the military services function as one of these enemies eliminates the ability to use the budget as a tool to achieve specific objectives. True, budgets can achieve overall goals; but it must be accepted that when dealing with career systems agencies, it is best to not force specific tactics. Hence, the politics of coercion and the price paid for enforcing that coercion play a major role in the calculations of bureaucrats like Laird. McNamara, as a Washington outsider, could not or would not recognize this fact. THE EFFECT OF INTEREST-GROUP LIBERALISM Like Rosenbloom, Theodore Lowi has noticed the problems resulting from the political approach.40 Lowi argues that pluralism, which he terms “interest-group liberalism,” was an effective tool in American government because it made the “state an acceptable source of power in a capitalist society.”41 Unfortunately, according to Lowi, “The zeal of pluralism for the group and its belief in natural harmony tended to break down the very ethic of government.”42 Interest groups have gained such power that it is difficult to determine whether interest groups influence 38 Frederick C. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982), 173. 39 Mosher, 172-173. 40 Theodore J. Lowi, The End of Liberalism: Ideology, Policy, and the Crisis of Public Authority (New York: W. W. Norton, 1969). 41 Lowi, 48. 42 Lowi, 48. 14 policy or actually make it. Long-range contingency planning within government is now gone, and the informal politicking of lobbyists threatens both government ethics and the rules structure, which as a result cannot be codified. Robert K. Merton agrees, and states that formality facilitates the interaction of the occupants of government offices.43 According to Merton, “A formal, rationally organized social structure involves clearly defined patterns of activity in which, ideally, every series of actions is functionally related to the purposes of the organization.”44 If a bureaucracy is to function effectively, it must exert constant pressure on officials to be “methodical, prudent, and disciplined.”45 This view agrees with Charles E. Lindblom, who argues that government cannot decide on a path of action and stay the course, and instead chooses to “muddle through.”46 Rosenbloom, of course, bases his political argument on the premise that the accountability of elected officials and administrative appointees are “crucial to the maintenance of constitutional democracy.”47 But to accept this, we must discount the idea that all bureaucrats behave in a predictable, rational manner, or else Merton’s view will turn against Rosenbloom and imply that politics, management, and the law are distinct from one another. DISMANTLING “RATIONAL ACTOR” Beyond the relatively simple question of “muddling through,” because of political discord, government faces another quandary that often produces the same result. Often in political Robert K. Merton, “Bureaucratic Structure and Personality.” In Robert K. Merton, et al., Reader in Bureaucracy (Glencoe, IL: The Free Press, 1952). 43 44 Merton, 361. 45 Merton, 365. 46 Charles E. Lindblom and David K. Cohen, Usable Knowledge: Social Science and Social Problem Solving (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1979). 47 Rosenbloom, “Public Administration Theory and the Separation of Powers,” 434. 15 science, there is a tendency to accept a “rational-actor” theory, which states that an actor will attempt to maximize gains after performing a cost-benefit analysis of the available “facts.” The operative term, of course, is “facts.” Rarely do government organizations know everything. Combine this with the fact that organizations are run my people with material concerns. That is, instead of running the organization benignly, policymakers are inclined to further there own political agenda, which frequently is fueled by misperception in the first place. It is this problem of misperception that Lindblom addresses. He identifies several occasions in the policy process where misperception is free to enter. The first is the stage where analysis meets interaction. Lindblom quotes Thomas Dye as stating, “The solution of societal problems generally implies a rational model,” and that model “requires complete understanding.”48 Yet, according to Lindblom, these models “seem to deny—sometimes flatly and with ambiguity—the frequency with which interactions solve problems without anyone’s understanding or analysis.”49 So if one extreme is possible, it is also similarly possible that despite the “best” information available, government organizations are still unlikely to overcome problems. Herbert Simon generally agrees, but takes the idea a step forward.50 Simon argues that not only can government agencies make incorrect decisions when confronted with information, but that it is impossible for bureaucrats to have all the information required, or at least unlikely that a large quantity of information can be accurately processed and analyzed. Simon writes, “Limits include (a) limits on his ability to perform and (b) limits on his ability to make correct decisions.”51 But 48 Quoted in Lindblom, 30. 49 Quoted in Lindblom, 30. 50 Herbert A. Simon, Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organizations, Third Edition (New York: Macmillan, 1976. 51 Simon, 39. 16 knowledge of consequences is difficult, and one error made about the future destroys the schema of the decision maker, which forces yet another reevaluation of values.52 Herbert Kaufman concurred, and argued for a need to reshape government bureaucracy so it was more representative, decentralized, and composed of neutral, competent bureaucrats.53 It is precisely this representativeness that Paul Appleby cites when he explains what makes government different from private enterprise. Can the same style of management and supervision succeed equally in both realms? Appleby says that the politics-administration dichotomy was a self-imposed restriction that held no consistency with real-world functioning of bureaucracy. Politics, according to Appleby, was removable from public administration. Appleby wrote, “This difference is a fact and I believe it to be so big that the dissimilarity between government and all other forms of social action is greater than any dissimilarity among those other from themselves.”54 Rosenbloom reconciles all of these contributing ideologies. Simon writes, “The principle of efficiency should be considered as a definition rather than a principle: it is a definition of what is meant by ‘good’ or ‘correct’ administrative behavior. It does not tell how accomplishments are to be maximized, but merely states that this maximization is the aim of administrative activity.” 55 Simon gives lip service to the hope that managers strive for efficiency , but he is actually promoting the idea that efficiency may not be the best way to get things done. It is merely a goal, an objective, not mandatory. It may be even better achieved if vigorous public participation guides management. 52 Simon, 80-81, 243. 53 Shafritz, 170. 54 Paul Appleby, Big Democracy (New York: Knopf, 1945). 55 Simon, 39. 17 The representation Kaufman would prefer to have conflicts with the ideas of Frank J. Goodnow, the founder of the politics-administration dichotomy. Goodnow was a pioneer writer in the field of public administration, and was the first to differentiate the ideas of “politics” and “administration.”56 Goodnow wrote, “The principle of separation of powers in its extreme form cannot. . . be made the basis of any concrete political organization. For this principle demands that there shall be separate authorities of the government, each of which shall be confined to the discharge of one of the functions of government.”57 This limitation then leads to a consideration of where the demarcation between politics and administration lies. Goodnow answers, “practical political necessity makes impossible the consideration of the function of politics apart from that of administration. Politics must have a certain control over administration.”58 Because Goodnow argues that “the function of politics. . . consists in the expression of the will of the state,” “if no attempt is made in the governmental system to provide for the separation of politics and administration. . . the control and superintendence of the function of administration tends to be assumed by the governmental body which discharges the political function.”59 In other words, Goodnow fears that any diminution of the politics-administration dichotomy will eliminate one of the checks on power imposed by the Constitution’s separation of powers. Appleby claimed that political involvement was a benefit, since “Government administration differs from all other administrative work to a degree not even faintly realized outside, by virtue of its public nature, the way in which it is subject to public scrutiny and public outcry.”60 Frank J. Goodnow, “Politics and Administration” in Jay M. Shaft Ritz, ed. Classics of Public Administration, Fourth Edition (Fort Worth: Harcourt-Brace, 1997). 56 57 Goodnow in Shafritz, 28-29. 58 Goodnow in Shafritz, 29. 59 Goodnow in Shaft Ritz, 28-29. 18 So, representation by its very nature seems to be opposed to the politics-administration dichotomy, which itself is opposed to efficiency because of the links it promotes in its change of command and the fact that officials need to report to more than one leader. But if we look at the process as essentially one which develops a general strategy, then strategy, and only then tactics, then this approach is a wholly accurate description. The key to bringing these interpretations together lies in recognizing the separation of powers; as does Rosenbloom, Dwight Waldo remarked that the politics-administration dichotomy “tells us nothing at all about the organs to which these functions should be assigned, or the desirable relationships among these organs.”61 But since Waldo, those who dismiss the dichotomy, have automatically assumed that since no clear cut definition exists, then the entire process is unworkable. Rosenbloom’s theory legitimizes the dichotomy as a constricting device that limits the ability of administrators to complete tasks with wild abandon. At the same time, though, Rosenbloom is quick to point out that the inability of administrators to push programs through to completion often contributes to better policy. This raises the question: Does the public policy making process impact public administration, or does public administration impact the public policy making process? With respect to core functions, that is a difficult question to answer. Michael Lipsky points out a problem with bureaucracy in his book Street Level Bureaucracy.62 Lipsky defines “street level bureaucrats” as workers such as police officers, teachers, and others who receive considerable discretion while 60 Appleby, Big Democracy, 7. 61 Dwight Waldo, The Administrative State: A Study of the Political Theory of American Public Administration (New York: Ronald Press, 1948), 115. 62 Michael Lipsky, Street Level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Services (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1980). 19 completing tasks assigned to them. Lipsky claims that certain job circumstances, such as work overloads or harsh working conditions, or personal needs for security or fulfillment can persuade street-level bureaucrats to simplify their jobs, usually resulting in a shirking of responsibility. Many of these street level bureaucrats have some sort of expertise gained either on the job or through special training programs. It is disconcerting, therefore, that Warren Bennis points out that “there is a positive correlation between [level of] education and need for autonomy.”63 Daniel Katz and Robert Kahn point out that personality factors can be the “determinants of role expectations.”64 Street level bureaucrats have “great discretion in their interactions with clients,” which equates “description with prescription.”65 Effectively, Rosenbloom’s theory could have a corollary which would state that political ineffectiveness, specifically the inability for politicians to specify managerial control of the functions of street-level bureaucrats, will lead to managerial ineffectiveness because “it is unlikely that the. . .approaches can be synthesized without violating values deeply ingrained in the United States political culture.66 Rosenbloom’s theory, however, accommodates street-level discretion better than others. But the people are ultimately supreme. Appleby concedes, “Because of these circumstances, every governmental executive lives and moves and has his being in the presence of public dynamite. Every action he may take is influenced by his condition—whether before or after an explosion. . . .In a narrow sense, government is less efficient because of its public nature.”67 63 Warren G. Bennis, Changing Organizations: Essays on the Development and Evolution of Human Organization (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1966), 11. 64 Daniel Katz and Robert Kahn, The Social Psychology of Organizations (New York: Wiley, 1967), 193. Richard E. Matland, “Synthesizing the Implementation Literature,” In Richard J. Stillman, Public Administration Concepts and Cases, Seventh Edition (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 2000), 410. 65 66 Rosenbloom in Shafritz, 432 67 Appleby, Big Democracy, 8. 20 Public input can occur either before or after the fact, and indeed Appleby is convinced that “The part played by criticism after a decision has been reached , a program launched, is not sufficiently understood or appreciated. . . . popular discussion and criticism after the fact has far greater value than it has before the fact.”68 Appleby sees genuine value in debate before the process, but once a decision has been made, it is only prudent that debate should be ended and administrators given the green light to do their jobs. The only problem with that is that administrators are rarely indifferent in their political views, and organizations promote these increases in influence. So, the debate between representativeness and the value of the politicsadministration dichotomy hinges on the question of when each component, politics or administration, is predominant at which times during the process. This of course, means that the political approach begins the process, then surrenders its authority to the managerial process, whose arbitrary actions can be checked by the legal process. Anthony Downs discusses the organization structure of agencies with respect to their individual components. According to Downs, bureaucratic study must include an examination of the life cycles of bureaus, which are influenced greatly by the personalities of workers inside those bureaus.69 Workers can be identified as climbers, conservers, zealots, advocates, or statesmen.70 Climbers are the pertinent members in this discussion. Downs claims that climbers are seeking to acquire specific functions not performed by anyone else in the bureau, and has strong incentives not to economize.71 Politically, to achieve this agenda, a climber must be aggressive, ignore official policy, and behave flamboyantly to become noticed, even if this 68 Appleby, Big Democracy, 83. 69 Anthony Downs, Inside Bureaucracy (Glenview, IL: Scott Foresman, 1967). 70 Downs, 88. 71 Downs, 92, 94. 21 means shirking official policy. By doing this, administrators frequently fulfill the requirement of being responsible to clientele groups.72 This is the primary reason for the blurring between when the managerial, political, and legal processes are acting. The second stage identified by Lindblom as an entry point for misperception is at the individual decision-maker level. Even more important than the nature of the problem itself is how the officer charged with eliminating it views the problem. If the problem is dismissed as insignificant, remedies will be slow in coming. In addition, Lindblom correctly points out that “an interactive process will eventuate in a decision that can be attributed to an official or committee; but often not. Instead, the outcome will emerge from such interactions as, for example, when a price is established in a competitive market without anyone playing the role of price setter. The price is more a happening than any one person’s decision to establish it, even if thousands of buying and selling decisions lead to the result.”73 This analogy directly relates to Rosenbloom’s “political approach.” Policies are the result of a similar process. Constituents often dictate policy concerns to their elected officials, who then attempt to formulate responses in the form of legislation or administrative overhaul. E. Pendleton Herring agrees with this assessment, and sees the accompanying dangers.74 Herring wrote that legislatures can pass laws that fall into disfavor through institutional personification.75 Meanwhile, the obtrusive law may not garner enough dissent to be changed, 72 Herbert A. Simon, Donald W. Smithburg, and Victor A. Thompson, Public Administration (New York: Knopf, 1964), 413. 73 Lindblom, 33. E. Pendleton Herring, “Public Administration and the Public Interest.” In Jay M. Shafritz, ed., Classics of public Administration, Fourth Edition (Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt-Brace, 1997),76-81. 74 75 Herring, “Public Administration,” in Shafritz, 77. 22 despite the fact that it does not promote its original interests. Legislative reform may not be possible because of “a change of economic or political conditions” that “may alter the alignment of social forces.”76 Herring states, “Upon the shoulders of the bureaucrat has been placed in large part the burden of reconciling group differences and making effective and workable the economic and social compromises arrived at through the legislative process.” In other words, the bureaucrat, who is “in a better position than the legislators,” has the duty of fleshing out vague laws.77 “The words of the statute limit his purpose, but within the margin of his discretion he must write his interpretation of state purpose.”78 (emphasis mine). Rosenbloom argues that not only is this possible, but it is preferable. Congress’s job is to provide a general policy program. It is the bureaucrat’s job to provide a strategy for implementing that program, and job of “streetlevel” bureaucrats to develop tactics. Perhaps that is where the policy goes awry. THE EFFECT OF STRUCTURE ON GOVERNMENT ORGANIZATIONS Not surprisingly, public administration is often under the knife, usually under the auspices of “reinventing government.”79 Many have suggested reinventing the politics-administration dichotomy, in an effort to recreate the balance between input and output. Yet, the very nature of the American system of public administration precludes such sweeping change. Barbara Coe argues that “The concept of structural conflict explains much of what occurs when organizations move forward in a determined and vigorous matter, then move away from the target, oscillating and often ultimately giving up on their (original) goal.”80 This prompts us to ask why 76 Herring, “Public Administration.” In Shafritz, 77-78. 77 Herring, “Public Administration,” in Shafritz, 76. 78 Herring, “Public Administration,” in Shafritz, 76. H. George Frederickson, “Comparing the Reinventing Government Movement with Public Administration.” Public Administration Review, Vol. 56 (May/June 1996). Accessed from http://firstsearch.org 19 February 2000. 79 Barbara A. Coe, “How Structural Conflicts Stymie Reinvention.” Public Administration Review, Vol. 57 (March/April 1997), 168-173. Accessed from http://firstsearch.org 19 February 2000. 80 23 government organizations that have outlived their usefulness persist, missionless, and why many government organizations have concurrent powers that promulgate inefficiency The classic work on this subject is Herbert Kaufman’s 1976 work “Are Government Organizations Immortal?”81 Kaufman argues that government organizations are indeed essentially immortal, and this is the result of an evolution between 1923 and 1973.82 Components favoring long agency life include difficulty in overturning legislation, the sheltering of independent organizations like the Post Office, and the size of the federal budget.83 Kaufman argues that agencies develop their own clientele; this clientele routinely incorporates many of the ideas advanced by Rosenbloom’s “political approach. According to Kaufman, “whether an agency provides services for its clients or regulates them, its clientele can frequently be counted on to come to its assistance when it is in trouble.”84 In addition, agencies who compete frequently “divide the field” so their competition for resources in the form of tax dollars does not drive either agency out of business.85 So we also see that the political approach forces agencies to act in rational ways to preserve their power. Agencies frequently take on new, additional missions as a by-product of the fight to remain alive when they are challenged by new agencies that infringe on their territory. Kaufman points out several examples where politics has forced agencies to modify their original mandate. There is considerable tension between the Bureau of Customs and the Immigration and Naturalization Service with regard to smuggling on 81 Herbert Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal? (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1976). 82 Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal, 29. 83 Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal, 3-7 84 Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal, 11. 85 Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal, 15. 24 the U.S.-Mexican border.86 It is quite possible that prosecution of smugglers could be conducted purely through either agency, and funds diverted to the most capable agency. Instead, the two organizations conduct their own operations almost independently, resulting a waste of time, energy, and taxpayer dollars. Yet, Rosenbloom helps here as well, since simple efficiency is no the primary goal. In fact, the redundancy imposed by such a system often leads to fewer smugglers falling through the cracks. Another example is the frustration experienced by various other agencies towards representing the government in court. Currently, the Justice Department holds a monopoly on this privilege.87 General counsel of various agencies are likely to be more cognizant of the special circumstances concerning cases their agency brings, yet, bureaucratic structure and rules prevent them from representing their agencies, which leads to uninformed Department of Justice lawyers wasting more taxpayer dollars. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC), for example, shares power with the Justice Department to regulate business and prevent monopolies. Yet, the FTC cannot bring a case to challenge the practices of a certain business; it can only request that the department of Justice investigate the matter. This wastes time and money, and allows the business extra time to cut a deal with the Justice Department, after already failing to do so with the FTC. The FTC has been especially aware of threats to its longevity. When the Consumer Product Safety Commission (CPSC) was created, the FTC rushed to begin prosecuting the “most politically powerful industries in the nation—life insurance, the legal, medical, and other professions, automobiles, and pharmaceuticals.”88 It pursued these industries for two reasons; 86 Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal, 15. 87 Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Immortal, 15. Mark V. Nadel, “Making Regulatory Policy.” In Allen Schick, ed. Making Economic Policy in Congress (Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 1983), 227. 88 25 first it tried to reassert its role in protecting consumers, and secondly, because that role had been taken, the FTC was forced to justify it existence by pressing aggressively on another track. This drastic change in policy was the result of the CSPC usurping the power of the FTC to regulate industries for the benefit of consumers. As a result of the massive number of prosecutions, Congress was inundated with requests from lobbyists to curtail the power of the FTC. This is an indication of how politics drives the policy-making process. These two examples are typical of the way that the political requirements of pubic administration impair the effectiveness and efficiency of various organs in the system. We would expect a backlash because of this intense level of control, but Rosenbloom’s theory addresses drawbacks to such an approach. Rosenbloom reminds us, “public administration is an intensely political process that should be responsive to interested publics and legislators.”89 Kaufman agrees, and states that reforms should incorporate central values, which include administration through executive leadership, representativeness, and decentralization to promote better oversight, even if such systems compromises national mandates for economic and social equality.90 Although Rosenbloom and Kaufman differ on the merits of such a system, it can still be concluded that Rosenbloom’s model is a true model of the American system of public administration. The implications can seem bleak. The above cases suggest a runaway bureaucracy, one that is self-sustaining and looks out for its own interests. Yet, bureaucracy sometimes needs freer reins. Peter Grier points out some of the problems that result from too much upper level management.91 NASA, in response to Congressional cost 89 Quoted in Barbara Coe. Herbert Kaufman, “Administration, Decentralization, and Political Power.” In Jay M. Shafritz, ed., Classics of Public Administration, Fourth Edition (Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt-Brace, 1997), 289, 291, 296-297. 90 91 Grier, Peter. “At NASA, Signs of Too Much Scrimping.” Christian Science Monitor 29 March 2000. 26 cutting, has been forced to adopt a “faster, better, cheaper” philosophy of operations. 92 This has led to a reduction in staffing, which eliminated many internal testing programs for components. This policy has had drastic effects on NASA’s efficiency and success. The Mars Observer and Mars Polar Lander both disappeared or quit responding, and engine seals for the new International Space Station are reputed to be cheaply made, requiring astronauts to wear earplugs while they are in use.93 Clearly, pushing too hard for government efficiency can result in substandard products that actually waste more money than they save. THE RESULTING QUESTIONS OF ETHICS One of the ethical dilemmas of political science results from the “political power struggle underlying the politics-administration dichotomy.”94 Herring addresses another ethical dilemma, political neutrality. Herring defines political neutrality as “loyalty to the broad social purpose to which the country seems to be committed.”95 In reexamining the relationship between the role of the administrator to political parties, Herring was disturbed to find that the requirement for administrators to follow the policies of the party in power were being shunned. Many of the important regulatory functions have been given to “quasi-judicial tribunals,” which have considerable autonomy from the political process.96 In addition, to Theodore Lowi’s dismay, Paul Appleby points out that “Administrators in a modern liberal regime will be more attentive to pressures from popular groups than they are in a conservative regime.”97 Patricia 92 Grier, Peter. “At NASA, Signs of Too Much Scrimping.” Christian Science Monitor 29 March 2000, 1 . 93 Grier, Peter. “At NASA, Signs of Too Much Scrimping.” Christian Science Monitor 29 March 2000, 1-2. Eliza Wing-yee Lee, “Political Science, Public Administration, and the Rise of the American Administrative State.” Public Administration Vol.55 (Nov./Dec. 1995), 538-546. Accessed from http://firstsearch.org 19 February 2000. 94 95 96 E. Pendleton Herring, The Politics of Democracy: American Parties in Action (New York: Rinehart, 1940), 379. E. Pendleton Herring, The Politics of Democracy, 379. 27 Wallace Ingraham sees this question a little differently; she frames it as one of “Neutrality versus Responsiveness.”98 She cites two major trends that undermine the ability of the civil service to adjust when elections prompt changes in the ideology of the government. First, Ingraham claims that the very structure of the civil service, which is designed to prevent undue external political influence, combines with an ever-increasing bureaucracy and its operating procedures to isolate civil servants from changes imposed by new administrations.99 Second, the esoteric and complex nature of new programs has forced bureaucrats to become active in the actual decision-making process, in addition to their role of carrying out decisions.100 Rosenbloom’s methodology provides each of his approaches with ethical challenges.101 The managerial model dictates that agency heads be singular rather than plural to emphasize responsibility and accountability.102 Second, by definition, this system demands strict subordination. Because of this intensive power concentrated in managers, a limited span of control is essential. Rosenbloom argues, “just as plural leadership was considered inappropriate, members are expected to be loyal to the organization and their managers.103 Disciplinary measures enforce that provision. Finally, internal audits promote accountability. These form the bases for ethics under the managerial approach. They serve as checks against Lowi’s concerns 97 Paul Appleby, Policy and Administration (Birmingham, AL: University of Alabama Press, 1949), 122. 98 Patricia Wallace Ingraham, The Foundation of Merit: Public Service in American Democracy (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press, 1995), xix. 99 Ingraham, xix. 100 Ingraham, xix-xx. 101 David Rosenbloom, Public Administration: Understanding Management, Politics, and Law in the Public Sector (New York: Random House, 1989). 102 Rosenbloom, Public Administration, 475. 103 Rosenbloom, Public Administration, 475-476. 28 of runaway liberalism and strengthen Ingraham’s argument. Ingraham maintains that neutrality is an important value in pubic administration. Rosenbloom takes that idea a little farther. According to Rosenbloom, “a public administrator who is unwilling to follow orders is expected to leave his or her post.”104 There is no room for squabbling or compromising; proficiency compels any administrator to leave if they cannot carry out their objectives. This harsh reality is balanced as technology and government growth allows lower-level administrators to take a more active role in establishing policy, often times stretching laws as far as possible. Unlike the managerial approach, the political approach to ethics involves significant external, rather than internal, mechanisms. Legislative oversight, budgetary control, office rotation, and public participation dampen the tendency of organizations to seize power.105 “Sunshine laws” and the Freedom of Information act also allow citizens to monitor organizations.106 External checks are particularly helpful in placating Lowi, but they also remedy Herring’s concerns. Herring’s primary concern is that administrators will not be responsive to the party in power, and will instead follow their own agenda or preserve the status quo initiated by the former party in power. Rosenbloom’s theory, though, contains ethical safeguards that make such behavior unlikely. The external nature of the controls and the incentives provided for “whistle blowers” make it abundantly clear that anyone exposing their organization’s shortcoming will be rewarded. In addition, because the party in power in the United States must win a majority of votes, any willful disobedience of directives would be a disobedience of the public in general, which would surely be noticed and condemned by the public. Therefore, it is unlikely that an organization could pursue a policy contradictory to that of the government, and the fact that 104 Rosenbloom, Public Administration, 475. 105 Rosenbloom, Public Administration, 477-479. 106 Rosenbloom, Public Administration, 479-480. 29 directors are appointed by the President emphatically deny any organizations that try to push their prerogatives. The legal approach also has distinct ethical ramifications. Constitutional values and requirements, although not as frequently used against the managerial and political approaches, have far greater power when they are invoked. The judicial system is unique in that it provides public administrators with powerful incentives to respect the constitutional rights of those they encounter while performing their official duties.107 The primary enforcement tool here is the power of those injured to seek redress in the civil courts. This is the key; by limiting the power of administrators, the American political system closes the gap created by the growth of government. Discretion in adopting policy is diluted, and administrators cannot completely concentrate on adopting a managerial approach to achieve goals in an expeditious fashion, while sacrificing whomever gets in the way. In this way, the legal system provides the most important safeguard against especially egregious administrative behavior. To cope with this challenge, Dwight Waldo lists a series of obligations civil servants have: to the Constitution, to law, to nation, to democracy, to bureaucratic norms, to professionalism, to family, to friends, to the public interest, to humanity, and to God.108 Perhaps the best part of Rosenbloom’s model is that its three-pronged approach promotes these ethics on three semi-parallel fronts that allow the defense and pursuit of ethics from more than one source. THE FUTURE With the rise of what Stillman terms a “global professional technocracy,” public administration will be asked to contend with more dilemmas.109 According to Stillman, the 107 Rosenbloom, Public Administration, 451. 108 Dwight Waldo, The Enterprise of Public Administration (Novato, CA: Chandler and Sharp, 1980), 103-106. 109 Richard J. Stillman, Preface, 82. 30 characteristics of such a system are sheer size and technical complexity, transitory professionals that move in and out of government agencies with ease, new technology and its global spread, the meshing of powers, the invention of new human liberties, and the new “fifth estate” of government.110 The most interesting of these developments is the “meshing of powers” concept. According to Stillman, the Constitutional concept of the separation of powers had been eroded into a system where “separated institutions sharing powers.”111 Stillman fails to cite any concrete examples of this though, and perfunctorily states that “the executive branch is deeply involved in the messy realities of legislative and judicial activities, as well as vice-versa, across a wide spectrum of activities from nuclear disarmament to local welfare policies.”112 Rosenbloom, on the other hand, argues that it is this separation of powers that causes problems in public administration. So who is right? Stillman seems to confuse activities and realities. True, it is common for executives and administrators in public agencies to cooperate, but usually this cooperation takes the form of resource-sharing. It is possible for two completely different federal agencies to have the same goal. For example, in cases of ecological or environmental disaster clean up, the Environmental Protection Agency’s primary goals are to contain the damage, treat the affected are in the most cost-effective manner, and to restore as much territory as possible to normal status. The cabinet agency of Housing and Urban Development, on the other hand, is solely interested in making sure that Americans have safe and adequate housing. The mission of these two agencies is entirely different. But if we apply a specific case, like the cleanup of the Love Canal site in Buffalo, New York, we see that both agencies had something 110 Richard J. Stillman, Preface, 82-87. 111 Richard J. Stillman, Preface, 84. 112 Richard J. Stillman, Preface, 84. 31 to gain by working together. In cases like these, both sides would be foolish to conduct their own ecological and chemical damage studies, when a single study and a copy machine would suffice. Cases like these of resource-pooling are common, and do not contradict Rosenbloom. CONCLUSION Clearly, there is no one “correct” theory of public administration. This paper merely attempts to find a coherent method of organizing the available writings in the doctrine so that they can be analyzed in a similar frame of reference. As it stands now, the closest attempt to create a broad based, all-encompassing theory is that of David Rosenbloom. His three approaches, the “managerial approach,” the “political approach,” and the “legal approach” best summarize the barriers to effective public administration. The scope of the theories presented here in comparison vary by discipline, time period, and motivation. Somehow, in each of these competing theories, Rosenbloom is present. By adopting the Rosenbloom framework as a basis for future study, these competing ideologies can be unified into a grand theory of public administration. Whether we are examining the executive, implementation, methods of analyzing bureaucratic output, or discrepancies between bureaucratic policy and tangible results, the Rosenbloom benchmark can remind us that each independent theory has merit, based on its application in the Rosenbloom model. Rather than attempting the impossible task of assimilating all these theories, the first step is to determine where they differ, which has been completed, and what they share in common. Only following this step, can we achieve a synthesis. Public Administration is a composite of compromises, but rather than merely “muddling through,” we should look to negotiate the managerial, legal, and political hurdles and accept the limitations in our constitution that allow us to enjoy a wide degree of personal freedom and reasonably effective public administration. 32 WORKS CITED Appleby, Paul H. Policy and Administration. Birmingham, AL: University of Alabama Press, 1949. Investigates the checks on administrative power. Appleby, Paul H. Big Democracy. New York: Knopf, 1945. Presents the case that government is different from the private sector, and explains the limits and opportunities because of this arrangement. Bennis, Warren. Changing Organizations: Essays on the Development and Evolution of Human Organization. New York: McGraw Hill, 1966. Bennis provides an important counterweight to Kaufman’s model of the life cycles of government organizations. Coe, Barbara A. “How Structural Conflicts Stymie Reinvention.” Public Administration Review, V. 57 (Mar./Apr. 1997), 168-173. Accessed 19 February 2000 from http://www.firstsearch.oclc.org Relates to Frederickson’s call for “new public administration,” but has more of an emphasis on why the “old public administration” remains alive and well. Downs, Anthony. Inside Bureaucracy. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman, 1967. Downs focuses on goal setting and a model hierarchy, which are blueprints of Rosenbloom’s model. Frederickson, H. George. New Public Administration. Birmingham, AL: University of Alabama Press, 1980. Introduces the “five classic models” of administration and argues that substructures and individuals link to the superstructure of organizations. Frederickson, H. George. “Comparing the Reinventing Government Movement with the New Public Administration.” Public Administration Review¸ V. 56 (May/June 1996), 263-70. Accessed 19 February 2000 from http://firstsearch.oclc.org Expands on his earlier models of “new public administration,” and challenges conventional rationale of public administration. Grier, Peter. “At NASA, Signs of Too Much Scrimping.” Christian Science Monitor 29 March 2000. An article that explains why NASA’s budget cuts have been fundamentally destructive. Gulick, Luther and Urwick, L., eds. Papers on the Science of Administration. New York: Institute of Public Administration, 1937. Includes Gulick’s “Notes,” and several other articles that advise on the proper role of administration. Herring, E. Pendleton. The Politics of Democracy. New York: Rinehart, 1940. This source has Herring’s spin on administrative ethics, which differs markedly from his stance on group representation. 33 Ingraham, Patricia Wallace. The Foundation of Merit: Public Service in American Democracy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins, 1995. Wallace examines the civil service system and determines if the best applicants are receiving the best jobs. Ingraham, Patricia W. “Play it Again Sam; It’s Still Not Right: Searching for the Right Notes in Administrative Reform. Public Administration Review, V. 57, (July/Aug. 1997), 325-31. Accessed 19 February 2000 from http://firstsearch.oclc.org This source elucidates the options available to would-be reformers of public administration. Katz, Daniel and Kahn, Robert L. The Social Psychology of Organizations. New York: Wiley, 1966. These sociologists explain organizations on an individual level, using the idea that certain factors, coupled with the “hierarchy of needs and wants,” causes organization members to take certain actions. Kaufman, Herbert. Are Government Organizations Immortal? Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1976. Kaufman provides a corollary to the Rosenbloom argument by basically arguing that the legal, managerial, and political approaches have an effect on the life of organizations. Kaufman, Herbert. The Administrative Behavior of Federal Bureaucracies. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1981. This source dedicates itself to the confines of bureaucratic leadership and perspectives. Krislov, Samuel and Rosenbloom, David H. Representative Bureaucracy and the American Political System. New York: Praeger, 1981. Discusses the different methods that bureaucracies use to implement policy. Lee, Eliza Wing-yee. “Political Science, Public Administration, and the Rise of the American Administrative State.” Public Administration Review, V. 55 (Dec./Jan. 1995), 538-546. Accessed 19 February 2000 from http://www.firstsearch.oclc.org Addresses the politicsadministration dichotomy problem and contends that it is not in the best interest of public administration to meddle with a naturally-produced system. Lindblom, Charles E. and Cohen, David K. Usable Knowledge: Social science and Problem Solving. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1979. Lindblom’s infamous work on “muddling through” to solve public administration problems helps to explain why Rosenbloom’s “managerial approach” is salient. Lipsky, Michael. Street-Level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Services. York: Russell Sage, 1980. Offers an explanation of how problems faced by individual public servants are almost always resolved in a negative manner. Lowi, Theodore J. The End of Liberalism: Ideology, Policy, and the Crisis of Public Authority. New York: W.W. Norton, 1969. Lowi’s contention that liberalism must go is in complete accordance with Rosenbloom’s arguments. 34 Maslow, Abraham. Maslow on Management: New York: Wiley, 1998. Maslow ‘s compilation of writings over his forty year career. McGregor, Douglas. The Professional Manager. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967. This book discusses the intricacies of the managerial perception of reality. McGregor, Douglas. The Human Side of Enterprise. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1960. Advances theories involving management, the development of managerial talent, and his trademark “Theory X”/conventionalism debate versus “Theory Y”/Modernization. Meier, Kenneth J. “Bureaucracy and Democracy: The Case for More Bureaucracy and Less Democracy.” Public Administration Review, V. 57 (May/June 1997), 193-199. Meier’s article enhances Rosenbloom’s argument; Meier feels that excessive intervention in administration in the name of democracy is wrong. Merton, Robert K., et al. Reader in Bureaucracy. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press, 1952. Contains many articles on administration by notable authors from other disciplines. Moe, Ronald C. and Gilmour, Robert S. “Rediscovering Principles of Public Administration: The Neglected Foundation of Public Law.” Public Administration Review, V. 55 (Mar./Apr. 1995), 135-146. An insightful article that demonstrates how the laws that form the backbone of public administration have eroded substantially. Mosher, Frederick C. Democracy and the Public Service: Second Edition. New York: Oxford University Press, 1982. Mosher’s book concentrates on the system of due process within organizations. Present, Phillip E. People and Public Administration. Pacific Palisades, CA: Palisades, 1979. Offers a perspective focusing on the consumers of the fruits of public administration. Pressman, Jeffrey L. and Wildavsky, Aaron. Implementation. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1973. Accounts for the sometimes wide gap between official policy and results on the street. Rosenbloom, David. Public Administration: Understanding Management, Politics, and Law in the Public Sector. New York: Random House, 1989. Includes an ethical discussion of the legal, managerial, and political approaches. Shafritz, Jay M. and Hyde, Albert C. Classics of Public Administration, Fourth Edition. Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt Brace, 1997. An excellent overview of the history and evolution of public administration, containing many important works by influential authors of public administration doctrine. An extremely useful tool for dissecting public administration thought. 35 Schick, Allen, ed. Making Economic Policy in Congress. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 1983. A contemporary look at how Congress is influenced and constrained by political, managerial, and legal concerns. Simon, Herbert A. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization: Third Edition. New York: Macmillan, 1976. Decision making is the heart of any organization, and this book seeks to prove that theory holds, even when confronted by varying types of organizations. The book also presents a useful nomenclature for defining organizations. Simon, Herbert A., Smithburg, Donald W., and Thompson, Victor A. Public Administration. New York: Knopf, 1964. Focuses on the distribution of work and its effect on administrative efficiency. Skok, James E. “Policy Issue Networks and the Public Policy Cycle: A Structural-Functional Framework for Public Administration.” Public Administration Review, Vol. 55 (July/Aug. 1995), 325-332. Skok tackles the problem of whether policy issue networks drive the public policy, or vice versa. Stillman, Richard J. Preface to Public Administration: A Search for Themes and Direction, Second Edition. Burke, VA: Chatelaine, 1999. Discusses the main themes prevalent in public administration, and compares American public administration to European models. Waldo, Dwight. The Administrative State: A Study of the Political Theory of American Public Administration. New York: Ronald Press, 1948. Includes a section discussing the relevancy of the concept of separation of powers. White, Leonard D. Introduction to the Study of Public Administration, Revised Edition. New York: Macmillan, 1942. The chapter in this book on the role of the executive is helpful, but even more interesting, although only peripherally related to the topic of this paper, are tactics to ensure compliance with regulations. Wildavsky, Aaron. The Politics of the Budgetary Process: Second Edition. Boston: Little, Brown, 1964. In typical Wildavsky fashion, this book dissects the proper way of using budgets to obtain policy objectives, without PPBS. Wilson, James Q. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. New York: Basic Books, 1989. Discusses bureaucratic strategies, their implementation, and their successfulness.