Zenonas NORKUS „Kokia demokratija, koks kapitalizmas? Pokomunistinė transformacija Lietuvoje lyginamosios istorinės sociologijos požiūriu“. Vilnius : Vilniaus universiteto leidykla, 2008. - 744 p. - ISBN 978-9955-33-231-2 Which Capitalism, Which Democracy? Postcommunist Transformation in Lithuania from the Viewpoint of Comparative Historical Sociology. Vilnius : Vilnius University Press, 2008. 744 p. - ISBN 978-9955-33-231-2 (in Lithuanian) Contents Introduction PART I FEATURING COMPARATIVE SOCIOLOGY AND ITS BASIC CONCEPTS Chapter 1 On Lithuanistic and Non-Lithuanistic Sociology (and More) 1.1. Comparative Research in Natural Science 1.2. Comparative Research in Social Science and Human Studies 1.3. Society, Culture, Civilization, and Empire as Basic Concepts in Social Comparative Research 1.4. Comparative Research and Ethnocentrism 1.5. The Genealogical Features of the Contemporary Disciplinary Structure of Social Science 1.6. Evolutionist Comparative Research in the Classical Sociology Chapter 2 Between Ladder of Evolution and Network of History: The Development of Comparative Sociology in Outline 2.1. Comparative Historical Sociological Research in Germany, Late 19th-Early 20th Century 2.2. Area Studies and Modernization Theory in U.S. 2.3. The Europeization of the International Quantitative Comparative Research and Historical Turn in the American Comparative Sociology 2.4. Comparative Historical Sociological and Capitalist World System Analysis 2. 5. The Postmodern End of “Grand Metanarratives” or the Renaissance of the Modernization Theory? 2. 6. Great Convergence and the End of Comparative Sociology? PART II THE DILEMMAS IN COMPARATIVIST METHODOLOGY Chapter 3 What is Comparative Method? 3.1. The Paradox of Adamo Przeworski ir Henry Teune 3.2. Arend Lijphart on Comparative Method 3.3. The Classification of the Comparison Forms 3.4 The Canons of John Stuart Mill as the Rules of Comparative Method 3.5. The Comparative Method and the Case Study Method Chapter 4 The Search for Middle Road in the Contemporary Methodology of Comparative Research 4.1. Fractal Aspects in the Comparative Methodology 4.2 Two concepts of a case 4.3. Synthetic Strategy in the Comparative Research and the Problem of the Multiple Conjunctural Causality 4.4. Comparative Qualitative Analysis as Logical Technique in the Synthetic Strategy of Comparative Research 4. 5. What Does Synthetic Strategy in Comparative Research Synthesize and What Does Not? Chapter 5 Comparability, Concept Formation, and Measurement 5.1 The Problem of Comparability 5.2. The Problem of Equivalence 5.3. Taxonomic Constructs 5.4. Typological Constructs: with Adjectives and Without Them PART III COMMUNISM AS A PROBLEM OF COMPARATIVE HISTORICAL SOCIOLOGY Chapter 6 Marxist Social Theory and Communist Social Order 6.1. Marxism as Social Science and as Utopia 6.2. The Irony and Paradoxes in the History of Marxist Communism 6.3 Was USSR a „Degenerated Workers’ Class State”? 6.4. Was USSR a State Capitalist Country? 6.5. Communism as Anti-Utopia: From Lev Trotsky to George Orwell Chapter 7 Communism as Totalitarianism 7. 1. Communism and Fascism: Kindred Enemies 7.2. Totalitarianism: Perverse Modernity or a Relapse into “Closed Society”? 7.3. Totalitarianism with Adjectives and Without Them 7.4. The Decline and Renaissance of the Theory of Communism as Totalitarianism Chapter 8 Was Communism a Way into (Different?) Modernity or into a Neo-Traditionalist Impasse? 8.1. Modernization Theory and Sovietology 8.2 The Barrington Moore‘s Analysis of the Dilemmas of Communist Power and Alternatives of Its Development 8.3. „Really Existing Socialism” as Unfinished Modernization: The Convergence Theory Approach 8.4. Convergence with the … “Third World”? The Communist Neo-Traditionalism Theory Approach 8.5. What Was Communism Really? PART IV EXIT FROM COMMUNISM AS PROBLEM OF COMPARATIVE HISTORICAL sOCIOLOGY Chapter 9 Was the Collapse of Soviet Communism a Failure of Social Science? 9. 1. The Forecasts of the Communism’s Breakdown 9.2. The “Osmanization” or Gradual Transformation of Soviet Communism? Mikhail Gorbachev’s Perestroika in the Mirror of Sovietology 9.3. Why Nobody Predicted How and When Will the Soviet Communism Collapse? 9. 4. Was the Collapse of Soviet Communism in 1989-1991 Unavoidable? 9.5. The Last Crossroad of Soviet Communism Chapter 10 The Transformation of Chinese Communism 10.1 The Way-Stations and Achievements in China‘s Exit from Communism? 10.2. Did China Build Socialist Market Economy? 10.3. The Problems and Prospects in the Transformation of China‘s Communism 10.4. Chinese Way Out of Soviet Communism as the Avoided Tragedy of the Restoration of the Lithuania‘s Independence Chapter 11 Exit from Soviet and Yugoslav Communism: Orientations, Modes, Ways, Outcomes 11. 1. Two Paradoxes of the Exit from Communism 11.2. The Conceptual Foundations of the Typology of the Ways of Postcommunist Transformation 11. 3. Restorative Orientation for the Exit from Communism 11.4 Imitative Orientation for the Exit from Communism and the Program of „Great Leap“ into Market Economy Chapter 12 The Political Economical Outcomes and the Macroeconomic Dynamics in the Exit from Communism 12.1. The Political Economical Outcomes of the Exit Out of Communism 12.2. The Macroeconomic and Welfare Outcomes of the Capitalism Restoration: 12.3. The Problem of the Causes of Transformational Economic Recession 12.4. Types of the Pathways of Postcommunist Transformation 12.5. Pathways and Initial Conditions of Postcommunist Transformation Part V LIBERAL WESTERN DEMOCRACY: IDEAS AND POSTCOMMUNIST REALITIES Chapter 13 The Idea of Liberal Democracy and its Typologies 13.1. The Problem of Social Cost of Postcommunist Transformation 13.2. Consumer’s Welfare and Citizen’s Wellbeing 13.3. Coercion, State, Democracy 13.4. Democracy as Contested Concept and Its Deductive Typologies 13.5. Liberal Democracy as a Measurement Object 13.6. Arend Lijphart‘s Quantitative Inductive Typology of Liberal Democracy Chapter 14 New Latin America or New West? The Consolidation Problems of the Postcommunist Liberal Democracy 14.1. Why All Postcommunist World Did Not Become New Latin America? 14.2. Revolution, Reform, and “Refolution” in Latin America and in the Central and Eastern Europa 14.3. The Concept of Consolidated Liberal Democracy 14.4. The Problem of the Conditions for Consolidation of Liberal Democracy Chapter 15 New “Wild West”? The Questions about the Quality of the Postcommunist Liberal Democracy 15.1. The Concept of the Quality of Democracy 15.2. Which Democracy Type Do Postcommunist Liberal Democracies Represent? 15.3. The Quality Problems of the Postcommunist Liberal Democracies 15.4. Authoritarianism and Democracy with Adjectives: Failures of the Postcommunist Democratization PART VI CAPITALISM: THEORY AND HISTORY Chapter 16 The Change and Diversity of Capitalism as a Problem in the Classical Economic Sociology 16.1. Karl Marx: Capitalism as a Mode of Production 16.2. Maxas Weberis: Capitalism as Economic Action and as Economic System 16.3. The “Atom of Property” Splitting: Adolf Berle and Gardiner Means on Managerial Corporate Capitalism 16.4. Joseph A. Schumpeter: Capitalism as Creative Destruction 16.5 Karl Polanyi and John Maynard Keynes: Free Market Capitalism – Utopia or Anti-Utopia? Chapter 17 The Rise and Decline of Fordist Capitalism 17.1. Fordist Capitalism and Its Welfare Regimes 17.2. Globalization and the End of Managerial Capitalism 17.3. Whose Capitalism is Most Viable and Best? Chapter 18 The Diversity of Rational Entrepreneurial Capitalism as a Problem of the Contemporary Comparative Economic Sociology 18.1 Coordinated and Liberal Capitalism 18.2. Conditions for the Stability of the Capitalism Types 18.3. How Many Capitalism Types? PART VII POSTCOMMUNIST CAPITALISM: PRESENT AND FUTURE Chapter 19 What Kind of Capitalism is Emerging in the Baltic and Central Europa? 19.1 From Communism into Peripheric Capitalism and Feudalism? Pessimistic Diagnoses and Predictions 19.2. From Communism into „Better“ Capitalism? Disappointed Hopes of the Postcommunist Messianism 19.3. Postcommunist Capitalism in the Mirror of the „Neoclassical Sociology“ 19.4. Methodical Difficulties and Discoveries of the Quantitative Inductive Typology of Postcommunist Capitalism 19.5. Postcommunist Capitalism in Central Europa: a New Stable Type or Transitional State? Chapter 20 Why Estonians Did Overtake Us? 20.1. North-South Gap in the Political and Economical Transformation of the Baltic States as an Explanation Problem 20.2. Economical Explanation of Lithuania’s Backwardness 20.3. Political-Economical Explanation: Does the Blame Lay on Lithuanian ExCommunists? 20.4. Culturalist Explanation: “Weber’s” Thesis for Baltic Countries? 20.5. Difficulties of the Culturalist Explanation of the Estonia’s Success Chapter 21 Between Estonia and Slovenia: Postcommunist Capitalism in Lithuania and Its Prospects 21.1. Estonia, Slovenia, Lithuania: Two Antipode Champions of the Postcommunist Transformation and One Mediocrity 21.2. Why Capitalism in Lithuania is Akin to Estonian, but not to Slovenian Capitalism? 21.3. Whom to Run after: Estonia or Slovenia? 21.4. Will Eurocapitalism be Neoliberal or Social? REFERENCES SUMMARY IN ENGLISH SUMMARY Which Democracy, Which Capitalism? Post-communist Transformation in Lithuania from the Standpoint of Comparative Historical Sociology The book is a comparative historical sociological study of the processes of postcommunist economical and political transformation, focusing on its course and outcomes in the author‘s native country – Lithuania. Its goal is to provide the synthesis of two bodies of literature: (1) swelling body of native social scientific research work that is published in Lithuanian and is mostly ethnocentric in its methodological orientation (see e.g. Adomėnas et al. 2007; Aidukaite 2004; Ališauskienė, Dobryninas and Žilinskienė 2005; Bernotas and Guogis 2003; 2006; Bielinis 2003; Dobryninas 2001; Gaidys 2000; Gečienė, Juknevičius et al. 2001; Genzelis 1999; 2005; Gylys 2002; Grigas 1995; 1998; 2001; 2004; Gruževskis 2001; Guogis 2000a; 2000b; Grigas ir Ružas 2007; Juknevičius, Mitrikas et al. 2003; Krupavičius ir Lukošaitis 2004; Kuzmickas 2007; Kuzmickas and Astra 1996; Laurėnas 2001; Lazutka et al. 2004; Leonavičius 2002; Leonavičius and Keturakis 2002; Lopata and Matonis 2004; Maniokas 2003; Maniokas ir Vitkus 1997; Matonytė 2001; Matulionis. 2005a; Matulionis 2005b; Melnikas 2002; Mitrikas 2000; Novagrockienė 2001; Poviliūnas 2003; Rakauskienė 2006; Ramonaitė 2007; Stankūnienė et al. 2003; Stankūnienė, Jasilionienė ir Jančaitytė 2005; Socialiniai pokyčiai 2000; Šabajevaitė 1999; Šaulauskas 1996; 1998a; 1998b; 2000; Vilpišauskas 2001; Vitkus 2006; Vitkus ir Pugačiauskas 2004; Žiliukaitė, Ramonaitė, Nevinskaitė, Beresnevičiūtė and Vinogradnaitė 2006), and (2) Western scholarly work from the fields such as comparative politics and comparative political economy. The book is sociological by bridging the disciplinary boundaries, historical by covering time span between 1914 and 2004 (year of Lithuania‘s accession to the EU and NATO), and comparative by discussing the social change in Lithuania in the comparative frameworks of varying scope, beginning with intercivilizational comparisons and closing with comparisons according to the most similar cases design (i.e. with other Baltic countries). In his use of both bodies of literature, the author follows two questions: (1) how the achievements of the international comparative research help to illuminate Lithuanian case? (2) In which respects is Lithuania an interesting and important case for the comparative research aiming at broader generalizations? These questions are directed to four research areas: (1) communism; (2) exit from communism; (3) post-communist democracy; (4) post-communist capitalism. The topics from the first area are discussed in the third, those from the second – in the fourth, those from the third – in the fifth, and those from the fourth – in the sixth and the seventh parts of the book. The discussion of all these topics is guided by the two questions put above, formulated more specifically: what were specific features of the communist regime in the Lithuania? In which respects is it of the interest for comparative communism studies? What are the specific features of the Lithuania‘s exit from communism? How and why is it important for transitological research? How should post-communist democracy in Lithuania be classified? In which respects is it important and interesting for the comparative research on post-communist democracy and on liberal democracy generally? What kind of capitalism exists in contemporary Lithuania? How the research on contemporary capitalism in Lithuania can enrich comparative research on capitalism? The discussion of these questions are instrumental to achieve the main goal of this book – to provide a macrosociological diagnosis of the present state of Lithuanian society that is a subject of the ongoing public discussion in this country, displaying a broad range of opinions from the triumphant optimism to the apocalyptic pessimism, describing recent transformations in Lithuania as a social catastrophe leading to the extinction of the Lithuania as a distinct state and nation in the wake of the ongoing globalization and europeanization. The book was inspired by author‘s conviction that creating an objective image of the present state of Lithuanian society is not possible to be made without thorough comparison of processes of economical, political, and social change with other post-communist countries. This is the only way to find out in which respects Lithuania‘s development is normal, and in which it is not. Although the comparative research in Lithuania has old traditions going back to the works of Lithuanian philosophers of culture Antanas Maceina and Stasys Šalkauskis in the interwar Lithuania, and it is practised in the contemporary Lithuania (Antanas Andrijauskas, Vytautas Kavolis, Leonidas Donskis), up to this time it was represented only by the work in comparative civilization analysis, working with the civilizations as the biggest possible units of comparison and straggling the line between social science and speculative philosophy of history. To introduce Lithuanian reader into other, more down-to-earth styles of comparative research, author reserves two opening parts of the book for the methodological prolegomena, including discussion of the basic concepts (categories), techniques, and directions of international comparative social research in its historical development. The discussion of the basic concepts of comparative research in the first part of the book is focused on the concepts of modernity and modernization, and involves also concepts of society, culture, empire, international system. This discussion identifies two key metaphors in the comparativist imagination, competing to guide the thinking about the long-time socio-cultural change. One of them directs to conceive this change as evolution – ascent or descent along the stages representing evolutionary types of social systems. Another metaphor suggests thinking about social and cultural change as a history – growing rhizomatic network where social systems are related by the filiation and cultural diffusion, considered in the book as unique features of socio-cultural change. Competition of these key metaphors accounts for differentiation of the comparative social research into two broad directions – evolutionist and historicist one, and for the ambiguity in the concepts of modernization and modernity themselves. In the evolutionist framework, modernity is a stage-like evolutionary type of social systems. The emergence of the first social systems of this type in the Western Europe at some specific (modern) time (i.e. in the 16-17th centuries) is considered as historically accidental for the very essence or identity of being modern, with sinic or arabic modernities as possible alternative cases of modern societies and cultures. In the historicist framework, modernity is defined by its origin in one specific – Western – civilization, with its identity shaped by the unique genealogy of this civilization, worldview and values. In the historicist framework, modernization of non-Western societies and cultures basically means their westernization, leading to the long-time convergence of presently existing civilizations and the extinction of the present diversity of cultures and forms of political and economical organization. Meanwhile, the evolutionist framework is also compatible with an idea of multiple modernities, allowing for the emergence of the new lines of the cultural and social diversification despite (or due to) the economic forces of globalization. The subject-matter of the second part of the book is sources of diversity in the comparative research itself deriving from the differences in the design of the research and in the strategies of comparison. This strategy can be variable-oriented and quantitative, applying methods of statistical analysis to large populations of cases (states, cultures) to detect co-variations, interpreting them as confirmations or falsifications of general causal hypotheses. However, the comparison can also be qualitative, guided by John Stuart Mill‘s canons of eliminative induction, and involving only few cases that are known in depth. This is what comparative method means according to its influential description provided by Arend Lijphart. The author prefers the broader conception of comparative method by Charles Ragin. According to this conception, the distinguishing feature of comparative social research is the presence of macrosocial variables in the causal hypotheses that are articulated or tested, and the use of the populations of cases displaying the variation of such variables across at least two big (macrosocial) cases. In Ch. Ragin‘s description of comparative method, the dichotomy of quantitative (variable-oriented) and qualitative (case-oriented) strategies is replaced by the trichotomy of quantitative, qualitative, and „synthetic“ (diversity-oriented) strategy, with algorithms of Boolean qualitative comparative analysis designed to serve as logical technique of synthetic strategy. The methodological half of the book closes (in the chap. 5) with the discussion of the methods of concept formation applied in the empirical half (chaps. 6-21) of the book. The bulk of the research surveyed and discussed in this half is typological. Its foremost goal is to classify communist regimes, ways and outcomes of exit from communism, to identify emerging types of post-communist political regimes and post-communist capitalism, and to detect the causes of this diversity. Two strategies of typological concept construction are distinguished and applied: a deductive (from above) and an inductive (from below) one. Applying deductive strategy, typological concepts are articulated in the context of a theory that identifies conceptual dimensions in the phenomenon under consideration. These dimensions define logical space of the possible diversity of this phenomenon. After the comparison of this space with the empirically available diversity, the space of the logical possibilities is reduced to several types. Of special interest for the goals of comparative analysis are „ideal types“ made famous by Max Weber. They are defined by combinations of the values of variables that are located at the limits of the logical space delineated by theory and represented (if at all) by its „pure“ cases, that may be not present in the empirical reality. To apply inductive quantitative strategy, a researcher should have at her disposal a data-set that is appropriate for application of the statistical techniques of factor and cluster analysis. Factor analysis helps to discover implicit conceptual dimensions (factors) in the set of available variables, and the cluster analysis helps to group the cases into the clusters according to the degree of their mutual similarity. By act of interpretation, these clusters can then be related to the theoretically constructed types. The empirical half of the book starts with third part, encompassing chapters 6-8 and dealing with communism as a social system. According to working definition, communism means a really existing social system that emerged as an outcome of an attempt to materialize Karl Marx‘s utopia of classless society. However, such definition still says nothing about the intrinsic character of this outcome, except that communist countries were ruled by communists. As a matter of common knowledge, the communists themselves did not consider that the societies under their rule already are communist, postponing the realization of the communist idea for the more or less distant future. More informative description and explanation of communism as a really existing social system is the task of the social scientific analysis, with its conclusions dependent on the theoretical and comparative perspectives applied for its conceptualization. The author draws a distinction between etic and emic accounts of communism (in the sense of Goodenough 1970: 104-119; Harris 1980: 29-45)). Emic are the accounts of communism from the standpoint of Marxism as the social theory that has produced communism. These accounts are divided into apologetic and critical ones. Apologetic accounts are represented by the official ideological doctrines of the former communist countries that have described communism as “socialism” – first phase of the communism as the highest and last stage of social evolution. Critical accounts are alternative marxist conceptions of really existing communist regimes as state capitalism, bureaucratic collectivism and so on. Emic accounts of communism are discussed in the chapter 6. Next chapters 7-8 deal with etic (i.e. non-marxist) theories of communism. Three types of etic theories of communism are distinguished: (1) communism as totalitarianism; (2) communism as a way into modernity; (3) communism as neotraditionalism and neopatrimonialism. This typology is grounded by the idea that the character of the etic theories of communism is determined foremostly by the perspective of comparison used for its conceptualization and explanation. Theory of communism as totalitarianism assumes that the key to understand communism is provided by its comparison with nazist Germany (and vice versa). In one version of this theory (Hannah Arendt, Zbigniew Brzezinski, Carl J. Friedrich) communism and nazism are considered as pathological phenomena peculiar to modern societies, a form of rule without precedents in the former history. Proponents of another version (Karl Popper, Karl A. Wittfogel) discover totalitarianism in the premodern societies, considering nazist and communist totalitarianism as recurrence of deeply archaic forms of social organization characteristic for closed tribal societies or Oriental despotism. Theories of communism as a way into modernity, alternative or incomplete (arrested) modernity assume that the key to understand and explain the realities of the (already extinct) communist countries can be provided by their comparison with advanced liberal democratic Western countries. Assumption of their basic similarity was implicit in the numerous attempts of the sovietologists to explain social phenomena in the communist countries by applying theories of interest groups, corporatism, bureaucratic politics and many others ones that were developed targeting social reality of advanced Western countries as their intended scope of application. In the theories of communism as neotraditionalism and neopatrimonialism, the social reality of premodern and underdeveloped (third world) countries is used as communism‘s mirror. The author advances proposal to solve the controversy between different theories of communism by taking into account internal differentiation in the communist world that was increasing from the very establishment of communist regimes and was greatest at the eve of communism‘s collapse. The countries that fell under communist rule differed greatly with respect to their civilizational identity and the level of the social-economic development achieved on the threshold of communism. These initial conditions decided both the role of communism in the history of the particular countries, and the shape that the communist regimes took in the late phases. Although theory of communism as totalitarianism provided a sharp phenomenological picture of communist regimes in their early phases, it was no more adequate for late communism. At least three pure types of late communism can be distinguished (see Kitschelt, Mansfeldova et al. 1999). In the countries that were economically, socially, culturally and even politically modern before communism (the Czech Republic, East Germany, Latvia, Estonia), communist totalitarianism has transformed itself into the bureaucratic authoritarian communism. In these countries, communism brought just the displacement of the normal modernity with its pathological version. In the countries where the processes of modernization were advanced but unfinished before communism, economic, social, and cultural modernization continued under communist regime that took the shape of national communism in its late phase. In the countries where modernization was in very beginning, the coming of communism initiated a singular way of modernization that can be described as turbomodernization (Marius Povilas Šaulauskas). After the totalitarian phase of communism, its transformation into the patrimonial communism followed, whose distinguishing feature is the paramount role of particularistic patron-client networks in its social organization. This form of late communism prevailed in almost all republics of the former Soviet Union and in the Balkan countries. None of the etic theories of communism were able to predict exact timing and circumstances under which Soviet communism will collapse, because time and shape of communism‘s collapse were determined by the contingent conditions and subjective factors that cannot be derived from general causes that are subject matter of social science. However, etic theories have correctly identified structural weak spots of the communist system that made it unable to win economic competition with advanced liberal democratic capitalist states and to demonstrate to be a superior social system. Losing this competition, communist system suffered from the dwindling legitimacy even in the eyes of the members of communist party. This loss of legitimacy was most important long-term or structural cause why communism had collapsed. Best explanation of the short-term dynamics of this collapse is provided by the theory of preference falsification that discloses the causes why political regimes suppressing or restricting freedom of speech are more fragile or less stable in comparison with liberal democracies. In the chapter 11, the analysis of the conceptual foundations for classification of the pathways out of communism is provided. In this analysis, five conceptual dimensions are distinguished: (1) orientation of the transformation (according to Šaulauskas 2000) – innovative, imitative, continuative, restorative); (2) mode of political transformation (reform, revolution, „refolution“); (3) mode of economic transformation (shock therapy, gradual transformation); (4) political outcomes (liberal democracy; illiberal democracy or one of the forms of authoritarianism); (5) economic outcomes (rational entrepreneurial capitalism (REC)), political oligarchic capitalism, state monopoly capitalism, state capitalism). The combinations of the values of the variables describing these dimensions define many different kinds of the transition pathways. Some of these combinations are logically impossible (inconsistent); others may be consistent, but did not materialize empirically. Focusing on those ways out of communism that were observable empirically, the conceptual classification is reduced to empirical typology discussed in detail in the chapter 12. This discussion is introduced by the criticism of the mainstream in the post- communist transformation research (so-called transitology) that singles out one particular outcome out of the whole range of possible outcomes (REC + liberal democracy), classifying the diversity of the transformation pathways into successful and unsuccessful ones. To make the criticism of the transitological teleology constructive, the author provides elaborated classification of the transformation outcomes (including distinction between different versions of REC and liberal democracy themselves), and tries to take into account whole range of variation of the outcomes. He singles out six empirical types of the exit ways from communism:(1) innovatively oriented gradual way leading to combination of REC and liberal democracy (Slovenia) or authoritarianism (China); (2) restoratively and imitatively oriented gradual reformist way to REC and liberal democracy (e.g. Hungary); (3) restoratively and imitatively oriented shock therapy revolutionary way to REC and liberal democracy (e.g. Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia); (4) imitatively oriented shock therapy revolutionary way to semi-authoritarianism and state monopoly capitalism (e.g. Russia); (5) continuatively oriented gradual reformist way to political oligarchic capitalism and illiberal democracy (e.g. Ukraine); (6) continuatively oriented gradual reformist way to state capitalism and authoritarianism (e.g. Belarus, Uzbekistan). Instead of just asking about what causal conditions were crucial for the success of transition (e.g. arrival to station REC+liberal democracy), author focuses on those conditions that were crucial for entering different exit ways from communism. According to his view, different legacies of the late communism together with civilizational differences (legacies of the long duration history) explain why different countries entered exit ways from communism of specific types and arrived at specific outcomes. In the countries of bureaucratic authoritarian communism, the restorative orientation of post-communist social change was prevailing. Countries with the legacy of national communism displayed most clearly the imitative orientation. In those with patrimonial communism as exit point, the continuative orientation dominated. China and Slovenia were the only former communist countries with pronounced innovative orientation. In Slovenian case, innovative orientation of the exit from communism can be related to the traditions of the Yugoslav communism that was the most liberal and bent for revisionist piecemeal social experimentation. In China‘s case, where communism was marked by leftist egalitarianism, innovative orientation may be related to the civilizational traditions from older times. In both cases, post-communist transformation was realized by means of piecemeal social engineering as the process of incremental change. Imitative and restorative transformation was enacted in two modes: by gradual reforms, and by shock therapy marked by revolutionary and holistic features. Success of shock therapy in number of post-communist countries refutes Karl Raimund Popper‘s theorem that successful holistic social engineering is impossible. The imitational and restorative orientations of exit from communism prevailed in most countries that were admitted in the 2004 to the EU and NATO. Accession of some post-communist countries to these organizations is interpreted as the certification of the successful (in the transitological sense) conclusion of the postcommunist transformation: the consolidation of rational entrepreneurial capitalism (REC) and liberal democracy. However, in many post-communist countries failures of shock therapy or gradual reforms led them to oligarchic or state monopolistic capitalism and to semi-democratic or semi-authoritarian regimes, whose nature can be described in the more accurate way by concepts of delegative democracy, hegemonic electoral authoritarianism, competitive electoral authoritarianism. In some post-communist countries where continuative orientation prevailed, the outcome of post-communist transformation was state capitalism and closed authoritarian or sultanistic political regime. These outcomes of post-communist transformation are focus of the ongoing heated discussions: is the post-communist transformation in the authoritarian and halfauthoritarian states of political oligarchic capitalism simply arrested, remaining for some time behind the achievers of the post-communist transformation (newly accepted members of the EU and NATO)? Or are configurations of political and economic institutions in these countries relatively stable and will survive in the present shape for the foreseeable future? In author‘s opinion, the second viewpoint seems to be more compelling, because it seems to be more sensitive for the restrictions that were put on the course and outcomes of post-communist transformation not only by the legacies of the antecedent type of communist regime, but also by the civilizational differences that are legacies of the long duration history. These differences are important also for the evaluation of the prospects of the further processes of the social change in China (and Vietnam). The communist nomenclature that has initiated in China the economic reforms from above, could use the cultural resources of the social and economic ethic inherited from the millennial Confucian tradition, and to usurp the status and social functions of the mandarin estate peculiar to the Chinese civilizational tradition. Because of the Chinese civilizational legacies, outlooks for liberal democracy in China may be much dimmer than those for REC that is already a reality in this country. The prospects of democratization are not null and void in China, but the shape of democracy in China may differ from its Western patterns much more than the Chinese and other Asian varieties of REC deviate from their Western relatives. Do civilizational differences also matter in answering two further questions that are intensively discussed in the transitological literature: could the Soviet Union leave the communism in the „Chinese way“ of gradual reforms? Why neoliberal shock therapy reforms had not brought expected results in Russia and some other post-soviet countries? The author argues that the attempt to apply the Chinese strategy in the Soviet Union most probably was doomed to fail because of two crucial differences between late communist China and the Soviet Union. Firstly, the Soviet Union was an empire in crisis, while imperial features of the communist Chinese state are not sharp enough to become a source of structural weakness. Secondly, differently from agrarian and rural China, the Soviet Union was industrialized (and even over-industrialized), and had no resources for extensive growth that enabled China‘s grand leap just after the legalization of private enterprise (first of all, in the agriculture). Therefore, even if Chinese-style economic reforms had been implemented under conditions of authoritarian regime (say, in the alternative counterfactual history after the successful coup in the August 1991), they would not have resolved economic crisis and would only have prolonged the agony of the Soviet empire. In this case, the disintegration of the Soviet empire would most probably have gone in the violent “Yugoslavian” way, enormously increasing social costs of the exit from communism. Most important causes of the failure of the neoliberal shock therapy in Russia were some mistakes of the Russian reformers and their advisers from the international financial institutions. The key mistake was the delay in the liquidation of the rouble zone, that was the cause why the policy of macroeconomic stabilization failed in 1992-1993. Another important cause of the failure was procrastination of the governments of Western countries to provide Russia with a financial assistance at the precise time when it could have made difference (in 1992). Most probably, this procrastination was determined by the perception of Russia as a civilizational Other bound to remain a geopolitical rival of the West no matter what type of political regime and economic system it has. The parts 5-7 continue in the depth the analysis of the diversity of the ways and outcomes of post-communist transformation that was started in the fourth part. This is done, firstly, by the narrowing the focus of the analysis. In the third and the fourth parts, it encompasses the whole communist and post-communist world. From the fifth part on, only while discussing some specific problems (to achieve the variation in the dependent variable), the set of cases compared is expanded to include also those states that do not belong to the elite club of the achievers of the post-communist transformation (countries joined to EU and NATO). Secondly, general constructs of the modernization theory that served as theoretical lenses for comparison in previous parts, are replaced by the more specific conceptual constructs from the middle range theories designed and tested in the comparative political economy and comparative economic sociology. The subject matter of the part 5 is the processes of democratization and their outcomes in the post-communist countries. The analysis of these outcomes is of paramount importance for the evaluation of the comparative social costs of different ways of post-communist transformation. Taking into consideration only economic costs and benefits, one should consider the Chinese exit way from communism as superior, because it satisfies the criterion of optimality according to Pareto: income of all Chinese has increased, but to different extent, with increasing social-economic inequality as overall outcome. In Central Europe, Baltic countries, and former Soviet Union, similar or even greater inequality has emerged as outcome of the redistribution of wealth under conditions of economic recession. While economic situation of the minority of the population markedly improved from the very start of transformation, it has worsened for the large majority. Only part of this losing majority was compensated by the fruits of the resumed economic growth. Many losers did not live long enough to survive the recession or even died because of the worsened living conditions, because even after 15 years from the collapse of the communism the economy of many post-communist countries has not reached its precommunist level. Significant part of the surviving losers has remained excluded from the benefits of the economic recovery, and they are absolute losers or victims of the postcommunist transformation. Therefore, the author starts the fifth part of the book with an argument, that while assessing the achievements and losses of the post-communist transformation one should take into account not only consumer‘s welfare. In those countries, where processes of the post-communist transformation came to the end with the consolidation of the liberal democratic regime, the losses in the consumer‘s welfare were compensated by the newly acquired civil and political rights (that could be also used by the absolute economic losers). However, not every kind of democracy provides such compensation. Democracy as such is a political regime where top government officials are elected in the free competitive election. Only under conditions of liberal democracy, civil and political rights of the citizens are protected from their own elected government. This protection is achieved institutionally by the division of power between branches of government and their mutual control (horizontal accountability), by the developed network of nongovernmental organizations and free media. Applying discourse analysis, one can distinguish two varieties of liberal democracy: libertarian liberal democracy and social liberal democracy. In the first variety, citizens have only civil and political rights. Under social liberal democracy, citizens have also social rights. Paramount importance of this cleavage is also confirmed by the means of the inductive statistical typological analysis in the work of A. Lijphart. This work discloses two dimensions of differentiation between existing liberal democracies: joint responsibility/power and divided responsibility/power. Next, it detects two clusters (inductive types), called majoritarian democracy and consensus democracy. These two inductive types of liberal democracy approximately correspond to libertarian liberal and social liberal democracy as two deductive types of liberal democracy. Existing attempts (Fortin 2005; Roberts 2006) to gauge typological identity of the post-communist liberal democracies by A. Lijphart‘s means do not allow to draw unambiguous conclusions. In some respects (strong judicial power, independent central banks) post-communist liberal democracies resemble consensual democracies. However, in other respects (pluralist system of interest groups, high disproportionality of elections, weak local municipalities) they are more similar to majoritarian democracies. Cocktail character of the post-communist democracies can be partly explained by the imported character of its institutions – in many countries, they were imported following fashions in constitutional law that have dominated among Western experts in the late 1980s, when independent central banks and strong judiciary were „a must“. Therefore, many formal institutions of the post-communist liberal democracies are consensual, while political process inside these institutions is strongly adverse: political parties fight do-or-die for survival, and the membership in the set of the politically effective parties is rapidly changing. So although formal institutions of post-communist democracy favor development of the consensual social liberal democracy, libertarian and majoritarian features strongly mark its present real content. Because post communist liberal democracies lack stable systems of political parties, some political scientists doubt whether they can already be qualified as consolidated. To resolve these doubts, the author proposes to draw clear distinction between two questions: (1) what is the difference between consolidated liberal democracy and unconsolidated liberal democracy? And (2) what is the difference between consolidated liberal democracy of low quality and that of high quality? In author’s opinion, there are no reasons to doubt the fact that post-communist liberal democracy is consolidated. In those countries that were admitted to NATO and the EU as its new members, liberal democracy is the „only game in town“ (Juan Linz) beyond all reasonable doubt. In all of them, free, fair, and competitive elections have taken place many times, with loosing government parties transferring power in orderly fashion to victorious opposition. There are no strong (and sometimes any) „antisystemic“ political forces that would aspire to come to power and keep it by nonconstitutional ways. At the same time, the quality of democracy is low in almost all dimensions that have been distinguished in the recent work on the quality of democracy. In this respect, the state of the young Lithuanian liberal democracy does not differ much from the situation in other post-communist liberal democracies. In the procedural dimension (including rule of law, competitiveness, vertical and horizontal accountability) there are no significant problems only with respect to competitiveness and horizontal accountability. High corruption and frequent violations of civil rights are symptomatic for weak rule of law. Due to the instability of the system of political parties, vertical accountability is low: after losing trust of voters, politicians manage to avoid punishment by changing political party membership. Elected officeholders are not successful in their attempts to bring public administration under their control, where the influence of the unelected and unaccountable „statesmen“ manipulating elected officials remains widespread. Low quality of the post-communist democracies is also indicated by low voter satisfaction with the activities of the politicians that they have elected and low policy responsiveness: governments rule without taking the public opinion into consideration. Low level of quality in post-communist democracies is manifested most sharply by the fact that the outcomes of the elections did not influence government policies: frequently, the policy of new government did not differ from that of their predecessors. However, these weaknesses of the post-communistic democracy should not be absolutized in an alarming way. Firstly, some of the problems in the liberal democracies (first of all, decreasing responsiveness) are also characteristic for the old liberal democracies. Decreasing responsiveness is one of the negative collateral effects of the deepening European integration. The problem, how to cope with it, remains unsolved not only in practice, but even in the theory. Secondly, it is impossible to improve the quality of democracy in all dimensions at once. For example, horizontal accountability can be increased by giving more power to judiciary and nonmajoritarian agencies. However, this can lead to the decrease of vertical accountability. On the other hand, there can be a hypertrophy of responsiveness, contradicting rule of law and even leading to degeneration of the liberal democracy into the populist democracy. The author makes two conclusions from this analysis. Firstly, the same level of democratic quality can be achieved in alternative ways. Secondly, the methods that work best to increase quality of democracy in the short-term perspective, are not necessary the best ones to achieve this goal in the long-term perspective (and vice versa). Political class that disregards present preferences of voters may succeed in the long-term perspective to educate the electorate with preferences that suit its present policies. Therefore, (and thirdly), the greatest impediment for high quality of democracy in the post-communist countries are their low quality citizens (inherited from the communist times), especially their lack of republican virtues (participatory civic culture). However, there is no sufficient reason to assume that such high quality citizens with republican virtues are needed also for the consolidation of the liberal democracy. One of the two important lessons of the post-communist democratization that contradict influential views in the comparative politics, may be described in the following way: under favourable external conditions, liberal democracy (even if of rather low quality) can also consolidate in countries that lack those structural conditions that were considered as necessary for democratic consolidation in the former research. They include broad middle class (bourgeoisie), stable political party system and participatory civic culture. Another lesson of the post-communist transformation says that dual transition – both parallel democratization and marketization – can succeed. Some designers of the neoliberal shock therapy were not sure about such success. Their advice was to implement all market reforms with maximal speed simultaneously to the destruction of centrally planed-administrative economic system in order to make left populists and neocomunists unable to re-erect it in the case of their comeback. Fearing that dual transition may fail, they preferred presidential democracy, considering as its advantage the possibility to enact at maximal speed (by presidential decrees) those economic reforms that a team of technocrat experts consider as best, without moving legislation proposals through parliamentary procedures subject to procrastination and spoiling through pork-barreling. As a matter of fact, in many post-communist countries simultaneous democratization and marketization displayed a synergetic effect that was strongest under conditions of parliamentary democracy. Frequent change of governments was the obstacle for the groups of early winners, interested in delaying reforms to appropriate rents created by partial reforms, to capture the state and to direct the restoration of capitalism towards political oligarchic capitalism that occured in Russia, Ukraina, Bulgaria, Romania and in number of other postcommunist states. With exception for ambivalent Slovenian case, where market reforms were started in tandem by post-communist president and anticommunist government, market reforms were most consequential and successful in those countries where first free election was won by anticommunist political forces. These were countries of former bureaucratic authoritarian and national communism. In most countries of the former patrimonial communism, liberal democracy remains unconsolidated (e.g., Ukraine) or broken down (Belarus and most probably, Russia). In some cases, communist regime was continued after dropping communist ideology (countries of Central Asia) without any democratic intermezzo. The diversity of the economic systems that have emerged in the sphere of the former Soviet and Yugoslav communism is even greater, representing a new challenge for comparative economic sociology. Differently from the vulgarized basics of neoclassical economics, preached by influential nongovernmental public education institutions in Lithuania, ideas of classical and contemporary economic sociology are comparatively less known for Lithuanian reader. Therefore, the entire sixth part of the book is reserved for introduction into classical (K. Marx, M. Weber, Joseph A. Schumpeter, Adolf Berle, Gardiner Means, John M. Keynes, Karl Polanyi) approaches in the economical sociological and political economical sociology. The author uses the work both of M. Weber and of J. A. Schumpeter to construct the ideal type of rational entrepreneurial capitalism (REC) that provides the reference point for analysis of the diversity of post-communist capitalism. To M. Weber‘s work on capitalism, this concept owes the idea that capitalist economic action can be oriented either productively (towards wealth-creation), or unproductively (towards rent-seeking and redistribution), rational capitalism displaying the first, and the political capitalism the second orientation. Along with entrepreneurial and managerial activities directed to the organization of production employing free labour, M. Weber includes into the scope of the rational capitalism the speculation on the financial markets, considering them as necessary parts of rational capitalism as economic system consisting of markets for consumer‘s goods, labour, land, capital and risk. The activities of financial speculators help to institute risk markets, enabling entrepreneurs engaged in the real economy to act in the relatively stable and predictable (parametric) environment. For M. Weber, rationality of rational capitalism connotes not only the orientation to the profit-maximization at the micro level, but also tendency to optimal allocation of resources at the macro level due to the workings of the „invisible hand“ of the markets. However, this Weberian (and neoclassical) rationality of the rational entrepreneurial capitalism (REC) stands in tension with the role of private entrepreneurship that is pointed to by the second adjective (entrepreneurial). This role was central topic in J. A. Schumpeter‘s work. To entrepreneurs as managers (bearers of the function of optimising calculation), capitalist economy owes its trend to equilibrium and quantitative growth. Entrepreneurs as agents of organizational and technological innovation are driving force for the change of capitalist economy as qualitative development. They bring capitalist economy out of equilibrium and make out of its working the process of creative destruction, proceeding by leaps and bounds. However, because of this feature, rational entrepreneurial capitalist system is also a source of new life risks. Under conditions of the total dependence of a worker on the market, surges in unemployment during the recession phases of the short and long cycles of economic activity expose broad segments of population to dangers of social degradation. These aspects of capitalist economic dynamics are in focus of the work by K. Marx, K. Polanyi, and J. M. Keynes. Theorizing capitalism as a process of development – a process of qualitative change with different regimes of regulation and accumulation – is considered in the book as the unique contribution of the comparative economical sociological analysis, complementing the mode of its analysis practiced in the neoclassical economy, that abstracts from the changes and variations in the institutional framework of economic activity or assumes the existence of the single best institutional framework. Although some institutional frameworks (for example, political oligarchic capitalism, state capitalism, state monopolist capitalism) may be defective in the sense of providing incentives for unproductive, rent-seeking activities, suppressing technological innovation, leading to misallocation and waste of resources, two or more institutional frameworks can be „equally good“ as different versions of REC. They all display the same basic features of economic rationality – microeconomic calculation, orientation of private entrepreneurship to the productive, wealth-creating activities, efficient (in the sense of Pareto optimality) allocation of resources. At the same time, they can strongly differ in their distributive and social consequences (welfare regimes). This is the basic insight in recent work on the varieties of capitalism in the historical institutionalist sociology (Peter A. Hall, David Soskice), that draws upon the former work about Fordist capitalism in the neomarxist French regulation school, upon the research on neocorporatist capitalism in the international political economy, and upon the work on the national versions of capitalism in the institutionalist economy itself. This work has been focused on the causes of the variations of the macroeconomic performance and international competitiveness among the advanced REC countries. In the varieties of capitalism approach by P. A. Hall and D. Soskice, two ideal types of REC – liberal market economy (LME) and coordinated market economy (CME) – are distinguished. This typology is grounded by the analysis how main economic agents (firms) in the capitalist economies coordinate their activities. In the LME, this coordination is realized by classical relations of market competition, while in CME various methods of non-market strategic coordination (conditional on the high levels of trust) are used. Detailed analysis of the differences between two types of capitalism includes comparative analysis of their financial systems, industrial relations, relations of firms with their employees, systems of education and professional training. While ownership rights of the LME firms are widely dispersed among stockholders and frequently change their owners, CME firms have main owners or are related by the relations of cross-ownership, building clusters usually centered around a house bank, providing them a patient capital. In LME, trade unions are weak and divided, both employment and unemployment protection is weak, and wages are settled by the individual agreements between employers and employees. For industrial relations in CME, collective agreements on wages and work conditions at the level of firm, industrial group, branch or even at national level are the norm. Both employment and unemployment protection is strong. Work force builds a community loyal to employing firm. For LME rapid turnover of work force and purely instrumental orientation in the relations between employer and employees are main characteristics. Therefore, firms in LME avoid investing into the professional training of their workers, while this is the case in CME economies, where the public education system, focused on the cultivation of general competences, is supplemented by the professional training run by firms or their associations, and focused on the acquisition of special skills. Basic conclusions of the analysis by P. A. Hall and D. Soskice are confirmed by the findings of the inductive statistical analysis by Bruno Amable who used as inputs the data of the OECD states social and economic statistics. However, B. Amable finds not two, but five types of capitalism: (1) Anglo-Saxon market-based capitalism, (2) Scandinavian social-democratic capitalism, (3) Continental European capitalism, (4) Asian capitalism, (5) Mediterranean capitalism. Because LME and CME are ideal types, it stands for discussion which countries approximate them most closely. While contemporary U.S. capitalism is the most unambiguous case of LME, one can recognize characteristic features of CME in the institutional organization of German, Japan, and Scandinavian capitalism. Some types of capitalism can be qualified as transitory or mixed. Important conclusion made by P. A. Hall and D.Soskice says that both pure CME and pure LME are stable types of capitalism. This contradicts the view of the neoliberal economists who maintain, that only LME, most closely approximated by U.S. capitalism, is stable, and who predict the convergence of the present national and regional diversity of capitalism towards LME under relentless pressure of the forces of globalization. Besides the well-known idea of path-dependence, P. A. Hall‘s and D. Soskice‘s arguments for stability of CME are grounded in the theories of (1) institutional complementarity and (2) comparative institutional advantages. Institutional complementarity means mutual fit of institutional practices from different spheres. Institutionally complementary practices increase each other‘s returns. If these spheres function according to contradictory institutional logics, these returns decrease, leading to the loss of international competitiveness and pressure for change in the direction of the more coherent architecture of institutions. Institutional complementarity is an obstacle for construction of perfect capitalism by borrowing best practices from different types capitalism (e.g., social protection from Sweden, venture capital markets from U.S., and professional training system from Germany). Since firms in LME have no patient capital, they are forced to be “cruel” with their workforce, shedding it when demand slumps. The flexibility of employment has as its collateral consequence lack of loyalty to their firms. By employing disloyal employees, firms avoid investing in their training. Therefore, they do not have at the shop floor level work force with local, largely tacit, knowledge necessary to meet challenges of the high quality diversified production. Another condition of the stability of the type of capitalism as a set of institutional practices is a capacity of these practices to generate institutional advantages in the competition in the world market. These advantages are institutional, because their source are constraints and incentives that institutions provide for entrepreneurial energy and initiative. Because of the crucial role of the sustained innovation for long-term success in the international competition, types of capitalism can be defined as social systems of production and innovation (B. Amable). Institutional architecture characteristic for LME enables a country with such architecture to be successful in the industries and services where radical innovation is a key to success, while CME countries are stronger where incremental innovation leads to success (e.g. diversified quality production of producer‘s and consumer‘s goods). Unlike the mainstream neoliberal views on the consequences of globalization, varieties of capitalism approach predicts not one-, but two-pole convergence, with some of the really existing national capitalisms moving toward purer LME, and another part having a prospect of moving towards CME. Radical innovations bring into life new branches of industry and services. However, as an example of post-war Japan shows, a country that has started to produce products using foreign patents, can outdo inventor countries thanks to the ability to display more flexibility and responsiveness to costumer‘s needs. To put the impact of globalization on the diversity of capitalism in correct perspective, one needs to de-mystify this concept by drawing distinctions between cultural, political, and economic dimensions of globalization. As huge parts of the world (e.g. worlds of Islamic, Indian, Chinese civilization) remain immune for the spells of Hollywood pop culture production, there is no sufficient reason for the diagnosis of cultural globalization. The description of political globalization as decline of national state and rise of the power of international organizations is contradicted by the recent choice of most powerful state in the world (U.S.) to pursue its interests by unilateral actions. Of course, one can define political globalization as the rise of U.S. to global domination. However, this state of affairs can be temporary and transitional thanks to the rise of new powers – first of all, of the socalled BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, China) states. As for economic globalization, its real content seems to boil down to the emergence of the global financial market, while ongoing processes of the integration in the real economy (trade and international division of labour) seem to be described in the more precise way by the concept of regionalization. While internationalization of capital markets makes capital more mobile, giving capital the edge in relations with labour, this is not enough to obliterate national and regional differences between the types of capitalism. It is not the case that the cost of labour is only one or the most important factor deciding where capital moves. Instead, transnational corporations use existing differences between capitalist economies for institutional arbitrage, locating their different divisions in countries with institutional environments most fitting for activities and products of these divisions. The author argues that long-time fluctuations in the economic activities known as Kondratieff waves should be taken into consideration when discussing long-term prospects of the convergence versus survival or even increase of the diversity of capitalism. These fluctuations are caused by revolutionary changes in the production technologies (production functions). Most credible explanation of recent success of U.S. capitalism refers to the ability of LME to provide best institutional framework for radical technological innovations. Neoliberal economic reforms in the early 1980s that have destroyed managerial capitalism in U.S., replacing it with stockholder capitalism, provided the capital market of this country with supply of venture capital surpassing that in other countries. This enabled U.S. to be first in realizing opportunities for radical innovation that were opened by the advances of the information and telecommunication technologies, and to reap pioneer‘s advantages. However, present Kondratieff wave is the only one of five waves that can be distinguished since the 18th century. The history of the former waves teaches the lesson that after pioneer‘s advantages (characteristic for the first (ascending) phase of a wave) are exhausted, later developers have good chances to catchup with them, using non-market methods of coordination of economic activities to accelerate the reception of the leader‘s know-how. An example of such state-led spurt was the rise of East-Asian “tigers” in the seventies and nineties that took place during the descending phase of the former (the fourth) Kondratieff wave. While LME provides best institutional environment for radical innovation, countries featuring CME institutions are best performers during the phase when potential for radical innovation in the framework of new technological paradigm becomes exhausted and competitive success becomes conditional on the capabilities of incremental innovation. Hence, one can expect the emergence of new successful national versions of CME during the coming downward phase of the world economy. The discussion of the state and prospects of global capitalism provides the horizon for 7th part of the book that is focused on the question what kind of capitalism is emerging in the post-communist countries, with special attention being paid for the peculiarities of Lithuanian capitalism. This discussion starts with the survey of the body of available literature. In the work on post-communist capitalism during the first postcommunist decade, one can discern two approaches. Skeptics and pessimists (e.g. Michael Burawoy and Katherine Verdery) have focused on destructive effects of postcommunist transformation, conceiving post-communist realities as economic involution that means the rise of primitive forms of capitalism (trade, comprador, peripheric capitalism) and even processes of (re)feudalization. Optimists (David Stark, Laszlo Bruszt) asserted that in some post-communist countries new form of capitalism is in making that may be superior to the really existing capitalism in the old West. During the second decade, another cleavage has emerged. Some researchers maintain that differences between post-communist capitalism(s) on the one side and rational entrepreneurial capitalism(s) in advanced countries on another are still deeper than similarities between them. Others argue that in the diversity of post-communist capitalism one can detect the same lines of differentiation that were disclosed between the cases of mature or advanced rational entrepreneurial capitalism by P. A. Hall, D. Soskice and other historical institutionalists. This second line of thinking about postcommunist capitalism is represented by the work of David Lane, Mark Knell, Martin Srholec, Clemens Buchen, Vlad Mychnenko, Magnus Feldmann and others. First approach is developed most consistently by neoclassical sociology – a group of researchers led by Ivan Szelenyi, and including Lawrence P. King, Gil Eyal, and others. Second approach is represented also by Bela Greskovits, Dorothee Bohle and other researchers who theorize post-communist capitalism through the viewpoint of the Immanuel Wallerstein‘s theory of the capitalist world systems and classify postcommunist capitalism as peripheric (in Eastern Europe and Balkans) or semi-peripheric (in Baltic and Central Europe), Neoclassical sociologists discern in the diversity of the post-communist capitalism(s) three forms of capitalism. The first one is represented by capitalism from without. This form resembles most closely REC in the old West. However, capitalism from without is different from the old Western REC in as much as it is capitalism without capitalists. Because of the very active participation of foreign capital in the privatization, no strong national economic bourgeoisie (class of the capital owners) has emerged in these countries. Instead, cultural bourgeoisie is socially dominant in these countries. It was recruited from the former (in the communist time) technical and humanist intelligentsia. Coming to power after the collapse of communism, intellectuals thwarted national communist nomenclature to privatize public property. Instead, they sold it cheaply to foreign capital and took the positions of its local agents and trustees. In those countries where nomenclature privatization was not blocked, second form of capitalism has emerged that is described by I. Szelenyi as top-down capitalism, or alternatively (because of the role that client-patron networks play in its social organization) as political patrimonial capitalism. Thus, this form includes cases that are classified in the 12th chapter of this book in the more differentiating way as political oligarchic, state monopolist, and state capitalism. Third way for post-communist capitalism to emerge is to grow from below. It grows out of private sector, functioning along with state sector and gradually overshadowing and outdoing it. In this way, capitalism is emerging in China and Vietnam. Because of the important role that state sector still plays in the economies of these countries, I. Szelenyi also calls this third form of post-communist capitalism hybrid capitalism. In this book, following view is defended with respect to the question of the comparability between post-communist and old Western capitalism: although there are essential differences between the oligarchic, state monopolist, and state capitalism in most former republics of Soviet Union on the one side, and REC on the another, typological methods and concepts from the historical institutionalist work on the varieties of capitalism in the advanced Western countries are already fruitfully applicable to the Baltic and Central European countries that have joined the EU and NATO in 2004. Findings of the typological quantitative statistical research (Berrou and Carrincazeaux 2005; McMenamin 2004) are presented that provide the evidence that on the eve of joining the EU, the institutional architecture of three Central European (Vyshegrad) countries – the Czech Republic, Poland and Hungary – displayed most similarity with the Mediterranean capitalism countries. Among post-communist countries, one can find only one case with the marked features of CME. This country is Slovenia that was most consistent and successful in leaving communism by the way of innovationally oriented incremental gradualist reforms, and has arrived at social or corporate capitalism. At the opposite pole, one finds as Slovenia‘s antipode – the neoliberal Estonia. Although exit ways from communism and present architectures of economic institutions are very different in these countries, both of them are reputed achievers of post-communist transformation. Therefore, one can use them as corroborating instances for the thesis of P. A. Hall and D. Soskice claiming that different institutional architectures of capitalist institutions can display similar levels of macroeconomic performance. Concluding two chapters of the book are focused on the topic of the typological identity of Lithuanian capitalism. Seeking to find out which type of capitalism is forming in Lithuania, the author compares this country with two antipode cases of the postcommunist communism – neocorporate Slovenia and neoliberal Estonia. In the 20th chapter, author argues that capitalism in Lithuania represents the same (neoliberal) variety of capitalism that capitalism in Estonia exemplifies, and discusses the question why Lithuania‘s macroeconomic performance after neoliberal reforms was weaker than in Estonia‘s case. The author criticizes explanation of Lithuania‘s weaker performance by economic policies of Lithuania‘s excommunists who came to power in 1992, when market reforms in Lithuania were at the very height. He draws attention to the facts that main, nominally right, political opponent of excommunists – Lithuanian conservatives – promoted political initiatives that were Leftist populist in terms of Western political discourse both while in opposition and during their comeback to power (in 1996-1999). He advances a culturalist (Weberian) hypothesis that attributes relative success of Estonia‘s neoliberal choice to peculiarities of the Estonia‘s cultural legacy that was decisively influenced during the 18th-first half of 19th century by the current of ascetic Protestantism known as Herrnhuter movement. Due to this legacy, Estonians were quicker in their adaptation to new conditions of the economic action than Lithuanians, whose culture was marked by the traditions of the rural way of life and by the mentality shaped in times of baroque Catholicism. At the first sight, the thesis that the post-communist capitalism in Lithuania is of LME type, is contradicted by the facts that many institutional spheres in Lithuania have features characteristic for other types. For example, present system of social protection in Lithuania is most similar not to the residual Anglo-Saxon welfare state, but to clientelist corporate model characteristic for countries of Southern Europe (Bernotas and Guogis 2006: 161). Even in that champion of post-communist neoliberalism – Estonia – one does not find active and liquid stock market that is crucially important attribute of LME. However, what matters most for the detection of the typological identity of Lithuanian capitalism, are trends of the change in the institutional architecture that are governed by the logic of the complementarity between different institutional spheres. Even those post-communist countries that had chose the most radical shock therapy, were not able to reform all institutional spheres of the social life at once. The reform of the systems of education, health care, social protection (first of all, pension system) was postponed for later time. At the very start of the exit from communism, only minimal changes in the order inherited from the communist time were made. For this reason, institutional architecture of most post-communist countries still remains an unstable conglomerate of institutional spheres working according to contradictory logics with dysfunctional consequences. These contradictions mount the pressure to continue reforms. However, these contradictions may be solved either by reforms leading in the direction of the more consequent neoliberal, or that of social capitalism. Observation of the ongoing reform process in Lithuania during the last decades discloses unambiguous trend leading in the direction of the more consequent LME system. Importantly, in most cases the direction and contents of these reforms are better explained not by arguments that are publicly advanced in their favour, but by functional needs and interests associated with the construction of the more consequent LME. Arguments in favour of privatization of pension system, refering to unsustainability of the present pay-as-you go system, are flawed (Lazutka 2006). However, they will help to construct active and liquid stock market. The reform of higher education in making has as its key element the switch from the public to private (by students‘ fees) financing of higher education, and is legitimated by the argument that it will promote the quality of higher education by pressing universities to be more responsive to the turns and twists of the market demand. It is difficult to believe that this will be real consequence of coming reforms, because total funds at the disposition of the Lithuanian universities will not increase, and desired outcomes cannot be achieved simply by the better use of available resources. However, among the consequences of the reform, there will be the development of the market culture of the self-responsible living. Credit markets will expand, creating new business opportunities for banking sector in Lithuania, and labour market will be refilled by new fungible entrants starting their working lives under the burden of higher education loan. Is (was) there no alternative to the neoliberal capitalism in Lithuania? To answer this question, the comparison of Lithuania and Estonia is supplemented by the comparison of both countries with Slovenia. Slovenia‘s case is important, firstly, as a demonstration that catholic cultural legacy was no fatal impediment for macroeconomically successful exit from communism. Secondly, Slovenia‘s case demonstrates that indeed there was an alternative both to the neoliberal mode of exit from communism (via shock therapy), and to its overall neoliberal imitative orientation, leading to the present path of post-communist transformation where Lithuania is presently moving in the steps of Estonia. Could Lithuania make its exit from communism in Slovenian mode and way, transforming itself not in the direction of the Anglo-Saxon neoliberal but that of the Scandinavian social-democratic or neocorporatist continental European capitalism? The author answers this question in a negative way, substantiating his answer by the comparison of the initial conditions of post-communist transformation in Lithuania, Estonia, and Slovenia. The three most important obstacles for Lithuania‘s exit from communism in Slovenian mode and way are considered (1) lack of the basic market institutions and skills how to govern enterprises under market condition that Slovenia has inherited from Yugoslav market socialism; (2) nearly complete absence of the Lithuanian products at the Western markets before communism‘s collapse, while nearly quarter of Slovenian export was directed to these markets on the eve of the exit from communism; (3) adversary character of the Lithuanian politics during the early phase of postcommunist transformation, leading to the ideologization of the technical questions of the market reforms. Early establishment of consensus democracy in Slovenia was facilitated by preservation of the intellectual hegemony of the Left in Slovenia, where its reputation was not tainted by the record of antinational policies in the service of the foreign (Soviet) imperialism, as this was the case in Lithuania. Can present pathway of the institutional change in Lithuania change its direction, leading towards social or neocorporate capitalism? The author argues that since Lithuania joined the EU, the single most important factor deciding the future of Lithuanian capitalism is the course that the processes of European integration and europeanization will take during the next decades. Important part of the legitimating ideology driving these processes is so-called European social model that can be considered as a programme for convergence of the European national political economies towards the CME. However, external pressure to harmonize national legal systems with acquis communitaire (body of common European law), led to the continuation and deepening of the neoliberal reforms rather than to the change of their overall direction towards social capitalism or CME. Up to the present time, processes of European integration have corresponded to the greater degree to the neoliberal than to the social-democratic ideals. This was the case because these processes involved mainly negative integration – the removal of the obstacles for free movement of the goods, services, capital, and labour. Social policies of the EU were oriented towards the minimal standards. Therefore, they did not work as a stimulus to reform post-communist countries following patterns of Scandinavian or continental social capitalism. Rather than direct the transformation processes in the post-communist countries towards CME, Eastern enlargement of the EU can be the turning point directing institutional change in the EU towards LME, with accession countries acting as Trojan horses for the forces of the neoliberal Anglo-Saxon capitalism. However, it remains beyond the reasonable doubt that in the time horizon closing with the convergence of the Lithuania‘s level of social-economic development with that of older members of the EU, stronger (in comparison with the U.S.) social orientation of eurocapitalism will remain its distinguishing feature.