EXIT OR LOYALTY: THE EFFECTS OF COMPENSATION ON CEO TURNOVER * Maria Hasenhuttl The University of Texas at Dallas School of Management P.O. Box 830688, Richardson TX 75083 Tel: (972) 883-6359 Fax: (972) 883-6521 e-mail: h1562@utdallas.edu J. Richard Harrison The University of Texas at Dallas School of Management P.O. Box 830688, Richardson TX 75083 Tel: (972) 883-2569 Fax: (972) 883-6521 e-mail: harrison@utdallas.edu September 2002 * We appreciate the comments of Jim Walsh on an earlier version of this paper. EXIT OR LOYALTY: THE EFFECTS OF COMPENSATION ON CEO TURNOVER Abstract This study explores the relationship between chief executive officer (CEO) compensation and CEO turnover using a sample of 1233 companies included in Standard & Poor’s ExecuComp database in 1995. The results show that total CEO compensation has limited effects on CEO turnover. For manufacturing firms, no compensation components are positively associated with CEO retention, and restricted stock grants actually increase the likelihood of CEO turnover. For non-manufacturing firms, only stock option grants promote CEO retention. The implications of the findings for CEO compensation policy are discussed. 1 Exit or Loyalty: The Effects of Compensation on CEO Turnover The corporate board of directors is responsible for overseeing management and safeguarding shareholder interests. Two of the board’s most important strategic roles are providing compensation – including incentive compensation – for the chief executive officer (CEO) and assuring the financial viability of the firm. The strategic performance of the board has frequently been questioned on the issue of CEO compensation. On April 12, 1997, the cover of Business Week declared, “Executive Compensation: It’s Out of Control.” And the cover of the April 3, 2000, issue of Forbes featured “The $100 Million CEO.” In the wake of recent corporate debacles, broader concerns are now being raised about the board’s role in executive compensation and fiscal oversight, with substantial emphasis on stock options and grants. According to Morgenson (2002: C11), “...the scandals at Enron and other corporations have alerted investors...to how severely stock option plans can dilute both their stakes and their companies’ earnings.” A major concern – now being addressed by many firms – is that options haven’t appeared as expenses on corporate financial statements but may have substantial impact on the future financial health of the firm. This debate has significant implications for corporate governance and strategy, and involves a wide range of issues. In this paper, we address one of these issues: corporate justifications for the huge compensation packages of CEOs, including stock options, based on the rationale that generous compensation is necessary for their retention. (Another common rationale is that stock options, a major component of CEO compensation, help to align CEO interests with those of shareholders.) We break no new ground theoretically, merely restating the theoretical arguments for the retention effects of compensation and its components. Instead, we focus on examining the empirical evidence for this rationale. 2 If high levels of compensation are necessary for – or even influence – CEO retention, then higher-compensated CEOs should be less likely to leave their firms. We test this idea with a sample of 1233 American corporations during the mid-1990s. Our findings show that the retention justification for high CEO compensation has limited merit, supported only by the effect of stock options in non-manufacturing industries. The retention justification is supported by no other compensation component, and restricted stock grants actually promote CEO turnover rather than retention in manufacturing industries. BACKGROUND Recent academic studies of corporate justifications for high CEO compensation have focused on the explanations provided by companies in their proxy statements. Partly in response to criticisms of excessive compensation, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) adopted significantly modified proxy disclosure requirements for executive compensation in October 1992 (see SEC Release No. 33-6940, 57 Federal Register 48126). The revised rules require companies to disclose in their proxy statements all elements of top management’s compensation in a standardized format. In addition, the compensation committee – the committee of the board of directors composed primarily of independent outside directors and responsible for setting executive compensation, sometimes subject to approval by the full board (Elhagrasey et al., 1999) – is required to provide in the proxy a description of the rationale for the reported compensation and its relationship to performance. Zajac and Westphal (1995) studied the proxy justifications of Fortune 500 firms when they adopted an executive long-term incentive plan (LTIP). They identified two rationales for incentive compensation: an agency theory explanation (the alignment of managerial and 3 shareholder interests) and a human resources (HR) explanation. The HR explanation focuses on the ability to attract and retain scarce managerial talent as the main rationale for the particular compensation given to the CEO (Gomez-Mejia and Welbourne, 1988). Zajac and Westphal (1995) found that 51 percent of the 352 firms in their study used an HR explanation. An example of an HR explanation is Lattice Semiconductor’s 2001 proxy assertion that “…total compensation packages must be competitive with other companies in the industry to ensure that Lattice can continue to attract, retain and motivate key employees … “(p. 5). Wade et al. (1997) studied the justifications reported by the compensation committees of 266 Standard & Poor’s 500 firms. They identified three types of compensation justification: external validation justifications (the use of compensation consultants and external surveys); shareholder alignment justifications (equivalent to the agency theory explanation of Zajac and Westphal, 1995); and performance justifications (pay for performance). But their classification system did not explicitly identify retention justifications, which could fall into the external justification or performance categories. Stock options have been viewed as a particularly potent retention mechanism, since they usually don’t vest for three or four years after they are granted, and CEOs lose their unvested options when they leave the company. Stock options have represented an increasing proportion of total compensation in the 1990s (Anderson et al., 2000). The effectiveness of compensation as a retention mechanism for talented CEOs is questionable. High compensation can serve as a signal that the CEO is outstanding, and other firms attempting to lure the CEO away can match or exceed the CEO’s current compensation. In addition, they can offer equivalent value for the restricted stock and stock options that the CEO would forfeit when changing firms. When the CEO is compensated for such forfeitures, it is said 4 that the CEO is “made whole,” a frequently reported phenomenon (Lublin, 1998). This is illustrated in National Semiconductor’s 1999 proxy statement: “The compensation package made available to Mr. Halla was heavily weighted in stock and stock options…to compensate him for the significant value in unvested stock options granted by his prior employer forfeited by him in order to join the company.” Does high compensation really enhance CEO loyalty? Only one study, Coughlan and Schmidt (1985), included compensation in an investigation of executive turnover. However, Coughlan and Schmidt (1985) did not directly measure compensation, and their model is underspecified (it includes only age and performance in addition to compensation). There is a vast amount of literature on executive turnover (for reviews, see Furtado and Karan, 1990; Kesner and Sebora, 1994; Finkelstein and Hambrick, 1996; Pitcher et al., 2000). However, according to Finkelstein and Hambrick (1996), the relationship between executive compensation and turnover has not been subjected to rigorous empirical examination. Given the emphasis on retention as a justification for high CEO compensation, we find this quite surprising. Redressing this gap in the literature is the purpose of this paper. THEORY AND HYPOTHESES Social comparison theory posits that individuals evaluate their situations through comparison with similar others (Festinger, 1954; Kulik & Ambrose, 1992). O’Reilly et al. (1988), applying this theory to the CEO compensation-setting process, focus on other CEOs as the relevant comparison group. Social comparison is the foundation of equity theory (Adams, 1963, 1965), which argues that low relative compensation decreases perceived equity, causes dissatisfaction and 5 subsequently leads to efforts to restore equity. Pay inequity has been shown to increase the likelihood of turnover (Levine, 1993; Telly et al., 1971). Research on lower level employees has found a modestly significant relationship between the perceived fairness of compensation (equity of rewards) and turnover (Hom & Griffeth, 1995). Cotton and Tuttle (1986), in a meta-analysis of turnover research, found strong support for a negative relationship between pay, pay satisfaction and turnover, indicating that dissatisfaction with pay leads to turnover. Finkelstein and Hambrick (1996) applied equity theory to executive compensation. They argued that for CEOs, pay has a strong symbolic value and is “a primary scorecard for managerial success” (1996:286). This argument is supported by March (1984), who suggests that job performance of CEOs is quite ambiguous and difficult to determine; as a consequence, high compensation might be associated with a perception of high performance and high ability. Based on equity theory, Finkelstein and Hambrick (1996:287) then hypothesized that “The greater the compensation of executives relative to peer groups, the lower their turnover.” Of course, March’s (1984) signaling argument can also lead to the opposite prediction: If compensation is an indicator of performance, then highly compensated CEOs may be sought by other firms, resulting in a positive relationship between compensation and turnover. Nevertheless, we follow the retention rationale used by firms to justify high CEO compensation, supported by equity theory. In our view, the relevant comparison group is other CEOs in the same industry, since this is the primary labor market in which CEOs operate. Thus we hypothesize: H1: There is a negative relationship between total CEO compensation relative to the industry and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. 6 Compensation Components Total CEO compensation is made up of various components: salary, annual bonus, stock option grants, restricted stock, stock appreciation rights, and other forms of long-term compensation based on company performance, such as performance shares. Proxy statements filed with the SEC also report additional compensation components (perquisites, contributions to retirement plans, etc.) which generally account for only a small percentage of the total compensation received by top executives. The social comparison and equity arguments can also be applied to the components of CEO compensation. In particular: H2: There is a negative relationship between CEO salary relative to the industry and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. H3: There is a negative relationship between CEO bonus relative to the industry and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. We also consider two other compensation components, stock option grants and restricted stock grants. In these cases, the social comparison and equity predictions are reinforced by the predictions of agency theory (Fama and Jensen, 1983). Options and restricted stock link CEO compensation to the future performance of the firm and defer CEO income from these sources. So not only do they align CEO and shareholder interests, but they also provide an incentive for the CEO to remain with the firm. 7 H4: There is a negative relationship between the value of stock option grants relative to the industry and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. Restricted stock grants are grants of shares that are earned if the CEO remains with the company over some specified period of time (usually 3 to 5 years). CEOs only receive these shares if they are still employed by the firm when the shares vest. Restricted shares may be a more powerful incentive to stay, compared to stock options, for two reasons. First, the value of restricted shares does not depend on performance (except perhaps a minimum constraint), so unlike options, a future payoff is more “guaranteed.” Second, the payoff is the full share value, not the price differential inherent in options. So potentially, restricted stock grants provide a more certain and larger payoff. In rational economic decision theory, a larger certain payoff is always preferred to a smaller, more uncertain one. This parallels the longstanding argument by Mobley et al. (1979) that employees’ expectations about future desirable outcomes can promote loyalty. Many reports on executive compensation in corporate proxy statements present restricted shares as the tool of choice to retain qualified executives. H5: There is a negative relationship between the grant of restricted shares relative to the industry and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. Stock options have an additional dimension. The CEO is not only tied to the company through the current grant of stock options but also through the total stock options accumulated over his/her tenure. CEOs can accumulate substantial numbers of options since options are frequently granted once or more per year. 8 H6: There is a negative relationship between the aggregate value of stock options and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. Of course, stock options and restricted share grants will only promote retention if CEOs are not “made whole” if they change employment. But not all CEOs are in high demand by other firms, and these incentives to remain with the firm may reduce the likelihood of looking elsewhere. Other Factors A CEO may be less motivated to seek employment elsewhere if the potential for financial improvement is limited. A change of employer is associated with significant risks for the CEO, and the CEO has to prove his/her ability in the new position. Therefore, we expect that CEOs will be more motivated to seek employment elsewhere and be more willing to accept increased risk if the potential financial gains are higher. H7: There is a positive relationship between the difference in the compensation of the highest paid CEO in the industry and the compensation of the focal CEO, and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. CEOs who have previously received substantial pay raises are expected to be less likely to seek employment elsewhere. Pay raises provide financial incentives for the CEO to stay and 9 signal a stamp of approval from the board. They also make salient the potential for additional increases in the future. H8: There is a negative relationship between the raise received by the CEO and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. CEO ownership is generally considered to be a source of power (Finkelstein, 1992). A CEO who has a substantial amount of his/her wealth in stockholdings of the company enjoys a position of high power and has motivation to stay with the company. Ownership also reduces the likelihood of CEO dismissal by the board (Boeker, 1992). We expect that CEOs who own a large amount of stock in the company are less likely to seek employment elsewhere. H9: There is a negative relationship between the value of the shares owned by the CEO and the probability that the CEO will leave the company. METHODS Sample and Data Sources The ExecuComp data set, developed by Standard & Poor’s, was the main data source for all data on CEO and company financial information. This data set includes detailed information on compensation components of the top five executives for all firms included in the S&P 500, mid-cap, and small-cap indices. Most previous studies of executive compensation used reviews of compensation by Fortune and Business Week, which cover only larger companies and have less detailed breakdowns of compensation components. Researchers engaging in the laborintensive task of extracting data from corporate proxy statements generally worked with smaller 10 samples. The ExecuComp data set allows the opportunity to include in the analysis detailed compensation information for a large number of companies with a broad size range. (A word of caution is in order for ExecuComp users, however; this data requires substantial cleaning – for example, the value of severance packages is included in total compensation – necessitating careful reading of the footnotes.) The original population for this study consisted of all 1392 firms included in the ExecuComp data set that were in existence from 1995 through 1997. Firms were then excluded if the CEO died, if fiscal year changes made the compensation data not comparable, if the CEO was not in office during the whole year in 1995, or if the company had more than one person identified as the CEO in 1995. The final sample used in the analysis included 1233 firms, including firms from a broad range of economic sectors encompassing 61 2-digit SIC categories. Missing data for some variables further reduced the firms included in the various models estimated. Table 1 provides a description of the final sample, including a description of the 2-digit SIC categories and the number of firms in each. In some cases, there were too few firms in a 2digit category to obtain estimates, or estimation was not possible due to a lack of variation in outcomes. In these cases, the categories were combined with others to avoid further reduction in sample size. These combinations are also shown in Table 1. Further analyses, not presented here, were conducted with these cases omitted rather than combined; in no instance was the pattern of significance in the estimates changed. ----------------------Table 1 about here ----------------------- 11 Variables Dependent variable. The measure of CEO turnover is based on a comparison of the individuals identified as the CEO in 1995 and in 1997. Turnover was observed whenever the CEO listed in the ExecuComp database for 1997 differed from the CEO listed in 1995. For the 1233 firms included in the final sample, 214 changed the CEO, a two-year turnover rate of 17.4 percent. Although it would have been preferable to distinguish between voluntary turnover and dismissal, we did not attempt to make this distinction. As other researchers have found, there is no reliable way to classify the motives for CEO turnover (Ocasio, 1999), and researchers have generally been forced to combine these types of turnover due to data limitations (Denis et al., 1997; Ocasio, 1994; Puffer & Weintrop, 1991). Prior studies have found that most turnover is voluntary. James and Soref (1981) were only able to identify 16 turnover events out of 110 as probable firings. Friedman and Singh (1989) reported that only 14 of 130 succession events were “board initiated”. Cannella and Lubatkin (1993) identified 95 of 472 succession events as dismissals, using a measure – severance of all ties with the firm – that they admit may overstate the number of dismissals. Parrino (1997) classified 87 percent of 977 turnover events in large public firms between 1969 and 1989 as voluntary turnover. Overall, it appears that dismissals constitute ten to 15 percent of CEO turnover events. As Vancil (1987:29) observed, “It is rare for a board to lose confidence in its CEO to such an extent that it dismisses him and seeks a replacement.” Still, the inability to identify involuntary turnover is a limitation of this study. Independent variables. All independent variables are measured for 1995. Total compensation is measured as salary, bonus, value of restricted share grants, value of stock option grants and “other annual” and “all other” compensation. These are the main categories reported 12 in the proxy statements. “Other annual” compensation includes compensation not categorized as salary or bonus (e.g. perquisites, payments to cover an executive’s taxes). The “all other” category includes compensation that is not reported under any other column of the Summary Compensation Table, including contributions to defined contribution plans and insurance payments. Total compensation is transformed into relative compensation by dividing the log of total CEO compensation by the log of the average total compensation, excluding the focal firm, for the industry identified at the 2-digit SIC level (the industry level used for all comparative measures). The log is used to capture the utility of the CEO’s compensation and to improve the statistical properties of the compensation distribution. Relative salary, relative bonus, and relative stock option grants are calculated by dividing the logs of salary, bonus and the Black-Scholes value of stock option grants in 1995 by the logs of the industry averages, calculated excluding the focal firm. We set bonus and value of stock option grants to $1 if CEOs did not receive these compensation components, so as not to loose too many observations in the log transformation (dropping these cases reduces sample size without substantially affecting the findings). Aggregate option grants is measured as the log of the value of all unexercised options that are not exercisable (option grants that had not yet vested). This value is reported in proxy statements as the difference between the exercise price and the market price for all unexercised and not yet exercisable stock options granted to the CEO since he/she joined the company. We excluded unexercised options that are exercisable because they do not provide an incentive for the CEO to stay with the company; they can be exercised by the CEO at any time without forfeiting any part of them. Again, we set this value to $1 if a CEO did not have any unexercised but not yet exercisable options, so as not to loose too many observations in the log transformation. The granting of restricted stock is measured as a dummy 13 variable that takes the value of 1 if the CEO received restricted stock in 1995 and 0 otherwise, since few CEOs receive this form of compensation (only 236 out of 1233); it was then transformed to relative restricted stock grants by subtracting from it the industry average (calculated by excluding the focal firm) for this dummy. Distance to the highest compensation in the industry is measured as the percentage difference between the total compensation of the CEO and the highest total CEO compensation in the industry. Pay raise is a percentage calculated as the change in CEO salary between 1994 and 1995 divided by the salary in 1994. CEO ownership is calculated by multiplying the number of shares held by the CEO by the share price at the end of fiscal year 1995, and taking the log. Control Variables. We included control variables for firm size and performance, for the CEO characteristics of tenure, retirement age, and serving as chairman of the board, and for industry. Firm size was measured as the natural log of the firm’s assets in 1995. Firm performance was measured in two ways. Stock market performance was measured as the average total return to shareholders (TRS) for the three-year period ending in 1995. Operating performance was calculated as the return on assets (ROA) in 1995. Industry adjusted measures are used for both performance measures. CEO tenure was measured by the number of years the CEO had held the position in 1995. Retirement is controlled for by a dummy variable (Retirement) with a value of 1 if the CEO is 63 years of age or older in 1995. Missing age data in the ExecuComp database was filled in by using proxy statements and Standard & Poor’s Directory of Corporations, Executives and Directors. Chairman was measured as a dummy variable with the value of 1 if the CEO was also Chairman of the Board in 1995. We controlled for industry using dummy variables for each 2-digit industry. Interactions. Additionally, we examined a number of interactions. The objective of the 14 interaction tests was to identify other potential effects on turnover. First, we explored the possibility that compensation relative to the industry only has an impact on turnover if CEO ownership is low; if CEOs have a high stake in the company, they may not be motivated to leave simply for more compensation. Next, we examined the possibility that compensation and performance interact to influence turnover; an interaction may be expected if high CEO compensation is not justified by firm performance, and could indicate involuntary turnover. Finally, we considered interactions between performance and ownership. Two opposing arguments can be made about such interactions: from a rational perspective, a CEO with a strong ownership position may step aside if performance suffers, in the hope that a successor will be able to improve performance and enhance the stock value; from a political perspective, however, poor performance may lead a CEO with power through ownership to react defensively and become more entrenched in his/her position (see Pfeffer, 1981). FINDINGS Table 2 reports descriptive statistics for all variables used in the analysis. Table 3 gives the correlation matrix for the variables. ------------------------------Tables 2 and 3 about here ------------------------------- We tested our hypotheses using logistic regression models to estimate the likelihood of CEO turnover, since the dependent variable is dichotomous. In testing performance interactions, we tried both performance measures. Of the interactions tested, we found only a significant interaction between CEO ownership and total return to shareholders, and report this in the tables; 15 the other interactions, all insignificant, are not included. We present the findings in two sets of tables to avoid the problems of estimating effects of total compensation in the same models with its components and estimating effects of aggregate option grants in the same models with current option grants. The first set of findings is shown in Table 4. All models in this and the other tables include CEO ownership, all control variables, and dummy controls for all 2-digit industries; to conserve space, the estimates for the dummy industry controls are not shown in the tables. To this base, Model 1 adds relative compensation, and Models 2, 3, and 4 substitute distance, pay raise, and aggregate option grants, respectively. Model 5 includes all variables. (In this and subsequent tables, we report the hit rate for the models and, for comparison, note the expected hit rate for a random model; see Bayus and Gupta, 1992, and Gulati, 1995.) Model 6 includes a significant interaction between CEO ownership and shareholder return, along with the significant effect of aggregate stock options. Model 7 shows all variables in Model 5 with the interaction term added. ---------------------Table 4 about here ---------------------- Collectively, these models test all hypotheses not focused on individual annual compensation components (Hypotheses 1, 6, 7, 8, and 9). We find no support for effects of relative total compensation, the CEO’s distance from highest compensation in the industry, or pay raises on the likelihood of the CEO leaving the firm. In analyses not reported here, we also tested total compensation in a variety of alternate functional forms, including unlogged versions, quadratic forms, and the non-relative measure. No significant effects were observed in any form. 16 The best model in Table 4, based on Chi-square tests, is Model 6. We found significant effects regarding CEO ownership and the aggregate value of stock option grants. CEO ownership (Hypothesis 9) enhanced retention; this effect was very robust. The aggregate value of stock option grants (Hypothesis 6) also enhanced CEO retention. The interaction of ownership and shareholder return was also significant. This effect is interpreted in Figure 1, which shows the interaction surface along with the sample points plotted in the x-y plane. The vertical line in the figure shows the location of the saddle point on the interaction surface, and the two heavy lines in the x-y plane show the x and y values of the saddle point. Most of the data points lie below the saddle point value for performance. The figure indicates that CEO turnover is lower for poorly performing firms with high CEO ownership, and turnover is higher for poorly performing firms with low CEO ownership. ----------------------Figure 1 about here ----------------------We extended this analysis by separating manufacturing and non-manufacturing firms in the sample. The results are shown in Tables 5 and 6 (again not showing the industry control estimates). In Table 5, Model 6 is again the best model; the interaction interpretation is the same as for Table 4 and the plot is nearly identical, so it is not shown. In Table 6, Model 4 is the best model; the interaction effect is not significant for non-manufacturing firms. These two tables show that CEO ownership reduces turnover only for manufacturing firms, while aggregate stock options promote CEO retention only for non-manufacturing firms. ------------------------------Tables 5 and 6 about here ------------------------------- 17 Retaining the significant CEO ownership effect and the control variables, we then tested for effects of individual components of CEO compensation. These tests are shown in Tables 7, 8, and 9. Following a strategy analogous to Table 4, we examined the individual effects of relative salary, bonus, stock option grants, and restricted stock grants (Models 1-4). Model 5 includes all these variables in the same model, Model 6 includes the significant compensation terms and the interaction of ownership and shareholder return, and Model 7 re-estimates Model 5 with the interaction term included. Again the industry controls are not shown in the tables; in Tables 7 and 9, one industry was dropped by the statistical package for lack of variance, affecting the degrees of freedom reported. As with total compensation, various operationalizations of the compensation components were tested, with no change in the patterns of significance from that reported here (except that stock options lose significance for non-manufacturing firms in Table 9 when their value is not logged). ---------------------------------Tables 7, 8, and 9 about here ---------------------------------- As Table 7 shows, both relative stock options and relative restricted stock grants have significant effects, as do CEO ownership and the interaction of ownership and shareholder returns (based on Chi-square tests, Model 6 is the best model). The stock option finding supports Hypothesis 4. However, the restricted stock grant effect is the opposite of what we predicted in Hypothesis 5. We expected that relative restricted stock grants would decrease the likelihood of CEO turnover; however, as Model 6 shows, they increase the likelihood of CEO turnover. A possible explanation for this result is provided in the discussion section. Hypothesis 9 (CEO ownership) is again supported, but Hypotheses 2 and 3 (salary and bonus) are not. The interaction effect is nearly identical to the earlier ones and is not plotted. 18 As before, we then separated manufacturing and non-manufacturing firms and reran the analyses to produce Tables 8 and 9. Model 6 is the best model in Table 8, and Model 3 is the best model in Table 9. These two tables show that restricted stock grants actually promote turnover for manufacturing firms and that, consistent with the earlier findings, stock options only promote CEO retention for non-manufacturing firms. The interaction effect persists only for manufacturing firms. Of the control variables, we observed a weak quadratic effect of tenure, with CEO exit being most likely for CEO tenure of about 12 or 13 years. There is also a strong retirement effect. We observed a positive effect of firm size on CEO turnover for manufacturing firms. Holding the board chair position had a positive effect on turnover only in Table 5. The only performance effect is that associated with the ownership interaction for manufacturing firms. DISCUSSION The lack of significant effects for most of the compensation-related variables casts doubt on the argument that higher compensation is effective in retaining CEOs. One exception is stock options, but given this variable’s lack of significance in the manufacturing sub-samples, it appears that options are at best only effective for CEO retention for non-manufacturing firms. The limited support for the effect of stock options lends some credence to the agency theory perspective that options link the CEO more tightly to the firm’s future. Although CEOs may be “made whole” when other firms try to hire them, it is not known how prevalent this practice is; perhaps most CEOs are not in enough demand to command the extra expenses required for this practice. 19 We found a surprising result regarding the effect of restricted stock grants for manufacturing firms. CEOs who receive restricted stock grants in manufacturing industries where they are less prevalent are more likely to leave the company. CEOs who do not receive restricted stock grants in industries where other CEOs receive them are less likely to leave. This finding conflicts with the commonly held assumption that restricted stock grants will increase CEO loyalty by motivating them to stay at least for the duration of the vesting period (usually 3 to 5 years), and contradicts the social comparison and equity perspectives. One possible explanation for this effect may be the signaling content of restricted stock grants. It could be that grants of restricted stock are perceived as signs of managerial competence. A grant of restricted stock is a good signal in Spence’s (1974) terms, since it is costly for the firm (they are essentially giving away shares) and it is relatively rare compared to stock options (only 236 out of 1233 CEOs received restricted grants). So CEOs who receive these grants really stand out, and other firms may be much more likely to make the CEO “whole.” Overall, there is strong evidence that the retention justification for grants of restricted shares is not valid. CEO ownership showed effects on turnover only for manufacturing firms, mediated by total return to shareholders. The interaction analysis reinforced the view that ownership fosters power. CEOs with ownership power apparently use their power to entrench themselves, enabling them to survive periods of poor performance. Ownership, then, provides CEOs with a buffer against poor performance, consistent with Boeker’s (1992) finding. The power perspective also offers a possible interpretation of the failure to find a strong relationship between compensation and turnover. CEOs have a great deal of power over the compensation-setting process, and can use this power to obtain compensation packages as large as can be reasonably justified; social comparison and equity arguments are a part of the 20 justification process (Elhagrasey et al., 1999). If CEOs have strong influence on their compensation and are earning as much as they can reasonably expect, they should be less likely to leave their firms because of dissatisfaction with compensation. The effects of the control variables vary across model specifications. Size is only significant for the manufacturing sub-sample. Previous research did not find a consistently significant effect of size on turnover (Ocasio, 1999). James and Soref (1981) found that larger firms were more likely to dismiss their CEOs than were smaller firms, but Boeker (1992) did not. Harrison et al. (1988) found that larger firms experience higher rates of CEO turnover, but Puffer and Weintrop (1991) and Ocasio (1994) did not. So our findings do nothing to resolve this inconsistency. Our sample is larger and includes more small firms than most previous work, however, so it is possible that the effect is confined to very large companies, which are more likely to have older CEOs (Vancil, 1987), mandatory retirement requirements, and succession plans. Having a separate chairman had inconsistent effects. There was no significant effect in the full sample but a positive effect in the manufacturing subsample for one model (i.e., the combined position increased the chances of turnover). Previous work has found a significant relationship in the other direction. Harrison et al. (1988) and Ocasio (1994) found that the combined position decreased CEO turnover. So this issue remains unresolved. As with the size finding, the number of small firms in the sample could be a factor. Perhaps CEOs holding the combined position in small firms may be more in demand in the CEO labor market and interested in positions with larger firms (carrying higher compensation), while CEOs of larger firms may be more content when they have combined positions. 21 We found in our sample that operating performance was never significantly related to CEO turnover in the best models, and stock market performance was only significant in the interaction with performance for manufacturing firms. These findings are surprising, considering that previous researchers generally found a significant effect of performance on turnover. Again, one explanation for our non-finding might lay in the broader sample used in this study, as compared to most previous turnover studies. The dummy variable for retirement age is consistently significant across the models, indicating that the probability of turnover is significantly higher if the CEO is 63 years old or older. There is also a weak quadratic relationship between CEO tenure and turnover for manufacturing firms. We find an increasing effect of tenure on turnover for lower tenure, followed by a decreasing effect as tenure increases further. These findings support those of Ocasio (1994). A major issue raised by our findings is the difference in retention/turnover patterns between manufacturing and non-manufacturing firms. Using t-tests, we found that the nonmanufacturing firms in our sample were significantly larger, but there were no significant differences between manufacturing and non-manufacturing firms in terms of turnover, performance, CEO ownership, tenure, chairman, stock options, or restricted stock grants. Finally, we call attention again to the study’s limitation of not identifying involuntary turnover (other than through the retirement control). Pitcher et al. (2000) discuss the importance of distinguishing between voluntary and involuntary turnover and recommend field studies for this purpose, but note the high level of difficulty in making this distinction in large-sample research. Although we expect from previous work that involuntary events constitute a relatively small proportion of our sample, and although we found no compensation-performance 22 interaction, which could indicate involuntary departures, future studies of the effects of compensation on CEO turnover that can reliably identify involuntary turnover would be desirable. CONCLUSION Corporate proxy statements contain various justifications used to explain the compensation scheme of a particular company. One justification frequently used is that higher CEO compensation reduces exit and increases loyalty. The goal of this paper was to examine the empirical validity of this justification and the social comparison and equity perspectives associated with it. The findings, based on a large sample of companies in a wide range of industries, indicate that the relative level of total CEO compensation has little effect on the loyalty of CEOs, refuting frequent justifications made in corporate proxy statements that high CEO compensation is a tool to retain managerial talent. This result also holds across different operationalizations of compensation and most components of CEO compensation. The grant of restricted stock relative to the industry, in fact, showed the opposite effect. Restricted stock grants seem to facilitate CEO departures. It could be that grants of restricted stock act as a strong signal of managerial competence. As a consequence, CEOs who receive them will be in higher demand in the managerial labor market and will have a better chance of being “made whole” by a new employer. Our results therefore strongly imply that the retention justification for restricted stock grants is not valid. The value of stock options in non-manufacturing firms was another exception to the general pattern of findings. Stock options can be an effective retention mechanism for non- 23 manufacturing industries. Our findings also show convincingly that substantial share ownership by the CEO provides a strong incentive to stay loyal to the company; to the extent that stock options eventually increase share ownership by CEOs, they can serve to promote CEO retention – but not if they are simply “cashed in” when they are exercised. From a shareholder perspective, however, the question remains of whether the excessive use of stock options is justified by the value of retaining the CEO. The large-scale exercise of stock options has the potential to depress earnings and stock prices. Further, long-term CEO retention may not be in the best interests of the firm: CEO loyalty, including entrenchment through ownership, may be detrimental in an industry that frequently requires new leadership talents to effectively deal with the changing strategic environment. Questions concerning the structure of compensation plans – particularly their executive retention value – are timely in the current debate on the efficacy of corporate governance mechanisms. They offer fruitful grounds for further investigation. In this area, academic research has the potential to provide guidance for board decision making and to inform public policy on corporate governance. 24 REFERENCES Adams, JS. 1963. Toward an Understanding of Inequity. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 67, 422-436. Adams, JS. 1965. Inequity in Social Exchange. In Berkowitz, L (ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 2: 267-299. Academic Press: NY. Anderson, MC, Banker, RD, Ravindran, S. 2000. Executive Compensation in the Information Technology Industry. Management Science 46: 530-547. Bayus, BL, Gupta, S. 1992. An Empirical Analysis of Consumer Durable Replacement Intentions. International Journal of Research in Marketing 9: 257-267. Boeker, W. 1992. Power and Managerial Dismissal: Scapegoating at the Top. Administrative Science Quarterly 37: 400-421. Cannella, AA Jr., Lubatkin, M. 1993. Succession as a Sociopolitical Process: Internal Impediments to Outsider Selection. Academy of Management Journal 36: 763-793. Cotton, JL, Tuttle, JM. 1986. Employee Turnover: A Meta-analysis and Review with Implications for Research. Academy of Management Review 11: 55-70. Coughlan, AT, Schmidt, RM. 1985. Executive Compensation, Management Turnover, and Firm Performance. Journal of Accounting Research 27: 21-39. Denis, DJ, Denis, KD, Sarin, A. 1997. Ownership Structure and Top Executive Turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 45: 193-221. Elhagrasey, GM, Harrison, JR, Buchholz, RA. 1999. Power and Pay: The Politics of CEO Compensation. Journal of Management and Governance 2: 311-334. Fama, EF, Jensen, MC. 1983. Separation of Ownership and Control. Journal of Law and Economics 26: 301-325. Festinger, L. 1954. A Theory of Social Comparison Processes. Human Relations 7: 117-140. Finkelstein, S. 1992. Power in Top Management Teams: Dimensions, Measurement, and Validation. Academy of Management Journal 35: 505-538. Finkelstein, S, Hambrick, DC. 1996. Strategic Leadership. Top Executives and Their Effects on Organizations. West Publishing: St. Paul, MN. Friedman, SD, Singh, H. 1989. CEO Succession Events and Stockholder Reaction: The Influence of Context and Event Context. Academy of Management Journal 32: 718-744. 25 Furtado, EPH, Karan, V. 1990. Causes, Consequences, and Shareholder Wealth Effects of Management Turnover: A Review of the Empirical Evidence. Financial Management 19: 6-75. Gomez-Mejia, LR, Welbourne, TM. 1988. Compensation Strategy: An Overview and Future Steps. Human Resource Planning 11: 173-189. Gulati, R. 1995. Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances. Academy of Management Journal 38: 85-112. Harrison, JR, Torres, DL, Kukalis, S. 1988. The Changing of the Guard: Turnover and Structural Change in Top-management Positions. Administrative Science Quarterly 33: 211-232. Hom, PW, Griffeth, RW. 1995. Employee Turnover. South-Western: Cincinnati, OH. James, DR, Soref, M. 1981. Profit Constraints on Managerial Autonomy: Managerial Theory and the Unmaking of the Corporation President. American Sociological Review 46: 1-18. Kesner, IF, Sebora, TC. 1994. Executive Succession: Past, Present and Future. Journal of Management 20: 327-372. Kulik, CT, Ambrose. ML. 1992. Personal and Situational Determinants of Referent Choice. Academy of Management Review 17: 212-237. Levine, DI. 1993. What Do Wages Buy? Administrative Science Quarterly 38: 462-483. Lublin, JS. 1998. CEOs Who Get “Made Whole” Get Rich. Wall Street Journal. April 22: B1. March, JG. 1984. ‘Notes on Ambiguity and Executive Compensation. Scandinavian Journal of Management Studies August: 53-64. Mobley, WH, Griffeth, RW, Had, HH, Meglino, BM. 1979. Review and Conceptual Analysis of the Employee Turnover Process. Psychological Bulletin 86: 493-522. Morgenson, G. 2002. Business Lobby Seeks to Limit Investor Votes on Options. New York Times. June 6: C1, C11. Ocasio, W. 1994. Political Dynamics and the Circulation of Power: CEO Succession in U.S. Industrial Corporations, 1960-1990. Administrative Science Quarterly 39: 285-312. Ocasio, W. 1999. Institutionalized Action and Corporate Governance: The Reliance on Rules of CEO Succession. Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 384-416. O’Reilly, CA III, Main, BG, Crystal, GS. 1988. CEO Compensation as Tournament and Social Comparison: A Tale of Two Theories. Administrative Science Quarterly 33: 257-274. Parrino, R. 1997. CEO Turnover and Outside Succession. A Cross-sectional Analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 46: 165-197. 26 Pitcher, P, Chreim, S, Kisfalvi, V. 2000. ‘CEO Succession Research: Methodological Bridges over Troubled Waters. Strategic Management Journal 21: 625-648. Pfeffer, J. 1981. Power in Organizations. Ballinger: Cambridge, MA. Puffer, SM, Weintrop, JP. 1991. Corporate Performance and CEO Turnover: The Role of Performance Expectations. Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 1-19. Spence, AM. 1974. Market Signaling: Informational Transfer in Hiring and Related Processes. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA. Telly, CS, French, WL, Scott, WG. 1971. The Relationship of Inequity to Turnover among Hourly Workers. Administrative Science Quarterly 16: 164-171. Vancil, RF. 1987. Passing the Baton: Managing the Process of CEO Succession. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. Wade, JB, Porac, JF, Pollock, TG. 1997. Worth, Words, and the Justification of Executive Pay. Journal of Organizational Behavior 18: 641-664. Zajac, EJ, Westphal, JD. 1995. Accounting for the Explanations of CEO Compensation: Substance and Symbolism. Administrative Science Quarterly 40: 283-308. 27 Table 1. Sample description (N = 1233) SIC Description of SIC 01 02 10 13 14 Agricultural production - crops Agricultural production - livestock Metal mining Oil & gas extraction Mining & quarrying - nonmetallic minerals Building construction - gen contractors Heavy construction except building Construction-spcl trade contractors Food & kindred products-mfrs Tobacco products-mfrs Textile mill products-mfrs Apparel & otr finished products-mfrs Lumber & wood prods except furntr-mfrs Furniture & fixtures-mfrs Paper & allied products-mfrs Printing publishing & allied industries Chemicals & allied products-mfrs Petroleum refining & related inds-mrfs Rubber & miscellaneous plastics-mfrs Leather & leather products-mfrs Stone clay glass & cncrete prods-mfrs Primary metal industries-mfrs Fabricated metal products-mfrs Industrial & comm. machinery-mfrs Electronic & otr electrical equip mfr Transportation equipment-mfrs Measuring & analyzing instrmnts-mfrs Misc-manufacturig inds-mfrs Railroad transportation Local/suburban transit & hwy pssngr Motor freight trans/warehouse 15 16 17 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Nr of firms 4 1 13 37 3 Combined with 7 5 2 34 2 16 13 11 8 22 31 102 14 12 5 8 34 21 72 71 41 54 12 6 1 11 16 01 16 39 39 25 30 30 45 SIC Description of SIC 44 45 47 48 49 Water transportation Transportation by air Transportation services Communications Electric gas & sanitary services Nr of firms 4 14 4 26 104 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 67 70 72 73 75 78 79 80 82 87 Wholesale trade - durable goods Wholesale trade - nondurable goods Building materials & hardware General merchandise stores Food stores Auto dealers & service stations Apparel & accessory stores Home furniture & furnishings stores Eating & drinking places Miscellaneous retail Depository institutions Nondepository credit institutions Security & commodity brokers Insurance carriers Insurance agents-brokers & service Holding & other investment offices Hotels rooming houses & camps Personal services Business services Auto repair services & parking Motion pictures Amusement & recreation services Health services Educational services Engineering & accounting & mgmt svcs. 28 16 7 18 11 4 15 10 23 24 60 9 15 44 7 2 3 6 63 2 6 6 15 1 13 28 Combined with 45 53 59 60 64 78 73 73 78 73 Table 2. Descriptive statistics (N = 1233) Variable All Firms Mean Manufacturing Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum Mean NonManufacturing Mean 1. CEO turnover .17 .38 0 1 .17 .17 2. Relative compnsation .95 .11 .51 1.47 .95 .96 3. Distance 10.65 19.71 0 274.24 13.61 7.97 4. Pay raise .06 .17 -1 3.57 .08 .05 4.37 3.40 0 11.41 4.55 4.22 6. Relative salary .98 .11 -1.05 1.30 .98 .98 7. Relative bonus .79 .40 0 1.73 .81 .78 8. Relative stock options .65 .49 0 2.71 .67 .64 -1.76e-09 .40 -.5 1 -7.92e-10 -2.63e-09 10. CEO ownership (log) 8.34 2.05 .98 15 8.47 8.23 11. Size (log of assets) 7.15 1.73 2.26 12.67 6.80 7.46 12. CEO tenure 8.60 7.40 1 51 8.50 8.68 128.70 248.65 1 2601 127.29 129.96 14. Retirement .17 .37 0 1 .19 .15 15. Chairman .66 .48 0 1 .66 .65 16. Return on assets .77 9.11 -76.75 34.60 .38 1.13 17. Shareholder return (3-yr avg) -.32 20.39 -71.36 110.231 -.64 -.04 18. Ownership * Shareholder return 5.89 181.10 -562.14 1044.08 .38 10.71 5. Aggregate stock options (log) 9. Relative restricted stock grants 13. CEO tenure squared 29 Table 3. Correlation matrix (N = 1233) Variable 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. CEO turnover Relative compensation Distance Pay raise Aggregate stock options Relative salary Relative bonus Relative stock options Relative restricted stock grants CEO ownership Size CEO tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return Ownership*Shareholder return Variable 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. CEO ownership Size CEO tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return Ownership*Shareholder return *p < .05 **p < .01 1 2 1.00 -.02 .02 -.03 -.10 -.004 -.02 -.06 .03 -.06 -.01 .02 -.002 .27 .03 -.07 -.05 -.03 1.0 -.57 -.005 *** .40 .49 .51 * .57 .26 * .12 .55 -.002 -.004 *** -.02 .22 * .12 .20 .18 10 11 1.00 .07 .44 .35 .20 .21 .19 .17 .16 * 1.00 *** -.09 *** -.09 *** .02 *** .20 *** .07 *** .03 *** -.009 3 *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** 1.00 -.003 -.18 -.30 -.29 -.28 -.12 .01 -.34 .03 .04 -.001 -14 -.05 -.08 -.06 4 1.00 *** .0004 *** -.02 *** .008 *** .03 *** .01 -.007 *** -.08 ** .02 -.01 ** -.05 *** .02 -.10 *** ** .04 * .05 12 ** ** *** ** 1.00 .93 .40 .22 .10 .07 .06 13 *** *** *** ** *** p < .001 30 1.00 .41 *** .15 *** .09 ** .04 .04 5 1.00 .15 .33 .45 .05 .05 .26 -.08 -.10 -.10 .06 .10 .32 .31 6 *** *** *** *** * ** ** * ** *** *** 14 1.00 .14 *** .07 * -.02 -.05 1.00 .28 .16 .11 .05 .43 .04 .002 .05 .18 .08 .03 .03 15 1.00 .03 .03 .02 7 *** *** *** *** *** ** 1.00 .21 .12 .05 .34 -.002 -.01 -.01 .14 .24 .24 .21 8 *** *** *** *** *** *** *** 16 1.00 .33 *** .30 *** 1.00 .13 -.05 .24 -.15 -.15 -.13 .07 -.02 .07 .07 9 *** *** *** *** *** * * * 17 1.00 .97 *** 1.00 .01 .13 *** -.06 * -.06 -.02 .11 *** .03 .03 .03 18 1.00 Table 4. Logistic regression estimates of CEO turnover in all firms Variable Relative compensation Model 2 Model 1 Model 3 -.71 (.84) Aggregate stock options CEO tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return (TRS) -.09 (.03) -.17 (.06) .18 (.07) .09 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.14 (.24) .15 (.23) -.02 (.01) .005 (.006) -1.44 (1.6) -.03 (.02 -.98 (.87 -.11 (.04) -.19 (.06) .28 (.10) .13 (.05) -.005 (.002) 2.17 (.26) .12 (.26) -.02 (.01) .008 (.007) -.005 (.008) Pay raise Size Grants Model 5 -1.03 (1.08) Distance CEO ownership Model 4 -.16 (.06) .19 (.09) .10 (.04) -.004 (.001) 2.18 (.24) .10 (.24) -.02 (.01) .0004 (.005) ** * * ** *** * -.16 (.06) .11 (.08) .09 (.04) -.004 (.001) 2.19 (.24) .09 (.24) -.02 (.01) -.0005 (.005) ** * ** *** * -.21 (.06) .24 (.08) .14 (.05) -.005 (.002) 2.14 (.25) .11 (.26) -.02 (.01) -.001 (.006) *** *** ** ** *** ** ** * * ** *** * ** ** ** * ** *** Ownership * TRS Constant N Hit rate a Chi square Df -1.39 (1.63) 989 85.14 152.65 *** 51 -2.03 (1.45) 991 85.07 152.43 *** 51 -2.86 (1.50) 896 85.71 146.85 *** 51 * p .05 ** p .01 *** p .001 Expected hit rates from a random model range from 72.09 to 73.02 . Industry control variables not shown. Standard errors are in parentheses. a 31 -2.13 (1.43) 1001 85.31 157.78 *** 51 -1.47 (2.01) 889 85.83 15844 *** 54 Model 6 Model 7 -.09 (.03) -.15 (.06) .20 (.07) .09 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.24 (.24) .14 (.24) -.02 (.01) -.05 (.02) .006 (.002) -2.54 (1.45) -1.41 (1.63) -.03 (.02) -1.04 (.86) -.11 (.04) -.18 ** (.07) .31 (.10) .13 (.05) -.005 (.002) 2.27 (.26) .12 (.27) -.02 (.01) -.05 (.02) .007 (.003) -1.88 (2.00) ** ** ** * ** *** * ** 1001 86.01 165.70 *** 52 ** ** ** * ** *** * ** 889 86.73 164.94 *** 55 Table 5. Logistic regression estimates of CEO turnover in manufacturing firms Variable Relative compensation Model 2 Model 1 Model 3 Model 5 -.07 (.05) -.23 (.09) .24 (.10) .12 (.06) -.004 (.002) 2.32 (.34) .74 (.39) -.03 (.01) .002 (.008) -.43 (2.58) -.04 (.03) -.72 (1.28) -.10 (.06) -.24 (.10) .20 (.15) .21 (.08) -.008 (.003) 2.37 (.37) .81 (.44) -.02 (.02) .007 (.010) .32 (.1.78) Distance -.003 (.01) Pay raise -.11 (1.07) Aggregate stock options CEO ownership Model 4 -4.42 ** (1.59) -4.11 ** (1.37) -5.02 *** (1.39) -4.13 ** (1.31) -3.37 (2.44) N Hit rate a Chi square Df 466 85.41 88.47 *** 23 466 84.98 88.56 *** 23 426 85.92 80.56 *** 23 468 86.54 87.93 *** 23 426 86.15 86.86 *** 26 468 86.32 93.76 *** 23 CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return (TRS) * * *** -.24 (.09) .19 (.11) .16 (.07) -.006 (.002) 2.36 (.34) .77 (.39) -.03 (.01) -.003 (.008) ** * * *** -.25 (.09) .28 (.10) .21 (.08) -.007 (.003) 2.29 (.35) .77 (.43) -.02 (.02) -.001 (.008) ** ** ** ** *** ** * * *** * -.33 (2.59) -.03 (.03) -.80 (1.26) -.11 (.06) -.21 (.10) .25 (.16) .20 (.08) -.007 (.003) 2.46 (.37) .86 (.45) -.01 (.02) -.08 (.04) .009 (.004) -4.16 (2.45) Constant CEO tenure ** Model 7 -.19 (.09) .21 (.10) .11 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.44 (.34) .87 (.41) -.02 (.01) -.009 (.003) .01 (.003) -4.84 (1.36) Size Grants -.24 (.09) .19 (.14) .16 (.07) -.006 (.002) 2.35 (.34) .76 (.39) -.02 (.01) -.003 (.008) Model 6 ** ** *** * Ownership * TRS * p .05 ** p .01 *** p .001 Expected hit rates from a random model range from 72.51 to 73.19. Industry control variables not shown. Standard errors are in parentheses. a 32 * * *** * ** ** *** * ** ** *** * * 426 86.15 92.59 *** 27 Table 6. Logistic regression estimates of CEO turnover in non-manufacturing firms Variable Relative compensation Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 -1.98 (1.42) Distance -.005 (.02) Pay raise -2.16 (1.42) Aggregate stock options Model 5 -2.34 (2.25) -.02 (.03) -1.96 (1.45) -.11 * (.05) -.16 (.09) .35 * (.14) .06 (.07) -.003 (.002) 2.02 *** (.38) -.34 (.36) -.01 (.02) .007 (.009) Model 6 -.09 (.08) .16 (.12) .06 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.05 *** (.35) -.32 (.31) -.02 (.02) .002 (.007) -.08 (.08) .05 (.11) .05 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.03 *** (.35) -.35 (.31) -.02 (.02) .0007 (.007) -.18 * (.09) .21 (.11) .08 (.07) -.003 (.002) 1.98 *** (.37) -.32 (.35) -.01 (.02) -.0009 (.009) -.09 * (.05) -.10 (.08) .11 (.10) .06 (.06) -.003 (.002) 1.97 *** (.35) -.23 (.31) -.01 (.02) .006 (.008) Constant -.35 (1.89) -1.62 (1.60) -2.48 (1.74) -1.74 (1.56) -.75 (2.60) -.09 * (.05) -.10 (.08) .13 (.11) .06 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.06 *** (.36) -.26 (.31) -.01 (.02) -.03 (.03) .004 (.003) -2.02 (1.58) N Hit rate a Chi square Df 523 84.7 76.76 *** 36 525 85.33 75.08 *** 36 470 86.81 76.73 *** 36 533 84.99 79.01 *** 36 463 87.26 83.70 *** 39 533 85.55 80.95 *** 37 Grants CEO ownership Size CEO Grants tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return (TRS) Ownership * TRS * p .05 ** p .01 *** p .001 Expected hit rates from a random model range from 67.84 to 72.89. Industry control variables not shown. Standard errors are in parentheses. a 33 Model 7 -2.35 (2.26) -.02 (.03) -1.91 (1.43) -.10 * (.05) -.16 (.09) .36 * (.15) .06 (.08) -.003 (.002) 2.12 *** (.39) -.36 (.36) -.02 (.02) -.03 (.03) .004 (.004) -.91 (2.60) 463 86.83 84.96 *** 40 Table 7. Logistic regression estimates of CEO turnover in all firms Variable Relative salary Model 2 Model 1 Model 3 -.50 * (.21) Relative restricted stock grants CEO tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return (TRS) .48 (.23) -.17 (.06) .10 (.07) .09 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.18 (.24) .10 (.24) -.02 (.01) -.001 (.005) -1.30 (.94) .06 (.28) -.52 (.21) .55 (.24) -.16 (.06) .20 (.09) .09 (.04) -.004 (.001) 2.21 (.25) .11 (.24) -.02 (.01) .0003 (.005) -.007 (.27) Relative stock options Size Grants Model 5 -1.37 (.85) Relative bonus CEO ownership Model 4 -.17 (.06) .18 (.08) .09 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.19 (.24) .14 (.23) -.02 (.01) -.001 (.005) ** * * ** *** * -.16 (.06) .12 (.07) .09 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.17 (.24) .15 (.25) -.02 (.01) -.0008 (.005) ** * ** *** -.16 (.06) .16 (.07) .08 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.13 (.24) .14 (.24) -.02 (.01) .0003 (.005) ** * * *** * * ** * * *** * * * ** * * ** *** * Ownership * TRS Constant N Hit rate a Chi square Df .90 (1.63) 999 85.39 152.59 *** 51 -1.94 (1.52) 995 85.43 150.68 *** 51 -1.64 (1.53) 978 85.07 153.72 *** 50 * p .05 ** p .01 *** p .001 a Expected hit rates from a random model range from 72.09 to 72.29. Industry control variables not shown. Standard errors are in parentheses. 34 -1.61 (1.48) 999 84.98 154.59 *** 51 -.72 (1.65) 975 84.92 160.21 *** 53 Model 6 Model 7 -.55 (.21) .53 (.24) -.15 (.06) .18 (.08) .08 (.04) -.003 (.001) 2.26 (.25) .09 (.24) -.02 (.01) -.06 (.02) .007 (.002) -1.93 (1.50) -1.45 (.96) .08 (.28) -.53 (.21) .54 (.24) -.15 (.06) .22 (.09) .09 (.04) -.004 (.001) 2.31 (.25) .10 (.24) -.02 (.01) -.06 (.02) .006 (.002) -.95 (1.65) ** * * * * *** ** ** 978 85.69 167.38 *** 52 * * * * * ** *** * ** 975 85.85 167.44 *** 54 Table 8. Logistic regression estimates of CEO turnover in manufacturing firms Variable Relative salary Model 2 Model 1 Model 3 Model 4 -1.88 (.99) Relative bonus -.38 (.46) Relative stock options -.41 (.35) Relative restricted stock grants CEO ownership Size Grants CEO tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return (TRS) -.24 (.09) .28 (.11) .13 (.06) -.004 (.002) 2.38 (.34) .78 (.39) -.02 (.01) -.002 (.008) ** * * * *** * -.23 (.07) .23 (.11) .11 (.06) -.004 (.002) 2.34 (.34) .78 (.39) -.02 (.01) -.001 (.008) ** * *** * -.23 (.09) .25 (.11) .11 (.06) -.004 (.002) 2.32 (.34) .77 (.39) -.02 (.01) -.002 (.008) ** * *** * * .94 *** (.33) -.25 ** (.09) .14 (.10) .12 (.06) -.004 (.002) 2.43 *** (.35) .68 (.39) -.02 (.01) -.003 (.008) Model 5 -2.09 (1.04) -.34 (.48) -.45 (.36) 1.05 (.34) -.28 (.09) .33 (.13) .15 (.06) -.005 (.002) 2.48 (.35) .67 (.39) -.03 (.01) -.0005 (.008) Model 6 * -2.53 * (1.02) ** 1.02 (.34) -.23 (.09) .28 (.12) .15 (.06) -.004 (.002) 2.60 (.36) .78 (.41) -.02 (.01) -.10 (.03) .01 (.004) -3.20 (1.45) *** * * * *** Ownership * TRS Constant -3.21 * (1.35) -4.18 *** (1.30) -4.25 *** (1.30) -3.79 ** (1.33) -2.73 * (1.40) N Hit rate a Chi square Df 468 85.47 88.62 *** 23 467 85.65 86.37 *** 23 467 86.3 87.33 *** 23 468 86.32 93.72 *** 23 466 86.27 98.92 *** 26 * p .05 ** p .01 *** p .001 a Expected hit rates from a random model range from 72.41 to 72.51. Industry control variables not shown. Standard errors are in parentheses. 35 Model 7 ** * * * * *** ** ** * 468 86.54 105.65 ** 25 -2.48 (1.05) -.17 (.50) -.51 (.37) 1.07 (.35) -.24 (.09) .36 (.13) .15 (.06) -.005 (.002) 2.60 (.36) .77 (.41) -.02 (.01) -.09 (.03) .01 (.004) -3.27 (1.46) * ** ** ** * * *** ** ** * 466 87.12 107.35 *** 27 Table 9. Logistic regression estimates of CEO turnover in non-manufacturing firms Variable Relative salary Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 -.77 (1.49) Relative bonus -.07 (.09) .07 (.10) .04 (.06) -.003 (.002) 1.96 *** (.35) -.26 (.31) -.02 (.02) .003 (.007) -.005 (.34) -.10 (.08) .05 (.10) .06 (.06) -.003 (.002) 1.98 *** (.35) -.29 (.31) -.02 (.02) .0002 (.007) -.59 * (.26) Relative restricted stock grants -.60 * (.26) Constant -.79 (1.97) -1.52 (1.71) -1.04 (1.72) -1.32 (1.68) -1.25 (2.12) N Hit rate a Chi square Df 531 85.31 74.69 *** 36 528 84.85 74.88 *** 36 511 83.95 78.38 *** 35 531 85.31 74.44 *** 36 509 84.09 78.78 *** 38 511 85.32 80.99 *** 36 CEO tenure CEO tenure squared Retirement Chairman Return on assets Shareholder return (TRS) -.10 (.08) .04 (.11) .07 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.04 *** (.35) -.29 (.31) -.01 (.02) .00009 (.007) Model 6 -.06 (.08) .10 (.11) .05 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.08 *** (.36) -.31 (.32) -.02 (.02) -.04 (.03) .005 (.003) -1.42 (1.73) Size Grants -.10 (.08) .08 (.11) .07 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.01 *** (.35) -.29 (.31) -.02 (.02) .00007 (.007) Model 5 -.04 (1.84) .24 (.35) -.60 * (.27) .06 (.35) -.06 (.09) .06 (.13) .05 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.02 *** (.36) -.28 (.32) -.02 (.02) .003 (.008) .18 (.34) Relative stock options CEO ownership Model 4 Ownership * TRS * p .05 ** p .01 *** p .001 a Expected hit rates from a random model range from 71.75 to 72.22. Industry control variables not shown. Standard errors are in parentheses. 36 Model 7 -.07 (1.84) .23 (.35) -.60 * (.27) .05 (.35) -.06 (.09) .07 (.13) .05 (.06) -.003 (.002) 2.11 *** (.37) -.30 (.32) -.02 (.02) -.03 (.03) .004 (.003) -1.38 (2.12) 509 85.07 80.10 *** 39 CEO turnover probability 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 -50 -25 sh 0 ar eh 25 ol de rr 50 et ur 75 n 100 4 2 8 6 CEO 10 r sh owne 12 ip ( lo 14 g) Figure 1. Interaction effect of shareholder return and ownership on CEO turnover 37