Name: Naomi Hirst Degree programme: MSc Migration Mobility and Development Course: Political Economy of Development Essay No: 1 Seminar Tutor: Mr Marco Boffo Seminar Group Number: T1/15 Essay Title: Examine the process and the economic and social effects of trade liberalisation in one developing country. Submission Date: 10th January 2011 Word Count: 2999 1 Trade liberalisation is above all things contested: debated in its adoption, tested in its practice, disputed in its theory and undecided in its results. Taking this lack of clarity as a starting point this essay will examine the process and effects of South Africa’s entrance into the global market by assessing the emergence of neoliberal trade policies in the context of the nation’s post-apartheid political settlement and by reviewing South Africa’s trade performance, assessing the extent, changes and social costs of trade liberalisation in the textiles sector. I argue that trade liberalisation has embedded South Africa’s unemployment deeper within its economic structure. In addition the political ramifications of this process have been manifold: greater unemployment has gone hand in hand with the derogation of the political power of unions and the labour they represent. From nationalisation to liberalisation Although atypical compared to many other liberalising developing economies South Africa makes an interesting case study both because of its combination of comparative advantages and because at no point did South Africa have to liberalise its trade. Trade liberalisation has been embraced, not enforced: this short assay into the tale of South African trade liberalisation is thus a story of the encroachment of neoliberal rationality onto a polity previously defined, among other things, by its close relationship to labour. In 1990 Nelson Mandela assured the nation that the ANC anticipated the “nationalisation of the mines, banks and monopoly industry” and that a “change or modification of our views” would be “inconceivable” (Marais 2001:122). In 1994 he was able to declare that the economic polices of the ANC contained not a single reference to “things like nationalisation”, that there was not “a single slogan that [would] connect us with any Marxist ideology” (Marais 2001:122). This volte-face in economic policy reflected the sea-change in influence that now held sway in the upper echelons of the ANC. The change took the government, and eventually the nation, from a Confederation of South Africa Trade Unions (COSATU) policy, which advocated state planning and growth through redistribution, to the ANC flagship economic programme of 1996: ‘Growth, Employment and Redistribution’ (GEAR), which predicated economic growth from a menu of fiscal austerity, wage restraint and trade liberalisation in which redistribution was predicated on growth. GEAR’s affiliation to the Washington Consensus was thus characterised both in its policy recommendations and in the way it which this ‘reform from above’ was declared ‘non- 2 negotiable’ by the Finance minister Trevor Manuel (Marais 2001:162). In 1996 the message to the unions and to the government was that there was no alternative. The only path to sustainable growth was to free the market from the binds of the state and the tyranny of labour. Neoliberal foundations: a critique When the ANC was unbanned in 1990 it had no economic policy, only slogans and broad statements of principle in lieu of an economic brief. A historic neglect of economic policy opened the way for a stream of foreign experts to court their unformed heterodoxy (or ‘macro-economic populism’) with an assortment of seminars, workshops, briefings and conferences, commissioned and paid for by foreign and local business development agencies (Marais 2001:125). Envoys of the mainstream created histrionic scenarios depicting the unsustainability of the ‘growth through redistribution’ pathway and in flamboyant language cast ANC economic policy as an Icarus jeopardising growth with state-oriented policy1 (Marais 2001:126). The foundation upon which GEAR was built was heavily influenced by these paeans to free enterprise. In the context of the collapse of the Soviet experiment and the daunting task that unprepared policy actors faced, the rhetoric of neoliberalism proved seductive. At the theoretical core of the pronouncements that predicted redistribution through growth was the neoliberal faith in the market as the single most efficient allocator of resources. In this framework the liberalisation of trade is cast as the means to growth: an open market free from tariffs will necessarily lead to the more efficient allocation of resources between sectors and nations as each comes to realise their comparative advantage in producing and exporting commodities particular to their national resources. In an open market static and dynamic gains will proliferate: one-off efficiency gains, ongoing economies of scale and the persistent pressure to innovate are made possible in a global marketplace of competitors integrated with one another in the absence of state interventions. The origin of trade policy as prescribed by GEAR and espoused by international financial institutions lies with Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage: it is of mutual benefit to each country participating in trade to specialise in the good in which it has a lower relative cost and exchange it with the other (Patnaik 2005:31). The 1 As in the Mont Fleur scenario 3 benefit arises from an actual physical increase in total output owing to specialisation; and this is a truth, deduced from an impartial observation of reality and universal in its applicability – “a perfectly general argument” (Patnaik 2005:32). As Utsa Patnaik points out however, this is a ‘perfectly general argument’ only in so far as all nations to which this ‘law’ applies could be said to be blessed by a ‘comparative advantage’ drawn from greater military might and diplomatic surety. The Britain that Ricardo drew upon was a nation lent advantage in woollen cloth over a militarily and diplomatically subdued Portugal; the advantage was military and the benefit unilateral. Set in its historical context and read as a social construct Ricardo’s market necessarily loses the glossy sheen of objectivity neoliberal ‘truths’ seek to confer. This weakness within the central tenets of neoliberal advocacy of trade liberalisation is echoed in empirical analysis: the effects of open trade on growth, productivity, technological change and efficiency are at best ambiguous (Fine Deraniyagala 2001). Yet orthodoxy persists: a neutral trade regime is seen to increase labour intensive production, an increased demand for unskilled labour along with an upward pressure on unskilled wages is predicted and lauded as route to reducing poverty (Deraniyagala 2005:104). Trade liberalisation was instigated by the drastic reduction and simplification of tariffs, as a result of GEAR the South African economy became more open. However, the links between trade and poverty reduction and employment, between growth and redistribution have not been clear. South African trade liberalised Under GEAR a number of tariffs were simplified or reduced or removed. The market became open to imports and under the rubric of trade theory specialised exportorientation was expected to counter the increased domestic competition from imports. This statement of fact and statement of prediction is about as clear as any one can make about trade liberalisation in South Africa, even the pronouncement that ‘since the early 1990s South Africa has made good progress in liberalising its trade regime’ with reducing the average nominal protection in manufacturing falling from 23% in 1994 to 8.2% in 2004 (Dunne Edwards 2005:1) can be contested: “ the much hyped liberalisation of SA economy in 90s has not been fully realised” (Fedderke Vaze 2001:436). Some sectors have experienced increased protection in the years since GEAR was implemented (finance, insurance, agriculture, gold, uranium) whilst liberalised sectors have been shown to account for just over 15% of total GDP (Fedderke Vaze 2001:445). These contrary claims are the tip of the 4 iceberg, there is not only substantial debate as to the extent of liberalisation and its links to increased import penetration and export orientation, but arguments too as regards the empirical means used to ascertain such data (Edwards 2006:234). However a hazy picture does emerge and it is one that throws South Africa’s 25.5% unemployment rate and comparative advantages into stark relief. Under a liberalised trade regime South Africa’s comparative advantages are twofold: compared to developed countries it is abundant in unskilled labour, compared to developing countries it is abundant in skilled labour. Although trade has had a net positive effect on employment since 1994 at 0.6% per annum (Edwards 2005: 245) this has lagged behind population growth, the employment currently generated through trade being insufficient to offset unemployment. Over the past three decades employment growth has been biased towards skilled labour (Edwards 2005:244): the period 1994-2002 saw net trade raised amongst that demograpihc by 0.8% pa against 0.4% pa amongst unskilled labour. A partial explanation for these figures can be found by considering the regional composition of South Africa’s trade. Despite its comparative advantages the sector composition of South Africa’s manufactured exports is similar across regions, with basic chemicals, iron and steel (reflecting South Africa’s natural resource endowment), machinery and equipment, and motor vehicles dominating exports to most regions (Edwards 2006:241). The result is an imbalance and one that does not strike an accord with neoliberal pronouncements; from 1994 growth in net trade has been shown to be biased toward skilled-labour-intensive sectors with rises in export orientation most concentrated in chemical and metal product sectors. In the same period less-skilled-labour-intensive sectors have experienced poor export and strong import growth: with textiles and footwear facing significant import penetration compared to other sectors. Despite an abundance in less skilled labour South Africa has been unable to compete with China and India in sectors such as textiles, leather and footwear; the result of this failure is mass unemployment amongst South Africa’s alleged comparative advantages. The substitution of capital for labour, the effect of biased tariff reductions and the resultant import penetration on domestic demand for manufactured goods all give vital context to South Africa’s 25.5% unemployment rate. Analysis conducted by Lawrence Edwards and Paul Dunne has shown how liberalisation, as mandated by GEAR, has disproportionately affected manufacturing; though tariffs still remain high 5 in certain sub-sectors, manufacturing underwent the sharpest decline in nominal tariff protection between 1994 and 2004 (Dunne Edwards 2005:2). Over the same period employment growth within manufacturing stagnated with total employment within manufacturing declining by 10%. Growth in openness is negatively correlated with growth in employment, with the biggest falls occurring in industries experiencing the largest reductions in tariffs – showing both that reductions in protection were biased towards labour intensive sectors and that liberalisation has reduced the demand for unskilled labour relative to capital. I will later examine the effects of liberalisation on the textiles sector to further illuminate the social costs of South Africa’s commitment to open trade; however at this juncture an assessment of how the faltering performance of manufacturing is figured within the neoliberal paradigm sheds light not only on neoliberal theory, but illuminates in turn the process by which the alliance between COSATU and the ANC was eroded and in turn replaced by what COSATU, in the second resolution of their 9th National Congress, identify as the “dominant influence of big business on the policy direction of our country and the marginalisation of representative institutions from decision-making” (COSATU:2006). Dani Rodrik’s analysis of South Africa’s ‘economic puzzles’ claims that had their been a decline in the real wage at the low end of skill distribution the shrinkage of the manufacturing sector may not have been so severe. However this he claims was “an unrealistic option in view of social expectations and political realities created by democratic transition” (Rodrik 2008:772). There was, and evidently still is, a widespread assumption amongst mainstream policymakers and economists that South Africa’s labour market is primarily defined by its inflexibility. The marginalisation of labour In a neoliberal framework trade unions represent an inefficient market intervention and in the journey towards GEAR labour representatives were hounded by business interests, conservative thinktanks, experts and advisors for the supposedly stultifying effect of unions on growth. The election of the ANC with the support of COSATU and the passing of labour legislation on 1995 that codified the right to collective bargaining was the end, rather than the beginning of labour’s political power in South Africa. 6 Opposition to the neo-Keynesian policies that figured the state as the protector of labour standards and progenitor of growth had long been derogated2. In 1996 The South Africa Foundation, an association of South Africa’s largest corporations and major multinational companies, issued an attack on the state, lauding government intervention as the inhibitor of natural growth. Their paper ‘Growth for All’‘ pinpointed the industrial council system and its contribution to the inflexibility of the market as one potent source of unemployment: high wages made South Africa uncompetitive in global trade. Despite the fact that this line of reasoning was thoroughly discredited by the ILO’s report to the Labour Review Commission later that year3 the inflexibility of labour was accepted and codified. The release of GEAR augmented this rhetoric through the ambivalence with which the language of flexibility was deployed4. Within the context of its macro-economic strategy, the vagueness of GEAR’s prescriptions for the labour market created space for opponents of a ‘rigid’ labour to translate GEAR into a programme in favour of de-regulation (Bezuidenhout Kenny 2000:11). The labour market debate had shifted: from issues of inequality to a focus on flexibility and efficiency to promote competitive advantage. The textile industry This short case study will illuminate the ways in which liberalisation has altered the modus operandi of textile firms and impacted upon workers. Textiles can be exported at any stage of their production; it is thus a sector especially sensitive to trade liberalisation and it is one that has been in long term decline since the 1980s. In 1993 the left-leaning ‘workerist’ Macro-Economic Research Group’s paper was largely discredited by the ANC: its endorsement of public works programmes and the introduction of a national minimum were resisted by the DEP in the same year the ANCissued a letter of intent to the IMF which which committed the new government to fiscal discipline (Bezuidenhout Kenny 2000:4) 2 Guy Standing, Director of Labour Market policies for the ILO: ‘South Africa has a flexible labour market...It is almost comical to describe SA as having employment inflexibility. Many workers have little employment protection, retrenchments are fairly easy and widespread, notice periods are short or non-existent, and most firms can resort to temporary or casual labour and, if need be, labour contracting...’ (Bezuidenhout Kenny 2000:9) 3 4 At this point in the evolution of economic policy COSATU role had already been reduced; the National Economic Forum of 1992 became the National Economic Development and Labour Council in 1995, a purely consultative body, no longer the negotiating forum that COSATU had initially envisaged (Marais 2001:133). 7 Increased import competition has led to increased export competition, but this has not led to a necessary and absolute improvement to firm performance; within the textiles sector there is no necessary relation between exporting and better performance or growth (Roberts Thoburn 2003:88). It is the motivation for export that counts: firms reporting the motivation to increase their scale of production as a reason for export were 50% more likely to have achieved high levels of turnover growth compared to the 76% of firms that exported for defensive reasons, motivated both by the threat to the domestic market and the need to maintain their capacity utilisation (Roberts Thoburn 2003:89). Threats to the domestic market from trade liberalisation have been the primary driver of growth in production with a strong association between experiencing a very high impact of import competition and having made changes in production changes, suggesting that liberalisation has contributed to production changes and restructuring (Roberts Thoburn 2004:131). Defensive exporting and specialisation have required firms to invest in new machinery and to rationalise production. Upgrading and restructuring programmes have involved significant job losses, as have the defensive cost-cutting measures of those firms less able to adapt to a competitive market5. The effect on textile workers has been severe: a 40% drop in the levels of employment within the industry has been ongoing since the mid 1990s (Roberts Thoburn, 2004:133-5). Textile factories have closed or have become progressively more capital intensive, with increases in output possible without much new employment. Amongst a demographic heavily dependent on wage income, increasing unemployment has increased the burden for individuals who may find themselves supporting yet more extended family members. Of workers still in the employ of the textiles sector, informal work patterns are prevalent; work has become increasingly casual with fixed-term contracts, home-working and subcontracting becoming more entrenched in response to vulnerability of the industry since the onset of trade liberalisation (Bezuidenhout 2007:552). The informalisation of work allows producers to maximise the flexibility of work and to minimise the costs of labour; there is no formal security, no legal or social protection. Workers bear a high risk, but in the textiles sector it is risk or nothing. 5 The neoliberal claim that blame lies with an unsustainable real wage is given the lie by the textile firms surveyed by Roberts and Thoburn: their postal survey results showed that firms did not view wage rates as a hindrance to their competitiveness ( 8 Conclusion South Africa’s participation in world trade since the early 1990s has been characterised by a performance biased towards skill-intensive labour intensive sectors that at its best has led to a negligible net increase in overall employment, and at its worst has contributed to the increasing unemployment of unskilled labour. The relative decline of the country’s manufacturing sector has been to the detriment of vast swathes of unskilled labour and has profoundly altered the texture of employment itself. Employment has become increasingly informal and insecure and its political representatives increasingly marginalised, both due to the erosion of formal labour from within the labour market, but equally due to the political negotiations that enshrined trade liberalisation as ANC government policy and legislation. It has been beyond the scope of this essay to explore further the precise nature of South Africa’s trade liberalisation, both in terms of the effects of this highly atypical economy on African regional trading agreements, and in turn the effect of preferential trade agreements on the economy’s textile sector. Further study in this contested field would lead to a review of the effects of the Africa Growth and Opportunity Act and a consideration of how mainstream economists continue to favour and justify trade liberalisation today6. Bibliography Adelzadeh, Asghar. (1996) ‘From the RDP to GEAR: The Gradual Embracing of Neo-liberalism in Economic Policy’, Transformations 31: 66-95 Barrientos, Stephanie and Andrienetta Kritzinger (2004). ‘Squaring the Circle: Global Production and the Informalization of Work in South African Fruit Exports’ Journal of International Development 16:81-92 Bergsten C. Fred (2001) ‘Fifty Years of Trade Policy: The Policy Lessons’, The World Economy, 24 (1):1-13 Bezuidenhout, Andries (2000) ‘Towards a global social movement unionism? Trade union responses to globalization in South Africa’ Labour and Society Programme Discussion Paper 115. ILO. 6 See the Hausmann (2009) vs Fine debates (2009a), (2009b) 9 Bezuidenhout, Andries et al. (2007) ‘Globalisation and Poverty: Impacts on Households of Employment and Restructuring in the Textiles Industry of South Africa’, Journal of International Development 19: 545-565 Bezuidenhout, Andries and Bridget Kenny (2000) ‘The Language of Flexibility and the Flexibility of Language: Post-Apartheid South African Labour Market Debates’, Sociology of Work Unit, University of the Witwatersrand: http://www.swopinstitute.org.za/files/bezuidenhout_kenny_flexibility.pdf Chang, Ha-Joon (2005) ‘Policy Space in Historical Perspective – with special reference to Trade and Industrial Policies’, Talk presented at Tufts University, October 27, 2005 Cornia, Giovanni Andrea and Julius Court (2001) ‘ Inequality, Growth and Poverty in the Era of Liberalization and Globalization’. UNU-WIDER Policy Brief (4) Deraniyagala S. (2005) “Neoliberalism in International Trade: Sound Economics or a Question of Faith?” chapter 10 in Saad-Filho and D. Johnston (eds.) Neoliberalism: A Critical Reader, pp. 99-105 Deraniyagala S. and Fine, B. (2001)‘New trade theory versus old trade policy: a continuing enigma’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 25(6):809-825 Draper, Peter and Nkululeko Khumalo (2005) ‘Friend or Foe? South Africa and Sub-Saharan Africa in the Global Trading System’ in Reconfiguring the Compass: South Africa’s African Trade Diplomacy. ed. Peter Draper, The South African Institute of International Affairs: Braamfontein Dunne, Paul and Lawernce Edwards. (2006) Trade and Poverty in South Africa: Exploring the trade-labour linkages, Trade and Poverty Project, South Africa Labour and Research Unit, University of Cape Town Edwards, Lawrence (2006). ‘Trade liberalisation and labour demand in South Africa during the 1990s’, Poverty and Policy in Post-Apartheid South Africa, eds. Haroon Bhorat and Ravi Kanbur. HSRC Press: Cape Town Edwards, Lawrence and Robert Lawrence (2008) ‘South African trade policy matters: Trade Performance and Trade Policy’ Economies of Transition 16 (4) : 585-608 Fedderke, J and P Vaze (2001). ‘The Nature of South Africa’s Trade Patterns by Economic Sector, and the Extent of Trade Liberalisation During the Course of the 1990’s’, The South African Journal of Economics 69(3): 463-478 10 Fine, Ben (2009a). ‘Submission to the COSATU Panel of Economists on “The Final Recommendations of the International Panel on Growth” (the Harvard Panel)’ Transformation 69: 5-30 -------- (2009b). ‘Rejoinder to “A Response to Fine’s ‘Harvard Group Shores up Shoddy Governance’’ Transformation 69: 66-80 Hart, Gillian (2002). Disabling Globalization: Places of Power in PostApartheid South Africa University of California Press: Los Angeles Hausmann, R. and Klinger, B. (2008) ‘South Africa’s export predicament’, Economics of Transition, 16(4) : 609–63 Hausmann, Ricardo and Matt Andrews (2009). ‘Why we still believe exports for jobs will lead to shared growth: A response to Fine’s “Harvard Group Shores up Shoddy Governance”’. Transformation 69: 31-65 Kowalski, Przemyslaw, Ralph Lattimore and Novella Bottini (2009) ‘South Africa’s Trade and Growth’ OECD Trade Policy Working Paper (91), Working Party of the Trade Committee, OECD McCulloch, Neil, Winters, L Alan, Cirera, Xavier (2001). Trade Liberalisation and Poverty: A Handbook. CEPR: UK Marais, Hein (2001). South Africa: Limits to Change, The Political Economy of Transition. Zed Books, University of Cape Town Press: Cape Town Patnaik U. (2005) ‘Ricardo’s Fallacy: Mutual Benefit from Trade Based on Comparative Costs and Specialization?’ in Jomo K.S. (ed.) The Pioneers of Development Economics: Great Economists on Development, ch. 3, London: Zed Books Qobo, Mzukisi (2005) ‘The Political Economy of Regional Integration in Southern Africa’ in Reconfiguring the Compass: South Africa’s African Trade Diplomacy. ed. Peter Draper, The South African Institute of International Affairs: Braamfontein Roberts, Simon and John Thoburn. (2003) ‘Adjusting to Trade Liberalisation: The Case of Firms in the South African Textile Sector’, Journal of African Economics 12 (1): 74-103 -------- (2004) ‘Globalisation and the South African Textiles Industry: Impacts on Firms and Workers’, Journal of International Development 16:125139 Rodrik, Dani. (2008) ‘Understanding South Africa’s economic puzzles’, Economics of Transition, 16(4) :769-797 Singh, Ajit (1995), ‘North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill- Driven World’. The Economic Journal, 105 (432): 11 1287-1289 UNCTAD (2004) Least Developed Countries Report 2004: Linking International Trade with Poverty Reduction, Weisbrot, M. and Baker, D. ‘The Relative Impact of Trade Liberalization on Developing Countries’ in The Development Imperative: Toward a People-Centered Approach, eds. Hershberg, E. and Thornton, T. Social Sciences Research Council New York: 2005 12