NIRA page.doc

advertisement

<p>If the <a href=”banking.html”>Emergency Banking Act</a> opened Roosevelt’s <a href=”hundred_days.html”>“Hundred Days”</a> the National Industrial Recovery Act closed it. When Congress passed it on June 16, 1933, many thought its proposed stimulation of industry and recuperation of consumer purchasing power were the keys to economic recovery. While the banking and farm bills were important first steps in the

New Deal, “the heart of the American economy was neither finance nor agriculture but industry; and that heart was only beating faintly.” (Schlesinger, 87) Between 1929 and

1932, manufacturing production declined by 50% and the total value of finished commodities dropped from $38 billion to $17.5 billion. Many believed that “a rise in agricultural prices without corresponding stimulation of industry would be fatal to recovery.” (Schlesinger, 87) The central question remained, how would the government stimulate industry? Would it involve a business-government partnership? How would the

American people and industry respond to a break from the traditional “hands-off” economic policy?</p>

<p> It was clear that the old laissez-faire policies hadn’t worked, but neither was socialism a viable option. Instead, the Roosevelt brain trust looked to a practice that had become common in the 1920s of trade organizations providing self-government for business. While averse to central controls, there was a movement for industrial coordination from many directions, including the businesses themselves. Industry wanted to protect prices and profits; trade unions to protect labor standards; and liberals sought some form of national planning. (QB Halt Decline”) A business-government partnership, it was decided, could provide “codes of fair competition” that would benefit industry, labor and consumers. Business would work with government “to prevent overproduction, to prevent unfair wages, and to eliminate improper working conditions.”

(Schlesinger, 98)</p>

<p>A complex series of events and combination of individuals set the plan in motion and after many drafts, two groups of administration officials came up with separate proposals. Roosevelt had the groups work together and by May 15, a bill was ready for Congress. While the legislation was passed in the House in over a week, it saw tough times in the Senate. (The National Association of Manufacturers and Chamber of

Commerce had a problem with some of the labor provisions.) The NIRA was finally signed on June 16. </p>

QB 102

<p> The NIRA was divided into two parts: </p>

Title I, “Industrial Recovery” was “to promote the organization of industry for the purpose of cooperative action among trade groups.” It provided for fair competition along with an anti-trust exemption for businesses and allowed for collective bargaining and labor standards for unions. Most importantly, it established the National Recovery

Administration, which was to be headed by <a href=”newdealers.html”>General Hugh

Johnson<a/a>. “Roosevelt saw the NRA as “the means for a long-run reform and reorganization of the economy.” (<I>Ibid</I>, 104)

<p> Title II, “Public Works and Construction Projects” established the Public Works

Administration, headed by Interior Secretary <a href=”newdealers.html”>Harold

Ickes</a>, and appropriated it $3.3 billion. </p>

<p> The NRA opened its doors on June 20, 1933. Its basis was the development of codes for each industry by which it would pledge itself to shorter hours, higher wages, better trade practices and better labor relations. Cooperation would be ensured by the codes, the use of federal licenses (which were never implemented) and a two-year exemption from anti-trust statutes. The problem remained enforcement: despite his enthusiasm for the program, Johnson had questions about the constitutionality of forced cooperation. Instead, he sought a way to implement a voluntary approach to industrial planning based on social compulsion. Using the terminology of war Johnson sought to enforce the codes through public opinion. He created the blue eagle as the symbol of the

NRA and employed the slogan, “We Do Our Part.” These would be provided to businesses and consumers who pledged compliance with the program and used to stigmatize those who did not. “Those who are not with us,” the General asserted, “are against us.” Over two million employers signed up and consumers signed a pledge of their own. The blue eagle was celebrated throughout the country and parades and speeches praised it. The NRA brought a cheerful attitude to the American public for the first time since the 20s. The industry codes began to surge into Washington: 144 in the second half of July, 546 in August, and even the big industry holdouts like lumber, steel, oil and mining were on board by September (in the auto industry, the lone exception was

Henry Ford). </p>

QB 114-115, Fireside

<p> But the NRA may have over promised results. Success was elusive as social compulsion (threat of removal of the blue eagle) came up short and enthusiasm faltered by fall. The primary obstacle was the argument over price fixing. Roosevelt wanted to keep prices down and industry wanted price fixing powers. Many felt that price policy was the key to either expanding or constricting the economy—prices had to be high enough to support the labor provisions but low enough for consumers to afford. By 1935

568 out of 700 codes had some form of minimum price provision (<I>Ibid</I>, 125).

(QB on Price policy). The NRA had not achieved its goals of re-employment and recovery and had failed to hold companies to their end of the labor provisions.

Additionally, the PWA was, run by the stingy Ickes, was not approving enough projects at a reasonable pace to channel money (as wages) into the economy. (Fireside NIRA

9/30/1935) </p>

<p> Administrative shuffling, reversal of price policy and organizational contraction and restraint did not succeed in revitalizing the NRA. Due to expire in June of 1935,

Roosevelt hesitantly called on Congress in February to renew the NRA. Before a judgment could be made, however, the decision was made by the <a href=”court.html”>

Supreme Court<a/>. On May 27, 1935 in A.L.A. Schecter Poultry Corporation v. United

States the Court, in a unanimous ruling, abrogated Title I of the NIRA as

“unconstitutional delegation of legislative power to the executive.” The NRA, perhaps the program most associated with the New Deal, faded out of existence, to the relief of most, including the Roosevelt Administration.</p>

<p> The legacy of the NIRA is a mixed one. In 1935 the Research and Planning

Division of its review board found that there was no increase in real wages in the previous year, and the increase in retail prices exceeded the gains in wages. The codes were never effectively enforced and economic recovery was stifled. But there were important and long-lasting results, only some of which measurable with financial

indicators. During its six years of operation, the PWA would finance 34,508 projects at a cost of over $6 billion, with projects in all but three of the nation’s over 3,000 counties, and employed over 500,000 workers in any given year. (Watkins, 145) Additionally, the legislation established a new labor policy and, in the National Labor Relations Board, had a body to enforce it.</p>

<p> Perhaps more important was the impact that the NIRA had on the American people. As Arthur Schlesinger points out, while poorly administered and with questionable regulation, the NRA served an important psychological function—as the sense of crisis waned, so did the psychological foundation of the NRA. QB 176 It was forward motion and “represented an essential continuity which in face of crisis helped preserve an American unity.” (Schlesinger, 176) The NRA is perhaps the perfect illustration of the psychological function thesis: the New Deal was not always about success or failure in relation to economic recovery. By uniting the American people and giving hope, the programs could succeed in providing hope and motivation where there was previously none.</p>

Download