1 Bl...04.doc 1. Introduction and Overview. I have recently maintained that certain narrow new issues in global trade negotiations belong there quite naturally.1 I labeled those issues market-supportive regulations -- regulations that enhance the “market system” by making it work better and for a broader constituency. Here I extend that claim, and maintain that the same narrow new issues are closely conformable to the World Trade Organization (WTO)’s founding principles and time-refined instruments. I argue that the WTO is indeed the right forum for the new-issue experiments that I propose. I believe that the inclusion of market-supportive regulations in WTO-conformable trade negotiations is in fact the key to generating a new wave of gains from trade and to widely disseminating those gains within and among societies. Ideally both market enthusiasts and society will “win,” much as they did during the Progressive Era in the United States around the turn of the last century. But only a narrow sub-set of new issues belong. Only those regulatory principles that conform most closely to the WTO and to the market system belong on the negotiating agenda. Too broad an array of new issues would threaten the organization with mission creep and complicate global trade negotiations. My preferred narrow sub-set includes principles and practices from the domains of intellectual-property policies, competition policies, and – provocatively --labor-relations policies. But the broad issues are better addressed in dedicated organizations such as the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) and the International Labor Organization (ILO). Going forward on my specific new issues has unappreciated value. It is a way to do two urgently needed things: to further empower the WTO-centered global market system and, simultaneously, to increase its constituency and thus enhance its broad legitimacy. Doing two things in one negotiation is a bargain – in this case a grand social bargain that both supports the global market system and diffuses its benefits widely. Why does the market system need further empowerment? I will argue that the market system is a remarkable social mechanism for reaching objectives of all kinds -- necessary and noble, individual and communal, monetary and intangible -- non-coercively. Its global extension promises similar rewards.2 Second, and more important, I believe that the current market system needs an incentive to negotiate on issues of its own legitimacy, limits, and regulation. Its gains 1 2 Richardson (2000b, 2001). Further negotiated market integration is still well worth it for all WTO members, including the United States. New research suggests sizeable gains to further global liberalization, even for relatively open countries like the United States. These gains are of many kinds -- gains from goods and services, from stronger export engagement and deeper import dependence, and from inward and outward investment and technology transfer (OECD (1998)). Much of this new research has been carried out at the grass roots -- firm-by-firm, worker-by-worker, county-bycounty. It is surveyed in Richardson (2000a) and Lewis and Richardson (2001). 2 from negotiating new liberalization with new issues, standing side by side with procedural and material gains for worker organizations, technology users, and nascent and small firms, are what make my proposed way forward viable -- because it is mutually attractive, “win-win.”3 Why pay any attention to shrill, sometimes violent pleas for legitimacy? Why any new issues at all, however narrowly defined by the term “market-supportive”? Why not WTO business as usual? Why not just say no to new issues?4 I maintain that “business -- as usual” is no longer an option. The broad, global backlash against it is here to stay.5 There will be no successful multilateral negotiations this way, no chance to enjoy the new gains from global integration without some broadening of the perceived beneficiary base beyond business. In fact such broadening within the United States 100 years ago, via wisely targeted market-supportive regulation, was the key to unlocking 20th-century prosperity in the integrated American market.6 Why the WTO for my proposal when there are alternative forums and mechanisms? Part of my answer is that it is natural -- the WTO already oversees a market-supportive body of regulations; indeed that is one of its main purposes. Another part of my answer is that the WTO has already started implementing new market-supportive regulation in the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) Agreement, and in basic telecommunications and other services.7 The most important part of my answer is that WTO principles and precedents, painstakingly forged over a half-century, have significant promise in helping implement marketsupportive, constituency-broadening, multilateral agreements over new and old concerns. The principles are already the vital heart of the WTO process -- periodic ministerial meetings and negotiations over reciprocal, non-discriminatory concessions, implemented transparently with consultations at the beginning of conflict resolution. The precedents include familiar WTO tools such as notification, consultation, standstill, and others. Sanctions and formal dispute settlement play no initial role in my proposals. Nor do I try very hard to go beyond established principles and precedents to “model” the ideal WTO; that is admittedly a vital question, but better addressed in a broader essay.8 3 In the language of labor negotiations (see especially Walton and McKersie (1965)), I am proposing integrative bargaining in restarting WTO negotiations; I am trying to minimize distributive bargaining. Odell (2000) applies similar categories to ten recent international economic negotiations, comparing them along a spectrum from valuecreating to value-claiming behavior. 4 As recommended most strongly, for example, in a number of the chapters in Bhagwati (1999) or Bhagwati and Hudec (1996). 5 For evidence that the backlash characterizes even the middle classes of the richest countries, and not just Seattle street protestors, see Scheve and Slaughter (2001), O’Rourke and Sinnott (2001), and Mayda and Rodrik (2001). 6 This observation, however, begs the question of how the global governance structure (including that of the WTO) might have to change to accommodate further market-supportive regulation. For provocative treatments of this question, see Falk and Strauss () and Schott and Watal (). 7 8 See Blackhurst (1998) and Winham and Lanoszka (2000). See, for the beginnings of debate on what the WTO should be ideally Barfield (2001), Charnovitz (2001), Howse and Nicolaidis (2001), Ostry (2001), and Roessler (2001). 3 Why include any incendiary labor issues, putting at risk easier and wiser incorporation of policies to buttress competition and diffusion of ideas? My primary answer is that without some predictable means for typical workers world-wide to share more widely in the gains from deeper global integration, there is no longer a political coalition to sustain it. Its mutual benefits are no longer adequate to be approved in a democratic referendum, to say nothing of popular opinion.9 My secondary answer is that narrow, well-designed regulations to govern worker-agency services actually alleviate market shortcomings; allowing open trade in worker-agency services would alleviate them even better. In Section 2 below, I describe what I mean by idiosyncratic terms such as market system and market-supportive regulation, and relate them to the WTO. In Sections 3, 4, and 5, I outline my case for including three very specific market-supportive new issues in the WTO’s negotiating agenda. In Section 6, I review in more detail how it could work for the WTO in practice, naturally. I finish with brief discussions of why domestic political constituencies might come to support incorporation of these narrow new issues into the WTO, and how my proposal differs from those that emphasize political deal-making or stakeholder democratization. 2. Market-Supportive Regulation and the Market System Market-supportive regulations are those that enhance the market system, making it more effective, stable, and sustainable, both economically and politically. They are in fact vital organs for a healthy market system. What I call the "market system" is a peculiar mix of competition and cooperation. Everyone is familiar with the competition. But few reflect very deeply on the cooperation. Almost all the units that compete are social groupings, whose internal organization is for the most part cooperative, not competitive. “Firm” is the generic term for these units -- corporations, partnerships, “not-for-profits,” labor unions, and others. The final goods, on which households and much of economics focuses, are assembled from materials and components that have already been bought and sold many times by firms, through a long series of exchanges in both input markets and in internal, intra-firm transactions. The market system is thus a complex, vertical, and social network of purchases and sales, contracts and conventions among firms -- social units. The market system is itself a mix of competition and cooperation, a social organism.10 The quality of the organism’s competition and cooperation determines how effectively and efficiently it combines fundamental inputs such as 9 See Richardson et al. (1998)) for expansion of this argument that the distribution of gains from traditional trade liberalization is not democratically sustainable. See Scheve and Slaughter (2001), Ch. 4, for evidence that in the United States, the typical worker and voter has gained disproportionately little of the gains from recent globalization. See Elliott and Freeman (2001) for an argument that some form of international agreement on core labor standards, though not ideally at the WTO, is the natural complement to freer trade because of its income distributional effects. 10 Lindblom (2001) and Fligstein (2001) describe a market system in similar terms, and provide extensive discussion of “market-systemic” thinking and issues. 4 worker services to produce final goods for those very workers. In other words, the quality of this social market system determines the standard of living of its workers. Economic regulations condition this competitive-cooperative market system, internally within a firm and externally across them.11 Among other goals, such regulations aim to make the market system work better and for a broader constituency. Designed properly, they are marketsupportive and simultaneously part of the broader social infrastructure.12 They regulate the intensity of competition, the scope of cooperation, and define the due processes and legal boundaries for both, including the important boundary between coercive and voluntary transactions.13 Specific examples help to make this argument tight. 1. Company law enhances the market for corporate control; it establishes categories of voting rights and procedures for shareholders, and determines when and how a rival firm’s managers can compete for the shareholders’ allegiance (cooperation). 2. Labor-relations law enhances the market for cooperative representation -- agency14; it establishes workplace voting procedures for workers to be represented collectively by a union, and when and how another union could compete for certification to organize the workers cooperatively. 3. Intellectual-property law aims to undergird the markets for artistic creation and productive innovation, indirectly compensating for externalities and for missing inter-generational markets. In sum, the market system is socially populated, socially rooted, socially conditioned, and socially constructed. It is far, far away from the chaotically competitive "law of the jungle" with which it is sometimes rhetorically confused. Many of the market’s social groups have legal status that grants them the right to collectively own and exchange property, including intangible property (e.g., intellectual property) and licenses (e.g., to represent a set of workers), and to differentiate and isolate their legal liability as group members from their liability as individuals. 11 This “progressive” view of the way government regulation can support markets (or “augment” them, to use Mancur Olson’s term) has deep roots in economic history and philosophy, in the institutional school, and in the social gospel. For recent articulations, see Reich (1991), World Bank (1997), Garrett (1998), Holmes and Sunstein (1999), Olson and Kahkonen (2000), and Blunden and Burke (2001), and, for underlying theory, Anderson and Young (2000) and Glaeser and Schleifer (2001a,b). It is unfortunate that the progressive view is often submerged by both shallow, breathless defenses of “free” markets and alarmist, populist accounts of the war between greed and governance. 12 13 Not all economic regulations are market-supportive. Some are market-prohibiting, others market-inhibiting -though often “for a good cause” (e.g., prohibitions on slavery or on markets in socially dangerous goods and services, or limitations on current markets to avoid extinction of future markets, as in fisheries regulation). Still other regulations are distant from markets, such as so-called social regulation (Noll (1997)). Social regulations are important -- vitally important -- but they are not promising issues for impending trade negotiations. Social regulations are too distant, too diversionary, not sufficiently conformable, orthogonal ((Nivola (1997), though Rodrik (1997), Ch. 5 provides an economist’s counter-position). 14 Markets for agency are often missing because of well-known dilemmas such as coordination or collective-action problems. 5 I maintain that, correspondingly, an economically and politically sustainable global market system will be socially constructed and conditioned, too, by policy design.15 I maintain further that three kinds of limited, market-supportive economic regulations are natural companions to global markets, enhancing their performance and broadening their legitimacy, and natural friends of the WTO process. The best illustration and least controversial of these three is the WTO’s Trade-Related Intellectual Property (TRIPs) Agreement. 3. Supporting Both Markets for Ideas in the WTO. The TRIPs Agreement is a noble and natural WTO experiment in market-supportive regulation, with promising features to be nurtured and imitated. Yet I maintain that it is a pilot for only half of what I have in mind. It supports the global market for generating new ideas far more strongly than it supports the global market for selling and distributing new ideas. In a sense, it is too narrow. The whole market is really two markets, innovation and dissemination, as are production and distribution for many other goods. A TRIPs distributionAgreement could empower final users of intellectual property, not just the owner/developer. It would also broaden the constituency of support for TRIPs and the WTO. At a basic level, ideas are information. Reasonably complete, diffuse information is a good itself, capable of being owned, and a pre-condition for markets to work well — effectively, fairly, with minimal discrimination. These three criteria are virtually the same desiderata as the WTO pursues fundamentally for global markets. Market-supportive information is the reason that the WTO insists on detailed, accurate, accessible “notification” of border-relevant policies by every member country (an unsung requirement and benefit of membership). The WTO’s firm commitment to non-discrimination is both fair and efficient. Markets work anyway, of course, in environments with imperfect or asymmetric information, including uncertain property rights. But they don’t necessarily work well (effectively, fairly, with minimal discrimination). A large microeconomics literature has shown this over the past twenty years. Imperfectly informed markets sometimes waste resources; they sometimes leave capable buyers isolated (rationed by discrimination); they sometimes violate the market system’s self-imposed limitation to voluntary, non-coercive transactions. Imperfectly informed markets and information markets themselves need regulatory support to enhance their performance and to make them both defensible and legitimate. That is what led to the development of intellectual property (IP) rights historically. The globalization of these markets led to the family of IP treaties overseen by the World Intellectual Property Association (WIPO), and the WTO’s TRIPs Agreement refined and rationalized aspects of that regulatory support. But it embodied only partial support at best. It was a good beginning at further support for producing new information, new ideas, and new technologies. But ongoing 15 Wright (2000) and the more constructive globalization protestors argue a similar thesis. 6 second-phase TRIPs negotiations should more strongly support the global sub-market for distribution -- the business-to-business “retail market” for information users and traders.16 With this aim, in Richardson (2000b, 2001) I proposed two families of marketsupportive, constituency-broadening TRIPs refinements: facilitation measures for the distribution market and standstill on controversial carry-over issues. The terms both spring from long WTO experience, and I read the Doha Ministerial to have endorsed the spirit of each. 1. Facilitation. There has been little formalization of the technical and financial assistance provision of the TRIPs Agreement (Part VII). New adopters of TRIPs regimens have been loathe to pay their own administrative implementation costs, especially when short-term forecasts have these countries together paying out up to $5 billion annually in royalties and fees to IP-abundant countries.17 A market-supportive way to cover up-front administrative fixed costs is to finance them by external loans from idea producers. The loans could then be serviced out of transitional “facilitation fees” on cross-border royalties paid for host-country IP protection. Such an arrangement facilitates and finances mutually beneficial technical assistance, and licensing (distribution) as well. It is similar to the way many countries fund ports. It should be conceived as “rent-reinvestment” rather than “rent-shifting.” It could be tactically implemented by Copyright and Patent Offices and by public-private consortia, rather than by diplomatic agencies. It would create natural forums for negotiating licensing and “follow-on innovation,” which aid in both the production and distribution of technology and information. But it requires the WTO to authorize and regularize user fees for the “technology turnpike,” essentially a temporary tariff (possibly degressive) on imports of the services of IP. Like user fees in many countries, tariff revenues would be earmarked for servicing the loans that financed the infrastructural implementation of TRIPs in the importing country. 2. Standstill. The current TRIPs Agreement preserves a great deal of national discretion (sovereignty). For example, there is national discretion on implementation definitions and procedures (e.g., “working requirements”), publishing conventions for patents, exemptions (e.g., for plant breeding, health-related and other non-commercial research, environmental and species preservation, non-commercial use), and treatment of parallel imports. Such discretion has surprising market value (option value) in cultures and environments where the very idea of property rights to technology is new. It allows experimentation with different standards and regulatory competition among them, in essence “innovation” in the procedures of IP protection to establish regulatory “best practice.” Considerations like these suggest the value of stabilizing and regularizing such status-quo discretion, via a TRIPs standstill agreement, at least for a time, rather than pushing ahead with deeper, tighter TRIPs commitments along the technology- 16 Maskus (2000b), pp. 225-226, and World Bank (2001), Ch. 5, seem to share this conviction. The two sub-markets for innovation and dissemination are very different (see, for example, Stoneman (1992) and Geroski (2000)), and the agents (constituents) involved are also very different, just as they are for electricity generation and distribution (U.S. Economic Report of the President (1999), Ch. 5, pp. 211-218). 17 McCalman (1998). 7 production lines emphasized in the existing TRIPs Agreement. I think the Doha Ministerial came close to agreeing.18 I have also argued in Richardson (2000b, 2001) that technology aspects of the WTO’s current TRIMs (Trade-Related Investment Measures) Agreement might also benefit from a standstill aimed at preserving national discretion (sovereignty). In particular, technology-transfer performance requirements on inward investors were not banned by the Uruguay-Round TRIMs Agreement. Preserving a country’s option to negotiate technology-transfer requirements for inward investors -- a ban on any ban -- is arguably supportive of the market for distributing technology. Unlike other performance requirements, these may “pay off” in host countries.19 Among other reasons, technology transfer performance requirements encourage commercial negotiations over licensing, without necessarily dictating its terms. Without them, anticompetitive, anti-market “refusal to deal” can become entrenched. Many technologies are, in essence, akin to “essential facilities” in the competition-policy protocols that govern transportation and telecommunications markets. In such cases “negotiated compulsion” is a familiar market-supportive tool of competition authorities20 (e.g., compulsory divestiture, ceaseand-desist orders, consent decrees over licensing) and of buyer-protection agencies (e.g., compulsory warranties, truth in advertising). But why the WTO for any of this? The most obvious reason is that the WTO has already committed to incorporating new market-supportive regulations along these lines, not only in TRIPs and TRIMs, but also in its Information Technology Agreements, in financial services and 18 The one exception to such discretionary forbearance, also an exception at Doha, is negotiations to create a distribution-encouraging agreement disciplining parallel imports of public-health-related products and technologies, as endorsed by Maskus (2000a, 2000b, pp. 229-230) (see also World Bank (2001), Ch. 5). The aim of such an agreement would be to allow some international price discrimination in relevant pharmaceuticals and related products, and to discipline the arbitrage that sometimes undermines it. The aim would be low prices in poor countries with significant public health needs, offset by higher prices in richer countries. The aim would be to expand markets to include users willing/able to pay only the marginal cost of public-health-related goods. The “progressivity” of the implicit financial transfers is obvious. The likely positive (global) welfare effects of permissible price discrimination are less obvious, but are presumptively significant from the analysis of Malueg and Schwartz (1994). 19 Technology-transfer requirements need not be actually imposed to be a powerful negotiating tool, and they will not be imposed if a valuable investor would go elsewhere because of them. Nor does a government itself have to negotiate the precise terms of any technology-transfer requirement, but can empower its local constituents to do so instead. Though Moran (1998, 2001) argues persuasively that investor performance requirements for local content or joint ventures actually inhibit the global dissemination of technology, the research support he cites is much weaker for his view that export and technology-transfer requirements also inhibit technology dissemination. I suspect that well-designed export and technology-transfer performance requirements, in fact, often serve pro-competitively as internal host-country antidotes to foreign investors negotiating exclusive, privileged, anti-competitive local market power for themselves (e.g., exclusive rights to supply). See Hausman and Sidak (2000) for a recent treatment of the related idea that mandated “unbundling” of the different elements of a telecommunications network is pro-competitive. Process technologies especially can often be unbundled from other productive inputs and sold separately (licensed out). See Jensen and Thursby (1996) for a theoretical explanation of the way compulsory licensing in the context of global standard setting can enhance the quality and quantity of trade. 20 8 basic telecommunications, and maybe in coming e-commerce protocols. But most of the regulations support idea and technology production. The time is ripe for a second phase, undertaking technology commitments along the distribution-oriented lines sketched above. If done wisely, the WTO will pull users of technology and ideas into the group of beneficiaries from global integration and broaden its support base beyond the creative but elite innovator community. A less obvious reason for making the WTO the forum for IP-distribution agreements relates to competition policy. Article 40 of the TRIPs Agreement explicitly recognizes that anticompetitive practices can be an unwelcome by-product of IP protection, and illustrates several such practices. The TRIMs Agreement formally calls for competition policies to be taken into account when the agreement is subjected to its first WTO review. The WTO is thus already scheduled to consider its own texts in a competition-policy light. But the frontier of critical thinking in competition policy is clearly the tension between protecting the incentives to innovate and encouraging the distribution of its fruits to users. 21 4. Supporting the Market for Entrants in the WTO. Given the WTO’s support of global markets for new ideas and technologies, it is not unnatural to consider WTO support of global market access for new outputs of new rivals – new entry in the language of competition policy. It is especially attractive to consider constituencybroadening versions of both kinds of market support – support that benefits users of new ideas/technologies and that also benefits innovative firms, with new products and processes, wanting to penetrate the markets of entrenched rivals. These kinds of support go together naturally, because new entry is often the means by which new ideas reach the market. I will maintain -- more controversially, in the next section – that it is a short further step for the WTO to support “markets” for new labor institutions that embody new ideas, new processes, and new rivalries, while simultaneously broadening its constituency to workers. Baseline competition policies are one of the best examples of market-supportive regulations that conform to the fundamental purposes of the WTO and that enhance its legitimacy. Multilateral trade negotiations and competition policies usually have very similar objectives. An important aim of both is more open, contestable, non-discriminatory market organization of economic activity. Contestability denotes the right to compete for market access by exporters, foreign investors, and small and new home suppliers alike. These groups are the beneficiaries and constituents of the WTO’s potential incorporation of competition-policy baselines that answer fundamental questions about the social conditions of competition. Who may compete with whom? Or displace them, or absorb them? Under what contingencies? With what kinds of government support? Using what processes, technology, contractual practices, employment relations? The development of baseline competition policies a century ago in the 21 Admittedly, perspective and practice on how competition policies need to be different, if at all, for technologyintensive activities, is still being worked out. Gilbert and Shapiro (1997), U.S. Economic Report of the President (1999), Ch. 5, and Shapiro (2001). 9 United States helped quell the strong opposition to “robber-baron” capitalism that threatened American national market integration. In previous writings, Edward M. Graham and I22 recommended that first-generation initiatives include only the gradual commitment of all WTO members to implementing narrow competition policies concerning cartel practices and anti-competitive horizontal restrictions, and to creating guidelines for merger and acquisition. In our approach these baseline policies involved no cross-territorial rules and minimal imposition on sovereignty. They were notified to the WTO, which also oversaw a process of consultations, 23 and maybe conciliation, but initially not formal dispute settlement. To emphasize the modest, though market-supportive goals of these proposals, we endorsed a plurilateral approach within the WTO.24 Graham’s and my initial proposals met significant skepticism, especially among American commentators, though less so among Europeans.25 More recently, however, antitrust officials around the world have endorsed cautious moves in the direction we recommended, albeit with no focus on the WTO. Specifically, they have embraced both a Global Competition Initiative recommended by an expert panel (ICPAC (2000)) that would begin a process of cooperation on competition policies, and a narrower International Competition Network of competition-policy officials from both developing and developed countries to discuss bestpractice procedures and substance.26 22 See Richardson (1998a,b; 1999), Graham and Richardson (1999), and the series of papers brought together in Graham and Richardson (1997a,b). 23 We envisioned obligations undertaken by competition-policy authorities (perhaps in concert with trade-policy authorities) to investigate, if requested after consultations, behavior in their jurisdictions that spills over anticompetitively to others (perhaps subject to some threshold of injury), and to mediate conflicts that remain, perhaps along lines outlined in EPG (1995), pp. 12-15 and Annex. Not all behavior would be eligible. Only that which impedes horizontal contestability, as defined for both trade and investment, would be covered. Investment coverage would include mergers and acquisitions with effects on the value of other WTO commitments. The procedural effort would itself be nurtured sequentially. It would begin with a process of positive comity, advancing to (mandatory) consultation, even among countries with little formal competition policy. It would ultimately involve a commitment to informational mediation or conciliation, as nations take on more organized competition-policy commitments. It would explicitly not involve dispute settlement procedures. Only in a second phase did we imagine a commitment to negotiate a Trade-Related Antitrust Measures (TRAMs) Agreement, focused on first-phase baseline practices, and to bring normal dispute settlement to bear, and only contingent on successful experience in the first phase.. 24 Additional plurilateral agreements under the WTO must be approved by consensus, but at least one informed commentator (Jackson (2000), pp. 343-344) thinks that sufficiently attractive WTO plurilaterals could be “normally accepted,” i.e., accepted without explicit objection. 25 See Tarullo (2000) for a recent and extensive American skepticism. See Lloyd (1998), Llyod and Vautier (1999), and Meiklejohn (1999) for less skeptical weighing of pros and cons. See Brittan (1997) and Van Miert (1998) for early European enthusiasm. See Mattoo (2000) and Maskus and Lahouel (2001) for sympathetic treatments from the perspective of developing countries. Other recent and valuable discussions of the issues include Evenett, Lehmann, and Steil (2000), Janow and Shapiro (2001), and the five Annual Reports of the Working Group on the Interaction Between Trade and Competition Policy (downloadable from www.wto.org under WT/WGTCP/number of report). The Global Competition Initiative would be institutionally free-standing, a “forum” focused initially on procedural cooperation and merger review, involving the WTO, but not focused on it. It would also involve the OECD, 26 10 But why should the WTO be the focus of such initiatives, albeit with continued existence of these new competition-policy bodies? An important reason is that WTO-sponsored liberalization in key services sectors, basic telecommunications, and information technology (where newer and smaller suppliers are numerous) will be the principal proving ground for how broadly contestable global markets really are. A second reason is that baseline competitionpolicy commitments by large, new, members of the WTO, especially China and Russia, will solidify the organization. Without such commitments, all the more traditional WTO conventions “at the border” will be seriously undermined by private practices “behind” it; both countries are still implementing internal, inter-regional freedom of trade. A third reason is that the adoption of baseline competition policies in all WTO members helps to ease each member’s transition toward more open borders. Enhancing internal contestability helps rationalize a country’s internal market structure, allowing the fittest firms to prosper, absorbing weaker firms, and thereby finding it easier to cope with additional pressures from freer trade and investment.27 A fourth reason is that baseline competition policies can protect an economy from the worst abuses of other policies that support markets – specifically from abuses of policies that protect technological property rights and rights of workers to associate and to be represented by an agent, policies to which we turn next. 5. Supporting the Market for Agency in the WTO. WTO agreement on narrow market-supportive labor regulations is the most radical -- and the most speculative -- aspect of my thesis. But I claim it is still natural. It would encompass only one of the familiar core labor principles, specifically freedom of association and collective bargaining. It belongs in the WTO because it is basically a proposal for liberalization of trade in services — worker agency services -- the market services of “agency” that worker organizations and labor unions ideally provide.28 It therefore falls sensibly and naturally under the rubric of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). Under my proposal, the International Labor Organization would remain the forum for discussion of and commitment to the many important broader labor-market principles, beyond this one. In Elliott and Richardson (2002), a colleague and I evaluate, then endorse, open trade in worker agency services. We see it as entirely conformable to the WTO’s endorsement of open UNCTAD, the World Bank, governments, and practitioners and commentators in an advisory capacity. See, for detail, Janow (2000). The International Competition Network, involving competition-policy authorities only, is already in operation: see www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org. 27 See Broadman (1999, 2001) for documentation of this in the Russian case. Agency in this sense is merely representation; agents represent “principals,” in the familiar technical language – workers in this case. For a more detailed exposition of such agency in labor markets, see Stiglitz (2000), Part II. Pencavel (1991) is the most comprehensive treatment I know of labor unions as agents for their worker/principals, though he restricts his attention only to their wage, hours, and employment effects. See also Freeman and Medoff (1986), Freeman and Kleiner (1990), and Kochan (2000). 28 11 trade in other services. We maintain that all workers should enjoy the (property) right to be represented by an agent. Not that all should exercise that right. Not that most will. On the contrary, the right to be represented is an option, a non-coercive aspect of free choice, but with one important condition, a quid pro quo. The important condition is group obligation – a social contract with other workers represented by that agent. Such legally enforceable group obligations are not exotic or strange; they are familiar features of all market systems and polities.29 We understand such worker agency services to encompass a wide range. They include: collective representation and bargaining over wages, benefits, and working conditions; workplace safety monitoring; grievance and dispute settlement; training, apprenticeship, and employee assistance; financial counsel and management of other benefits (e.g., pensions, child care). We emphasize the market-supportive character of these services. They alleviate market failures associated with collective action problems, workplace public goods,30 imperfect information, and relationship-specific assets.31 They discipline practices that border on coercion (recall that the market system pre-supposes voluntarism). They create countervailing market power to any anticompetitive market power of firms. When entry and accessibility are present, that is, when alternative local and global suppliers can contest the right to represent workers as agents, they perfect the market for such services. They enhance their quality and variety, they encourage innovation in worker agency services, they lower their cost. We foresee the same sort of gains from open trade in worker agency services as exist for other agency services. Open trade in distribution services provides enhanced agency for producers. Open trade in accounting and legal services provides enhanced agency for users of information about firms (e.g., investors in them). Open trade in brokerage and underwriting provides enhanced agency for borrowers, entrepreneurs, and innovators. Open trade enhances options non-coercively,32 including the default option of being one’s own agent. 29 Such obligation is no more coercive than laws that constrain individual voters, whether they voted for the laws or not, or by-laws that constrain individual members of a firm or other social unit. 30 Workplace public goods are defined by Pencavel (1991, p. 6) as the unwritten rules and conventions that are too costly to write down in detail, and that benefit workers (and often employers) in a non-excludable, non-rival way. Relationship-specific assets are essentially what a firm’s incumbent workers provide. In general, they are defined in the context of contractual relationships that add extra economic value to the intrinsic value of assets that contracting agents bring to the relationship. The relationship-specific value of these assets is the extra value that the contract adds. But once negotiated, contracts are usually costly to break. In that case there is an incentive for each agent, through opportunistic behavior, to tilt the distribution of the extra value in their favor. This is called the “hold-up” problem. Such opportunism, almost always present in contracts covering relation-specific assets, is more than a distributional question. It causes inefficiency, specifically under-investment in all relation-specific assets, including the employment relationship. On the general issues, see, for example Besanko, Dranove, and Shanley (1996), pp. 110-121. On their application to employment relationships, see Stiglitz (2000), pp. 16 passim. 31 32 Especially if baseline competition policies are in place and applicable (perhaps applicable in special ways) to worker agency. 12 Implementation of a market-supportive worker-agency agreement at the WTO would necessarily proceed modestly and procedurally, because this is a radical idea in many dimensions. But given the structure of the GATS, it could begin quite innocuously. A charter group of WTO members could explicitly include worker agency services (along with suitable definitions and mutual recognition arrangements under Article VII of the GATS) among the other sectors with “specific (binding) commitments” that they were prepared to make. The commitments would cover only freedom of association and the right to collective bargaining, and would presumably designate activities (e.g., movement of personnel, “commercial” presence) and/or economic sectors in which national treatment would be offered to foreign labor unions and other workeragency organizations. There would be no initial need for any plurilateral agreement on traderelated worker-agency services, though that might be the natural outcome of ongoing negotiation and favorable initial experience in “trading” such services. There would be no need for any specific WTO working group on core labor rights, though presumably the standard reporting of the Services Council and the Trade Policy Review Mechanism would provide monitoring of the particular commitments made. Only in the distant future might one imagine widely crosssectoral rights of establishment and national treatment for foreign worker-agency organizations (subject to a limited number of negotiated exceptions). In the early stages of any such experiment, national discretion (sovereignty) would be virtually unaffected. Only those countries committed to implementing baseline freedom of association and collective-bargaining would need to notify these commitments to the WTO under the GATS. Mechanisms might even be initially negotiated for committing “provisionally,” in a non-binding way, without dispute settlement or sanctions, yet with (non-binding) consultations, conciliation, and forms of mediation.33 Our focus on just the most market-supportive core labor right -- freedom of association and collective bargaining -- leaves a great deal of scope for both distinctive national laborrelations law and for ILO initiatives on broader labor rights. Countries would maintain considerable sovereign flexibility, even with binding GATS worker-agency commitments. Their sovereign ability would be unimpaired, for example, to regulate the locus of collective bargaining (plant, firm, industry, country) and to determine conditions for strikes (sectoral restrictions, arbitration/mediation rules, worker-replacement strictures, etc.). Our vision inevitably involves more than the traditional amount of competition among traditional unions and rival worker-agency institutions, including innovative new entrants. It opens labor relations to cross-border competition, too. But our vision does not disparage traditional worker solidarity. In fact, it emphasizes the fact that some unions serve their combined membership better than others (with fewer internal inefficiencies or political diversions, and less corruption). It also emphasizes global worker solidarity -- similar workers 33 Mechanisms could be similar to those featured above in the first phase of market-supportive competition-policy commitments. 13 world-wide can collectively and globally modulate the competition among themselves in the same way that nationally unionized workers in a single plant or firm do.34 But why the WTO? The most important reason is that our proposed arrangements for trade in worker agency services are market supportive, market-opening, and indistinguishable from GATS protocols for other services. They open trade in labor agency services to new entrants -- specifically to new kinds of labor unions and to traditional unions who are rethinking their objectives and roles under the heading “new unionism,” to developing-country unions who might be the most natural agents for future movements of natural persons cerified under Mode 4 of the GATS, to new sorts of employee and professional associations, and even to contract-labor and temporary-labor firms.35 Moreover, many familiar issues in labor relations, such as contract compliance and certification/de-certification, have natural analogs in competition policy.36 We envision that a WTO competition-policy agreement could be tailored to protect open and transparent competition among agents that represent workers, globally. Critics, of course, will have much to say skeptically about the detail of this proposal.37 They might find instructive, however, some of the detailed historical lessons from the American experience in forming nation-wide trade unions from regional counterparts as corresponding product markets became national a century ago.38 Critics may have even more to say about the apparent fundamental weakness of the proposal. “Unions just aren’t like that.” This paper’s answer is, “Maybe some are not, but they could be and should be.” Labor unions admittedly depart from market-supportive ideals, but so do firms. Mundane political objectives of labor unions can often conflict with market objectives (wages, benefits, working conditions), but mundane political objectives of firms similarly compete with their market objectives.39 Labor unions can be undemocratic, but so can firms (e.g., in voting vs. non-voting shares and in rights of minority shareholders). Labor unions can be corrupt, but so can firms. For an account of labor agents’ potential constructive role in modulating globalization, deregulation, and reform, see Freeman (1993), Section III and Stiglitz (2000), Part III. 34 35 For example, it is natural to contemplate temporary-worker and contract-worker locals of traditional unions, whose members want such jobs because of age, health, training experience, family commitment, or personal preferences. It is also natural to contemplate transferable membership across different types of locals and different regions. See Ulman (1966), Ch. 4-6. 36 And in technology policy, too, perhaps. For example, agent (union) certification might be time-limited, then renewable, like a patent. 37 Rollo and Winters (2001), for one recent example, is a thorough and critical dismissal of the WTO-suitability of broad environmental and labor standard; see also Brown (2001) recently on the unsuitability of labor standards. 38 39 See Ulman (1966). See Pencavel (1998), pp. 30-40. For example, firms, like unions, can divert enormous resources from market activities to support political parties, candidates, and regulatory agencies whose decisions will guarantee the firms political access and political security. 14 6. Why It Might Work Naturally at the WTO. My discussion above has explicitly and implicitly included many of the WTO’s historic principles and procedures that make narrow new issues “natural” for incorporation in future multilateral negotiations: fundamental commitments to openness, transparency, reciprocity, and nondiscrimination; instrumental commitments to notification, policy documentation, consultation, dispute resolution, standstill, mutual recognition, plurilateralism, accession. All this notwithstanding, there would be innumerable uncertainties and details to be worked out if these narrow market-supportive issues were to be integrated into the WTO. The uncertainty alone tempts long-time WTO supporters to “just say no to any more new issues.” Yet the intellectual-property and services issues are already on the table, including the labor-marketcentered Mode 4 of the GATS (movement of natural persons). These cannot be avoided, and may be insoluble without minimal competition-policy commitments that are conformable to WTO practice. One neglected feature of the WTO and the GATT encourages me not to say no, and instead to favor tackling the market-supportive sub-set of the new issues directly and in an integrated, constituency-broadening way. That feature is that the “organization” has always been malleable and incremental, almost experimental, moving from border taxes to non-tariff-barrier codes to standards and investment measures and single undertakings in gradual, precedentrespecting ways, measuring progress in decades, not years. It is this historic rules-oriented flexibility and incrementalism that makes me optimistic about details I cannot see. It is not clever constitutionalism that has made the organization successful, it is patient pragmeytism. The model of the WTO that I have in mind is meant to remain somewhat amorphous, somewhat elusive, somewhat experimental. Finally, WTO member governments right now may see grave risk and insufficient reward from incorporating any of the narrow new issues I have recommended. But I believe that is largely because large groups of their own citizen-voters see only grave risk and little reward for themselves in the traditional WTO agenda.40 There’s an equilibrium of torpor there, but it’s not the only equilibrium. My particular new sub-issues are not just market-supportive; they broaden the constituency of those with stakes in the WTO system. With such issues on the table, WTO member governments might soon find that open trade policy attracted new and supportive voter voices and coalitions. This vision is spelled out in greater detail in the next section. 7. Where The Local Political Support Lies. In democracies, no good idea is ever adopted without political support. Where would local political support come from for the provocation of this paper, that the WTO should embrace a narrow sub-set of new issues to enhance global markets and buttress its own global legitimacy? At first, the answer seems to vary with a member country’s standard of living. 40 This is borne out in the surveys cited in note 5 above. 15 Where would the local political support come from in richer countries? Not from the usual suspects. That would be looking for love in all the wrong places. The traditional private-sector trade community is lukewarm toward information dissemination, skeptical about global competition policies, and downright opposed to the global adoption of any core labor rights. At least for the moment .... But educators and farmers and hospitals and public-health agencies ought to recognize the value of baseline policies that facilitate distribution of technology. But small business ought to recognize the value of baseline competition-policy protection in home and foreign markets. But workers and their unions ought to recognize the value of multilateral support for the global association and bargaining rights that put them on the same footing as corporate owners of tangible and intellectual property rights. And if socially-oriented agencies, small businesses, workers, and unions are not seeing any significant gains for them from further globalization of the traditional kind, can anyone really blame them for thinking that multilateral liberalization serves only the profit-minded, capitalist owners of big business? And where would the local political support come from in poorer countries? Not from corrupt elites. They will realize that their power is undermined by open markets — open markets that are sought by competition policy and that are enhanced by worker-oriented competition among unions and other labor agents. They will realize that their power is also undermined by the security of all kinds of property rights, including those to develop and fairly apply innovation and those to represent workers collectively. But honest firms, and honest unions, and honest technology users, no matter how poor, are all potential gainers from these initiatives. So perhaps the answer to where the local political support lies does not vary across standards of living after all. Perhaps it can be summarized very crisply. Everywhere it comes from the margin — the margin of persons and groups on the outer edge of gains from the narrow, naked globalization of commerce alone. If, by contrast, the market system — as I have described it — is what is on the WTO’s negotiating table, are there not gains for large masses? And extra enhancement of global markets, too, as long as regulations are what I have called market-supportive? So that even commercial interests end up gaining, too, after all? Surely there’s more promise in positive WTO-based momentum on these new issues than the trickle-down of rising commercial tides, either within a country or among them! 16 8. Conclusion. I am persuaded that the WTO’s incorporation of a narrow sub-set of market-supportive new issues would unleash large mutual gains to a broad constituency of businesses, worker groups, and others, and clear the way for more legitimate and more sweeping global market integration in the new millennium. Others agree in part. But my proposal for sequentially embodying market-supportive new issues in the coming WTO negotiations is importantly different from two others. One is the stance of real politique -- concede new issues to buy off the opponents of further global integration -- “feed the trade sharks” as one commentator put it.41 The second is the populist stance of stakeholder economics, that somehow everyone has a civil or human right to voice or ownership in market institutions -- therefore new constituencies have a natural democratic right to be at the commercial negotiating table with their new issues. My problem with the first stance is that it is too crass, and yields too quickly to the nearzero-sum practice of tossing lesser bones to rival dogs. My problem with the second stance is its fundamental mis-understanding of both the limits of real democracy and the way that it has made itself prosperous by ceding conditional and exclusionary -- apparently un-democratic -- property rights to social market institutions. References Anderson, James E. and Leslie Young. 2000. “Trade Implies Law: The Power of the Weak,” Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7702, May. Barfield, Claude E. 2001. Free Trade, Sovreignty, Democracy: The Future of the World Trade Organization. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute Press. Besanko, David; David Dranove; and Mark Shanley. 1996. The Economics of Strategy. New York: John Wiley. Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1999. A Stream of Windows: Unsettling Reflections on Trade, Immigration, and Democracy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish and Robert E. Hudec. 1996. Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade?, Volumes 1 and 2, Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Blackhurst, Richard. 1998. “The Capacity of the WTO to Fulfill its Mandate,” in Anne O. Krueger, ed., The WTO as an International Organization, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 41 Stokes (1999). See also Destler and Balint (1999) and Wright (2000) for more extensive proposals apparently motivated by real politique. 17 Blunden, Margaret. 2001. “The State and the Market: Liberal Economies and the Democratic State,” in Blunden and Burke (2001). _ _ _. and Patrick Burke, eds. 2001. Democratic Reconstruction in the Balkans. London: Centre for the Study of Democracy. Brittan, Sir Leon. 1997. “Competition Policy and the Trading System: Towards International Rules in the WTO,” manuscript, remarks given for the Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C., November 20, 1997. Broadman, Harry G., ed. 1999. Russian Enterprise Reform: Policies to Further the Transition. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank. _ _ _. 2001. “Competition and Business Entry in Russia,” Finance & Development, June, pp. 22-25. Brown, Drusilla. 2001. “Labor Standards: Where Do They Belong on the International Trade Agenda?,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (Summer), pp. 89-112. Charnovitz, Steve. 2001. “Triangulating the World Trade Organization,” manuscript. Del Monte, Alfredo, ed. 1992. Recent Developments in the Theory of Industrial Organization, Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press. Destler, I. M. And Peter J. Balint. 1999. The New Politics of American Trade: Trade, Labor, and the Environment, Policy Analyses No. 58, Washington: Institute for International Economics, October. Elliott, Kimberly Ann and Richard B. Freeman. 2001. “Global Labor Standards and Free Trade: the Siamese Twins of the Global Economy,” manuscript, June. Elliott, Kimberly Ann and J. David Richardson. Forthcoming 2002. Open Trade in Worker Agency Services. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, in process. EPG (Eminent Persons Group). 1995. Implementing the APEC Vision. Singapore: APEC Secretariat. Third Report of the Eminent Persons Group, August. Esty, Daniel C. 1994. Greening the GATT: Trade, Environment, and the Future. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Evenett, Simon J.; Alexander Lehmann; and Benn Steil, eds. 2000. Antitrust Goes Global: What Future for Transatlantic Cooperation?, London: Royal Institute of International Affairs and Washington: Brookings Institution. 18 Falk, Richard and Andrew Strauss. 2001. “Toward Global Parliament,” Foreign Affairs, 80 (January/February), pp. 212-220. Feketekuty, Geza with Bruce Stokes. 1998. Trade Strategies for a New Era: Ensuring U.S. Leadership in a Global Economy, New York: Council on Foreign Relations. Fligstein, Neil. 2001. The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First Century Capitalist Societies. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Freeman, Richard B. 1993. “Labor Market Institutions and Policies: Help or Hindrance to Economic Development,” Washington, D.C., World Bank: Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1992. _ _ _ and Morris M. Kleiner. 1990. “The Impact of the New Unionization on Wages and Working Conditions,” Journal of Labor Economics, 8 (January), pp. S8-S25. _ _ _ and James L. Medoff. 1984. What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic. Garrett, Geoffrey. 1998. “Global Markets and National Politics: Collision Course or Virtuous Circle?,” International Organization, 52 (Autumn), pp. 787-824. Geroski, Paul. 2000. “Models of Technology Diffusion,” Research Policy, 29 (), pp. 603-625. Gilbert, Richard and Carl Shapiro. 1997. “Antitrust Issues in the Licensing of Intellectual Property: The Nine No-No’s Meet the Nineties,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, Washington: The Brookings Institution. Glaeser, Edward L. and Andrei Shleifer. 2001a. “Legal Origins,” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8272, May. _ _ _. 2001b. “The Rise of the Regulatory State,” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8650., December. Graham, Edward M. and J. David Richardson. 1997a. Global Competition Policies: An Agenda, Washington: Institute for International Economics, Policy Analyses in International Economics No. 51. _ _ _, eds. 1997b. Global Competition Policies, Washington: Institute for International Economics. _ _ _. 1999. “A U.S. - E.U. Road Toward Multilateralism in International Competition Policy,” Economic Perspectives (An Electronic Journal of the U.S. Information Agency), 4 (February 1999), pp. 27-29. 19 Hausman, Jerry and J. Gregory Sidak. 2000. “A Consumer-Welfare Approach to the Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks,” Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute. Hoekman, Bernard and Peter Holmes. 1999. “Competition Policy, Developing Countries, and the World Trade Organization,” Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, Development Research Group Policy Research Working Paper No. 2211, October. Hoekman, Bernard and Will Martin, eds. 2001. Developing Countries and the WTO: A ProActive Agenda, Oxford: Blackwell. Holmes, Stephen and Cass R. Sunstein. 1999. The Cost of Rights: Why Liberty Depends on Taxes. New York: W.W. Norton. Howse, Robert and Kalypso Nicolaidis. 2001. “Legitimacy and Global Governance: Why Constitutionalizing the WTO is a Step Too Far,” in Porter et al. (2001). Hufbauer, Gary C. and Rita M. Rodriguez, eds. 2000. Ex-Im Bank in the 21st Century: A New Approach?, Washington: Institute for International Economics. ICPAC (International Competition Policy Advisory Committee). 2000. Final Report. Washington: U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division. Jackson, John H. 2000. The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations, second edition. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Jaffe, Adam B.; Josh Lerner; and Scott Stern, eds. Innovation Policy and the Economy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press and National Bureau of Economic Research. Janow, Merit E. 2000. “The Global Competition Initiative (GCI): Possible Next Steps,” manuscript. Janow, Merit E. and Andrew J. Shapiro. 2001. “A Trusting Approach to Antitrust,” The International Economy, September/October, pp. 42-43, 53. Jensen, Richard and Marie Thursby. 1996. “Patent Races, Product Standards, and International Competition,” International Economic Review, 37 (February), pp. 21Kochan, Thomas A. 2000. “Building a New Social Contract at Work: A Call to Action,” Presidential Address to the Industrial Relations Research Association, January, manuscript. Lewis, Howard and J. David Richardson. 2001. Why Global Commitment Really Matters! Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics: Globalization Balance Sheet Series. 20 Lindblom, Charles E. 2001. The Market System: What It Is, How It Works, and What to Make of It. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press. Lloyd, Peter J. 1998. “Multilateral Rules for International Competition Law?,” The World Economy, 21 (November), pp. 1129-1149. _ _ _ and Kerrin Vautier. 1999. Promoting Competition in Global Markets. Elgar. Malueg, David A. and Marius Schwartz. 1994. “Parallel Imports, Demand dispersion, and International Price Discrimination,” Journal of International Economics, 37 (), pp. 167-195. Maskus, Keith E. 200a. “Intellectual Property Issues for the New Round,” manuscript, October, in Schott (2000). _ _ _. 2000b. Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics _ _ _ and Mohamed Lahouel. 2001. “Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights in Developing Countries,” in Hoekman and Martin (2001). Mattoo, Aaditya. 2000. “”Shaping Future Rules for Trade in Services,” manuscript, August 8. Mayda, Anna and Dani Rodrik. 2001. “What Determines Individual Preferences Over Trade?,” manuscript, July. McCalman, Phillip. 1998. “Reaping What You Sow: An Empirical Analysis of International Patent Harmonization,” Canberra: Australian National University Working Paper in Economics and Econometrics 374. Meiklejohn, Roderick. 1999. “An International Competition Policy: Do We Need It? Is It Feasible?,” The World Economy, 22 (December), pp. 1233-1249. Moran, Theodore H. 1998. Foreign Direct Investment and Development: The New Policy Agenda for Developing Countries and Economies in Transition. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, December. _ _ _. 2001. Parental Supervision: The New Paradigm for Foreign Direct Investment and Development, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics Policy Analyses in International Economics No. 64, August. Nivola, Pietro S., ed. 1997. Comparative Disadvantages? Social Regulations and the Global Economy, Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Noll, Roger G. 1997. “Internationalizing Regulatory Reform,” in Nivola (1997). 21 Odell, John S. 2000. Negotiating The World Economy. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press. OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). 1998. The Benefits of Trade and Investment Liberalization. Paris. Olson, Mancur and Satu Kahkonen, eds. 2000. A Not-So-Dismal Science: A Broader View of Economies and Societies, Oxford: Oxford University Press. O’Rourke, Kevin and Richard Sinott. 2001. “The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence,” manuscript, July, forthcoming 2002 in Brookings Trade Forum, 3 (), pp. Ostry, Sylvia. 2001. “World Trade Organization: Institutional Design for Better Governance?”, in Porter et al. (2001). Pencavel, John. 1991. Labor Markets Under Trade Unionism: Employment, Wages, and Hours. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Basil Blackwell. _ _ _. 1998. “The Appropriate Design of Collective Bargaining Systems: Learning From the Experience of Britain, Australia, and New Zealand,” Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, November. Porter, Roger B.; Pieree Sauve; Arvind Subramanian; and Americo Beveglia Zampetti, eds. Efficiency, Equity, and Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading System at the Millennium, Washington: Harvard University and Brookings Institution Press. Reich, Robert B. 1991. The Work of Nations: Preparing Ourselves for 21st-Century Capitalism, New York: Alfred A. Knopf. Richardson, J. David. 1998a. “The Coming Competition Policy Agenda in the WTO,” in Schott (1998). _ _ _. 1998b. “Multilateralizing [Competition Policy] Conventions,” Brookings Institution Trade Policy Forum on Private Practices and Trade Policy, Washington, DC.. _ _ _. 1999. “A Cooperative Unilateral Road Toward Multilateralism in International Competition Policy,” in USDOJ (1999). _ _ _. 2000a. “Exports Matter ... And So Does Trade Finance,” in Hufbauer and Rodriguez (2000). _ _ _. 2000b. “The WTO and Market-Supportive Regulation: A Way Forward on New Competition, Technological, and Labor Issues,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 82 22 (4), July/August, Proceedings of the Twenty-Fourth Annual Economic Policy Conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, pp. 115-129. _ _ _. 2001. “Designing a Market-Enhancing WTO,” forthcoming in Rugman and Boyd (2001). _ _ _; Armando E. Rodriguez; Chi Zhang; and Geza Feketekuty. 1998. “U.S. Performance and Trade Strategy in a Shifting Global Economy,” with, in Geza Feketekuty and Bruce Stokes, eds., Trade Strategies for a New Era, New York: Council on Foreign Relations. Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, March. Roessler, Friedler. 2001. “Are the Judicial Organs of the World Trade Organization Overburdened?,” in Porter et al. (2001). Rollo, Jim and L. Alan Winters. 2001. “Subsidiarity and Governance Challenges for the WTO: Environmental and Labor Standards,” in Hoekman and Martin (2001). Rugman, Alan M. and Gavin Boyd, eds., 2001. The World Trade Organization in the New Global Economy: Trade and Investment Issues in the Millennium Round. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar: New Horizons in International Business Series. Scheve, Kenneth F. and Matthew J. Slaughter. 2001. Worker Perceptions and Pressures in the Global Economy. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, Globalization Balance Sheet Series. Schott, Jeffrey J. 2000. The WTO After Seattle. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics. Schott, Jeffrey J. and Jayashree Watal. 2001. ??? Shapiro, Carl. 2001. “Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting,” in Jaffe, Lerner, and Stern (2001). Stiglitz, Joseph. 2000. “Development Strategies and the Labor Market,” Keynote Address to the Industrial Relations Research association, Boston, Massachusetts, January, manuscript. Stokes, Bruce. 1999. “Feeding the Trade Sharks,” National Journal, July 24, p. 2180. Stoneman, Paul. 1992. “Technological Change and Market Structure: The Diffusion Dimension,” in Del Monte (1992). Tarullo, Daniel K. 2000. “Norms and Institutions in Global Competition Policy,” American Journal of International Law, 94 (July), pp. 478-505. 23 Ulman, Llyod. 1966. The Rise of the National Trade Union. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. United States. 1999. Economic Report of the President. Washington, February Van Miert, Karel. 1998. “The WTO and Competition Policy: the Need to Consider Negotiations,” manuscript, Speech/98/78, Geneva, April 21. Walton, Richard E. and Robert B. McKersie. 1965. A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations: An Analysis of a Social Interaction System. New York: McGraw-Hill. Winham, Gilbert R. and Anna Lanoszka. 2000. “Institutional Development of the WTO,” in Rugman and Boyd (2001). World Bank. 1997. The State in a Changing World. Washington, DC: World Development Report. _ _ _. 2001. Global Economic Prospects for Developing Countries. Washington, D.C. Wright, Robert. 2000. “Continental Drift,” The New Republic, January 17, pp. 18-23.