Federalism and Regionalism in Contemporary Russia by Igor Kossikov, expert of State Duma Professor at the Russian Academy of Sciences, Institute of Ethnology and Anthropology This speech has been pronounced during the Thirteenth International Seminar European Union, Federalism and International Democracy, hold in Ventotene on September 1st-8th 1996 Issues of federalism are today and will for a long time remain critical for the political and economic life of Russia. The contemporary Russian state is a special type of a federation which knows no analogues in the world. It emerged as a result of the disintegration of the USSR, on the basis of its largest republic which had no sovereignty before. Having adopted the Declaration of sovereignty in 1990 and elected its own president, Russia became an independent state and a subject of international law. At the same time, it inherited its internal structure from the Soviet era - the division into administrative territories and ethnic (nation) state formations, as well as the formal title "the Russian Federation", although it was a unitary state de facto as of the moment of adopting the Declaration. The entire development of Russia starting from 1990 until today has been a complicated transitional period the transformation of a unitary state into a real federation. State reform coincided with systemic reforms - the transition to democracy and market economy throughout the entire former Soviet Union, and Russian in particular. That represents one of the key differences in the emergence of the model of Russian federalism. This fact accounts for special difficulties of this process. In the course of 6 years (1990-1996) the Russian Federation (RF) has gone through several phases in its transformation. Let me briefly remind the reader of them: 1. 1990-1992 (until March) - the so-called parade of sovereignties. During that period the ethnic formations within Russia (former autonomous republics and okrugs) sought to upgrade their political status, to win recognition as independent republics as a part of the RF. Movements for sovereignty were led by the republics of Tatarstan, Bashkorostan, Yakutia and others. At the same time the national idea, the idea of the restoration of ethnic states, language and culture clearly prevailed. It was by all means promoted by small-scale ethnic movements and was taken up by local and regional political elites which sought to retain power under new conditions or obtain power from the hands of former party nomenklatura. In 1991-1992 there existed a real threat of ethnic separatism, a split of the unified country, and because the trend of decentralizing power obviously dominated, and the power of the Center was extremely unstable. 2. The Federation Treaty concluded in March 1992 served to overcome the increasing ethnic separatism. It presented the maximum possible compromise of the central authorities and regional ruling elites as of the moment of its conclusion, and preserved the unity and territorial integrity of the Russian Federation within its historical borders. The time from March 31 1992 until December 1993 is the first period when the RF existed on this new legal basis. The Treaty failed to satisfy both unitarists and separatists. although it played the positive role of dividing authority within the Russian Federation for the first time, albeit not fully. Two republics within Russia - Tatarstan and Chechnya - did not sign the Federation Treaty in March ~992, having seriously challenged the territorial integrity of Russia. They proclaimed themselves fully independent states which were not a part of the federation. Chechnya's location on the border worsened the situation by presenting the possibility of real secession. The location of Tatarstan in the very center of the RF's territory made the chance of its "secession" from the Federation rather problematic. In 1992. neither republic suggested any formulas for coexistence with the unified federation. The formulations that they used were very vague. especially from the viewpoint of the international law phrases "together with Russia, but from without". For this reason, the federal authorities did not recognize independence of Tatarstan and Chechnya and instead considered them inseparable parts of a unified Russia. The period after the Federation Treaty was been signed only partially eased the separatist trends in Russia. A number of the republics signed the Treaty, but ensured the legal priority of their republican constitutions on their territory Russia entered a true legal crisis, for the RF had no Constitution of its own, and it regions adopted their own Constitutions without prior consent from each other and the Center. This process affected not only the republics, but oblasts and other administrative territories in the RF, which also sought the upgrading of their status and the recognition of their rights equal to the republics. Constitutions of their own (the Statutes of the obalsts) began to appear, and there were attempts to proclaim independent states ( The Ural republics, Far Eastern republic). Although in contrast to the republics, the oblasts did not use ethnic slogans in their movement for greater independence of the Center and autonomy, there emerged a threat of Russia's disintegration, division into regions. 3. The time after December 1993. when the Constitution of the RF was adopted, was the third period. The Federation Treaty, or, more precisely, its main provision, became a part of the Constitution. In line with the Treaty, the Constitution secures the composition of the federation: 89 members (in the Constitution of the RF they are referred to as the "subjects of the federation"). Among them there are 21 republics, 6 krais, 49 oblasts, 10 autonomous okrug, 1 autonomous oblast and 2 cities of federal significance. Two types of the subjects can be identified - nationstate formations, i.e. the members of the federation which have the attributes of independent states (these are all republics) and administrative territorial formations (krais, oblasts, cities - Moscow and St. Petersburg). At present independent subjects of various kind are referred to as "regions" in academic works and political practice. The relations along the axis Center - regions (89 subjects), i.e. between the allfederal bodies of power and administration. on the one hand. and the leaders of the regions. on the other hand. represent the main factor behind the stability and effective development of the country. The process of division of power between the bodies of federal and regional authorities was not completed by the adoption of Constitution in 1993. It is still under way and is being corrected by political, social and economic reforms in Russia. The transformation of the Russian Federation is far from being complete. We find ourselves at yet another transitional stage when the prospects of the future state system and the mechanisms of its functioning are not entirely clear. Discussions between the adherents of various models of Russian federalism who have different views on the status of this or that region within the model have not quieted. There is a provincial model (in Russian - gubernia) or unitary-provincial. In accordance with this model, Russia would be divided into provinces roughly equal in size (the territories which would be analogous to German lands or American states), not taking into consideration the ethnic composition of the peoples living on these territories or their social and cultural orientations. The opponents of dividing Russian into provinces, on the contrary, tend to see the current asymmetrical federation as an absolute and categorically deny the possibility of allocating equal political rights to republics and oblast's - this is a nationalist-federalist model. Theoreticians of federalism in general claim that contemporary multisubject federation will not last long as administration is too difficult. These skeptics think that in the future, the number of independent regions in Russia will decrease as the regions themselves grow larger. Current interregional associations formed as an instrument of cooperation for neighbouring territories which are closely related one to another geographically and economically are seen as prototypes of future Russian regions. There are associations such as Chernozemie (oblasts of central Russia;), the Urals, the Volga region, the Siberian agreement, etc. As of today the Russian Federation seems to be still a long way from any of these three models. It maintains its unique features: - it consists of many subjects and is difficult to administer, with tensions emerging not between the republics and oblasts, but between national okrugs which are a part of the number of oblasts. For instance, there are two ethnic okrugs on the territory of Tyumen oblast: Yamalo-Nenetz and Khanty-Mansi. All three formations are equal subjects of federation, according to the Constitution of the RF. However, it is unclear to whom the natural resources of these territories oil and gas - belong as of today, i.e. the issues of property have not been fully resolved. There are quite a few of such cases. - Federative relations in Russia are still formed by means of delegating proxies "from the top down", i.e. from the federal bodies of power and administration to the regional ones. Opposite examples, when the territories delegate their proxies to the Center, are extremely uncommon. In this sense, Russia has so far preserved the strong features of a unitary state with the elements of a federation. But a certain unitarism seems to be saving the country from turning into a confederation. - In equalities in the rights of the subjects now are being evened out by means of bilateral treaties between the executive federal authority and the administration of the regions. It has become customary to talk about a Russian Federation that is built on constitutional and contractual relations. The treaties that the Center has concluded with the regions are meant to deal with the political and legal problems which arise in their relations - in the sphere of differentiating the areas of responsibility and adopting the decisions of federal bodies of the state authority and the bodies of authority in the regions. The first treaty was signed with the Republic of Tatarstan (RT) in February of 1994, it put an end to the disputed relations between the federal authorities with this republic. It partially smoothed over the contradictions and discrepancies between the Constitution of the RF and the Constitution of the RT. A package of mostly economic was appended to the Treaty. Currently (August 1996) more than 20 treaties with the subjects of federation have been signed. notably. not just with the republics. but with oblasts and krais. Treaties with the republics of Tatarstan. Bashkortostan, Kabardino-Balkaria, North Ossetia, etc. were the first to be signed. as for the oblasts, they were Sverdlovsk oblast, Krasnodarsky krai, Kaliningradsky and Orenburgsky oblast.. The treaties on the differentiation of the issues of administration and mutual delegation of power between the federal authority and the subjects of the RF are a new formula for relations within the framework of the federation. They conform with Article II of the Constitution of the RF and at the same time it considerably broaden the legal framework for the activity of the regions. Such a resolution of internal federal problems found many opponents among lawyers, fiananciers and economists. The lawyers believe that the treaties with the subjects of the federation violate the single legal place created by the Russian Constitution. Financiers and businessmen express their doubts whether the practice of concluding treaties will complicate the process of conducting economic reforms according to common "rules of the game" for the whole country. Undoubtedly, there are certain controversial aspects. However, life has proven that the treaties, even not quite perfect, are better that open confrontation which developed into the war with Chechnya. The practice of concluding bilateral treaties between the center and the regions, initially of a limited character, being 'trial" or "experimental" as in the case with Tatarstan will be broadened in the nearest future. However it will not cover all 89 subjects, dealing only, according to our prognosis, with a number of problem regions. Preparatory work to adopt the federal Law "On the general principles of differentiating the issues of administration and proxies between the bodies of state authority of the Russian Federation" is under way now. It will stipulate unified demands to the process of concluding treaties, will lead to the unification of approaches in this matter, for until now the developers of the treaties and agreements have acted on the basis of the President of the RF's decrees. Along with political and legal problems. the treaties and agreements deal with the economic issues of the Center's interaction with the regions In this respect four groups of problems can be identified: 1. budget and tax relations within the framework of the federation; 2. the differentiation of property rights of the subjects. which has turned into an area of conflict in the course of privatization; 3. the rights of the regions and Center in foreign economic relations (customs and currency regimes, border cooperation); 4. the mechanism of distribution of federal budget aid to regions in crisis and depression. levelling of economic and social conditions of development through regional policy. Today there is undoubtedly a common trend in political and economic life of Russia -a gradual delegation of authority from the top to below, the growth of the independence of the Russian regions. At the same time, after the stage of "sovereignization" which became especially noticeable in the republics, there seems to have been a marked sobering both in the Center and in the republics. The regional elites realized that quite often they were not capable of carrying out market reforms without the assistance of the Center and close interregional cooperation. The Center, in turn, has recognized the danger of absolutizing regional peculiarities, which leads to the destruction of the territorial integrity of the country. The majority of experts who have studied the problems of modern state systems in Russia and various aspects of Russian federalism agree that at present the separatism of certain subjects of the Federation, especially national separatism has to a large extent been overcome (with the exception of Chechnya). At the same time, economic regionalism has become more pronounced, the development of different regions in Russia are becoming more and more differentiated. Although this differentiation existed from the start in such fields as natural resources, climate, demography, social, economic and ethnic spheres, the very course of the reforms has intensified it. Regions with varied economic specializations have demonstrated different abilities to adapt to new market conditions, and, naturally, their economic and political interest are quite diverse. It is absolutely necessary for the Center to take this fact into consideration in order to prevent sharp contrasts in the standards of living, income and rates of economic development between the regions. At present the following are recognized as the principal goals of federal policy. of which regional policy is a part: the defense and maintenance of the interests of the Russian Federation on a whole, maintaining the integrity of its territory, as well as the integrity of its legal and economic space. In reality, the range of authority of federal structures to ensure the defense of the interests of the Federation without infringing upon the rights and the independence of the subjects granted by the Constitution remains to be determined. The most complicated issue in the formation of the Russian Federation is Chechnya. This is related to both the history of the Chechen people and to serious mistakes of the current Russian leadership in its ethnic policy. There appear to be two mutually exclusive views on the role and status of Chechnya. In the view of Moscow leaders, Chechnya is an integral part of Russia, one of the subjects of the federation, whereas for the Chechens, or at least for their vast majority, the republic is an independent state. The Chechen Republic, in their belief , determines the fate of its own people on its own but retains close ties with Russia. Chechnya adopted a Declaration of state sovereignty back in 1990 and during all the subsequent years under D.Dudayev's regime attempted to uphold independence, not having signed any treaties with the RF, not taking part in referendums on the Russian Constitution, etc. In the language of lawyers, Chechnya remained within the legal space of Russia but functioned by its own laws. At the same time, it had open borders with Russia, used Russian currency, and enjoyed freedom of travel for its citizens and other advantages of a common economic space. Surprising as it may seem, Russia was extremely tolerant of Dudayev's regime and the freedom of his actions for about four years, although it failed to recognize him in the legal sense. Experts find it difficult to explain much of the bilateral relations between Moscow and Grozny in 1991-1994. Undoubtedly there is a background. hidden policy of either certain influential persons or groups of people with their economic interests. It is precisely due to this that Chechnya has in fact turned into a criminal zone. a shadow economy on the territory of Russia. In Chechnya itself, there were many opponents of Dudayev's regime under his rule, an opposition formed among politicians and common people who advocated the preservation of former ties between the republic and the RF. The talks between the Center and Chechnya on a bilateral treaty and resolving the issue of the republic's status were slow and regularly interrupted. The military actions started in December of 1994 by federal troops have only led to the consolidation of a majority of the Chechen people against the federal Center. The extreme cruelty of this war erased the line between the opponents and proponents of independence, having united all people in their struggle for independence as they understand it (often an idealistic concept). Today it is obvious that this problem does not have a military solution. The prospects for Chechnya's future are still unclear. One of the versions of a possible resolution would be to giving the republic a status that no other Russian territory had ever had. Such a formula would mean the following: Russia recognizes Chechnya's independence, while Chechnya remains a part of Russia tinder a special protectorate. In this respect, there is a possibility that the Chechens in the future will demand a broader international representation and might claim admission to the UN. Until now, the Chechen Republic of Ichkeria has not been recognized in the international sense. The Chechen leaders have already made attempts to make their power in Chechnya legitimate, in particular, by having turned to the Organization of Unrepresented Peoples. In the coming years the world public and international institutions may face the necessity to either resolve or at least consider the issue of the participation of several republics which are a part of the RF in international organizations. The Republic of Tatarstan, for instance, which used to regard itself as the "independent state, associated with Russia" would like to have an independent representative in the UN. So far it seeks to broaden its presence in the EC and other European economic organizations. In the future, this and other problems will need to be taken into account when dealing with the whole complex of issues related to reforming the UN. Raphael Khakimov. Path Forward for the Russian Federation. After four years of debate and inconclusive results, the problems of regional policy and ethnic relations have now come to the fore of the political agenda in the Russian Federation. The 1993 Constitution left the issue of state structure far from resolved. There has been no effective institution for implementing ethnic and regional policy (the Russian Ministry for Nationalities and Regional Policy has had four different heads in three years). The leadership in Moscow has declared a clear commitment to federalism. In the current situation, however, ill-conceived attempts in the area of regional and ethnic policy might result in a backtrack to unitarism and a compromise of democratic values in an effort to strengthen central state control. There is a dilemma at the heart of the problem: the current Russian Federation was constituted on the basis of a mix of some ethnically-based and some purely administrative territories. In the modem world, from the point of view of protecting the right of all citizens regardless of their race or ethnic affiliation, it is in principle more desirable for a state to replace the ethno-territorial principle with the concept of "cocitizenship," as was mentioned in President Yeltsin's annual address. A multitude of ethnic problems have been engendered by the contradictory nature of two principles which, from the very beginning, were established as the basis of the structure of the Russian Federation: the ethno-territorial principle and the administrative-territorial principle. This becomes clear today as a redistribution of functions and powers is taking place between the federal government and subjects of the Federation. Under present conditions, a historical necessity for both principles to co-exist persists. At the same time the contradiction between them will diminish on the basis of a new notion of the nation as co-citizenship (sograzhdanstvo). which is enshrined in the Constitution.1 If the Russian Federation had states (US), or Lands (Germany), or governorships (Tsarist Russia) instead of ethnic republics, the argument goes, then the federal government would be in a better position to protect the civil and political rights of all citizens regardless of their ethnicity. But the current state structure of the Russian federation is ≈ like it or not ≈ a historical reality. On the face of it, the current structure seems absurd in many ways: there are some ethnic republics that have a majority of the local ethnic group and a strong sense of national identity (Tatarstan), while others, such as the Republic of Sakha-Yakutia which have a majority of Russians (50% of the population) and a minority of the titular ethnic group (33%). The creation of many of these ethnic republics was part of a Stalinist policy of dividing and coopting local and national elites. There are also some non-ethnic subjects of the Federation, such as Lipetsk Oblast, which relative to others is small and economically less significant. Even if it were in principle desirable to move toward "co-citizenship" as the key principle for organizing the complex state structure of the Russian Federation, what strategy would produce this outcome and over how much time? Over what period must this be done in order not to threaten overall political stability? How can existing ethnic groups be accommodated ? Some regions pose a particular challenge. Though the Russian Federation is 82% Russian, there are a few regions with a majority non-Russian population and a history of their own governing structures. These regions were incorporated into the Russian empire by conquest (Tatarstan, North Caucasus). These regions might be compared to Quebec, a French-speaking region conquered by the English in the eighteenth century. In the Volga-Ural region today, Russians account for 44% of the population, while the share made up by indigenous ethnic groups is growing. The peoples of the North Caucasus are not only an ethnic mosaic but they differ dramatically from other groups in Russia in terms of worldview, value systems and social structures, particularly in the persistence of clan identities. The religious factor is also important: against the background of the Chechen conflict, Islam as the dominant religion in the North Caucasus currently reinforces existing ethnic cleavages with the traditionally Orthodox Russians. Islam is also the dominant religion of Tatarstan, though it has not been a significant factor in political developments to date. It was precisely in these two regions that Moscow has had the greatest difficulty in its efforts to build a new Federation. Tatarstan and Chechnya were the only two republics that refused to sign the Federation Treaty of March 1992, which the leadership in Moscow saw as an effort to preserve the integrity ≈ and stem the possible breakdown ≈ of the Russian Federation in the face of the "parade of sovereignties." Bashkortostan, a Republic bordering Tatarstan that has more Tatars and Russians than Bashkirs, signed with specific reservations. There are other areas with special historical circumstances such as Tyva (an independent state until 1944). They signed the Federation Treaty but still represent problematic cases. In order to clarify the relations of Tatarstan and Chechnya with the federal center, Moscow proposed to sign treaties with these two regions that did not sign the Federation Treaty. Vice Premier Sergei Shakhrai has recently stated that the following principles guided their actions: ∙ To sign framework treaties only with those subjects of the Russian Federation that were not party to the 1992 Federation Treaty; ∙ To sign in advance concrete agreements on critical questions of social and economic policy; ∙ To rely on the results of a legal analysis of the corresponding constitutions, laws and other normative acts of the Federal Constitution and laws of Russia; ∙ Not to allow any specific subject of the Federation to obtain any "special" status not envisaged by the Constitution of the Russian Federation or leading to infringement of the rights of other subjects of the Federation.2 In actual fact, the federal leadership was so preoccupied with critical problems of economic and political reform, as well as internal power struggles (where regional support in the form of the Council of Heads of the Republics was used by President Yeltsin in his battle with the old parliament), that some actions may have been more improvisations or dictated by Realpolitik than by the above listed principles stated ex post facto. In practice, Moscow in large part signed treaties with those regions that were wellorganized and powerful ≈ politically and economically ≈ and where the internal political situation was particularly complex, involving a risk of destabilization or separatism. Tatarstan was a case of a powerful and well-organized republic where accommodation of President Shaimiev could guarantee internal stability and the moderation of extreme nationalist groups within Tatarstan. Moreover, Tatarstan possessed significant oil resources, developed industry and trained personnel. Republics and regions that were net contributors to the federal budget were in a stronger bargaining position vis-a-vis Moscow and many managed to stray farther and exercise a greater degree of independence. On the other hand, subsidized regions sought to garner more resources from the Center by "behaving themselves" to a greater degree. After three years of serious negotiations and the signing of twelve specific agreements, Moscow signed a Treaty with Tatarstan in February 1994. At that time (in contrast to his current position), Sergei Shakhrai stated that Moscow was ready to sign similar treaties with any subject of the Federation that was willing to follow the same process. He specifically mentioned Chechnya, but negotiations with General Dudayev, a nationalist leader, failed and resulted in the current tragic outcome. Subsequently, Moscow did sign a treaty with Bashkortostan in the Volga region (August 1994). In the North Caucasus, though no agreement was reached with General Dudayev in Chechnya, Moscow did sign a treaty with Kabardino-Balkaria (November 1994) and North Ossetia (March 1995). President Yeltsin personally supported these cases, but Sergei Shakhrai, representing the government Commission on Preparation of Intra-State Treaties, sent a memorandum to President Yeltsin right afterwards recommending that the process of signing treaties be stopped immediately. Those standing in line to sign a treaty include Udmurtia in the Volga region; Dagestan; Ingushetia and KarachaevoCherkessia in the North Caucasus; the Republic of Sakha-Yakutia (Far East) and the Kaliningrad Oblast. Again, we see a dilemma for the federal leadership. What if all 89 subjects of the Russian Federation want to sign a separate treaty with Moscow? This would seem to threaten the very basis of a coherent federation. Some experts argue that a federation can be asymmetrical and give special status to a few select subjects, but not all subjects. Moreover, businessmen do not want to have special laws in each region that might contradict federal legislation. There is a need for a standard legal framework for market relations to develop effectively. At the same time, federal authorities cannot simply abolish the existing state structure without serious risk of destabilization. Shakhrai has proposed that "territorialadministrative reforms be conducted before the June 1996 elections." The most influential republican leader. President Shaimiev, has been highly critical of this proposal and has warned publicly that altering the situation with the Treaty would "result in longterm destabilization of the Russian Federation. Citizens of the Republic of Tatarstan would most definitely boycott elections to the Federal Assembly as well as the Russian Presidency, as they did once already."3 The challenge, then, relates to finding a strategy to achieve over time a coherent centralized government with a healthy degree of decentralization and accommodation of ethnic groups. What is an appropriate degree of devolution of power in the Russian Federation? We must keep in mind that the degree of local autonomy that obtained by Tatarstan, the leader in the effort to devolve power to the local regions, is still on all counts less than any US state such as California or Montana.4 From the perspective of the traditionally highly centralized Soviet/Russian state, however, the degree of local sovereignty obtained by Tatarstan may seem significant. Though there are some common principles of federal relations, every federative country has its unique experience such that the German model differs substantially from the Canadian model. The experience of the United States or Switzerland cannot be mechanically transplanted to Russian soil. At the same time it would be misguided not to glean valuable lessons from the experience of other countries, m doing so one has to bear in mind such peculiarities of Russia as its vast size, economic capacity and ethnic and cultural diversity. Russia has a particularly complex historical legacy as a result of its imperial conquests and the arbitrary territorial divisions and deportations of the totalitarian Soviet period. As noted, there is also a complex political process underway in Russian Federation today as it undergoes a political and economic transition of unprecedented proportions. Any approach would need to take into account the mentality and political culture of Russian society, the nature and character of existing and evolving institutions, as well as their current capacity to grow and develop democratically. In an effort to summarize the challenge, the following two primary goals can be stated. First, there is a need to achieve a federation in Russia that is ultimately coherent, stable and democratic, providing equal rights for all subjects. Simply put, this can be achieved either by pushing down those regions ≈ like Tatarstan ≈ that have already achieved some local decision-making power, or else by raising the status of other subjects, the oblasts and krais, to the level of republics like Tatarstan. President Shaimiev has supported the latter position and sees the status of Tatarstan as a step in the direction of a normal, democratic Russian Federation. The second main goal is to find ways to accommodate those particularly complex regions where there is a genuinely challenging ethnic situation with special historical circumstances, such as Tatarstan, the North Caucasus, and Tyva. These regions may have a claim to some special arrangement or status, at least in the short-term. Any political plan to eliminate the republics is fraught with destabilizing consequences. For some ethnic groups that were forcibly deported under Soviet rule, the issue of preserving their republics has an existential dimension: it represents a safeguard against the possible recurrence of such tragedies in the future. There is also the fact that behind the existing republics stand entrenched interests and inertia formed over decades of Soviet rule. There are also new interests formed in the post-Soviet period of redistribution of economic wealth controlled by local authority figures. For all these reasons, any attempt at massive political restructuring entails unpredictable and destabilizing elements. In order to achieve these two aims, we elaborate an approach below, a step-by-step strategy over five years: 1) Refrain from efforts to cancel the current infra-state treaties, which are pragmatic responses to complex relationships needed to maintain stability in the process of building a new Russian Federation. For the time being, there is a need to give special treatment to particularly difficult cases to allow voluntary integration into the Federation. This is a complex challenge for federal authorities throughout the world. As Donald Horowitz has argued, central government authorities generally believe that devolution of power to regions will lead to secession and the breakdown of the central state, hi fact, however, such devolution can work in favor of moderate leaders and ultimately contribute to a strong federation and preempt secession. This analysis clearly holds for the case of Tatarstan, where early devolution of power strengthened a moderate leader and basically eliminated the danger of secession, m the case of Chechnya, however, the particular leader who took power. General Dudayev, refused to accept less than total independence; his personal power in Chechen domestic politics depended upon taking an extreme nationalist position. Had a more moderate political leader been in power in Chechnya, Moscow might have succeeded in its effort to sign a Tatarstan-like treaty and thus avoid the current tragedy. The Russian government should make new efforts to sign such a treaty with a representative body of Chechens as a way of ending the current violence and beginning the difficult path of bringing the Chechen Republic back into the Russian Federation. 2) Declare a policy of raising over five years the status of all subjects of the Federation to the level of current republics like Tatarstan, which allows for a local constitution and symbols, election of local leader, and reasonable local decision-making power. These are powers that are normally given to local regions in any modem federation. Some oblasts, such as Nizhny Novgorod and Ekaterinburg, have unilaterally decided to elect their leaders; most heads of administrations are still appointed from Moscow. 3) Over time it is possible to imagine that some existing subjects of the Federation will voluntarily merge and form new subjects through regional economic associations. The principle stimulus should be economic as opposed to political. Rather than endeavoring to destroy old forms, new forms should be created in parallel to the old, allowing the latter to fade away gradually. 1 Boris Yeltsin, "Federalizm I mezhnatsional'noe soglasie" in "Ob ukreplenii Rossiiskogo gosudarstva" Rossiiskaya gazeta. 25 February, 1994, p.4 2 Sergei M. Shakhrai, Official Memorandum to President Boris N. Yeltsin No. 1576 (March 1995). 3 Izvestia Tatarstana. December 23, 1994, p.l. 4 The only exception is possibly the area of military service, where Tatarstan is claiming the right for its young men to serve on the territory of Tatarstan and not to be involved in ethnic conflicts within the Federation. In principle, Tatarstan has declared itself a neutral and nuclear-free zone. As an enclave Tatarstan may be able to maintain some such rights that would be impossible for a border region to claim (federal troops must defend the border), but this is not clear. Raphael Khakimov. Prospects of Federalism in Russia: A View from Tatarstan. 1. Introduction THE PECULIARITY of Russia is that democratic laws have rarely been adopted there, and even when they have been adopted they have never been observed. Two points are important for understanding the political situation in Russia: (1) Russian society has traditionally been undemocratic, and (2) the existing constitution and laws have usually been ignored. Each new leader considered creating a brand-new constitution to be of primary importance, while that same leader rarely cared about observing that constitution. There are quite a few cases in the history of Russia which demonstrate that its leaders have often preferred the use of force to political methods for dealing with the people and with different ethnic groups. The war in Chechnya conforms with those traditions. The treaty with Tatarstan contradicts them. One should not be so naive as to think that in Russia the age of democracy has now arrived. Russia's Constitution may look pretty good as seen from Europe, but one should not forget its dubious legitimacy. Only one third of the electors voted for it; it did not get approval in 32 regions subjects of the Federation, while in Tatarstan no plebescite whatsoever was held. Moreover, the legitimacy of the Federal Sobraniye (the Parliament) is also very doubtful, for the subjects of the Federation did not take part in elaborating the Statute of the representative bodies of Russia. Moscow has exhausted its reformative potential. It has brought Russia to a dead end. The army of officials, which has grown threefold since Soviet times, does not need federalization or democratization of the country. What it needs is tax increases. The interests of Russia and the interests of Moscow are not the same. Today it is the republic and some administrative territories that are really interested in the federalization and democratization of Russia. 2. An Approach to Federalism in Russia 'Democracy' and 'federalism' arc synonyms for poly-ethnic Russia; the one is impossible without the other. National-state arrangements remain the key problem. Unless it is solved, there can be no political stability, and the continuation of the political and economic reforms is impossible. Russia seems to be the only territory where its numerous peoples are able to maintain their cultures. These peoples are indigenous, having lived there long before the Russians came. That is why it is natural that they should demand to participate in forming the state on an equal basis with the Russians. Russian federalism should be based on the interests of all nations living in Russia. Any other approach would lay the foundation of inter-ethnic tension. At the same time, however, there is a purely Russian problem involving the development of Russian territories. On the all-country scale the variety of the geographic, economic and cultural factors is too great for Russia: therefore it cannot be ruled from one single place. Federalism in Russia should be based on two principles: (1) the ethno-territorial principle, which takes into account the interests of non-Russian peoples; and (2) the territorial principle, which defines the status of predominantly Russian subjects. There are two basic approaches to the federalization of Russia: one is constitutionaltreaty, the other is treaty-constitutional. The first approach was traditional for the official structures of Russia; the second one has been asserted by Tatarstan and several other republics. 'Constitutionalists' affirm that sovereignization of the republics can lead to the breakup of the Russian Federation as was the case of the Soviet Union, therefore the central government should pursue a policy of strict control over the republics and allow them only minimal powers. Supporters of treaty-based federation do not consider Russia a real federation; they keep to the principle of establishing relations with the central government 'from below upwards', i.e. through the voluntary transfer of their authority by means of bilateral treaties. In this case, sovereignty becomes a necessary legal basis for the self-determination of the subjects of the Federation. While supporters of the first approach assert that the constitutions of the , republics should conform to the Constitution of Russia, advocates of 'concordant federation' Tatarstan among them - maintain that it is the Constitution of Russia that should be brought into conformity with the constitutions of the republics, and the central government should be under the control of the subjects of the Federation. The functions of the federal governing bodies should consist of the authority voluntary transmitted to them by the subjects of the Federation, each subject being entitled to determine the list of these powers and to withdraw them at any time. The source of power in any democratic federation is the people. Thus the foundation of the state, the functions of the central governing bodies, etc. should all be determined by the subjects of the federation. In post-imperial Russia, reformation of the state 'from above' is impossible, because the 'center' is interested in preserving the unitary state and not in decentralizing the system of government. Tatarstan has always viewed decentralization and federalization of Russia as a means of dismantling the state structures of the empire, enabling a change towards truly democratic foundations of life. 3. Tatarstan's Sovereignty Tatarstan consists of two main ethnic groups roughly equal in number: Tatars (48.5%) and Russians (43.3%).1 Tatars all over the world regard the territory of Tatarstan as their historical birthplace and the center of their cultural development.2 The Tatars enjoyed statehood in the form of the Bulgar Khanate, the Golden Horde and Kazan Khanate. They were later annexed by Russia under Ivan the Terrible, but the Tatars have always played a special role in the history of Russia. Certain traits of state structure and social life of Russia were influenced by the Golden Horde, while Russian culture experienced some influence on the part of Tatar culture. The Tatars accepted Islam in 922. Orthodox Christianity has been historically perceived by the Tatars as the religion and culture of the Russian conquerors. Christianization is associated with the most tragic pages in the annals of Kazan Khanate. Only since late 18th century, after Catherine the Great's decree on religious tolerance, were Muslims no longer persecuted in Russia. In the 19th century Islam was reformed. This new version of Islam which combined Muslim canons with the ideas of liberalism (the so-called jadidism) could be called 'Euro-Islam'. The Muslim movement in Russia has, both in the past and nowadays, been headed by die Tatars. At the moment there are no religious frictions in Tatarstan. Indeed, the republic can serve as an example of peaceful coexistence of the two world religions, and its positive experience could be of use for other countries. The Tatars have a level of culture and education high enough to claim their. own statehood. The Russians understand that, but in their turn want to play the same role in the republic as the Tatars. The essence of Tatarstan's sovereignty lies not in its striving for complete independence (although this option has been discussed in the parliament)3 but in getting guarantees for the republic's autonomy and establishing new relations with Russia, relations in the interests of the people. Tatarstan does have reason to distrust the central government even if it is headed by democratic forces. In 1920 the republic got its autonomy from Moscow, but then, in 1937 (after adopting 'Stalin's Constitution'), was completely deprived of it. There arc no guarantees that if someone like Zhirinovsky comes to power in Russia he will not try to follow Stalin's example, not least since the new Russian Constitution makes the establishment of an authoritarian regime plausible. For this very reason Tatarstan has become active on the international scene, signing bilateral treaties with foreign countries and opening permanent representations. Life in Tatarstan is largely determined by the decisions made by the local legislative and executive bodies as well as by the activities of the local parties. All-Russia parties are not very influential and do not have their structures in Tatarstan. Nevertheless, the political and economic situation in Russia has considerable influence on Tatarstan, especially its economy. That is why the republic has to coordinate its activities with the policy of Moscow. Article 61 of Tatarstan Constitution says: 'The Republic of Tatarstan is a sovereign state and a subject of international law associated with the Russian Federation on the basis of the Treaty on mutual transmission of authorities.' Tatarstan did not sign the Federative Treaty, being determined to have a bilateral treaty with Russia. Relations of association are more in the interests of Tatarstan, as they give the republic more independence than the Constitution or the Federative Treaty. Although the initiative came from Tatar community, the state sovereignty of Tatarstan was declared on behalf of all its people. The Constitution of Tatarstan declares Tatar and Russian as two offical languages. In areas where people of other nationalities live - the Chuvashes, the Udmurtis, the Marts and the Mordvas - the languages of these people are also used as official languages. (For example, in Tatarstan ballot papers are published in six languages.) The policy of the Tatarstan government is directed at keeping a balance between all ethnic groups and religious communities. Nationalistic parties are not influential in Tatarstan. The recent elections and plebescites have shown that ethnic belonging is not decisive in determining people's opinion. 4 Thus, the poly-ethnic and multi-cultural society which is taking shape in Tatarstan is based on the principle of territorial, not ethnic, sovereignty. 4. 'Tatarstan Model' In August 1991; Moscow and Kazan started negotiations which on 15 February 1994 resulted in signing the Treaty on Delimiting the Jurisdictions and Mutual Transmission of Authorities Between the Organs of State Power of The Russian Federation and The Republic of Tatarstan. Along with this Treaty the two governments adopted a package of agreements regulating relations between the two countries in the spheres of trade, property, budget, finances, banking, defence, the military-industrial complex, customs regulations, higher education, ecology, and the coordination of law-enforcement activities.5 After the Treaty had been signed on the background of the Chechen events, the international press began to speak about Tatarstan model'.6 Indeed, in the former Soviet Union this is the only positive experience of conducting negotiations between the central government and a region. Several factors determined the success of these negotiations.7 The political stability of Tatarstan helped it to stand up for its interests. Moscow, in rum, had probably hoped for inter-ethnic dissent in the republic, and demanded that a referendum be conducted on Tatarstan's status. Russia put forward this demand as a precondition for the continuation of the negotiations. The referendum, scheduled for 21 March 1992, had the following question: 'Do you agree that the Republic of Tatarstan is a sovereign state and a subject of international law which develops its relations with the Russian Federation and other republics on the basis of bilateral treaties?' Before the referendum (which was held according to procedures laid down by Russian law) Tatarstan experienced some pressure on the part of Russia's General Office of Public Prosecution, the Supreme Soviet and the President of Russia.8 Leaflets exhorting the people to say 'no' streamed into Tatarstan from Russia. Army exercises were held around me borders of the republic. Still, 61.1% of those who took part in the referendum said 'yes'. Moscow had to continue the dialogue. Negotiations were held simultaneously on three levels: (1) the top level, where the 'political' treaty was being worked out; (2) the government level, which was concerned with working out the package of agreements determining the mechanisms for realization of the 'big' treaty; and (3) the ministry level, where specific issues of finances, the budget, the army, etc. were discussed. These tactics were to determine the basic principles of the bilateral relations as well as the mechanisms of delimiting of powers. The shortcoming of the Federative Treaty was not only its controversial character but the lack of a mechanism for implementation. Despite tremendous efforts on the part of the republics to bring it into force, it remained a mere declaration.9 The Tatarstan-Russian Treaty, on the other hand, also involved a package of intergovernmental agreements on the most important aspects of Tatarstan life, which made it a practical document. One factor that assisted the success of the negotiations was the fact that year by year the position of Tatarstan was reinforced by its newly developed domestic legislation. Espedally important was the adoption of the Constitution, which Tatarstan carried out before Russia. Moscow was also put under pressure by the abstention of Tatarstan citizens from several Russian plebescites. The changes in the numbers of Tatarstan voters participating (and this is a reliable indication of the population's attitude to the policy of Russia) were as follows: (1) 36.5% of the voters took part in Russia's presidential elections of 1991. Only 16.4% voted for Boris Yeltsin; (2) 22.6% of the voters took part in the all-Russia referendum of April 1993, where 14.9% expressed their trust to President Yeltsin; (3) 13.8% of the voters took part in the elections to the Federal Sobranie and the referendum on the Constitution of Russia of 12 December 1993, with 10% of Tatarstan voters voting for the Russian Constitution. The tendency was the same in Kazan and the towns and rural districts of Tatarstan with a predominantly Russian population. The interest of Tatarstan citizens in all-Russia political events was steadily going down, threatening to isolate Tatarstan political processes from the political life of Russia. That worried the Federal government and helped to make it more compliant. Tatarstan made a certain use of the solidarity of the republics, especially its neighbors in the Volga-Ural region, who have always been influenced by Tatarstan because of its geographic closeness, ethnic similarity, economic cooperation, etc. The Volga-Ural republics and Tatarstan had signed treaties on friendship and cooperation, and the political leaders of those republics often issued joint declarations and demands. Conducting negotiations on three levels simultaneously made it possible to broaden the circle of the participants of the negotiation process. In Russia there was considerable opposition to the 'separatist deal' with Tatarstan. From 1991 Moscow newspapers published articles denouncing the very fact of conducting such negotiations. That is why it was so important to have allies on all levels: in the circle of President Yeltsin's coworkers, in the government, in the parliament. Otherwise the great effort made by both sides on the summit level could be brought to naught on the lower level: in the government and especially in the ministries. Finally, the success of the negotiations was assisted by the fact that Tatarstan delegation acted as one team, always composed of the same members. By contrast, in the course of three years, Russia changed all the members of its delegation.10 The Tatarstan-Russian Treaty is a means of settling the political conflict between Kazan and Moscow which developed on the basis of two deeply rooted ' tendendes: the demand for the decentralization of power and change to true federalization of Russia on the one hand, and striving to keep the maximum power in the hands of the central government, on the other hand. The latter tendency was the heritage of the old Soviet empire. Moscow was here guided not by strategic, but by tactical considerations, hoping after some time to force Tatarstan and other republics to obey the commands of the 'center'. Although the Constitution of Russia stipulates the right to conclude treaties (Article 11, paragraph 3), it does not set out the principles or the scope of concordant relations. By contrast, for Tatarstan the concordant character of relations with Moscow is a policy of principle reflected in many official documents. The Treaty has historical significance, as it confirms Moscow's renunciation of the use of force. In legal terms, the Treaty is to serve as a sort of buffer between the Russian and the Tatarstan Constitutions. Essentially, the Treaty means that Moscow does not demand that Tatarstan bring its Constitution into line with the Constitution of Russia. This in turn implies recognition of the pre-eminence of Tatarstan laws over the laws of the Russian Federation - between which there are considerable differences. For instance, Tatarstan has adopted legislation on private property and land ownership. Its laws give privileges to foreign investors which Russian laws do not. The Treaty recognizes Tatarstan's right to introduce its citizenship along with Russian citizenship, and also Tatarstan's right to participate (although not fully) in international and foreign economic relations. The fact that many Tatars live in Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan and Azerbaijan influences the republic's foreign policy. The religious factor is also salient in foreign policy: for instance, the stand of Tatarstan's leadership and general public on the Bosnian problem differs from the official position of Russia's Foreign Ministry. The Treaty does not stipulate the creation of joint legislative or executive bodies. Russian laws practiced on the territory of Tatarstan are limited to the powers that remain with the Federal bodies (currency, finances, Russian citizenship and some others), for which reason relations between Tatarstan and Russia are best described as association. The political status of Tatarstan still needs to be elaborated in terms of a broader interpretation of federative relations and their correspondence to international law. The closest analogy would seem to be the status of Puerto Rico, whose relations with me USA are set out in the 'Bill to approve the compact of permanent union between the United States and Puerto Rico (1975)'. Tatarstan, however, has certain pecularities that make it different from Puerto Rico. These pecularities are the result of Russia's postempire traditions and Tatarstan's enclave situation. After the Tatarstan-Russian Treaty had been signed, there were attempts to stop the concordant process between the two governments. Certain politicians began to speak of establishing the Russian Federation solely on the territorial principle, as opposed to the national (ethnic)-territorial principle.11 In spring and summer of 1995, two drafts of the bill 'On the principles of distribution of the 'jurisdiction and authorities between the organs of state power of Russian Federation and the subjects of the Federation' were brought before the Duma. The bill was aimed at interrupting the concordant process between Tatarstan and Russia. The tougher draft (originating in the Duma itself) directly banned any treaties between the Federal government and the subjects of the Federation. Both drafts met with resistance from the republics and some oblast. In September, Boris Yeltsin declared that treaties would be signed not only with the republics but with oblast as well. Such treaties have been demanded by Kaliningradskaya oblast, Yekaterinburg and some other oblast. Thus the process of concluding treaties, initially considered an exception for Tatarstan and Chechnya (the republics that did not sign the Federative Treaty), is now viewed as normal and necessary for all subjects of the Federation. By the summer of 1995, supporters of the treaty-constitutional foundation of the Russian Federation had reinforced their positions and induced the head of Russia to speak in favour of the concordant process. 5. The Asymmetry of Federative Relations The Russian mentality, always inclined to egalitarianism, does not easily accept the existence of some special relations between Kazan and Moscow, or differences in the status of subjects of the Federation. The oblast are irritated by the 'privileges' that Tatarstan enjoys, particularly by the lower share it has to contribute to the Federal budget. At the same time, however, they fail to consider the greater responsibility that these 'privileged' republics take upon themselves. The issue of symmetrical vs. asymmetrical federation is in (he focus of political debates. The asymmetry of relations between the Federal government and the subjects of the Federation is a fact that cannot be ignored or eliminated. Differences in the status of the republics, oblast, krai and autonomous okrug are obvious. The extent of the powers devolved to Tatarstan and other republics are also different. There are certain differences in the status of the subjects of the Federation that are patently unfair. Although Russian Constitution considers all subjects of the Federation equal, the krai and the oblast still do not have their Charters (Fundamental Laws) and their heads are appointed, not elected. Thus, they can scarcely be considered as subjects of full value. In the next few years the powers of the republics and administrative territories are going to become more equal. The heads of several oblast and krai are now speaking of making their powers equal to those of the authorities of Tatarstan. These tendencies are becoming widespread. The case of Edward Rossel, head of the selfproclaimed Ural Republic, is significant here. Although dismissed by President Yeltsin, he was elected Governor by the population of Yekaterinburg. At his first press conference, Rossel said he wanted a treaty with Moscow similar to the treaty Tatarstan had. This indicates another tendency: when elections take place among other subjects of Russia, it will be very difficult for Moscow to control them. At the same time, a certain asymmetry will survive. There are major disparities in the levels of. economic development of the various regions. Border regions have their own peculiarities. Subjects of the Federation have their historical and regional traditions. Some cannot and will not accept greater responsibility for their regions. Finally, certain republics have claims rooted in their ethnic interests. Tatarstan has come out in favor of a flexible policy of the Federal government, one not based on abstract egalitarian principles but oriented towards the ethnic and historical peculiarities of the regions. In early 1995, the Presidents of Tatarstan, Bashkiria and Yakutia sent President Boris Yeltsin a message entitled 'For Consistent Democratization and Federalization of Russia' in which they state: The policy of the central government with respect to its subjects should be flexible, taking into consideration the political realities. There are and there will be differences between the subjects of the Federation. This only reflects the natural variety of life. Unity and stability of the state are achieved not by making everyone fit some artificial standard, but by taking into account the peculiarities and requirements of each subject. 12 It is not the symmetry of relations that makes a federation firm but the possibility for the subjects to find support for their interests in the face of the federal government - of course, without prejudice to the interests of other subjects. 6. The Hague Initiative The Tatarstan model' kindled interest on the part of those former Soviet republics that had conflicts between the central power and the local governments. With some of these republics Tatarstan had bilateral treaties and partnership relations. In January 1995, within the framework of the international project 'Management of Ethnic Conflicts in the Post-Soviet States' supported by the Administration of the President of Tatarstan, the political leaders of Georgia, Abkhazia, the Ukraine, the Crimea, Moldova, the Transdnestr Republic, Russia and Tatarstan had a round-table discussion in the Peace Palace in The Hague, with the participation of international experts. The main discussion topic was the conflicts in the former Soviet regions and the possible use of the Tatarstan experience in settling them.13 The informal exchange of views showed that Tatarstan had managed to find the solution for numerous complicated problems and, although the 'Tatarstan model' could not be applied in situations where armed clashes had taken place, the republic's experience was nevertheless useful in other aspects.Tatarstan is interested in continuing The Hague initiative and in broadening die circle of its participants. The next meeting is scheduled for early 1996. 7. Association as a Form of Self-determination History can show no examples of direct transition of empires to federations. Nevertheless, Tatarstan is trying to induce Russia to develop federalization. The prerequisite for creating a true federation is the independence of its subjects: otherwise it is impossible to provide them equal rights and reform the central power. But striving for independence is fraught with conflicts. The 'Czechoslovak divorce' is an exeption in this regard. Relations of association can become the key factor that will allow the transition from empire to federation without infringing upon the territorial integrity of the states, because in this case the question of borders is not raised. Relations of association are flexible: they do not require the creation of joint organs of government, nor do they place any limitations on transferring powers to the central organs. This could be a possible form of relations between Georgia and Abkhazia, the Ukraine and the Crimea, Moldova and the Transdnestr Republic. The international community must, of course, be involved as the guarantor of security in establishing such new relations. 8. Global Federalism The international community cherishes the illusion that the world is made up of states. In fact, it is made up of peoples. The leaders of the great powers believe that they determine the world order and the development of political processes, but their conceit comes into collision with the determination of peoples to gain their freedom and independence. Not infrequently, tension in international relations is caused by the confrontation between people striving for self-determination and the state insisting on its territorial integrity. International law does not provide any ready-made solutions to this problem. Pleading the principle of non-interference in internal affairs, the international community prefers to leave the solution of such problems to the discretion of the states involved. But as the conflict worsens, it becomes difficult for the international community to remain aloof, and finally it decides it has to interfere. But by this point the conflict has already reached the stage when it is difficult to change anything. Bosnia and Chechnya are convincing examples; the latter conflict had been brewing for three years before the eyes of the whole world and the outcome had been predicted by many experts long before it started. International relations are regulated by organizations like the UN. But, as life shows, the development of political events is influenced not only by states, but by peoples who do not have their own statehood and who are striving to gain it. The exclusion of these peoples from world politics is one of the main reasons for the international instability today. Global federalism can become an effective instrument of preventing inter-ethnic and political conflicts. Its essence lies in recognizing peoples, represented as such in democratic institutions, as subjects of international relations on a par with states. The most radical step towards a renewal of international relations would be to establish a second chamber of the United Nations, one which would represent peoples and not states. This would change the structure of many international organizations, including the International Court of Justice. An approach like this changes priorities. It views the world as a community of peoples and not of states. It puts forward values above and beyond the interests of the national states, values of a global character. For many peoples, the struggle for a state of their own is only a manifestation of struggle for worthy living. The very fact of including them in international life will be enough for many of them to dismiss the idea of creating their own independent state. Global federalism makes the idea of statehood less attractive, and divests the border issue of its conflict character. This is a real way of strengthening security on our planet. Notes and references 1 Due to recent migration into Tatarstan, the Tatar population now numbers more than 50% of the total. 2 The total number of Volga Tatars in the world is now about 7 million. 3 See the Decree of the Supreme Soviet of Tatar Soviet Republic 'On the act of the state independence of the Republic of Tatarstan' in: The White Paper on Tatarslan. The way to sovereignty (collection of official documents) 1990-1995. Kazan, 1995, p. 12. (in Russian) 4 For example, at the elections to the Stale Soviet of Tatarstan in March 1995 in the predominantly Russian-speaking district of Spasskii, a Tatar candidate was elected, while in the Tatar-speaking Agryz district the majority voted for a Russian. 5 See the text of the Treaty and the 12 agreements in: The White Paper on Tatarstan... and in journal of South Asian and Middle Eastern Studies, vol. 18, no. 1, Fall 1994. 6 Bruce Allyn, 'One Enclave's Solution to Ties with Mother Russia', Christian Science Monitor, 12 October 1994; Trudy Rubin, 'Yeltsin Must Ease Ethnic Leaders to Negotiate Peace in Chechnya', The Philadelphia Inquirer, 13 January 1995; John Lloyd, 'A Delicate Balance', Financial Times, Weekend 25/26 February 1995. 7 Here let me add that I myself took part in the negotiations as a member of Tatarstan delegation. 8 See President's Shaimiev's lecture at Harvard University. The text was published in Izvesia Tatarstana, 14 October 1994 (in Russian). 9 Until October 1993 there was a group of experts of the Council of the Heads of the Republics (of which I was a member) that paid special attention to working out the mechanism of the realization of the Federative Treaty. 10 Negotiations started on 12 August 1991 under the supervision of Gennady Burbulis; he was later replaced by Valery Tishkov, Sergei Shakhrai and, finally, Yury Yarov. 11 In early 1995, Sergei Shakhrai, Russian Vice Prime-Minister, in a memorandum to President Yeltsin wrote that 'the practice of conducting internal treaties will complicate the administrative-territorial reform which is so important for Russia and which it would be important to carry out before the 1996 elections'. See Molodezh Tatarstana, 12-18 May 1995 (in Russian). 12 For the text of the message see Panorama-Forum, Kazan, 1995, no. 1, p. 7 (in Russian). 13 See details in Raphael Khakimov, 'Russia and Tatarstan: at the Crossroad of History. The Hague initiative' in Molodezh Tatarstana, 1995, no. 12 (in Russian); Bruce Allyn, The Hague Initiative', Ethnic Conflict Management in the Former Soviet Union: Bulletin (Cambridge, MA: Conflict Management Group, June 1995). The Conference "Future of Russian Federalism: Political and Ethnic Factors" February 25-26, 2000 Phillip A. Petersen, Director of the Russian Programs, the Potomac Foundation (USA). Russia's Place in the 21st Century? Russia's government, and even most of its own critics in the Russian Federation, chafe when its policies or actions are criticized by foreigners: ⌠Who are you to criticize us?■ So I will attempt to avoid ⌠criticizing■ Russia. Instead, I shall discuss the kind of world that is rapidly emerging and about how, even among those who do have a pretty good sense for what's happening, there remains a fundamental necessity to avoid breezily employing terms such as flexibility, liberalization, or even privatization. Yet, make no mistake about it, behind the differences of presentation≈the taboo words and the patriotic talk of defending traditional values≈in economics and economic policy, a truly global common market is emerging. Competition, innovation, and enterprise are now being understood to be directly connected to lower unemployment and a higher standard of living. Lower taxes, less public spending, and a lighter hand of regulation is the future. I'll leave it for the reader to integrate the facts into his or her own frame of reference, but only argue that competition makes for better business and even more effective government. The Third Wave Builds When Alvin Toffler offered his conceptual architecture for understanding the economic basis for the advance of civilization in The Third Wave, he offered his readers the opportunity to know ⌠the destinations toward which change is carrying us.■1 Certainly, nobody needs to remind citizens of the Russian Federation about the violence of the clash between the Agricultural Revolution of the First Wave and the Industrial Revolution of the Second Wave. The Bolsheviks remain the epitome of a political party of the Second Wave. Yet, when Nikita Khrushev was threatening to ⌠bury■ the United States in terms of industrial production, the country was already entering the Third Wave n with more workers engaged in what was then referred to as ⌠white collar work■ than in industrial production. Never a true ⌠nation-state,■ the United States has become the womb of ⌠globalization■ and, thereby, the leading edge of an Information Revolution. Moving humanity beyond mass production, as noted by Toffler, the Third Wave ⌠provides the world's poorest nations, as well as the richest, with wholly new opportunities.■2 In his book The Digital Economy, Don Tapscott pointed out that the Information Revolution of the Third Wave has created ⌠a knowledge economy based on the application of human know-how to everything we produce and how we produce it. In the new economy, more and more of the economy's added value will be created by brain rather than brawn.■3 The essence of industrial production today is ⌠masscustomized rather than mass-produced.■4 Tapscott argues that ⌠our traditional mind-set≈even if we use sophisticated mathematical techniques and impenetrable sociological jargon≈has always somehow perceived business as buying cheap and selling dear. The new approach defines a business as the organization that adds value and creates wealth.■ 5 As a result, he observes, ⌠success in the new economy will require inventing new business processes, new business, new industries, and new customers≈not rearranging old ones.■6 Tapscott concludes that ⌠what counts is a company's ability to attract, retain, and continually grow the capabilities of knowledge workers and provide the environment for innovation and creativity.■7 As technology was added to the Information Revolution, it increased dramatically the tempo of change and, as this Information Technology Revolution expands its hold over economic relations, will redefine the nature of these relations in ways that will fundamentally reconstruct commerce itself. As observed by Don Tapscott a number of years ago, the process of ⌠virtualization■ will mean that people will be working and participating in one country's economy while physically located somewhere else. Already between 1993 and 1999, the number of Americans connected to the Internet rose from 3 million to 80 million.8 Yet, between 1995 and 1999, the percentage of internet users, which grew from 26 million to 179 million, grew even more dramatically outside Canada and the United States, from 16% to 43% of the total internet users.9 While fewer that 1% of the population of China has access to the Internet, for example, that still amounts to nearly 10 million users in China alone. 10 In 1998, the Internet generated about $301 billion in U.S. revenue, closing in on the automobile industry. Business-to-business commerce alone is expected to increase from $48 billion in 1998 to $1.3 trillion in 2003.11 According to The Economist, ⌠between 1995 and 1998 the IT sector, despite accounting for only about 8% of America's GDP, contributed, on average, 35% of the country's economic growth.■ 12 Furthermore, ⌠U.S. high-tech companies poured a record $95 billion into international markets in 1998, spreading the country's spectacular Internet wealth around the globe and further stitching together the economies of the world.■13 Contrary to most perceptions, globalization is as enabling for small-businesses as much as it is cost-cutting for large-business, largely because ⌠innovation drives every aspect of economic and social life.■14 As Tapscott observes, ⌠in the innovation economy, human imagination is the main source of value.■ He, therefore, argues that ⌠the critical challenge for any company in the digital economy is to create a climate in which innovation is prized, rewarded, and encouraged. Every country needs innovative workplaces and organizations that foster creativity. Growth in the innovation economy comes from small- and medium-sized businesses rather than large corporations or governments.■15 In the United States, for example, ⌠the federal government estimates half the nation's output comes from businesses with fewer than 100 employees.■16 As a result of the need for innovation, ⌠there is a concurrent trend towards self-employment and the creation of small knowledge-based industries providing work on a contract basis. In the digital economy, as intellectual capital becomes the most valuable resource, the means of production shifts from the plant floor into the innovative minds of knowledge workers≈those who create value.■ 17 Fearful of missing the opportunity to profit from this dynamic, venture capitalists are pouring millions of dollars into the creation of small-business portals to bring ecommerce to the fragmented small-business community.18 While globalization and mergers draw much attention, the processes they represent are not world-dominating predatory acts, but competition as much a threat to lumbering giants and ⌠boon for the nippy little firms that create most of today's new employment and wealth.■19 Deregulation has resulted in the growing importance of foreign firms in national economies: they pay their workers more; create jobs faster; spend heavily on research and development; and export more than domestic firms.20 What we are observing is the appearance of two economies in the industrialized world, those of the old industrial dinosaurs and another ⌠dominated by aggressive new entities in the software or Internet sectors, but including older concerns nimbly adapting to the information age.■21 Bidding for the Future The emerging global economic system is one is which whatever makes commercial sense is no longer deterred by legal, cultural, or political uncertainty. As observed by The Economist, ⌠behind this trend is a new generation of managers who understand that firms belong to shareholders, not bosses or ⌠society■. 22 So-called ⌠hostile■ takeovers ⌠have recently succeeded in Italian telecomms and insurance, French banking and energy. Venture capital, leveraged buy-outs and cross-border mergers are booming. Old companies are shrinking and new ones springing up. Europe, which has for years been exporting more capital than it imports, may finally start to attract the investment from foreign financiers that it needs. And as a genuine market for corporate control is forged, managers might at last be held to account for their companies ⌠performance.■23 Underpinning the new corporate attitudes, is a fundamental shift in relations between companies and their banks. ⌠Banks are pulling out of corporate lending, which offers paltry returns. They are also treating industrial stakes more like other investments.■ At the same time that the banks are pulling out of corporate lending and becoming more active as shareholders, ordinary middle-class folks are themselves piling into shares. The arrival of shareholder capitalism has set the stage for increasing corporate accountability and, as a result, a rapid increase in the pace of globalization. All this, in turn, will drive the world toward a single standard of transparent efficiency. If a company wants to lower its cost of capital, it needs to list its shares on America's stockmarkets.24 ⌠The U.S. capital markets probably now comprise some 60-70% of the world's available private capital resources. Should a company... lose access to the U.S. bond market on a sustained basis, it would not only pay more for the funds it raises elsewhere (e.g., in Europe or Asia) but would likely find itself unable to attract the volume of funds required to meets its development needs.■25 It is for this reason, for example, ⌠nine of Germany's biggest companies have already [listed on American markets].■26 The movement toward a truly global (that is, it has been noted, American-dominated) common market will not only provide for greater innovation and competition, but do it transparently. ⌠In some countries, structural rigidities are delaying progress. The failure to reform pensions affects national budgets, and also stunts the development of institutional shareholders. Radical restructuring and deregulation are threatened by union power and rigid labour markets.■ Yet, while there will be hesitations and setbacks along the way to the globalization of economics, the direction is clear: ⌠a capitalism more transparent, more efficient and, yes, redder in tooth and claw.■ 27 As observed by British Prime Minister Tony Blair, ⌠there is now a new direction for Europe, away from the social regulation agenda of the e80s and instead in the direction of enterprise, innovation, competition and employment.■ 28 The New Left Ever since the new left swept to power, in the United States (1992), Britain (1997), France (1997), Germany (1998) and Italy (1998), all the governing center-left parties follow conservative macro-economic policies. And in the United States and Britain, Mr. Clinton and Mr. Blair have turned out to sound as market-minded on structural reform as their conservative predecessors. Even their continental European counterparts, leading ⌠a majority of centre-left governments, [are] not clinging unthinkingly to old ways.■ The rhetoric may sound similar to the past, but ⌠the political boilerplate is deceptive. In fact, something more subtle is taking place: the gentle, growing, if sometimes reluctant recognition by Europe's left that reform of the social model they did so much to develop is necessary.■29 While delivering upon the details will involve contentious debate, the general outline of government's role in the reconfiguration of public participation in and administration of the new economy has been understood for some years: - Create the regulatory conditions for an open competitive marketplace for the evolution of the information infrastructure. - Use the new technologies to reinvent itself to cut costs and improve the delivery of government programs. In doing so governments would not only deliver better and cheaper service but as a significant purchaser place considerable demand on the market. - Take steps to ensure that technology serves people by implementing policies and programs to ensure universal access, equity, privacy, and security. - Act as a catalyst for new kinds of partnerships that would encourage demands for networks, the growth of applications, and the use of the new technologies.30 ⌠In the new economy, those workers with access to the new infrastructure can participate fully in social and commercial life. Those without access, knowledge, and motivation will tend to fall behind.■31 As demonstrated by Ford Motor Company and Delta Air Lines, the companies that want to be successful in the 21st century will provide such access to their workers to accelerate development of the skills in order to fully utilize the Internet and related technologies.32 Individual knowledge workers will be the new owners of the means of production, but require ⌠motivation and trusting team relationships to be effective.■33 This new reality requires ⌠a reexamination of the basic power relationships of the workplace, marketplace, household, and society. Knowledge work, the new consumer sovereignty, localized infrastructure for the Net, all of these demand a reconfiguration of public participation and administration.■34 While Russia's ⌠economy has now slid to something like one percent of world output,■ it does not have to re-tool its industry by Second Wave rules. In a global economy based increasingly on knowledge and technology, the door is wide-open to all who submit to the normal rules of the digital economy. Russia is faced with a clear choice. She cannot integrate into the global economy and subsidize her antiquated industry of the tools of suppression. Those who know him say that Vladimir Putin most certainly does understand that creating the strong Russia he wants requires prosperity, and that this will require subordinating politics to economic considerations. It was argued in late February 2000 by Marat Galeev of the Presidium of the Republic of Tatarstan that ⌠Putin is not a black box, but a blank sheet of paper.■ Rafael Khakimov, State Advisor to the President of Tatarstan, agreed in arguing that Putin ⌠has no clear impulse towards a return to a unitary state structure.■ The great Russian scientist Evgeny Velikhov, as well, urged that Putin be judged only by his actions after the March 2000 Russian presidential elections. To quote a more simple soul from Kazan: ⌠We shall live, and we shall see.■ 1 Alvin Toffler, The Third Wave, New York: Bantam Books, April 1981, p. 4 2 Toffler, The Third Wave, p. 337. 3 Tapscott, p. 7. 4 Tapscott, p. 8. 5 Don Tapscott, The Digital Economy: Promise and Peril in the Age of Networked Intelligence, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1995, p. 85. 6 Don Tapscott, The Digital Economy: Promise and Peril in the Age of Networked Intelligence, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1995, p. 4. 7 Tapscott, p. 47. 8 Mark Leibovich, Tim Smart, and Lanthe Jeanne Dugan, ⌠Internet's E-conomy Gets Real: New Business Math Gains Solid Ground,■ Washington Post, June 20, 1999, p. A17. 9 New World Coming: American Security in the 21st Century, Washington: The United States Commission on National Security/21st Century, September 15, 1999, p. 6. 10 See Clay Chandler, ⌠Dot-Comrades Start Small,■ Washington Post, March 26, 2000, p. H1. 11 Mark Leibovich, Tim Smart, and Lanthe Jeanne Dugan, ⌠Internet's E-conomy Gets Real: New Business Math Gains Solid Ground,■ Washington Post, June 20, 1999, p. A1. 12 ⌠The New Economy: Work in Progress,■ The Economist, July 25, 1999, p. 21. 13 Ariana Eunjung Xha, ⌠U.S. Firms Spin a Web Worldwide: High-Tech Dollars Flow To International Markets,■ Washington Post, March 13, 2000, p. A2. 14 Tapscott, p. 61. 15 Tapscott, p. 62. 16 Leslie Walker, ⌠Web's Next Big Thing Is Small,■ Washington Post, February 17, 2000, p. E4. 17 Tapscott, pp. 66-67. 18 Walker, p. E4. 19 ⌠The world's view of multinationals,■ The Economist, January 29, 2000, p. 22. 20 ⌠Globalization: Foreign friends,■ The Economist, January 8, 2000, pp. 71-72. 21 Clay Chandler and Akiko Kashiwagi, ⌠Japan Inc.: Diverging Onto Dual Tracks?■, Washington Post, February 16, 2000, p. E1. 22 ⌠EUROPE'S NEW CAPITALISM: Bidding for the future,■ The Economist, February 12, 2000, p. 72. 23 Ibid., p. 71. 24 Ibid., p. 72. 25 Remarks of Hon. Roger W. Robinson, Jr., President and CEO of RWR Inc. and former Senior Director of International Economic Affairs at the National Security Council before the Non-Proliferation Policy Education Center, May 19, 1999. 26 ⌠EUROPE'S NEW CAPITALISM: Bidding for the future,■ The Economist, February 12, 2000, p. 72. 27 Ibid., p. 74. 28 As quoted in William Drozdiak, ⌠EU to Push Growth in Innovation, Technology,■ Washington Post, March 25, 2000, p. E2. 29 ⌠EUROPE'S NEW CAPITALISM: Bidding for the future,■ The Economist, February 12, 2000, p. 19. 30 Tapscott, p. 316. 31 Tapscott, p. 67. 32See, for example, Warren Brown and Frank Swoboda, ⌠Ford Offers Home PC TO Every Employee,■ Washington Post, February 4, 2000, p. A1 and p. A12; and Frank Swoboda, ⌠Delta Joins Ford, Offers Home PCs To Workers,■ Washington Post, February 5, 2000, p. E1 and p. E2. 33 Tapscott, p. 67. 34 Miller, as quoted in Tapscott, p. 318. The Conference "Future of Russian Federalism: Political and Ethnic Factors" February 25-26, 2000 Donna Bahry, Doctor of Philosophy, Professor of Political Science at Vanderbilt University. Rethinking Asymmetrical Federalism. Introduction The design of the federal system has prompted a long and contentious debate in Russia since 1991. Efforts to balance central state interests with ethnic, regional and local diversity have generated a succession of different approaches, from the federal treaty in 1992, to the Constitution of 1993, to region-by-region treaties and agreements from 1994 on. The net result since the mid-1990s has been an asymmetrical federal system with substantial differences in powers across different regions. New initiatives by President Putin in the spring of 2000 represent an effort to remake the system once again. Much of the debate focuses on the issue of asymmetry.1 To its adherents, this plural brand of federalism allows needed flexibility for a country that includes eleven time zones and one of the most ethnically diverse populations in the world. Tailoring particular terms to individual regions provides the opportunity for local resolution of local problems. It also offers the prospect of broadening democracy, by increasing representation and opportunities for participation beyond the level of the central state. Critics, on the other hand, point to several drawbacks. One is an issue of principle: asymmetry, so the argument goes, challenges the underlying assumption of equal rights under democratic government. And differential powers based on ethnoterritorial criteria imply the preeminence of group rights, while democracy should give primacy to the individual. Other critiques rest on more pragmatic arguments. Differential powers across regions can add to the difficulties of coordination across institutions and policies; and inhibit the ability of the central state to reallocate resources across jurisdictions. The ultimate criticism, of course, is that centrifugal forces can unravel the state itself. While all of these arguments have some merit, they miss a crucial point. Asymmetry is a common and growing feature of democratic federations, especially those with compactly settled ethnic minorities. Individual territories and groups enjoy special status and rights ranging from the cultural and linguistic to the political and economic realms. Moreover, even unitary systems have increasingly devolved authority to the regional level and granted asymmetrical rights to different regions in recent years. Globalization and broad societal changes have made highly centralized states less and less able to cope with demands for economic, social, and cultural development. The response has been to reconfigure the allocation of state power between central and subnational governments. Thus the idea of negotiated, asymmetrical federalism is hardly unique to Russia. My aim here is to provide a comparative perspective on it, by exploring the sources of devolution over the past 25 years, and the various forms of asymmetry in selected countries. Patterns of Federalism Federal systems, as Watts (1994; 1996) argues, have emerged in three broad waves since the mid-nineteenth century.2 The first wave developed with the formation of nationstates in Western Europe and the British Commonwealth, as cities, states and regions coalesced into larger units. This integrative form of federalism was exemplified in Germany (1870), Switzerland (1848), Canada (1867), Australia (1901), the U.S. (1787), Austria (1918) and Brazil (1891). The defining characteristic, according to Stepan, was the primarily voluntary decision by smaller units to pool their sovereignty. The second wave accompanied decolonization in the post World War II period. In this case, newly emerging states confronted a mismatch between administrative boundaries established by colonial powers on one hand, and pre-existing ethnic, linguistic or religious communities on the other. Federalism thus provided a compromise, allowing the creation of new nation-states while recognizing internal diversity. Examples of this attempt to knit together distinct populations ranged from India (1950), Pakistan (1956), Indonesia (194549), Malaya (1948) and Malaysia (1963), to Nigeria (1954), French West Africa and the Mali Federation (1959) (see Watts, 1996). In many cases, however, these efforts to forge new states were unsuccessful as various groups and territories pushed for independence and some federations simply dissolved. The third wave has had a broader geographical focus, and a different trajectory. Beginning in the mid-1970s, it has primarily brought devolution in existing nation states. Central governments have increasingly handed responsibilities downward to the regional and local level, and recognized special political and economic status for specific regions and groups. Examples include devolution and recognition of special status for Quebec and the Northern Territories in Canada; federalization of previously unitary states in Belgium and Spain; and decentralization of economic and social policies in a host of other cases. This emphasis on devolution and asymmetry can be traced to several broad trends in the global economy, in politics, and in society over the past 25 years. Shifts in technology and communications have transformed international trade and capital, and with them, the economic role of central governments. National borders and economic barriers have diminished in importance, allowing greater mobility of goods and capital. Protectionism has grown both more difficult to sustain and more unpopular as an economic strategy. These developments, plus the rise of the post-industrial information economy, have prompted widespread reassessments of the efficiency of large, hierarchical firms. The development of "turbo-capitalism," to use Edward Luttwak's (1999) phrase, has generated ever greater demand for smaller, more flexible forms of corporate organization that can react quickly to rapidly changing, global markets. The same trends have also bred a reassessment of centralized, hierarchical government. Declining barriers to trade and increased capital mobility suggest growing constraints on governments' ability to regulate and tax business. The capacity to redistribute revenues is thus increasingly limited. The constraints pose a particular dilemma for the state's role as guarantor of social welfare. The graying of the population in many countries suggests heightened commitments but limited ability to continue to pay for social welfare programs such as social security, health care, and public services. The common response has been to trim welfare at the national level by handing various programs down to regions and localities. 3 Central governments can thus reduce their obligations while avoiding the political costs of cutting or eliminating benefits. The second broad trend behind devolution is political. The spread of democratization since the early 1970s has prompted increased concern with representation and participation, and these, in turn, heighten the role of regional and local governments (Faletti, 1999). The expansion of democracy below the national level has also come to be seen as a potential counterweight to the reemergence of authoritarianism. A third source of devolution stems from broader societal changes during the same period. There can be no doubt that ethnic and/or communal identity has become more important - making questions of cultural preservation, language use, and territorial autonomy all much more salient. This is complemented by a parallel trend toward "individualization": the appeal of centralized collective organizations such as political parties and trade unions has diminished over time, while the role of the individual has increased. As a result, people are less likely to see themselves as part of a large centralized organization, and more likely to identify with local communities (Keating 1999). Altogether, these trends have led to a paradox, heightening the role of transnational ties but also enhancing the role of subnational governments. The diminishing importance of national borders has facilitated increased efforts at integration across countries, as evidenced in the European Union, and to lesser degrees in NAFTA, Mercosur and other regional organizations. The same forces have also led to what Michael Keating (1999) calls a "re-territorialization" of politics, moving the locus of responsibility for public policies from the central to the regional and local level. Patterns of devolution Responses in individual countries have varied from radical and broad devolution to more measured decentralization, primarily in the economic sphere. Space does not permit a complete survey of all of them here. Instead, the following discussion focuses on cases where the change has been most substantial, where unitary governments have evolved into federal or quasi-federal ones.4 Spain's transformation since the mid-1970s offers one of the most radical examples. Negotiations over the transition to democracy in the mid-1970s led to recognition of regional autonomy in general, and of special status for historical communities in Catalonia and the Basque country. The result, since 1978, has been substantial devolution of powers from the center to the regions, especially to the two historical communities.5 Spain's seventeen autonomous regions (which include a total of 50 provinces) now have six co-official languages and far more responsibility for domestic policy. Degrees of devolution and asymmetry vary by policy area, however. With respect to economic development, what had been a centralized industrial policy up through the early 1980s has been transformed into a regional concern. Special economic zones were created to scale down subsidized enterprises in heavy industry and to give regions authority over investment policy and tax credits (in conjunction with entry into the European Community). The goal was to help promote research and development, technical training, and the development of small business (Agranoff, 1994). In health care, six regions conduct their own policy, while the other 11 have regional managers to coordinate and implement federal health policies. In welfare, the federal government stipulates minimum services and provides bloc grants to finance them; but each region has its own policies and programs. And on budgetary matters, two regions (the Basque country and Navarre) have a single-channel tax system, while the 15 other regions rely on shared taxes (Agranoff and Gallarin, 1997). The Spanish system also proves to be asymmetric in the fields of public order and international economic ties: the Basque region alone among the 17 autonomous communities has its own police force (subject to oversight from Madrid). And the Basque country has its own representative in Brussells (Agranoff, 1994). In Belgium, national government policies have long recognized the distinct languages and cultures of the Flemish and Walloon communities, under a unitary state. The 1990s brought a constitutional change from a unitary to a federal system, with separate parliaments for Flanders, Wallonia and Brussells, and also for the three main language communities (Dutch, French and German). The three regions now hold primary responsibility for much of domestic policy, from economic development, public works and transportation to foreign trade. Federal government functions include defense, foreign affairs, social security, management of the public debt, and the criminal court system (Judt, 1999). Devolution in the United Kingdom has been even more recent. Here, too, some official recognition had long been given to the distinct communities in Scotland and Wales, while the state remained unitary. But growing local support for home rule beginning in the 1970s, and changing party fortunes at the national level in the 1990's (from Conservative to Labour dominance) led to referenda on new legislative assemblies in both regions in 1997. The two parliaments will differ, however: in Scotland, where local autonomy on some issues had traditionally been broader, (and the movement for home rule was stronger), the new assembly has primary powers of legislation in several areas -- economic development, health care, education and manpower training, housing, social work, regulation of local government, environmental matters, and the justice system (plus all residual powers not specifically reserved to the national government) [Keating, 1998]. The Welsh assembly is to have more limited powers of secondary legislation, i.e., the ability to adjust legislation from Westminster (Keating, 1998). Both Scotland and Wales have gained the right to participate in the British negotiations and delegations to the European Community; and Scotland is now recognized as having the right to a representative in Brussells. Many more cases of devolution and asymmetry are focused primarily on the economic sphere. In China, reforms since 1978 have created a variety of special regimes in different regions. The first initiative in 1980 designated four southern regions as Special Economic Zones (SEZ), offering preferential tax policies to lure foreign investment. That was followed by the creation of 14 "Coastal Open Cities" (COC) in 1984; 32 "'Economic Technology Development Zones;" 13 "Tax-Bonded Areas;" 52 "High-Technology Industrial Development Zones," and other special regimes for regions and localities. (Cho and Tung, 1998; Dutta).6 Efforts to create 57 SEZ's have been launched in the four countries of Latin America's Mercosur (Argentina, Brazil, Uruguay and Paraguay) [Kotabe, 1998]. The SEZ's, with differential economic rights, are intended to help stem capital flight and increase exports. These economic measures have accompanied a more general trend across Latin America to devolve powers to the regional and local level since the 1980s (Faletti, 1999). Thus the shift from central to regional and local authority has extended across continents, and across both new and old democracies. However, while similar trends seem to be at work in virtually all the cases, both the process of devolution and its results have varied from country to country. After all, decisions about when and what to decentralize are inherently political. In many cases, they have depended on the fortunes of political parties at the national and regional level. Madrid, for example, has varied over the years in its willingness to cede power to the Spanish autonomies, depending on the strength of the ruling party/coalition at any given time and the need to form alliances with regional parties (Agranoff and Gallarin, 1997). And the push for home rule in Scotland and Wales developed momentum once the Labour and Liberal parties signed on, and the Conservatives' electoral support eroded (Keating, 1998). The Dilemmas of Asymmetry As devolution and asymmetry spread globally, they raise a host of questions about the implications for democracy, equality, and national integration. With respect to the fit between democracy and asymmetry, the standard argument, as noted earlier, is that rights should be guaranteed to individuals rather than groups. But this is a narrow view: democracy is also about protecting rights of minorities, and guaranteeing representation and participation. As Stepan (1999b) notes, asymmetric federalism is an effort to recognize these multiple dimensions of democratic rights. Whether devolution and asymmetry do in fact broaden democracy, however, obviously depends on how political institutions operate in specific cases. Stepan (1999b) argues, for example, that democracy is enhanced where the transfer of authority between center and regions is subject to open, transparent approval procedures at the national level -- that is, where devolution is legitimized either through the constitution or by approval in the national parliament. Democracy is also enhanced when there are common rules of the game to promote political competition and accountability within regions.7 Thus, in the Spanish case, the autonomies hold uniform regional elections, using proportional representation and a common formula for allocating seats; their legislators face term limits; their cabinets are limited to ten members; and their legislators may vote a prime minister and cabinet out of office via a constructive vote of no-confidence (Agranoff and Gallarin, 1997).8 In Germany, each land has its own constitution -- and laender all have the right to decide on a unicameral or bicameral legislature (only one state, Bavaria - has opted for bicameralism). Laender also decide themselves whether the executive is directly or indirectly elected (Boase, 1994). Finally, democracy is enhanced where there are commonly accepted mechanisms for resolving the inevitable conflicts that arise over central, regional and local jurisdiction. In fact, it might be argued that democracy is valuable precisely because it provides a framework for managing such disputes. Agranoff and Gallarin (1997) note, for example, that both the Spanish central government and the autonomies have turned to the constitutional court repeatedly since the 1980s to resolve federal conflicts. In 1981, the central government challenged 41 percent of the laws and decrees issued by the 17 autonomies; but that number dropped over the years, to seven percent in 1990. Over the same period, the autonomies (especially the two historical regions of the Basque country and Catalonia) also raised hundreds of challenges to the national government through the court system. But the number of challenges from the regions has also diminished over time. The constitutional court, for its part, has ruled for both sides, upholding the principles of devolution and asymmetry, but also recognizing the central government's prerogatives in some areas. In addition to the legal system, some federations also possess other mechanisms for resolving center-regional conflicts. In Germany, for example, the upper house of parliament (Bundesrat) holds absolute veto power over questions affecting the laender. The question of inequality across regions is similarly complex. By definition, the provision of asymmetrical powers to regions and localities means that regional policies should differ, reflecting varied preferences for public goods and services. The problem, of course, is that regional preferences and regional economic and fiscal resources are often mismatched. Levels of economic development and corresponding revenue bases vary; as does economic profile (e.g., between "rustbelt" versus "sunbelt" regions). To add to the complexity, central governments' capacity to reduce these differences by traditional methods has grown more difficult, due to the trends outlined above. As Keating (1999) notes, federal-level governments have experienced a striking loss of capacity to forge territorial economic compromises by traditional means: "Diversionary [i.e., redistributive] regional policy measures┘are much more difficult to implement in a globalized economy because firms have a wide choice of location outside the boundaries of the state." Thus old strategies for regional protection, such as tariffs, diversionary regional policies, and state-directed investment strategies no longer prove as feasible or effective (Keating 1999). Instead, many central governments have handed more responsibility for economic development to regions themselves. Central policies often focus on stimulating growth in less developed regions by promoting local competitiveness -- for example, with credits for infrastructure, high-technology, creation of special economic zones etc. These steps, so the argument goes, reduce centralization and regulation, and thereby encourage economic growth, as demonstrated with dramatic results in China. There, the adoption of SEZ's yielded average growth rates in eastern regions (i.e., primarily coastal) of 11.4 percent per year during 1984-1993, while initiatives in Western regions yielded average growth rates of 8.9 percent per year during the same period (Dutta). However, most central governments have shown much less of a tendency to devolve revenue sources to regions and localities. The preponderance of taxes remains concentrated at the national level, since the ones with the highest yields generally tend to be more easily and efficiently collected on a central rather than regional basis (Norregaard, 1997). If anything, the advantages of national governments have increased in this regard, given the impacts of globalization and increased capital mobility noted above. Thus devolution in expenditures and in economic policy has not been matched by a corresponding decentralization of revenues. The alternative in most cases has been to rely instead on various mechanisms to reallocate federal funds, from tax-sharing to special-purpose grants for specific programs to outright subsidies. And the choice of mechanism seems to depend on the goals of the central government. Where these goals emphasize cross-regional equalization, as in Germany and Canada, for example, federal revenue sharing emphasizes explicit redistribution to offset regional differences in tax capacity (Krelove, Stotsky and Vehorn, 1997; Spahn and Fottinger, 1997). Where federal goals are more diverse, as in the U.S., mechanisms for central funding of state and local programs are less explicitly redistributive. Finally, the trend toward devolution also raises questions about the prospects for national integration. It seems obvious that a diminished role for the central government and divergent policies across regions would exert increased centrifugal pressures on the national state. Belgium and Canada may be the clearest examples of the difficulties involved in preserving the federal system overall. But whether they can be preserved depends in part on identifying the real sources of devolution and responding to them. If trends toward devolution are indeed products of global changes in economic and social life, then ignoring them would seem to be a losing battle. The question is how to build institutions that can adapt. Conclusions Asymmetry and devolution have become facts of life in both federal and unitary systems over the past 25 years. My aim here has been to demonstrate that these are the result of broader global trends in economics, society and politics. They suggest increasing limits on the economic effectiveness of centralized states. However, whether regions actually benefit from these changes depends on how governments at the grassroots adapt to the global market and to commonly accepted democratic rules of the game. References Agranoff, Robert. 1994. "Asymmetrical and Symmetrical Federalism in Spain: An Examination of Intergovernmental Policy," in DeVilliers, pp. 61-90. Agranoff, Robert and Juan Gallarin, 1997. "Toward Federal Democracy in Spain: An Examination of Intergovernmental Relations," Publius, 27:4, pp. 1-38. Aslund, Anders. 1999. "The Problem of Fiscal Federalism," Journal of Democracy, 10:2, pp. 83-86. Boase, . 1994. In DeVilliers, Cho, Stella and Samuel Tung. 1998. "Investment Incentive Zones And Regional Tax Incentive Policy In The People's Republic of China," International Tax Journal 24: 4, pp. 81-91. DeVilliers, Bertus, ed. 1994. Evaluating Federal Systems. Dordrecht: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers. Downs, William. 1999. "Accountability Payoffs in Federal Systems: Evidence from Belgium," Publius, 29: , pp. Dutta, . "China's Economic Growth during 1984-93," Falletti, Tulia. 1999. "New Fiscal Federalism and the Political Dynamics of Decentralization in Latin America," Paper Prepared for Delivery at the American Political Science Association Annual Meeting, Atlanta, 1999. Gelman, Vladimir and Olga Senatova. 1995. "Subnational Politics in Russia in the PostCommunist Transition Period: A View from Moscow," Regional and Federal Studies, 5: 211-223. Judt, Tony. 1999. "Is There a Belgium?" New York Review of Books, 46:19, pp. 49-53. Keating, Michael. 1998. "Re-Forging the Union: Devolution and Constitutional Change in the United Kingdom," Publius, 28: 1, pp. 217-234. Keating, Michael. 1999. "Asymmetrical Government: Multinational States in an Integrating Europe," Publius, 29: 1, pp. 71-86. Kotabe, Masaaki et al. "South America's Free Trade Gambit," Marketing Management, 7:1, (spring 1998), pp. 38-46. Krelove, Russell, Janet Stotsky, and Charles Vehorn, 1997. "Canada," in Ter-Minassian, pp. 201-25. Lapidus, Gail. 1999. "Asymmetrical Federalism and State Breakdown in Russia," PostSoviet Affairs, 15: 1, pp. 74-82. Luttwak, Edward. 1999. Turbo Capitalism: Winners and Losers in the Global Economy. New York: HarperCollins. Lynn, Nicholas and Alexei Novikov, 1997. "Refederalizing Russia: Debates on the Idea of Federalism in Russia," Publius, 27:2, pp. 187-203. Mershon, Carol and Kerstin Hamann, 1999. "Regional Coalition Government in Spain: The Impact of Institutions and Regionalist Conflicts," Paper Prepared for the American Political Science Association Annual Meeting, Atlanta, 1999. Moreno, Luis. 1994. "Ethnoterritorial Concurrence and Imperfect Federalism in Spain," in DeVilliers, pp. 162-193. Norregaard, John. 1997. "Tax Assignment," in Ter-Minassian, pp. 49-72. Ordeshook, Peter and Olga Shvetsova. 1997. "Federalism and Constitutional Design," Journal of Democracy, 8:1,pp. 27-42. The Solnick, Steven. 1995. "Federal Bargaining in Russia," East European Constitutional Review (fall 1995), pp. 52-58. Spahn, Paul Bernd and Wolfgang Fottinger, 1997. "Germany," in Ter-Minassian, pp. 22648. Stepan, Alfred. 1999a. "Federalism and Democracy: Beyond the U.S. Model," Journal of Democracy, 10: 4, pp. 19-34. Stepan, Alfred. 1999b. "Russian Federalism in Comparative Perspective: Problems of Power Creation and Power Deflation," Paper prepared for the American Association for the Advancement of Slavic Studies, St. Louis. Stoner-Weiss, Kathryn. 1999. "Central Weakness and Provincial Autonomy: Observations on the Devolution Process in Russia," Post-Soviet Affairs, 15: 1, pp. 87-106. Teague, Elizabeth. "Russia and the Regions: The Uses of Ambiguity," in John Gibson and Philip Hanson, Transformation from Below: Local Power and the Political Economy of Post-Communist Transitions. Edward Elgar, 1996, pp. 13-36. Ter-Minassian, Teresa, editor. 1997. Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. Watts, Ronald. 1994. "Contemporary Views on Federalism," in DeVilliers, pp. 1-29. Watts, Ronald. 1996. Comparing Federal Systems in the 1990s. Kingston, Ontario: Institute of Intergovernmental Relations, Queen's University. Willis, Eliza, Christopher da C. B. Garman, Stephan Haggard. 1999. "The Politics of Decentralization in Latin America," Latin American Research Review, 34: 1, pp. 7-56. Notes 1 For an overview of the debate, see Lynn and Novikov (1997). 2 In keeping with the common definition in the literature, I define a ⌠federal■ system here as one with two or more levels of government holding distinct constitutional status and separate (if overlapping) jurisdictions. 3 Devolution in social programs would be expected to limit expenditures, because regional and local governments would find it more difficult to finance them (i.e., they have fewer revenue sources of their own to draw on). 4 For a comparative overview, see Keating (1999). 5 Initially, the plan for devolution in 1978 provided for two kinds of paths to autonomy -- a "fast track" for regions with a historical claim to differential status such as Catalonia and Basque country; and a "slow track" for the fifteen others. In practice, all 17 regions have witnessed substantial decentralization since then. 6 Cho and Tung (1998) write that these different regional economic regimes vary in emphasis. Some, such as "High-Technology and Industrial Development Zones," are generally built in university districts of major cities to promote investment in research and development of high-technology sectors. Others may focus on the development of local infrastructure to promote greater foreign investment, or on a host of other incentives to generate economic growth. 7 Note, however, that devolution itself can also complicate the issue of accountability, as voters are faced with a diverse array of elected officials with overlapping responsibilities. See Downs (1999). 8 According to the Basque government, legislators also serve full-time, and may not be members of the royal family, the government, electoral commission, the police or the armed forces. I was unable to determine whether these provisions apply to all 17 autonomies. The autonomies do differ in defining electoral districts: some have a single district encompassing the entire region; while others have multiple districts (Mershon and Hamann, 1999). List of publications of the team concerning the role of regions: "Country Summaries: Situation after the Meeting at Mehrerau" in Newsletter 2 of the project Russian Regional Studies Network Russian Regions Regionalization of Russian Foreign and Security Policy: Interaction between Regional Processes and the Interest of the Central State The objective of this international research project is to analyze regional dimensions of Russian foreign and security policy, an aspect of center-periphery relationship that has not yet been researched systematically. The aim of the project is to determine whether and how the central state understands the specific interests of Russian regions and to what extent regional processes have an impact on Russia’s external relations and on integration processes within the CIS space and beyond. A main task of this project consists in establishing profiles of selected Russian regions in order to examine their international security environment and relationship to the Moscow center. In order to present a true picture of Russia’s uneven regional landscape, the regions have been carefully selected according to various criteria. Border regions and central regions, ethnic republics and oblasts and krais, poor agrarian regions and rich oil- and gas-producing regions are among the regions selected: the Tatarstan, Komi and Karelia republics, the Sverdlovsk, Kaliningrad, Pskov, Nizhnii Novgorod, Novosibirsk, Volgograd, Kursk, Belgorod, and Ryzan olasts, the Primorskii Krai, as well as the two cities of St.Petersburg and Moscow. Apart from field research, several studies are planned to further elaborate on issues of a more general and/or theoretical character. Problems such as the regions’ place in a globalizing world, the understanding of “sovereignty” from a regional point of view, the importance of external factors for Russia’s regionalization, the impact of information and communication technology on center-periphery relations, and the role and political orientation of Russia’s regional elite will among others be the issues included. During the course of research, close cooperation has been established with research institutions and organizations in Russia and several Western countries such as the Centre for Russian and East European Studies at the University of Birmingham, the Scottish Centre for International Security at the University of Aberdeen, the Copenhagen Peace Research Institute, the Swedish Defence Research Agency, the Royal Institute of International Affairs, the Nizhnii Novgorod Linguistic State University, the Ulianovsk State Technical University, the Department of Political Science and Sociology at Ural State University, the School of International Relations at St. Petersburg State University, the Center of Geopolitical Studies at the Moscow Institute of Geography, the Faculty of History and International Relations at Volgograd State University or the Novosibirsk State Academy of Water-Transport Engineers. Contacts: Prof. Dr. Andreas Wenger Regions Carp as Center Flounders By MICHAEL DEMAR THURMAN Institute for the Study of Conflict, Ideology and Policy With the campaign slogan "Break Moscow's Fetters," Nizhny Novgorod mayoral candidate Dmitri Bednyakov seems to reflect the opinion of an increasing number of Russians with greater confidence in regional, rather than federal, authorities, as the latter are seen as incompetent and unreliable. (1) The present economic and political crisis has exacerbated this mistrust and has caused various regions to react with creative, if not entirely desperate, techniques for survival. The result has been an acceleration of the process of political decentralization, which has developed quietly over the last few years. The effect of the present crisis on center-regional relations cannot be known at this early stage, but judging by the constitutional structure of the federal government and the inability of the federal authorities to provide even minimal leadership, an increase in regional autonomy is assured. Any shift in power may be permanent or of long duration for, if history is any guide, power once given--or taken--is loath to be surrendered. It is too soon to claim that centralism is dead; but for the first time in modern Russian history, significant political authority can be found in areas outside of palace, party, or president. A review of the structure of Russian federalism, the actions of the regions in response to the crisis and Moscow's abrogation of leadership, suggests that some devolution of power is occurring. Constitutional Structure Federalism is enshrined in the 1993 constitution in chapters 3, 5, and 8. Chapter 3, "Russian Federation," recognizes 87 subjects (states, Länder, provinces) of the federation with the status of Moscow and St. Petersburg to be determined later. (2) Article 71 enumerates the powers reserved for the federal government, Article 72 discusses powers shared by the federal government and the regional governments, (3) and Article 73, similar to the Tenth Amendment to the United States' constitution, reserves "the entire spectrum of state power" for the regions. (4) Chapter 5, "The Federal Assembly," provides that regions will be directly represented in the upper house of the Federal Assembly, the Federation Council. Each region is given two seats in the Federation Council, but unlike the American Senate, regions do not elect representatives expressly for this purpose. Rather, Article 95 provides that "two deputies from each subject of the Federation shall be members of Federation Council: one from the representative and one from the executive body of state authority." A subsequent presidential decree defined this to mean that each region would be represented by its governor, or chief executive, and the head of its regional parliament. The Federation Council has the potential to save the flawed system during this crisis. This is because the Federation Council is at once both central and regional, and thus embodies both levels of sovereignty within the federal system. Members of the upper house of the Russian parliament do not merely represent the interests of the regions--they are the regions. In other words, in an institutional sense, the Federation Council is less about representation than it is a caucus of regional authorities. During times of "normal" politics, the Federation Council can be a terrible burden on the governor and speakers or presidents of regional legislatures because direct regional representation is not really necessary for the day-to-day functions of government. However, during times of constitutional crisis, the regional sovereignty within the Federation Council, legitimated by a democratic process separate from the federal source whose legitimacy would then be in question, can become the "provisional" representation of the nation until the truly national institutions--the president and/or the Duma--can re-establish themselves. Most importantly, all of this is largely possible within the confines of the constitution. In fact, governors have been brought directly into the presidium of the government. Chapter 5 provides for the election of the lower house of the Federal Assembly, but is silent as to how the members are to be elected. Article 95, Section 3 says only that the Duma shall consist of 450 members. A 1995 law on Duma elections provided that one-half of the Duma be elected by single-member constituencies and one-half by national party lists distributed by proportional representation. (5) This election method has had a significant impact on the structure of Russian political parties both inside and outside the Duma. Single-member districts undercut the ability of Duma factions and national parties to maintain party discipline. The existence of singlemember electoral districts makes for lawmakers whose concerns lie more with their districts than with national party issues. In order to survive, "national" parties which are managed from Moscow must address the needs of specific regions. This too enhances regional influence in the Duma. Chapter 8, "Local Self-Government," may be the most important section of the constitution for the development of federalism by virtue of what it omits: It does not tell the regions how to set up or run their governments. Article 130, Section 1 says that "local selfgovernmentŠshall ensure independent solution by the population of local issues," and Article 131, Section 1 allows "the structure of bodies of local self-government [to] be determined by the population independently." Article 132, Section 1 empowers local governments to "independently manage municipal property, form, approve, and execute the local budget, establish local taxes and levies, and ensure law and order and solve any other local issues." This seemingly simple absence of instruction forced the regions to become responsible for an entire host of post-Soviet transitional issues, as well as the more quotidian affairs of government. It also provides the regions with a broad constitutional argument for their recent actions. Thus the constitution allows the creation, perhaps unwittingly, of real centers of popular decision-making where only hollow regional administration existed before. The inability of the federal government to implement its own laws contributes to the structural causes of increased regional autonomy. The catastrophic disarray of the Russian bureaucracy is no secret, but it seems often ignored in the debate about reform proposals. Even if meaningful reform were to be introduced in Moscow, it is a long way from the Kremlin to the regions, i.e., the average citizen's front door. (6) The reverse is also true; the representatives of regional governments often must go begging hat-in-hand to particular federal bureaucrats who have the connections to dispense the necessary help. The system is capricious, personalized, and wildly ineffective. Regional governments often must find their own way because they simply cannot trust the federal government to make good on its promises. Another obvious case of expanding regional competence is the process of signing center-region treaties, themselves an admission of the lack of federal control after the collapse of the Soviet Union. The process began more than four years ago with the Republic of Tatarstan. Since then more than 40 other regions have signed such agreements. Crisis and the Changing Federal Relationship In view of the federal nature of the Russian political structure, it is hardly surprising that response to the present economic and political crisis has come in a decentralized or regional form. From regional currencies, to price caps, to trade prohibitions, the regions are struggling to feed, house, and clothe their citizens because the central government is incapable of doing so. The crisis began with the effective devaluation of the ruble in August. This led to a partial collapse of the banking system. (7) The crisis was compounded politically with Prime Minister Sergei Kirienko's dismissal as well as Viktor Chernomyrdin's nomination and two-time rejection by the Duma, culminating in the Duma's ratification of Yevgeni Primakov's prime ministerial candidacy on 11 September. Responses to the crisis range widely, but several trends are clear. Some, or most, regions are withdrawing from the Russian market as a whole, and some are taking control of law enforcement agencies, thereby taking control of their own borders. For instance, certain regions, such as St. Petersburg, asked banks to invest not in federal treasury bonds, but rather in regional bonds. Often those who transferred their funds to regional bonds did better than those who did not. But buyer beware: Several regions, such as Tatarstan, have defaulted on their debts. (8) The Tatarstan case makes an important point. Much of what is presently happening is not necessarily the result of the crisis; rather, regional authorities have used the center's mess to explain the failure of local economies. Vechernyaya kazan reported that Tatarstan would have defaulted on its debts anyway, regardless of the ruble devaluation, because the money it raised was mishandled. (9) Kaliningrad Governor Leonid Gorbenko noted that "it is becoming ever more evident that power structures in the provinces are trying to 'grab' a maximum of powers that unquestionably belonged to the central administration as recently as a week agoŠ." Gorbenko goes on to claim that this is understandable because "Moscow is currently unable to control the situation in the state," (10) but another reason for the power struggle may be to lessen the chance of future financial control by Moscow. In a July interview, the speaker of the Khanty-Mansi Autonomous Area, Sergei Sobyanin, argued that the true sources of power in the regions were not Moscow "oligarchs" or politicians but the finance ministry, since 79 out of 89 regions received federal subsidies and were therefore subject to intimidation by the ministry. (11) Times have changed, at least temporarily. As more and more regions refuse to pay taxes or hand over central bank deposits, federal treasury employees posted in the regions are finding themselves increasingly at the mercy of regional authorities for assistance in resolving matters of business, as well as for help in day-to-day living. (12) For years, regional authorities had to beg the federal treasury for attention. Now that the tables have turned, it would be small wonder if a little retribution were not in order. Sergei Sobyanin also noted that the "power" ministries play a significant role in intimidating the regions. According to Sobyanin, "they are engaged in collecting bags of compromising materials against regional leaders." (13) Perhaps this is one reason why many regional and local governments are setting up their own security councils, chaired by the governor or mayor and including regional and local representatives from law enforcement agencies. Duma Security Council member Vladimir Lopatin says that, with Moscow unable to pay the salaries of local law enforcement officers, they turn to local authorities who, predictably, want control over how enforcement groups operate. The regional and local officials then gain control of agencies which are technically under the exclusive purview of the federal authorities. The situation is illegal, says Lopatin, but the regions find having their own security councils is helpful for extracting more power from Moscow, (14) and possibly protecting themselves from future abuses of federal authority. Some regions have erected trading barriers in clear contravention of the constitution. Chapter 3, Article 74, Section 1 states that "no customs frontiers, duties, levies, or any other barriers for free movement of goods, services, or financial means may be establishedŠ," but many regions are doing just that. Tatarstan's president, Mintimer Shaimiev, prevented exports of sugar and sugar beets from the republic--as well as imports of alcohol from other regions. (15) (It seems that several regions have created their own monopoly on alcohol production.) In Volgograd, governor Nikolai Maksuyuta sent the militia to prevent the shipment of 257 tons of produce and the transfer of 200 sheep from the region, and some Volgograd firms show signs of substituting local raw materials for imported resources. (16) Sakha and Kemerovo are moving to set up their own gold reserves, which could lead ultimately to their own central banks. (17) Many regions have ceased to pay federal taxes. Although the regions that contribute most of the federal budget (Moscow, Khanty-Mansi, Yamal-Nenets, Samara, Sverdlovsk and Krasnoyarsk) are still paying, the chairman of the Federation Council, Yegor Stroev, noted that presently, the "transit of financial resources is the most difficult problem." (18) From Tomsk, to Omsk, to Irkutsk, to Kakhassiya, regions are not sending their federal tax receipts to Moscow. To illustrate the level of distrust between the regions and center, Altai Krai is refusing to send 40 million rubles, in exchange for a federal payment of 180 million rubles, because the krai believes the promised payment would not be forthcoming. (19) Better one in the hand than four and one-half in the bush. Moreover, regions are taking control of federal shares in local factories. For example, with the use of Eurobond money, the administration of Nizhny Novgorod Oblast' purchased a controlling share in many of its local companies and successfully lobbied the federal government for the transfer of federally owned company shares to them. Prime Minister Primakov recently endorsed this measure. (20) Regions are also developing their own financial systems based largely on barter. Last year the Karpov commission reported that the country's largest companies conducted 73 percent of their business in barter and other non-monetary ways. (21) Interestingly, they paid 80 percent of the taxes owed to the federal government, but only 8 percent in cash. In the Udor District of the Komi Republic, rent and utility bills are paid with potatoes: 1 kilogram of potatoes = 2 rubles. A decree by the president of the Komi Republic, Yuri Spiridonov, provides for the settlement of debts by payments in kind. The public utility workers who were owed wages quickly snapped up the potatoes. (22) In Tatarstan, the regional government was told by Moscow that 24 local companies with federal tax arrears could pay their debt by supplying the armed forces stationed in Tatarstan with food and other consumables. (23) Impact on Future Center-Region Relations That the regions "circle their wagons" in slightly different ways, as their specific crises warrant, is not surprising. What is important is the possible shift in regional attitudes and the increasing permanence of crisis-born regional institutions which may challenge future attempts by Moscow to rein in the regions. If it is felt that Moscow dithers while the regions wither, there may be a regional reluctance to cooperate fully with Moscow and the regions may tend to "squirrel away" assets rather than surrender them to a central authority. Institutional change may include: an expansion of regional financial institutions and their close association with the regional authorities; an increase in bilateral relationships, both inside and outside the federation; and the continuation of barter economy and a distrust of cash. Also evident is an increased profile for interregional association, or super-regions, (24) the leaders of which have been granted seats in the presidium of the government. The superregions may also constitute the basis for some future administration of the economy, although the chances of that seem dim. (25) Three things have changed permanently in Russian political culture as a result: an increase in the number and type of players in the Russian political system; the proliferation of power venues and "entry points" into the political system; and the slide from political power or authority as a singular concept to one which is increasingly plural in nature. It is often said that adversity builds character. Perhaps it will also build Russian federalism. Notes: 1 Institute for East-West Studies, Russian Regional Report, Internet Edition, 10 September 1998. 2 Presently they are recognized as full subjects of the federation, bringing the total number of regions to 89. 3 I use region as a generic reference to all administrative subjects of the federation. 4 All subsequent quotations from the Constitution of the Russian Federation are taken from the copy found at . 5 President Yel'tsin suggested changing the law so that the entire body would be elected by single-member districts, and predictably, encountered fierce resistance from the national political parties. 6 Former Deputy Prime Minister Boris Nemtsov pointed to his inability to overcome the opposition mounted by the entrenched bureaucracy as one of the mistakes he made while in office. See Obshchaya gazeta, 1-7 October 98; FBIS-SOV-98-287. 7 "Regional Newspapers and the Russian Crisis," The Business Development Service of the Russian National Press Institute, 16 September 1998 (New York: The Center for War, Peace, and the News Media, New York University). 8 Vechernyaya kazan, 11 September 98. 9 Ibid. 10 Kaliningradskaya pravda, 10 September 98, pp. 1-2; FBIS-SOV98-260. 11 Argumenty i fakty, No. 30, July 98 (Signed to press 21 July 1998), p. 4; FBIS-SOV-98-203. 12 Ekspert Magazine, 14 September 98. 13 Ibid. 14 Ruskii telegraf, 21 August 98. 15 Russian Regional Report, Internet Edition, 17 September 98. 16 Volgogradskaya pravda, 15 September 98. 17 Kommersant Daily, 10 September 98. 18 ITAR-TASS, 0946 GMT, 9 September 98; FBIS-SOV-98-252. 19 Finansovie izvestiya, 15 September 98. 20 ITAR -TASS, 0923 GMT, 3 October 98; FBIS-SOV-98-276. 21 The Interdepartmental Balance Commission headed by the Deputy Director of the Federal Administration on Bankruptcy, Petyr Karpov. The commission was instructed to collect tax from major debtors. See Clifford G. Gaddy and Barry W. Ickes, "Russia's Virtual Economy," Foreign Affairs (September/October 1998); Business Week, 13 April 98. 22 Syktyvkar, Komi Republic. ITAR-TASS, 17 September 1998; nexis. 23 See footnote 8. 24 The super-regions are: Greater Volga, Greater Urals, The North Caucasus, Northwest, The Siberian Accord, Central Russia, Chernozemye (The Black Earth Region), and Far-East and TransBaikal. 25 ITAR-TASS, 8 September 98. Copyright ISCIP 1998 Unless otherwise indicated, all articles appearing in this journal have been commissioned especially for Perspective. Perspective Volume VI, No 3 (January-February 1996) Send us a note to subscribe to Perspective. The Crossroads of Russian Federalism By VLADIMIR YEMELYANENKO Moscow News Since the system of local soviets was abolished in 1993, the power struggle between the Kremlin and the Russian provinces on one hand, and the local executive and legislative branches on the other, can be characterized as open conflict, occasionally interrupted by armed neutrality. Issues concerning the rights of the "Federation Subjects" (Russia's 89 provinces and republics) emerged five years ago. The reasons for complicated interactions between the organs of state power are to be found in President Boris Yel'tsin's federal policy. Its direction was formulated in 1991 when the president stated that "every Subject of the Federation will try to assume as much sovereignty as it can." In a short period of time, the national-territorial entities, the republics, acquired some attributes of sovereignty after signing treaties concerning delimitation of power with the Kremlin. The republics managed to obtain agreements under which their contributions to the federal budget were lowered. As a result, 21 republics, 12 of which are subsidized by the center (e.g., 90 percent of Ingushetia's budget comes from federal subsidies, 92 percent in the case of the Adygei republic, while Komi and Karelia are subsidized to the tune of some 52 percent), were granted economic privileges at the expense of the rest of the 68 Russian territorialadministrative formations such as krais, oblasts, and okrugs .(1) Since then, the largest Russian regions, (Sverdlovsk oblast', which is economically more powerful than the republic of Tatarstan, Leningrad Oblast', (2) Maritime and Krasnodar krais, the five regions of Siberia,(3) and Kaliningrad oblast') have embarked on a permanent struggle for economic equity with the republics. Between 1993 and 1994 the regions lost the first battle. This was a period of regional separatism, when the oblasts were trying to consolidate into republics following the Tatarstan, Chechnya, or Yakutia models. The proclamation of Ural, Siberian, and Far Eastern republics was a provocative move vis-a-vis the Kremlin. However, these amorphous entities, with a mere paper legitimacy, had a single objective -redistribution of the federal budget. Under these circumstances, Moscow initiated treaties on delimitation of power with individual administrative entities, marking a new stage in the struggle of krais and oblast for equal rights with the republics. In 1995 the federal government signed a treaty "On Delimitation of Power With Orenburg Oblast '." Subsequently, in January 1996, similar treaties were signed between the Kremlin and Sverdlovsk, as well as between the center and Kaliningrad. The difference in status between these oblasts and the republics was narrowed, and it was clear that the government had provided the basis for favoritism in its federal policy. The preferential treatment Orenburg and Sverdlovsk received was not accidental: Orenburg and Sverdlovsk, respectively, are Prime Minister Viktor Chernomyrdin's and President Yel'tsin's hometowns. The establishment of direct bilateral relations between the Kremlin and Sverdlovsk encouraged the Far East, Tyumen, Krasnodar, and Kuzbass to solicit for special status. There is no doubt that certain regions should be granted prerogatives: the isolated enclave location of Kaliningrad and the territorial remoteness of the Far Eastern Maritime province dictate a different level of relations with the center than the "inner" regions. It is easier for Kaliningrad to maintain trade relations with neighboring Poland, Lithuania or Scandinavia, and it is more sensible for the Far Eastern Maritime region to trade with China, Japan, and Korea, than for either to deal with Central Russia. Tyumen is also insisting on a special status, since it provides 69 percent of Russia's oil production, but is allowed to use the profits of only one percent. Today Moscow views the signing of bilateral treaties with the leading regions as a continuation of the trend started with the republics. Federation Council experts analyzed the treaties on delimitation of power that were signed with Yakutia and Tatarstan and concluded that, initially, the preferential treatment in taxation allowed these republics to maintain lower prices in comparison with the neighboring regions. However, as these analysts discovered, eventually such a policy resulted in the disappearance of some products and price increases of others. According to the experts, such an outcome, stimulated by the Kremlin, is resulting in a type of economic separatism. A similar tendency in Orenburg and Sverdlovsk demonstrated the futility of the federal center trying to appease the largest and most developed Subjects of the Federation. In other words, delimitation of powers in bilateral agreements inevitably entails recarving the federal budget, which is doomed to become leaner with more regions in line for a piece of the federal pie. It is clear that the "special relations" and "bilateral agreements" between the regions and the center have only a symbolic character. The best solution, according to the former Minister on Nationality Issues, Valeri Tishkov, derives not from "special status," but from "regionalization," in other words, the unification of oblasts , krais , and republics into economic groups. For example, Bashkortostan, Sverdlovsk, Perm, Orenburg could unify into a large Ural region; the Siberian krais, oblasts and national entities into a Siberia region, etc. In proposing this model Tishkov suggests a departure from ethnic territorial entities as distinct economic areas. His idea is supported by the governors of Nizhny Novgorod (Boris Nemtsov) and Orel (Egor Stroev). However, the presidents of the ethnic republics do not welcome this idea. The Kremlin, so far, is aiming to preserve the status quo, while giving favorite treatment to certain regions. At the same time, the central government is trying to preserve maximum control over all Federation Subjects. The roots of such a policy are seen in Moscow's interference in the balance of power between the two branches of regional power. It is clear that elections have become an effective tool for the center to manipulate the regions. According to federal law, the heads of local administrations (i.e., the governors), and the chairmen of regional parliaments, soviets, or zemstvos (4)(the representative branch) should be elected to office. The results of such a supposedly democratic system were demonstrated on December 17, 1995, when elections to the Federal Duma coincided with gubernatorial elections in 12 Russian regions. Yel'tsin succeeded again in placing "his" people in the periphery. The gubernatorial elections were conducted in the absence of electoral law and were based instead on a 1993 presidential edict. In 1993, under a similar edict, an experimental set of elections was conducted in nine regions. As a result, the newly elected local executives, (representing a typical Yel'tsin electorate in cities like Yekaterinburg, Moscow, St. Petersburg, Nizhny Novgorod, Krasnoyarsk, and Irkutsk) usurped all functions of power. The distribution of power became even more uneven after the legislative functions of the local soviets were deprived of substance. In a period of two years regional legislatures gradually lost their authority, which was transferred into the hands of the governors. These heads of administration became enamored with their widened "responsibilities," performing executive and legislative tasks at the same time. Since 1993, both chambers of the Russian parliament have considered four versions of electoral law for gubernatorial elections. Each met its demise in the Duma over the issue of defining the limits of executive power. In the contest between the branches the 17 December 1995 elections mark yet another victory for the executive. In general, the results are also to Moscow's advantage; incumbents, who were originally appointed by Yel'tsin, won in nine of the 12 regions holding gubernatorial elections. Moreover, these regions had substantially higher voter participation; with 60% to 70% turnout in regions holding simultaneous gubernatorial elections as compared to 58% to 62% in other parts of Russia. The nine incumbent victors confirm the formation of a vertical flow of power, from a powerful executive to a legislature dependent upon him. Only three regions elected new governors; a communist in Novosibirsk and two former party apparatchiks in Tambov and Tver. This development should not be viewed as simply a restoration of the nomenklatura. Rather, it poses a more complicated problem; namely, that communists candidates were victorious in precisely those regions where the legislative branch was completely trampled by the executive. Over the last couple of years, not a single piece of legislation enacted by the regional parliament has been signed into law in Tambov and Novosibirsk. This "cold war" between the branches illuminates a rather interesting alliance; nowadays, former CPSU obkom secretaries do not rely solely on fellow communists. They have found new partners among the motley composition of the powerless legislative branch. "Offended" and "discouraged," local legislative representatives, either Communists, members of the Congress of Russian Communities or representatives of Zhirinovsky's LDPR, nominated gubernatorial candidates in all 12 regions. A month after the elections in Tver, Novosibirsk, and Tambov, where the united opposition proved victorious, the rival branches have declared a truce. This truce is an unwelcome development for Moscow, which has lost its levers in the periphery. The democratic parties originated in the capital and have little influence or organizational strength outside Moscow. The Communist party, on the other hand, is the only party which maintained and developed its infrastructure in the provinces. With this strategic disadvantage in mind, Moscow based the elections on a presidential edict rather than electoral law and forbade the most unreliable regions to hold elections. Such as Kuzbass, where 51 percent of the electorate voted for the Communists in the federal elections; Chita, where none of the laws of the local Duma was approved by the head of their administration; Volgograd, where the local soviet is constantly demanding the resignation of the governor; and Saratov, where the oblast ' Duma is in conflict with the city mayor. For four years all of these regions have been demanding the right to hold gubernatorial elections. If the new Duma passes legislation concerning gubernatorial elections, a return of the far left-leaning legislatures is predestined. In this context, Yel'tsin recently stated that those regions which had been forbidden to hold elections in December would be allowed to hold gubernatorial elections this spring. Such a move would constitute a serious challenge by Moscow to the rebellious regional elites. The Kremlin is giving assurances that such elections will not be held on the basis of a presidential edict, but in accordance with a to-be-adopted new law. If such legislation is passed by the Duma and signed by the president, it would reflect Moscow's new political course toward the regions, i.e., a shift from authoritarianism to real federalism. However, this policy also reveals a paradox; more federalism will legitimize the domination of Communists in the political life of the regions. Notes: 1. Republic -- territory with a non-Russian titular nationality; Krai -large region which contains smaller ethnic territorial formations, such as okrugs; Oblast' -- administrative entity without specific ethnic characteristics; Okrug - subdivision of a krai or oblast' -- Ed. 2. Although the city of Leningrad was renamed St. Petersburg, the name of the oblast' remains unchanged. -- Ed. 3. Omsk, Novosibirsk, Tomsk, Chitinsk oblasts, and Krasnodar Krai. --Ed. 4. Zemstvo -- elected district council in pre-revolutionary Russia (the name has been re-adopted today) --Ed. Perspective Volume II, No 3 (January 1992) Send us a note to subscribe to Perspective. Turmoil in Russia's Mini-Empire By MARJORIE MANDELSTAM BALZER Georgetown University A year ago, when Yel'tsin-leaning intellectuals criticized Gorbachev's nationalities policies by saying "if he keeps this up he'll have nothing left but Moscow," they were only half-joking. Their flippancy also revealed an underlying savvy: various national bids for sovereignty have been intertwined in the center-periphery dynamic. Given such complex interactions, each case must be examined in historical context. Even for Russia's "autonomous republics," specific legacies must be reviewed, indigenous leaders heard, and interrepublic relations assessed before generalizations can be made about whether a republic is likely to become a successful "nationalist" domino. The five mini-empire cases outlined here are in decreasing order of current secession-mindedness and turmoil. Chechen-Ingushetia, in the incendiary North Caucasus tier, has a sad legacy as home to two of Stalin's "punished peoples," who were accused en masse of Nazism during World War II, deported to Central Asia, and then returned to a cropped territory corresponding neither to their self-defined homelands nor to the territory they had before the war. By 1989, the Chechen numbered 956,879, and the Ingush 237,438, respectively 58 percent and 13 percent of their republic's population.(1) By 1991, they were ready for divorce from each other, and the Chechen leader General Dudaev campaigned for separation from Russia. He employed the rhetoric of Islamic fundamentalism yet also advocated state secularism. Some of his "Islamic Path" followers had volunteered to fight in the 1991 Gulf War, for Iraq. Dudaev, perhaps symbolizing Russians' worst nightmares, was furthered in his polarizing cause when Yel'tsin declared a local state of emergency. After angry parliamentary debate, Yel'tsin, and the speaker of the Russian parliament, Khasbulatov, a Russified Chechen, backed down. A few Russian troops in the region were surrounded by Chechen forces and sent packing. In late 1991, the Chechen, Ingush, Kabardin, Balkar, Karachai, Cherkess, Abkhas, Ossetians and others met for their Third Congress of Mountain Peoples of the Caucasus and vowed to form their own confederation of independent states.(2) Tatarstan presents only a slightly less anti-Russian, anti-Moscow case. Like the Chechen, many Tatars are Islamic, but some are proud of a reformist tradition, Jadidism, that at the turn of the century advocated education for women and sponsored a satirical journal called Kha, Kha, Kha. When Stalin's cronies were apportioning union republics to peoples with over a million in population, the Tatars qualified, but were denied the status, perhaps a slap against their already jailed "National Communist" leader Sultan Galiev. By 1989, the Tatars numbered 6,648,760. In 1991, their activist youth staged demonstrations demanding secession from Russia and return of Tatar lands.(3) Tatars form today about 50 percent of their republic, but nearly 75 percent live outside the republic. A referendum on independence could leave them within Russia, although radicals of the Ittifak (Alliance) Party are trying to lower the percent necessary for secession to less than 50. By 1992, Tatar legislators, with republic President Shaimiev, unilaterally declared Tatarstan to be a full member of the Commonwealth.(4) Tuva was a country, Tannu-Tuva, bordering on and analogous to Mongolia, from 1918-1944. Incorporation into Russia meant loss of some land, many resources, and much dignity. Today, Tuvans agitate for boundary changes, ecological clean-up, and far greater political autonomy, if not outright secession. Their popular front, with both moderate (accommodate Russians) and radical (leave yesterday) wings, has tried to discourage violence against the local Russians, but serious violence occurred in May-July 1990, concentrated in areas of high unemployment and recent Russian settlement. Soviet troops were brought in to quell the disturbances, angering Tuvans even further. Russian refugees, estimated at over 10,000, have been fleeing since 1989 across the high Altai mountains, although local officials beg skilled workers and professionals to stay.(5) Tuvans numbered 206,629, and were 64 percent of their republic, in 1989. They declared sovereignty as the Tuvan Socialist Republic in 1990. Their regional orientation is increasingly toward Mongolia. Buryatia was gerrymandered in 1937. The homeland of the Mongolic Buryats, surrounding Lake Baikal, was divided into the Buryat Autonomous Republic, and the Agin and Ust-Orda Buryat Autonomous Okrugs, with interspersed regions considered Russian. Within the Buryat Republic, which declared sovereignty in 1990, Buryats are only 24 percent, but this percentage would rise if lands they claim were theirs. Buryats numbered 421,380 in 1989, when non-communist party politicians began quietly trying to negotiate increased economic, ecological and political rights. The Buryat national movement, represented in part by the newspaper Tolon (Sunrise), is strong and thus far not radical, with an educated liberal intelligentsia whose roots go back to pre-revolutionary times and a massive popular following. Buryat political and cultural revival has included overtures to Mongolia and a resurgence of Buddhism, publicized by a ceremonial visit of the Dalai Lama to Ulan-Ude in July 1991.(6) The Yakut-Sakha Republic, declaring sovereignty in 1990, simultaneously signalled willingness to compromise with Russia by hyphenating their name. "Yakut" is an outsider's (Russian) name for the Sakha, who speak the farthest North Turkic language, and are neither Islamic nor Russian Orthodox. A cultural and spiritual revival that began before the Gorbachev era has led to resurgence of traditional religion and to rebirth of the Sakha language and literature. Although the Sakha occupy Siberian territory four times the size of Texas, they numbered only 381,922 in 1989, and were 33 percent of their republic population. While they too claim land (reaching to the Sea of Okhotsk) stolen from them under Stalin, this has not been the focus of ethnic politics. Rather, since 1990, a group called Sakha Omuk (the Sakha People) has led cultural, ecological and, especially, economic rights campaigns. Many Sakha, including republic president Nikolaev, reason that even if they had direct control of a mere 30 percent of their natural resources (oil, gas, gold and diamonds in abundance), they would be rich, and in a position to align themselves with Japanese, Korean and Western businessmen. Negotiations are proceeding, both with Yel'tsin's Moscow and foreign businesses. Leery of Russian-led secessionist Siberian regionalisms (which currently divide into at least three geographical parts), Sakha leaders, some from the pragmatic, reformist former communist party elite, are trying to navigate on the thin ice of Moscow and local Russian rule.(7) In sum, political and population dislocations produced by increasing nationalisms have been considerable and painful, in both union and autonomous republics. The flow of refugees from war zones into Russia, estimated at over 1 million by 1992, creates yet another tragic pull on resources stretched thin. Yet analysts must not jump to conclusions that most of the 25 million Russians living outside Russia will want to move back to its heartland, nor that most refugees are Russian. Many refugees from violence in Central Asia and the Caucasus are non-Russians (e.g., Mesketian Turks, Greeks, Armenians, Azerbaijanis), who sometimes move to non-Russian areas (e.g., Kazakhstan) before choosing Russia. Within Russia, Russian outflow from Tuva has been the most dramatic. Several thousand Slavic peoples also have been fleeing Chechen-Ingushetia, including some Cossacks whose houses have been raided. The Slavic majority in Tatarstan, Buryatia and Yakutia has been shrinking more slowly, especially through decline of in-migration. Estimates of refugee populations in the whole of the post-Soviet deconstructivist world vary widely (from 1-7 million), and require regional and comparative analysis.(8) In most areas of Russia, non-Russian populations, who together number over 30 million, have moved in the past decade from mildly politicized ethnic consciousness to various forms of nationalism. But this hardly means each of the over 16 autonomous republics (depending on how unilateral claims are counted) is demanding the same degree of secession as Chechen, Tatars and Tuvans. Many want better deals with Moscow, and are negotiating with Yel'tsin from an unaccustomed position of relative strength. How the Russian parliament and Yel'tsin, whose learning curve has thus far been dramatic, manage the details of this messy internal process of genuine economic and political power sharing will make an enormous difference in the transformation of Russia from a miniempire to a relatively democratic, perhaps smaller, federal state. RUSSIAN FEDERATION "Autonomous Formations" "Autonomous Republics" (Have Asserted Independence) Tatarstan* (Tatar Republic) Buryatia* (Buryat Republic) Yakut-Sakha* (Yakut Republic) Chechen-Ingushetia* (Chechen-Ingush Republic) Tuvan Republic* Kalmyk Republic Other "Autonomous Republics" Kabardino-Balkar Republic Severo-Osetin Republic Dagestan Mordov Republic Chuvash Republic Mari Republic Udmurt Republic Karel' Republic Komi Republic Other "Formations" Adygei Region Gorno-Altai Region Karachai-Cherkess Region Khakass Region Aginsk Buryat Region Evrei Region Komi-Permyatsk Region Koryak District Nenetsk District Taimyr District Ust'-Ordyn Buryat District Khanti-Mansiy District Chukot District Evenki District Yamalo-Nenetsk District Bashkortostan (Bashkir Republic) *Discussed in this article Notes: 1Statistics here and below are from Natsional'ny Sostav Naseleniya SSR Moskva: Finansy i Statistika, 1991. Data and analysis are based in part on fieldwork, June-August 1991. See also Alexander Nekrich, The Punished Peoples (New York: Norton, 1978). 2 Ann Sheehy, "Power Struggle in Checheno-Ingushetia," RL/RFE Report on the USSR, November 15, 1991, pp. 20-26; Center for Democracy in the USSR Bulletin, 004, January 14, 1991; D. Mirzoev, "Dzhokhar Musaevich Dudaev," Argumenty i Fakty, 44, 1991, p. 8. 3 For example, "Tatarstan: Burlit Ploshchad' Svoboda," Pravda, October 17, 1991, p. 1. See also A. Zyubchenko et al., "O tak nazyvaemoi sultan-galievskoi kontrrevolyutsionnoi organizatsii" Izvestia TsK KPSS, No. 10, 1990, pp. 75-88; Azade-Ayse Rorlich, The Volga Tatars: A Profile in National Resilience (Stanford: Hoover, 1987). 4"Tatarstan Announces Joining Commonwealth," Moscow Radio, FBIS, December 31, 1991, p. 50. 5 Ann Sheehy, "Russians the Target of Interethnic Violence in Tuva," RL/RFE Report on the USSR, September 14, 1990, pp. 1317; M. Ya. Zhornitskaya "Natsional'naya situatsiya v Tuvinskoi ASSR i Khakasskoi AO," Institute of Ethnology and Anthropology, 1990 MS. 6 Vladimir Kornev, "Poznavaya vselenniyu: k 250 letiyu buddizma," Soyuz, No. 30, July 1991, p. 14; Urbanaeva, I. S. et al., Natsional'ny Vopros v Buryatii, Ulan-Ude: A.N., 1989. See also Caroline Humphrey, Karl Marx Collective: Economy, Society and Religion in a Siberian Collective Farm (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983). 7 "Deklaratsiya," Sotsialisticheskaya Yakutiya, September 28, 1990, p. 1; "Ustav Sakha Omuka," August 10, 1990, MS.; interviews with Sakha leaders, June-July 1991. 8 P. Rudeev, interview, Ekonomika i Zhizn', 26 June 1991, p. 10; L. Krasnovsky, "Russkie bezhentsy v Rossii," Narodnoe Obrazovanie, August 1990, pp. 21-23; Murray Feshbach, "Soviet Population Movements: Internal, External and Nowhere," Oxford Analytica, 1991, MS.; Klaus Segbers, "Migration and Refugee Movements from the USSR: Causes and Prospects," RL/RFE Report on the USSR, November 15, 1991, pp. 6-14. Russian Federalism: Looking Forward from Today by Rashid Noureev The Russian State, for different reasons, throughout its history was traditionally oriented towards the goals of external policy (in struggle with Asian nomads, expansion of its territories, active participation in European conflicts, in attempts of building a worldwide "system of socialism"). Therefore the internal structure of power and social relationships was built in such a way, so that the state could activate huge human masses and resources for achievement of some titanic goal in short period of time. Only by the end of the XX century a fragile hope is being born that Man, his Rights and Freedom will become the supreme value of the Russian state. Formally, Russia becomes a federal republic since the formation of the Soviet Union in 1918-1922. At that time main structural contradictions of the system were already present. These contradictions lead to the fall of gigantic empire, and to the fire of national conflicts on all post-Soviet territory nowadays (Abkhasia, Chechnya, Nagorny Karabach, Pridnestrovye, Tajikistan, and many others). Bolshevics built the state on the national territory basis in order to strengthen a weak, growing state. That meant that a territory (state) of an ethnic group became a subject of the new Federation. This principle was pursued and made absurd in the slogan "right of nation to secession", which was successfully realized in later time. In 1970's in so called Soviet republics emerged new national elites. Gradually they seized all the middle range positions in local command administrative system of the totalitarian state. On a certain stage of social and economical development (1970-80) administrative position was regarded by the officer as his private property, be it a position in executive power institution, or administration of a large industrial enterprise. The desire of regional elite leaders to make their present status lawful forced them to use ethnocratic rhetorics to justify their participation in the destruction of USSR. These reason lead to the fact that Russia did not choose new model of federalism on the basis of rationality, based on desire to harmonize the relations of society and state on liberal and democratic principles. The process of federalization in Russia was a legal form of struggle for redistribution of power and economical resources between central and regional elites. The Federation Treaty of 1992 is the best evidence of that process. The Treaty states that subjects of Russian Federation have different status and competence to the benefit of those national republics that threatened to break away if their claims were not satisfied. Thus, the Federation Treaty was rather a political effort to cope with growing disintegration trends, than a result of a biased lawful agreement between the Federal center and the subjects. The problems are not completely solved in the Constitution of Russian Federation, accepted by national referendum, in which three principles of federation construction are stated: national state, national region and administrative region. The Constitution (article 5) states the following principles of federalism: state integrity, unity of government system, limitation of subjects of competence and powers between the federal and regional governments, equality of subjects of federation in their relationships with federal center, equality of rights for all the nations in Russian Federation. The Constitution of Russian Federation numbers the areas of social relationships that are subject of competence of federal government, and also those, that are subject of competence of both federal and regional governments. All the other issues, that are not mentioned in the document are the exclusive subject of competence of regional governments. The Federal Constitution admits composition of federal laws and agreements in limitation of subjects of competence on different levels of power. However, neither the law, nor the Constitution solve the problem of correlation between these two norms. Most of federation subjects signed such an agreement with the federal center, which contents do not correspond with, and in some cases directly contradicts the Constitution. The federal center in its attempts to keep its authority and loyalty of regional governors has given more power to some regions, to the losses of the other. It can be stated, that in contemporary Russia constitutional norms are being replaced by the right of agreement. In the field of taxation and economic policy vertical relationships are preserved.. Federal taxes prevail in the budget incomes on all levels. Most tax rate limits and tax collection bases are regulated by the federal laws. The budget system on different levels is somewhat contradictory. The issue of property on land and other resources is not solved, same as the issue of strict definition of rights and responsibilities in the usage of public property objects, and so on. Still, despite all the problems, we hope, that by the common efforts of politicians and experts there will be developed a holistic conception of federative reform in Russia, that would include not only concrete measures in some field of social relationships (legislation, economy, national relationships), but would also aim to change the mere political and law culture of Russian citizens. SOME FEDERALISM FEATURES AND PROBLEMS RUSSIA IS FACING TODAY by Tatiana Vinogradova (tatiana@strateg.spb.su) Director Economic Development Department St.Petersburg Center of Humanities and Political Studies “Strategy”, Russia Federalism in Russia is unique in many aspects. It is hard to find analogues to it in history and modern world. The attempts to copy experience of USA, Germany and other states were not successful, as did not correspond with Russia’s realities. Asymmetry, which exists in constitutional statements on federal organization of Russia, reflects the complexity and the past of the country. Russian Federation includes 89 subjects of Federation - republics, regions (“oblasts”), lands, cities of federal meaning (Moscow and St.Petersburg), autonomous regions and autonomous districts. Republic is a national state within the Russian Federation; oblast and land is an administrative-territorial or state-territorial formation; autonomous region and district - administrative-national formation; city of federal meaning is a populated area. Republics within Russian Federations announced their sovereignty, and these principle statements recognized by the Federal Agreement, declared in Constitutions of republics and other documents. In early 90s oblasts, lands and largest cities, proceeding from their economic potential, number of population and dimensions of territory, required to widen their rights (particularly in economy field), at least to equalize them with republics rights. The drive to change the status and get more independence was usual to autonomous regions and districts as well. The Constitution (1993) defined the composition of Federation and the most important organizational principles, but did not complete the formation process. We may consider Russian Federation has not an agreemental origins but constitutionalagreemental, which juridical base consists of Constitution and Federal Agreement. But Constitution and the method of its adoption partly disavowed Agreement, deprived its participants of corresponding status. For instance, it does not consider the subjects of Federation in the capacity of sovereign states, but define the objects of joint competence. The rest objects of competence are left to subjects of Federation (distribution of competence repeated the Federal Agreement). If the statements of Federal Agreement or agreements between subjects contradict the Constitution, then its statements act. We should notice here, that the issues of legislation process are not well regulated, especially in the field of joint competence. Is it possible for federal legislator to regulate everything detailed? What should the regional legislator do when on important issue for his region the federal law has not been yet adopted? The majority of regions chose the way of adoptions of their own regulations with a perspective to make them later corresponding with federal, but how does this practice correspond with Constitution and real federalism? At last, there are no acting mechanisms of Constitution defense from breaking it by regional legislators (i.e. many regional regulations, limiting movements of capital and goods). As far as almost three forth of subjects of Federation do not possess the status of state within Russia, and 32 of subjects are formed on the ethnical base, Russia, announced a federal formation, maintain not a little amount of constructions, habitual to unitary state. Many politicians because of a fact that the spontaneous economic reform in Russia continues not decreasing inequality of regions but on the opposite now there are very essential differences in regional financial resources excuse this. On the other side (as shows Prof. Leorkadia Drobizgeva, Institute of Ethnology and Anthropology of Russia Academy of Science), the idea of sovereignty of national republics as well as many other regions is supported of majority of native inhabitants and not only of local elite but nine tenth of respondents does not connect the idea of sovereignty with separation from Russia. From the juridical point of view the paradoxical thing would be the sovereign states which are included in the other sovereign subjects of Federation - autonomous regions and national districts within lands and oblasts. The main way of competence distribution in the situation of absence of clear legislation remains the “beating them out” of the federal center, including the personal meetings with President of Russian Federation. However rights received in this manner concern the separate issues, they do not solve problem in complex, on the opposite, make situation more mixed. The analysts see danger for Russia and its peoples in remaining this model. The present political sympathies or antipathies may damage enormously the economic development and neighborly relations of peoples in the country. It is necessary for Russian Federation qualitatively different approach to the distribution of competence between Federation, its subjects and local government. MARKING OFF THE RIGHTS OF CENTER AND REGIONS SOLVING ONE OF THE KEY PROBLEMS OF RUSSIAN FEDERALISM by Evgeny Zakablukovsky (mail@eugenezak.com) Assistant to the Speaker Nizhny Novgorod Legislative Assembly, Russia One of the main federalism development problems in the Russian Federation is the distinction of control matters and authority between the Federation and its subjects (republics, regions, autonomies). The history of our country has shown that, with the exception of autonomies which had special rights regarding language and national culture, Russia has been created and developed as a centralized unitary state. The Declaration of State Sovereignty, passed on June 12, 1990 as well as the Federative Treaty, concluded in 1992, have not only formally but also de- facto confirmed Russian political system developing according to the tenets of sovereign nationhood. The new Russia announced the federative state structure in the Constitution of the Russian Federation, passed by the plebiscite on December 12, 1993. Articles 71 and 72 of the Russian Constitution determine the exclusive control matters of the Federation and the matters under the joint supervision of the Federation and its subjects. However, it remained indefinite, how to mark off those matters, what would be the demarcating tools. It could be expected that right after the Constitution a special act would be written which would have established the above principles and the order of their implementation. However, there was no such act hitherto. In 1994, two treaties were signed which specified a variety of issues regarding the relations between the central power and subjects of the Federation, in particular, the republics. These are treaties of the Federation with Tatarstan (October 15, 1994) and Bashkortostan (August 3, 1994). Other treaties followed immediately, for example such a document was signed with Nizhny Novgorod oblast (region) on June 8, 1996. Having become quite brisk, the practice of concluding treaties and agreements between governing institutions of the center and the subjects of the Federation produced vivid debates on whether our country is just a constitutional federation or a federation of the mixed constitutional and treaty kind. Or: what to do if such a treaty contains provisions contrary to those of the Russian Constitution. Many of the vexed problems go back to the events in the Chechnya area. Concluding treaties on power delegation actually is not a feature 'sine qua non' of the Russian federalism development. At the same time, it may be considered necessary and useful. Such treaties are to supplement and develop the provisions vested in the Constitution, especially in cases when specific issues remain unsolved, e.g. which matters must be controlled by the center and which by a subject of the Federation. The concept of the joint control implies that both the center and a subject of the Federation should know their regulation limits. The need for agreement can also emerge when a subject of the Federation has particular natural, national, geographic and other conditions. However, all treaties should be in congruence with the Constitution of the Russian Federation. All aforesaid allows to define the Russian Federation as constitutional. The treaty with Tatarstan stands somewhat apart but this is rather an exception from the general rule. It is hard, if even possible, to find something analogous to the Russian federalism, both in the history and among the modern state models. It does not resolve itself to the nation-state structure, what the Soviet model was like; at the same time it did not take the path of just a territorial structure, the latter common to most foreign countries. Smooth theoretical concepts, even being attractive externally, similar to the structures already approved in the West could not eliminate, not even soften the complex and contradictory processes generating crises and destabilizing Russian state structure. Russian historical traditions, its population structure and huge territory, the mentality of the nations and its geopolitical position are too essential for this country. It was necessary to build federalism in a country where the relevant parameters of the state constituents differ from each other: such as economic development, social characteristics, scientific, educational as well as cultural formation. There are 89 subjects of the Federation with more than 150 nationalities in this country. The situation in which two sovereignties are combined within a framework of one state, when the sovereignty of a federative state encompasses, covers the sovereignty of its republics, contributes to already quite a sophisticated design. The federal act "On principles and order of distinction of control matters and authorities between governing institutions of the Russian Federation and governing institutions of the subjects of the Russian Federation" came into force on July 24, 1999. This act has got across the forms of implementation of such authorities as well as across adoption order for the federal acts regulating matters under the joint supervision of the center and the subjects of the Russian Federation. The order of conclusion of the treaties and agreements between them was also established. This document grants the right to the subjects of the Federation, when federal acts are being prepared, to influence the concept of such an act on the very first stage - by sending regional representatives (with the right of advisory vote) to the applicable committees and commissions of the Lower House of the Parliament - the State Duma. The controversies on the control matters' distinction and the delegation of authorities will be now resolved by the parties concerned during negotiations with using diverse conciliation procedures. Prior to this act, the President could have signed a treaty with a governor or a chief of republic, and the agreement was sometimes not even published in the newspapers; now all the treaties may be signed only after having passed them through the regional Legislative Assembly and through the Upper House of the Federal Parliament - the Federation Council. The law also requires that all the branches of the state power key their legal acts according to the above Act within the period of six months. The treaties and agreements operating presently at the territory of the Russian Federation are also to be keyed according to the federal Act and the Constitution of the Russian Federation within a period of three years. The subjects of the Russian Federation should do the same with their acts within a period of one year. As already was said, the federative structure of the Russian Federation is asymmetrical, i.e. its subjects are not uniform, thus having their particular problems. The solutions are also sometimes unique. However, the ways in which the solutions are made should be legally clear. The above mentioned Act has to determine this order, in exact conformity with provisions of the Constitution of the Russian Federation. Facts on Federalism Federalism is based on (1) the dissolution of empires, (2) regional variation and (3) ease of administration. Examples of the dissolution of empires are the British empire in North America in 1776, the Russian empire in 1917, the USSR in 1991,the German Empire in 1918, the Nazi "empire" in 1945 and Yugoslavia and Bosnia in the present. Examples of regional variation are Switzerland, Canada, the USSR and Russia. As to ease of administration, even unitary states like France and England are divided into departments or counties. Constitutional basis of the US federal system is Article IV (admission of new states), Article VI (national government supremacy), Amendment X (reserved powers) and Amendment XIV (national control of state action). The "enumerated powers" in Article I, Section 8, list the specific powers of the national government. While these are supposedly the only powers it has, in fact the commerce and "elastic" clauses have permitted great enlargement. National laws that form the basis of the federal system include the laws admitting new states into the union. Since Tennessee, 16th state, Congress has used the phrase that the new state is admitted on an "equal footing" as the other states. A number of specific laws define the federal relationship. Major examples are the decentralized programs like welfare, employment services and environmental protection. Grant program are a major factor in the federal system. Since 1862 the national government has given grants for "land grant" colleges, highways, welfare (but not social security old age pensions), environmental protection, Model Cities, and revenue sharing. The grant authority is based on exchange, not on the Constitution. If a state does not like the terms, it should refuse the money. Interstate relations within the United States are handled much like foreign affairs. States can negotiate and enter into treaties with other states. A historically important example is the treaty negotiated in 1785 between Maryland and Virginia on use of the Chesapeake Bay. Sometimes the states negotiate under the provisions of a national law. The interstate compact on low level radioactive waste that led to the tentative selection of Riga Township for a possible site for disposal was in this category. Because Michigan failed to find a site, it was expelled and the responsibility now belongs to Ohio. Another example of an interstate treaty is the Port Authority of New York and New Jersey. The relationship between the state and local government is not a true example of federalism. States have total authority to create, modify and abolish counties and municipalities. The relationship is referred to as the "federal analogy." In the United States the word "federal" also means the national government as in the Federal Bureau of Investigation. As a means of emphasizing the word to mean the relationship, for the ten weeks of the term, use the word federal exclusively for the system, not for the government in Washington. Refer to that as the national government or as US for an adjective. "Federalization" Beth Mitchneck, University of Arizona Steven L. Solnick, Columbia University Kathryn Stoner-Weiss, Princeton University Prepared for the Kennan Institute Workshop on Russia’s Regions. Washington, D.C., August 1999 Russia offers a rare opportunity to examine the political and economic consequences of decentralization in large states. One of the striking aspects of Russia’s decentralization is its pace. Only ten years ago, the Russian provinces were almost totally under the control of Moscow; even trade between provinces was almost completely controlled by bureaucrats in central ministries. Regional leaders were dependent on central institutions for their authority (especially the centralized apparatus of the Communist Party), and even trains across all eleven time zones ran on Moscow time. Today, while not a textbook federation in practice, Russia has moved far from the unitary legacy of the Soviet Union. In contrast to the Soviet system, in which all political and economic decisions at the subnational level were controlled and monitored by Moscow, many of post-Soviet Russia’s 89 regional governments have taken the initiative in determining the distribution of power across the Russian federation and in extending power beyond that legislated by the center. Regional and urban governments are now comprised of popularly elected executives and legislatures. They enjoy considerable latitude in many areas of personnel administration, operate relatively autonomously in policy areas such as social protection, education, and (with certain constraints) municipal administration. In addition, they have been able to exert considerable influence over regional financial and industrial organization, especially in setting the pace of regional privatization and restructuring. The federal government, for its part, has preserved a unified judiciary, defense structure, monetary system, and tax administration. In many areas, such as fiscal policy and regulation of trade, the division of responsibility between the center and regions remains murky and contested. Decentralization, in some cases, has extended from the federal or regional level down to the municipal or district level. To understand the role and significance of political end economic decentralization within the Russian federal structure, we examine the consequences of such decentralization. In doing so, we will consider both political and economic factors. By examining the actual and perceived consequences of structures that devolve power to the sub-national level, we hope to better understand how institutions governing central-local relations in Russia function, and how institutional alternatives might emerge from the intersection of political and economic cross-pressures. Our paper proceeds as follows. We first examine the political and economic benefits and pitfalls of decentralization discussed in the broader literatures of political science, economics, and political geography. We then turn to the Russian case, and ask whether the particular configuration of institutions we encounter there has yielded the consequences predicted by theory. This section consists of three parts, by each of the co-authors, illustrating different approaches to understanding the Russian experience with decentralization. A fourth section will provide some initial conclusions regarding the extent to which the data indicate Russia is reaping the benefits of decentralization. I. Why Decentralize: Theoretical Expectations This section considers economic and political theories of decentralization, with particular attention to theoretical predictions about the consequences of devolution of power. I.a. The economic case for decentralization. There is a wide range of efficiency-based arguments for decentralization within government structure. Tiebout for instance, and those who followed his lead argued that in the absence of barriers to mobility of population, decentralization can stimulate forces in government analogous to market forces in the economy. Individuals "vote with their feet" and are able to move to jurisdictions that provide the public goods they most desire. Homogeneous subpopulations could emerge from within large heterogeneous populations. In effect, such decentralization makes it possible to cater to regionally diverse tastes, to take advantage of geographic specialization, and to deliver more efficient government performance. In addition to the tonic effects of competition among jurisdictions, decentralization lowers information barriers, thereby making it easier for policy makers to perceive the demands and tastes of constituents, and rendering smallscale policy "experimentation" more feasible as a purely practical matter. By a similar logic, Barry Weingast and others have argued that devolving control over regional economic policies, while maintaining centralized control over enforcement of property rights and free movement of factors across internal borders, can deliver important benefits for economic performance. Weingast has classified these virtuous institutions as a special sub-category of federalism: market-preserving. For Weingast, as in Tiebout’s scheme, decentralization allows citizens to benefit from competition among sub-national governments in the same way they benefit from competing economic producers in the marketplace. There are, however, analogous economic arguments for centralization. Certain public goods--like a monetary system or navy, for instance--exhibit powerfully increasing economies of scale. Some public goods are best provided on a large scale. More vexing are the distributional consequences of decentralization. As Coase demonstrated, the efficient provision of public goods through market mechanisms depends critically on the absence of transaction costs. Where transaction costs are significant--as they are in the real world, optimal equilibria may be unattainable, and all outcomes have important distributional implications. Thus, allowing regional governments to set social protection policies could result in some citizens being over-supplied while others in a different territory are under-supplied (as some of our evidence from Russia indicates). Since both citizens belong to the same national jurisdiction, such an outcome creates divisive sources of inequality and social stratification. Centralization could therefore be advocated as a means of restoring some standards of equity to this situation. A related argument in favor of centralization stems from problems of externalities across jurisdictions. Since citizens might be expected to flock to a region offering high levels of social welfare, regions may engage in under-bidding to discourage an influx of benefitsseekers. This could trigger a "race to the bottom" among states, leading to the underprovision of public goods on a national scale. Such fears have been cited in the American context as justification for federal re-assertion of control over welfare policy, minimum-wage, and corporate regulation, though empirical validity of the "race to the bottom" model is far from clear. I.b. Political arguments for decentralization Efficiency gains and economic growth are only one set of objectives that could drive governmental decentralization. Often, devolution of political and economic power is driven by more purely political motives. For instance, creating smaller electoral units as the building blocks of a republic can enhance democratic accountability by magnifying the influence of citizens’ votes for regional officials. Thus, citizens can more closely monitor and better evaluate the performance of local officials--in part they can better evaluate the quality of local government services and their interests are more likely to be homogeneous. Conversely, local representatives should be expected to be more responsive to the needs and demands of local constituencies, in part because informational problems are less acute on the smaller scale. Finally, political decentralization in a democracy can also help to train local leaders and enhance civic consciousness. In diverse societies, decentralization offers another important potential benefit. By devolving authority over clusters of policy issues, national officials may be able to achieve and sustain ethnic peace by eliminating direct arenas of policy conflict. While in these societies, decentralization is a means of avoiding catastrophe rather than of stimulating growth, many underlying assumptions in the federalist literature are that polities that manage to achieve unity in the face of diversity are also poised to reap positive economic or social gains. There are, therefore, benefits to hanging together beyond the minimal standard of avoidance of disaster. In spite of this long list of purported benefits from decentralization, there are also political arguments for centralization. Decentralized polities multiply the opportunities for graft, corruption and rent-seeking. Decentralized structures create institutional mechanisms that may lock-in pork-barrel politics as a costly norm. With a proliferation of lower-level jurisdictions, capital investments can easily become the price of political support, divorced from any rational long-range investment plan on a national scale. As a consequence, many theorists of development in the 1980s argued for centralizing economic policy making in developing states to remove it from the politicized influence of local and regional interests (as well as national lobbies). II. State Structure and the Impact of Economic and Political Decentralization How can we begin to understand the nature of decentralization in Russia and assess whether decentralization in Russia is producing tangible economic and political benefits, or pressures for recentralization? The preceding discussion of federalism and decentralization in capitalist democracies highlights several implications for the utility of those theories for the transition context and for analysis of the emerging Russian federal structure. We also must consider how applicable these theories are for our particular context. In other words, what are the effects of the context-specific conditions in Russia? The economic arguments for decentralization assume free factor mobility across space (of both population and goods). We know that this condition does not exist in Russia either in theory or reality. Many jurisdictions maintain barriers to free mobility. Additional constraints include underdeveloped (and in some cases non-existent) housing markets, high rates of unemployment and underemployment, and poor information flows. These conditions suggest that the economic arguments for decentralization hold little salience for our case. On the other hand, if local and regional policymakers do respond to local conditions and tastes in ways that enhance economic welfare, then decentralization may be producing economic benefits through some other mechanism, not well captured in current theories. In Russia, decentralization and centralization occur almost simultaneously. De facto decentralization is one consequence of the weakening of the Russian central state in the wake of the Soviet collapse. Within this context, neither centralization nor decentralization can deliver the banafits anticipated by theory without regional and central governments coordinating their expectations on the division of jurisdictions? Conflict over the scope of responsibilities of each level of government may erode support for federal structure, since it denies the benefits of either devolution or of strong central policy making. Theory also suggests that strong economic performance should be linked with a clear property rights regime enforced by the center, and unambiguous devolution of economic regulatory powers to the region. Though the model of "market-preserving federalism" would require these conditions to hold across the entire federation, we should still see some marginal gains in economic performance in those regions where these conditions are more closely met. Theory then predicts that aggregate regional economic performance would improve in some regions. Theory also suggests that an important political benefit of central intervention in economic policy making is the possibility of restoring some measure of equity among regions. Favoritism of certain regions would undermine the "market-forces" that theoretically drive federal polities toward greater economic efficiency, and would also undermine any political benefits driving from more responsive regional representation. In addition, any difference in treatment between ethnically defined regions could erode the "ethnic peace" presumably supported by federal institutions. We need to ask, therefore, whether decentralization in Russia has been accompanied by a rise or fall in favoritism in the treatment of privileged regions. If they do favoritism has fallen, then we should expect to see improved aggregate regional economic performance and some measure of equitable regional social policy. If, however, favoritism is on the rise, then our task is to explain the variation and impact across space. III. Russia’s Decentralization: Alternative Perspectives In this section, we consider three perspectives on the impact of decentralization on Russian political and economic dynamics. We hope these capsule analyses will help us better understand whether the political and economic benefits of decentralization are being reaped in Russia today and whether, in turn, we might expect to see the emergence of constituencies for greater devolution or a return to centralization. In the first part of this section, Mitchneck looks at how the urban and regional governments perceive interactions with federal authorities and suggests that decentralization has not disempowered federal authorities in local politics but modified the nature of participation in local affairs. In part two of this section, Stoner-Weiss analyzes the extent to which de facto authority has devolved to the subnational level in Russia. The evidence here indicates that some tangible economic benefits have flowed to some regions from this process. Despite this, the central government’s marked inability in many instances to enforce national policy at the local level undermines the full realization of the economic and political benefits that might otherwise come from a truly federal structure. In the third part of this section, Solnick examines whether or not and why certain regions enjoy benefits in their relationships with the federal government. III. a. The View From The Regional And Urban Governments Since the break up of the former Soviet Union, the distribution of power between levels of government has fluctuated. In the absence of a highly centralized system, the new federal structure, however, has by necessity begun to use a variety of measures, including new fiscal ones, to influence local politics. Within the context of decentralized government and variable power relations between the local and central government, local governments for their part have also begun to use a variety of measures to govern. How do local (regional and urban) government actors view the role of the federal government for the determination of local policy priorities and then the implementation of policy measures and strategies? Has the system decentralized to the degree that the federal government has become irrelevant to local governance? Do local government actors view the federal role as one of partner or adversary? An argument against decentralization is that the federal level loses the ability to directly influence actions at the subnational level. That is, the local level will not respond to federal level stimuli. Many have suggested that this has occurred in Russia. In fact, the discourse in the middle 1990s consisted of the necessity of constructing mechanisms to insure compliance with federal policies (e.g., the placement of presidential representatives in Russian regions). The discourse further suggested that those runaway Russian regions did not respond to federal policy objectives and thus recentralization was necessary. Evidence presented below from a 1997 survey of close to 700 regional and urban policy makers in seventy regions suggests that the opposite has occurred. In the perception of urban, oblast, and republic policy makers, legislators and executive bureaucrats (hereafter referred to as local policy makers), federal level stimuli strongly influence the way that local policy makers identify policy priorities. In fact, federal level stimuli are as important as place-specific economic conditions. Furthermore, local actors view the participation of federal level actors as an essential component of carrying out local policies. The respondents viewed fiscal measures and partnerships between central and local authorities as highly important means of influencing and participating in local politics. Whether the results of such interactions include following national policy and improving the national economy is debatable. III.a.i. Federal Influence Over Local Policy Priorities The survey examined two main explanations for the variation of local policy that include the role of the federal level of government, the economic structure thesis and urban regime theory. The economic structure thesis maintains that local policies are constructed in order to respond to local demographic and economic conditions and thus vary according to those conditions. The federal level can influence those conditions through its own policies. Urban regime theory, on the other hand, suggests that local policies vary because of the motivations of and relationships between politicians, business people, and community leaders. The survey incorporated these approaches by including three sections where respondents were asked to evaluate the importance of a variety of potential influences over the determination of local priorities: (1) demographic and economic conditions, (2) political relations within the government structure, and (3) individual participants both within and outside of government. We used a five point scale where five indicated the most important and 1 the least. We then calculated mean scores and compared them over government branch (executive and representative), government scale (regional and urban; oblast/kray and republic), length of time in government (holdovers from the Soviet period or new entrants during the post-Soviet period). We also compared mean scores over broad regions. Respondents consistently rated the influence of the federal level among the most important influences over the determination of policy priorities - in fact, greater than actual local demographic and economic conditions. Respondents were given a list of demographic and economic factors that may influence their determination of policy priorities. While demographic factors were not cited as important influences over the formulation of policy priorities, economic ones were (see Table 1). Displaying amazing consistency over branch, scale, and length of service, policy makers cited federal tax rates as the most important influence over their choice of policy priorities. Unemployment, inflation, bank credit rates, and a desire to maintain previous economic structure were also highly rated but not as highly as federal tax rates. The strong weighting given to federal tax rates suggests that the federal level can and does influence local policies using fiscal means. Despite fiscal decentralization, the federal government maintained a relatively strong influence in the local arena using economic measures. As urban regime theory suggests, local policy makers rate political relations as the most influential group of factors (see Table 2). While political relations within the regional environment appear most important to the determination of local policy priorities, respondents highly rated federal political influence in the local arena. Local policy makers consistently rated the influence of federal laws and presidential decrees and federal financing rated among the highest in influence for all respondents (4.2 and 4.1 respectively). Respondents, however, gave the presidential representative the lowest rating within this category of factors (2.7). The distinction between the federal influences suggests that direct political interference by federal agents in local affairs is less influential than federal decrees or fiscal measures. Urban regime theory also suggests that a variety of social and economic actors outside of local government institutions influence the determination of policy priorities. Russian local policy makers, however, view the identification of policy priorities as a government centered process without broad participation by social actors. While the respondents clearly view political relations as the most important set of factors, political participants are important, perhaps less so than economic conditions. When asked about the influence of particular participants in the policy making process, the respondents are once again fairly consistent in their ratings. Respondents rated the influence of federal authorities among the most important (3.7) with local self-government and local and regional business circles as the other two most important influence (3.9 and 3.4 respectively) (see Table 3). The press certainly deserves honorable mention as many respondents view its role as having the same importance as that of local and business circles (3.3). The respondents remained consistent with the view that the presidential representative was not an influential part of the policy making process by rating this participant among the lowest in importance (2.4). Only social actors (labor unions, the church, and other social organizations) rate lower or at the same level as the presidential representative. The evidence suggests that local policymakers do have a strong role to play in local politics. Local policy makers, however, voice a somewhat different view of the role federal authorities should play in a purely local issue like land use policy. When respondents were asked their view of whose voice should be decisive in determining land use policies, federal authorities ranked a distant third or fourth behind urban authorities and residents (Table 4). III.a.ii. Federal Influence Over Local Policy Implementation I suggest above that local policy makers consider the federal level as very influential in determining local priorities and that policy making is a government centered process. Additional evidence from the survey suggests that policy implementation is also government centered with respect to both the measures used and the participants; however, policy implementation is closely connected with the business community not with the broader community of local population. The local policy makers appear to hold the view that the central-local and business-government relationships are ones rooted in partnership. Imbalances in those partnerships undoubtedly exist. Respondents were asked to identify which policy instruments and strategies they use and which are most successful for local policy implementation. We then asked with whom they worked most successfully on policy implementation. Local policymakers use fiscal strategies and partnerships between government levels and private business most often (see Table 5). Despite the fact that two-thirds of the respondents noted that they use federal partnerships, very few believe federal partnerships are one of three most useful strategies. The same policy makers though cited federal authorities as one of three most successful participants in policy implementation (see Table 6). The apparent contradiction actually underscores the importance of working in partnership with federal authorities and working with them in indirect ways, perhaps as facilitators rather than controllers. It also underscores the importance of individual interactions over institutional. When asked about the three most successful participants in policy implementation, local policy makers overwhelmingly noted the importance of local business and regional government actors (see Table 6). Next in importance came federal authorities and the mass media. Again, the responses are highly consistent across categories of respondents. Respondents from republics, however, gave very different responses to the question of participation in policy implementation. Republic level respondents cited higher successful participation for the federal level and lower successful participation for local business than did the urban and oblast respondents. The variation across government scale with respect to successful cooperation in the policy arena underscores that the federal level’s influence is not the same across the country. III.a.iii. Summary and Conclusion In local policy makers’ views, neither federal laws nor authorities have become irrelevant to urban and regional policymaking. The strong consistency over government branch, scale, and region suggest that within Russian federalism, the central government remains one of the most important players. Despite decentralization, federal laws, decrees, and tax regimes are among the most important factors stimulating and directing local policy choices. We know that those choices are not always the most efficient ones (see next section). But the dominance of federal influences over local economic and social ones has several implications. First, the theory that competition among jurisdictions produces economic efficiency and regionally appropriate bundles of provision of public goods and services should receive serious skepticism in the Russian case. Also supporting the lack of relevance of the Tiebout thesis is the configuration of important individual and public participants in shaping local policy agendas and in implementing policy. The evidence from the survey indicates that local policy makers rely most on local business interests and federal authorities to shape agendas and carry out policies. Public preferences then are dependent on a nonlocal group and on a group whose individual interests may diverge radically from that of the general population. As stated previously, decisions that produce aggregate gains in regional economic performance may not produce concomitant gains in social welfare. Has the post-Soviet federalism reproduced the Soviet patterns of non-local interference and dominance? Not at all. Fiscal influence has replaced the directives in the command economy. The minor importance given to the presidential representative highlights the diminished importance of central directives in the local arena. The direct interference of Soviet central authorities appears to have given way to a combination of partnerships with the federal authorities or the complete lack of assistance on the part of federal authorities (see section III.b.). The switch to partnerships, however, brings up the critical issue of asymmetry in the political and economic relationship between the federal and regional governments (see section III.c. for a discussion of the implications). The dominance of the local business community in both influencing priorities and carrying out objectives also distinguishes the new from the old system. One could venture that business leaders have replaced central ones in the primary influence over local politics. III.b. The De Facto Devolution of Power in Russia The previous section presented evidence indicating that the federal government plays a strong role in Russia in determining local and regional policy priorities. This section looks more deeply into the concrete relationships between federal and regional policy actors. Like the previous section, this section illustrates the point that although the central government plays a role in policy formation, other actors (regional governments and local business) often must play a role in policy implementation as the center is often too weak to enforce uniformity in this regard. This may serve to undermine the realization of the positive political and economic efficiency gains of decentralization outlined earlier in this paper as Russians in different regions enjoy radically different levels of public policy provision. As we noted earlier, this may encourage divisive sources of inequality and social stratification. Stronger central political institutions would serve as a means of restoring some uniform standard of service provision in key areas to remedy this situation, although in the Russian case it is difficult to see what institutional solutions would be effective. Since February, 1994, the federal government in Russia has signed bilateral treaties with more than half of the 89 constituent units of the Russian Federation. While central government officials intended for these treaties to place center-periphery relations on a more stable and predictable footing in Russia, it is important to note that many regions in practice actually exercise autonomy beyond what is provided for in either the bilateral agreements, the constitution or existing federal law. That is, the treaties are far from definitive in terms of lending predictability into center-periphery relations, nor in ensuring implementation of and adherence to central policy at the provincial level. To a great extent de facto policy autonomy has arisen because the center, through weakness in certain key policy areas, has defaulted on many of its jurisdictional responsibilities. Regions, to the degree that they are able, are left to fill the empty policy space as best they can. Others cannot afford to implement central policy and so have carved out for themselves a different sort of autonomy -- the freedom to do nothing. Examples of policy autonomy taken (as opposed to granted by Moscow) come from a whole host of regions and policy areas. De facto policy autonomy is particularly evident in the area of social welfare – a sphere of the utmost importance in a country whose economy all but collapsed in the early 1990’s and is only now showing flickering signs of positive economic growth. According to article 72, point j of the constitution of the Russian Federation, social welfare is under the joint jurisdiction of the regions and the federal government. As early as 1993, however, before it concluded its bilateral treaty with Moscow, the Republic of Tatarstan embarked independently on its own need-based set of social assistance programs (that is, prior to the conclusion of the republic’s bilateral treaty with Moscow or the adoption of the December, 1993 federal constitution). Social assistance at the federal level is not yet need-based – that is, certain categories of citizens receive assistance from the state regardless of whether they actually have a financial need for this assistance (e.g. single parent families). According to the officials in Tatarstan’s ministry of social welfare, however, national policy in this regard was essentially unimplementable since the federal government was not providing sufficient funds to support such an approach to social assistance. Tatarstan’s approach then, was to simply seize the initiative and adopt a need based system regardless of central policy dictates at the time. Issues of Culture and Identity: "Cultural Entrepreneurship" in Russia’s Regions by Nicolai N. Petro, University of Rhode Island Lawrence Robertson, University of Miami The decentralization of post-communist Russia has dramatically changed the focus of post-Soviet studies. While Soviet studies concentrated on understanding the situation in Moscow, post-Soviet Russia has been wracked by the rise of localism and a concomitant revival of interest in issues of identity and culture, both national and regional. This has forced analysts of the region to go beyond political, economic, and social issues to examine questions of culture. Although culture first became a core concept in anthropology, it has recently been utilized by scholars to understand distinctly political phenomena. From this perspective, cultural analysis explains why and how individuals and groups behave as they do, and why people are likely to act in the particular ways they do. It does so by providing a system of meaning and identity to participants in a variety of distinct and discernible ways. First, it orders the political priorities of a society. Second, it is at the very core of how political communities define themselves. It is therefore key to the establishment of legitimate authority in society. Finally, culture shapes political conflict by defining what is worth fighting about, how such conflict should be undertaken and, ultimately, resolved. Culture therefore provides a crucial link between the individual and his social identity, defining group boundaries and organizing actions between them. It provides a framework for interpreting the actions and motives of political actors and linking them again to the broader social setting. To date cultural contributions to the study of post-Soviet politics have been few and far between. One major reason has been the difficulty of defining culture. Factors as diverse as territory, language, religion, descent, and norms have all been linked to culture and have served to unite some people and differentiate them from others on cultural grounds (by general consensus, this differentiation is one of the central functions of culture). But such differentiation can arise from many different sources, greatly complicating the quest for causal explanations. Because writers are rarely explicit about the mechanisms linking culture to political behavior, cultural analysis has frequently been shunned as a means of accounting for political change. As a result, a singularly important concept for understanding politics in transition societies has been overlooked. Since culture is funadmentally about the construction of boundaries and the production of meaning, it can be used both to determine the members of a group and to divide them from others. The late Ernest Gellner defined culture as a "system of ideas and signs and associations and ways of behaving and communicating." According to this definition, the cultural basis of any group is only revealed through the actions of the group. Culture then is not objective but subjective — the subjective self-interpretation of the meaning of actions by group members defines their culture. Identity can be defined as the recognition of group membership by individuals. Such membership carries with it both obligations and privileges. Given these close ties to identity and behavior, it is not surprising to find cultural attributes being used to construct and manipulate groups for all sorts of political, economic, and social goals. Culture, while embodying a host of specific attributes that vary for any group as well as among group members, can also foster a strong sense of group identity. The absence of such a common cultural identity has emerged as one of the central problems in post-Soviet society. While the transformations of the past decade have undermined the Soviet cultural identity that lay at the center of associational life before 1991, nothing has emerged to replace it. An ominous cultural void has appeared that manifests itself most clearly in the weakness of civil society. In general, the movements and groups that grew up and accompanied democratization have been weak ones with few members, lacing both cohesion and resources. These circumstances leave both individuals and elites uncertain about what cultural foundations should be used to constitute the civic groups that are the basis of the society and the polity. Nearly a decade after the collapse of the Soviet Union, Russia remains a society without any strong sense of attachment to the state, primarily because the state has failed to define itself. How to reconnect state and society on a new, democratic cultural foundation (and the encouragement of associational life along with it), has become one of the country’s most pressing tasks. Culture and the Prospects for Creating Community Culture and identity are constructed, varied, and flexible. This view of culture clashes with two other common approaches to the subject. The first sees culture as given and fixed; the second views culture as irrelevant and illusory. Both of these views address only one aspect of culture which, in reality, has attributes of both perspectives. On the one hand, identities appears as real and given; something that can be searched for and discovered. On the other hand, identities can be constructed and reconstructed as social opportunities change. It is particularly this second aspect of culture that affects how elites form support groups, and shapes the lines members of society use to associate with likeminded individuals to promote their interests. The process of group creation thus lies at the intersection of both politics and culture. Culture matters in conjunction with - rather than in opposition to - interests and institutions precisely because it is such a powerful resource in defining community. But most importantly for the purposes of our study, culture provides resources for political organization and mobilization. Frequently, groups and leaders use cultural organizations to pursue goals that they cannot achieve directly. Anthropologist Abner Cohen has identified six political problems that cultural organizations in society help to resolve. They include, helping to establish a group's distinctiveness; meeting the political need for internal communications among the group's constituent parts; developing mechanisms for decision-making; providing authority for implementing decisions and speaking on behalf of the group; providing a political ideology that lends legitimacy to power and converts it into authority; and, finally, providing discipline of ritual, needed to connect the ideology to current community problems. Culture then can be a vehicle for creating not just a common identity, but a common political identity for individual members of the community. This process is reinforced by a lifelong process of socialization and learning. But culture and identity remain fluid rather than static concepts, which makes the analysis of culture and identity all the more difficult. In addition, no one identity is exclusive or all encompassing. Instead, individuals generally hold a number of different, overlapping identities simultaneously and have even more potential identities to add to this mix. This means that in the absence of a stable, well established pattern of cultural expectations, individuals may find it very difficult to form civic associations—they simply don’t know how to interpret the behavior of their fellow citizens. One of the most notable transitions in the post-Soviet period is the devolution of power, authority, and responsibility away from Moscow. To the extent this actually takes place, it marks a tremendous change in the nation’s civic tradition, forcing individuals to begin the process of creating a new political culture. This might even be equated with democratization, if the collective culture were but the sum of the culture of its individual members. But here politicians as well as political and social institutions invariably intrude. Culture creates expectations about the allocation of goods and future possibilities for cultural group members since it provides powerful tools for political and economic transformations, enabling new regimes to shift the objectives of society, break down old taboos (and erect new ones), as well as endorse new possibilities. The rising appeal of nationalism in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union illustrates the increasing recognition by politicians of the importance of setting the political agenda through the manipulation of cultural symbols and rituals. This can have either positive or negative consequences for democracy. The importance of having a common cultural framework comes sharply into focus when a society undergoes rapid transformations. In such "transition" societies new patterns will tend to emerge only very slowly and only at a high cost to social stability. Second, the cultural discontinuity that inevitably accompanies social upheavals will tend to lead not to the embrace of radical change, but to a prolonged period of what Harry Eckstein calls "formlessness." Since culture has lost its ability to make allow individuals to make sense of the world around them, the "cognitions that make experience intelligible and normative dispositions must be learned again." It is precisely during such periods of orientational uncertainty that, as Edmund Burke remarked of the French Revolution, "the worst rise to the top." Post-Soviet Russia would therefore seem to be a good test of the impact culture has on politics, particularly in the regions. From a culturalist perspective, after all, the fact that socialization occurs at many different levels of society should alert us to the existence of cultural differences within a society as well as between societies. We have therefore chosen two cases that illustrate the very different uses to which the political manipulation of culture, or what we call "cultural entrepreneurship," can be put. Lawrence Robertson argues that a comparison of language policies pursued in Russia’s twenty ethnic republics shows that the "national revival" in native language usage is generally far more motivated by the political needs of the local elites (regardless of ethnic identity) than by the demands of constituents. The republics support titular peoples and cultures in a very limited manner, and the ever present role of the state in these revivals also suggests that their impact in forging a greater sense of community identity and civic participation has been limited. By contrast, Nicolai N. Petro argues that the key to political stability in the homogeneously Russian region of Novgorod, lies in the fact that local politicians have used culture to build a broader base of public support for reforms. By portraying local policies as a return to lost traditions, rather than as something imported from abroad, the local elite has increased the level of public support for far reaching economic and political reforms. Civic versus Cultural Entrepreneurs: The Case of the Republics In the ethnic republics within Russia, cultural questions complicate the formation of associational life and regional identity. One broad cleavage in the republics is an ethnic one - based on cultural constructions of groups as ethnic nations that are indigenous to the territory - as Buryats, Kumyks, and so on. This notion of "us" leaves out members of different cultures, in particular ethnic Russians that are a majority or a plurality of the population in sixteen of the twenty republics. Cultural entrepreneurs emphasize this ethnic definition of "us" while civic entrepreneurs stress inclusive definitions of the citizenry (us) based on residence._ This notion of "us" is more inclusive and less divisive in the multiethnic republics. Language and cultural politics are important for both conceptions of community and central to state action in the republics, which must decide on which languages to use in administration and in education as well as on resource flows to literature, the arts, and mass communications. All of these decisions and flows have distributional consequences for in and out-group members._ Cultures in contact become cultures in conflict in these areas where different definitions of us have consequences for current as well as future welfare of individuals._ And some argue for normative consequences for language choices as well, where the lack of a state role has encouraged a bad - the mass extinction of small languages across the globe. While language and cultural choices are not exclusive - the choice of one language does not preclude knowledge and use of another - these choices strengthen and weaken languages and the underlying culture by varying the premium placed on any language by its users, by others, and by the state. In the twenty ethnic republics in Russia, republican institutions and cultural movements promote the linguistic revival above through titular language schooling, support for titular culture, and native language media. And there is some evidence that the linguistic choices reported by individuals through the census and sample census in 1989 and 1994 suggests national identities - or at least knowledge of and affiliation with the languages of these groups - appears to be increasing among titular peoples in Russia. Although the strength of titular languages varied widely among the populations of these groups in 1989, there is little variation in the slight turn to titular languages by group members across the republics . The research in this part of the chapter suggests that "national revivals" are less national in content than they are in form. While the revivals are conducted through ethnofederal institutions, it appears to be the state via republican institutions and governing elites rather than "real" nationalists that drive the revivals. The republics support titular peoples and cultures in a limited manner, and the role of the state also suggest the limited nature of these revivals. Republican Language and Cultural Policies Russia contains many different ethnic groups with diverse languages and cultures. The old Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic (RSFSR) was the only federal republic in the USSR because of the large number of indigenous minority groups that lived in concentrated areas within its borders. The same principles of ethnic federalism that resulted in the creation of union republics for some ethnic groups, such as the Uzbek Soviet Socialist Republic for Uzbeks, led to the creation of 16 autonomous Soviet socialist republics (respubliky), five autonomous regions (oblasty), and ten autonomous districts (okrugy) for minority groups within Russia. The republics were explicitly designed for ethnic groups and designated as their homelands to promote their cultural and economic development. The official ideology, based on Marxist, Leninist, and Stalinist concepts, held that the flourishing (rastsvet) of nations would lead towards the merging (sblizheniye) and ultimate fusion (sliyaniye) of nations. In the Brezhnev period, fusion receded as a central concept and was replaced by an emphasis on asymmetrical bilingualism through the promotion of the Russian language on top of titular languages. In contrast to these ideological expectations, under the permissive politics of the Gorbachev period, national assertiveness among the titular peoples of the Union republics grew and led them to declare sovereignty and demand greater control over their republics. The ethnic components of Russia also sought increased local power and prerogatives and moved to declare sovereignty as well, usually from both the Union and Federation. Sovereignty was proclaimed in the name of the population of the republic and often in the name of the indigenous population as well. Greater autonomy implied increased attention to the cultures and languages of these peoples, and such provisions were often explicit in the sovereignty declarations of the republics. With the demise of the Soviet Union, Russia remained a federation under a new name, with the names Russia and the Russian Federation given equal status in December 1991. The following year the Federation recognized the activism of some national components by officially upgrading four of the five autonomous oblasts to republics as well as accepting the split of the Chechen-Ingush republic into its two components, Chechnya and Ingushetia. Independent Russia is thus formally composed of 21 republics, although Chechnya declared independence in 1991, refused to sign the Federation Treaties in 1992, and has maintained de-facto independence despite the attempt to crush the separatist regime by military force from 1994 to 1996. Since little information on language use or cultural policies is available from the devastated Chechen Republic/Ichkeria, the following section examines patterns of language use among the titular groups of the twenty remaining republics. Titular groups are the peoples for which the region is named. For examples, Tatars are the titular group in Tatarstan and the Khakass are the titular people of the Republic of Khakassia. Additional complexity is presented by other republics with more than one titular group. For these republics, the analysis examines all of the groups in the titles of these regions: the Karachai and the Cherkess for the Karachai-Cherkess Republic and the Kabardins and the Balkars for the Kabardino-Balkar Republic. And in yet another exception, I examine the six largest "peoples of Dagestan" as the titular peoples in the Republic of Dagestan: the Avars, Dargins, Kumyks, Lezgins, Tabasarans, and Laks. The linguistic characteristics and any changes with greater local prerogatives devolving to the eleven smaller autonomous regions in Russia are not examined below. Political struggles in these republics centers on questions of group and regional identity as well as on issues in economic reform. Questions of group membership arise almost immediately since determining the members of the polity precedes the shaping of policies for that polity. Questions about how to define rather than simply defend national interests - the interests of ethnic constituents - are at issue and debated by current office- holders and the leaders of national movements in the republics. Disputes between governing elites and the leaders of national movements focus on two opposed sets of ideas about membership of the republic. Broadly framed, a republic can be constituted on either an ethnic or a civic identity. Ethnic conceptions of republican citizenship emphasize the cultural basis of the territory and republican status rests on particular characteristics of titular groups. But these ethnic notions of republican identity and civic conceptions of republican citizenship are often combined by republican politicians, who appeal to constituents on both civic and ethnic criteria with little attention to inconsistencies between these different programs. Civic arguments emphasize the benefits of sovereignty and greater local control for the region as a whole. Ethnic arguments instead push for cultural policies and the distribution of these economic benefits to favor titular groups. Many republican administrations seem to have successfully created coalitions that link these opposed policy programs even in times of economic stringency. Despite seven years of independence, the national republics and the central government of are still determining the parameters of the lose asymmetrical federation in Russia. With the policy choices of republican administrations only loosely restricted by the federal authorities, the republics have a wide range of options in determining their polities. Despite the provisions of the 1993 Russian Constitution that assert that the members of the federation are equal, center-periphery relations are characterized by large asymmetries in power and resources between components of the federation and a contentious bargaining process over bilateral treaties with the central government. The development of federalism from the top has been ad hoc, which has created an asymmetrical federalism that generally favors the republics with greater prerogatives than the territories, regions, and districts. But the powers of the republics vary widely as well, due to the appropriation of prerogatives at different rates and to different extents by these 20 republics. Formally, while the residual clause in the Russian basic law reads like the American constitution and grants all powers not vested in the federal government or in "joint jurisdiction" between the center and the regions to the members of the federation, in fact all powers are contested. Language, as one of the main parameters of most ethnic groups, is central to their cultures. And cultural policies are also integrated into issues of language use and status in the republics. The republics were granted the right under the 1991 law "On the languages of the peoples of the RSFSR" and in the 1993 Russian constitution to establish their own state languages. But before this right was granted by the center, many republics developed their own language laws and programs that focused on the rebirth and strengthening of titular languages in 1990 and 1991. The typical practice was to declare the titular language and Russian as the state languages of the republic, with equal status. This was the practice in Chuvashia and Kalmykia. On the other hand, some republics such as Tuva declared the titular language the sole state language and left Russian, as the official language of the USSR and Russia, as the language of interethnic communication in the republic. But implementing the new language legislation proved difficult in all the republics. This often led to follow-up resolutions, as in Chuvashia, that noted the failure to meet targets set in the earlier legislation and to establish new, less ambitious goals for the future promotion of titular languages and cultures. Demographic Characteristics of the Republics These twenty republics and twenty-seven titular groups vary widely in all sorts of attributes. Some of the most politically consequential demographic differences are in the size of republic, the size of the minority group, the percentage of the population of the republic that members of their respective titular groups, and the percentage of the titular group that reside in their republic (Table 1). The absolute size of the republics is one of the ways that these regions matter in Russian politics and minority group size is another indicator that suggests the political relevance of these ethnic groups in federal politics. The extent the republic is demographically dominated by the titular group addresses another way ethnic groups may matter in politics by considering ethnic politics within the republic. The extent to the minority group is concentrated in the republic is often another consequential aspect of ethnic politics for these titular groups, as examined below. The republics vary in size at the start of 1997 from over four million inhabitants of Bashkortostan to a mere 200,000 people in the Republic of Altai. Eight republics have populations of over a million people and many of these units are located in central Russia. The titular groups of these republics within Russia in 1989 ranged in size from five and a half million Tatars to 78 thousand Khakass and Balkars, 69 thousand Altai, and 50 thousand Balkars. Five titular groups had populations above a million people within Russia in 1989. But few minorities were demographically dominant within their republics. Only the Republic of Ingushetia, the Chuvash Republic, the Republic of Tuva, North Ossetia/Alaniya, and the Chechen Republic have an absolute majority of the population of the titular group. In addition, together the six largest peoples of Dagestan comprised 76.5 percent of the population in 1989 and the Kabardins and Balkars together made up 57.6 percent of their republic in the last Soviet census. And ethnic Tatars were close to becoming a demographic majority of the population of their republic in 1989 and have likely become one since then due to ethnic differences in fertility and mortality rates as well as migration to and from the republic since the last Soviet census. On the other hand, titular minorities made up a mere 10 percent of the population of Karelia and 11 percent of all residents of Khakassia. Titular minorities were between twenty and thirtynine percent of the population of eight other republics. While many republics were largely non-titular, the extent to which the titular population in Russia lived in their republics varied as well. Although the concentration of titular ethnic groups within Russia in their republics remained high for almost all groups, only a third of ethnic Tatars and Mordovans and about half of all ethnic Chuvash and Mari lived within their republics. Most of these dispersed minorities outside their republics were in neighboring regions or republics. On the other hand, Ossetians and Lezgins had substantial numbers of coethnics that lived in neighboring Union republics which became independent of Russia at the end of 1991. Relations with coethnics across more consequential international borders and the nationalizing states of Georgia and Azerbaijan pose difficult problems for both of these ethnic groups. Table 1: Demographic Statistics for the Republics and Their Titular Groups Republic/Titular Group(s) Population Titular Percentage Percentage of Population of Republic Republic Start of 1998 of Titulars in Russia Titular in Republic 1989 1989 1989 Republic of Adygeya/Adygey 449,903 122,908 22.1 77.7 Altai Republic/Altai 201,742 69,409 31.0 85.2 Republic of Bashkortostan/Bashkirs 4,104,004 1,345,273 21.9 64.2 Republic of Buryatia/Buryats 1,042,669 417,425 24.0 59.8 Republic of Dagestan 2,094,200 Avars 544,016 27.5 91.2 Dargins 353,344 15.6 79.4 Kumyks 277,163 12.9 83.6 Lezgins 257,270 11.3 79.4 93,587 4.3 83.6 106,245 5.1 86.3 792,488 898,999 57.8 81.7 312,6445 215,068 74.5 76.1 386,055 48.2 94.2 78,341 9.4 90.4 165,821 45.4 88.2 Karachai 150,332 31.2 86.1 Cherkess 50,764 9.7 79.3 Tabasarans Laks Chechen Republic (Ichkeriya)/Chechens Republic of Ingushetia/Ingush Kabardino-Balkar Republic 785,848 Kabardins Balkars Republic of Kalmykia (Khalmg-Tangch)/Kalmyks 317,069 Karachai-Cherkess Republic 433,690 Republic of Karelia/Karelians 775,189 124,921 10.0 63.2 1,162,888 336,309 23.3 86.7 Republic of Mari El/Mari 762,957 643,698 43.3 50.4 Republic of Mordovia/Mordovans 943,668 1,072,939 32.5 29.2 1,016,017 380,242 33.4 96.1 661,552 402,275 53.0 83.2 3,777,767 5,522,096 48.5 32.0 309,731 206,160 64.3 96.3 Udmurt Republic/Udmurts 1,632,581 714,833 30.9 69.5 Khakass Republic/Khakass 582,412 78,500 11.1 80.1 Chuvash Republic/Chuvash 1,360,868 1,773,645 67.8 51.1 Komi Republic/Komi Republic of Sakha (Yakutia)/Sakha (Yakuts) Republic of North Ossetia (Alaniya)/Ossetians Republic of Tatarstan/Tatars Republic of Tuva/Tuvans Data for Tables 1-3 were taken from USSR Goskomstat, Itogi Vsesoyuznoy perepisi naseleniya 1989 goda. Tom VII: Natsional'nyi sostav naseleniya SSSR, Chast' I [Results of the 1989 all-union population census. Volume 7: The national composition of the population of the USSR, Part 1] (Minneapolis: Eastview, 1992). 1998 population data was taken from Goskomstat Rossii, Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik Rossii [The demographic yearbook of Russia] (Moscow: Goskomstat, 1998). Language Use Data on language use in the Russian republics is self-reported. The information comes from census data that surveyed the entire population of the RSFSR in 1989, the sample census of five percent of the population of the Russian Federation in 1994, and from a number of polls in particular republics. All three of these kinds of data reflects the subjective evaluations of ethnic group members themselves. The attitudes towards and attributes of individual members of ethnic groups towards language use are often taken as a proxy measure to assess ethnic nationalism. Language data provides one way to tentatively evaluate the effects of national revivals on members of these ethnic groups throughout Russia and in their national regions. Soviet and Russian censuses asked respondents for their "native language" (rodnoi yazyk) as well as whether they "freely command" (svobodno vladet') another language of the country. While neither term is defined carefully, both elicit subjective answers from respondents that provides aggregate information about the characteristics of ethnic groups. Soviet ethnographers and demographers were critical of these vague formulations and the lack of clarity about relationships between these two questions and actual language use. As a partial response to this criticism, the 1994 Russian sample included two additional questions. The first asked about the language spoken at home and the second queried language use in the workplace. Tables 2 and 3 contain language data for the titular ethnic groups of the Republics from the 1989 Soviet census and the 1994 Russian micro-census. The information is presented in language use per thousand ethnic group members. Each entry gives the subset of every 1,000 people that claimed to be a members of these ethnic groups that assert that their native language is the language of their group, they speak Russian as a first or second language, and use their native language at home and at work. The native languages of peoples with autonomous republics in the RSFSR, like most titular minority groups in the USSR, were overwhelmingly the language of their groups throughout the Soviet period. Avars spoke Avar, Bashkirs spoke Bashkir, Tuvans spoke Tuvan, and so on. And this trend has continued in the Russian Federation. And in general, groups did not vary much in their selection of the titular language as their native language. Only Bashkirs, Karelians, Komi, and Mordovans reported titular languages as their native languages at rates of less than 800 per 1000 group members in 1989. However census data shows a gradual decline in the identification of indigenous languages as native languages for some groups. For the titular groups in Table 2, the mean per 1000 population that answered that the language of their group was their native language was declining and fell slightly to 871 for 26 groups in 1989. But not all groups followed this trend; the titular groups became less alike over time. Linguistic groups in the Caucuses tended to remain native language speakers while some groups in central and northern Russia shifted to Russian. This shift is most notable for the Karelians who have received the most attention in Western work on cultural and linguistic Russification. Table 2: Native Language and Russian as a Second Language in Russia (per 1,000 population) Ethnic Group Native Native Speak Language Language Russian as Speaker 1989 Speak Russian as Speaker a Second a Second 1994 Language Language 1989 1994 Adygey 952 959 821 857 Altai 851 890 656 734 Bashkirs 728 738 726 753 Buryats 866 872 723 771 Avars 977 974 653 777 Dargins 979 977 680 807 Kumyks 977 981 747 869 Lezgins 939 953 687 782 Tabasarans - 979 - 785 Laks - 943 - 882 Chechens 988 - 740 - Ingush 982 980 803 875 Kabardins 976 980 781 812 Balkars 953 983 803 871 Kalmyks 931 951 869 928 Karachay 977 984 798 891 Cherkess 915 810 772 859 Karelians 486 428 463 415 Komi 710 706 627 651 Mari 819 826 695 752 Mordovans 690 597 643 578 Erzya - 896 - 852 Moksha - 904 - 844 Sakha (Yakuts) 940 963 650 677 Ossetians 932 931 832 835 Tatars 856 855 727 761 Tuvans 986 985 592 634 Udmurts 708 726 623 654 Khakass 766 733 673 711 Chuvash 775 784 659 689 Additional data for Tables 2 and 3 were taken from Goskomstat Rossii, Raspredeleniye naseleniya Rossii po vladeniyu yazykami [The distribution of the population of Russia by language] (Moscow: Goskomstat, 1995). But with national revival and sovereignization of the former autonomous republics, this gradual decline of titular language use as the native language among members of these groups appears to have been reversed. Although the data are imperfect and a direct comparison of the sample census and with the actual census is problematic, over the five year period from 1989 to 1994, the mean assertion that the titular language was the native language increased slightly - by 1 person per 1000 - to 876 for 29 groups. While this mean is affected by a number of outliers, it appears that there is a slowdown in the rate of decline of titular languages as native languages for some of these groups and a small increase in titular as native language for many other groups. And over this short five-year time period, the variation between ethnic groups continued to grow, with the standard deviation of titular language as native language per 1000 group members rising to 135. Particularly pronounced increases in titular language as native language per 1000 are apparent among the Altai (39), Balkars (30), Kalmyks (20), Sakha (23), and Udmurts (18). On the other hand, the use of Cherkess as the native language of self-identified members of the group fell dramatically by 105 per 1000, which seems to be an implausibly high rate of decline in just five years. Karelians (down 58 per 1000) and Khakass (down 33 per 1000) continue to shift away from their titular languages just as in prior census periods. Table 3: Native Language and Russian as a Second Language in the Republics (per 1,000 population) Ethnic Group Native Language Speaker 1989 Native Speak Speak Language Russian as Russian as Speaker a Second a Second Language Language 1994 1989 1994 Speak Native Language at Work 1994 Speak Spea Native Nati Language Langu at Home at Ho 1994 199 (Al Russ Adygey 984 988 832 866 316 929 858 Altai 896 920 673 753 617 790 743 Bashkirs 747 760 739 770 342 643 558 Buryats 894 899 736 779 286 682 648 Avars 989 987 645 781 492 942 912 Dargins 989 992 661 805 394 930 893 Kumyks 990 993 743 880 275 922 896 Lezgins 980 990 682 788 498 938 842 Tabasarans 984 995 598 781 487 956 897 Laks 977 984 783 909 123 807 724 Chechens 998 - 734 - - - - Ingush 996 975 796 881 220 990 960 Kabardins 989 993 786 828 410 960 933 Balkars 984 992 824 879 202 916 896 Kalmyks 961 981 897 957 16 364 351 Karachai 992 995 797 899 183 940 907 Cherkess 979 990 782 874 245 890 699 Karelians 515 475 492 458 34 175 146 Komi 744 736 653 676 284 432 399 Mari 884 902 753 830 357 637 527 Mordovans 885 919 803 856 331 696 236 Erzya - 894 - 853 322 565 598 Moksha - 909 - 767 286 665 647 Sakha (Yakuts) 951 971 650 681 776 917 907 Ossetians 982 977 869 866 193 834 753 Tatars 966 978 773 827 335 816 608 Tuvans 990 990 583 633 708 967 956 Udmurts 757 773 676 718 311 470 423 Khakass 832 804 724 777 108 492 418 Chuvash 850 860 692 727 517 671 508 Skepticism about the utility and veracity of Soviet census data on knowledge of Russian as a second language has been widespread since the question was introduced in the 1970 census. The acquisition of Russian as a second language was promoted by the Soviet state and the development of bilingualism taken as an indicator of the merging of nationalities in the Brezhnev period and after. The number of minority group members throughout the Federation that could "freely command" Russian as a second language appears to have grown for most of the titular minorities of the Russian republics in the early 1990s. Karelians and the Khakass, two of the groups that appear to have shifted to Russian as their native languages instead, stand out as exceptions. However, despite high retention levels for national languages as native languages, other evidence suggests that the meaning of this measure varies widely among the members of ethnic groups. One survey of five republics found that while 90 percent of Bashkirs claimed their native language was Bashkir, only 54 percent of them could freely use Bashkir for reading and writing. Similarly, only 36.9 percent of the 84.7 percent of Kalmyks that claimed their language was their native one felt comfortable reading and writing in Kalmyk. This survey found Udmurts and Karelians called their titular languages their native ones at lower rates, 59.1 and 42 percent of respondents respectively. And the 1994 sample suggested similarly that native language did not mean that the language chosen was the one used at home. Respondents indicated that they used their native language at home less frequently than they asserted their titular language was their native language for all but ethnic Ingush in Ingushetiya. Interethnic marriages, for example, are one way that the use of titular languages is reduced within the home. Native language use at work was far less frequent than at home. Majorities of only the Altai, Sakha (Yakuts), Tuvans, and Chuvash stated that they used their native language at work, and barely a majority in case of the Chuvash. Russian remained the language of the workplace for most members of these titular groups even within their national republics. Karelian and Kalmyk in particular have almost no economic role within their republics. Language Use in Education in the Republics One of the ways republican administrations were to promote titular languages was through education and the school system. But Russian has overwhelmingly remained the language of general education across the republics. Tuva is the only exception to this general pattern; 60.5 percent of all students in the republic were educated in Tuvan rather than Russian in the 1994-1995 school year. The absence of change rather than much of a national revival is the dominant trend in the language used in general education in most republics, although in several republics the percentage of students educated in the titular language has grown substantially. This growth pattern is clear in calculations that compare the percentage of students in general schools educated in the titular languages of the republics between 1990/91 and 1994/95. In addition to Tuva, the percentage of students educated in their native (korennoy) language has grown and been in double-digit proportions in five other republics: from 10.1 to 21.3 percent in Dagestan, 5.4 to 15.1 percent in Kabardino-Balkariya, 23.3 to 34.8 percent in Sakha (Yakutia), 12.8 to 19.1 percent in Tatarstan, and less dramatically 11.2 to 11.8 percent in the Altai Republic. However, even for these six relatively nationalizing republics, only half had titular language schooling at higher rates in 1994/95 than in the Brezhnev period of "stagnation" (zastoy) of 1980/81: Sakha (Yakutiya), Dagestan, and the Altai Republic. And in Chuvashiya, while almost 15 percent of students were in Chuvash-language schools in 1994/95, this proportion was down slightly from 1990/91 and down substantially from 1980/81. National movements, such as the Chuvash National Congress, dissatisfied with this trajectory have focused on the need to open more national schools and classes to support their language and culture. The Altai republic, like the four other former autonomous oblasts promoted to republican status in 1992, had no general schooling in their titular languages in the late Brezhnev period and have thus achieved important linguistic gains with upgrading to republican status. This is the case for six other republics as well; Buryatia, KabardinoBalkaria, North Ossetia, Mari-El, Chechnya, and Ingushetia began their linguistic revival in the schools in 1990/91 from an all-Russian basis in 1980/81. The nativization of the schools has not gone very far in most of these republics. Except in the Altai and Kabardino-Balkar Republics, none of these or the rest of the republics use the titular language as the language of instruction in more than 8 percent of the schools in the region, although the use of these languages grew between 1991/92 and 1994/95 in all but Buryatia and Mari-El where these figures were unchanged. Khakass remains the language least used in education: under one percent of the schools of the republic were in the language in 1994/95. The remaining three republics have not moved to institute titular language schooling at all in the general schools. In Karelia, Komi, and the Udmurt Republics, all students in 1994/95 were still taught in Russian, although some students took titular languages as elective subjects. But only in the Komi and Udmurt Republics were significant numbers of students attracted to titular languages as electives; 15.3 percent of students in the Komi Republic and 12.7 percent of students in Udmurtia took these languages as electives. In Karelia, Finnish was more popular than Karelian, although only a few thousand students took either language as an elective (6.2 and 1.3 percent of all students respectively). Some other scattered evidence suggests efforts to broaden the understanding of titular languages by making them required subjects for all students although the main language of instruction would remain Russian. For example, Khakass was supposed to become a required subject in schools in the Republic of Khakassia in accordance with a new education policy approved by the republican government at the end of July 1998. The plan also envisages courses in Khakass history and the environment in the republic. And some other schools in the republic were due to offer language courses in Chuvash. But the republican plan remains dependent on the federal government and must be coordinated with the federal Education Ministry before implementation can begin. Cultural Outreach Programs Since the boundaries of the republics do not coincide with the territory inhabited by all the members of these 27 republican titular groups, some portions of each nation are left outside the republic. The protection and support for titular languages from republican administrations extends only to their members within the republics. But, as noted in Table 1, a large proportion of some ethnic groups lives outside their nominal "homelands." This is especially true for the largest and most dispersed titular minority in Russia, the Tatars. As part of their cultural policies, republican administrations have sought to support the language and culture of members of their ethnic groups that live outside of the republic. These outreach activities are typically conducted on a government to government basis, with the participation of prominent intellectuals, local members of the ethnic group, and members of the national movements of the group from the republic. Bilateral agreements seek to guarantee linguistic and cultural rights for concentrated minorities and ensure that support from "their" republic flows to promote cultural autonomy. But minority populations outside their national regions are sometimes distinct from the rest of "their" group. This is because the definition of the group can be seen differently by both populations. Many Tatars in Siberia view themselves as members of a separate ethnic group - the Siberian Tatars. While the 1989 Census did not accept this self-defined group as an ethnic groups, the 1994 sample census enumerated Siberian Tatars as a separate group. And some members of the group has organized to seek national-cultural autonomy. In their effort to form the first national-cultural autonomy in Russia, they stress their separateness from the Tatars of the Middle Volga region and that they do not receive aid from Kazan'. And the main goal noted for the proposed autonomy is the use of Tatar in national schools. While reportedly already 35 percent of Tatar children in the oblast study in their native language, the expansion of Tatar schools is sought for more than just linguistic reasons. The schools are also to help "protect and develop their national culture, traditions, way of life, ethnography, arts, national products and handicrafts, and traditional working ways." Conclusions Regional elites are widely seen as influential in Russian regional politics. In the Republics, elected leaders tend to be members of the titular minority group or groups. While arguments for sovereignty and economic autonomy tend to focus on the civic, nonnational benefits for the entire population of the republics, this policy program is often supplemented with language policies with a more ethnic orientation. And language policies is one arena for ethnic counter-elites to argue for a more nationalistic policy. Alternatives to the "party in power" come from national movements in the republics, who may strengthen republican language policies through competition with republican authorities. These data and the above analysis suggest that at least some aspects of titular minority cultures remain strong and have increased in strength across Russia with these national revivals. But regional governments in the federal system appear to have little to do with these national revivals, at least in terms of language change. Republican governments empowered by sovereignty and with greater local prerogatives do not seem to have dramatically altered the pattern of titular language use or the language of education among the peoples of Russia. Titular preference policies and education systems that at least in party functioned through native languages encouraged the retention of titular languages in the Republics. Members of these republican nationalities that lived outside their republic lacked this institutional support for their language and culture and were systematically less likely to call the titular language their native language in the 1989 census. While this pattern grew more pronounced with national revivals after 1989, the differences in titular language as native language are small. Other scattered evidence about the Russian republics argues that in some ways republican governments systematically favor titular ethnic groups at the expense of ethnic Russians. Russian journalists in the regions and in Moscow write about ethnic tensions in daily life as well as republican ethnic policies, and argue over the extent to which ethnic Russians are disadvantaged by these policies. And some public opinion data measures popular attitudes towards republican leaders and their policies directly. While public opinion polling suffers from many problems in Russia, pollsters are far better at conducting polls in urban areas. Polling data from November 1994, before the Chechen debacle worsened center-periphery relations, suggests that urban titular populations and ethnic Russians in the cities of some Russian republics have dramatically different views of the central government and republican authorities. In the ethnofederal system in Russia, the governments of the republics are led and dominated by members of the titular group, just as these groups had predominated in republican administrations the USSR. While precise data on the ethnic composition of republican administrations is unavailable, the most visible positions in the republics are overwhelmingly held by titulars, and each republic has continued to expand its prerogatives and sovereignty. On the other hand, the central government is overwhelmingly made up of ethnic Russians. As in other countries, the general pattern across the Federation is for people to provide stronger support for local political leaders than for the central government. For example, one 1993 poll found support for the federal government, State Duma, and Federation Council at 10, 9, and 8 percent of respondents respectively, while 28 percent of those polled assessed the affairs of their regional government positively. But in the ethnic republics, ethnicity leads to different a different pattern of support for local and central political institutions. The pattern was split by national cleavage in one comparative survey of 4,000 people in four republics (North Ossetia, Sakha (Yakutia), Tatarstan, and Tuva). This survey found that the members of titular groups demonstrated greater trust in the organs of republican power than did ethnic Russians. And in contrast trust in the central government was higher among Russians that titulars in all four republics. Almost 40 percent of the urban populations of each titular ethnic group had greater trust in the republican than central government, while greater trust in republican rather than central authorities was asserted by only 8.5 percent of Russians in Tuva, 11.1 percent of Russians in North Ossetia, 18.7 percent of Russians in Sakha (Yakutia), and 20.8 percent of Russians in Tatarstan. These data suggest that other kinds of subjective evaluations of ethnic politics may divide members of titular ethnic groups from ethnic Russians in the republics. On the other hand, other politicians strive to construct coalitions that unite titular and non-titular populations in the republics, with at least some success. These effects are evident in the elections of Presidents in 19 of the republics. While ethnic gerrymandering affects legislative elections and has some effects on the elections of heads of the republics as well, it appears that Russians as well as titular group members voted for the titular presidents that lead most of the republics today. But other aspects of central government policies towards Russia's "nationalities problem" may lead to more republican policies that endeavor to reinforce titular groups and their languages. This tendency is apparent in the reaction of many republican administrations to dropping Article 5, which that indicated "objective" nationality in Soviet internal passports, on new Russian passports in 1997. The State Council of Tatarstan called not designating nationality in the new passports the "biggest provocation in the history of Russia" and asserted hyperbolically that this measure may "destroy inter ethnic harmony in the country." But despite the verbal hysteria, the practical reaction has been more measured. Tatarstan and other republics are considering creating their own passports or their own official documents which would include nationality. Despite the concerns expressed by a number of republican governments over the removal of the category "nationality" from the new Russian passports, other selfidentified characteristics of nationality such as language retain strong support among group members of the largest indigenous minorities in Russia. And these trends are pronounced even with the neglect of ethnic politics and republican concerns in the central government. As one critic has noted, the government in Moscow has apparently "not financing the extra budget Fund for national-cultural rebirth of the peoples of Russia" instead of using fiscal policies and other sources of funding to shape national revivals. And the disarray from the rapid turnover of Russian Prime Ministers and governments in 1998 and 1999, as well as repeated organizational changes at the Ministry for Nationalities and Regional Affairs, hampered central policymaking all the more. The data and analysis of trends in language use and cultural policies in the republics casts doubt on explanations that look to the national uprisings as a cause of the disintegration of the USSR and the threat of minority nationalisms for the integrity of Russia. If the "major reason behind the disintegration of the USSR as a multi-ethnic state was the diminished status of and discrimination against the non-Russian peoples whose cultures and identities were forcibly suppressed," the devolution of greater power and authority to these titular regions should be accompanied by substantial efforts to redress these results through republican policies. Such policies are readily apparent in a number of the newly independent states. But within Russia, while titular preference policies and new language laws have been strengthened or created in almost all of the republics, the results to date appear meager. Perhaps the short five-year time period is insufficient to capture the magnitude of linguistic or cultural change. Alternatively perhaps other differences in demographic change between ethnic groups swamps any linguistic changes. Further analysis and the results of the next Russian census, if it is finally held in 2001, ought to clarify the position of titular languages and cultures in Russia today and in the future. Civic and Cultural Entrepreneurship: The case of Novgorod-the-Great In the midst of Russia’s general turmoil, the Novgorod region shows how culture can also be used to promote democratization and economic progress. In just a few short years, Novgorod-the-Great (not to be confused with Nizhny Novgorod) has gone from the bottom third of Soviet regions in terms of economic productivity, to one of the most prosperous and stable in Russia. Situated in the northwestern economic area of Russia, approximately three hours southeast from St. Petersburg along the main highway to Moscow, the region has a population of approximately 740,000 and covers an area approximately the size of West Virginia. The largest city, Novgorod-the-Great, has 230,000 inhabitants, and the second largest town is Borovichi, with about 61,000 inhabitants. The urban population constitutes about 71% of the region’s inhabitants, 96% of whom are ethnic Russians. Despite its lack of natural resources, extensive military-industrial infrastructure, and large rural population, foreign direct investment in the region increased twenty-fold between 1994 and 1997. By the end of 1997, Novgorod had the second highest level of per capita foreign investment in Russia, 94% of local industry had been privatized, and small businesses provide over 20% of local budget revenues. In a nutshell, the administration has begun a massive reorganization of the economic structure of the region that is aimed at replacing the declining industrial tax base with one that relies on personal income tax. It has paid for reforms (such as a regional stabilization fund and regional small business fund) from the money it saves on communal housing expenditures, and social and cultural initiatives, and has managed to substantially reduce its dependence of federal subsidies. In fact, during two of the last four years, the regional budget has actually shown a small surplus (Tyshkevich and Bryushkin, 1998, p.12). The impact of these economic reforms on people’s lives has been dramatic. Between 1995 and 1997 real incomes in the region grew 1.7 times (Ruble and Popson, 1998, p. 441). They continued to rise by 6.6% between January -April 1998, compared with same period in 1997. By contrast, incomes in Russia during this period fell by 7.2%, and in the northwest excluding Novgorod, they fell by nearly 8% (O sotsialno-ekonomicheskom . . ., 1998, p. 106). The first seven months of 1998 also saw a 5.2% increase in industrial production in Novgorod compared with same period in 1997, while industrial production in Russia as a whole fell (Starostenkova, 1998). Had the crisis of August 1998 not occurred, First Deputy Governor Skibar estimates that economic growth in the region for 1998 would have been around 9% (Kolotnecha, 1999, p.3).At the same time the official poverty and unemployment rates remain significantly lower than the national average, even falling during the first half of 1998 (Ruble and Popson, 1998, pp. 441-2). To be sure, Novgorod still faces many problems as its pursues economic reforms. While official unemployment is low, if one uses the methodology of the World Labor Organization to project hidden unemployment, regional unemployment stood at 9.4% in 1996, well above the Russian average of 8.7% (Tyshkevich and Bryuzgin, 1998, p. 4). This rate is unlikely to be reduced any time soon since nearly half of the remaining large industrial enterprises are showing losses (O sotsialno-ekonomicheskom . . , 1998, p. 90). Sometimes, as in the case of "Start", which provides specialized electronic components for the military, the defense industry will not allow the company to privatize, but will not pay its arrears either (Izmailov, 1997). And despite the efforts of the administration to promote local agriculture and private farming, neighboring Leningrad region produces 3.3 times more agricultural produce, despite having 20% less cultivated land (Tyshkevich and Bryuzgin, 1998, p. 9). The ruble devaluation of August 1998 hit the region hard, though less so than many other regions of the country. Overall industrial output for the year rose a bare 1.7%, while output for Russia as a whole fell 5.2%. Housing starts, one of the region’s more stable economic indicators in recent years, fell by 16.2% for the year, although somehow construction of individual homes continued to rise by 7.2% (Sotsial’no-ekonomicheskoe . . ., 1999). New foreign direct investments in the region have been scaled back more than forty percent in 1998 compared to 1997, which translated into a 21 million ruble shortfall in the 1998 budget. Commercial lending within the region fell by nearly a quarter, and for the first time in years pension payments were delayed 2-3 weeks in August and September. The region’s flagship investor, Cadbury-Schweppes, suspended production for a month in September (Koval’, 1998). Still, by March 1999 the region’s other major investor, the Danish chewing gum manufacturer Dirol, had returned to a level of profitability that allowed it to cut short its tax holiday from regional and local taxes. In June 1999 Dirol opened a second multi-million dollar facility in the region that will allow for both packaging and local manufacture of their products. Indeed, of twenty potential new investments (totaling a possible 1.1 billion dollars) that were being negotiated in latter half of 1998, only one--a Yugoslavian pharmaceutical manufacturer--has withdrawn. The region’s success in attracting foreign investment has largely overshadowed its other accomplishments but, as local officials never tire of repeating, attracting foreign investment is just one part of a broader agenda of social transformations. This transformation centers around reviving local self-government or, as the region’s governor Mikhail Prusak has put it, "returning to the roots of our system of government" (Prusak, 1998b). Self-government: "Our system of government:" Unlike most other regions of Russia, when the new administration was appointed in 1991, it faced a popularly elected local city government that was already quite active in promoting reform. Relations between the administration and the city Soviet were not always easy during this period. At the time the leadership of the Novgorod City Council was firmly in the hands of the United Democrats, a group of local businessmen and civic leaders bent on a radical democratization of city politics. Many of them worried that the new governor would be beholden to Moscow interests, and might chose political expediency over democratic principles They felt their worst fears confirmed when, instead of holding speedy elections for local office, the governor argued that the legal basis for such elections had not yet been established by the Supreme Soviet. The governor’s implementation of Yeltsin’s decree # 1760 of October 26, 1993 abolishing all Soviets (even those that had supported the President) left a bitter taste in the mouth of those who felt the local administration should have been more supportive of local government institutions. Despite there initial tensions, however, the regional administration has turned out to be very supportive of local self-government, if for no other reason than as an important cost cutting measure. In 1997, Novgorod became the first region in Russia to successfully conduct elections for every level of government, ushering in a new era of political accountability. If local self-government is to mean anything, adequate financing would be key. Developing an economic foundation for self-government meant first and foremost, economic decentralization. Economic decentralization in turn required the adoption of a revolutionary approach to budgeting, amounting to having all financial decisions made and executed not at the regional level, but in each city and district. Forming the budget at the district level revealed that nine of the region’s twenty-one districts could not cover their expenses with their current tax base. As a result, richer districts were asked to share their revenues. This put tremendous pressure on local administrators to become more effective managers. Thanks to these and other economies, the region has been able to reduce federal subsidies to the budget from 40% in 1993-94 to between 5 and 10% in 1996-1997 (Tyshkevich and Bryuzgin, 1998, p. 14). Eventually, the regional administration would like each district be directly responsible for attracting investors, thus shoring up their own tax base just as the region has done (Khoroshukhin and Shchegol, 1998, p. 46.Shifting the burden for social expenditures from the region to the districts has also meant finding adequate funding, since budgetary expenditures(in particular for social needs) are now primarily the responsibility of each district. This has been a difficult transition for the region since only two of its twenty-two districts, Chudovo and Novgorod-the-Great, are "donor" districts within the region. In effect, they provide transfer payments to the poorer region through the regional stabilization fund (Soldatova, 1997, pp. 38-9). In the city of Novgorod-the-Great, all tax receipts collected within the city are transferred from Moscow directly to the city coffers, entirely bypassing the region. Despite the increased burden this has placed on the city budget, for the mayor, Aleksandr Korsunov, the new system’s benefits far outweigh its shortcomings; it has even led improved social cohesion, since people are now more likely to turn to city rather than regional or federal officials for help (Korsunov, 1997, pp. 10-11). Korsunov seems to be right. In the past two years nearly 900 people have sought out their representative in the Novgorod City Duma seeking redress of grievances. City and regional officials now hold monthly "open house" meetings, which any citizen can sign up for. These are publicized in the local newspaper, Novgorod, which is distributed free to each family in the city. In addition, each year regional officials organize some two hundred meetings with local groups around the region to explain local policies and hear people’s grievances (Fabrichnyi, 1996, p. 40). The most innovative self-government initiative, however, has undoubtedly been territorial’no obshchestevennoe samoupravlenie, or simply TOS. The TOS derive from the need to reduce government expenditures on housing by encouraging residents to assume maintenance responsibilities themselves. Reasoning that there are few areas more likely to elicit civic involvement than the condition of one’s neighborhood, the administration has encouraged the formation of what are, in effect, neighborhood associations, and given them the ability to raise funds, represent their interests before the city council, and even sue in local courts (O vremennom . . ., 1997, pp.8-9). In the first stage, condominium or cooperative housing owners would set up a TOS to resolve issues affecting their neighborhoods. In the long run, however, the hope is that the TOS will form the basis for new cooperative arrangements throughout the city, and perhaps even the basis for new electoral districts (Korsunov, 1997, p.11). By the end of 1998, five district TOS were in operation, including four with an average of 200 apartments, while the smaller, fifth one has only fifty apartments. Four have registered with the city administration, while the head of the fifth feels that since he was elected to serve the neighborhood, official registration is superfluous (Bessonov, 1998). The TOS illustrate the administration’s willingness to extend self-government to the most basic grass roots level. Still, some supporters fear that administration sponsorship discourages self-reliance. Others fear that the TOS will become a mechanism for mobilizing the electorate in favor of government candidates. By far the greatest impediment to the development of the TOS, however, is the fact that with wage earnings so low, few can afford to become property owners. Civic Associations: "To unleash and stimulate people’s initiative" With local self-government on the rise, it is not surprising to find civic associations in Novgorod thriving as well. At the end of 1998, there were some 521 officially registered civic organizations and many more that are active but not registered. Before 1991, civic activism in Novgorod lagged significantly behind the rest of Russia. From 1987, when the first neformaly received Mikhail Gorbachev’s blessing, to the end of 1991, the number of civic associations in Russia quadrupled. In Novgorod official statistics go back only as far as 1991, and there is no evidence of significant activity by neformaly before that time. Since 1991, however, the rate of growth of civic organizations has slowed in Russia as a whole, but increased dramatically in the Novgorod region. A recent survey of civic associations in 35 regions of Russia shows that between 1991 and 1996 the total number of civic associations increased by 63% (Alekseyeva, 1998). During the same period, the number of civic associations in Novgorod increased 16 fold. As a result, according to Goskomstat, Novgorod is now among the top quarter of all Russian regions in number of clubs and cultural associations per capita (Marsh, 1998, pp.152-4). Even more interestingly, Table 2 suggests that unlike the rest of Russia, this rate of growth has not slowed in 1997 and 1998. Civic associations in Novgorod fall into one of six broad categories, represented graphically in Table 3. About two-thirds are either charities, political groups or professional and trade associations, with the latter being the largest single category. Robert Putnam, who has studied the successes and failures of regions in Italy, has argued persuasively that "participation in civic organizations inculcates skills of cooperation as well as a sense of shared responsibility for collective endeavors. Moreover, when individuals belong to ‘cross-cutting’ groups with diverse goals and members, their attitudes will tend to moderate as a result of group interaction and cross-cutting pressures." (Putnam, 1993, p. 89). Table 2* Total Number of Associations Registered in Novgorod Region, 1991-1998 Table 3* Comparing Italian regions to Novgorod reveals some interesting differences.For one thing, nearly three-quarters of all civic associations in Italy are sports clubs; all other groups have very low rates of participation. By contrast, in Novgorod sports associations form less than 10% of the total; instead most civic associations are manifestly political or economic in nature. Removing sports clubs from the total reveals a "high" participation rate of one club for every 1050 inhabitants in Trentino/Alto-Adige and 2117 in Liguria at one extreme, and a very "low" participation rate of one club for every 13,100 inhabitants in Sardinia at the other extreme (Putnam, 1993, p. 92). Applying the same methodology to Novgorod results in a participation rate of one club for every 1643 inhabitants, which is quite high by Italian standards. This high level of participation is less surprising if one views civic associations as, first and foremost, a response to the government’s failure to cope with economic crisis, a point suggested by the steady growth of charitable organizations shown in Table 6. Table 6* Major Categories of Civic Associations in the Novgorod Region, 1991-1997 Civic activism is another characteristic of Novgorod. Its impact is most visible in the Obshchestvennaya Palata, or "Social Chamber," where representatives of registered social organizations can participate in the review of legislation pending before the Duma and offer their alternatives. The Social Chamber meets no less than once every 2 months and is chaired by either the head of the regional Duma or the governor. Such co-optation has worked well for the administration in its dealings with civic associations. But unlike many other regions, the Novgorod administration actually seeks the input of these groups and has consistently sought to expand contacts with them. For example, the original decree from Moscow advocated setting up a Social Chamber attached to the governor’s office. Prusak, however, decided that it should be attached not only to his office, but also to the regional Duma and the entire administration, thereby giving civic associations legal access to all levels of local government. To encourage public involvement and debate, the law setting up the Social Chamber stipulates that all decisions of the Chamber must be conveyed to the media, along with any minority opinions supported by no fewer than one-fifth of those present. The administration has also encouraged trade union participation, which has formed the basis for subsequent legislation on "social partnership" between business, labor and government leadership. Yet another example of this policy of inclusion is the proliferation of "social councils for . . . " [obshchetvennye sovety . . . pri gorodskoi/oblastnoi administratsii ] within the city and regional administrations. Any major initiative being considered by local government is generally put before such a council for preliminary evaluation and coordination. There were seventeen administrative committees in the Novgorod city administration in 1996, each handling 3-4 social councils, and each with a membership of roughly 15-20 members chosen from the city’s leading citizens. Thus, in this town of slightly more than 200,000 inhabitants, roughly a thousand are involved in one or another aspect of public policy. Membership in such councils is an important facet of two-way contact between the government and key social groups (Alexandrov, 1998). These examples sum up the administration’s strategy toward independent civic organizations. First, whenever possible co-opt potential opponents. Second, whenever possible make politics more inclusive by expanding public participation. By encouraging civic participation in regional decision making, the administration has built up a reservoir of trust with local civic activists and made the region a haven of social tranquility even as it introduces painful social and economic changes. Why has civic engagement worked in Novgorod when it has met with such mixed success in the rest of Russia? The answer seems to lie in the local elite’s ability to ease the psychological tensions of change by utilizing Novgorod’s past as an alternative cultural model. By tapping into the city’s ancient heritage as medieval mercantile republic and the cradle of Russian democracy, the local elite has created what anthropologist Clifford Geertz might term a new "political imaginary"— one that offers a Russian historical reference point to the Soviet past of economic and political overcentralization. This has resulted in an unusually high level of public confidence in local government and increased the level of public support for far reaching economic and political reforms. The Novgorod Model: Inventing a Democratic Cultural Tradition While the governor’s personal charisma may account for a good part of his popularity, they do not fully explain the region’s remarkable political and economic achievements, or the popular support his policies have received. After all, as the example of Nizhny Novgorod shows, there have been other charismatic governors in far more industrially developed regions who have failed. A comment by the Archbishop Lev of Novgorod and Staraya Russa, may shed light on the distinctive cultural environment in Novgorod. In an interview he remarked that: "Novgorod may have been fortunate to get someone like Prusak, but Prusak was also quite fortunate to get Novgorod." (Lev, 1999). The Archbishop is alluding here to a factor often mentioned by both civic activists and government officials—the region’s "intuitive feeling for history." Although the average inhabitant of Novgorod remains unconcerned about the region’s mythical history as the cradle of Russian democracy, for the more highly educated elite, it has been a frequent source of inspiration. During lengthy interviews that I conducted in October and November, 1998 with sixteen senior members of the administration and seven members of the local intelligentsia active in civic affairs, in response to the question: "Do you believe that Novgorod’s distinctive history plays any role in how the region has developed politically and economically since 1991?," nine respondents responded affirmatively and showed extensive familiarity with the history of the Novgorod Republic, four answered no, and the remainder were neutral but skeptical. Some of the most positive responses came from senior and mid-level regional officials. One leading activist explains the level of civic activism by drawing an analogy to religion. During the Soviet era period people clung to their faith even though few churches were open for worship. Yet today, after generations of official atheism, religious sentiment is undergoing an astonishing revival. "Political activism in Novgorod is high," he concludes, "not because of Soviet ideals, but because of the historical ideals of the past" (Alexandrov, 1998) The spontaneous emergence of such a regional consensus implies the existence of a common set of values (a regional political culture) attuned to the myth of "Lord Novgorod-the-Great" as a democratic and trade-oriented mercantile republic that dominated northwest Russia from the 12th to 15th centuries. The emergence of this myth as a factor uniting the elite and helping it to forge a common agenda was made more likely by the coincidence of several factors. First, the collapse of the official communist party ideology and the constraints that it imposed on the discussion of local history made it possible to discuss the significance of Novgorod’s history for the present. Second, the blanket restoration of old street names (an initiative promulgated by the City Soviet), the restoration of churches, including the politically and historically significant Cathedral of St. Sophia in 1993, the revival and official recognition granted to local holidays and festivals, all set the stage for a critical assessment of the Soviet era and broader public acceptance of alternatives to it. Third, to many local activists the problems facing Novgorod today seem not that dissimilar to those it faced in the past. Then, as now, the city must expand trade to survive, introduce local self-government, and keep a safe distance from Moscow to preserve its freedom. As any medieval historian can attest, these are precisely the issues that Novgorodians had to grapple with in the 12th to 15th centuries. Finally, issues of regionalism and regional autonomy were very much in the public eye at the time, as the shape the new federation would take under the 1993 constitution was being hotly debated. Given this context, it is not all that surprising that the local elite should look to the past for solutions to their current problems. Examples abound. When the local research center "Dialog" was given the task of developing the region’s housing reform initiatives, one of their first efforts was a study entitled, "The Establishment of the Communal Economy of Novgorod-the-Great, 12th -17th Centuries," with appendix and charts comparing that period with the present (Panov and Ovcharov, 1997). A 1996 conference on local self-government in historical perspective included presentations from the mayor, the deputy head of the regional Duma, and leaders of local civic associations, as well as professors. The head of the university’s history department, Vasily F. Andreyev, another former a member of the City Soviet, even presented a paper noting the similarities between the current Russian federal structure and that of republican Novgorod (Andreyev, 1997, pp. 19-24). Strikingly, whenever the history department of the local state university (named, interestingly, for Prince Yaroslav-theWise) organizes a conference dealing with public affairs, senior administration officials are generally in attendance and present papers (Romashov, 1996 and Moiseev, 1998). Governor Prusak himself has written poignantly on the significance of Novgorod’s past for his administration: Not only time, but location determines the nature of events and dictates the logical conduct of its participants. Each of us, upon beginning some new task, has probably been tempted to overlook the past. This would scarcely be possible in Novgorod, a city with its own distinctive history and former national greatness, embodied in the monument, "One Thousand Years of Russia." When, after the well-known events of August 1991, a new administration was formed in the region, it faced the age-old question: "What is to be done?" We decided to study more deeply the traditional capabilities of our region, to meet with long time residents, to listen to young people, and to review the archives. As a result, we saw very clearly that the history of Russia did not begin in 1991 or in 1917, but far earlier. Our generation has a unique chance and, most importantly, a duty to restore the broken thread of time, to create a normal way of life, and to unleash and stimulate people’s initiative.(Prusak, 1997) Eric Hobsbawn calls such creative use of the past "the invention of tradition."(Hobsbawm and Ranger, 1983) Anthony P. Cohen in his study of the Newfoundland community has referred to it as "the management of myth." (Cohen, 1975) Murray Edelman, writing primarily about the United States, has written about "the symbolic uses of politics" (Edelman, 1970) In each case, the authors point to one constant—as governments strive for legitimacy, they promote those traditions that best serve their needs. Similarly, in Novgorod after 1991, we find officials encouraging those traditions that stress self-government and openness to trade with the West. The former coincided with the interests and aspirations of local civic activists (which the administration was courting), while the latter could be used to promote public acceptance of massive foreign investment. Conveniently, Novgorod’s reputation as "the cradle of Russian democracy" and "Russia’s European gateway" has been so widely mythologized by Russian historians and writers that these two salient features are quite familiar to the public. But if the past were only a convenient tool for implementing whatever policies the government wanted, it would hardly be evidence of self-sustaining democratic practices. For this, we need evidence of new patterns of behavior and mutual accountability developing between the government and the populace. This is where the unintended consequences of political myths loom large. Initiatives embraced by the local elite for very specific purposes, often wind up assuming a life of their own. Thus, with the financial impact of Western investment now accounting for more than half of local GDP, regional administrators find themselves forced to be more efficient managers. The shift in the regional tax base requires on-going attention to the improvement of legislation so that it meets the needs of investors. In other words, dependence on investment has created a situation where just balancing the budget requires a government that is constantly reinventing and improving itself. Second, the impact of foreign assistance projects aimed at Novgorod, while much more recent, has already led to a reduction in state tutelage over civic associations. At a meeting of the non-official Social Chamber in 1998, one senior regional official reportedly remarked that the administration had not foreseen the number of projects that would arise in response to such funding. Since it does not have enough administrators to deal with them all, such groups would increasingly have to fend for themselves. (Alexandrov, 1998) Third, in addition to increasing the variety of new housing associations, the TOS initiative has restructured the work of city government. Each elected representative to the Novgorod City Duma now has 2-3 "social assistants" [obshchetvennye pomoshchniki] who act as liaisons between the deputy and his district. In a few electoral districts of the city, "social councils" have formed to tackle local problems (Shaikovksii, 1998, p.3). But while Novgorod has made a good start toward developing a sound government and a sound economy, the process is still fragile, since it depends so largely on economic conditions in the country and on political stability in Moscow. Nor can we say that Novgorod has fully met the criteria of democratic local government. Local officials are still too keen on bringing as much of civil society as possible in to the fold of government. A vice-governor, for example, still sits on the editorial board of the region’s only commercial newspaper, Novgorodskie vedomosti. Still, it is largely thanks to such support that grass roots activism is steadily growing, and people are beginning to utilize their institutions of local self-government. While the preconditions for civil society to play an important role certainly exist, future progress will require even broader public participation in local politics. This in turn presupposes a more sharply defined sense of regional identity. To help anchor this regional identity in people’s consciousness, local opinion makers will probably emphasize the positive myths about Novgorod’s past even more prominently in the future, and encourage the population to draw clear distinctions between the "Novgorod heritage" of democracy and openness and the "Muscovite heritage" of centralization and isolation. Recently, the governor has made this contrast a prominent part of his own political agenda. In his book, Reform in the Provinces (Prusak, 1999) the final chapter is devoted to addressing why the country remains so divided after nearly a fifteen years of reforms. Clearly, he says, people are searching for some unifying national ideal that avoids the propagandistic bombast of both Soviet ideology and western mass consumerism. His analysis of what the country needs is a text book example of inventing a tradition to suits current political objectives. Not surprisingly, it rings very much like a campaign platform: "There is no need to invent artificial ideas, no need to mechanically transfer the American dream onto Russian soil. If we refer to our own past, and we see that in Russian history there was a city that was able to combine democracy, free market relations and other accomplishments of civilizaiton with national traditions. That city was Lord Novgorod-the-Great, the capitol of a once flourishing civic republic that extended form the White Sea to the Urals. Academician Yanin, who has devoted his entire life to studying Novgorod’s history, has shown conclusively that Rus’ originated here. In contrast to the starkly centralized model that Muscovite Rus inherited from Kievan Rus (adding its own absolutist tendencies to it), the Novgorod model was characterized by greater openness and democracy. All major decisions were taken by the popular assembly –the veche. It elected the its spiritual leader— the archbishop—who was the leading figure in the city, while the prince fulfilled the role of military commander. The Novgorod model has shown its viability by giving the world a unique culture, creating enormous material and spiritual wealth. But history decreed that the nation should take another path. The eastern tradition, represented by the principality of Vladimir-Suzdal, and later Moscow, gained the upper hand. The Novgorod Republic was forcibly destroyed and yet, over the course of centuries, she continued to exist in the people’s memory. Today, this model has received a new historical chance. Our generation can return to the principals of our ancestors, but on a new basis. Self-government, elections, public accountability of authority, private property, individual liberty—the very cornerstones of the Novgorod Republic—are regaining their former significance. On January 27, 1998 a joint session of the city and regional dumas took a truly symbolic step. The deputies unanimously resolved to restore to Novgorod her previous historical name—Novgorod-the-Great. In taking this decision, the deputies not only rectified a historical injustice, but reaffirmed their commitment to those principles by which our ancient city lived. Without foisting our views on anyone, it seems to us that it is precisely in these principles that one must seek the roots of that national idea that the new Russia so desperately needs. (Prusak, 1999, pp. 94-96) Novgorod success in forging a social consensus suggests some practical lessons for the rest of the former Soviet Union. First, ideas and symbols matter and they can have a direct impact on the formation of social capital. Second, with a bit of ingenuity, local governments can be not only passive respondents to crisis, they can take the initiative in defining common social values and priorities for the community. Third, localism is more conducive to the development of democratic authority patterns than centralization. The example of Novgorod, which has avoided confrontation with the center while assuming greater responsibility for its own well being, suggests that a consensus preserving regional distinctions within a vision of national unity is not impossible. It remains to be seen whether such a consensus will be realized at the national level, or remain merely the preserve of a few fortunate regions. Conclusion: Culture remains not only an essential factor in Russian political life, it has been made more so by the harsh impact of economic and political transitions from socialism. The radical change in orientations of the country’s leadership has created a profound sense of discomfort among older generations socialized into unquestioning faith in the country’s previous ideals. People are searching for value orientations that allow them to make sense of the present change. This makes them particularly susceptible to the manipulation of cultural values by both new and old elites. The cultural vision adopted by the elite is therefore of primary importance, but it is equally important to understand that cultural options are just as fragmented and competitive as the new political landscape of Russia. With the regionalization of Russian politics, the rather primitive vision of "law and order" (read: centralization) proposed by Moscow authorities can be easily countered by regional cultural entrepreneurs seeking to launch their political careers. This applies both to "ethnic" regions" and to homogeneously Russian ones. Second, while the manipulation of culture often serves to reinforce the control of traditional, Soviet elites, this is not the only possibility. At different times and for various reasons, regional elites have expanded access and participation in political and economic life to non-traditional groups. One of the regions that has gone furthest in this direction is Novgorod, in no small measure because the regional elite there has rallied around a quite well defined alternative vision of Russian political culture. As a result, we can conclude that regional elites will be the main groups shaping the cultural foundations of the new Russian polity. Although this suggests a large measure of continuity with previous, Soviet-era cultural values (now wedded to ethnic, patriotic and religious, rather than communist themes), sharp discontinuities within regions are possible if people are presented with a sufficiently compelling cultural alternative. To achieve broad support such a "discontinuous" alternative must give meaning to the present by connecting it symbolically with the broader stream of history (either Russian or that of other ethnic groups). In this regard, it is highly suggestive that an avowed atheist like Governor Prusak nevertheless argues that the "Slavic worldview rests on spiritual and ethical norms rooted in Eastern Orthodoxy (Prusak, 1999, p. 94)." For the foreseeable future, until those generations that have been socialized under communism die out, the national culture will continue to be highly fragmented. Moscow has neither the resources nor the cultural appeal that would allow it to forge a unified cultural vision for the country of the kind that guided Imperial or Soviet Russia. What many observers have aptly described as the new "Time of Troubles" is therefore likely to continue for several generations. During this period the question of what cultural values should lie at the root of Russian self-identity (and political identity) will be hotly contested, forcing regions to define their own cultural distinctiveness from the center, and perhaps even to offer their own vision of a common political culture. If, out of this competition, a new national ideal for Russia does emerge, it will most likely be because one particular regional cultural ideal triumphs of over the rest, rather than as a result of combining bits and pieces of several alternatives. While Moscow has many advantages in this competition, it is no longer the sole player. In the end, culture is what the local elites successfully make of it. REFERENCES Alexandrov, Igor’ B., chairman of the United Democratic Center, interviewed by Nicolai N. Petro, November 1, 1998. Alexandrov Igor B., "Russia’s ‘Road Less Travelled:’ Novgorod Oblast Today" The Jamestown Foundation Prism, July 25 1997. Alekseyeva, Olga, "Tendentsii razvitiya nekommercheskogo sektora i budushchee resursnykh tsentrov (Tendencies in the development of the non-commercial sector, and the future of resource centers)" a paper presented at national meeting of NGOs in Moscow October 29, 1998, personal copy. Andreyev, Evgeny, former first deputy chairman of the Novgorod City Executive Committee, interviewed in "Zavody dlya prestizha (Prestige factories)" Novgorod, April 10, 1997. Andreyev, V. F., "O mestnom samoupravlenii v Novgorodskoi respublike (On local selfgovernment in the Novgorod republic)" in B. Kovalev, Mestnoe samoupravlenie v Rossii (Local Self-Government in Russia). Novgorod: Novgorod State University, 1997. Andreyeva, L. A., "Vzaimodeistvie organov mestnogo samoupravleniya s gosudarstvennymi organami vlasti (The interaction of institutions of local selfgovernment and state institutions)" in B. Kovalev, Mestnoe samoupravlenie v Rossii (Local Self-Government in Russia). Novgorod: Novgorod State University, 1997. Bennett, Vanora, "Restive Regions Wriggling Under Moscow’s Thumb," Los Angeles Times, September 14, 1998. Bessonov, Sergei E., deputy of the Novgorod City Duma, interviewed by Nicolai N. Petro, November 4, 1998. Cohen, Anthony P., The Management of Myths. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1975. "Dom, v kotorom my zhivem (The house we live in)" Nauchno-issedovatelskii tsentr Dialog, October 1996, personal copy. "Ekonom," a weekly television show broadcast by the regional television station "Slavia," October 28, 1998. Edelman Murray, The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Champaign: University of Illinois Press, 1970. Epanchin, Gennadi interviewed by Viktor Troyanovski for ITAR-TASS June 3, 1998. Fabrichnyi, Sergei Yu., "Razvitie mestnogo samoupravleniya na territorii Novgorodskoi oblasti (The development of local self-government in the Novgorod region)" in V. I. Romashova comp., Zemstvo i vozrozhdenie ego kul’turno-khozyaistvennykh traditsii (The Zemstvos and the Rebirth of Their Cultural and Economic Traditions). Novgorod: Novgorod Regional Scientific Library, 1996. Hobsbawm, Eric and Ranger, Terence, The Invention of Tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983. Izmailov, Vladimir, "Kurs--na razvitie (Our course—development)" Novgorod, February 18, 1997. Khoroshukhin S. and Shchegol’A., "Investitsionnaya politika v regione (Investment policy in the region)" Ekonomist January 1998, p. 46. Kolotnecha, Ol’ga, "Na investitsiiakh stoyali i sotyat’ budem, ili o tom kak my prozhili 1998 god (We remain committed to investment, or how we survived 1998)" Novgorodskie vedomosti plus, February 5, 1999. Korsunov A. V., "Reforma mestnogo samoupravleniya--shag k pravovomu gosudarstvu (Reforming local self-government—a first step toward a law-governed state)" in B. Kovalev, Mestnoe samoupravlenie v Rossii (Local Self-Government in Russia). Novgorod: Novgorod State University, 1997. Koval’, Ludmila, "’Cadbury’ gotovit rossiyanam sladkuyu zhizn’ (Cadbury is preparing a sweet life for Russians)" Segodnya October 19, 1998. Lev, Archbishop of Novgorod and Staraya Russa, interviewed by Nicolai N. Petro, January 27, 1999. Likhachev D. S., "Drevnii Novgorod kak stolitsa--predshestvennik Peterburga (Ancient Novgorod as capital—a precursor to Petersburg) " in V. A. Koshelev comp. Novgorod v kul’ture drevnei Rusi (Novgorod in the Culture of Ancient Rus’). Novgorod: Novgorod State University, 1995, pp. 4-5. Lisichkin, Gennadii, Est’ li budushchee u Rossii (Does Russia Have a Future?). Moskva: Progess, 1996. Marsh, Christopher, "Making Russian Democracy Work: Social Capital, Economic Development, and Democratization," doctoral dissertation University of Connecticut, 1998, pp.152-154. Data collected by Valeria S. Kalashnichenko, Special Order Department of Goskomstat in Moscow. Moiseev, S. V., 1917: metamorfozy revolutsionnoi idei i politicheskaya praktika ikh voploshcheniya (1917: metamorphoses of a revolutionary idea and its political implementation). Novgorod: Arkhivnoe upravlenie Novgorodskoi oblasti, 1998. "Nashi inostrantsy--ne igroki, a investory (Our foreigners are investors, not gamblers)" Banki i bankovskaya deyatelnost’, September 7, 1998. "Nastupilo vremya stroit’ (It is time to build)" Possev, 4:56-8, July-August 1994. O sotsial’no-ekonomicheskom polozhenii Novgorodskoi oblasti v yanvare-iune 1998 goda (On the socio-economic situation in the Novgorod region, January-June 1998). Novgorod: Goskomstat Rossii i Novgorodskii oblastnoi komitet gosudarstvennoi statistiki, 1998. "O vremennom polozhenii i territorial’no obshchestvennom samoupravlenii v gorode Novgorode, (Temporary decree on territorial-social self-government in the city of Novgorod)" decree No. 71 of the Novgorod City Duma February 28, 1997 Novgorod, April 3, 1997. Panov A. N. and S Ovcharov. G., Stanovlenie kommunal’nogo khozyaistva Novgoroda Velikogo v XII-XVI vekakh (The establishment of the communal Economy of Novgorod-the-Great from the XII-XVI centuries). Novgorod: Severo-zapadnaya akademiya gosudarstvennoi sluzhby, 1997. Petro, Nicolai N., "Can Decentralizatin Solve Russia’s Ethnic Problems?" in Ian M. Cuthbertson and Jane Leibowitz eds., Minorities: The New Europe’s Old Issue. New York: Institute for East-West Studies, 1993. Prusak, Mikhail, Reformy v provintsii (Reforms in the Provinces). Moscow: Veche, 1999. Prusak M. M., "Vosstanavlivayem svyaz vremen (Reconnecting with the past)," in Rossiiskoe predprinimatel’stvo: istoriya i vozrozhdeniya (Russian entrepreneurship: History and Rebirth). Moscow: Russkoe delovoe agentstvo, 1997. Prusak, M. M. interviewed in "Vybory otmenit’, Dumu raspustit’(Cancel the elections; Dissolve the Duma)," Argumenty i Fakty, 15:6, April 1998a. Prusak, Mikhail interviewed by Viktor Troyanovski for ITAR-TASS, October 3, 1998b. Putnam, Robert D., Making Democracy Work, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993. Ruble, Blair and Popson, Nancy, "The Westernization of a Russian Province: The Case of Novgorod," Post-Soviet Geography and Economics, 39, 8: [], 1998. Shaikovskii, Vladimir, "Vperedi eshche dva goda (Still two more years to go)," Novgorod, October 15, 1998. Soldatova Elena, Munitsipalnaya vlast’, 1:38-39, October 1997. "Sotsial’no-ekonomicheskoe polozhenie v oblasti v 1998 godu (The socio-economic situation in the region in 1998)" from the Novgorod Regional Administration’s web site at <http:niac.telecom.nov.ru>. Starostenkova, Yelena, "The Economic slump is over, but growth has yet to begin," Finansovye izvestiya, May 14, 1998. Timofeyeva, Ludmila, "Inostrannye proizvoditeli veryat v Rossiyu (Foreign manufacturers believe in Russia)" Ekonomika WPS reprinted in "Novgorodskaya oblast po soobshcheniyam pressy i informatsiannykh agentsv s 16.10.98 po 21.10.98," prepared by the informational and analytical center of the regional administration. Trofimov, Valery I. Inteviewed by Nicolai N. Petro, April 10, 1997. Tyshkevich, Evgeny and Bryuzgin, Kirill, "Novgorodskaya oblast (The Novgorod Region)," a research report prepared by the Russian Development Bank, Moscow, February 1998. Yanin V. L., "Na zemliakh drevnego Novgoroda: u istokov Rossiiskoi gosudarstennosti (In the lands of ancient Novgorod: at the origins of Russian government)," Novgorod, October 22, 1998. Yarysh, T. N., "Svyaz’ s obshchestvennostyu: vos’midesyatye gody--nachalo dialoga (Links with the public: Mid-eighties and the beginning of dialogue)." Upravlencheskoe konsultirovanie 1:40-42, 1998. Zavidovsky Dmitry G., interviewed by Nicolai N. Petro, October 29, 1998. Endnotes Globalization: the international relations of Russia’s regions By Andrey S. Makarychev, University of Nizhniy Novgorod, Russian and Michael J. Bradshaw, University of Birmingham, UK INTRODUCTION There can be little question that the processes of systemic transformation (which includes the internationalization of the economy) and regionalization in Russia that are the topic of this book are taking place in increasing globalised political economic system. Events in one part of the world are quickly translated to others. Thus, the Asian Crisis of 1997 quickly became the Russian Crisis of 1998. Together, the two crises triggered talk of global economic recession, which, so far, has been avoided. It is widely recognised that globalisation is a geographically uneven process. Consequently, some cities and regions are far more prominent in the global system, while others remain relatively untouched. The first order World Cities such as New York, London and Tokyo are seen as key nodes in this global network. The process of globalisation also poses a fundamental challenge to the state, national governments now find themselves unable to fend off the speculative attacks of the global financial system and some cities and regions now find their fortunes tied to the global system, rather than their home economies. In such a context, it is no surprise that many of Russia's regions have sought to create an independent identity in the global political economy. Moscow has emerged as Russia’s node in the global system, but other cities and regions are also seeking a place in the hierarchy. In Russia today the vertical relationship between the global and the local, transects the relationship between centre and periphery. Regions are seeking to develop economic and political links with the international system to compensate for failings in the Russian federal system. Equally, regions are seeking to shape their own international political relations with bordering states. At the same time, foreign assistance programs and the investment strategies of multinational corporations are seeking to bypass the federal authorities in Moscow to deal directly with the governments in Russia’s regions. This chapter presents a preliminary exploration of the interrelationships between the global and the local and the centre and the regions. The chapter is divided into two sections: the first section, by Andrey Makarychev, considers the international political activities of Russia's regions and the second section, by Michael Bradshaw, analyses the adoption Russia's regions by the global system. The conclusion focuses on the relationship between globalization and the potential fragmentation of Russia. THE INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ACTIVITIES OF RUSSIA'S REGIONS The contemporary world is characterized by apparently paradoxical trends. On the one hand, the process of internationalization is underway as national governments respond to an expanding range of international linkages, economic interdependencies and the demands of policy issues that can no longer be managed within the framework of individual political systems. On the other hand, there is a growing alertness on the part of subnational interests, both governmental and non-governmental, to those same pressures. Underpinning these trends are two developments which both reflect and help to explain this apparent paradox: the expanding agenda of foreign policy and the diminishing distinctions between domestic and foreign policy. Traditional distinctions between ‘high’ and ‘low’ politics, or perhaps even ‘national’ and ‘local politics’ now appear far removed from reality. When subnational units establish their own cross-national links with foreign counterparts, they represent a true departure from the traditional concept according to which the conduct of all international relations is the exclusive domain of the central government. The most important driving forces for economic regionalization come from markets, from private trade and investment flows, and from the policies of individual companies. Regionalization is therefore often conceptualized in terms of ‘complexes’, ‘networks’, ‘flows’, or ‘mosaics’. Yet patterns of regionalization do not necessarily coincide with the borders of states. Migration, markets and social networks may lead to increased interaction and interconnectedness tying together parts of existing states and creating new cross-border regions. The core of such ‘transnational regionalism’ might be economic (as in the development of industrial corridors, or networks linking major industrial centers), or it can be built around high levels of human interaction. At one level, therefore, the international economy is becoming increasingly integrated whilst many individual polities are becoming more and more fragmented. Thus, fragmentation is not a problem unique to the post-socialist world. This, in turn, is related to another casual factor in the foreign policy localization process, namely the frequent inability of modern governments to manage political systems and satisfy the demands generated within them. State sovereignty is weakening. It cannot maintain its ordering of social life across the endless play of multiple forces of fragmentation and integration. The growing desire on the part of localities to become involved in ever-larger sectors of public policy reflects the fact that national governments often find it impossible to serve community interests from a single center of power. In countries where that national government is ineffective in dealing with the concerns of subnational communities, provincial or local governments have been asserting themselves. Witness the recent creation Welsh and Scottish regional assemblies in the United Kingdom, a unitary state. This process has also been supported by the creation of trade blocks such as the European Union that provide a supranational authority that the regions can appeal to while circumventing the national state. At the level of non-central governments there is recognition that the needs of the locality cannot be satisfied without greater involvement in the international system. This is particularly true when it comes to attracting foreign investment. Here, regions within states see themselves competing with on another to attract investment from ‘footloose’ multinational corporations. By the same token, national governments may seek to divert some pressures by delegating their responsibilities. This may occur in specific functional areas (encouraging local export promotion, ecology, etc.) Several general factors are promoting the international activities of non-central governments: Geographic contiguity in transborder regionalism; Imperatives of global and regional interdependence; Extension of national foreign policy into non-security issue-areas traditionally within the jurisdiction of noncentral governments; Populist resentment against big and distant national government; Dwindling national resources available for provincial/state developmental programs; Provincial/state/cantonal/municipal capacity to influence national foreign policy by means of taxation, political protests, etc; ‘Me-Tooism’ (external activities as a status symbol or political patronage); Separatism. Many of the most pressing contemporary global problems, such as ecology, epidemics, education, and social welfare, represent issues that remained within the competencies of provincial governments. Here, the local and provincial authorities assumed increased roles in the shaping of many international issues. The combination of local domestic problems and broader international relationships can create significant problems for foreign policy managers. There are many issues-specific groupings, such as environmental organizations, whose strategies involve the internationalization of the domestic and the domestication of the international. The rise of social activism at the local level is symptomatic of a new form of politics, which is bypassing legal and territorial definitions. In such a context, there are two ways in which Russia's regions can interact with the international political arena. First, they can try to influence the decision-making process of the central state from within. Second, they can establish and develop their own networks of transitional contacts and start to develop their own foreign policy. This section considers both processes in turn. Regional influences on Federal policymaking The political decentralisation of the Russian Federation has significantly complicated the foreign policy making process. In the Soviet system the constituent republics and regions had no part to play in the policy-making process and regional leaders were unlikely to question Moscow's policy direction. Now policy makers in Moscow must be sensitive to the interests of the regions, particularly those regions that form Russia's borders with the outside world. Increasingly foreign policy formulation involves consultation with regional authorities. Governors are now invited to joint diplomatic visits as official members of the Russian delegation. For example, when the then Prime Minister Primakov attended the APEC summit in Malaysia in December 1998 the Governor of Primorskiy Kray accompanied him. Similarly, the Governor of Sakhalin has been part of Russian delegations visiting Japan. Regional representatives are also gaining access to discussions between the Federal Government and international organisations. Regional leaders have become increasingly outspoken on matters of foreign policy that have traditionally been the purview of official Moscow. In many cases the regions may be in a position to assist the Federal Government. For example, the regional authorities in Dagestan, Astrakhan and Kalmykia could help support Russia's position over the control of the Caspian Sea's oil resources. It was to promote such cooperation that the Ministry of Foreign Affairs set up a consultative council with the constituent parts of the Russian Federation. Yevgeny Primakov, then Foreign Minister, promised that the Federal Government would help the regions to develop their external relations. In 1996 he noted that the number of Russia regions with representative office abroad would increase to 37 and stressed that the regions must play an active part in the preparation of international agreements. Primakov particularly favoured the development of interregional ties with other CIS members. At the same time, such interventions are not always constructive. For example, Yevgeny Nazdratenko, the Governor of Primorskiy Kray, was openly critical of the agreement reached between Moscow and Bejing to demarcate the Sino-Russian border in the Russian Far East. The Foreign Ministry criticised some regions for bypassing Russian embassies in their dealings with foreign partners. Despite these positive developments, it is still the case that the necessary legal arrangements and procedures to enable the incorporation of regional interests in Russian foreign policy making have yet to be created. Regional authorities continue to make statements and take actions that impact upon Russian foreign policy, but Moscow seems unable to include such concerns in its policy making process. Thus, for example, there was no official reaction to the appeal made by several governors of Central Russian regions to reconsider the terms and conditions for the chemical weapons located on their territories on the grounds that their implementation might adversely affect regional budgets. The development of a legal framework to co-ordinate the international activity of Russia's regions is still in its infancy. Part of the reason for this lies in the lack of a coherent 'regional voice' in Moscow that might co-ordinate with government ministries. The upper chamber of the Parliament -- the Federation Council -- is composed of the governors and legislative leaders of the regions, but its members, loosely tied and circumscribed by the narrow interests of their political careers, have failed to create a forum with a strong regional voice in the Russian legislature. Similarly, the federal government structure has spread responsibility for regional issues and regional programmes among various ministries. The impact of the regions upon Russia's international relations takes many different forms, but most of them are informal and non-institutionalised. In many fields the regions share the same problems in their dealings with the federal government, but in many respects regions have divergent and even competing interests. The Presidential Administration and the Federal Government have pursued a policy of 'divide and rule', granting favours and special status to particular regions. This approach is enshrined in the various 'power-sharing agreements' between the regional administrations and the Federal Government. The weakness of the inter-regional associations is further testament to the success of the Federal Government's policies. Nevertheless, the Federal Government does have to respond to grassroots pressure from the regions. It is noteworthy that the short-lived Primakov government sought to involve the heads of these regional associations in policy discussion in Moscow. Very often regional authorities lobby in favour of specific foreign economic decisions, such as control over oil and gas export quotas and taxes or the revision of production-sharing legislation. The struggle between regional elites over discontinuing the State's gold export monopoly has had a strong regional dimension. One of the major proponents of the demonopolisation of this lucrative sector was the deputy governor of gold-rich Irkutsk Oblast, who was also the deputy chairman of the Lenzoloto Company. He insisted that the gold market be freed from state control and that Russian regional banks be allowed to export gold. Another example is the Republic of Sakha (Yakutia) which extracts 90 per cent of Russian diamonds, its interests have often collided with those of the Federal Government over negotiations with the DeBeers diamond cartel and the division of export revenues. In the aftermath of the economic crisis in the summer of 1998, Sakha sought to restrict the export of gold beyond its borders. Irkutsk oblast also protested loudly when the Kirylenko government tired to close the tax loopholes that permit tolling operations in the non-ferrous metals industry. The regions have also challenged the right of the Federal Government to tax their export operations. For example, the governor of Khabarovsk Kray challenged the imposition of Federal export taxes on the grounds that they would damage already established links with the region's foreign partners. Some regions have been eager to introduce their own legislation framing their external contacts in certain areas, thus provoking a 'demonstration effect' across the country. For example, Tula, Omsk and some other cities have imposed their own limitation upon the operations of foreign religious missions, at a time when there was no federal legislation governing religious freedom. These decisions were explained by declarations that many organisations coming from abroad "are explicitly inimical to the traditional Russian outlook, spiritual, aesthetic and cultural values". The restrictive practices of local authorities triggered complaints from Christian charitable groups in Moscow, Roman Catholic priests in Siberia and the Far East, Lutheran pastors in Khakassia, the Salvation Army in St. Petersburg, the Jewish congregation in Bryansk, Pentecostals in Yaroslavl', and Baptists in Mari El, to mention a few. These groups were expressing their disappointment at the attempts of local officials to censor their activities, to expel then from the region or to substantially increase the rent on their buildings. Since all of these religious groups have direct links with foreign organisations (and receive financial support from abroad), many officials in Western Europe and the United States protested about the actions of the regional authorities. To a large degree, it was these regional practices of restricting the operations of foreign religious groups that led the State Duma and the Federal Government in 1997 to adopt new legislation, which placed restrictions on the activities of foreign missions in Russia. Thus, initiatives, however regressive they might be, taken at the regional level prompted a change in national legislation. The issue of troop withdrawal was another area where international agreements have fed into regional problems. Troops evacuated from the Central Europe and the 'Near Abroad' have placed an additional burden upon the regional authorities in the regions where they have 'returned'. The regional response to this additional burden has complicated Russia's ability to carry out its international obligations. The capacity of the regions to accommodate the troops pulled out from abroad directly influenced the schedule of evacuation and, thus, Russia's relations with neighbouring countries. Under the present economic realities, the regional authorities have protested the additional burdens placed upon them as a consequence of troop stationing, military exercise, logistics, food supply and border regime maintenance. These burdens have been exacerbated by the inability of the Federal Government to finance the operations of its armed forces. Thus, federal activities have contributed to the non-payments problems in many regions. Since the degree of regional leaders' support now has a clear bearing upon the state's defence capacity, they are now consulted on a wide range of military issues. The Pskov region, which borders Latvia, Estonia and Belarus, is considered by the federal ministries as a test case for resolving major border security problems. The mobilisation of local resources is seen as important part of the strategy for dealing with the new border realities. For example, most contractors serving as border guards are recruited locally. Thus, the reconfiguration of Russia's external borders has created a new opportunity for cooperation, and conflict, between the federal centre and the constituent regions of Russia. Foreign policymaking in Russia's regions The second form in which regions participate in international affairs is through the creation of their own 'paradiplomatic' contacts with foreign partners, skirting the regulations of the central authorities. On the one hand, these communications might take the rather benign shape of transborder cooperation between neighbouring territories, sister relations between cities and municipalities, cooperation between NGOs within the framework of 'people's diplomacy' or 'global microdiplomacy' concepts. On the other hand, the regional state might promote its own foreign policy independent of Moscow. The latter is potentially far more damaging to the central state, especially when regional policy contradicts and undermines central policy. The Federal authorities have little choice but to recognize the leading role of Moscow (the city) in such issues as investments, foreign contracts in banking and financial spheres. However, Russian MID and other federal ministries disapprovingly observe the number of new foreign initiatives of the Moscow mayor. He openly obstructed the treaty between Russia and Ukraine in the Federation Council. The Moscow municipality is eager to serve as a chief organizer of the Russian pilgrimage to the Holy Land in the Year 2000, which might give big profits to Moscow-based tourist agencies. Yuri Luzhkov was successful in obtaining the confirmation from the Israeli government to be its chief Russian partner, despite the protests of other Russian mayors. According to a Russian diplomat, contacts between Moscow and Jerusalem reflect bilateral relations between two capitals, however, Russia does not recognize Jerusalem as Israel’s capital. Certain public pronouncements by Alexander Lebed, Governor of Krasnoyarsk kray, have also challenged the federal authorities. In 1998 he threatened to subordinate to the kray authorities (i.e. to himself) nuclear forces located near Krasnoyarsk unless the Ministry of Defense reimbursed all its debts to the military in the regions. Several months later he refused to keep fulfilling previous arrangements with Ukraine according to which the Krasnoyarsk Enterprise for Mining Chemistry was reprocessing nuclear waste from Ukraine. Lebed insisted on increasing the payment received for that operation threefold, thus provoking sharp reaction from Kiev. The Federal Security Service (FSB) also pays attention to the international activities of Russian regions. For example, A.Antipov, Chairman of the FSB Board in Tyumen oblast, has claimed that foreign companies were actively looking for access to classified information, including the commercial data related to geology, geophysics. Similar accusations have been made in Sakhalin oblast in relation to foreign interest in the offshore oil and gas projects. Notwithstanding the activities of the Federal Government, many regions in Russia have adopted their own measures to gain access to foreign markets or to restore direct contacts interrupted by the collapse of the USSR. The latter have been particularly important in terms of relations with the former Soviet Republics, the so-called 'Near Abroad' and the CMEA. At the same time, many regions have been disappointed by the effectiveness of Russia's trade missions abroad and have looked for ways to promote their own identity on the international stage. Among the most active regions, in terms of agreements signed with foreign partners, are Bashkortostan which has signed treaties with the Province of Bergamo, Kustanay Oblast in Kazakhstan, the Republic of Kyrgyzstan, the Crimean Republic, Turkey, the Latvian Ministry of Economics, as well as individual firms from Germany and France; Tatarstan which has opened missions in Australia, Ukraine, the Czech Republic and the Slovak Republic, Mordova has established a mission in Syria; Nizhny Novgorod has a number of pilot projects with international organisations, as does Novgorod. In the Russian Far East, the Republic of Sakha (Yakutia) has a trade mission in Tokyo, while Sakhalin Oblast has signed various agreements with the State of Alaska and the Japanese Prefecture of Hokkaido. Sakhalin has trade offices in Seattle and is considering opening a mission in Anchorage. Regional authorities are anxious not to miss a single opportunity to advertise their regions as dynamic and open entities. Many regional authorities have their own internet sites, which advertise the opportunities available to foreign. Novogord region led by the dynamic governor Mikhail Prussak, has won a number of international tenders which have allowed the region top procure finances for housing and public transportation. Effective the tax policies and positive attitude of Novgorod Oblast have attracted large- scale foreign investors. For example, Novgorod provides investors in the productive sphere with a tax holiday until they achieve full return on their capital investment. The UK Confectionery Company Cadbury is said to have chosen a location in Novgorod Oblast from a list of 100 potential sites in Russia. Novgorod was chose because of the positive attitude of the regional administrators towards foreign investors. However, the plant is actually located in the city of Chudovo and its strategic location on the railway between Moscow and St. Petersburg was also a key factor. In addition to trying to market themselves to potential foreign investors, some regions have managed to borrow from abroad. Three issued Eurobonds in 1997 (Moscow, St. Petersburg and Nizhniy Novgorod) and another 10 had planned to follow suit; however, these plans fell foul of the Federal Government and have been postponed indefinitely by the financial crisis of August 1998. In a situation where the Federal Government cannot service its debt, regional authorities are unlikely to be able to borrow in their own right for the simple reason that such loans require a sovereign guarantee from the central state. Thus, the financial problems of the central state have constrained to abilities of the regions to raise capital. Furthermore, many of the regions that have resorted to external borrowing now find themselves unable to service their debts following the devaluation of the rouble. This is unfortunate as it likely penalises the most progressive regions. As economist Alexei Uliukaev puts it: "the higher the degree of liberal reform implemented in a region (less administrative interference in business matters, less bureaucratic regulation, more successful privatisation, no attempts to control prices or redistribute income), the better the local investment climate. However, as we shall see in the second section of this paper, the geographical distribution of foreign investment is no measure of regional attitudes to market reform, access to natural resources and geographical location are also a key factors in attracting investment. The special case of border regions Trans-border cooperation is treated by the Council of Europe Convention of 1980 as any joint activity undertaken in order to enforce neighbor contacts between communities and territorial authorities of two or more parties. Trans-border cooperation is restricted by the prerogatives of local communities and territorial units as defined by domestic laws. From a theoretical perspective, a ‘trans-border region’ is a territory which crosses at least one state border, and which contains at least two social-economical spaces of polycentric organization. In a narrow sense, trans-border cooperation implies mutually fruitful linkages between immediate neighbors; in a wider sense, this notion might be used for describing a relationship between two subjects with no common border (which is synonymous to ‘inter-regional’ cooperation). Near-border and inter-regional cooperation are widely viewed in Europe as first the steps towards further integration at the continental scale. Yet border regions might be divided into two broad categories. In the first we have borders that perform the role of frontier guards or barriers that defend Russia's military, economic and political security. The second type might be described as 'open border' regions, where the function of contact with foreign territories, and not that of separation from them, is predominant. Hence, there is the possibility of two different versions of border: exclusive and inclusive. In the context of Post-Soviet Russia, some regions that were garrison frontiers in the Soviet period have now become more open and are promoting cross-border cooperation and openness. At the same time, many regions that were not external borders in the Soviet period have now become international points of contact between the post-Soviet republics. For these regions their role as a border region is new. In addition, because they were not borders during the Soviet period they have not inherited the paraphernalia associated by neither border regions nor the strategic or psychological baggage of having been a garrison. An exclusive border "marks the limit of the milieu, the beginning of an alien area, often conceived as strange and full of perils" which often results in practical conflicts over the delineation of land claimed by two parties. This is the case in regions bordering with Azerbaijan, Georgia and the Baltic States where the border region assumes the role of 'Russian outpost'. Not all of these regions have adjusted smoothly to this new task. Mobilization of local resources is of growing importance for sustaining international obligations and responsibilities of the federation. Lack of a fully-fledged border infrastructure has made many of these regions a paradise for smuggling operations and the movement of illegal immigrants. This has become a matter of paramount concern for the Russian security services. It is symptomatic that institutions like Security Councils have been established in the majority of Russia's borders regions in the past two or three years. In the absence of adequate financial and material support from Moscow, Regional Administrations are often left to find their own solutions to problems of illegal immigration, fortification of borders, customs regulations and anti-crime measures. Thus, being a border region may bestow additional costs and responsibilities. Historically, the Cossacks played a major role in securing and patrolling Russia's borders. Today, the Russian Government and Regional Administrations have again turned to the Cossacks for additional forces to secure border regions. For example, in the Russian Far East, the Primorskiy Kray administration has encouraged Cossacks to settle in the border region with China. Liberals fear that the regional Cossack regiments could become out of control and form alliances with nationalist forces. The Russian Human Rights activist Sergey Kovaliov has publicly accused the administration of Krasnodar Kray of privileging Cossacks and discriminating against major migrant groups coming from the Caucasus, the Fergana Valley and Tashkent. One of the most striking examples of regional interference in Russia's foreign policy is the stand taken by Primorskiy Kray with regard to China. At the heart of their concern is the demographic imbalance between the bordering provinces of China and the Russian Far East, "while the Russian Far East is populated by about 8 million people, the three north-eastern provinces of China alone have a population of 92 million". Furthermore, the Governor of Primorskiy Kray Evgeny Nazdratenko has refused to recognise the agreement reached between Russia and China with regard to the delineation of a common border. The sticking point is a protracted dispute over islands in the Argun and Amur rivers and some other segments totalling 21 kilometres. The Governor has repeatedly declared that territorial concessions to China will inevitably damage the Russian ports and dislodge Russia from the Far East. Since Nazdratenko's appeals on this subject have significantly complicated bilateral relations, President Yeltsin has instructed him to coordinate all future public pronouncements with the Ministry of Foreign Affairs. However, Nazdratenko was in no hurry to obey. The so-called 'Maritime Party', created under his patronage, began a campaign aimed at collecting signatures to support of referendum to reverse the transfer of territory to China. One observer has described Nazdratenko as "a populist whose idea of politics is to demand money with menaces to the federal government". Despite the actions of Nazdratenko, it would be misleading to reduce the problems of the Russian Far East to the personality of a single governor. The position of the Russian Far East and the role of its regions have raised considerable controversy. From one side, the Russian Far East gravitates toward the Asia-Pacific region where APEC (of which Russia is now a member) promotes the virtues of 'open regionalism'. For the Russian Far East, increased trade with its neighbours is seen as a means of addressing the regions most pressing economic problems. In fact, cross border trade with China has helped to alleviate the shortage of goods in the Russian Far East following the break-up of the USSR. In the longer run, it is hoped that the Tumen River project can serve to develop the border region between Russia, China and North Korea. However, in both cases, border trade and the Tumen River, the xenophobic fears of Primorskiy Kray have undermined cooperation. Starting in 1994, the Russian Government stopped its 'open border' policy with China and introduced visa and border controls. The result was a substantial decline in cross border trade. Both ‘Asian Financial Crisis’ and the ‘Russian Financial Crisis’ have hit the region hard. Depressed markets in Asia have reduced demand for the Far East’s exports, while the devaluation of the rouble has reducing the region’s purchasing power. A good illustration of ‘tug-of-war’ between the federal and regional authorities is the debate over the subordination of major Russian ports. Regional authorities in Novorossiysk, Magadan, Makhachkala and some other port cities are claiming to have full financial control over their operations. Should the ambitions of the local leaders be implemented, the federal center would certainly lose the control over sea export, including oil. Bordering territories, especially those adjacent to Mongolia, Kazakhstan, Ukraine, Belarus, Finland and Norway) may also frequently play the role of 'contact regions', as opposed to the 'border barriers' discussed above. The larger the territory of a state, the greater the chance that regions having at their disposal direct entry to foreign states find themselves within that state's 'gravitational field'. It may even be the case that these contact regions develop external links at the expense of contacts with their own centre. Thus, the Federal Programme for the development of the Russian Far East and Transbaykal talks of the 'distancing' of the region from European Russia. This distancing results in the regions of the Far East forming trade with relations their foreign neighbours to replace linkages that are no longer feasible under the current economic conditions in Russia. Thus, for example, Magadan and Kamchatka have used funds provided by the Federal Government to purchase fuel and food from the United States. Following the August 1998 financial crisis Moscow was unable to provide the Far North with the funds to purchase supplies, this resulted in hardship and increased reliance upon foreign humanitarian aid. The nature and specificity of border problems varies from region to region. Thus, it is a part of the practice of interstate relations between Russia and former USSR republics (including Baltic countries, Belarus and Ukraine) to hold working meeting of customs officers in bordering cities where the training centers are located. Officials from Leningrad oblast are permanent participants of the Russian-Estonian Commision on Trade and Cooperation. The key issues related to the interests of Leningrad oblast are: the hydroelectric station in Narva. The problem is that in the Narva water reservoir, the state border is drawn on the middle of the dam, which makes its technical maintenance from the Russian side complicated due to visa regulations; water supply of Ivangorod. The Estonian side requires quick reimbursement of the existing financial debts; bituminous shale processing from Leningrad oblast in Estonia, under the conditions of barter exchanges. In the Barents Sea and Baltic regions one can observe the emergence of subregional structures, sometimes called ‘euroregions’. Thus, Karelia and adjacent communes of Eastern Finland are discussing the perspectives of forming a new ‘euroregion’, a concept that is compatible with the formation of Free Economic zone in Kostomuksha. The idea of such a ‘euroregion’ includes pipeline construction from Karelia to Finland and further eventually to Sweden, collaboration in forestry, hotel building, communication, etc. Of course, many problems remain, including budgetary and legal procedures. There is evident interest on the part of the Scandinavian countries to develop transborder relations. For instance, the Norwegian Ministry of Justice has decided to provide legal status to the Russian small vendors doing their business in Norway. The Governor of Murmansk oblast is advocating the idea of creating a transnational institution to bring together all subnational territories adjacent to the North Sea. This initiative was presented to Goskomsever (which is now part of the RF Ministry of Regional Policy), the Russian governmental agency in charge of the northern territories. Another example would be the inclusion of the European North in the 'Barents EuroArctic region'. Here the Russian regions of Murmansk, Arkhangelsk and the Karelia participate in the Barents Euro-Arctic initiative alongside neighbouring provinces in Norway, Sweden and Finland. As part of this initiative, Finnish authorities have promoted trans-border cooperation between Lappenranta - Vyborg and Imarta Svetlogorsk. Joenniemmi suggests that Finland has a clear interest in fostering cooperation with Karelia as an alternative to staking territorial claims on the border regions. For Joenniemmi, border transparency is a special importance to those citizens of Finland whose ancestors used to live in Karelia. One can contrast this transparency with the current situation in the Russian Far East where Japanese citizens have ancestors buried on the disputed Kurile Islands. In the past they have been allowed to visit these ancestral graves; however, Japanese citizens do not have easy access to the islands. Despite the improvement in Russian-Japanese relations, no resolution of the dispute seems imminent and the Governor of Sakhalin has spoken against any agreement that is reached without regional approval. Also in the Russian Far East, the Tumen River project can be seen as an equivalent of the Euroregion concept, with the major distinction that none of the participants is willing or able to finance the scheme. There would seem to the potential to extend the Euroregion concept to the border regions of the CIS. For example, the Belgorod - Kharkov - Lugansk - Kuban' - Crimea Rostov - Donbass axis has been mentioned as a potential pioneer of post-Soviet transborder cooperation. However, such a scheme has its problems. For the Russian side it presents both political and economic problems, the Russian border regions are economically depressed and form part of the so-called 'Red Belt' which is dominated by Communist leaders. For the Ukraine the scheme has to potential to pull the ethnically Russian border regions towards Russia and may stir up the irrendentist claims of Russian nationalists towards the Crimea. It is probably the case that neither the border regions nor the central states involved are sufficiently stable to promote such cooperation at present. Clearly the disintegration of the Soviet Union has strongly affected the state of regional affairs within the Russian Federation. Previously, out of the 11 economic regions of Russia, only 6 had an outlet to state borders or the ocean. At present only the VolgaVyatka region lacks such an outlet. Before 1991, 29 territorial units in Russia were border areas; today there are 46 such border areas. As Alexander Granberg, adviser to the Russian President, put it: "these changes gave rise to new problems of production specialisation, the structure of goods turnover, protection of the local markets of neighbouring states, population migration, relocation of armed forces, creation of new jobs and accelerated development of the social infrastructure. By virtue of their unpreparedness they lie as an additional heavy burden on the regional authorities". It may be the case that there are substantial differences between those border regions that served such a function during the Soviet period and those have been made border regions by the break up of the Soviet Union. On the one hand, the old Soviet border regions now bear the burden of a heavy military-industrial presence and a tradition as 'exclusive' frontier region. This is certainly true of the Far East, but less so of Karelia. One the other hand, for the new created border regions the concerns are more economic than strategic, here problems stem from the break up of old linkages and the imposition of barriers between regions that were previously part of a single economic space. For such regions the priority may to promote a more open and 'inclusive' border regime. Ethnicity and internationalisation Today in Russia's regions many initiatives to promote transnational regionalism are promoted by strong ethnic and cultural traditions. The collapse of the Soviet Union has allowed non-Russian ethnic groups to join international networks. Thus, the Republics of Bashkortostan, Mary El and Mordova are playing an important role in the World Council of Finno-Urgian Peoples. In Tatarstan, the city of Ufa has been selected as home for the International Organisation of Turkic Youth. Since the Tatar diaspora is concentrated in Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan, it is conceivable that the Kazan government has a special interest in developing closer links with those two countries. In the Far East, the President of the Republic of Sakha (Yakutia) Mikhail Nikolaev is publicly developing ideas aimed at bringing together peoples belonging to the 'northern circumpolar civilisation'. Elsewhere in the Russian North the indigenous peoples (referred to in Russia as the small peoples of the north) are developing international ties with other northern peoples. At the same time, international organisations such as Survival International are taking an interest in the plight of the peoples of the Russian North. In 1994-95 some of the Republics within the Russian Federation (Tatarstan, Bashkortostan and Kabardino-Balkaria) signed bilateral treaties with the Republic of Abkhazia which was then struggling to separate from Georgia. At that time the Russian Ministry of Foreign Affairs expressed its 'regret' about the encroachment upon its prerogative by constituent parts of the Federation, since the actions of those republics contradicted the commitments made by the Russian Federal Government in the Russian-Georgian Friendship Treaty signed in 1994. However, it is increasingly the case that Russia's foreign policy makers have to take into account the political attitudes of the different minorities that reside within the Federation. Thus, for example, it is inconceivable to develop a strategy of countering Islamic fundamentalism in the southern borders of Russia without taking into account the religious feelings that dominate in Tatarstan or Bashkortostan. For example, it is an important factor that after the outbreak of war in Chechnya, the President of Tatarstan distanced himself from all radical versions of Islamic fundamentalism, including those of foreign origin. At the same time, Tatarstan has demanded that it is recognised as a 'subject of international relations', a status denied it by Moscow. Nevertheless, in matters to do with the Middle East, such as Iraq, it may suit Moscow to play the Islamic card. Given its potential to break up the Russian Federation, it is very important to examine how ethnic problems are tackled at the regional level. For example, Orenburg oblast, has 1,800 km of borders shared with Kazakhstan, Tatarstan and Bashkortostan. In 1992, the President of Bashkortostan Murtaza Rakhimov declared that his republic would never be resigned to the fact that 38 kilometres of the territory of Orenburg that separate his republic from Kazakhstan. Implying that Bashkortostan would not be satisfied until it has a common border with Kazakhstan. Elsewhere, 'divided peoples' could become an important factor shaping transborder regimes, for instance, Lezgins reside on both sides of the Russian-Azeri border. The problems of irredentism, nationalism and territorial conflict that now abound in the former Soviet Union are symptomatic of the break up of empire. The post-colonial history of Africa is replete with examples of conflict resulting from the inheritance of colonial boundaries that paid little regard to the pre-colonial ethnic landscape. Now, in the former Soviet Union and within the Russian Federation, those same stresses are appearing. It may be that increased interaction between the regions and the outside world can help diffuse tensions created by the heavy hand of the dominant ethnic groups and the central state. At the same time, it is likely that the central state will see the international activities of the regions as a threat to its integrity. Thus, the international activities of the regions create a tension between the axes of global-local relations and centre-regional relations. So far this analysis has considered how the regions themselves have sought to influence the policies of the central state and how, by their own actions, they have sought to establish new linkages with the international system. The second section considers the action of the international community in terms of the regional patterns of foreign investment in Russia and the regional dimensions of multi-lateral and bi-lateral technical assistance programmes. GLOBAL ACTORS IN RUSSIA'S REGIONS This section considers the ways in which various global actors have adopted Russia's regions. Three sets of actors are considered. First, private international actors, principally, multinational corporations that have invested in the Russian economy and whose investment decisions generate a geography of foreign investment activity. Second, the programmes of foreign state organisations, such as the US American Business Centres, whose role it is to promote the foreign policy goals and commercial interests of their state. Third, the programmes of multilateral international organisation, such as the European Union's Technical Assistance for the CIS (TACIS) programme and the EBRD's regional venture capital funds, which are targeted at particular regions. Before examining the activities of these three groups of actors, the next sub-section consider the 'regional risk ratings' that have been produced in the last year or so. These ratings aim to identify those that are most likely to attract the attention of global actors. In trying to explain the geography of 'globalisation' across Russia, the ratings can be compared to the actions of the global players. In sum, this section seeks to identify those regions in Russia, which are being coming integrated into global political and economic networks. Rating Russia's Regions Given that the Russian Federation is comprised of 89 federal subjects, each with its own resource endowment, demographic and ethnic structure and political culture, it is no surprise that there have been a number of attempts to assess the relative merits of the regions from the viewpoint of the would-be investor. During the Soviet period when the Ministry of Foreign Trade exercised a monopoly over foreign economic relations, and when foreign companies were not permitted to invest in Soviet enterprises, the first, and last, port of call for the foreign business representative was the relevant Foreign Trade Organisation in Moscow. In contemporary Russia it has become somewhat of a cliché to state that it is necessary to go 'beyond Moscow'. However, it is now the case that foreign businesses need to engage directly with potential Russian partners and that they need to pay as much attention to the administrative structures in the regions as they do do to Moscow. Not surprisingly, foreign companies often find themselves 'piggy in the middle", caught between the demands and rules and regulations of the Central Government and the Regional Administration. For large-scale resource development projects, failure to gain the support of the Regional Administration can effectively stop the investment process. Therefore, when first approaching Russia, it is advantageous to gain some sense of the relative political and economic standing of the various regions and their attitudes to economic reform and foreign investment. The information presented in Table 1 summarises the finding of five regional-ranking exercises. All of the analyses presented here have used statistical material for 1995 and 1996; therefore their finding should be comparable. However, each survey employs a different methodology and some have a quite specific intent. In addition, some, like the Troika Dialog, are modest exercises focusing on the top ten regions; while others, like the Ekspert Institute and Bank Austria analysis, are substantial undertakings generating a large amount of data and lengthy publications. The CS-First Boston analysis is more specialised, focusing upon the credit worthiness of the regions. Both the Bank Austria and Ekspert Magazine analyses are repeat exercises. The Bank Austria sponsored ratings were first calculated in 1995, while for the last three years Ekspert Magazine has published a set of regional ratings. There is not the time, nor the need, to delve into the details of the methodologies employed in each analysis. Unfortunately, some of the analyses say very little about the methodologies employed or the date used. They all create a composite index using a number of dimensions of 'risk'. For example, the Bank Austria study creates indices for five sub-groups: natural environment, ecological situation and related risk; political environment and related risk; social environment and related risk; risk associated with the economic environment; and the experience of foreign and joint enterprises. Each of these sub-groups uses a number of indicators to arrive at an overall index for that risk. The five indexes are then standardised to produce a general risk rating. In some of the analyses differential weighting is given to certain sub-groups. For example, the CS-First Boston analysis gives the fiscal sub-group a 40 percent weighting and the economic and political sub-groups 30 per cent each. In constructing each index, it is necessary to decide which direction is 'good' and which is 'bad'. This can be a complicated matter. For example, is a high level of unemployment a good or a bad thing? In a Western economy it is usually considered a bad thing, depressing a region's standard of living and causing social unrest. The same is true in Russia today; however, one could see high unemployment a good thing if it is an indication that economic restructuring is taking place within a region. Similarly, low cost of living and low inflation are normally considered good; in Russia they might be considered bad because they might indicate the use of local price controls and subsidies. Thus, the process of choosing indicators and deciding how to interpret them is directly informed by how one interprets the transition process in Russia. Consequently, each set of ratings should be treated with caution and, despite the fact that they use the same data, they are not directly comparable. Those that generate a numerical index, do so in a different way, some rate regions relative to the national average, others relative to Moscow. Having said that the various ratings are not comparable, they do generate a very similar set of top ten regions. This is likely because they make similar judgements as to what is good and bad. If they place particular emphasis on economic indicators they are likely to be using the similar data sets. Similarly, if they use electoral data to assess political risk, be it at federal or regional level, they will, again, be using the same data sets. A comparison of the results of the five analyses reveals that four regions appear in all of the top tens - - Moscow City, Tyumen, Samara and Sverdlovsk -- and four regions appear in four out of five -- St Petersburg, Nizhniy Novgorod, Krasnoyarsk and Irkutsk. A simple computation of the average placing of all the regions in Table 1 produces a aggregate top five of: Moscow City, Tyumen, St Petersburg, Moscow Oblast and Samara. The results of these analyses tell us as much about the data and criteria employed as they do about the 'top' regions. It is no surprise that Moscow City is a clear winner and that St Petersburg and Moscow Oblast are in the top five. The position of Tyumen (which in some analyses includes Khanty-Mansy) is explained by its dominance of oil and gas production. In fact, these analyses show a strong bias towards resource-producing regions -- Khanty-Mansy, Krasnoyarsk, Kemerovo and Irkutsk. This is because they have tended to vote pro-Yeltsin, they have faired between in economic terms and, as we shall see below, are the regions most involved in foreign trade and investment. The remaining regions one might consider major industrial centres and potential 'hubs', namely Samara in the Volga, Nizhny Novgorod in the Volga-Vyatka (potentially in competition with Samara), Chelyabinsk (in the Southern Urals) and Sverdlovsk (in the northern Urals). Tatarstan and Bashkortostan are hybrid regions being both resource producers and industrial centres; but they are also among the most independently minded Republics in the Federation. Perm seems somewhat of an outlier here, but it has resources and a substantial industrial base. What is perhaps more interesting is the regions that are not here, most obviously Novgorod. Also missing are the southern and eastern gateways of Krasnodar and Primorskiy Krays. Before considering these omissions, it is necessary to consider which regions have succeeded in attracting foreign investment. Investing in Russia's Regions The internationalisation of the domestic economy is a critical component in the reform programme of any transition economy. In Russia the 'opening-up' of the economy predates the collapse of the Soviet Union. In 1987, as part of the programme of perestroyka, foreign companies were able to form joint ventures with Soviet enterprises. The liberalisation of the foreign trade and investment process gained momentum in the early 1990s and today there are a variety of ways a foreign company may operate in the Russian economy. First, a company may create a joint venture with a Russian enterprise -- this provides certain tax benefits and the advantage of local knowledge, however, it may also mean a loss of control of the business to the Russian partner. Second, a foreign company may create a 100% owned foreign subsidiary -- this has the advantage of retaining control, but at the cost of local knowledge and identity. Thirdly, a foreign company or individual may buy shares in quoted Russian companies -- unless the foreign company has a substantial holding they are unlikely to be able to influence the management of the company. In addition there have been instances where Russian companies have refused to recognise the foreign ownership of shares, or they have issued additional shares to reduce the level of foreign control. More recently there has been a fourth route into the Russian economy, that is through the purchase of state and municipal bonds. The Federal Government has used bond issues (so-called GKOs) to fund its deficit and, as noted above, some regions in Russia have issued Eurobonds. However, in August 1998 the Russia government defaulted on its GKOs and it still remains unclear how it will meet its medium- and long-term loan obligations. The following analysis focuses on two components of the flow of foreign capital into Russia's regions, foreign direct investment (FDI) and and the activity of joint ventures and socalled enterprises with foreign involvement (EFIs). Before examining the regional distribution of foreign investment in Russia, it is necessary to put the scale of investment in an international context. According to a study by staff from the EBRD, the cumulative FDI inflow into Russia between 1989 and 1996 was US $ 5. 8 billion, 46.8 percent of the total FDI inflow into the CIS during that period, but only 13.3 percent of the total inflow into the 25 transition economies of Eastern Europe, the Baltic States and the Commonwealth of Independent States. On a country-by-country basis, Russia ranked third behind Hungary (US $ 13.3 billion) and the Czech Republic (US $ 7.1 billion). On the basis of per capita total FDI inflow, Russia ranked 16th with $ 40 per capita. In short, Russia has massively under performed when it comes to attracting foreign investment. Given the size of its domestic economy, its resource wealth and the size of the domestic economy, it should have attracted substantially more foreign capital. In 1997 the Economy Ministry stated that Russia needed to attract $ 10-12 billion in foreign investment a year to achieve economic growth and assist serious economic restructuring. By the end of 1998 total accumulated FDI amounted to $ 13.7 billion. Therefore, when discussing the role of foreign investment in the Russian economy one must be conscious of its modest proportions. There are, however, at least two reasons to suppose that the impact of foreign capital might be greater than it might first seem. First, in an environment of a total collapse in domestic investment, foreign capital is often the only source of 'new'. Second, if that foreign investment is concentrated in particular economic sectors and regions, its impact on those regions may be much greater than its impact upon the national economy (see Map 1). As Figure 1 shows, the mid-1990s saw a steady increase in the volume of foreign investment in Russia; however, the majority of that increase was due to the finance of state debt (classified as other). Foreign direct investment did not grow very quickly and portfolio investment remained modest. During 1998 the level of FDI and portfolio investment actually fell compared to the previous year. Anecdotal evidence for early 1999 suggests that investment is already substantially lower than 1998. In fact most observers suggest that substantial foreign investment in Russia is unlikely until after the 2000 presidential campaign. Examination of the sectoral distribution of foreign investment shows that of the US $ 6.5 billion invested in Russia in 1996, 33 percent went to industry (11.5 percent to the food industry), 29.6 per cent went to financial services (finance, credit, insurance and pensions) and 23.6 percent went to other market-related commercial activities (such as retail activity). Data for 1998 show that the fuel industry was the major recipient of foreign investment, followed by the food, trade and consumer goods sectors. The geographical origins of foreign direct investment in 1998 are shown in Figure 2. The most important investors are the US, the Netherlands, Cyprus, Germany, the UK and Finland. The presence of Cyprus and Switzerland suggest the return of Russian flight capital. What is also noteworthy is the absence of Japan the world's largest source of foreign investment. Which regions have been the major recipients of foreign investment activity? Whatever measure one looks at, the most striking feature of the geography of foreign investment is the dominance of Moscow City. In 1997, Moscow City accounted for 67.4 percent of total foreign investment in Russia, 78.4 percent of FDI, 85.9 percent of portfolio and 60 percent of 'other' forms of investment (see Table 2). However, its relative prominence declined dramatically during 1998. In 1998 it also accounted for 51 percent of the joint ventures operational in Russia and in 1998 56.4 percent of EFIs (see Table 3). A certain amount of this dominance may be due to reporting bias, in other words investment bound for elsewhere in Russia is registered in a firm's Moscow head office, nevertheless, even the most casual observer can not help but be struck by the rapid internationalisation of the Moscow economy. Until August 1998 this was seen as a distinct advantage, now it may seen as Moscow's Achilles' heel. In the aftermath of the August crisis, a number of foreign companies have downsized their Moscow offices, but the city seems to have weathered the crisis. Tables 2 and 3 present the 'top-ten' ranking regions for the period 1995 through 1997 in terms of FDI and the number of operating joint ventures. Both show a high degree of concentration with St Petersburg and Moscow oblast in competition for second place. The regions listed on these tables show a strong bias towards port/gateway regions and resource producing regions. This pattern is also illustrated on Map 1, which shows the regional distribution of cumulative FDI on a per capita basis. The gateway/port regions include St Petersburg in the northwest, Krasnodar, Rostov and Stavropol in the south and Khabarovsk and Primorskiy in the east. The resource regions are divided between the oil and gas regions such as Tyumen (and Khanty-Mansy) and Sakhalin, metalprocessing and mining centres such as Irkutsk and Magadan. Given the resourceorientation of Russian exports (in 1998 energy and metals accounted for 55.8 percent of Russian exports, these resource regions are also those regions most likely to be involved in foreign trade. Goskomstat data for 1997, based on customs information, show that Moscow accounted for 25.2 per cent of Russia exports to non-CIS states, followed by: Tyumen (14.5 percent), Krasnoyarsk (4.9 percent), Sverdlovsk (3.5 percent) and Irkutsk (3.1). In total, the top ten regions accounted for 64 per cent of Russia’s exports and all, with the exception of Moscow, Samara and St Petersburg, were resource-producing regions. There is also another group of regions attracting investment, represented by regions like Samara, Sverdlovsk and Nizhniy Novgorod, that are the hubs of large manufacturing regions aimed at serving the domestic market. Thus, we see regional expressions of both export-oriented growth and importsubstituting activity. The information presented in Table 4 tells us something about the activities of joint ventures in 1997. The column entitled workers ranks regions by the average size of the workforce in joint ventures in that region. The dominance of Moscow and the second play of St Petersburg are confirmed. However, the resource-orientation of joint venture activity is clear. This table also highlights the role of the exclave of Kaliningrad as an entrepot into the Russia economy. Thus, geographical location appears to be a key factor in determining the level of internationalisation across Russia's regions. Supporting Russia's Regions This final section considers the assistance programmes of foreign governments of multilateral organisations that are targeted at Russia's regions. This analysis makes no claim to be exhaustive and it must be recognised that all forms of assistance, either directly or indirectly, will have a differential impact upon Russia's regions. According to the G7, between 1991 and late 1997 the international community provide Russia with US $ 90.5 billion in external assistance. Of that sum, $ 55.0 billion (61 percent) came from bilateral sources (G7 countries, the European Commission, Denmark, Finland, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden and Switzerland) while $ 33.2 billion dollars (37 percent) came from international financial institutions. The remaining $ 2.3 billion (3 percent) came from other sources. These figures exclude debt rescheduling and represent five main categories of external assistance: balance of payments and budget support (29 percent); investment (34 percent); export credits (25 percent); technical assistance (7 percent) and humanitarian and food aid (4 percent). Figures 3 and 4 illustrate the regional and sectoral distribution of this assistance during the 1991-1997 period. The patterns parallel that of foreign investment, a concentration on the Central region and upon the energy sector. As one might expect, foreign assistance is also channelled into education and science sector as well as various social services. This brief review of the regional dimensions of foreign assistance focuses upon four programmes: the EBRD Regional Venture Funds, the European Commission's TACIS Programme; US-Russia Binational Commission's (which started life as the GoreChernomyrdin Commission) Regional Investment Initiative; and finally, the US Department of Commerce's American Business Centres. The focus of the review is upon the intent of the programmes and the choice of regions targeted for support. The EBRD's programme of Regional Venture Funds was part of an agreement reached between the G7-governments and the European Union at the Tokyo Summit in 1993. The aim of the programme is to support Russian enterprises that were privatised under the Russian Government's mass privatisation scheme. The funds are designed to assist selected enterprises to restructure and adapt to operating in a market economy. The first fund was established in Smolensk oblast in January 1994, a further three were established in 1994, six during 1995 and the eleventh and final funds was established in the Black Earth region in 1996. The programme of 11 funds involves a commitment of US $ 312 million in equity from the EBRD and US $ 208 million from the donor governments. Table 5 shows the regional structure of the funds, which do not cover all of Russia. In each case a consortium of companies from the donor countries manages the fund. For example, the Black Earth Fund is known as the 'Rabo Black Earth Regional Venture Fund' and is managed by a consortium which is led by the Dutch Rabobank International. The fund is committed to investing 75 percent of its funds in the region; the remaining 25 percent can be invested elsewhere in Russia. As of 2nd July 1998, the Regional Venture Funds has made 40 investments in 25 privatised and 15 private companies. The total amount invested was $ 64 million and the average investment was $ 1.6 million. The major problem faced by this regional initiative has been the shortage of fundable projects. It would seem that such initiatives can only work if the regional economic situation is supportive of new entrepreneurial activity. The venture funds alone cannot support economic restructuring and market reform. At present, the European Union's TACIS programme lacks an explicit regional programme. Instead it funds specific structural programmes. The TACIS Action Programme for 1998 includes the following programme components: human resources development, social protection, enterprise support, transport and telecommunications, environment and energy, food production, processing and distribution. Each of these programmes delivers assistance to particular regions. The one element of the TACIS programme that has an explicit regional identity is the system of TACIS technical offices, which have been set up across Russia to promote TACIS' activities. At present, TACIS technical offices are located in St Petersburg and Petrozavodsk (with special involvement in the Cross-border programme), Krasnodar, Novosibirsk, Ekaterinburg (capital of Sverdlovsk oblast) and Irkutsk. Through TACIS, the European Union is also helping the Russian Federal Government to devise its own set of regional policies. Following the recent economic crisis, the European Union may look at providing more direct assistance to Russia's regions. The US-Russia Binational Commission (U.S.-Russian Joint Commission on Economic and Technical Cooperation also known as the Gore-Chernomyrdin Commission) was created at the summit between President Clinton and President Yeltsin in Vancouver in April 1993. The Commission's original mandate was to enhance cooperation in the areas of space and energy, but is has since widened its activities to promote trade, assist in the development of Russian capital markets and environmental protection. There are two components related to the commission that have an explicit regional focus. The first is the U.S. West Coast-Russian Far East Ad Hoc Working Group that seeks to promote trade and investment. The priorities established by the group include: customs policy and administration, telecommunications, transport, creation of a regional investment fund, modernisation of air traffic control and implementation of commercial development of the Sakhalin shelf oil and gas deposits as well as resources in Sakha (Yakutia). The second, is the Commission's Regional Investment Initiative. This initiative was announced in February 1997 following the 8th Meeting of Gore-Chernomyrdin Commission. The aim of the initiative is to work closely with several Russian regions 'to improve their investment climates, promote normal trading relationships, and attract private investment, both foreign and domestic'. The initial programme was a pilot project and the U.S. hoped to extend it to other regions in Russia over time. The programme is see as a tripartite collaborative effort between the U.S., the Russian Federal Government and the Regional Authorities. Three regions were chosen for the pilot scheme: Novgord, Samara and Khabarovsk-Sakhalin. Judging by the information on their web site, the Novgorod programme has made the most progress. The final regional programme considered here is the network of American Business Centers set up by the U.S. Department of Commerce to help support American businesses in Russia and elsewhere in the CIS. The aim of the ABC is to provide a 'home away from home' for the visiting American businessperson. The ABC also provides various services that will help American business gain a foothold in Russia's regions. Among the services provided are: telecommunications, the finding of business partners, key contacts in the local administration and business community, temporary office space and on-site logistics. The ABC also helps run trade events and conferences to promote their regions and/or raise the profile of US business in their region. At present the following locations have ABC: Chelyabinsk, Khabarovsk, Nizhny Novgorod, Samara, St Petersburg, Vladivostok, Yekaterinburg and Yuzhno-Sakhalinsk. It is noteworthy that following the establishment of the network of ABC's in the Russian Far East the Japanese Government felt compelled to create a competing set of Japan Centres. The various programmes discussed above show the wide variety of assistance and the difference in intent between multinational and bilateral support. The EBRD and TACIS programmes have a general goal of promoting economic restructuring and marketisation in Russia, while the US programmes have a clear goal of support American political and economic interests. The two are not contradictory, but they do point to a duplication of effort between the various national and international agencies. The fact that the same regions seem to come up again and again suggests that there are a few regions of Russia swarming with western consultants and government officials (and academics for that matter), while the bulk of Russian territory is relatively ignored. This geographical concentration of technical assistance is paralleled by the concentration of foreign investment into a relatively small number of regions. Those same regions are also the ones favored by the various risk assessments. This is because those analyses pick up the relatively good economic performance of resourceproducing regions, as well as the advantages of port regions and large urban agglomerations. However, case study research on Russia’s regions suggests that many of these regions have less than progressive local administrations, which, rather than encouraging inward investment and the development of market institutions, seek to maintain local control over the key region-forming sectors. The exceptions are those regions that possess no natural resource endowment or geographical advantage and have little alternative but to try and attract foreign investment and technical assistance. Novgorod and Nizhny Novogorod are the most obvious examples. The problem here is that this model of ‘success’ is not readily transferable and is a limited benefit the majority of Russia’s regions, which remain isolated from the global system. CONCLUSIONS It is less than a decade since the Soviet Union collapsed, yet, as this chapter attests, the political landscape of Russia has been totally transformed. The fact that this process of systemic transformation is taking place in an era of globalization is of great significance. The central state has the task of orchestrating the transformation of Russia’s political and economic systems at a time when the evolution of the global system is eroding the ability of all states to control their economies and regions. In the context of contemporary Russia, as elsewhere, globalization is both a positive and negative force in terms of its impact upon centre-region relations. It is a positive force in the sense that it liberates regions and localities and enables them to develop new links with the outside world. Thus, it is a force promoting democratization. At the sametime, it enables regions to attract foreign investment and assistance in their own right and to us external sources of capital and technology to restructure and rejuvenate local economies. Thus, it is a force promoting marketization. However, these same processes also have negative consequences. First, globalization is a spatially selective process, only certain regions and localities are able to ‘hold down the global’ to attract the attention of international lending agencies, bi-lateral assistance programs and multinational corporations. Thus, globalization promotes uneven development and regional inequality as certain regions benefit politically and materially and others remain neglected. A clear example of this is the massive gap between living standards in Moscow and in the North Caucasus. Second, while globalization can emancipate the regions, it creates tension with the centre. The independent actions of Russia’s regions are a source of suspicion in Moscow. Thus, globalization complicates the relationship between the centre and the regions and it does this in an uneven way, adding to the asymmetrical nature of Russian federalism. For example, border and port regions, as well as resource rich regions find that they have greater leverage in their dealings with the federal centre because of their role in Russia’s international relations. Third, for some regions globalization represents a transfer and/or a loss of local control. This is particularly evident in Russian attitudes towards foreign investment. Having been the victims of seventy years of external control, those in charge of Russia’s regions are benefiting from a period of enhanced relative autonomy. This is in part because the federal government in Moscow has abdicated its responsibilities to the regions. True, most regional politicians still look to Moscow for financial support, but there are anxious to maintain local control over their economies. In such a context, the prospect of foreign (and even Moscow-based) control of key enterprises is seen as a threat. The net result is that few regions in Russia have actually sought to increase the level of foreign investment in their economies, quite the reverse, they have sought to protect local interests. This is particularly true of the regions that have natural resource endowments and specific geographical advantages. However, as the analysis above suggests, these regions attract investment despite the actions of the regional authorities. Thus, you have the paradoxical situation of Russia’s southern (Krasnodar Kray) and eastern (Primorskiy Kray) gateways being controlled by governors with xenophobic attitudes. As a consequence, Russia is failing to make the most of the potential advantages offered by increased integration into the global system. That said, increased integration in the future could promote the fragmentation of the Russian State unless a more durable relationship is cemented between the federal state and the regions. In short, for Russia to benefit from, and manage, both the benefits and the costs of globalization it must first deal with the challenges of federalization. Notes Spatial Differentiation and Stratification Grigory Ioffe, Olga Medvedkov, Yuri Medvedkov, Tatyana Nefedova, and Natalya Vlasova 1. Introduction Spatial variance is in the very nature of socio-economic life, so much so that it is instances of monotonous homogeneity that warrant special scrutiny rather than spatial differentiation. In regard to Russia quite a few factors underscore the significance of spatial variance. Among these are the sheer size of the country, its uneven population distribution, and the relatively low horizontal mobility compared to similarly sized or smaller economically advanced countries. Lingering restrictions of domestic mobility -particularly when it comes to Russia’s largest cities and high "friction" of distance due to low motorization and an inadequate road system reinforce the mutual separation of population clusters and enhance their potential to develop differently from one another and to stay different. In the 1990s, at least two other prominent factors added themselves to the list of spatial variance "providers." These are the rather systematic attempts of regional authorities to fence off their respective areas from the rest of the country by drastically limiting the outflow of commodities (food, first of all) in short supply, and the 1992 advent of the population decline, which has a huge potential for making the traditional migration magnets of Russia even more attractive while aggravating the labor supply and already tenuous human capital in less attractive areas. In the context of this chapter, and this book in general, this outcome seems to have a dual implication. First, the notion of fragmented space assumes graphic literary meaning as Russia’s space comes to resemble an archipelago: scattered pockets of intensive land use and vibrant economic life in a sea of social stagnation and decay. Secondly, a seemingly inherent link between spatial variance and social stratification appears to be gaining in prominence simply because more prestigious areas are becoming more restrictive and exclusive than before. Whereas in the past getting a residence permit in Moscow by means short of marrying a Muscovite required connections or duping the system, now one has to circumvent this no longer constitutional residential restriction by paying a sum equivalent to 500 minimum monthly salaries to the city. The ensuing financial filtering of prospective migrants contributes to social stratification most directly. The link between spatial differentiation and social stratification has another side. In many instances socio-economic variance leads to the emergence of spatial units of unequal quality with respect to achieving a certain societal goal. It is in such instances when differentiation may imply diverging or uneven quality of socio-economic space, whose emerging divisions thus lend themselves to value judgment or fitness ranking. Spatial processes in population have been carefully monitored and theorized upon in the West. In the US, for example, population deconcentration has been unfolding over the whole post-war period. From 1950 to 1994, major cities in the American Northeast and Midwest lost 20-45% of their populations. This was caused by the flight of wealthier households to the suburbs, the inhabitants of which came to outnumber those of the central city by 1970. Spatial dispersal in America is ongoing and apparently no longer confined to suburbs, as suburbanites show signs of relocation to communities more and more distant from the city core, oftentimes outside the metropolitan realm. In the 1970s, population decline in large cities of northwestern Europe commenced and was similarly accompanied by the vigorous growth of suburbs and some freestanding small towns. This phenomenon was perceived as the waning of long-lasting urbanization trends and spawned numerous publications on the stages of urbanization viewed as consecutive patterns in a population’s spatial redistribution. According to some authors, "the move towards ‘counterurbanization’ – identified as a negative correlation between net migration rates and population densities of regions in a country – was most conspicuous in the Netherlands, Denmark, the UK, and Switzerland. It was also evident in Sweden, Germany, Belgium, and France, but Italy, Spain, Portugal, Ireland, and Norway continued to experience regional concentration." On this basis a distinction was drawn between a pattern of population redistribution that gained the upper hand in some US regions and in northwest Europe and was associated with a complete reversal of migration in favor of suburban and rural regions and that which occurred in the rest of Western Europe, where the flows from periphery to core merely diminished. One of the most straightforward stage approaches to population redistribution belongs to Hermanus Geyer and Thomas Kontuly. According to them, "counterurbanization represents the final phase in the first cycle of urban development," so it is not only preceded by a population’s spatial concentration (unfolding earlier within the same cycle) but is followed by it as well (which signifies the commencement of the next cycle). In Russia things look different than in Western Europe and North America. Specifically, a stage "of population redistribution in which the larger settlements decline (or stagnate) in their populations due to net migration losses, while the smaller ones, such as villages and small or medium-sized 'free-standing' towns, increase their populations through net migration gains" has never actually arrived in Russia. The 1991-1994 period during which the rural population experienced sudden growth stands as an exception; it was a short-lived phenomenon exclusively driven by the acute crisis in cities in the wake of the removal of state price controls and stalling industry. Already by 1995, the situation had, formally speaking, returned to what had been normal for Russia for over a century: a positive relationship between a settlement's growth rate and size. What we discern in the Russia of today, though, is not exactly a throwback to the pre1991 situation. First, the overall negative rate of natural increase has suppressed population growth everywhere it takes place at all. Second, draining the periphery of population is not as vigorous as before. Third, although essential preconditions for Western-style suburbanization (financially feasible consumer demand, spatially flexible housing market and tertiary job base, as well as quality roads and means of transportation) are largely unavailable in Russia, the pent-up desire to relocate from congested cities has already materialized in some modest population shifts. That resulting suburbanization is for the most part a seasonal (summer) phenomenon in part derives from inertia and in part from the still tight system of residential permits. Were it not for the fear of irretrievably losing the privilege of being, say, a Muscovite, more people would opt for permanent residence outside the central city even now. That centrifugal (periphery-directed) shifts in population distribution in Russia have not been nearly as significant as in the West also has something to do with the overall spatial pattern of Russia’s population. Russia is a country with a very sparse urban network. Even in the Industrial Center and the Northwest, there is just one town per 2000 – 2500 square km of land area; in the Volga and Ural regions, there are 5000 – 6000 square km per one town; in Western Siberia 30,000 square km; and in the Far East as much as 90,000 square km per one town. "Being a country of large cities, Russia suffers from their deficit," write Georgy Lappo and Pawel Polyan, the leading Russian experts on the issue, pointing out that zones within the immediate influence of big cities account for but a small percentage of Russia's land. Russia is a sparsely settled country, and the notion of sparse settlement by no means applies only to Siberia, whose territory is "literally torn apart by distance." Siberia is Russia's classic periphery, that is, an area that not only is perceived but actually is remote from the heartland. However, many Westerners do not realize that a sense of remoteness is far more acute in areas barely 150 km from Moscow and Saint Petersburg, for example, where the perception of living in the middle of nowhere belies the actual proximity to those population centers. Of course, the primitive conditions of roads and other means of communications create this perception in the first place. But so does a sparse network of vibrant urban cores, and long-lasting centripetal trends in migration only add to this polarized pattern. Even in European Russia the average distance between cities with populations over 250,000 is twice as large as in Western Europe (314 km vs. 158 km, according to our calculations). While American cities are illsuited for such comparison (one probably needs to take the entire Standard Metropolitan Areas into account, given that the level of infrastructure available there is comparable to what is available in Russian cities or within their corporate limits), in America and in Canada the densely settled heartlands and sparsely settled hinterlands are spatially disunited. In Russia, however, they interpenetrate. For example, today the population densities in Pskov, Novgorod, and Tver oblasts (13-19 people per square km with rural population densities being 4-5 persons per square km) are on a par with many areas in Siberia and in European Russia's North. Millions of hectares of previously cultivated land have been abandoned owing to rural depopulation. Note that the three oblasts just mentioned lie between Moscow and Saint Petersburg, two principal population centers 651 km apart, comparable to the distance between the northern and the southern tips of the North American megalopolis. It appears that in Russia the area of old colonization has shed its spatial continuity and dissociated into its original nuclei, large and small. Looking like oases in a rural vastness, these nuclei have been able to cast a web of intense social interactions upon only a relatively small part of the interurban space. Social conditions for large-scale population deconcentration have not matured in Russia and are unlikely to do so in the near future. This stands in contrast to North America and Western Europe. The above casts light upon the special role of areas located just outside the boundaries of large cities. In view of the advanced process of rural polarization, one side of which is the drastic depopulation of most areas beyond two hours accessibility to big cities (in Central Russia and in the Northwest, and to some extent in the Central Black Earth Region as well), the outskirts of those cities today contain almost the only pockets of viable commercial farming. And they are also the only areas where one can find the best features of both urban and rural ways of life. The core-periphery approach, naturally, works not only at the local and micro-regional level; it can be elevated to the level of large chunks of Russia’s social space, like the Industrial Center or West Siberia. For several centuries Russia’s space expanded resulting in higher population growth rates in the newly acquired periphery. Today, the reverse seems to be the case: populated space in Russia is shrinking and becoming more fragmented at all levels of spatial resolution. There are numerous implications of this development, one of which concerns agricultural location. This chapter examines the differentiation of urban (section 2) and intra-urban (section 3) socio-economic space in the Russia of the 1990s. The "urban" section begins with factors of spatial concentration of economic activities and proceeds to analyze regional patterns of population dynamics. The "rural part" begins with the demographic situation in the countryside and then focuses on Moscow Oblast, the internal divisions of which become units of spatial analysis. 2. Urban Areas The popular Russian attitude to contrasts between cores and peripheries has always been negative (despite the fact that even or equitable spatial development is hardly possible.) This attitude is well captured in phrases like "Moscow is a wart on Russia’s body," which Russian politicians, primarily on the left, like to quote. Understanding this leads from the repudiation of spatial contrasts and value judgments to detailed studies of the causes of polarization and inequality. They can be undertaken at different spatial levels: macro (Russia’s economic regions consisting of several oblasts), meso (center vs periphery within any oblast), and micro (within an urban settlement). Our objective is to discuss available information on spatial polarization in Russia’s urban realm as such and from the perspective of relevant theories. We will specifically focus on large urban centers with over 1,000,000 population. Cities of this size are major regional foci and so processes of polarization are detectable at several spatial levels simultaneously, including meso and micro (that is, intra-urban) scale. 2.1. Meso-Territorial Concentration and its Causes Center-periphery contrasts at this level of spatial resolution have been theorized by such classics of economic geography and regional science as Walter Christaller, August Losch, and Johann Heinrich von Thunen. While Thunen viewed urban centers as markets for agricultural goods, Christaller and Losch dealt with cities as central places in an hierarchial order. Perroux’s theory of growth poles emphasized urban-based economic multipliers. Because all the above models are based on some crucial assumptions pertaining to market economy with mobile production factors, these models lead to the conclusion that cities belonging to one and the same level of spatial hierarchy should converge in terms of achieved level of development and quality of life. If this outcome, however, is not realized, it is primarily because the mobility of production factors and externalities is less than perfect. What is the situation in Russia like? What spatial process is dominant here? It is our hypothesis that concentration and polarization continue to prevail over de-concentration and a trend toward even development. We believe that administration, geopolitics, economy of scale, demand, location, and prestige exert their centripetal or core-directed pull on population and regional economy. The administration factor is privileges in the distribution of state investment that centers of regional administration enjoyed for a long time. Many Soviet researchers underscored the significance and implications of this preferential treatment. The newly acquired status of Russian Federation’s "subjects" (by oblasts and former autonomous republics) only reinforces the capital-city functions of large cities since the overwhelming majority of them serve as regional centers. If anything, the role of each region’s center has grown appreciably and in part at the expense of Moscow. Other circumstances, like the political weight of a regional leader and even physical distance from Moscow have bearing on the overall significance of the administration factor. We believe that it will continue to exert its influence in the years to come. The geopolitical factor stems from the dissolution of the USSR. As a result regional centers situated along new national borders have acquired new foreign trade and border control functions. At the same time, gravitation to cross-border centers has sharply declined. What were formerly nearby regional centers are now parts of foreign countries. Their previous economic and social functions must now be taken over by the centers that have become Russian border settlements. The example of Belgorod’s longterm gravitation to the Ukrainian city of Kharkov is a case in point, as is the now heightened significance of Pskov, whose oblast is now located along tightly controlled national borders. Economy of scale has yet to exhaust itself in Russia. So heightened efficiency of large enterprises ensuring higher return on investment continues to be a factor of spatial concentration. Consumer demand acts to sustain the already achieved concentration through a growing inequity in per capita incomes, which tend to be highest in regional centers. This, in its turn, fosters entrepreneurial activity whose concentration has no immediate connection with investment priorities. Location of businesses and new residences does not enjoy the flexibility it does in countries with higher quality roads and transportation. In Russia suburbanization does not develop vigorously, in part, because transportation costs outweigh gains associated with lower population density. As a result, the concentration of population and investment within the confines of existing urban areas goes on. Finally, prestige, however secondary a factor, reinforces spatial concentration as well. Prestige is especially important for dealing with wealthy clients, so banks, law firms, fashion design, boutiques, etc. all gravitate to clusters of such clientele, which are located primarily in large regional centers. 2.2. Factors of Deconcentration Several factors may potentially lead to a more even distribution of economic activities. These are local self-governance, regional policy, competition, growth of entrepreneurship, and communications. Self-governance invokes new political actors with ties to local economic life. Regional policy at the federal level includes such blueprints as The Federal Complex Program of Revival and Development of Small Towns of the Russian Federation Under a Condition of Economic Reform and The Federal Program of Revival and Restoration of Historic Small and Medium Towns of Russia. These blueprints, initiated in 1991 and adopted by the Federal government in 1992, may potentially lead to the development of alternative growth poles in regions. Both programs were based on a broad societal and institutional consensus regarding to the necessity of boosting smaller urban settlements, particularly those with historical landmarks. In recent years, oblasts and republics dissatisfied with the scale of implementation of these programs began to adopt measures of their own. For example, in Irkutsk Oblast a law "On the Oblast Equity Fund" has been adopted This fund aids economically weak raions by assigning financial transfers proportional to the difference between per capita local budget revenues and a minimum threshold spending. This fund is divided into two components: current financial aid (70%) and investment (30%). The analogous measures are practiced by Sverdlovsk Oblast. Some region-based programs earmark funds for the development of the new growth poles. For example, in Sverdlovsk Oblast, a program was adopted in 1996 focused on the restoration of the historic landmarks of the town of Verkhoturye within the period between 1996 and 2005. This program links economic revival of the town with functions of a religious, historic, and cultural center. Unfortunately many such programs remain on paper because of the drastic shortage of financial assets. Factors of competition and demand can potentially influence the decentralization of economic activities, but a substantial income inequality keeps this influence in check. The entrepreneurial activity and spread of small enterprises may also play a role of decentralizer as may higher land values in large cities, zoning ordinances, and ecological restrictions. However, the significance of these factors is still low in Russia. 2.3. Empirical evidence Most Russian oblasts and republics are mono-centric with the oblast/republic capitals accounting, on average, for 32% of the entire population with the maximum in Leningrad Oblast (74%) and minimum in Krasnodar and Stavropol krays (13% in both cases). Figure 1 provides some examples of oblasts in the median range of population concentration. Usually the share of the oblast capital in its (oblasts’s) population grows fast at first and then approaches the level of saturation. The city of Ekaterinburg as the administrative center of Sverdlovsk Oblast is a case in point (Fig. 2). [Place Fig. 1, Fig. 2, and Table 1 here] The concentration of economic activities may, of course, deviate from that of population. In Soviet times, though, the concentration of industrial output in large cities was very high (Table 1) and exceeding that of population. However, the economic crisis somewhat reduces the significance of this indicator, because it is in the largest cities that the industrial decline has been most dramatic. Thus the concentration of other functions, such as managerial, commercial, and financial, comes to the forefront. Small production units and joint ventures are representative of these functions, if only because they promptly react to the emerging demand. For example, in the city of Chelyabinsk are located 68% of all joint ventures of Chelyabinsk Oblast; they account for 52.7% of all oblast’s joint-venture employment. In 1995, in Russia as a whole the average regional center’s share of joint ventures was slightly above 60%. Small enterprises in general are also concentrated in oblast capitals. For example, Ekaterinburg hosts 72% of all small enterprises of Sverdlovsk oblast, and in Novosibirsk and Nizhnii Novgorod the share is close to 90%. [Place Figure 3 here] As a rule, in oblast centers the level of general unemployment is lower than in their regions (Fig. 3) because of better opportunities for side employment and selfemployment. The ratio of registered job seekers to job vacancies is more spatially variable than the numerator of this ratio, that is, general unemployment. And so in this regard the situation is much more favorable in large cities, where vacancies in many cases outnumber job seekers. Also, the possibility of youth employment and, correspondingly, life chances of youths are better in large cities. Figure 4 shows the share of unemployed under thirty years of age in the overall unemployment. [Place Figure 4 and Table 2 here] Statistics reveal that average income depends upon settlement size. For example, in the countryside incomes are almost two times lower than in urban areas. Table 2 shows differences between incomes in regional capitals and regions as a whole. Higher personal incomes immediately lead to higher buying power and thus create better conditions for entrepreneurship. True, one has to exercise caution when using income statistics. First, there are a lot of unrecorded earnings from personal auxiliary farming in the countryside and the dacha plots of urbanites. Secondly, the possibilities of side employment and a shadow economy put smaller settlements at a considerable disadvantage in terms of personal incomes. If, however, one takes cost of living into account, then the advantages of large and largest cities will look even more vivid and pronounced. For example, whereas 1995 recorded personal incomes in Moscow were three times as high as the Russian average, the cost of a standard consumer basket in Moscow exceeded the Russian average cost only by a factor of 1.3. Such income superiority typifies the city of Moscow at the most. According to the calculations of Andrei Treivish, the city of Moscow accounts for about one-third of the country's excess of officially recorded income over the normative consumer-basket spending. Even Saint Petersburg shows a much more modest income polarization vis-à-vis the rest of Russia. And yet virtually each oblast center towers over its oblast as far as income level is concerned. The gravitation of economic activity toward one center can also be viewed from the perspective of spatial differentiation in per capita housing construction and sales of automobiles and other durables. In recent years, the largest cities have substantially exceeded the Russian average in motorization. As for housing, in Soviet times the principal policy was the leveling or smoothing out the inequity in quality of life. Table 3 shows the results of this policy. [Place Table 3 and Figure 5 here] However, in the 1990s, it is unlikely that the situation continued to evolve in line with this policy. Figure 5 shows that Chelyabinsk’s share in the oblast’s housing construction has come to exceed Chelyabinsk’s share in the oblast’s population. As far as we know, similar developments take place in Eketerinburg, Nizhnii Novgorod, and Samara. Just as before, the largest cities stand out in terms of access to institutions of higher learning, because the latter are located overwhelmingly in such cities. Also of importance is the location of tutoring facilities, which are also primarily located in the large cities. Without resorting to their services, it is difficult to get accepted by a college because enrollment decisions are based on passing entrance exams. Although large cities do not stand out in terms of sheer capacity of secondary schooling relative to student population, they do in terms of quality of secondary schools. For example, in 1996, the city of Ekaterinburg accounted for 74% of all gymnaziya and 95% of all lyceum students in Sverslovsk Oblast, and 10 of the 15 private secondary schools in the oblast were located in the capital. It should be noted that while enrollment in such schools does not guarantee higher levels of education, all three mentioned school categories are characterized by better equipment, smaller classes, and higher social prestige. Polarization in education is worth mentioning, if only because schooling is one of the major channels of upward mobility. The above evidence allows us to conclude that concentration of socio-economic functions in Russia’s largest cities typifies their current stage of development. Although some growth impulses have spread out a bit, as shows up in the emerging outlying affiliates of banks and insurance companies, the largest cities appear to be the major beneficiaries even of this process. Spatial imbalances are very tenacious and smoothing them out will take a lot of time and investment. There is a growing concern in Russia that its largest urban centers develop at the expense of the hinterlands, pumping out their material and intellectual resources. Given Russia’s vast geographic space, the poles of spatial concentration typically do not overlap, which exacerbates social decay in the periphery. Such polarization is clearly at odds with political decentralization and local self-governance and can lead to social conflicts. Polarization is not derived from the transition economy. It has been inherited from the Soviet period with its ostensibly unlimited freedom of maneuver in the area of resource allocation. During the transition period of the 1990s, the largest cities have managed to take advantage of their enormous concentration of resources. Economic restructuring, the development of housing, labor, land, and capital markets are more vigorous in such cities than elsewhere in Russia, which spawns a new wave of polarization, this time not immediately related to government and/or central planning. In some ways processes at micro-level, that is, within large cities, resemble those at meso-level. This similarity does not necessarily show up in the concentration of economic output in certain urban quarters, but it shows up in new business formation, relative prestige, and corresponding population re-distribution. Recent publications focusing on the city of Moscow show the immense social prestige of the historical downtown and some other circumscribed areas inside the city. For example, Olga Gritsai mapped locations of new business services in the city of Moscow based on the 1995 telephone directory. She came to the conclusion that most law firms, stockbrokers, real estate agencies, and almost all international banks are confined to the relatively small central prefecture of Moscow. Figure 6 singles out real estate agencies as another example. The downtown and the Southwest continue to be the most prestigious areas of the city. Downtown pockets of new housing construction and renovation attract those wielding power. The ensuing spatial segregation of social groups unfolded in Soviet times as well, but it is in the 1990s that it was given a major boost. Location is now the most important component of housing prices in Russia’s large cities. [Place Figure 6 here] The average Russian does not change his or her place of residence nearly as frequently as the average American. Evidently lack of capital rivets a person to one and the same place. In contrast, possessing capital ensures one’s presence in several places simultaneously due to unlimited access to transportation and communication. In today’s Russia one’s place of residence is a no less meaningful aspect of one’s social status than income, education, and origin. The lower level of spatial mobility only increases the significance of location. According to Weber’s sociological tradition, lifechances are one’s opportunities to take advantage of the economic and cultural benefits supplied by the society. With the spatial distribution of such benefits being exceedingly polarized, life-chances appear to be polarized as well. It is safe to say, for example, that the larger the settlement size that one was born in, in Russia, the better are the odds for professional success. 2.4. Urbanization and Population Decline Russia’s population decline has been widely publicized and analyzed. However, between 1992 and 1999, the decline in the numbers of de jure urban residents was 2.4 million, whereas total population declined by 2 million. Why did the decline of urban population exceed that of the total population? How was this urban population loss distributed among cities of different size categories? How was it distributed among Russia’s regions? In this section we attempt to address these questions. Figure 7 shows the "S" shape curve that is well known in the theory of urbanization stages. The curve has a distinct turning point and indicates the entry of Russia into the terminal stage of urbanization. The same figure shows that the initial stage of urbanization was dominant in Russia up to 1926. From 1914 to 1926 the percent of urban population in the territory of present-day Russia had barely increased (17% and 17.4%). By 1923, World War I, followed by the Civil War and the Red Terror, resulted in urbanization dropping to 14.9%. By 1926, Russia was at the urbanization level that the United States had attained in 1855. Russia had a millennium of history behind its major cities, unlike the US. Potentially, this could have led to an early commencement of the acceleration stage. Instead, within the first three decades of the 20th century, Russia's urbanization was delayed. [Place Figure 7 and Figure 8 here] The acceleration stage took place in Russia between 1926 and the late 1980s. It was long overdue when it started. The acceleration stage was accompanied by heavy cost and the sacrifice of millions of human lives, a consequence of devastating wars and of cruel political decisions. Much was changed in the urban hierarchy of Russia because the state run economy favored the largest cities, which reshaped, in turn, the geodemography of the nation. Socialist urban life-styles in congested cities and the constant shortage of housing accelerated the demographic transition. Figure 8 shows the curves of population change in Russia's cities by size group. These curves reveal a flip-flop in the rates of urban population change. Until 1987, the urban hierarchy was being shaped by the trend towards "bigness". Figure 8 confirms that the fastest growth rates characterized the group of cities with more than 1,000,000 residents. As soon as the acceleration stage finished and the terminal stage commenced, the growth paths of these "millionaires" were disrupted. And in 1992-1996, the fastest growth of "millionaire" cities eventually gave way to the fastest decline. Incidentally the resident population of Volgograd, the smallest "millionaire," actually oscillates around the 1,000,000 mark. As a result, fluctuations occur in the upper curve (Fig. 8), because Volgograd is intermittently in and out of the largest size group. Between 1992 and 1998, the combined population of cities with more than 1,000,000 residents decreased by 2.2 million. This was the largest change across all size groups of cities. Both in 1992 and 1998, Volgograd was part of the group, so overall population decline is not due to this city’s erratic trajectory. During the same period, 1992 to 1998, the combined population of cities from 250,000 to 1,000,000 residents, declined by 0.6 million. In contrast to that, the smaller sized cities had collectively gained 1.6 million. Although the advent of population decline in Russia does not seem to be immediately related to the dissolution of the Soviet Union, we believe that population losses in the largest size group of cities may be associated with this event. In the Soviet period "millionaire" cities depended heavily on the long-distance exchange of goods with other union republics. Thus, cities of more than a million residents became the casualties of the Soviet Union’s disintegration as long-distance trade decreased. The regions with urban population loss or gain in 1992-1998 are specified in Figure 9. The eastern margin of the Ural region and the diagonal across the North region serve as a dividing line on the map. It separates areas with a preponderance of growing cities from areas in which most cities’ population numbers decline. East of the Urals cases of growing cities with more than 250,000 residents are nearly absent. Tyumen and Surgut, cities of the oil industry, are exceptions to this rule as is Khabarovsk, a city that profits from border trade with China. The opposite case is found in the Central Chernozem region, wherein between 1992 and 1998, all cities larger than 100,000 gained populations. The Central region, Northwest, and Volgo-Vyatka showed population decline in major cities and growth in numerous smaller cities. In Povolzhye (Volga region) growing cities are located mainly in Tatarstan. In contrast, in the North Caucasus the cities with non-Russian majorities lost population, primarily due to outmigrating ethnic Russians. [Place Figure 9 here] It appears, therefore, that, on the one hand, regions with marginally developed urban systems have approached the terminal stage of urbanization, whereas this stage is reached also by regions with advanced urban levels such as the Central and Northwest. The former case is associated with the inflated demand for labor in Siberian and Far Eastern cities during the Soviet time. For several decades the Soviets attempted to hastily extract important resources in those frontier areas by injecting manual labor. Problems emerged in the post-Soviet years as soon as economic efficiency became important and the subsidies from the federal budget stopped or drastically decreased. The Russian media features numerous reports about the exodus from the frontier communities due to unemployment, under-employment, and non-payment of wages by bankrupt enterprises. Urban population decline in more developed European regions of Russia is conditioned by factors similar to those in some developed nations of Western Europe. The most influential factor is changing age structure. Specifically, deaths outnumber births because the former occur, mainly, in the large cohorts of seniors while the latter occur in small cohorts of young people. [Place Table 4 here] The current numerical decline of Russia’s urban population does not lead to population decline in all cities. Table 4 provides evidence for 69 cities that experienced growth during the period of the overall urban population decline. From 1992 to 1998, these cities increased their populations notwithstanding the terminal stage of urbanization. All of them are sizable communities with over 100,000 residents. In 27 cities the average annual rates of growth from 1992 to 1998 were even higher that in the last Soviet years, 1989 to 1991. We have discovered that the most prominent post-Soviet growth occurs in cities with "import substitution" operations. These cities took over functions that were formerly fulfilled by other parts of the Soviet Union. For example, Stary Oskol of Belgorod Oblast grew by compensating for the loss of iron ore from Krivoy Rog, Ukraine. From 1992 to 1998, Stary Oskol increased its population from 184,200 to 109,800 – a 2.2% average annual rate. Cherepovets, a city in the North economic region, grew modestly but steadily, at 0.3% per year, because its integrated steel works replace the metal that Russia got previously from Donbass, Ukraine. Novorossiysk and Kaliningrad grew, at 1.03% and 0.63% per year respectively, because they expanded port operations and replaced the services of Odessa and Riga, now foreign ports. Volodga grew, at an average annual rate of 0.77% from 1992 to 1998, because of its lucrative trade in timber. There is a growing market for timber in Russia and also in forest-poor Ukraine and Kazakhstan. 2.5 Overall and Regional Components of Urban Population Decline There are three components to urban population change: natural increase, migration, and re-classification, that is, change in settlement status. Figure 10 provides information on their relative significance in 1992-1996. The main component of population "loss" is negative natural population increase, minus 2.51 million over these years. [Place Figure 10 here] This moves Russia's urbanization further into the terminal stage. The birth rate in urban places is typically low. The crude birth rate per 1000 urban population has decreased from 9.8 in 1992 to 8.3 in 1996. The crude death rate in the urban population is typically high, the result of a larger proportion of aged people. The rate was 13.4 in 1996, 14.4 in 1995, 15.0 in 1994, 13.8 in 1993, and 11.5 in 1992. Poor medical care and environmental degradation are contributing causes of unfavorable mortality rates. Net migration to cities was negative in 1991 and 1992. Those two years stand as an exception to the overall powerful migration pull of Russia’s cities. Prior to 1991 and after 1992, Russia’s cities have been gaining from net migration. In 1993, net migration compensated for 43% of the population decline in cities caused by the excess of deaths over births. In 1997, the compensation increased to 57%. That the negative rate of natural increase in urban areas is not outweighed by migration explains why Russia’s urban population has declined more significantly than its entire population. A minor component in urban population dynamic, reclassification, exacerbated the decline. The most frequent case of reclassification involves moving a small urban place (poselok gorodskogo tipa) to a rural settlement status. In most cases, this change in status stems from population decline as well as from the recognition that the settlement in question lacks what Russians perceive as mostly urban amenities. In 1997, the reclassification rate for the country as a whole amounted to –0.41 per 1000 urban residents. This was little changed from the 1993 rate of minus 0.65 per 1000. During 1992-1998, the number of settlements in the ‘poselok’ category dropped from 2164 to 1963. Figures 11 and 12 show distinct regional patterns in urban population change due to the discussed demographic causes. All regions with gains from net migration are in the densely populated part of Russia's territory and in the oil- and metallic ore-rich areas of West Siberia. For example in 1997, the Altai Republic, Khanty-Mansi Okrug, and Belgorod Oblast showed the highest gains from net migration. Belgorod Oblast has held the most stable place amidst the most attractive migration magnets of Russia. Other stable migration destinations have been Stavropol and Krasnodar Krais and Ulyanovsk and Volgograd oblasts. [Place Figures 11 (A & B) and 12 (A & B) here] Urban settlements in East Siberia, Far East, and in the European North experienced population decline due to out-migration (Fig. 11). Homelands of Siberian aboriginal peoples stand out in this regard. In 1997, Chukotka had the highest out-migration (-57.5 per 1000 people) and Taimyr had the second-highest rate (minus 33.9 per 1000.) Evenk and Koriak Okrugs experienced heavy outflow as well. In contrast, many cities of Russia’s European section gained from net migration. This is certainly so for the Central economic region, Russia’s heartland. In 1996 this region added 116,300 newcomers to its urban residents. Net migration to the Center accounted for nearly 35% of all Russian regions’ population gain through migration. In 1997, the Central region got 120,100 new urban residents from net migration, which represented 40.5% of that gain in the nation. The heartland attracts many people because of diverse job opportunities. The heartland, with its highest level of privatization of industrial assets, also leads in making money. Generally, provinces sorted into groups by net migration rates mirror those sorted by natural increase. Provinces that lose urban population from one demographic cause are not losers from another demographic cause. Urban communities in thinly settled frontier areas are losers from net migration, but they gain from natural increase because of preponderance of younger age cohorts. Russia’s main triangle of settlement, with Saint Petersburg, Novosibirsk, and RostovDon at its apices, has plenty of urban communities that gain population from net migration, but lose population due to negative natural increase. More often than not, gain is outpaced by loss, because of a very high percentage of aged urban dwellers. The regional pattern of reclassification is island-like. Each year it is limited to a few provinces. Between 1992 and 1998, the most dramatic decline in the number of small urban places, poseloks, took place in Karelia (from 40 to 11), in Tomsk province (from 16 to 1), and in the Komi republic (from 43 to 38). All of them were demoted to rural villages. Settlements subjected to this downward reclassification are usually attached to unproductive mines, sawmills, and to abandoned military camps. The above analysis shows that population-related generalizations at the all-Russia level of data aggregation may be misleading. Trends in several regions do not replicate the curves of Figure 8 or bar graphs of Figure 10. The urban population of the Far East, for example, was negatively affected by all three processes: migration, natural increase, and reclassification. In other words, urban settlements in that region lost population because the death rate exceeded birth rate, out-migration prevailed over in-migration, and reclassification turned former urban communities into villages. In 1997 the total decline in the resident urban population of the Far East from all three causes was 59,000. In 1993 the decline had been as high as 100,200. The situation is quite similar in East Siberia. The total population change for all urban communities of Russia in 1997 was negative: the decline of 264,900 residents at the rate of –2.47 per 1000. But at the same time the Central Chernozem region and West Siberia gained population. ----The above sections on urban population allow for important conclusions that we relegate to the end of this chapter. However, one question still needs to be addressed at this point: how to reconcile the huge significance attached to spatial polarization with the fact that the largest cities have experienced the most significant population losses in the 1990s? In our view, two circumstances have to be considered in this regard. First, population numbers in the largest cities may be substantially under-recorded. Although currently unconstitutional, the practice of issuing residence permits has not been discontinued by large-city authorities. This leads to significant contingents of migrants whose status is not unlike that of illegal immigrants in the USA, only in Russia most of these illegals are actually fellow countrymen. Quite a few seasonal and temporary workers from former Soviet republics and from other foreign countries are not recorded as permanent residents either, even though some of them may in fact overstay their permits. This by no means undermines the significance of the above observations in regard to population decline in large cities: in any case those in transition form a special population category anyway and there is no assurance that they will stay in large cities for good. Secondly, the spatial polarization at a meso-geographical level (pertaining to cities and their oblast-size regions) evidently coexists with some local de-concentration. In other words, the foci of population concentration expand as areas immediately adjacent to the city line enter the stage of accelerated growth. With this in mind we now move to examine developments in the Russia’s vast intraurban space. 3. Rural Areas 1. Factors of spatial differentiation Based on available research, we assume that there are at least three underlying factors of spatial differentiation of Russia’s extensive rural or inter-urban space. First, Russia is a country of widely separated large cities. Historically it has been their primary role to cast a net of social contacts upon surrounding areas thus integrating the region’s population into one society. Both Russian geographers and demographers have pointed to the dearth of these integrating focal points in Russia – and not just east of the Urals, but in the heartland as well. Accessibility to these sparsely distributed cities under conditions imposed by an inferior network of paved roads could not help but become a powerful stratifier of Russia’s inter-urban space. We ought to expect that rural areas are made different by varying accessibility to cities and towns. As mentioned by Ioffe and Nefedova, "in European Russia a second-order (non-classic) periphery, a kind of hinterland within a heartland" has always existed; and the Russian prigorod appears to be vastly different from the western, particularly American suburb, of which prigorod is a direct lexical equivalent. Secondly, prior to 1991, Russia’s rural population had been declining for decades. The pace of this decline was spatially variable. The variable pace and length of rural outmigration affected upon the age composition of rural populations, because migration is normally age-selective with young adults and their children having a higher propensity to move out of economically and socially disadvantaged areas. The age composition, in turn, exerted influence on population dynamics with a highly asynchronous commencement of negative natural increase in Russia’s rural regions. We thus ought to expect that today’s rural demographics are spatially variable. Thirdly, rural demographics cannot help but affect prospects for economic reform in agriculture. A point was made by Wegren, Ioffe, and Nefedova that, until recently, "almost exclusive attention has been paid to the reform of legislation, rural institutions and policies in the agricultural food system". And while this emphasis has not been entirely misplaced, "lost among analyses of the Russian rural sector has been an awareness that people matter to the outcome of reform." Indeed for reform to succeed an adequate base of human capital must exist. We may, therefore, expect that while the legislative base of reform is being taken care of – or rather neglected – at the federal level, the actual and vitally important proceedings and accomplishments, e.g., privatization of land and production activities, are spatially variable, not in the least because of the differential accessibility of rural areas and varying rural demographics. We begin with what can be called the spatial re-alignment of the rural demographic situation in the 1990s. The oblast will serve as our unit of analysis. We will then proceed to uncovering spatial changes in rural population dynamics within a single oblast – Moscow – which has oftentimes been in the vanguard of changes subsequently replicated by other Russian areas. 3.2 Spatial Change in Russia’s Rural Population Dynamics After 1989, Russia’s long-lasting trend of rural population decline was reversed, and in 1991-92, migration from urban areas to the countryside exceeded the opposite flow. However, by 1994, the migration flow into urban areas already had effectively recovered its late 1980s level, and the "normal" direction of net migration (that is, out of the countryside) had been restored as well. Some flow into the countryside, though, continues; but it is declining and is being sustained almost exclusively by migrants from former Soviet republics. What has been the spatial pattern of Russia’s rural population changes? We distinguish between two groups of rural regions: A) those with a positive rate of natural increase in population, and B) those with a negative rate of natural increase. Group A is further subdivided into A1) those with net migration inflow and A2) those with net migration outflow. In its turn, group B has three subgroups: B1) those with net migration outflow; B2) those with net migration inflow short of the natural population decline; and B3) those with net migration inflow offsetting the natural population decline. We then compare 1990-91, 1993-94, and 1996-97 regional groupings. The logic of the whole analysis is reflected by Table 5, while three maps (Figures 13, 14, and 15) and Table 6 reflect our attempt at regional classification. [Place Table 5, Figures 13, 14, and 15, and Table 6 here, exactly in this order] We believe that the type of population dynamics, from A1 to B3 (Table 5) creates a specific environment more or less conducive to a robust rural economy. It seems clear that while B3 can be labeled revival, B1 is more like decay with B2 being a transitional case. Likewise, A-regions are those with a healthy demographic situation, with the qualification that A2s may in fact be regions with delayed or lagging demographic evolution. In 1990-91, 62% of Russia’s rural population still lived in A-regions. Because age- specific fertility has been traditionally high in the countryside, it takes a long time for outmigration to reduce the total fertility rate through aging. While age-specific fertility remains higher than in urban areas (as is the case in most societies; Russia is no exception), the number of prospective parents declines gradually as out-migration drains them from the countryside. In 1990-91, only in the Industrial Center, Central Chernozem Region, and Volga-Viatka, from which country folk have migrated for a very long time, was the rate of natural increase negative. In 1990-91, the dominant or largest single group of regions was A2 (Fig. 13, Table 6). It included 53% of all regions, and accounted for 43% of the total rural population. These regions had positive natural increase (that is, births outnumbered deaths) and negative net migration (that is, outmigration exceeded in-migration) with the latter typically outweighing the former. This group included the east and north of European Russia and most of Siberia. However, because migration is almost always age-selective, it is bound to change the age composition of population and reverse the ratio of births to deaths. This is exactly what happened between 1990-91 and 1993-94. In 1990, the rate of natural increase in rural Russia was 2.2 per 1000 population; by 1995, it had dropped to minus 5.6. While it is primarily the long-lasting migration outflow that had been actually instrumental in this change, two other factors also contributed. First, numerically small generations born in the 1960s and ‘70s entered the childbearing age (the echo of the World War 2 and a sharp reduction in fertility in the 1960s are to blame). Secondly, child bearing was often postponed due to economic crisis. One of the crucial changes between 1990-91 and 1993-94 shown by Table 5 is that the overall number of people living in A-regions had been reduced from 62% to 17%! It is highly ironic that this rapid deterioration in rural demographics occurred simultaneously with the reversal of rural-urban migration flows favorable to the countryside. Indeed, whereas in 1990-91, only 37% of rural population lived in areas with the net migration inflow, in 1993-94, as much as 74% did. In 1993-94, the largest single group of regions was B3, indicating signs of rural revival. It included the southern part of European Russia (North Caucasus, southern Volga, part of Central Chernozem, and south Ural. On a map it was a continuous zone ( see Figure 14) and it looked like rural revival was northbound. This could not help but fuel optimism as to the prospects of this revival. No sweeping change occurred between 1993-94 and 1996-97, yet the grounds for optimism were shattered. While 71% of the rural population still lives in areas with migration inflow, the sweep of negative rates of natural increase is even wider: 89% of rural population now lived in such regions. On the other hand, B3 regions reveal neither clustering nor the spatial continuity of the previous period (compare Figures 14 and 15). In 1996-97, four separate pockets of rural revival show up: ethnically Russian areas in the North Caucasus (Krasnodar, Rostov, and Stavropol) -- long-term migration magnets; Leningrad Oblast; Bashkortostan, Samara, and Sverdlovsk oblasts; and Novosibirsk, Tomsk, and Tyumen oblasts in Siberia. On the other hand, B2 regions, forming the single largest group in 1996-97, are contiguous and include quite a few regions of European Russia. Rural population continues to decline in these regions; but newcomers, predominantly ethnic Russians from Central Asia, are relatively plentiful. What is unfolding in the countryside of these regions is a kind of rural revival, but on a narrower demographic basis than in B3 and than could have been expected in 1993-94. It is unclear, however, how lasting this trend will be. 3.3. Spatial Change Inside Oblasts Earlier research summarized in Ioffe 1990, 1991 and in Ioffe and Nefedova 1997 showed that of all spatial trends affecting rural development within oblasts, polarization is the most pervasive one. To some extent this polarization is rooted in natural, coreperiphery contrasts in population density and land use intensity associated with the radial pattern of road networks. What is significant, however, is that core-periphery gradients in population density have been consistently getting steeper as outlying rural areas have been subjected to a more intensive out-migration compared with peri-urban ones. There are numerous implications of this demographic polarization, particularly in the agricultural sphere. First, agricultural output per unit of land becomes subject to the same spatial gradients that typify rural population density. In other words Russian "suburbia" accounts for an ever-increasing share of this output, an outcome alien to most Western countries. This outcome, however, is nothing unexpected considering the importance of manual labor in the Russian agriculture. Since it is the so-called periphery -- located in most cases outside the two-hour accessibility range to oblast capitals -- that is the single largest segment in most oblasts, the result is clear. It is, in fact, the most all-encompassing and profound decay that the Russian countryside has been subjected to since the years of Ivan the Terrible. This time there has been no outright coercion that immediately led to decay; it is the cumulative legacy of so many coercive periods in the past that has brought this situation about. By now more agricultural land has been abandoned in the Non-Chernozem Zone of Russia alone than is under farming in the whole of the European Union. We are witnessing the formation of what literally amounts to fragmented space with pockets of viable rural economy resembling small islands in an ocean of spontaneous/wild reforestation and social degradation. Secondly, as in post-Soviet years, multiple forms of farming have come to co-exist; but their penetration of each of the above segments of the countryside appears to be formspecific. Most economically viable socialized farms, that is, kolkhozes, sovkhozes, and their surrogates in the 1990s (in keeping with a purely nominal change of status), are to be found in the Russian-style suburbia, while whatever is alive in the periphery is for the most part subsidiary farms languishing under the umbrella of the same kolkhozes or joint-stock companies that only exist on paper to allow for channeling some supplies and services (seeds, veterinary aid, fertilizers, and pesticides) to rural families. In most Russian oblasts there is also a transitional case that we would call the semi- periphery. The semi-periphery forms a special, transitional case. Whereas the periphery contains archaic but occasionally robust subsidiary farms, and exurbia boasts of viable socialist agriculture, the semi-periphery seems to be a no-man's land. Depopulation has affected the semi-periphery to almost the same extent it has the most outlying districts, leaving myriads of abandoned villages. On the other hand, unlike in exurbia and the periphery, neither viable collective farms nor a robust subsistence economy (for those who choose to stay) are available. So the void is now being filled by two kinds of developments: summer-time recreational land-use (dachas or recreational second dwellings) and, to a lesser extent, private family farming. Both developments would in fact gravitate toward exurbia if land were available there, but since in most cases it is not, the semi-periphery, located 1-2 hours from provincial centers, becomes the only option. People now populating the semi-periphery tend to be the most open-minded: they are relatively less addicted to archaic communal bonds or to reliance on strong leadership and socialist enterprises. Dacha-owners, private farmers, and forced migrants at the crossroads of their lives may constitute the human capital with which the long-term prospects of the Russian countryside at large rest. However, the infrastructure in the semi-periphery cannot be upgraded solely on the basis of private investment, and its current condition is not conducive to economic development. Thus the irony of the situation is that, at this formative stage of the market economy in Russia, there is an unavoidably crucial role for the government in creating extrinsic conditions for economic growth. 3.4. Moscow Oblast: a Case Study of Fragmented Space We would now like to characterize changes which have been unfolding through the 1990s within the confines of one oblast. We will specifically focus on changes in population distribution and agriculture. Our task is to show that these changes have been unfolding in a spatially stratified environment: what matters in particular is the distance from the center, the city of Moscow in this case. The nature of this task, therefore, requires that we preface our brief analysis by a description of the network of spatial units that we used. Internal Divisions The principal features of the area's spatial structure are the overwhelming dominance of one center; radial spokes and concentric rings; an asymmetric "green west -- smoky east"; and the availability of significant urban-industrial clusters, including those at junctures with other oblasts. The complexity of the spatial structure and the economic functions performed by the area has given rise to a multiplicity of division patterns. We followed two habitual patterns: radial sectors and concentric rings. The analysis in this section will be based only on the latter pattern. [Place Figure 16 here] Grouping all 39 raions by the order of their proximity to Moscow, we identify four rings (Fig. 16). The first, inner ring has about a 20 km radius and more or less comprises the so-called Forest-and-Park Protective Belt. The second ring, including second-order neighbors of the central city, is within a 20-60 km radius and is more or less equivalent to the Exurban Zone (Prigorodnaya Zona) in physical planning schemes. The oblast's shape is far from a circle and the second zone's outer limits coincide with the border of the whole oblast in the northeast and southwest. The third ring is 60-100 km away from the city of Moscow, while the fourth ring includes the remote eastern and western raions. Spatial Pattern of Population The current population distribution by concentric ring is featured in Table 7. Altogether the inner ring or the first zone, which is the closest to the city (Fig. 16), accounts for 26% of the oblast's population and only 6% of its land area. The zone's average population density, 603 people per square km, is close to that in New York City's suburbs and declines steeply with distance from Moscow (Table 7). Note that the 199098 increase in population density in the inner ring is associated with the continuing contraction of this ring due to cession of some of its land to the city of Moscow (over 30,000 ha in 1990-98), not with population growth. If the land area of the first zone had remained the same as in 1990, its population density would be 541 people per square km or about the same as in 1990. The largest share of the oblast's total population (39%) lives in the second zone/ring. The distribution of rural population reveals the same pattern (Table 7), and the average size of a rural settlement declines from 480 residents within a 10-km radius from the city line to 130 residents in rayons located beyond 100 km, while the number of rural settlements per 100 square km declines from 23 to 8 over the same zonal range. [Place Table 7 here] Planners have attempted to reduce the settlement contrasts around the city of Moscow by restricting growth in its nearest satellites and promoting growth in the most distant ones. In reality, however, it was the two closest concentric rings where population grew the fastest. In the 1990s, statistics have recorded population declines both in the city of Moscow and in Moscow Oblast. This is associated less with migration than with the about-face in the natural increase of population. This change has been characteristic for Russia as a whole; however, the aging population of Moscow and its oblast took a heavier toll than elsewhere. In 1990, for example, the natural increase was plus 22 per 10,000 in Russia as a whole, while it was minus 22 in Moscow Oblast. By 1995, the former indicator reached minus 57, while the latter, minus 104. Net migration in 1995, plus 34 in Russia and plus 60 in Moscow Oblast, could not outweigh losses incurred by the landslide excess of deaths over births. In 1996 and 1997, the negative rate of natural increase in Moscow Oblast somewhat lessened but was still significant: minus 91 and minus 84 per 10,000 population respectively. The 1990s population dynamics by rings is revealed by Table 8. In the beginning of the 1990s, population losses in the two most remote rings slowed down. We believe it was because at the start of the economic crisis it seemed to many people in Russia that it would be easier to make ends meet in a provincial or semi-provincial environment than in the vicinity of a large city. This perception was still there in 1992-93 but was waning. It was waning because many people realized that they could maintain the inflow of food from their household farms without permanently living in the countryside and small towns, and it was only in Moscow and its immediate environs that multiple employment opportunities are available and extra earnings possible. As a result, after 1993 the rates of both urban and rural population decline began to mirror the traditional core-periphery gradient with peripheral population decline being steeper than exurban or peri-urban. And in 1996-97, population growth even resumed in the inner ring while rural population losses in the periphery intensified (Table 8). [Place Table 8 here] It thus appears that what seemed to be the forerunner of a consistent, Western-style population de-concentration was no more than a 1990-92 glitch related to the most acute stage of urban crisis. In other words, the voids between fragmented pockets of vibrant socio-economic space are not filling up. Also the urban way of life continues to be more attractive in the oblast; and those unable to enter the central city as permanent residents choose to cast anchor immediately outside Moscow, usually in an urban apartment complex. Among other things, suburbanization is kept in check by low motorization and inferior roads. In 1995, the number of private vehicles per 1000 population in Moscow Oblast did not significantly exceed that of the Russian Federation as a whole (89 and 84 respectively). However, in the city of Moscow, it was considerably higher (138). Although the paved road network density in the oblast is the highest in Russia -- 308 km per 1000 square km of land area versus 27 km per 1000 square km on average in the Russian Federation – it is substantially lower than in the West and even below the level of Estonia and Latvia. In the 1990s, the net inflow of migrants to Moscow Oblast began to exceed that to the city of Moscow. Thus in 1995 and 96, the former was 53 and 63 per 10,000 population respectively, while the latter was only 28 and 41. However, observations of Moscowbased experts give reason to believe that this central city vs. oblast ratio of incoming migrants may be a statistical artifact. It most probably derives from Soviet style migration restrictions that the city of Moscow clings to despite their unconstitutionality; as a result throngs of de facto residents of Moscow are unaccounted for. According to some estimates, for example, up to 80% of bus and trolley bus drivers in Moscow are temporary employees from CIS countries. And this is but one population category that skirts migration records. That migration to the city of Moscow may in fact exceed migration to Moscow Oblast does not mean, of course, that the latter is insignificant. Significant it surely is: during the first six months of 1996 alone, net migration amounted to 20,100 people. Of them 8300 came from other post-Soviet republics. The number one "supplier" of migrants, just as for Russia as a whole, was Ukraine, with 31% of all migrants; 13% came from Kazakhstan, 12% from Uzbekistan, and 23% from the Transcaucasus. Of those migrants whose place of origin was in Russia, 34% came from the Industrial Center (including a few Muscovites, but unfortunately not identified in the statistics); Siberia and the Far East contributed 31%; the European North, 8%; and Northern Caucasus, 7%. Three-quarters of all incoming migrants settled in urban places in Moscow Oblast. This is short of the percentage of urban population in Moscow Oblast. However, the few who settled in the countryside are not enough to increase population there appreciably. In 1993-96, the rate of migration inflow was inversely proportional to distance from the city of Moscow. Thus, 81 migrants per 10,000 population were recorded in the first ring; 64 in the second; 33 in the third; and only 25 in the most remote ring. Thus the distribution of migrants testifies to the on-going packing of the already most densely packed areas of the oblast. Agriculture As everywhere in Russia, agricultural output draws from three major sources: big or socialized agriculture represented by former collective and state farms and their current incarnation in the face of joint-stock companies, etc.; subsidiary or household farming, that is, growing food in rural residences’ backyards; and registered private farms. A quite substantial additional source of food comes from parcels of land located in the country but owned by urbanites. In Moscow Oblast the proportions of agricultural output shape up differently from Russia as a whole. For decades large farms have fared better in Moscow Oblast that almost anywhere else in Russia, primarily because the oblast was better supplied with labor in terms of both quality and quantity and received more investment per unit of land than any other Russian sub-division. The largest urban market for perishable produce influenced this preferential treatment, while the better labor supply largely derived from higher quality of rural infrastructure. Subsidiary or household farming in Moscow Oblast, while also a sizable asset, has never had all the spontaneous incentives it typically gains in areas poorly supplied with domestic and foreign food through local retail outlets. [Place Figures 17, 18, and 19, and Table 9 here] In Russia the notion of exurban (prigorodnoye) agriculture has long commanded the attention of agrarian analysts because of its heightened intensity and concentration on perishables. In fact, rings of outwardly declining agricultural land use intensity -- of the kind shown in Figure 17 that applies to the late 1980s -- still girdle every Russian city and constitute another peculiar dimension to the whole issue of fragmented Russian space. Because we lack statistics for the 1990s that would be comparable to those of Figure 17, we illustrate the point with characteristics like those in Figure 18 and Table 9. Note that dairy is the leading specialization of the oblast’s agriculture. Figure 18, however, shows a slightly different picture: it looks like two factors explain the variance in grain yields: proximity to Moscow and fertility of soil, the latter being the highest in the southeast (Zaoch’e). However, in the mid-80s, when we compared the significance of these two factors by means of multiple regression of public farms productivity, it appeared that 65% of the variation in agricultural output per unit of land in Moscow Oblast was due to proximity to the city of Moscow, whereas only 7% was due to the impact of variation in natural fertility. This result has definitely been influenced by a substantial co-periphery gradient in the number of cattle (Fig. 19). Because the first classic work on land use intensity and specialization of farms surrounding a market center was authored by Iohann Heinrich von Thunen in 1826, rings shown in Figure 17 and implied by Figures 18 and 19, are usually referred to as Thunian rings. In the West, however, the Thunian model has long abandoned its original area of specialty and migrated to intra-urban studies (as a means to explain a bid rent and land values). Western textbooks on economic geography still feature examples that fit the original contribution Thunen made to the field of agriculture, but these examples are sought in poor, Third World countries. For instance, Peter Dicken and Peter Lloyd focus on the environs of Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, while Frederick Stutz and Antony de Souza make their case based on the surroundings of Jaipur, India. It appears from our analysis that the area around Moscow in fact should quite satisfy those in pursuit of Thunen’s persistent relevance to agricultural location. The chief reason his model is no longer appropriate to Western farming patterns is because the enormous progress in transportation of perishables to urban markets has made formerly steep location rent gradients gentle. In other words, it is no longer economically necessary to assign, say, production of animal feed or milk, let alone potatoes, to suburbia/exurbia where residential developers always outbid farmers. Thus the differential rent associated with the natural fertility of soil by far outweighs Thunian location rent (that is, the significance of proximity to consumers) as a factor of farm location. Obviously this has not been the case all along. As Jean Gottmann noted as recently as 1961 in his classic study of the North-American Megalopolis, "a farm with good soil usually commands a better price than one of the same size with poor soil, but only if their locations are equal. The rockiest pasture ten miles from Boston is more valuable than the finest black loam in central Illinois." Now this observation of Gottmann is obsolete: what used to be a rocky pasture ten miles from Boston is most probably a densely packed suburban subdivision with some of the highest real estate prices in the nation. The same observation, however, is by no means obsolete as far as Russia is concerned, as our analysis has purported to demonstrate. True, in the 1990s agricultural land uses eventually began to be squeezed out of the Moscow environs’ inner ring: just in 1991-96, the inner ring, containing only 5% of the total agricultural land of the oblast, accounted for as much as 30% of the overall reduction of agricultural land (374,000 hectares = 100%) of agricultural land in the oblast. However, an average hectare of farmland in the innermost ring still produces 10 times more meat and 3-4 times more vegetables than in the remaining rings combined. Given such a core-periphery gradient in agricultural land use intensity, the expediency of land transfers from exurban agriculture may be called in question. At a time when the overall agricultural output is declining almost everywhere in Russia, intensive exurban farming grows in importance, especially amid popular anxiety over the alleged loss of national food provision security. 4. Conclusion Polarization is the most pervasive spatial trend both in urban and intra-urban realms of Russia. It spells not only strikingly uneven population distribution but also the uneven distribution of life-chances. The largest cities of Russia and their immediate environs continue to be islands of relative prosperity. The factors of spatial de-concentration of population and economic activity have not gained importance. The above spatial trend exists against the backdrop of Russia’s population decline. Although it suppresses growth of large cities, it does not allow for alternative growth poles either. This is particularly true for Siberia, where almost all cities larger than 250,000 residents have declining populations. In Russia spatial polarization of populated space also unfolds against the backdrop of initially sparse settlement. Its layout is different from the world’s other vast countries and so the outcome of polarization is different as well. While in the United States, Canada, Australia, and China densely packed heartlands and sparsely packed hinterlands are spatially disunited, in Russia they inter-penetrate. That is, even the areas of oldest human colonization, like those between Moscow and Saint Petersburg are "torn apart" by distance: there are islands of dense settlement immersed in depopulated vastness, so the whole settlement pattern resembles an archipelago. That people are currently migrating back to the most socially hospitable western and southwestern regions of Russia does not alter the above pattern, because most migrants set down in cities or in their immediate environs. After a short-lived reversal of rural-urban migration, the countryside resumed losing population. Rural depopulation, resulting from the excess of deaths over births, could not be reversed even for a short time. Instead the trend accelerated. There are, nonetheless, several pockets of rural revival in Russia. Inside Moscow Oblast, spatial developments are in line with the general polarization trend. Not only population re-distribution, but also the spatial pattern of agriculture are marked by steep core-periphery contrasts. When this chapter was completed we came across a provocative article by Boris Rodoman, a keen observer of Russian life. The thrust of his article is in line with our conclusions. According to Rodoman, the polarization of Russian space has deepened over the 1990s. He divides this space into three segments: capital cities and their immediate environs, provinces (all the remaining land within 2 km from railway lines, highways, and paved streets with year-round traffic), and the boondocks. The last category encompasses 10 million square kilometers or about two-thirds of Russia. Developments within this last segment are the antithesis of the modernization that has affected capitals and their surroundings. Pervasive signs of regress include abandoned villages, spontaneous reforestation of previously cultivated fields, rapacious cutting down of forests, lack of social services, and the profound decay of communication infrastructure – in contrast with the communication revolution in and around the capital cities with their widening access to internet and cellular phones. "The spread of internet and mobile phones," writes Rodoman, "does not preclude but only sets off a paradoxical situation: in most of Russia, population is being alienated from transport and communication because of rising prices and lowering incomes. An ordinary telephone is still off-limits to rank-and-file villagers, and the radio-broadcasting network dies away while postmen no longer reach outlying villages, and more and more people cannot buy a TV set or repair an old one….One way or another most Russians are plugged into ‘global civilization’ because they keep close to roads. But the minority that do not are cut off as is the bulk of the land." This spatial polarization is inherently linked with social stratification. Those services that are of no use for the elite disappear. For example, in many instances a peripheral settlement is unplugged from a cable telephone network precisely at the moment that local bosses acquire cellular phones. "Owners of bio-toilets, air conditioners, and buyers of bottled drinking water are less interested in mass sewage treatment, and in quality of piped water and street air. The clean and lively space equipped with modern conveniences lessens, shrinks around the elite, and the remaining space is driven into dirt and dark." For those who frequent only the large cities of Russia, the above image may seem surreal. However, it is not. The notion of "fragmented space" that appears in the title of this book is far from just metaphorical. Russia’s space is indeed torn apart and pockets of vibrant socio-economic life are like oases in a social desert or islands in a sea of stagnation and decay. Notes DEMOCRATIZATION Introduction: Is Democracy Developing in Russia’s Regions ? Vladimir Gel’man, The European University at St.Petersburg* James Alexander, Northeastern State University Andrei Degtyarev, Moscow School of Social and Economic Sciences For most Western and Russian scholars who have observed recent political developments in Russia, the evaluation of the Russian political regime as something "between authoritarianism and democracy" is common. Scholars have widely employed "quasi-," "semi-," "pseudo-," "proto-" and other descriptive adjectives to qualify evaluations of democratic development in Russia over the last several years. How relevant are these approaches for analyzing democratization in Russia, however? To provide a complete answer to this question, one must take a comparative perspective. There are two different, but overlapping dimensions to the comparative study of national politics: First, political researchers often make cross national (i.e. inter-national) comparisons. There are many examples of scholarship comparing the experiences of Russia and Eastern Europe, Latin America and Southern Europe as they make (or made) the transition from authoritarian regimes. Although the theoretical foundations, as well as the implications, of such comparative studies are still uncertain, this approach has become quite common in contemporary Russian politics. The second dimension of comparative studies of Russian politics, involving crossregional (i.e. intra-national) comparisons, is still neglected among Western and Russian scholars. Although several comparative cross-regional studies have appeared in recent years, they have been primarily concerned with governance, separatist activism, the elections of regional governors or have simply described current developments without employing specific theoretical frameworks. Furthermore, numerous case studies of transition at the regional level have been published, but they often ignore the comparative potential of such case studies. An interesting puzzle arises from actual cross-regional comparison, as well as the comparison of multi-level (national and regional) political developments: If democracy is developing in Russia’s regions, how can we explain the significant diversity of these developments? Are the regions less "democratic" than Russia as a whole, and why are some regions more or less democratic than others ? The varying perspectives presented in this chapter go a long way toward solving this puzzle. Part of the solution includes the application and development of theoretical concepts. When examining the development of democracy, Robert Dahl’s model of democracy, polyarchy, is a good place to start. Including two vital dimensions of democracy, competitiveness and participation, Dahl used polyarchy to establish a matrix of political regime ideal types: Table 1. Dahl’s model of political regimes Competitiveness/Participation Low High High Polyarchy Competitive oligarchy Low Hegemony Inclusive hegemony While the application of such a neatly constructed model would seem to be relatively straightforward, for Russia’s developing political regimes — both on national and regional levels – such is not the case. On the one hand, the application of a minimalist view of competitiveness and participation in the regions shows clear evidence of democratic development. The competitive elections of governors, as well as regional legislatures, accompanied by inclusive participation, based on universal suffrage. Thus, Dahl’s test of polyarchy seems to be clearly confirmed as almost half of the regional governors (primarily appointed by President Yeltsin) lost their offices in a wave of elections in 1996-1997. On the other hand, such a picture is analogous to making conclusions about the average world temperature through calculations based solely on the temperatures of Antarctica and California’s Death Valley in mid-August. There is great variance across a spectrum of intervening measurements that is ignored. This is the case for Russia, where there are many possible paths of political change across the 89 regions. Furthermore, despite clear signs of democratic development, the frequency of officially sponsored interference in electoral contests and the ineffectiveness of public participation undermines such an evaluation. These practices are widespread in Russia’s regions. As discussed below, developments in the city of Moscow and the Komi Republic show the challenges to democratic development in most regions. Moreover, political developments in even the most "democratic" regions are still highly fragile, often depending on the political allegiances of political actors. Such was the case in Nizhnii Novgorod’s 1998 mayoral elections, where regional authorities quickly denounced the results when the "wrong" candidate came to power. Using that candidate’s criminal past as the official pretext, the election was quickly invalidated. These issues raise the question of whether Russia’s regions have achieved what Dahl refers to as the "procedural" and "substantive" dimensions of democracy. Procedural notions of democracy generally focus on the existence of formally democratic institutions, such as a written constitution that recognizes a practice of regularly scheduled elections. Substantive democracy goes farther to add the norms of behavior and belief that underlie the political activities of elected officials and the existence of popular liberties. Within this context, the political institutions of Russia’s regions, including the legislature, the executives, and judicial branches must be investigated. There are many other issues that must be examined in a comparative fashion, including: law making, the existence of separation of powers, local government autonomy, electoral practices, the role of political parties and interest groups, voluntary associations and more. Taking such a broadly comparative perspective, Vladimir Gel’man highlights important distinctions among formal and informal political institutions and their impact on regional political developments. Gel’man’s contribution begins the discussion of regional democratization through the development of an analytical model that builds on the democratization theory developed over the last few decades. Adapting the contentions of Valerie Bunce that traditional approaches to democratization focusing on Latin America and Southern Europe may not be applicable to post-Soviet developments, Gel’man constructs a four-celled matrix for evaluating political change in the Russian regions. For analytical purposes, he examines the regions as if they were independent, national entities. In doing so, Gel’man’s presentation underlines the diversity of political change within the regions and shows the challenges of democratization in a country as large and varied as Russia. The controversies of regional democratization in Russia are, of course, only a part of the general problems of democratization. Narrow explanations, such as provided by theories of socio-economic modernization and political culture fail to solve the regional puzzle. As there are many difficulties in explaining the democratic possibilities of a whole country, the in-depth examination of particular regions, and their unique political challenges, provides a valuable perspective that informs the larger, national question of democratization. As the sections by Andrei Degtyarev and James Alexander clearly show, however, although polar opposites in many areas of development, the city of Moscow and the Komi Republic have more similarities than differences in terms of electoral competitiveness, popular participation and the operation of regional political institutions. As for Gel’man, Degtyarev takes an institutional approach to the analysis of Moscow’s city politics. He shows the emergence of a single actor, Mayor Yurii Luzhkov, resulted from the assertion of executive power, the concentration of overwhelming political and economic resources, the limitation of representative institutions as well as local government, and the elimination of political alternatives to the mayor’s office. Indeed, state-based semi-corporatist forms of political representation developed a form of horizontal accountability, as the political machine penetrated all levels of city politics and undermined any previously existing vertical accountability. The case of Moscow demonstrates the effective strategies of regional political elites to avoid political competition. Thus, democratization is still pending in Russia’s capital. In his examination of the Komi Republic, Alexander departs from the institutional analyses presented by Gel’man and Degtyarev. While institutional development is not absent from the discussion– in fact, this section does address post-Soviet institution building in the region– the focus of the analysis is upon the relative development of pluralism in Komi. In this fashion, Alexander employs a civil society approach to assess the impact of competing groups on policy-making within the Republic. Rather than examine policy-making as a whole, however, he focuses on the political controversy concerning the establishment of local self-government, an issue that several local organizations identify as key to the substantive development of Komi’s procedural democracy. Ultimately, Alexander finds that the establishment of local self-government emerges less from internal Komi political struggles than from the intervention of the federal courts. This chapter draws together the general and the particular in order to portray the complexities of Russian regional political development. As you will see, an answer to the question heading this section is still in process. In striving to solve Russia’s regional puzzle, the discussion that follows further contributes to the ongoing search for new frameworks of analysis, which could be helpful for understanding Russian politics as a whole. Regional Regime Transitions in Russia: Actors, Institutions and Uncertainty Regional Political Regimes in the Russian Context: A Framework for Analysis The term "political regime" is commonly applied in varying political contexts – such as constitutional models (parliamentary or presidential regimes) or forms of government as a whole (democratic or authoritarian regimes). However, these classifications are not always applicable to studies of politics in transition, where such forms are ill-defined and sometimes change very rapidly. In light of these issues, the understanding of political regime in cases of transitional society should be reexamined. Thus, my use of the concept of "political regime" is purely functional. It is a set of: 1) actors with resources and strategies and 2) political institutions (which are understood here not as a set of organization, but as a set of rules and norms). This definition is not related to institutional designs or ideological schema such as, for example, totalitarian regimes. The first dimension of a regime includes two ideal types: on one extreme is the dominant actor, who structures all political opportunities for other actors; on the other extreme is the unlimited competition of actors for dominance. Thus, we create a dichotomy of a monocentric non-competitive regime and a polycentric competitive regime. The second dimension of a regime is based on the distinction between formal and informal institutionalization processes in "new democracies." This dimension also includes two polar types, related to the supremacy of formal institutions (such as legislation, separation of powers, local government autonomy, elections, political parties, etc.) and informal institutions or arrangements of informal practices (such as particularism, clientelism, shadow economic relations). The former is associated with the principle of "rule of law", while the latter could be classified as "arbitrary rule". Applying this concept of political regimes to regional politics in Russia gives rise to new challenges. One might argue that the dependence of regional regimes on national political developments must be accounted for in making such an analysis. Yet, there is no empirical evidence of consistency in federal policies toward the regions, either nationwide or toward particular regions. Since the late 1980s, the degree of political independence in Russia’s regions has increased. After the wave of gubernatorial elections from 1995-97, the federal influence on regional politics became even more insignificant. Therefore, it is useful to analyze regional political regimes in Russia, and to treat these regional entities as if they were nation-states. Within this framework, national authorities (as well as other actors outside of the region) may be regarded as "external" actors. That is, one may consider their impact on regional politics as if analyzing the impact of international influence on national polities. As noted above, the post-Soviet period of political development clearly demonstrates the large-scale effects of diversity in Russian regional political regimes. In the late 1990s, the variety of political regimes includes features of pluralist democracy in St.Petersburg, authoritarianism in Moscow, a semi-democratic "elite settlement" in Nizhnii Novgorod Oblast’, and even "warlordism" in Primorskii krai, as well as hybrid regimes in other regions. The scholars of Russian regional politics need to explain this variation. Why have once nearly identical administrative units in the Soviet empire developed in such different directions over the last ten years? And in which regions can we expect, if any, movement toward democracy — in terms of political competition within the framework of formal institutions ? There are two approaches for solving this regional "puzzle" from a comparative perspective. First, the "structural" framework connects the causes and consequences of political changes on macro-level variables, such as the level of socio-economic development, or on popular values and attitudes as well as social capital. Initially, however, these explanations are at the very least challenged by the actual practices of Russia’s regional politics. We cannot truly employ the prism of socio-economic determinism to show that the absence of political competitiveness and the domination of informal institutions makes the political regime of pre-industrial Kalmykiya equal to that of advanced industrial Tatarstan. It is also hard to explain the emergence of completely different political regimes in the city of Moscow and in the Sverdlovsk Oblast’, as both regions exhibit clearly pro-democratic and pro-market orientations in mass voting behavior. As a result, the issue of applicability of this framework to Russian regional politics will remain on the agenda of future discussions. Second, the "procedural" framework explicitly rejects the idea of "objective" preconditions to democracy or other forms of political regime. Instead, this approach generally explains the causes and consequences of political regime change through the analysis of the transition process itself. This approach uses the composition of actors, their interactions and their strategies during the transition period as the main set of variables. This view, however, is also insufficient for solving the aforementioned regional puzzle. It seems useful for understanding how transition processes occur, but not why particular political events occur (or do not occur). This approach is undermined by a teleological schema of political development, or some kind of "iron law of democratization." According to such a perspective, all transitions will eventually arrive at democracy as the final stage. Yet, there are no well-founded reasons for why this should be so, save for macro-historical speculations. At least, in the case of Russia we know the point of departure (authoritarianism), but there is no way of knowing a priori the destination. The potential gains of these frameworks can be combined (while their "flaws" can be eliminated) by the use of a configurative (or "genetic") methodological approach. The core idea of such an approach includes analysis of the role of different factors in a new regime’s emergence--from the beginning until the end of the transition process--and then tests their impact through a number of case studies. Such an empirically-based theoretical model might then be explored and generalized. In this discussion, I shall employ genetic methodology to analyze the impact of late-Soviet regional political development (or the prior regime type) on post-Soviet regime transition and consolidation. Following previously defined dimensions of political regimes — competitiveness and institutional type — what can we learn from this link? Or, more concretely, what kind of regional peculiarities (if any) were more favorable for the emergence of post-Soviet political competition within the framework of formal institutions (i.e. for emergence of democracy)? For this purpose, I will analyze the genesis of political competition in advanced democracies and then apply the implications to nascent Russian regional regimes. I will begin by considering certain theoretical and methodological issues. I shall then attempt to explain the emergence of differing political regimes in the post-Soviet transition by examining the development of particular regions. I will close by presenting the implications and generalizations emerging from this discussion. Cleavage Structures and Institutional Changes Those scholars who initially observed historical roots in the development of the competitive political systems in advanced democracies, commonly accepted the central place of conflicts over modernization in the emergence of democratic politics. The structure of these cleavages reproduced conflicts between social groups during the industrial revolution and nation-state building, and then became "frozen" in the form of the party systems in these societies. These social cleavages had been carried into the political competition by mediators (or political entrepreneurs). Thus, intra-elite conflicts rather than societal conflicts are regarded as the foundation for the development of political competitiveness. In a broader sense, the main dimensions of a political regime — actors’ competitiveness and the predominant institutions — is significantly dependent on the structure of social cleavages, which emerge during the transition process. Intraelite cleavages emerging from the ancien regime can make or break the inevitable competition among actors during the early stages of the regime transition. This is especially important for the mode of the breakdown of the ancien regime. The "freezing" of intra-elite cleavages at the final stage of regime transition creates the conditions for the consolidation of new regimes. Yet, how does the formation and mobilization of these cleavages impact the regime transition process in Russia’s regions ? Cleavages — both on a societal and elite level — only became evident during elections in Russia. They are a byproduct of the Soviet modernization process. Industrialization, urbanization and mass migration formed the basis for societal cleavage, which may be seen in conflicts between a developed "center" and an underdeveloped "periphery." However, for regional politics, at least in those regions focused on the politics of the capital city, this cleavage has simultaneoulsy been referred to urban-rural and centerperiphery cleavages. Big cities — regional capitals and their metropolitan areas--were centers of simultaneous social, economic and cultural modernization for the surrounding area, while the remainder of the region falls into the semi-periphery or even periphery. This latent cleavage in the late-Soviet period is still neglected. Political regimes that existed in the USSR from the mid-1950s until the late 1980s — both on national and regional levels — were commonly regarded as non-competitive. Even pluralistrevisionist scholars, who analyzed regional politics in the Soviet Union during that period, observed significant limitations on competition among actors and the development of interest groups that was not accompanied by public contestation in the electoral arena. The center-periphery cleavage in the late-Soviet period was accompanied by contradictions in the two systems of economic governance of regional resources — industry and agriculture. The industrial system of governance, primarily associated with the large-scale military-industrial and fuel and energy complexes, was decentralized on the regional level and highly dependent on national ministries. In contrast, the agricultural system of governance was highly decentralized on the national level, but centralized in the regions, especially in grain producing regions. These systems of government produced, respectively, phenomena of departmentalism and localism (vedomstvennost’ and mestnichestvo, i.e. sectoral- or local-based clientelist networks)- EXPLAIN. Regional Communist party committees served as mediators between the two systems and integrated the regional government as a whole, while also pursuing their own interests. Modernization processes tend to lead to differentiation and rising complexity in the local governance of big cities, in which most regional resources are concentrated. Thus, city governments acquired more autonomy than the regional governments (more "ruralized" than "urbanized"). This autonomy provided structural pre-conditions for city-region conflict, which was different, although overlapping, with the industry-agriculture dichotomy. Thus, in the late-Soviet period the structural conditions of actor differentiation and interest conflicts had appeared. Yet, due to the continuing existence of the non-competitive Soviet political regime, these contradictions were latent. The balance of resources among the major latent actors (i.e. agrarians, industrial leaders, and city governments ) varied from region to region. Therefore, the allocation of these resources provided grounds for future cleavages and for the emergence of competition among actors during regime transitions. Cleavages could not emerge at all in some underdeveloped regions with weak latent actors, and either had limited significance due to the relative domination of some of actors over others or, conversely, played a crucial role in the future competition among actors. The opening of the political system and emergence of open intra-elite conflicts during the early stages of transition was not the classic clash between "hard-liners" and "softliners", but was related to the changing balance of power and the fluctuating values of regional resources that emerged out of policies from the center, in this case an external actor. During the 1990s, the center was a major source of institutional innovations, which determined the foundations of the formal institutions in regional political regimes. The major institutional changes which are important here were: 1) changes in the separation of powers between the executive and legislative branches; 2) a more autonomous system of local government; and, 3) the installation of electoral practices. These innovations were inconsistently realized due to the way in which they were implemented, and their impact was contradictory — across and within the different regions. The explanation for these contradictions is directly related to the structural characteristics of regional political developments. The center launched political innovations as discrete institutional changes. Yet, on the regional level these innovations were either accompanied or not by their incremental implementation. In other words, these innovations acted as a seed which had the potential to sprout in soil that had not been well prepared. Obviously the political consequences of institutional changes in the regions depends highly on the existence of internal actors who are interested in using these innovations for their own purposes. They serve to translate the innovations into concrete institutional change. Thus, the regional cleavage structure determined the limits of an actor’s political opportunities and the limits of institutional change. Therefore, structural cleavages and the opportunities to overcome them during the regional regime transition processes were the main factors impacting the institutional changes. In those regions where cleavage structures have negligible impact on regional political regimes or where their role was eliminated by effective patronage politics, institutional changes were successfully adopted by dominant actors to their own purposes. Yet, in regions where structural cleavages provided a number of competitive actors or where patronage politics was insufficient to establish a non-competitive elite settlement, these cleavages created a framework for successful installation of institutional changes. During the conflict for power, the main agents of institutional change and the installation of formal institutions were those actors who did not have enough resources to become the dominant actor. In contrast, dominant actors, or those actors who try to acquire this position, have little interest in the formal limitation of his/her strategies. Thus, for the "weak" competitors, the construction of formal institutions serves as a weapon in the struggle for survival. The opportunity for local government autonomy secured city governments (i.e. mayors) a number of arbitrary powers, while elections provided an opportunity to increase their political resources, even if these powers were not used for a decisive victory over their competitors. The launch of formal institutions in regions with structural cleavages that are unavoiable narrows the sphere of informal institutions and undermines the basis of patronage politics. The establishment of institutional guarantees for local actors autonomy strengthens these cleavages and limits the chances of a return to patronage politics. The additional process of regional political development, the adaptation of social cleavages to electoral politics, tends to occur through mass mobilization. Thus, actors were needed to create their own vehicles in the form of competitive "parties of power." The sustainability of these cleavages prevented a "zero-sum" outcome from electoral competition. Thus, if a condition of actor autonomy exists, holding competitive elections means the survival of: 1) the political competitiveness of actors through mechanisms of mass politics; and, 2) the inevitable role of formal institutions to create the rules and norms of regional political regimes. These circumstances have a significant impact on the crucial stages of regime transition: uncertainty and outcome. Regime Transition and Uncertainty Early in their seminal book on regime transition, O’Donnell and Phillipe Schmitter raise the issue of transition from certain authoritarian rule to uncertain "something else", which could be democracy or a new authoritarian regime. Despite this acknowledged degree of uncertainty, almost all works in this field are based on some kind of "iron law of democratization." Explicitly or implicitly, this type of research has been based on teleological schema of political development. According to such an approach, all transitions will sooner or later achieve democracy (at least, in Dahl’s "procedural" sense) as the final goal of political development. But there are no well-founded reasons why this should be so, save for macro-historical speculations. This kind of teleology of history seems similar to a pure Marxist-Leninist paradigm of "historical materialism." But why not employ an alternative paradigmatic approach to analyzing regime transition-transition as an open-ended process? Speaking purely in functional terms, the process of regime transition (i.e. the shift of one political regime to another), regardless of the regime type itself, includes several stages: 1) the decline and breakdown of the previously-existing "ancien regime"; 2) some kind of uncertainty in all elements of the political regime, 3) the outcome of uncertainty, meaning the installment of a new political regime; and, 4) the institutionalization of a new political regime (regardless of whether it is a democracy or something else). The crucial points in the process of regime transition are stages 2) and 4) – the breakdown of the ancien regime (i.e. "entry" into uncertainty), and the installation of the new regime (i.e. "exit" or "outcome" of uncertainty). This "gap" of uncertainty differs completely from the "transition to democracy" model, where the installation of democracy results from the breakdown of the authoritarian regime by default. Uncertainty is a crucial stage of transition, which is distinct from uncertainty in stable regimes. As Valerie Bunce has noted, the distinction is that within authoritarian regimes the positions of actors are more or less certain, yet the institutions are ill-defined (or uncertain). In democratic polities, however, the institutions are defined (or certain), while the positions of actors are uncertain or, at least, not defined a priori. During transition periods, both these elements of political regimes - the position of actors and the institutions – are uncertain to varying degrees. The key characteristics of uncertainty lie in the uncertain position of actors and an institution-free environment. Actors are free to fight for domination within the polity using all means of power maximization, but not for the creation of democracy. Even those politicians who call themselves democrats have no intentions of losing their positions to other actors. Such rational actors would reject an idea of competitive democracy, which needs an establishment of formal institutions for free and fair political competition, and threatens the loss (or, at least, limitation) of their powers. Indeed, the maximization of one’s own powers and the minimization of the powers of any other actors who potentially could challenge his/her position, fulfills a rational actor’s strategy in a stage of uncertainty. For certain regimes, this strategy is limited either by institutions (in democratic regimes) or by the opportunities of other actors, such as their positions or resources (in authoritarian regimes). During a period of uncertainty, actors either have no institutional limitations or have insufficient information about other actors’ resources. If one actor has enough resources to overwhelm all others, s/he simply occupies the position of the dominant actor. This position means an absence of limitations on the "leader" due to the relative weaknesses of other actors. If the resources of several actors are more or less equal, their struggle for survival could develop into a form of bargaining, if actors use a compromise strategy, or, in the case of the use of force, in a form of permanent violent conflict, such as Thomas Hobbes’ "war of all against all". A period of uncertainty – even large-scale and long-run – cannot exist forever. This stage must inevitably come to completion. The outcome (or exit) of uncertainty is a kind of reaction to the "entry" into uncertainty. Thus, a partial application of the aforementioned Karl/Schmitter schema of modes of transition engenders the development of a matrix similar to Table 4 that focuses on scenarios of outcomes of uncertainty. Variables in such a matrix include: 1) the position of actors and 2) their use of strategies during the period of outcome of uncertainty. The first of four possible outcomes of uncertainty, war of all against all involves a decision by actors about outcomes, but does not yet qualify as an "exit" from uncertainty. If actors use force strategies of force, without one actor possessing overwhelming resources over others, the war of all against all will continue, probably evolving into new forms. The "warlordism" described by Kirkow in Primorskii Krai's political regime is the typical result of such a scenario. Nevertheless, from the viewpoint of new regime installation, this scenario of outcome of uncertainty is not regarded as a unit for future analysis. A second scenario could be realized if the use of a force strategy became successful for one of the actors, and s/he achieved the position of the dominant actor. The result of this scenario is a dominant actor victory in a zero-sum game based on the principle of winner takes all. The third scenario of outcome of uncertainty could be developed as a result of an explicit or implicit agreement between the dominant actor and other actors over the common acceptance of institutions, which secured them their positions. This scenario is called an elite settlement, using the term by John Higley and other authors. The final outcome of uncertainty is the balance of force among actors, as well as the danger of defeat in a zero-sum conflict, that leads to the use of "weapons" in the struggle for survival. These self-perpetuating weapons are the regular use of democratic and/or legal institutions to define the field of combat. This outcome is called a struggle over the rules, quite the opposite of war of all against all (i.e. struggle without formal rules). As will be shown below, the varieties of scenarios of outcomes of uncertainty in Russia’s regions were contingent upon previously existing cleavage structures as well as upon modes of transition. Those regions, where intra-elite cleavages either did not emerge, or had been eliminated due to the policies of dominant actors, are generally close to the winner takes all or elite settlement scenarios. Only if cleavages strengthen during the outcome of uncertainty in the form of formal institutions will a struggle over the rules became inevitable. Recognizing that the matrix is simply an analytical tool, I examine several Russian regions representing these ideal-types provides for a clearer explanation of each scenario and its impact on a new political regime. This brings us from theoretical considerations to the comparative analysis of Russia’s regional political regimes. Scenarios of Outcomes of Uncertainty Winner Takes All: Saratov Oblast’ The reasons for the emergence of a dominant actor, who maximizes his/her power through the use of force strategies, may vary widely. The long duration of uncertainty and weakness of cleavages in underdeveloped regions provides opportunities for "outsider" populists to seize all power. This assertion of power by top executives in new democratic polities is an option in the winner takes all scenario. It may result from the decay of the previous political regime after long-run and large-scale uncertainty in a war of all against all. The case of Saratov Oblast’ is typical in this respect. Sergey Ryzhenkov evaluated the political struggle in this region during 1991-96 as the aspiration for the (re)establishment and assertion of the "obkom" position. This position is characterized by total political, economic and ideological control over the state sector and public life through the establishment of a hierarchical system of government without any control over the governing group". Yet, none of actors in Saratov were able to achieve such a goal. Despite strong localism in the late-Soviet period and the emergence of an intra-elite cleavage in the form of a conflict between the city government and an agrarian group in the post-Soviet period, a "rebellion" of subordinate city groups failed due to a lack of resources. This conflict continued over a period of five years, and the position of all actors have been weakened. Under these conditions, most of the actors were forced to agree to an assertion of executive power as a "lesser evil." Thus, conflict was resolved as a zerosum game when the former vice-mayor of Saratov, Dmitrii Ayatskov, came to occupy the position of the Governor. With the rebellious actors weakened, the political competition in Saratov Oblast’ has fully disappeared. The winner takes all scenario is similar to those "scenarios" without any breakdown of the ancien regime. These types of political regimes have emerged in some Russian republics, such as Tatarstan, where the ancien regime of the late-Soviet period directly transformed during the post-Soviet period into a power monopoly of the governing elite without open intra-elite conflict. In referring to the political development in Brazil, Juan Linz classified these regimes as an "authoritarian situation" rather than an "authoritarian regime." The principal distinction here is that the formal institutions of a democratic regime still survive (i.e. legislatures, legislation, elections, and political parties), but they have little influence on the decision-making process. The dominant actor has no obstacles to exclude other actors from the political process and secure direct or indirect control over the political society and the media. Any expectations that the dominant actors will disappear in the future have little foundation: under conditions of an absence of real alternatives, successful governments can survive, secure popular support, and diminish any evidence of uncontrolled political activity. Overall, the winner takes all scenario is likely to enhance the power monopoly of the dominant actor and the supremacy of informal institutions. The consequences of this scenario are the emergence of political regimes with numerous aspects of authoritarian rule. These regimes could be relatively stable, and the prospects for their democratization are minimal. Elite Settlement: Nizhnii Novgorod Oblast’ The scenario of elite settlement is similar to a "pact" which includes the reorganization of elite interests and the achievement of substantial compromises among competing actors over the crucial political issues. This perspective is commonly accepted by scholars of political transition that see pacts as the most effective (fast and peaceful) means of democratization. However, pacts which occur during the breakdown of the ancien regime are quite distinct from agreements achieved among actors simply for the sake of an end to uncertainty. The former (such as classical Spanish "Moncloa Pact") focused on defining formal institutions, such as the rules of public contestation during regime transition. Alternatively, the latter is based on the actors’ intentions to secure their positions and, thus, to consolidate the new regime under conditions that minimize competitiveness. In a transition to democracy framework, pacts serve as a mode of democratization. But the outcome of uncertainty through pact scenario serves to keep democratization pending, or, at least, to diminish the unpleasant consequences of democracy, such as the danger of an actor losing his/her power through public contestation. This kind of elite settlement is based on explicit or implicit agreements between the dominant actor and his/her competitors over the sharing of powers, or the sharing of spheres of influence in a political market. The formation of a "minimal winning coalition" of dominant and subordinate actors is an immediate result of these agreements. The formation of this coalition has multiple goals, including preventing the breakthrough of political outsiders (who are not included in the elite settlement) to powerful positions. Among Russia’s regions, the case of Nizhnii Novgorod Oblast’ is typical of this scenario. This region had developed departmentalism in the late-Soviet period, and an autonomous city government as well as an industrial directorate which led to some intra-elite cleavages in the post-Soviet period. When appointed in 1991, Governor Boris Nemtsov had no influence over regional elites. Nemtsov was limited to an ineffective force strategy, yet achieved several important informal agreements with the majority in the regional legislature, a number of enterprise directors, and parts of the regional administrative elite. Ultimately, intra-elite conflicts were eliminated, and subordinate actors became loyal to Nemtsov as the dominant actor, yet they had acquired greater security in their previous positions. Nemtsov used this strategy to establish more effective regional government performance and for successful conflict resolution within and outside the region in ways that worked to his own benefit. At the same time, the political competition of actors had been limited. During the 1995 gubernatorial elections, Nemtsov won with an overwhelming majority; his vote totals were more than twice that of his closest challenger. In 1997, however, Nemtsov was appointed as a first deputy prime minister of the Russian government and left Nizhnii Novgorod. Thus, the basis for the regional elite settlement was undermined. A scholar in Nizhnii Novgorod has characterized the main features of the regional political regime under Nemtsov as follows: 1) the prevalence of executive authority over the legislature; 2) an informal contract of mutual loyalty between regional and national authorities; 3) the indirect control of regional authorities over the media; 4) the neutralization or limitation of real or potential centers of political opposition in the region; and, 5) the patronage of regional executives over public associations (both over political groups and "third sector" NGO’s) in exchange for their loyalty. Although he referred to these features as "regional authoritarianism," the relative autonomy of the legislature and political parties, the absence of explicit violations of political and civil rights provided more grounds for classifying the impact of Nizhnii Novgorod’s elite settlement on regional politics as a hybrid regime, or "semi-democracy." The achievement of the elite settlement does not mean, however, the sustainability of the political regime itself. It is challenged by the informal institutionalization of arbitrary rule that undermines functioning democratic institutions. In the case of Nizhnii Novgorod Oblast’, core decisions about a regional program of economic reform in 1992 were issued not by the legislature (or by any other formal institution), but by an informal coordinating council, which included the executive and legislative heads of the region and City of Nizhnii Novgorod. The continuation of these informal practices of decisionmaking provides a pre-condition for the danger of power assertion, such as occurred when the "wrong" candidate (discussed above) won the mayoral race. Regional authorities quickly invalidated the elections and called for a new race. Thus, public contestation was limited from above. Nevertheless, in the next round another challenger won, finally breaking the "elite settlement". This kind of elite settlement is generally fragile, and changes in the balance of resources among actors easily undermine its stability. The breakdown of the elite settlement either results in movement toward an "authoritarian situation" (if the dominant actor strengthens his/her position), or "entry" into a new cycle of uncertainty (if the dominant actor loses his/her position). The elite settlement scenario of outcome of uncertainty includes the sharing of powers between dominant and subordinate actors in order to limit public political contestation, and establish the supremacy of informal, rather than formal, institutions. These regimes are fragile and very dependent on changes in the political situation. Speaking more generally, this scenario tends to act as a transition between winner takes all and the following scenario – struggle over the rules. Struggle Over the Rules: Sverdlovsk oblast’ In this scenario, a struggle over the rules develops when intra-elite cleavages cannot be eliminated due to patronage policies. When force strategies are exhausted, and the level of uncertainty is relatively high, the positions of political actors threatened, either as a result of defeat in a "war" or due to unsuccessful bargaining over the elite settlement. Therefore, the installation and adherence to formal institutions becomes the only opportunity for actors to survive within a regime. Moreover, while supremacy of one actor tends to be fixed in the institutional design, the uncertainty or balance of forces are likely to lead to the general acceptance of those rules, which allows actors to avoid the winner takes all outcome. The case of the Sverdlovsk Oblast’ demonstrates a more advanced version in the development of the struggle over the rules scenario. The cleavage between naturalresource rich mining districts, the city of Yekaterinburg, and the rest of the oblast’, was formed during the Soviet period, and was associated with strong departmentalism. During that period, the cleavage was formed on the basis of three competitive actors, while the struggle of elites for power maximization was forced to develop within the framework of formal institutions. The use of this framework really limited the opportunities for the assertion of individual powers and opened opportunities for actor contestation; the use of formal institutions as "weapons" was accompanied by the electoral competition of actors. Under the arbitrary rule of a dominant actor, mass politics have been based on "political machines" and administrative mobilization. Alternatively, the struggle over the rules scenario created an environment for the emergence of a competitive party system. After the 1993 dissolution of the "Urals Republic" and the resignation of regional governor Eduard Rossel’, regional elites in the Sverdlovsk Oblast’ have lost their unity, and no actors occupied a dominant position. On the one hand, having lost access to administrative resources, Rossel’ was forced to use alternative mechanisms of electoral mobilization for his return to power; he headed his own political party, an organization labeled as the non-party movement "Transformation of the Urals". On the other hand, the use of formal rules/institutions likely underlay the legislative decisions to create political institutions which excluded a winner takes all outcome (such as a PR electoral system and the autonomy of local government). Thus, even after victory in the 1995 gubernatorial elections, Rossel’ was still unable to monopolize power in the region. Simultaneously, his main contenders (the city government led by the mayor of Yekaterinburg and representatives of mining districts) were forced to establish their own parties for elections to the regional legislature: "Our Home is Our City" and "Mining Industrial Urals." After the series of 1995-1998 electoral campaigns, the party system of Sverdlovsk Oblast’ became the basis for competition among political actors. Speaking more generally, limitations of political struggle by formal institutions makes it unlikely that actors will return to positions of power employing force strategies. Transferring this struggle into the field of electoral competition created an environment for contending with the various alternatives through the structure of a party system. In this sense, elite conflicts, rather than settlements, are more likely to limit the influence of informal institutions and aid in the growth of political society as a whole. In the end, the struggle over the rules scenario of outcome of uncertainty is likely to provide an institutional framework as a precondition to democratization in the sense of horizontal accountability through the institutional limitation on assertions of power. Nevertheless, this outcome has not yet achieved a full-fledged, democratic regime as there has been no turnover of political actors within these same institutions. Huntington’s test of democratization based on the achievement of a second electoral cycle is very helpful in this sense. Until the institutionalization of the new regime through the second elections of chief executives, it is still quite fragile. In contrast with "authoritarian situations," the consequences of the struggle over the rules scenario may refer to a "democratic situation". Conclusion: Prospects for Democratization It is still difficult to provide definitive conclusions concerning Russia’s regional puzzle without systematic comparative study of regime transition in a large number of cases of regions. Adding a more in-depth perspective to this discussion, the following analyses of political developments in Moscow and Komi by Andrei Degtyarev and James Alexander, respectively, provide empirical evidence of the applicability of my approach to the analysis of Russian regional politics. Even based on a limited number of case studies, tentative conclusions can be made about conditions of democratization in Russia. So, what of the conditions for successful democratization in Russia’s regions ? First, the emergence of competitive politics within the framework of formal institutions becomes possible as an outcome of intra-elite conflicts, not due to the intentions of competitive actors. Second, these conflicts are not likely to be resolved as a zero-sum game (i.e. as a full-fledged victory of one actor). Third, these conflicts are unlikely to be eliminated under conditions of patronage politics and elite settlements. Finally, the installation of institutional changes and formal institutions (i.e. competitive elections) inevitably transfers intra-elite conflicts into the legal framework and the electoral arena. In the light of these observations, the case of successful democratization can be explained as a path-contingent model through the diachronic projection of the following qualifications: 1) structural cleavages provide political opportunities and make actor competitiveness inevitable. With the cleavages at the base of the political regime, actor competitiveness become indispensable; 2) actualization of elite cleavages for the installation of formal institutions tends to make the use of these institutions a weapon in the struggle for political survival; 3) translation of intra-elite and societal cleavages in the electoral arena in the fixed configuration of competitive actors by a framework of formal institutions, makes the democratization process self-sustainable. The Trials and Tribulations of Moscow: The Untold Story Democratization and the Komi Republic: The Struggle for Competitive Politics As the processes of political development in Russia’s regions have often been characterized more by the creation of political fiefdoms than the flowering of democracy in a new age, Gel’man’s regime typology provides a nice sub-text to this more empirically based discussion of political events in the Komi Republic. As he has shown, a significant trend in these developments has been the centralization process around a group of regional elites at the expense of other contenders. In concert with this process are the varying degrees to which certain key regional leaders represent an extension of Soviet nomenklatura privileges and their extension into post-communist Russia in new and variegated forms. Overall, the trend toward regional elite dominance has been exhibited in constraints on the activity of independent groups and individuals that might interfere with the centralized, regional authority. By striving to constrain the evolution of civil society, political leaders are impeding the transition toward substantive democracy. Part of the strategy to guide regional affairs has been expressed in the open resistance of many regional elites to the directives of central authorities. As a result, the many regional fiefdoms that have emerged in post-Soviet Russia are the targets of both federal policy and local political opposition alike–from above and from below. This scenario describes political development in the Komi Republic. Rather than a font for democratic development, Komi models the obstacles to political reform in a post-communist society. Over the past several years, political power in Komi has shifted along a spectrum between the winner take all and elite settlement scenarios of Gel’man’s typology, thus falling into the category of a hybrid regime. The Politics of Pluralism This discussion emerges from thoughts concerning the development of pluralism in Russia. If one simply conceives of pluralism as the division of power across society through the presence of autonomous entities, it is reasonably accurate to argue that at the national level Russia has achieved at least a semi-pluralistic political system, with numerous "national" parties and the clear influence of business interests. While other groups--including unions and the church--carry varying, and clearly lesser, degrees of influence, Russia has moved beyond nascent pluralism. When considering the resistance of the regions to central directives and their simultaneous attempts to influence central political decision-making, this becomes even more evident, although one may question whether this is an entirely healthy development for the Russian Federation. As exemplified by the power-sharing treaties between the Kremlin and various regional governments since Tatarstan began the process in 1994, the regions carry significant influence on the center. As discussed above, the political regimes within the regions themselves have shown much greater resistance to politically liberalizing forces. Looking to both strengthen federal authority and expand local competition, federal authorities have sought to break the regional political hierarchies. At the center of this policy has been the August 1995 federal law directing the establishment of local self-governments throughout the 89 regional entities of Russia. Resisted by many regions from the start, the difficulties of establishing local selfgovernment have been two-fold: 1) getting regional elites to open political processes by relinquishing a degree of control over sub-regional politics; and 2) whether sufficiently strong independent local interests exist, or can be developed, to take advantage of the competitive opportunity. By early 1999 most regions had to some degree complied with the federal legislation. The Komi Republic, however, had consistently resisted all efforts to break the vertical authority structure constructed by Republic Head Yuri Spiridonov and his political and economic allies. Moreover, federal difficulties dividing local political resources from above have been mirrored in ineffective attempts from below by local political parties, socio-political groups and movements. The center ofthe struggle rests on who–the people or the head–has the right to elect/appoint the 21 sub-regional heads of administration that have been part of the executive chain of command. If, as has been the practice, the head appoints these officials, they are dependent on him for their livelihood. This discussion looks at the struggle over the establishment of local self-government in Komi as the vehicle for assessing the relative development of pluralism, or politically competitive activity, in the republic. In linking federal and sub-regional activity, I will detail the Spiridonov regime’s efforts to resist central edicts while ignoring political opposition within the republic. While neither level of government has been particularly effective in altering the character of Spiridonov’s rule, events in 1998 and the first half of 1999 (court decisions and economic and political crises) appear to have sparked some movement toward the eventual development of independent local self-government and the expanding influence among liberal-democratic organizations. Located in the far north of Russia and bordering the western Ural Mountains, the Komi Republic is most identifiable as a location for Stalinist state labor camps (gulags), its ethnic divisions and abundant natural resources. On the political front, Spiridonov has been a strong figure in Komi politics since the late 1980s (he was the last First Secretary of the Komi Communist party) and is serving his second term as Head of the Republic. He is an independent-minded leader, who has been willing to resist central Russian directives, both in the interests of the republic and his own political future. As the regional executive, Spiridonov is a member of the Federation Council and has been active in pursuing the interests of Russia’s Northern Regions. As a fellow "oil man," Spiridonov was closely linked to former Russian Prime Minister Viktor Chernomyrdin. His dismissal in March 1998 and failure to be re-appointed in September 1998 appear to have had a marked influence on Spiridonov’s policy calculations. Komi is a multi-ethnic region in which Russians comprise over half of the population, while the indigenous Komi are less than 25%. While ethnicity issues are important in Komi, they do not threaten to destabilize the republic. Overall, an already declining population of 1,163,000 is expected to decline further to 1,034,00 by 2015. Komi would seem to have a bright economic future. Fuel (oil, coal and gas) is the largest industry in the region, making up approximately 50% of Komi’s GDP. Oil is the main export, providing 63% of total export revenue, followed by timber related products (16%) and coal (11%). Komi has trade relations with over 40 foreign countries and has been actively expanding its ties with other regions in Russia. The discussion is organized into three sections. The first section briefly details the political formation of Komi since 1990, showing the movement from an elite settlement preceding the 1993 political struggle in Moscow to a regime more closely approximating a winner takes all scenario by early 1995. The second section examines the cycle of attempts and failures of parties and socio-political groups to participate in Komi political processes that characterize the winner takes all period. This section continues by showing how one particular group reacted to this failure by challenging the Spiridonov regime in regional and federal courts. In a way that steps outside of Gel’man’s typology, the use of the federal courts represents a form of the "struggle over the rules" outcome of uncertainty, but one that includes an external actor. This section further examines the interplay of the legal system and legislation as Spiridonov has sought to delay implementing federal directives and court rulings that have threatened his position of power. Finally, I evaluate the mixed signals that have emerged from governing circles as Spiridonov has reacted to increasing federal and local pressure with greater recognition of "opposition" political forces and the formation and elections of institutions of local self-government in February 1999. In this fashion we find the political playing field widening as Komi–at least on the surface–moves back toward an elite settlement. The Cycles of Komi Politics Elite Settlement: Pre-October 1993 As the first Autonomous Soviet Socialist Republic to declare sovereignty from the dictates of the Soviet Union in August 1990, the Komi political leadership had to have had a basic level of consensus to make such a drastic step in the face of 70 years of Soviet control. After the collapse of the Soviet Union in late-1991, Komi continued to express its independent streak within the Russian Federation. At that time the power structure revolved around the Komi Supreme Soviet, headed by Spiridonov, and the Council of Ministers (the government), headed by Viacheslav Khudiaev. Part of the balance existed along ethnic lines as well, recognizing the Soviet policy of dividing authority in the ethnic republics (Spiridonov is Russian, while Khudiaev is Komi). The simple alliance among these institutions and the leaders of the enterprises producing Komi’s natural resources signified basic peace in the republic and a unified stance toward federal authorities. In this vein, Komi was a signatory to the short-lived 1992 Federation Treaty, which recognized national republics as state entities, providing the republics with complete legislative and executive authority over their territories. With the violent confrontation between President Yeltsin and the Supreme Soviet in October 1993, the Komi alliance for developing the republic’s sovereignty was ultimately broken by Yeltsin’s decree (although more of a recommendation at the republic level) dissolving all regional soviets (including the Komi Supreme Soviet). It also undermined the elite settlement then existing in the republic. With his position of power threatened, Spiridonov began a drive (initiating a zero-sum game) to become the singular leader within Komi. Furthermore, the release of the draft Russian Constitution in November 1993 pushed Spiridonov toward a more aggressive assertion of Komi sovereignty as the text did not carry the same degree of regional independence found in the Federation Treaty. Together, these two events were the catalyst for Spiridonov’s drive for sole leadership in Komi and his spirited resistance to federal authority. Winner-Takes-All: 1994-early 1998 In order to construct his power base, Spiridonov delayed the implementation of Yeltsin’s edict to dissolve the Supreme Soviet until January 1995 elections to the new legislature, the Komi State Council. During 1994, Spiridonov augmented his powers while "eliminating" his opposition, as represented by Khudiaev and his supporters. Early that year, he used his leadership in the Supreme Soviet to develop a constitution for Komi. In this document, Spiridonov discounted a 1993 defeat of a popular referendum item designed to create a Komi presidency to introduce an equivalent post, Head of the Republic. In May elections he soundly defeated Khudiaev to become the individual center of authority in Komi. That fall, Spiridonov employed his continued authority in the Supreme Soviet to pass the Komi Law on Executive Authority that ensured the election of a State Council dependent on his rule. These two documents created the vertical power structure within the republic. In this process, there have been many parallels with the consolidation of executive power in other regions, including Primorskii Krai and Omsk. By early 1995, Spiridonov had completed the task of marginalizing his opposition. This was shown when Spiridonov’s candidate for State Council Chairman, Vladimir Torlopov, overwhelmingly defeated an increasingly weak Khudiaev. Until recently, he and his supporters would largely disappear from significant Komi political activity. The Constitution identifies 20 districts in Komi of regional/ territorial importance. Additionally, the leadership position of each district (and an additional territorial subdistrict near Syktyvkar) was initially included in the executive branch under the direction of the head. These 21 heads of administration have been (until recently) appointed by the head of the republic. In turn, these heads of administration have been in the position to appoint local administrators in towns and villages, thus ensuring vertical control of the region. Overall, the 20 regional/territorial districts overlap with 30 electoral districts based on population to comprise the 50 electoral districts of the current State Council. With an inherent advantage in January 1995 elections, 13 of the administrative heads would be elected to the State Council along with others who were, or would become, beholden to the Head through ministerial appointments to the executive branch. Furthermore, although not as beholden to Spiridonov, 16 of the "generals" of Komi industry (oil, timber, gas, etc.) were elected to the Council as well. Ultimately, half of the council has been said to be in the "pocket" of the Head. In a corporatist arrangement that has been exhibited across Russia in various forms, the industry generals have generally supported the head. As the Spiridonov government is in a position to reward (i.e. tax breaks, subsidies, advantageous lending terms, etc.) or punish (tax inspection, higher tax rates, etc.) these industries, they have developed a mutually beneficial alliance. In this type of an alliance, Komi politics carry aspects of the elite settlement model. In part, the alliance is an important aspect explaining Spiridonov’s struggle to keep the republic vertically structured. Komi is a large region with various natural power centers. The Ukhta region is the primary center for the oil industry. Vorkuta is a center of coal production, an industry that has been traditionally the province of federal, rather than regional control. Thus, from Spiridonov’s perspective, keeping the Republic "unified" is vitally important. Spiridonov has used his position to influence State Council votes on issues he considers important. Probably most telling has been his ability to get the council to amend the Constitution, as shown in events leading up to November 1997 elections for head. Originally scheduled for May 1998, Spiridonov wanted to move the elections up to take advantage of relatively favorable economic conditions and avoid the uncertainties of the ruble re-denomination scheduled for January 1998. It would also put him in a significant advantage over his opponents, who would have little time to prepare for the election. To re-schedule the elections, the Constitution was quickly amended by an overwhelming 39-4 vote, well beyond the two-third majority needed. Spiridonov would go on to defeat his main opponent, State Duma Deputy Rita Chistokhodova, by an almost three-to-one margin in the popular vote. Although not always the case, Spiridonov has been a master at using the legislature and the legal system to his advantage. The Challenge To Authority The "Opposition" and Political Group Influence During the winner takes all period, independent political organizations (whether political parties or interest groups) have not had much success influencing political developments in Komi. Leaders in Komi’s weak civil society have, however, attempted numerous strategies to break the stranglehold of the executive branch. These have included the temporary union of opposition groups to present a more powerful block and the push for the creation of independent local government institutions to (hopefully) widen access to political processes and allow for more competitive, pluralist government in the region. While it might appear that the impetus of such a union was solely the acquisition of political resources, the development of "democracy from below" came to be seen as the only way they and other Komi residents could have influence over policy-making in the republic. The varying positions on this issue have been quite stark. The administration’s position then and through mid-1999 would be that Komi was neither sufficiently mature (i.e. the people are not ready) nor were there sufficient financial means to successfully implement the institutional changes leading to independent local self-government. Arguing that such a division of authority would place the republic in a particularly weak position in its relations with the Kremlin, then press secretary for the Syktyvkar Mayor, Andrei Borodikin, claimed that Komi’s vertical power structure was the most effective means of government. From opposition circles, a far different view emerged: only through the development of independent local government institutions--in which the people elected their local head of administration directly--could the Komi people ensure that local executives would fulfill their duties. These local politicians needed to be beholden to the people rather than the head. In this fashion, substantive democratic processes would develop. The difficulties for opposition groups to affect policy in Komi went beyond issues of local self-government, and extended into the regional legislature, underlining the broad, informal agreement among a narrow elite. Particularly vexing for representatives of the local political parties, none of the deputies elected in 1995 represented national parties, with only three of the 50 seats occupied by deputies carrying some affiliation with the local communists. For many of the successful candidates, rather than being beholden to a party, they could individually rely on their relative fame as local heads of administration, economic leaders or former CPSU elite to ensure election. Without any representation, it is difficult for the parties both to grow and press their diverse agendas as one would find in a Western legislature. Without a party structure, there were few clear points of interest around which to rally groups of deputies beyond the personal presence of the Head of the Republic. Whether or not political parties were to achieve representative status, the Komi Constitution provides little to recommend the Council as an effective legislature. The immediate stumbling block is the Council's non-professional status, a major victory for Spiridonov during 1994 constitutional debates. As a result, the legislature only meets once a month for two days. For some, the development of a professional parliament would return a balance to Komi political institutions, by creating a more independent legislative body. If being a deputy were a full-time job, the industrial generals that make up the "corporatist bloc" would go back to running their companies, ultimately unwilling to give up their large salaries for a deputy’s wage. Furthermore, this would also limit the number of heads of administration in the council when faced with such an increase in responsibility. Currently, however, because it is difficult for the body to address the majority of questions brought to each session, the head has greater leeway in running the Republic. In addition to concerns about the effectiveness of the State Council, temporary political unions have formed across a spectrum of parties. During the winner takes all period, however, these unions were linked by their almost universal failure. The Electoral Association of Democratic Organizations (PADORK) organized in 1995 to prepare for elections to the State Duma and to ensure that the Komi Constitution functioned in accordance with the Russian Constitution. Furthermore, since the release of the federal law on local self-government in August 1995, a primary focus for local political groups, including PADORK, has been upon establishing local self-government in Komi. Thus, these blocks have sought to unite their resources in pushing for access to Komi policymaking decisions on a number of levels. While PADORK brought together the self-proclaimed democratic opposition in Komi, in 1996 SOORK (Council of Public Organization of the Republic of Komi) combined the opposition groups regardless of political positions and ranged from the local branches of Democratic Choice of Russia, to the Communists and LDPR. Seeking a consultative role in the policy-making process of legislative and executive authority, SOORK had marginally greater success than PADORK: an agreement requiring the council to inform and consult the group about prospective bills and bills in process was signed by State Council Chairman Vladimir Torlopov. As would become clear relatively quickly, this agreement was ignored by Komi authorities despite SOORK’s public accusations of executive arrogance and legislative dependence on the executive scarcely two months later. Despite an impressive number of successes in resisting political parties, socio-political groups and even sub-regional legislatures, the Komi authorities have not been able to rebuff all challenges. Ultimately, the most effective means of interest articulation has occurred in court. By bringing suit against Komi authorities, the Komi division of the communist-leaning Popular Patriotic Union of Russia (NPSR) has taken the most successful path to overcoming official resistance to the federal law on local selfgovernment. Accompanied by the changing federal governments during 1998 and the sudden economic crisis following the August 17, 1998 collapse of the ruble, the judicial challenge to the vertical power structure in Komi is what eventually moves political authorities back in the direction of an elite settlement. The Judiciary and Local Self-government The vertical power structure in Komi has provided very few opportunities for "outsiders" to enter the policy-making process whether as elected officials or as political pressure groups. Thus, like the civil rights movement in the United States from the 1950s onward, political opposition groups that have been frozen out of local political circles have turned their attention to the court system to achieve political "justice." In Komi, various interests, from the administration in Vorkuta to groups of pensioners have brought suit against the Komi administration in republican and federal courts. While it has not been unusual for the plaintiffs to emerge victorious, it is also not unusual for Komi authorities to ignore or subvert the rulings through the implementation of ineffective "half" measures, or delay implementation through countersuits. Overall, the reform of legal standards in post-Soviet Russia has been a slow and uneven process, and Komi is no exception. While the implementation of the 1995 federal law would seem relatively straight-forward, ensuing court battles leading up to 999 elections to institutions of local government have been long and heated. The first half of 1996 saw the Spiridonov regime active in republic and federal courts. In seeking to avoid local government elections by March 1 as mandated in the federal law, Spiridonov complied with a "directive" from the State Council to bring suit to the Russian Constitutional Court with the claim that provisions of the federal law were in violation of the Russian Constitution. While Komi would lose the suit in May, Spiridonov was successful in delaying local elections past the original deadline, although this deadline had already been extended nationally by Yeltsin. It was during this period that the Komi affiliate of NPSR entered the local government issue as a litigant pushing for implementation of the federal law. There would follow a series of judicial rulings from 1997-1999 that are connected to the NPSR quest. A March 1997 ruling of the Komi Supreme Court noted that the Komi laws relating to local self-government violated federal standards. As a result, the court set October 19, 1997 as the last possible date by which elections could be held. With this ruling, the State Council passed a bill to identify the administrative divisions in which local government institutions were to be instituted. Ultimately, several legislative proposals were "replaced" by a proposal made by the Head's representative to establish local selfgovernment at the level of village, settlement, country village and parts/sections of the cities and districts subordinate to the republic. The eventual Law on the Formation of Municipal Districts was widely criticized for the potential of dividing functioning administrative regions into sub-districts with inadequate financial and service bases. From the head’s perspective, however, this "compromise" position ensured that he would continue to name the 21 Heads of Administration, rather than lose authority that would come with making these posts elected. In this fashion, the head subverted the federal law by essentially directing the State Council to adopt an unworkable institutional framework. The law on the formation of municipal districts underlined the all out attempt by the head to keep the vertical power structure intact, even if it meant the continual violation of federal laws and various court rulings. With the law falling far short of developments in pluralism envisioned by some federal authorities and local opposition, elections were delayed by the Russian Supreme Court when it chose to examine the constitutionality of two articles relating to local government in the Komi Constitution. This decision came at an opportune moment for the head, who was concerned about the electoral effect of holding the re-scheduled elections for head alongside local government elections. As a face saving measure, the State Council included a non-binding plebiscite on the November ballot. The item asked Komi voters: "Do you think that the formation of municipalities in the Komi Republic should include the entirety of the republic's subordinate districts and cities along with their entire territories?" As Viktor Kovalev notes, the question itself was particularly vague as to whether local institutions would be limited to the territorial districts or could be formed on another level and it ignored the central issue of how the territorial head of administration would be chosen. Still, the plebiscite passed overwhelmingly by 72.6% of voters, with a 48.5% turnout. As the question was unclear, the results of the vote were also unclear. Nevertheless, in a June 1997 survey, the populace had indicated that it was overwhelmingly in favor of the head of administration being a popularly elected post. This set the stage for the January 15, 1998 Constitutional Court ruling overturning the Komi law on the formation of municipal districts. With the ruling, Spiridonov variously claimed that the ruling violated provisions in the bilateral treaty signed in 1996, which gave the republic the right to determine independently its local institutions, and that the court did not consider provisions of the Federation Treaty. Yet, he would back off from his resistance and the State Council scheduled local self-government elections to coincide with State Council elections set for February 7, 1999. In preparation for the elections, the council prepared and passed a law in June 1998 on the formation of local governmental institutions. As before, this law provided for the popular election of the regional legislatures. Yet, while this law removed the Head’s authority to name the local heads of administration, it did not provide for their popular election, either. Instead, it allowed the head to recommend candidates to those locally elected legislatures. In this way, the head of the republic can ensure that candidates meet his specifications, even if he can no longer directly appoint them. Thus, while aspects of the vertical power structure were weakened, Spiridonov found a way to continue to manage the local institutions. It should be no surprise that NPSR Chairman Leonid Musinov would again file suit in the Komi Supreme Court challenging the law as a violation of the Russian Constitution. In a November 2, 1998 ruling the court agreed with Musinov. The case was appealed to the Russian Supreme Court by Komi authorities. In a December 25, 1998 ruling, the Russian court also agreed with Musinov. Again, it seemed that local groups would achieve their wish, the creation of independent local governmental entities. Again, however, they would be disappointed. Because the official ruling of the Russian Supreme Court had not been publicly released, Komi authorities argued that they were duty bound to follow the extant laws. The ruling was not released until late May 1999, well after the elections had been held in February. In the interim, Spiridonov followed the guidelines of the Komi law and nominated his candidates to the local head positions. Although there were a few obstacles to be overcome, all 21 candidates were eventually approved by the newly elected local legislatures. To ensure this would occur, Spiridonov attended the sessions of those legislatures that were predicted to be the most "troublesome." Toward Openness: The Return to Elite Settlement? With the February 1999 elections it would seem that Spiridonov has maintained the winner takes all aspects of the republic’s political situation. And, truthfully, the simultaneous elections to the State Council would seem to support such a conclusion, particularly as the number of heads of administration elected to the body has actually increased (16 of 21 were chosen). Yet, there were a number of events in 1998 that both bolster and undermine the winner takes all outcome of uncertainty. Three 1998 legislative decisions expanded the opportunities for him and his cohort. The first decision alters the law on state service that required retirement by age 60, thus allowing some (who are approaching, or have passed, age 60, including Spiridonov) of Spiridonov's team to continue working. Perhaps more significantly, a constitutional amendment was approved "rescinding the prohibition of the president or his deputies to hold posts in commercial and civic organizations." This amendment seemingly removes the de jure legal separation between the state and private sectors, and increases the corporatist relationship of the top actors in the republic. Perhaps most significant, however, the State Council bolstered Spiridonov’s political position by passing an amendment that removed the two term limit on the head, thus freeing Spiridonov to remain in his position (as the opposition quickly points out) until his death. Yet, there are also signs that "outsiders" might eventually infect political authority. One sign emerges from Komi’s compliance with the May 1998 Russian Constitutional Court ruling that led to the resignation of State Council Deputies who had simultaneously worked as civil servants (i.e. under the authority of the head). Another comes from the current redrawing of electoral districts more in line with federal laws mandating relatively equal population distribution across districts. Thus, for example, the more resistant Vorkuta region will gain greater representation in 2003 elections. Probably the most intriguing development in Komi political circles over the past year has been the reaction to the crisis conditions in Russia. There have been two collective organizations formed with Spiridonov’s blessing and would seem to be linked to the misfortunes of Spiridonov’s "patron" former Prime Minister Viktor Chernomyrdin. Forming on the heels of Chernomyrdin’s dismissal in March 1998, the first group brought together 14 regional organizations into a consultative body to the head. This group basically aims outward, toward federal and international relations. The second group, "Union for the Transformation of the North" brought together seven reformoriented political parties/movements (since expanded to 13) following the leadership of the local party of power, Our Home is Russia. With Spiridonov in attendance, this movement’s founding conference was held in October 1998. This latter group appears to have been the most durable, and is founded with the general goal of a unified defense of Komi (even the entire northern region) in the face of anti-reformist elements regionally and in the national government. In recognizing that a unified republic may help Komi contend with the vacillating federal government and rising economic instability, Spiridonov may be coming to a compromise position with the heretofore democratic opposition. There continues to be skepticism following failed agreements in the past, both within the political union and among those who either refuse to join and/or are excluded due to extreme views. Particularly vocal is the leader of the local Yabloko affiliate, Nikolai Moiseev, who views this organization as a meaningless play by the Head to coopt much of the political opposition. An important goal of the organization, however, is the election of a "democratic" representative to the national State Duma in December 1999 elections. To this point, Komi has only been represented by at least nominal communists and they hope that the union will lead to a focused vote for a democratic, reform-oriented candidate. Thus, to the extent that a group such as Transformation of the North is successful, there seems to be a rising consensus (if not surrender) that has not been seen in Komi since before the events of October 1993 and the assertion of Russian executive power. Conclusion It should now be clear how the development of competitive politics within Komi has been retarded by the consistent resistance of executive authority to more open political processes. Spiridonov’s dogged refusal to implement the law on local self-government and other federal directives allowed the head to construct a vertical structure of authority in the republic. Yet, Spiridonov’s administration has not been entirely immune to federal and regional pressure. Having succeeded in constructing a political regime that focuses authority on himself and a limited elite, Spiridonov has nevertheless been forced to give ground. Coupled with uncertainties in the federal government and continuing economic crises, he may have come to the realization that it is better to include the "outsiders" on some level rather than entirely ignore their interests. In this respect, Komi may be tracking toward a wider elite settlement. Out of this whole process of development, can one say that Komi politics have become more substantively democratic? I would say, "yes," even if it is not yet evident. From summer 1999 interviews, local opposition leaders are in agreement, calling the elections to local self-government a small step in that direction. While NPSR Chairman Leonid Musinov may again bring suit against the Komi government for violating the federal laws on local self-government, he believes that they have made progress toward popular rule. The same can be said for Yabloko Chairman Nikolai Moiseev who proudly pointed to the small blocks (up to 25%) of Yabloko deputies that were elected to several of the local councils in February. The pressures emerging from local opposition have intertwined with federal laws and court rulings to force some concessions from Spiridonov on a number of levels. Again, part of the process has been driven by continuing crises in Russia, leading the head to look to certain reform-oriented factions for support in the face of potential conservative challenges at the national level. While it may be the case that the ruling elite has simply extended a narrow foothold to a new set of actors (in this sense, coopting the former opposition), the reality is that the number of actors around governing circles would seem to be expanding. This along with the local government reforms and future redistricting of State Council districts offer the potential for an expanded number of voices that may carry the region toward greater pluralism, even if movement can only be measured in inches rather than miles. Conclusion: Regional Roadblocks to Democratic Transition ? In closing this chapter, it should become clear that many Russian regions still lack a number of procedural aspects of democracy, let alone having achieved its substantive form. Moreover, save for a few cases of struggle over the rules, there are no evident internal political forces capable of moving Russia further toward the fulfillment of democratization – neither on an elite or mass level. On the one hand, regional elites have no strong incentives for establishing competitive politics within the framework of formal institutions, especially if there are no pre-existing internal divisions. Instead, the strategy of regional leaders to protect their positions, on the way by-passing democratic forms of government (such as horizontal as well as vertical accountability), is quite rational. On the other hand, the seeds of civil society in Russia continue to be developed within a tiny strata of society, while mass dependence on political authorities provides the regional leaders the capacity for administrative mobilization and electoral corruption, often associated in Russia with the regional development of a dominant party of power. What then are the prospects for democratization in the Russian regions? Put another way, will the regional roadblocks to a democratic transition survive across space and time? As of yet, there is no clear answer.. At least three possible short-term factors could challenge the current state of affairs: 1) the influence of external actors, 2) the impact of mass politics, and 3) the dynamics of institutional change. Until now, however, none of these factors have played a significant role in the development of regional political regimes. The influence of external actors is an important source of democratization. External pressure – either from national organizations (such as the federal judicial branch in the case of Komi), or from national-based politicians (like former Prime Minister Kirienko’s criticisms of Moscow Mayor Luzhkov) – could provide some political opportunities for competitiveness and the growth of popular participation. To this point, however, political power is more often connected to the personalities who occupy powerful positions, not to the regional political regimes themselves. This lack of influence can be explained in two ways: First, state-building, which is based on the principle of rule of law, continues to be a low priority item for Russian authorities. Second, the administrative resources of the center, as well as its capacity to employ force strategies with the regions, were exhausted after the 1994-1996 Chechen war, the 1996-1997 gubernatorial elections, and the 1998 financial crisis. Although the center has used some substitute measures during the last several years (such as pushing particular economic policies in the regions, the strengthening of presidential representatives, and the development of local government autonomy), it has not been very successful. On the eve of a new wave of political struggles at the national level (especially during 1999-2000 national elections), a compromise strategy of the center toward the regions (i.e. an exchange of loyalty for the promise of non-intervention) seems the most rational. The impact of the Russian masses under conditions of widespread clientelism (a feature of Russia’s political culturei) is limited. "Political machines" as a tool of mass mobilization are more effective than the mobilization of the societal cleavages which can be transferred into forms of political competition if recognized by the elites.ii There is no basis to assume these will develop, however, given the uncertainty of regime transition. In the long-run, machine politics in American or Southern Italian cities have been undermined by modernization processes; after the breakdown of systems of mass patronage, mass politics has played crucial role in political competition. iii Yet, in the near term such a development is doubtful under conditions of arbitrary rule, which, pending the developments of incentives to develop a party system in the regions, seems to be the only alternative to the patron-client linkages exhibited across Russia. Ultimately, political institutionalization in Russia has strengthened rather than undermined regional political regimes. Arbitrary rule not only resulted from the decay of the ancien regime, but serves to strengthen actors in new political regimes, especially due to their use of rent-seeking strategies. There are no actors as of yet who believe that it is in their interest to shift institutional frameworks from arbitrary rule toward a rule of law. The emergence of such actors may come to be linked either with the institutionalization of democratic situations during the struggle over the rules scenario, or with the breakdown of those regimes and the resulting winner takes all and elite settlement outcomes of uncertainty. Thus, the democratizaiton experiences of regional Russia confirm Philippe Schmitter’s perspective on the dangers for new democracies: Democracy in its most generic sense persists after the demise of autocracy, but never gels into a specific, reliable, and generally accepted set of rules. These countries are "doomed" to remain democratic almost by default... Elections are held; associations are tolerated; rights may be respected; arbitrary treatment by authorities may decline — in other words, the procedural minima are met with some degree of regularity — but regular, acceptable and predictable democratic patterns never quite crystallize. Democracy is not replaced, it just persists by acting in ad hoc and ad hominem ways as successive problems arise.vv Speaking more broadly, democracy is not emerging "by default" (or even "by design"). It has not become inevitable because politicians who call themselves "democrats" occupy positions of power (even if they have good intentions). Democracy is a "contingent outcome of conflict,"v and nothing else. If political competition among actors continues to develop, transitions to democracy may occur. In this sense, Churchill’s well-known comment on democracy as a bad form of government, save for all others, means that political competition within the framework of formal institutions is simply the "lesser evil" for actors. The question, however, is whether Russia’s actors – on both national and regional levels – could actually view the evil of democracy in this way. Table 2. Political Regimes: Actors and Institutions Competitiveness of actors/ Informal Formal Predominant institutions ("arbitrary rule") ("rule of law") Competitive Hybrid regime Democracy Non-competitive Authoritarian regime Table 3. Stages of Regime Transition: "Transition to Democracy" and "Open-ended" Models "Transition to Democracy" "Open-ended" Model 1. Liberalization 1. Decline of ancien regime 2. Transition = Installation of 2. Breakdown of ancien regime democracy 3. Uncertainty 3. Consolidation 4. Outcome of uncertainty = Installation of new regime 5. Institutionalization of new regime Table 4. Scenarios of outcomes of uncertainty Positions of actors/ Compromise Force Dominant actor "elite settlement" "winner takes all" Uncertainty or balance of forces "struggle over the "war of all against all" Strategies of actors rules" Table 5. Elite Cleavages, Scenarios of Outcomes of Uncertainty and Characteristics of New Regimes: The Case of Russia’s Regions Scenario of Previously – Intra-elite Consequences of Characteristics outcome of existed elite conflicts outcome of of the new uncertainty cleavage during uncertainty political regimes transition period "Winner takes city resolved as a "authoritarian monopoly of a all" (Saratov government zero-sum situation" dominant actor, Oblast’) vs. agrarians game informal institutions "Elite settlement" city eliminated by hybrid regime (Nizhnii government informal powers between Novgorod vs. enterprise agreements dominant and Oblast’) directors vs. on power- subordinated oblast’ sharing actors, informal government sharing of institutions "Struggle over city unresolved "democratic competition of the rules" government and provided situation" actors, formal (Sverdlovsk vs. mining a basis of institutions, Oblast’) districts vs. electoral moving toward oblast’ competition rule of law government