R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Economics of Forests So far, we have studied economics related to exhaustible resources. We shall study economics of renewable resources – forests and fishery in the next few lectures. We shall take up the case of a renewable energy resource, namely fuel wood. Unlike exhaustible resources, renewable resources can get replenished over time. However, if our rate of consumption is faster than the rate at which these resources are replenished, then the stock of these resources will reduce over time, and may lead to their eventual exhaustion. The economic concepts that we shall be studying in this lecture are applicable to such renewable resources as fuel wood and biomass. Other renewable resources such as solar or wind are generally not studied by supply and demand branch of economics as their supply is virtually unlimited and not scarce in that sense. As indicated in the introduction, economics is a study of scarce resources. Forests are the source for fuel wood. However, forests have multiple uses and fuel wood is only one of them. We shall study the general aspects of forestry, which are equally applicable when forests are narrowly viewed as sources for fuel wood. 1 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Additional benefits from forests include the timber for houses, pulp for paper making, preservation of bio-diversity (housing a variety of plants and animals), purifying the air especially by consuming CO2 and releasing oxygen during photosynthesis. Deforestation is a serious problem because it intensifies global warming, decreases bio-diversity, reduces agricultural productivity, increases soil erosion and desertification, and has precipitated the decline of traditional cultures of people indigenous to forests. Instead of forests being used on a sustainable basis to provide the needs of the current as well as subsequent generations, forests are being "cashed-in." Unlike stocks of depletable resources, stock of renewable resources such as trees can be increased over time. However, there will be some finite level beyond with any given stocks of renewable resources cannot increase. The amount of biomass in an acre of land depends on two factors: on the input side, the amount of light and nutrients in the soil will determine the growth of biomass; on the external side, influence of disease, decaying agents and accidents will limit the growth of biomass. 2 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Some biological basics of trees and forests As a tree grows, the amount of wood usable for commercial harvests changes over time. The typical schedule of the tree's growth over time is sketched in the following figure. v(te) Wood v(t*) Volume v(t) t* te Age of tree t The figure plots the volume available from the tree v(t) as a function of the tree's age. The volume grows over the age of tree, until a maximum is attained at age te. Beyond this age, the 3 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 tree begins to decay from disease, insect predation, wind etc/ and collapses eventually. Wood volume develops slowly in the early stages, as the tree takes root. The rate of growth of wood volume (dv/dt) increases in the early stages, reaches a maximum at the age t* and then begins to decrease. The growth rate is zero at te, and then there is negative growth. Thus, the variation of wood volume with respect to its age follows a logistic pattern. A logistic pattern can be mathematically represented as follows. dv v r 1 dt k where represents the instantaneous growth rate of biomass and k is the carrying capacity of the forest (i.e., maximum biomass the forest can support). The volume-age schedule can be altered by arranging for the optimal density of the tress on a plot, by fertilizing the land, and by other activities such as thinning of trees and pest repression. The schedule can shift in a variety of ways in response to human intervention. This is part of forestry cultivation and management, generally known as silviculture. A forest stand with trees of identical age can also have a similar shape to this schedule. On a plot of land of a given size, many 4 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 trees can be grown so that there will be an aggregate v(t) schedule representing the sum of many separate v(t) schedules. If there are N trees, V(t) = Nv(t) only when we assume no interaction effects. This is a unrealistic assumption since the density of trees and other factors affect each one's growth. However, for simplicity, let V(t) = Nv(t). We are assuming here that all trees on the plot of land are identical in type and age at any point in time. this is certainly a common feature of cultivated forests, (e.g.), a forest of trees yielding large amounts of firewood. Forests grown artificially solely for the sake of getting firewood from it are called Energy Plantations. The volume-age schedule shown earlier can also be represented in terms of the rate of wood growth, dv/dt. As seen earlier, dv/dt increases at early years in the life of a tree, reaches peak at the age t*, and then reduces to zero at te. 5 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 dv/dt t* v(t*) V(t*) Age of tree t or Tree volume v(t) or Forest volume V(t) 6 te v(te) V(te) R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Note that the same relationship holds when the wood volume v(t) is used in the X-axis. For a forest with identical trees, it is also possible to get similar relationship when the total volume of the forest V(t) is used in the X-axis. Before proceeding further, let us briefly discuss certain concepts related to the economics of renewable resources, not necessarily the renewable energy resources. I am interested in highlighting the important concepts related to sustainability when we use renewable sources. Typically, the economic theory of renewable sources is built using the model of fisheries. We shall see later that basic concepts of forests are applied approximately well for the case of fisheries also. For example, the relationship between the growth rate of fishes in a fishery (dX/dt) and stock of fish X can be given by the relationship shown below. 7 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 F(X) = dX / dt F(X*) X' X* = XMSY Stock of fish, X 8 X'' k R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 When the stock of fish is small but positive, the biomass will grow rapidly because there will be surplus nutrients (food). New births will outnumber deaths. Growth will eventually reach a maximum at X = X*. By then, food becomes scarce as the limited food will be shared by a large stock now. We also account for natural predation of fish by their natural predators – other than human – in the deaths here. Beyond X*, growth rate declines as deaths outnumber births beyond this point. Equilibrium is reached at the point X = k, when the births and deaths are in equilibrium. The value k is called the carrying capacity of the fishery, which can be thought of as the maximum population or biomass the habitat can support. Note that the word habitat is used in a general sense. It represents the place where the resource is grown; it is a forest for trees or it is a fishery for fishes. The resource, tree or fish, is generally referred to as biomass. The same model can characterize a natural forest. In the absence of human intervention, forests have grown following approximately this pattern. However, the rate of growth of forests will be very slow compared to fishes. The point k is not the carrying capacity of the forests, the maximum number of trees that the forest can support. 9 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 dV/dt or dX/dt X* V* Volume of forests V or Stock of fish, X 10 k for forest k for fishery R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Let us now see what will happen when we introduce human intervention to the biological equilibrium. Let us study the binomic equilibrium, the concepts of renewable source literature connecting biological and economic factors – an equilibrium that combines the biological mechanics with economic activity followed by human beings. Specifically, we now assume that humans have begun to harvest the stock. Let us now consider three harvest rates and their effects on the biomass population in the habitat. 11 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 dX/dt H1 dX2/dt dX1/dt H2 H3 X' X1 X2 XMSY Biomass, X 12 X'' k R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Assume that the tock is in biological equilibrium at k. Let the harvest from the habitat be H1 in the above figure. This represents a harvest level that lies everywhere above the biological growth function. This means that the stock is removed from the habitat at each point in time than being renewed. Obviously, no population can survive for long if more are harvested than are renewed. Obviously, the stock will be depleted to zero levels if this level of harvest is repeated continuously. This is the extreme case of mining the habitat, and the stock will be eventually depleted. Actually, this is what has been happening to the stock of so called non-renewable resources. The rate at which they are extracted (harvested) is much higher than their rate of renewal. The principles can be applied to renewable energy sources – forests. If the rate of consumption of wood resources is much higher than the rate at which they are renewed, we will witness deforestation (what we see in many parts of the world now). Of course, unlike coal or oil, it is possible to affect the rate of renewability of forests by artificial means such as forestations programmes, plantation programmes, or through the use of fertilizers. Study of the best way by which the plantations can be carried out to maintain continuous renewable supply over time is an important area of the subject of forestry. We shall study these details later. 13 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Suppose now that the instantaneous rate of harvest is given by H2. H2 touches the growth function dX/dt at its maximum point. The point X* at which growth rate is maximum is called the point of Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY) from the population. Suppose that the population is at equilibrium k (where dX/dt is zero). In the next instant, if H2 quantity of stock is harvested from the habitat and H2 is maintained continuously, the stock will gradually decline from k to XMSY. The remaining stock of biomass will now grow at the maximum rate, because food and space are more ample now than at k. Note that the rate of growth at XMSY is equal to the harvest (i.e. the rate at which the stock is removed) H2. This means, if H2 amount of stock is removed at any instant, the growth rate, which is equal to H2, will make the stock to be replenished instantly. Thus, at the MSY stock, the largest sustainable harvest can occur. That the process of catching H2 amount of stock per unit of time can continue indefinitely (so long as no exogenous changes occur). In a very simple economic model, i.e., the model in which no harvesting costs or discounting of future revenue from the harvest are considered, the MSY is the most desirable equilibrium for the fishery (or forestry). Note that if the initial population were to the left of XMSY (say X1) to begin with, a harvest of H2 per unit of time will deplete the stock, because the population X1 cannot be sustained at a 14 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 harvest rate of H2. The maximum growth possible is dX1/dt, which is less than H2. Thus, in every unit of time, H2 – dX1/dt amount of stock will get reduced from the total stock. Eventually, the stock will be depleted. A harvest H3 is an interesting one. At this harvest, there are two possible equilibria, X' and X''. Which will occur? Suppose that harvesting has just began when the habitat is at equilibrium at the point k. Obviously, when H3 is captured where the growth rate is zero (at point k), total population declines. Equilibrium occurs at point X'' where the rate of growth is exactly equal to the harvest H3. Once this point is reached, the harvest H3 can be sustained forever. Note that this is not the maximum sustainable yield (XMSY). Suppose now that the original population was not at k but between X' and X'' when the harvest H3 has begun. The rate of harvest H3 will be lower than the growth rate, and hence population will begin to increase. Population will ultimately stabilize at X''. Thus, for harvest H3, X'' is called the stable equilibrium. This means that if there is a slight movement in the stock size to the right or to the left of X'', the system will ultimately return to an equilibrium at X''. The arrows in the above figure toward X'' show that it is a stable equilibrium. 15 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Suppose once again that the population lied to the left of X' when harvesting H3 begins. This can happen, for example, due to the destruction of forests due to fire or oil or chemical spills in fisheries. If harvesting H3 is continued, we can see that the growth rate is below H3, and hence H3 cannot be sustained. The population will be extinct. What happens at the point X'? Obviously, there will be equilibrium for a harvest of H3 because the rate of growth just equals the harvest. But, this will be an unstable equilibrium because a slight movement of stock (which can occur in the presence of some external factors – fire, predators, climate change, etc.) can make the population either extinct or be stable at X''. This is indicated in the figure by the outward going arrows at the point X'. Let us now go deeper in defining harvest. Harvest H is a function of stock X and the effort E. Here, effort can be considered as the aggregate of the factors of production – capital, labour, materials, energy, etc. Obviously, harvest will rise for a higher stock, i.e., H is an increasing function of X. What about the relation between H and E? 16 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Suppose we take a given level of effort, E'. The harvest will then be an increasing function of stock X. The function is shown in the figure in the previous page. The steady state equilibrium will now occur at the stock X' and the harvest will be H'. Let us see what happens when effort is increased from E' to E'', say by bringing more labour for cutting trees or more machinery and energy for the purpose. The slope of the harvest function will now be higher because now it is possible to get a greater harvest for a given increase in X. However, the amount of harvest cannot be increased because of the limitation of the biological growth process. Note from the figure that the steady state harvest is the same as the harvest with E'. However, now the equilibrium stock of biomass, X'' is now much lower. This means that if more firms operate on the forests (which increases effort), then the equilibrium level of forest stock for a given harvest will be lower compared to the same harvest when only a few firms operate in the forest. Or, the equilibrium forest stock will reduce as more firms begin operating in the forest. Let c be the constant, unit cost of effort. It may be the wage in a labour dominated forest industry. Then, the cost of effort is cE where E is the quantum of effort. Assuming that no other costs are involved, we have total cost, TC = cE. If p is the price per unit of timber, then pH is the total revenue TR from the harvest. 17 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 If we assume that forest is a common property and that no firm controls the products of forests, then price will be fixed exogeneously depending on demand and supply, and hence p will be constant. Given the total revenue and total cost functions, the optimal harvest will occur when TR = TC. Let us plot the variation of total revenue with respect to E. We first draw the variation of dX/dt with respect to E, which is similar to the figures we have seen earlier. Suppose we start with a biomass X = k, with no timber is harvested. As effort is introduced, the stock of timber falls. Harvests at first rise as the industry moves up the biological production function. They reach a maximum at XMSY and then fall again. The variation of dX/dt with respect to E is shown in the figure in the next page. Note that, as TR = pH, and as H is the same as dX/dt, the same variation captures the behaviour of TR for a constant p = 1. At p = 0.5, TR will be below the dX/dt curve, and at p = 2, TR will be above the dX/dt curve. 18 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 dX/dt TR(p = 2) dX/dt or TR(p = 1) TR(p = 0.5) E 19 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 TR in $ TC = cE H0=TR0 A E0 E 20 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 Let us assume a constant stock X. Then, H = H(E), is a function of effort. Let p = 1 so that TR curve is identical to H(E) curve. For a given c, total cost is cE, and the curve is linear. The equilibrium point is E0 where TC = TR. For any effort less than E0, TC < TR. This will cause profits and hence additional firms will enter the industry. Equilibrium occurs only at E0. The harvest is H0, and total revenue TR0 = pH0 = H0. Now let us see what happens at different prices. When the prices is at $0.50 per unit, equilibrium is at point A corresponding to effort E0 and harvest H0. When p = 1, the equilibrium is at (E1, H1). Note that the harvests are obtained by mapping to the TR curve when p = 1, which is also the curve showing the variations in optimal harvests. Let us now plot the variation of harvest with prices. Note that at higher price of 2, the harvest has reduced resulting in the backward bending supply curve. The supply curve shifts at a point above (p1, H1) because HMSY > H1. Note that the supply curve describes the maximum sustainable harvest of the forest for given prices. It is quite possible to increase the supply curve at higher prices, but will not be sustainable. Deforestation will result. 21 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 TC C TR(p = 2) HMSY TR(p = pMSY) H1 Harvest &$ B TR(p = 1) and harvest TR(p = 0.5) H2 H0 A E0 E2 E1 E p2 = 2 pMSY p1=1 p0=0.5 H2 H0 22 H1 HMSY R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 p2 D2 p1 D1 p0 D0 H2 H0 23 H1 R. Ramanathan/ Energy and Environmental Economics / HUT/ January-April 2001 At the demand function D0, equilibrium wil be (p0, H0). When demand rises from D1 to D2, harvest will reduce to H2 to be sold at the higher price p2. If the supply does not follow this trend, the forest will be over exploited leading to deforestation. The income preference for fuelwood suggests that higher prices, people will switch over to better cleaner fuels, but if the society has large poor people, exploitation will occur. 24