2. Organic agriculture: concepts and policies

advertisement
Ministeriet for Fødevarer, Landbrug og Fiskeri
Statens Jordbrugs- og
Fiskeriøkonomiske Institut
Rapport nr. 99
Organic Agriculture in Denmark
- Economic Impacts of a Widespread Adoption of
Organic Management
Els Wynen
Statens Jordbrugs- og Fiskeriøkonomiske Institut
Rapport nr. 99
Organic Agriculture in Denmark
Economic Impacts of a Widespread Adoption of
Organic Management
Els Wynen
København 1998
-3-
List of Contents
List of content ..................................................................................................................
3
Preface .............................................................................................................................
7
Sammendrag ....................................................................................................................
9
1. The issues in perspective .............................................................................................
11
2. Organic agriculture: concepts and policies .................................................................
2.1. Concepts ...............................................................................................................
2.2. Economic considerations .....................................................................................
15
15
17
3. Modelling the widespread adoption of organic practices ............................................
3.1. Production and consumption relationships ..........................................................
3.2. Model description ................................................................................................
3.3. Some assumptions ................................................................................................
3.4. Aggregation ..........................................................................................................
23
23
24
28
30
4. Data sources and assumption ......................................................................................
4.1. Available statistics ...............................................................................................
4.1.1. Conventional farms ....................................................................................
4.1.2. Organic farms .............................................................................................
4.2. Construction of data on organic farms .................................................................
4.2.1. Variable costs .............................................................................................
4.2.2. Fixed costs ...................................................................................................
4.2.3. Rotation ......................................................................................................
4.2.4. Yield and output .........................................................................................
4.2.5. Output prices ..............................................................................................
4.2.6. Elasticities ..................................................................................................
33
33
33
33
35
35
37
38
40
41
42
5. The current state of agriculture – the baseline ..............................................................
5.1. Land .....................................................................................................................
5.2. Input costs ............................................................................................................
5.3. Rotations and total land use .................................................................................
5.4. Yields ...................................................................................................................
5.5. Output ...................................................................................................................
5.6. Output prices ........................................................................................................
5.7. Returns to farming ...............................................................................................
47
47
48
52
55
58
60
62
-4-
6. Moving towards organic agriculture .............................................................................
6.1. Inputs ....................................................................................................................
6.2. Rotations and total land use .................................................................................
6.3. Yields and output .................................................................................................
6.4. Output prices ........................................................................................................
6.5. Returns to farming .................................................................................................
6.5.1. Returns at 80 per cent rate of adoption ......................................................
6.5.2. Returns to varying rates of adoption ..........................................................
69
69
71
74
76
78
78
79
7. Sensitivity analysis and limitations .............................................................................
7.1. Sensitivity analysis ...............................................................................................
7.2. Limitations ...........................................................................................................
83
83
92
8. Summary and concluding comments ..........................................................................
8.1. Summary ..............................................................................................................
8.2. Policy implications ...............................................................................................
97
97
98
References ....................................................................................................................... 103
Appendix A ..................................................................................................................... 105
Appendix B ...................................................................................................................... 111
Tables
Table 3.1. Number of full-time farms in different regions and sectors (1995-96) .......
31
Table 4.1. Number of organic farms in different categories (1996-97) .......................
Table 4.2. Crop rotations on conventional and organic dairy farms ............................
Table 4.3. Elasticities of supply in dairy sector in Southern and Western Jutland ......
34
39
43
Table 5.1.
Table 5.2.
Table 5.3.
Table 5.4.
47
49
50
Table 5.5.
Table 5.6.
Table 5.7.
Table 5.8.
Table 5.9.
Area per farm and total by region and sector (1995-96) .............................
Average input costs by sector at baseline ....................................................
Average input costs on dairy farms at baseline ...........................................
Crop rotation on full-time conventional farms and total land use by enterprise at the baseline (1995) ..........................................................................
Rotations by sector and farm type in Southern and Western Jutland at
baseline ........................................................................................................
Actual and estimated yields of different enterprises and management
systems in Southern and Western Jutland ...................................................
Productivity and prices on dairy farms ........................................................
Total crop production on full-time conventional farms (1995) ...................
Average national output prices at baseline and as percentage of baseline
(1995 and 1996) ...........................................................................................
54
54
56
58
59
61
-5-
Table 5.10. Financial net returns on full-time farms at the baseline ..............................
Table 5.11. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at
baseline ........................................................................................................
63
Table 6.1. Average input costs at 80 per cent of organic management, by sector .......
Table 6.2. Average input costs on dairy farms at 80 per cent of organic management
Table 6.3. Crop rotations on full-time conventional farms and total land use for
different sectors at 80 per cent of organic management ..............................
Table 6.4. Total crop production on full-time farms at 80 per cent of organic
management .................................................................................................
Table 6.5. Average national output prices at 80 per cent organic management ...........
Table 6.6. Financial net returns per full-time farm and total returns in agriculture at
80 per cent organic management .................................................................
Table 6.7. Gross finansial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at
80 per cent organic management .................................................................
Table 6.8. Net returns per sector at different rates of adoption of organic management
70
72
Table 7.1. Financial net returns per full-time farm at baseline in three sectors under
different scenarios ........................................................................................
Table 7.2. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at
baseline with different scenarios .................................................................
Table 7.3. National net returns at different rates of organic management with different scenarios ...............................................................................................
Table A.1. Average input costs under different management systems at baseline,
by region and sector .....................................................................................
Table A.2. Input costs on dairy farms in different regions at baseline ..........................
Table A.3. Crop rotations and total area per farm at baseline, by region and sector ....
Table A.4. Regional crop prices at baseline (1995) ......................................................
Table A.5. Financial net returns per full-time farm and total returns in agriculture
at the base-line, by region and sector ..........................................................
Table A.6. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at
the baseline, by region and sector .................................................................
Table B.1. Average input costs under different management systems at 80 per cent
of organic management, by region and sector .............................................
Table B.2. Crop rotations and total area per full-time farm at 80 per cent organic
management, by region and sector ..............................................................
Table B.3. Financial net returns per farm and total returns in agriculture at 80 per
cent of organic management, by region and sector .....................................
Table B.4. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at
80 per cent organic management, by region and sector ................................
65
73
75
77
78
80
81
84
85
87
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
-6-
Figures
Figure 3.1. Relationships in agricultural production ......................................................
24
Figure 5.1. Average input costs by sector at baseline ....................................................
Figure 5.2. Yields on organic farms (1996) relative to yields on conventional farms
(1995) ...........................................................................................................
Figure 5.3. National production by crop, 1995 ................................................................
Figure 5.4. Organic price premiums for selected crops .................................................
Figure 5.5. Returns on– conventional and organic full-time farms at baseline .............
49
Figure 6.1. Average input costs by sector at 80 per cent organic management .............
Figure 6.2. National production relative to baseline at 80 per cent of organic
management .................................................................................................
Figure 6.3. National net returns at different rates of adoption of organic management..
71
57
60
61
64
77
81
-7-
Preface
The objective of this report is to make a preliminary assessment of the possible economic
impact of a widespread adoption of organic practices within Danish agriculture. This form
of agriculture minimises or eliminates the use of synthetic fertilisers and pesticides, inputs
that have been associated with the increase in adverse off-farm environmental impacts.
Without an assessment and valuation of the environmental damage avoided, it is not possible to estimate the total costs and benefits of the adoption of organic agriculture. However,
the study indicates the likely financial costs incurred by the primary agricultural sector, and
provides analysis of the varying distribution of these costs across the crop, dairy and pig
sectors in four regions of Denmark. Costs related to agricultural supply and processing industries have not been assessed.
The report is part of the project The Potential of Organic Farming in Sustainable Development, funded by the Programme for Development of Organic Farming under the Danish
Ministry of Food, Agricultural and Fisheries. The Danish Institute of Agricultural and Fisheries Economics is undertaking further work in this area to complement and extend this report both within a macroeconomic and a farm economic framework.
The report was prepared by Els Wynen, a consultant of Eco Landuse Systems, Canberra,
Australia. The author benefited from assistance from David Vanzetti, of the same organisation, who designed and described the modelling framework presented in the report and reviewed the draft. Ole Olsen, Statistics Division, provided the data in an accessible form for
the analysis, and advised on its use. The work also benefited from assistance and advice
from other staff members of the institute, in particular Bjarke Poulsen, Pia Folkmann and
Nicolaj Nørgaard, and Tommy Dalgård, Danish Institute of Agricultural Sciences. The report was edited in cooperation with Aage Walter-Jørgensen.
Danish Institute of Agricultural and Fisheries Economics, August 1998.
Arne Larsen
-8-
-9-
Sammendrag
Med henblik på at vurdere virkningerne af en hypotetisk omfattende udbredelse af
økologisk jordbrug i Danmark er der udviklet en partiel ligevægtsmodel for den danske
landbrugssektor (DOAP). Modellen er specificeret for 4 regioner og 3 landbrugssektorer
(planteproduktion, kvæg og svin), der giver mulighed for at beskrive 16 produkter.
Produktionsomkostningerne er beskrevet i detalje for hver sektor og region. DOAP omfatter
to produktionsstrukturer: Konventionel produktion og økologisk produktion, hvor
sidstnævnte for øjeblikket repræsenterer mindre end 2 pct. af de danske landbrug. Ved at
specificere antallet af bedrifter i de to kategorier er det muligt at få et skøn for
indvirkningen på sektorens produktion og økonomi af skift fra konventionel til økologisk
drift.
Regnskabsdata fra Statens Jordbrugs- og Fiskeriøkonomiske Institut indikerer, at
konventionelle og økologiske mælkeproducenter afviger med hensyn til deres fysiske og
økonomiske struktur. Mest iøjnefaldende er, at brugen af syntetiske gødningsstoffer og
pesticider er minimeret på økologiske bedrifter. Det, der er registreret som anvendt, falder
formentlig inden for de kategorier, som er tilladt ifølge nationale standarder. Anvendelsen
af visse produktionsmidler såsom fodermidler til husdyrholdet og arbejdskraft er ligeledes
lavere på økologiske bedrifter, mens forbruget af andre inklusive husdyrgødning og
afskrivninger på maskiner stort set svarer til konventionelle brug. På udbudssiden er
udbytteniveauet generelt lavere på økologiske end på konventionelle brug, hvilket betyder,
at økologiske landmænd har behov for større areal, hvis de skal opnå samme produktion
som konventionelle. For at opnå en given animalsk produktion kræves derfor et større areal
med foderafgrøder, hvilket landmændene typisk reagerer på ved at reducere produktionen af
salgsafgrøder såsom hvede. Økologiske landmænd dyrker for øjeblikket også færre arealer
med sukkerroer, frøgræs, raps og ærter, hvilket skyldes dyrkningsmæssige begrænsninger
ved fravalg af pesticider, samt at der ikke er et marked for økologiske produkter på disse
områder.
Økonomiske data indikerer, at eksisterende økologiske mælkeproducenter kan opnå fuldt så
højt et økonomiske udbytte som konventionelle producenter. Lavere produktion pr. ha
(gennem ændringer i udbytte og sædskifte) på den ene side, og lavere
produktionsomkostninger og højere produktpriser (hovedsagelig gennem merpriser) på den
anden, resulterer i fordelagtige indkomstforhold for økologiske bedrifter. Opgørelser for
økologiske plante- og svinebedrifter skønnes at give et tilsvarende billede om end
udbytteniveauet er lavere og priserne er relativt højere end for mejeriprodukter.
- 10 -
Prisrelationerne forventes imidlertid at vende i takt med, at udbuddet af økologiske
produkter stiger. Det forudsættes her, at den nuværende markedsstruktur (for produkter og
produktionsmidler) samt den anvendte teknologi er uændret.
Hovedkonklusionen af modelanalyserne er, at indkomsten i den primære landbrugssektor
kan opretholdes eller stige svagt, hvis mindre end 25 pct. af danske landmænd går over til at
være økologiske, men at det vil indebære betydelige tab, hvis en større procentdel af
landmændene følger denne trend. Det understreges, at dette forudsætter, at de nuværende
forhold med hensyn til faktor- og produktpriser, teknologi og skøn for planteproduktionens
og svinenes økonomi kan opretholdes. Den lille stigning i sektorens afkast ved en begrænset
omlægning bygger på, at SJFI’s regnskabsdata for økologiske kvægbedrifter (1995 og
1996) og skøn for plante- og svinebedrifter indikerer, at økologiske producenter - specielt i
mælkesektoren - har større økonomiske afkast end deres konventionelle modpart. Mere end
halvdelen af de økologiske bedrifter er klassificeret som kvægbedrifter i statistikken.
Det højere økonomiske afkast pr. ha holder ikke, når flere landmænd lægger om til
økologisk produktion. Det skyldes at merprisen for økologiske produkter, som for
øjeblikket er gældende, vil blive reduceret eller helt elimineret, når udbuddet af økologiske
varer stiger. Betragtninger omkring bedre viden om økologisk drift over tid, mulighederne
for teknologiske ændringer, ændringer i driftsformen, bedriftsstørrelse og specielt bedre
effektivitet i markedsføringen af økologiske produkter er ikke gjort til genstand for
vurdering her. Sådanne ændringer vil have en tendens til at forbedre den økonomiske
situation for økologiske producenter. På den anden side vil eksisterende forskelle i alder
mellem økologiske og konventionelle producenter formentlig bidrage til at overvurdere de
økologiske producenters økonomiske situation. Det understreges, at på grund af
begrænsninger i det anvendte datamateriale for plante- og svinebedrifter skal resultaterne
for disse sektorer benyttes med forsigtighed.
Ved anvendelse af modellen er det muligt at identificere nøglevariable, der bestemmer
omkostninger, produktion og nettoafkast. Blandt disse er begrænsninger i sædskifte,
udbytteniveau, subsidier og tilstedeværelse af merpriser for økologiske produkter
væsentlige faktorer. Der er ikke modelleret ændringer i priserne på produktionsmidler
bortset fra de tilfælde (fx foderafgrøder), hvor produktionen benyttes i husdyrproduktionen.
Et markedsbestemt fald i produktprisen (som kan forventes i det økologiske marked) vil
have afgørende betydning for resultatet ved en mere omfattende omlægning til økologisk
produktion.
- 11 -
1. The issues in perspective
Readers of Danish newspapers will be aware that the environmental costs associated with
conventional farming are important issues in Denmark. Much discussion, and resources, are
focused on figuring out the most efficient ways in which to deal with this aspect of farming.
One approach is to seek high-tech solutions, such as genetic engineering or computer-aided
fertiliser or pesticide applications; to reduce the negative environmental impact associated
with high input use. An alternative approach is to radically reduce use of certain inputs, and
use different management practices to maintain productivity at a viable level. Organic agriculture follows this approach, and has been widely advocated in the popular press. There
are numerous examples of successful organic farms in Denmark, and these have prompted
suggestions that organic practices should be widely adopted. The large-scale adoption of
organic farming methods is seen as a means of solving several (environmental and health)
problems at a stroke.
To date, there has been little assessment of the potential economic effects of the major proportion of the Danish agricultural sector switching to organic methods. To enable policy
makers to come to informed decisions, greater knowledge of production potential, the scope
for reducing the negative externalities of the agricultural management system, the role of
subsidies and premiums in farm level profitability, and many other factors related to organic
agriculture is necessary. By filling in some of these gaps, this report contributes to more
informed decision-making.
The direct aim of this report is to examine, from an economic perspective, the effects on the
Danish agricultural sector of a change of a sizeable proportion (such as 80 per cent) of
farms in Denmark to organic management. To set the scene, in Section 2 a broad overview
of organic agriculture is presented. The definition and a discussion of the concepts convey
the essential issues. Where off-farm environmental issues are involved, there is clearly a
role for government. Also private interests (consumers of agricultural products and of the
environment) are involved. A summary of Denmark’s current public involvement with organic agriculture concludes Section 2.
A large part of the study is devoted to the private aspects of farming in Denmark. The essence of that part is how farmers, and farm sectors and agricultural regions would fare if
organic agricultural methods were employed. The key elements are simple. Organic producers in general in Denmark experience lower input costs and yields than conventional
producers, but receive a price premium. For many existing organic farmers, survey data
- 12 -
suggest that the mixture of premium price, combined with lower input costs per hectare and
changes in rotation and production, leads to higher net farm income. As more and more
farmers switch into organic production, the premium is likely to be eroded, affecting the
profitability of the industry, at least at present input prices and level of technology. Because
changes in yields, input costs, production and premiums differ across industries, a detailed
model of the agricultural sector is necessary to analyse large-scale changes. Such a model is
developed, described and used in this report. The model covers 16 commodities in three
different farm sectors (crops, dairy and pigs), and is disaggregated into 4 regions in Denmark. It is described in Section 3, in which also some general assumptions are explained.
The level of aggregation of the data and problems that can be encountered with aggregation
are discussed. A detailed description of the data and the assumptions made for this model,
for inputs, rotations, yields, prices and price elasticities are discussed in Section 4.
The fifth section contains a description of the baseline, the current situation. This is used
not only as a basis for comparison following the adoption of organic practices in the following section, but it also shows how conventional and organic farms are performing currently. The economic impacts of a switch to organic practices are presented in Section 6.
With an increasing number of farmers adopting organic practices, land use and product
prices can be expected to change, which will influence enterprise mix and output. Farm financial performance in the different farm sectors, both at the individual and regional level,
is assessed at various levels of adoption of organic management.
The results of such assessments can depend to a considerable extend on the assumptions
made in the study. In Section 7 a range of values for several key variables has been tested to
see which of them are crucial to the results, and what the range is in the results if assumptions were to be changed. One of the aims of this study is to identify those factors in organic
agriculture on which it will be most efficient to concentrate further work. The sensitivity
analysis gives an indication of the importance of the different factors in further work. Furthermore, other main problems to be expected in a study on the effect in the agricultural
sector, or possibly on a macro level, are highlighted so that early attention to those areas
may mean avoiding problems at a later stage.
Policy implications stemming from the farm performance are discussed. A policy change
can be implemented in many ways, and some ways are better than others. A summary of the
study together with different policy options in Section 8 conclude the study.
- 13 -
With the current level of technology, wholesale adoption of organic methods will involve a
financial cost to the agricultural sector. Estimates of these losses indicate the scale of environmental costs we would want to avoid to justify such a change. No effort is made in this
study to estimate or value the potential environmental savings.
- 14 -
- 15 -
2. Organic agriculture: concepts and policies
2.1. Concepts
In the early 1980s, organic organisations in many countries defined organic agriculture and
adopted standards that spelled out what the definition meant in practice. This meant that producers had production rules, and consumers could find out what they were buying. The International Federation for Organic Agricultural Movements (IFOAM) also designed standards
based on experiences in the different countries, which then became the minimum standards for
all organisations who wanted to be evaluated by IFOAM, often to facilitate international trade.
In the early 1990s, the then European Community decided that conformity in the organic industry was needed. It adopted Council Regulation EC No.2092/91 (EC 1991), in which the
word 'organic' was defined and standards for organic production were set. The standards follow to a large extent those of the International Federation for Organic Agricultural Movements
(IFOAM). which with the EU to establish the EU standards. Note that they relate to the
system of production, not to the end product per se. This has implications for the management
of, for example, the marketing of the product, where checking the end-product is not sufficient
to guarantee that a product has been grown under organic management.
The regulation required each member state to specify which word it wanted to use for the form
of agriculture specified. The Danes opted for the word ‘økologisk’; in English the word ‘organic’ was chosen. Hence, although this report is focused on Denmark, the word ‘organic’ is
used in this report.
Organic agriculture is often described as a form of agriculture where no synthetic fertilisers
and pesticides are used. However, this is a rather narrow interpretation, as the essence of organic agriculture is to adjust the management in such a way that soil fertility and pest problems are prevented. In 1980 the US Department of Agriculture (USDA) recognised this point
in its definition of organic agriculture as follows:
'...a production system which avoids or largely excludes the use of synthetically
compounded fertilizers, pesticides, growth regulators, and livestock feed additives.
To the maximum extent feasible, organic farming systems rely upon crop rotations,
crop residues, animal manures, legumes, green manures, off-farm organic wastes,
mechanical cultivation, mineral bearing rocks, and aspects of biological pest control
to maintain soil productivity and tilth, to supply plant nutrients, and to control insects, weeds, and other pests'.
- 16 -
The report also included the following observation:
'The concept of the soil as a living system which must be "fed" in a way that does not
restrict the activities of beneficial organisms necessary for recycling nutrients and
producing humus is central to this definition.'
Thus, the aim of organic farming is to use inputs (including materials and management
practices) in such a way that the biological processes of available nutrients and defences
against pests are encouraged. 'Nature' is seen as a resource which can be manipulated to
activate processes which increase farm productivity. More specifically, preventative actions
to protect farm crops and livestock include crop rotations, strip cropping, manipulation of
seeding rate and planting date, stock culling programs which emphasise genetic resistance
against certain diseases, judicious stock buying programs, and limited field size (see, for
example, Wynen and Fritz 1987, Lampkin 1990). The last author mentions that the organic
approach gives '... an indication of the underlying view of the soil as a living system that the
farmer, in harmony with nature, should seek to develop' (p.5). This view is often referred to
as holistic1. This kind of management system implies other characteristics. For example,
off-farm inputs are used to a lesser degree on organic farms than on conventional farms;
some inputs, such as nutrients, are used in a less treated (processed) form. This makes the
organic farmer less dependent on off-farm inputs, as a change in enterprise-mix can provide
some inputs (such as nitrogen) by other means.
Comparing organic agriculture with practices in conventional agriculture may clarify the
picture. Of particular relevance here is a reliance on synthetic fertilisers for plant nutrition,
and synthetic pesticides for protection against pests and diseases. The availability of these
inputs meant that enterprises on the farm with the highest profits could be included in the
rotation frequently, without running the risk of immediate nutrient and pest problems. It led
to the development towards monocultures and the use of relatively large machinery. This
kind of agriculture is therefore characterised by relatively intensive use of off-farm, manufactured inputs (fertilisers, pesticides, machinery) and is dependent on suppliers of such
inputs. The emphasis of the management system is on the treatment of problems once they
(are expected to) occur.
In summary, although it is too simplistic to say that in conventional farming symptoms of
problems are treated rather than causes, that is closer to being true than it is in the case of
organic farming. Many single techniques used in either farming system are similar. In
1
The point about 'holism' relates to the fact that processes on the farm are seen as interdependent (one
'organism', hence 'organic').
- 17 -
fact, there are few, if any, techniques practised on organic farms that cannot be used on
conventional farms. However, what differentiates the systems is the focus of the approach. Under the organic system, there is a stronger focus on maintaining and improving the overall health of the farm's soil-plant-animal system, the holistic approach. However, it is difficult to measure this state, so that in standards for organic agriculture proxies (synthetic fertilisers and pesticides) are used. It is for this reason that those inputs are
banned totally.
Although these definitions of organic agriculture say nothing of off-farm environmental
effects, the International Federation for Organic Agricultural Movements has as one of
its ‘Principle Aims’ to minimise all forms of pollution that may result from agricultural
practices’ (IFOAM 1996).
2.2. Economic considerations
Private and social costs and benefits
The costs and benefits of farming can be seen at two different levels. The private costs and
benefits, that is, the net private returns to farming, have traditionally been the focus. The
off-farm costs and benefits (negative or positive externalities) have enjoyed less attention.
However, the existence of externalities justifies a role for government, through policy tools
such as regulations and taxes or subsidies to change the behaviour of farmers, and for research and analysis to be carried out by public institutions to aid the search for
cost-effective solutions.
Externalities
As with most forms of production, agriculture generally causes some sort of pollution. Until
recently this was seen more as something like a ‘necessary evil’ than a serious problem requiring government action. This is partly due to the nature of agricultural externalities, in
that the effects of one single agricultural production unit are difficult to establish. As opposed to many industries where pollution occurs at a particular point (such as at the outlet
of a factory), the source of pollution in agriculture is often diffuse, for example over the
whole of the catchment area or region where nutrients or pesticides are applied (non-point
pollution).
It is often difficult to identify and control the source of non-point pollution. Furthermore,
setting absolute levels of input use will be inefficient if there are differences between farms
in absorptive capacity. The timing of input use, soil characteristics and other factors result
- 18 -
in differences in environmental (off-farm) damage done even if the same amount of input is
used. Administration costs of allocating externalities to these sources, so that appropriate
charges can be made to the polluter, are very high, and have no doubt contributed to a lack
of government intervention in this area. However, current policies imply that farmers do not
pay the true cost of their production, and the divergence between private and public costs
seems to be growing. Reasons for this include increased production (and pollution) levels
over time; delayed surfacing of effects; increased awareness of problems due to an increased standard of living; and enhanced possibilities to measure effects.
Unconstrained non-point pollution has lead to the de facto bearing of the external costs by
others, such as other farmers, rural dwellers and by taxpayers in the form of, for example,
additional health care costs and cleaning up of contaminated water and soil. Pimentel et al.
(1993) estimated the total 'indirect' private and external (off-farm) costs (excluding the input price) of the use of synthetic pesticides to amount to US$ 8.1 billion annually in the
USA, US$ 5 billion of which were environmental and public health costs. The total annual
expenditure on pesticide treatments including materials and application was calculated to be
US$ 4 billion, so that the non-material costs of pesticides was estimated to be twice as high
as the costs of the pesticides themselves. The private benefits from pesticide use amounted
to US$ 16 billion in revenues, giving farmers sufficient incentives to continue use. Such
estimates are not available in Denmark, but they do raise an interesting question from the
point of view of the society as a whole. Are there ways of reducing the costs without losing
a greater amount in benefits, for example through a different farm system?
Other work carried out show the costs of agriculture in a different way. For example, FAO
(1996) estimated the change in private costs of a reduction by 55 per cent in pesticide pollution that occurs during the production of different vegetable oils. The estimates ranged from
175 per cent (soybeans) through 120 per cent (sunflower) and 36 per cent (palm oil) to 28
per cent (rapeseed) of total variable costs. In other words, for example for rapeseed, production cost would increase by 28 per cent if measures were to be taken such that pesticide
pollution was reduced to 45 per cent of its present level. These percentages were calculated
over the cost of several variable inputs including, apart from pesticides, also fertilisers and
seeds. This means that the percentage cost would have been considerably higher if calculated as a percentage of pesticides only, as Pimentel et al. did.
In the United Kingdom, Redman (1996) estimated that the costs of conventional farming of
cleaning drinking water was over US$ 2 billion in initial investments and US$ 240 million
annually. These cost were incurred in regulating and removing pesticides from drinking
- 19 -
water and to control and abate nitrate pollution of drinking water. In certain areas in Germany (around Munich) and France (Brittany) farmers are encouraged to convert to organic
agriculture in a bid to maintain the drinking water quality (Heid 1996; Egmont-Florian
1996).
The effect of a change in agricultural management practice, such as to organic agriculture,
means that the cost of externalities is moved from the tax payer (who previously paid to
ameliorate the effects) to the farmer (who tries to prevent the problem). Depending on the
market structure, the farmer may be able to pass on some of the cost to the consumer
through higher output prices. From a national perspective it makes economic sense to ensure that environmental costs are conveyed to the producer. There are several instruments
with which this can be done, such as by regulation or taxation of polluting inputs.
Some policy guidelines
A sound policy is one that achieves its stated objectives in an equitable fashion at least cost.
Good policies are thus effective, equitable and efficient, and such policies are preferably
administratively simple, readily understood and easily enforced. Economists generally favour the polluter-pays principle, and recommend the use of market-based instrument, such
as taxes and subsidies, to implement it. The over-riding principle is that the source of the
pollution should be tackled as directly as possible. With non-point pollution, as in agriculture, taxes and charges may be inefficient because of the difficulties of targeting the source
of the pollution accurately. If all environmental costs of farming were to be charged to the
producer, it would make the conventional product more costly, thereby making the organic
product more competitive. This would mean that the consumer would pay most of the production costs, instead of the taxpayer. Denmark’s present policy of taxing pesticides and
fertilisers, and investigations into the possibilities of further pesticide reductions in agriculture, signal its interest in pursuing this avenue further.
Another approach chosen by many governments in Europe is to subsidise the non-polluting
technology, in this case the organic management system, thereby changing the taxpayers’
role from damage repair to damage prevention. Subsidising organic agriculture has happened in several different ways in Denmark. Since 1987, with the Act on Organic Agriculture, the word ’økologisk’ has been protected. The infrastructure connected with this, such
as the organic standards and the compliance system, was developed with government aid.
Those farmers who converted to organic management received subsidies to help them to
accomplish this. At present, established organic farmers also receive subsidies. Farm subsidies are expected to reach almost DKr.500 million between 1995 and 2000, increasing from
- 20 -
DKr.37 million per year in 1995 to an expected DKr.116 million in 2000 (Finansministeriet
1997). On average, Danish organic farmers receive between 4 and 37 per cent more subsidies per farm than their conventional counterparts (see Section 5). For research, Denmark
has set aside over DKr.100 million from 1996 to 1999, with likely additional amounts to be
allocated during that period (Finansministeriet 1996).
Within the existing policy structure, it is not clear whether Danish taxpayers would pay
more or less with a widespread change to organic management methods. The exact effect
on the public purse in Denmark would depend on the support arrangements. At present
most support to agriculture, including for environmentally-friendly management, is provided by the EU budget, but at least part of the support for organic agriculture per se is paid for
by national governments. Where subsidies are being provided by the EU, the Danish taxpayer does not directly contribute. In the case of subsidies related to outputs, if agricultural
production decreases, as is likely to be the case with a shift to organic agriculture at least for
some crops, lower payments would be due under organic than conventional management.
Subsidies for crops grown on an area basis, as is the case with many crops at EU-level at
present, do not differentiate between organic and conventional agriculture per se. However,
when rotations differ between the two systems, there is a de facto difference in subsidies to
the two systems. For these reasons, Danish organic farmers claim fewer compensatory
payments from Brussels than their conventional counterparts with similar sized farms. On
the other hand, organic farmers receive payments for practising organic management
methods, both from the EU and from national sources. If organic agriculture becomes
widespread, it is questionable whether the support level can be maintained. However, endogenous policy changes of this sort have been ignored in the quantitative analysis that follows.
International policy constraints
Denmark competes in the international market place for many of its agricultural products, and this must be recognised when contemplating the effects of a change in management system. Unilateral action which imposes additional costs on Denmark’s agricultural sector would change its competitive position relative to others. This would be a
financial burden, particularly in the short run. However, this does not mean that those
costs are unacceptable. If they are lower than the costs of pollution abatement, policies
affecting the adoption of organic practices may still be desirable even in the face of declining competitiveness. In addition, Denmark’s policies are influenced by its membership of the European Union and the World Trade Organisation. Denmark could not limit
imports of organic products to protect its local producers, nor could it subsidise its ex-
- 21 -
ports beyond the levels currently prescribed under the Uruguay Round Agreement.
However, international trade provision do allow it to provide its producers with domestic
(not trade-related) assistance for environmental purposes.
Summary
As agriculture not only effects private benefits for farmers but also off-farm costs and
benefits for the society more generally, governments have a legitimate role in modifying
the production process in agriculture. Up until recently, amelioration of environmental
effects were carried by the taxpayer in footing the clean-up bill, and by (some) consumers who paid extra for less polluting production methods, with a contribution of the taxpayers in extra subsidies for agriculture in which such methods were used. This study
should shed some light on whether there are more efficient ways of reducing externalities. Proximity to other countries, and international treaty obligations, may mean that in
certain circumstances part of the taxpayers’ input, through subsidies, could be enjoyed by
consumers in countries other than Denmark.
- 22 -
- 23 -
3. Modelling the widespread adoption of organic practices
3.1. Production and consumption relationships
In agriculture inputs such as land, seeds, nutrients, pest control measures, labour, machinery
and management skill are combined to produce output in the form of plant or animal production. The flowchart in Figure 3.1 illustrates these relationships. The choice of inputs will
depend on various agronomic constraints and the relative availability and prices of inputs.
The relationship between inputs and outputs is influenced by soil type, technology, climatic
conditions and other factors that may be outside the farmer’s control. Once produced, output can then be marketed at the going price. For most products, prices cannot be influenced
by individual farmers; but for the sector as a whole, increased production tends to be associated with lower prices. If prices fall sufficiently, farmers will generally respond by
switching to alternative crops to the extent allowed by agronomic constraints. Quotas,
set-asides and other policies may limit this response.
Consumers also react to prices, generally increasing their consumption with lower prices
and vice versa. Unless all prices rise and fall together, consumers will also switch between
products as relative prices change. At some price level, the available supply will just equal
the desired consumption. Distortions in the market may interfere with this market clearing
price, leading to over or under supply.
The relationships described above can be specified quantitatively in the model. Such models can vary enormously in their degree of abstraction and sophistication, depending on the
available data, the questions to be addressed and resources available for model development. In this study the conventional and organic farming system have been modelled to
identify the key variables and relationships and to provide a preliminary assessment of the
impact of a widespread change to organic management practices in Danish agriculture. The
model developed for this purpose is called DOAP (Danish Organic Agriculture Project) to
reflect its orientation to organic agriculture. Modelling involves first specifying the baseline, the status quo. The second stage involves changing aspects of the model to reflect
Danish agriculture when a given number of farmers (say 20, 40 or 80 per cent) change their
management system. The effect on production through a change in input use, rotation and
yield can be shown. Other effects, such as on prices, and subsequently on farmers’ decision
to change rotations, are then calculated. DOAP is described in more detail in Section 3.2.
- 24 -
FIGURE 3.1. Relationships in agricultural production
Inputs
Marketing
Production
Returns to
farming
Soil
Supply
elasticities
Nutrients
Area
Production:
- crops
- livestock
Pest
control
Labour
Yield
Prices
Demand
elasticities
Machinery
Management
Technology
Policies
Institutions
Consumption
3.2. Model description2
The DOAP model used for simulations described later is a multi-region, multi-commodity,
static, non-linear partial equilibrium model. As such, it is useful for analysing the impact of
a large-scale change to a different management system on input use, total production and
income and the effects of alternative assumptions on these impacts. The model is designed
to calculate impacts at a sectoral level in each region. Because the number of farms is assumed constant in each region, farm level data, such as returns per farm, are also presented.
The description presented below is algebraic, but otherwise complimentary to the flowchart
shown in Figure 3.1. It also emphasises the commodities and regions modelled.
2
By David Vanzetti
- 25 -
The essential elements of DOAP are as follows:
Production differs by region, and each region has its own supply characteristics for each
enterprise:
(1)
Sij = ij  Pij ij
where
 ij = constant
 ij = elasticity of supply
Pij. = price.
Sij is annual production of enterprise i in region j of conventional and organic products. Pij
is the price of conventional products and ij and ij are constant parameters determining the
position and slope of the relationship between prices received by farmers and their production.  indicates that the prices, Pij, for each commodity raised by their elasticity, ij, are
multiplied together to determine supply of one product. This means that the production of a
product depends on its own price and on the prices of substitutes and complements. The
functional form implies a constant elasticity, meaning that quantity increases in proportion
to price changes at all price levels. Many of the cross price elasticities are zero, implying
that the price of one good does not affect the production of another. In addition, many
products are used as inputs into the production of other commodities. These are specified in
fixed proportions or dependent on the specific rotation chosen.
For each enterprise in any region, the observed base year price and quantities and assumed
elasticities can be used to calculate the constant term ij as follows:
(2)
ij = Sij * Pij -ij.
By this method the model is calibrated so that demand equals supply at the current price.
Production shocks or other exogenous changes in supply result in a change in prices. Under
current policies within the European Union, farm support is provided directly through area
and headage payments and product prices are equal to, or at least move with, the world
price. For most products, Denmark provides a small share of world markets and has limited
ability to influence world prices through variations in supply. This implies that changes in
the quantities produced in Denmark have little impact on prices for most goods.
- 26 -
The consumption of goods is specified through the demand function:
(3) Di = i Pij ij
where
i = constant
 ij = elasticity of demand.
Whereas there is a different supply function for each region, there is only one demand function for each commodity. Consumers do not distinguish products by their source. Pork from
Southern and Western Jutland is the same as pork from Northern Jutland. Consumption of
product i is dependent on the price of the good in question plus the prices of substitutes and
complements. The demand function is downward sloping, and consumers purchase less of
the product as its price rises or as the prices of substitutes fall. Elasticities are discussed
further in Section 4.2.6.
Given observed base-year prices and quantities, and the estimated or assumed elasticities,
the constant term can readily be calculated:
(4) i = Di Pi i
Once the relationship between prices and consumption is completely specified, the price
changes that do occur are specified through an inverse demand function for each commodity:
(5) Pi = (Di/i ) (-i)
This equation takes advantage of the equilibrium condition, the assumption that prices adjust so that supply equals demand. The equation implies, for example, that an exogenous
shift, say fall, in production leads to an increase in price as specified above. The relationship between additional supply coming onto the market and the resulting prices reflects the
limited ability of Danish producers to affect prices within the European Union. Even substantial production changes in Denmark lead to very moderate price changes for most products.
Once produced, commodities are not differentiated by region, and all face the same implicit
demand curve. This means that all consumers respond to a price change in a similar fashion.
However, all prices are not the same. There are two types of differentials, quality differ-
- 27 -
ences and an organic premium. For conventional products, quality differences for products
grown in different regions reflect compositional changes between the different grades of the
same commodity. For example, some regions grow a high proportion of the higher priced
malting barley while other regions specialise in feed barley. Average prices in these regions
will differ. These differences are assumed to be constant, and are represented in the model
as follows:
(6)
where
Pij = Pi1 + qij
Pij = price of commodity i in region j
Pi1 = price of commodity i in region 1
qij = quality differential per tonne of commodity i between region j and benchmark region 1.
Organic prices, Pio, are linked to conventional prices in the same region as follows:
(7)
Pijo = Pij (1 + ij)
where
Pijo = price of organic product i in region j
ij = price premium for organic product i in region j
This implies that, as conventional prices vary, the prices for organic products vary in proportion. A 10 per cent increase in conventional prices leads to a 10 per cent increase in organic prices. As described earlier, the premium is not constant and varies with the proportion of farmers producing organic produce. This implies that organic products retain a premium of 20 per cent of their initial level when 80 per cent conversion has occurred. Organic
prices are assumed never to be below the conventional prices.
Equations 6 and 7 imply that prices for organic products in region j are linked as follows to
the price for conventional products in the benchmark region 1:
(8)
Pijo = Pij (1 + ij) + q ij.
The system of demand and supply equations is solved simultaneously. An optimisation
procedure finds the set of prices at which the available supply is equated with demand. This
occurs at a regional level, not at a farm level. It is not assumed that individual farmers optimise their input mix to generate the profit maximising set of outputs. Rather, farmers in
- 28 -
the region collectively alter their output mix in response to price changes. However, average farm estimates can be produced given the assumption that the number of farms is
known, and indeed held constant in this version of the model. Once equilibrium prices for
all products and output levels are determined, input use, costs, production, gross and net
margins and other variables for each enterprise in each region are readily calculated.
A production shift in one enterprise in one region will therefore affect prices of all products
and the area planted of most crops (except where cross elasticities are zero) in all regions.
Changes in area planted are reflected in changes in set-aside so that total land use remains
constant. Other inputs are used in fixed proportions to land, and it is assumed that the price
of these inputs remains unchanged with variations in use. Output is also proportionate to
land use, notwithstanding that a switch from conventional to organic production involves a
different set of input-output relationships.
To simulate the widespread adoption of organic practices, given proportions of Danish
farmers in each sector in each region are assumed to simultaneously adopt specified organic
rotations and accept organic yields and prices. The change in production leads to a new set
of equilibrium prices. This generates a new set of regional incomes and average gross and
net margins. Average farm data is checked to ensure that land is fully utilised and that
farmers are not producing unprofitable enterprises when superior options would be available within the constraints of the rotation. Model output is then calculated and compared
with the baseline.
3.3. Some assumptions
When modelling any change, it is desirable to specify clearly what is being changed and
what is held constant. This is the distinction between exogenous and endogenous variables. Exogenous variables are determined outside the model and the key variable here is the
rate of adoption. This is chosen to be exogenous for the purpose of this exercise, but in reality may depend on factors such as prices and subsidies. Most of the other variables reported
upon here are endogenous, determined within the model. This partly reflects the static nature of the model, with no projections of production, consumption, productivity and other
factors. A third group of inputs are constant, or parameters, such as yield per hectare or
farm size. Many of these could be endogenous, as in reality, but have been held constant for
simplicity. The choice of exogenous and endogenous variables is somewhat arbitrary and
reflects data availability and objectives and understanding of the modeller. Several important assumptions are specified below.
- 29 -
The nature of the analysis
The conversion process from conventional to organic methods is not modelled here. The
first years after conversion are often the more difficult in that the farmer is still learning
about the system. In that process, some financial losses may be due to inexperience with the
new system, and are not incurred in later years. Furthermore, more investments may be
needed due, for example, to differences in animal housing requirements, increasing livestock numbers, storage facilities for crops, fencing of fields, etc. In this study, it is assumed
that a steady state has been reached and farm productivity will not improve without additional inputs.
Enterprise and geographical differences
When a large number of farmers are assumed to spontaneously change their management
system, assumptions need to be made about the distribution of the change. For simplicity, it
is assumed first that homogeneous adaptation across regions and sectors occurs; that is, the
same proportion of each sector in each area changes to organic agriculture. Organic management is likely to be easier (less costly) in some areas and sectors than in others and in
reality those farmers who change first are likely to be concentrated in certain regions and
sectors.
Returns to size and technological change
Similarly, it will be less costly for some farmers to change to organic agriculture than for
others, as some will already have rotations and input usage rates that are close to those used
on organic farms. In other words, the average of inputs used, yields obtained etc. of the first
10 or 20 per cent of farmers to change is likely to be different from the average of the last
20 per cent of farmers. On the other hand, as more and more farmers convert and the industry matures, economies of size in the input and output sectors together with endogenous
technological change are likely to result in higher profitability on organic farms ceteris paribus. However, as no data are available about such details, the basis of comparison in this
study is taken as the present averages.
Output substitutability
When a large number of farmers adopt organic management this in itself will have an influence on input and output prices, and induce more changes in land use and output mix.
The question then is whether farmers in one sector (say crops) will stay in that sector, or
move to another, such as dairy or pigs. Regulations (such as milk quotas) may prevent
farmers from switching to that production sector which is most advantageous to them under
the new conditions. The basic assumption in this study is that farmers keep within the en-
- 30 -
terprise in which they are farming at present. Crop farmers do not become dairy farmers,
etc., but they do switch between crops within the bounds of the sector.
Farm size
In order to compare the farming sector under conventional and organic management, it is
assumed that area farmed is unchanged. The validity of this assumption depends on the net
income per hectare in the different systems. The issue is somewhat complicated by the fact
that the yield of dairy products per hectare is lower on organic farms than on conventional
farms. In order for organic farms to fill the quota obtained when they were conventional
farmers, a number of options are open to them. One is to keep the same kind of rotation,
and expand their total farm area. The second is to change the rotation such that the whole
area is under feed for cows while not much, if any, crop product is sold off the farm. A third
option, recently become available in Denmark, is to sell part of the quota without selling
land. This would mean that one could continue with a rotation more similar to that before
conversion. Looking at the results of the SJFI survey on organic farms, it seems that a combination of the first two options is practised. That is, in general organic dairy farms are
larger (see Section 5.1), yet their rotation is biased more towards roughage than on an average conventional farm. The milk yields per hectare on organic farms are approximately 17
per cent lower than on conventional farms. In this study, the second option (similar sizes of
farms, and less area under crops sold off the farm) is pursued, while in this version of the
model no quota is distributed towards other farmers. On pig farms the stocking rate is reduced (see Section 4).
Effects of management systems on inputs and outputs
The available literature provides a guide to the changes in rotations, input uses and output quantities to be expected under organic management practices (see, for example, several chapters in
Lampkin and Padel (1994)). In Denmark, data are available especially for dairy farming, less so for
crop and pig sectors. Assumptions about these sectors are detailed in the next section.
3.4. Aggregation
One purpose of the model is to look at the consequences of a change towards organic farming for the country, region or sector and to draw implications for average farms within each
sector. If the whole country was homogenous regarding input use, rotations and yields, each
farm would be the same: a typical farm would also be an average farm. In such a case the
average data for one farm (which are readily available via, for example, SJFI surveys),
could be taken and the results of the analysis would give a true picture of what happens on
each farm. Such a farm could then be adjusted to show the characteristics of an organic
- 31 -
farm, and differences in input use, total production and outputs could then be incorporated
in the model. Variables of interest (such as output of each enterprise and the returns to
farming) could then be multiplied with the total number of farmers in Denmark, and the
total use of resources and production in the country could then be calculated.
TABLE 3.1. Number of full-time farms in different regions and sectors (1995-96)
Region and sector
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Soil
Farms
Regional
National
type
-- no. --
---- % ----
---- % ---
2282
1071
1455
4808
47
22
30
100
8
4
5
17
1407
2894
2476
6777
21
43
37
100
5
10
9
23
1264
5840
2345
9449
13
62
25
100
4
20
8
33
703
4851
2468
8022
9
60
31
100
2
17
8
28
loam
loam mixed
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
sand
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
TOTAL
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Source: SJFI data and own calculations.
mixed
5656
14656
8744
29056
19
50
30
100
- 32 -
However, there generally is a large difference in production process between the different
sectors (crops, dairy and pigs), and also between the same sectors in different regions. Thus,
representation of the agricultural sector by one (average) farm in the country would not be
able to provide the possibility of a realistic change to organic management. It was therefore
decided to incorporate twelve representative farms, one for each sector in four regions. In
this way the farms included, which are average farms, are also close to being typical farms,
and can therefore be adjusted to reflect organic practices. In Table 3.1 the four regions are
shown, together with the predominant soil type and percentages of the total number of
farms in each sector and region.
As can be seen from the table, there are as many full-time dairy farmers as crop and pig
farms together. Most of the dairy farmers are on the lighter soils of Southern and Western
Jutland, and Northern Jutland. However, there is a good mix of farm types in all of the four
regions identified here. Availability of data for these sectors is discussed in the next chapter.
- 33 -
4. Data sources and assumptions
4.1. Available statistics
4.1.1. Conventional farms
SJFI collects physical and financial data from approximately 2000 farms across Denmark
each year. Raw data on structure and performance of the three farm types in the four regions are readily available for conventional farming from SJFI farm level surveys for
1995-96. The sample includes 550 part-time farmers, which are excluded from this analysis.
The aggregation of the production on full-time conventional farms times the numbers of
farms in the areas which they represent gives the total production of different farm enterprises in Denmark on full-time farms. Using this method, the difference between the estimated total production of grains and actual production comes within 4 per cent of the actual
production (including non-food) in 1995-96 as estimated by Danmarks Statistik adjusted for
part-time farms (1996, p.109). The corresponding figures for potatoes are 10 per cent, for
sugar beet 3 per cent. For rapeseed the figures are similar. Thus, the data representing the
baseline, where most farmers are conventional, can be considered to be reasonably accurate.
The SJFI survey provides detailed input and output figures for the 12 conventional farms
which were modelled in this study. Figures in this report, however, are not strictly comparable with those of the annual data published by SJFI. For simplicity, certain crops and activities have been excluded, such as green peas, seed legumes, grass for hay, fruit, vegetables, forest and ‘other’. In each area they made up less than 4 per cent of the total area involved, while in 5 of the 12 cases this figure was 1 per cent or less. These enterprises contributed in total less than DKr.10,000 to the returns per farm, and in 10 of the 12 cases less
than DKr.5,000.
4.1.2. Organic farms
In 1997 SJFI conducted its first full-scale representative survey on the organic farming sector. The data used in this study are for 1996-97 and are preliminary. In so far that farm data
differ between years, the data from the conventional and organic farms are not strictly
comparable. However, for those variables for which most variation can be expected, yields
and output prices, preliminary data from the conventional sector for 1996-97 are used in
order to determine ratios (see below).
- 34 -
The number of farmers in the different regions for which data were available, and the distribution of these farms in the different sectors, differentiated as ’in conversion’ and ’steady
state’, and full-time and part-time, can be seen in Table 4.1.
Table 4.1. Number of organic farms in different categories (1996-97)
Farm type
Crops + horticulture
Dairy
Pigs
Total
------ In conversion
-----FullParttime
Time
Total
7
53
1
61
10
5
2
17
17
58
3
78
------- Steady state
-----FullParttime
time
Total
10
38
4
52
16
8
4
28
26
46
8
80
Source: SJFI
Full-time farmers who have finished the conversion stage (that is, those in the ’steady
state’) were to be included (52). However, only for the dairy sector were there a sufficient
number of farmers (38) to provide reliable estimates. This number is too low to differentiate
by region. This means that in this study the same data are used for the organic dairy sector
in each region, adjusted for factors such as total farm area and prices on the average conventional farm in the particular region. No allowance is made for differences between input
needs in the different regions due to, for example, soil type. In this respect the regional disaggregation provides some spurious accuracy to the results to the extent that regional data
are in fact national data. The consequences of this constraint will be pointed out where appropriate.
Although ten farms were included in the SJFI crop sector, the number of hectares was rather
atypical for the crop farmers in general (33 as opposed to over 100), with an average area in
vegetables far exceeding that on the average conventional crop farms. These farms therefore tend more towards horticulture, and it would not have been realistic to include them for
comparison with conventional farms in that category. In the pig sector (which also includes
chickens), the organic farms in the sample kept mainly chickens, so that no representative
pig farm could be found.
Because of this lack of data, a number of assumption had to be made about input use and
outputs on the organic crop and pig farms. At present, in a separate study, SJFI is in the
process of developing a farm-level model of the conventional and organic dairy, pigs and
crop sectors (Poulsen and Folkmann, forthcoming). These detailed models contain infor-
- 35 -
mation about both quantities and prices of inputs and outputs, where appropriate. Each
model of a conventional farm portrays one situation, combining the type of enterprise (for
example, crop) with a particular soil type (for example, sand), irrigation technology (present
or absent), stocking rate and rotation. The organic farm to be compared is then adjusted
from the conventional model, taking into account the physical limitations of the particular
area (such as soil type and need of irrigation). These models can be seen as a series of typical farms. They are based on figures from SJFI, The Danish Agricultural Advisory Centre
and Foulum Research Station. Where appropriate, data generated in that study have been
used to arrive at assumptions for the crop and pig sectors in the DOAP model. These and
other assumptions are discussed below.
4.2. Construction of data on organic farms
Land area on the conventional farms is assumed to be the size of the actual average for the
particular region in which the farm is located. The organic farm is assumed to be the same
size. This means that the number of farms per region also is assumed to remain unchanged
when conversion to organic practices occurs. In reality, lower output per hectare (such as
litres of milk) on organic farms may encourage an increase in average farm size (due to a
lower requirement of labour per hectare).
4.2.1. Variable costs
Seed
Costs of conventional seeds are taken from SJFI, and the cost of organic seeds are related to
organic output prices. For seeds kept on the farm from the previous harvest, the output price
is the opportunity cost of the seed. For those crops where seed has to be bought (such as
potatoes), seed prices reflect other characteristics than what is needed in output for consumption, such as absence of disease and weed seeds. For this reason, seed prices tend to be
higher than output prices for consumption.
For this study, seed prices have therefore been set at output price plus 20 per cent. For the
comparison of systems as it is at present, this is not strictly correct, as non-certified seed is
currently allowed to be used for planting. However, in the future only organic certified seed
will be permitted. For those crops for which no market-determined premiums are available
(such as for roughage) relative seed prices have been taken from Poulsen and Folkmann
(forthcoming), and are therefore not adjusted with changing premiums. As the cost of seed
is small as compared with total input cost, this is considered not to affect results greatly.
- 36 -
Nutrients
Nutrients used on conventional farms include synthetic fertilisers and manures. Most of the
last group is produced on the farm, except in the crop sector. SJFI calculates the value of
manure used according to livestock type, fodder consumption (that is, taking into account
yield), opportunity costs of fertilisers/nutrients and an expected utility rate of the manure.
The total quantity thus calculated (and expressed in monetary value) is distributed to crop
enterprises according to parameters based on knowledge about nutrient needs of the crops.
Therefore, relative differences in manure use between crops are the same on organic and
conventional farms. It should be noted that the values are imputed and are not related to
actual manure production on the farm, nor to imports onto the farm. This last issue is difficult to measure anyway, as many farmers need to dispose of manure in order not to exceed
the amount allowed to be used on the farm and will sell it for a low price, which does not
necessarily reflect the value to the buyer. In some cases manure is exchanged for other services. For the organic dairy farms, manure values as calculated by SJFI are used in this
study.
For the crop and pig farms the use of nutrients had to be estimated. To obtain a measure of
fertiliser and manure use on organic pig farms it is assumed in this study that the use of this
input relative to the use on conventional farms in their sector and region is similar to that in
the dairy sector in Southern and Western Jutland. Thus, where the use of manure on spring
barley on the organic dairy farm in this region was 1.1 times that on the conventional farm,
the application per hectare on the conventional pig farm was multiplied by 1.1 to arrive at
the expenditure on the organic pig farm. For the crop farms a similar amount per hectare as
that on pig farms has been assumed, minus an (arbitrary) 20 per cent, to reflect the fact that,
when manure is scarce it is likely to be used more sparingly. This has been assumed to affect yield negatively, which is discussed in Section 4.2.4.
Pesticides
None are used on organic farms.
Energy and CO2 tax
Energy use on organic farms as compared with conventional farming was taken from
Poulsen and Folkmann (forthcoming), and was set at 80 per cent.
Labour
See under ‘fixed costs’.
- 37 -
Machinery and contract operations
The total costs of repairs and maintenance on machinery, of fuel and of contract operations
on conventional farms and organic dairy farms are obtained from the SJFI survey. The distribution over the different enterprises is carried out according to technical coefficients.
Figures for organic crop and pig farms relative to the conventional farms are taken from
Poulsen and Folkmann (forthcoming).
Animal inputs
Concentrates are purchased off the farm. If farmers keep their crop for feed, this is shown as
an income in the crop enterprise, and as a cost in the livestock section. The costs of roughage is taken as bought roughage in addition to the cost of producing roughage on the farm.
The price of this input on organic farms includes a premium (see below).
Concentrates used on organic pig farms are adjusted for:
- stocking rate, assumed to be 1 animal unit per hectare on organic farms as compared
with 1.7 on conventional farms;
- feeding ratio between organic and conventional pigs, see Nørgaard and Olsen (1995)
and Folkmann and Nørgaard (1996);
- premium for organic wheat for 80 per cent of feed costs. Although the requirement at
present is that 75 per cent is to be bought as organic feed, this will change to 80 per
cent in the near future, and has been anticipated here.
It is assumed that the animals kept on crop farms are pigs, rather than cattle.
4.2.2. Fixed costs
Labour
Labour is mainly a fixed cost, as most of it is family labour. However, hired labour is included under variable costs where relevant.
Expenditure on labour on the organic dairy farms is according to the survey results, and is
distributed by SJFI over the different enterprises in the same way as on conventional farms.
On organic pig and crop farms, labour use on crops relative to that on conventional farms is
as calculated by Poulsen and Folkmann (forthcoming). In the livestock enterprise on pig
farms, the ratio of labour use on conventional and organic farms is taken as the ratio of
conventional intensive pig farms and conventional free-range farms. It is derived from the
- 38 -
hours used per animal times the number of animals per hectare. In this calculation the proportions of breeding sows and baconers is taken assuming that the baconers are bred on the
farm. Although this is a somewhat restrictive assumption, on organic farms breeding of own
fattening animals is encouraged. In addition, in reality about 50 per cent of conventional
farms do have mixed pig breeding and rearing facilities. As the livestock enterprise on crop
farms is assumed to be dominated by pigs rather than by cattle, labour ratios in that farm
sector are set as for those on pig farms.
Depreciation and maintenance
Depreciation is a rather important item, which influences farm profitability significantly.
Depreciation represents the cost of machinery and equipment, buildings and land improvements, and maintenance on buildings and land.
Depreciation on organic dairy farms is obtained from the SJFI survey. For the crop enterprises on the organic crop and pig farms, the ratios are as used on dairy farms by Poulsen
and Folkmann (forthcoming). For the livestock enterprise, the ratio of capital between the
two systems is calculated by taking the same relative enterprise use (breeding stock – baconer) as described under ‘labour’, multiplied by the cost of investment under the two different systems. Once again, the livestock enterprise on crop farms is assumed to have the
same relative values of depreciation as on the pig farms.
4.2.3. Rotation
The rotation on organic dairy farms is taken from the SJFI survey. These figures are shown
in Table 4.2, together with those published by Halberg and Kristensen (1997). A comparison reveals that the dairy farms surveyed by SJFI have rotations biased more towards the
production of roughage, and away from cash crops, than is the case in the survey by Halberg and Kristensen (1997). Within the SJFI survey, organic farmers tend to use a high
proportion of the area in cereals for silage. Especially in the regions with sandy soils, the
total area in cereals on both types of farms is rather similar. The other distinctive difference
between the two systems is the area in grass on organic farms, especially that in rotation,
which takes up about one third of the total area on the organic farm. The area in fodder
beets is very small on organic farms, possibly an indication of the problems with row crops
in organic agriculture at present.
- 39 -
TABLE 4.2. Crop rotations on conventional and organic dairy farms
Grains
Other
Fodder Grass
Beets rotation
Grass
perm.
Silage
Setaside
--------------------------------------- hectares ------------------------------------------SJFI
Conventional:
Eastern Islands
Funen and Eastern Jutland
Southern and Western Jutland
Northern Jutland
Organic:
Ratio org/conv (S+W Jutland)
Halberg and Kristensen (1997)
Conventional:
Organic
Ratio org/conv
1995/96
1996/97
1989-93
1989/93
41
39
31
31
17
57
15
5
5
6
5
100
4
6
6
6
0,3
5
10
18
23
21
31
137
7
11
11
13
13
119
16
15
17
15
27
161
32
28
88
7
5
71
10
3
30
26
38
146
8
11
138
16
14
88
6
6
7
7
5
77
Source: SJFI surveys and Halberg and Kristensen (1997).
Assumptions for rotations on pig and crop farms build on the characteristics of the rotations
on the conventional farms, combined with knowledge of requirements on organic farms,
and are as follows:
-
-
-
area in roughage crops and set-aside area are the same as on conventional farms, with
the exception of grass rotation;
25 per cent of the farm is put under ‘grass in rotation’:
this implies that the total production of pasture increases. It is assumed here that the
product is sold against cost price and, if need be, exported;
the rest of the area is divided over grains and ‘other’ in the same proportions as on the
conventional farms in the particular area, for example 68 per cent in grains on crop
farms on the Eastern Islands, and 26 per cent on ‘other’ on pig farms in Northern Jutland;
the area in ‘grains’ and ‘other’ is divided along the same principle as above, that is,
each individual crop is allocated an area according to the importance of the particular
crop in its group on the organic dairy farm. It can be expected that the relative importance of each crop varies between regions. However, the variation is even more
pronounced according to management system. It is for this reason that the rotation
found on the organic dairy farms surveyed by SJFI are taken as the basis of reference,
even though this does not allow the regional variation to be expressed. In practice, this
means that the emphasis on organic farms is on spring barley, as opposed to winter
wheat on conventional farms. In the category ‘other’ the main crops grown on conven-
- 40 -
tional farms are potatoes, sugar beets, peas (green and for fodder) and rapeseed. On organic farms, potatoes, peas for fodder, and rapeseed were grown. Sugar beets, and also
green peas, are generally considered to be too costly to weed under present conditions
of technology and input and output prices. However, this aspect of production is now
being researched, and it can therefore be expected that these crops will become of more
interest to organic farmers in the future. They have not been included in this study at
present.
A rotation based on the arguments above gives an area of potatoes of approximately 13
hectares, on crop farms. As this seems rather unrealistic, the upper limit of area in potatoes is set at 5 hectares, with the rest to spring grains.
4.2.4. Yield and output
The SJFI-figures for organic dairy agriculture are national figures. They have been compared with conventional dairy farming in Southern and Western Jutland as that is where
most organic dairy farmers are located. For fodder crops on conventional farms (fodder
beets, grass in rotation and permanent, maize and cereals for silage) SJFI takes the yield
from the Denmark Statistics Authority (DSA). Those are obtained from the farm advisory
system, and SJFI then adjusts yields on individual farms for levels of manure and fertiliser
used. Yields of organically grown fodder crops are adjusted by SJFI to 20 per cent less than
those on conventional farms at the national level. The exception is fodder beets, where a
reduction of 10 per cent is assumed by SJFI on organic farms.
Organic crop and pig farms are expected to have different relative yields to those on conventional farms in their area. In the first place, rotations are different from those on dairy
farms, as no roughage is needed for livestock, although some roughage is being used on
organic pig farms. In addition, little or no manure is available on crop farms, although on
pig farms manure is produced. It was assumed that crop and pig farms put a quarter of their
area in grass, part of which can be used as green manure, with approximately 10 per cent (in
1995-96) under set-aside. Even so, yields on these farms can be expected to be lower than
on dairy farms. In this study the percentage yield obtained on organic crop farms has therefore been assumed to be 80 per cent of the percentage obtained on organic dairy farms, and
that on pig farms 90 per cent. For example, where organic dairy farms yield 93 per cent of
spring barley on conventional farms in their particular area, organic crop farms are assumed
to yield 74 per cent (93 x 80 per cent), and pig farms 84 per cent (93 times 90 per cent).
- 41 -
The livestock enterprise on pig and crop farms is assumed to yield 59 per cent (1/1.7) of the
production on conventional farms.
Total output figures are obtained by multiplying the yield with the area under production.
How much area farmers decide to put under a particular crop is dependent not only on rotational requirements as described above, but also on expected input and output prices. This
last topic is discussed below.
4.2.5. Output prices
Although not many organic crops are traded, prices for crops were obtained via the survey
on organic dairy farms, and these are also used for the crop and pig sectors. The reason for
the limited organic product market in Denmark is that most organic farms are dairy farms,
where crops grown (mainly grains and fodder) are used to feed cattle. Regional price differences are maintained as in conventional farming. Prices used for internal calculations
such as for roughage crops (fodder beets, grass, cereals for silage) in the dairy sector are
generated as for conventional agriculture, that is, prices are equated to the cost of production, which is then charged as a cost in the item ’roughage’ in the livestock enterprise. As
prices change over time, it is important to take prices at the same point in time when comparing them. For this reason, the percentages of price premiums have been calculated by
comparing organic prices in 1996 with those for conventionally grown products in 1996.
This was done despite the fact that the returns to farming for the conventional sector in this
study are based on outputs and prices received in 1995.
Prices for organic dairy products are easier to ascertain. In practice at present, many organic
farmers receive approximately 20 per cent as a basic premium, to which a variable amount
is added which reflects the percentage of milk sold as organic milk. For example, in the
second quarter of 1997, organic farmers received a premium of 22.4 per cent on what conventional farmers were expected to receive.
When many farmers practise organic management, organic products will be more abundant,
and prices are expected to decrease. At the same time, it is quite feasible that an outward
shift in the demand curve will occur, as suggested by the increase in demand for organic
products at higher prices in Denmark in the recent past, especially with dairy products.
Shifts in the demand curve, due to a change in incomes or preferences, should not be confused with movements along the curve, which reflect changes in prices. Demand is assumed
to match supply, although organic products will increasingly be seen as less of a luxury
- 42 -
item by most consumers, and the premium most people will be prepared to pay will diminish. In this study, the organic premium is set to drop one per cent of the present price for
each percentage point of increase in organic production. Thus, at 80 per cent levels of adaptation, crop premiums are 20 per cent of the current levels. This is a linear relationship,
and an argument could be made that the premium would erode more or less quickly. There
is little empirical evidence, one way or the other.
The price of organic pig meat is at present around 70 per cent higher than of conventional
pig meat at the farm gate. This premium also decreases in proportion to the increase in
number of organic farmers, as with crops. The livestock enterprise on crop farms is assumed to be pigs, and input, yield and price parameters used reflect this.
It is important to realise that premiums received by farmers do not necessarily reflect prices
paid by consumers, as the price for the raw material is a rather small percentage of the total
package, which includes transport, insurance, packaging and distribution. On average in
1995, farmers received 25 per cent of prices paid by consumers, though there was a large
variation in this figure in percentages for individual products, ranging from 45 per cent for
butter (with milk, meat and eggs between 30 and 40 per cent) to 5 per cent for bread. In
other words, a premium at the farm gate of 50 per cent translates into less than 20 per cent
for the final product of milk, meat and eggs, and 2.5 per cent for bread. A 20 per cent increase in wheat prices, as proposed here, increases bread prices by 1 per cent. The considerable increase in prices for organic products at consumer level in the past has therefore not
mainly been due to increased producer prices, but to higher ‘other’ costs, such as those of
transport. When the majority of farmers is organic, however, a considerable part of the extra
costs to the consumers should decline. This means that consumer prices are likely to drop
more than the premiums in producer prices as assumed in this paper. This is important in
connection with the effect on consumers’ behaviour, which in its turn will affect farmers’
production decisions, discussed in the next section.
4.2.6. Elasticities
At the heart of any economic model are the elasticities, the responsiveness of quantities
supplied or consumed to a change in prices. Quantities produced or consumed change not
only in response to changes in their own output price, but also to a change in the prices of
substitute or complementary products or goods and also the prices of inputs. Other variables, such as income levels, also affect consumption, but these factors are assumed constant
in this analysis and are not considered further. Supply elasticities are discussed first.
- 43 -
Supply
When a change in production occurs (which is what happens when many farmers change to
organic agriculture), input and output prices will change. This in itself will affect the willingness of farmers to produce a particular crop rather than another crop or livestock enterprise. The response of farmers to price changes is captured in elasticities of supply.
The elasticities of supply used in this study are taken from an OECD (1991) model. Estimates used for Denmark are for the European Union. These are based only on product prices, excluding area subsidies. The assumption here is that area-based subsidies do not affect
production, as subsidies do not change with supply (with the exception of rapeseed). It
could be argued that this is a strong assumption, and that payments to land bring forth
greater production by encouraging the greater use of capital and labour within the sector,
but this is ignored for the purpose of this study.
Cross-price elasticities of supply are also included in the study. Where OECD figures were
available only for a whole group of crops (such as for coarse grains) each individual crop in
that category was allocated a proportion of the total figure equivalent to its relative importance in the rotation. This implies that the figures for each region are not exactly the
same, though similar. An example of elasticities employed in the dairy sector in Southern
and Western Jutland is shown in Table 4.3. These data imply, for example, that a 10 per
cent increase in the price of spring grains (barley) would lead to a 3.9 per cent increase in
the production of spring grains and a 1.9 per cent fall in output of winter wheat.
TABLE 4.3. Elasticities of supply in dairy sector in Southern and Western Jutland
Quantity
Grains, spring
Barley, winter
Wheat, winter
Rye, winter
Peas, fodder
Potatoes
Sugarbeets
Seeds, grass
Rapeseed
Livestock
Grains
spring
0.39
0.02
-0.19
-0.06
----------------------------------------------- Prices ----------------------------------------------Barley Wheat
Rye
Peas
Sugar Seeds RapeMilk
winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass
seed
0.39
0.02
-0.19
-0.06
-0.21
-0.01
0.46
-0.02
-0.04
-0.21
0.39
-0.02
-0.02
-0.02
-0.02
-0.02
-0.02
0.95
-1.61
0.10
-0.02
0.10
0.10
-0.09
-0.80
-0.01
-0.80
Source: Adapted from OECD (1991).
-0.37
-0.80
-0.01
-0.80
-1.61
0.95
1.00
- 44 -
The effects of prices on outputs are constrained by rotational requirements and limited by a
number of (often institutional) aspects. These are not necessarily the same for all crops. The
following limitations are the most relevant in Denmark at present, and these are used to
frame assumptions in the model.
Grains
Within the group of cereals for grain production, the farmer does not differentiate between the
crops, apart from the fact that 60 per cent of the total land area needs to be covered during the winter. It is assumed that, if the grass and winter grains areas are less than 60 per cent, the spring grains
are undersown with grass.
Milk production and roughage
This includes grass in rotation and grown on a permanent basis, silage made of maize and
cereals, and fodder beets. These crops are directly linked to the dairy enterprise, which is
governed by the quota system. Any farmer delivering over-quota quantities of milk has to
pay a fine proportionate to the extra quantity delivered, thereby assuring that
over-production does not easily occur. Although quotas are transferable, with the establishment of a milk bourse in 1997, the total quantity of milk Denmark can deliver is fixed.
At present, conditions are such that it is likely that the purchase of a quota by a farmer occurs when additional land can be bought. Where no expansion of area per farm is permitted
it can be assumed that no change in the number of cows occurs once the transition to organic farming is complete. The area in roughage will therefore also not alter, even when
prices change. Reflecting this assumption, the price elasticities of supply for these enterprises is zero. The strict assumptions (no expansion of area on individual farms and no
change in enterprise, for example from crop to dairy farm) mean that the milk quota may
not be filled. This can be modified in additional scenarios.
Sugar beets
The quantity of sugar beets produced is related to a quota, and any quantity produced in
excess is sold at a considerably reduced price. This assures that, under present conditions,
no more sugar beets are grown even when prices increase. However, if organic farmers
continue to find it unrewarding to grow sugar beets at existing prices, those farmers who
stay conventional when a large proportion of farmers change to organic management could
grow more without delivering over-quota. However, in this version of the model the
non-filled quota is not reallocated.
Rapeseed and peas
- 45 -
Rapeseed and peas are break-crops for the grains, and as such these crops are not readily
substitutable with grains, but quite substitutable with one another. For rapeseed in particular, the EU subsidy plays an important role in the total returns (product price and hectare
subsidy). However, the subsidy varies with output prices, causing the gross returns to be
less variable than the output price. In addition, the subsidy is announced approximately half
a year after harvest so that farmers cannot take into account the actual subsidy when deciding on plantings. Although rapeseed and peas are used as an animal feed, they are sold off
the farm, even when livestock is present, as they need to be processed before used as feed.
Set-aside
This area is treated as the residual. As the total farm area is assumed to stay the same,
changes in total area in crop have been incorporated under this item. Thus, although the
elasticity is set at zero, the area can still change. This assumption is somewhat unrealistic
but, as it does not create much difference, it is accepted for convenience sake in this version
of the model.
Demand
Consumers react to changes in prices of goods, and may change their consumption patterns
irrespective of prices. Both these phenomena influence product prices, which in their turn
influence production.
Prices for agricultural products included in this study are similar throughout the European
Union. Products can be moved freely from country to country. This means that changes in
quantities produced in Denmark may not affect the price greatly. The extent to which prices
in Denmark are affected is dependent on the export elasticity of demand faced by the European Union. At present, this is assumed to be –10 for most products and –5 for pig products3. This implies that a 10 per cent increase in production in Denmark would lead to a 1
per cent fall in price for all products except pig products, for which the same increase in
price would be caused by only 5 per cent decrease in quantity sold.
The question is whether the same estimates can be used for organically produced goods. In
general, for those consumers who purchase organic products for dietary reasons it is likely
that the demand is rather price unresponsive. As the demand curve shifts out with an increasing number of people buying organic products, as seems the case at present in Denmark, price responsiveness for organic products is likely to increase. A greater proportion
3
These parameters can readily be changed by the model user if and when better estimates become available.
- 46 -
of consumers will have less compelling reasons to stick with organic products when prices
increase and are less reticent to buy organic products with decreasing prices. In how far this
differs from conventionally grown products is not clear, as little if any work has been done
on this topic. There is anecdotal evidence that, as long as premiums are below 30 per cent,
demand is reasonably stable. That is, the elasticity could well be similar to that for conventionally grown products.
Consumers would undoubtedly pay high prices for organic products if they have little
choice. However, competition from internationally traded goods is likely to limit the size of
premiums. This limits the extent to which premiums can be raised for domestically grown
products. As with conventional products, the level of willingness to pay a premium will
undoubtedly also depend on the nature of the good, as luxury goods have a higher elasticity
than necessities. The difference in elasticities between conventional and organic products is
therefore likely to be smallest in those products which are low cost (such as grain flour),
and highest in high cost items such as meat and luxury fruits. However, as the industry matures, organic products as a whole will become less of a luxury good and elasticities can be
expected to fall. Therefore, at increasing levels of organic management, similar price elasticities of demand are assumed to those used in this report for conventional products.
It is likely that the consumption of organic produce is more responsive to changes in incomes than conventional products. To the extent that organic products are seen as luxury or
high quality goods, consumption is likely to increase as incomes rise and fall more than
other food products when a recession in the business cycle occurs. In this study, changes in
income levels in the agricultural sector are assumed insufficient to significantly change the
income levels of consumers in the market for Danish organic products.
- 47 -
5. The current state of agriculture – the baseline
5.1. Land
The distribution of land use is important not only in determining production, but also in estimating the amount of environmental damage, as this varies according to the intensity of
input use in the different sectors. Although at the baseline (with only a negligible number of
organic farmers) crop farms make up less than 20 per cent of farm numbers (see Table 3.1),
30 per cent of the total farmed area is taken up by this sector. This is illustrated in Table 5.1.
The geographical distribution of the different sectors is rather distinct. The heavier the soil,
the more farm management is specialised towards cash crops as opposed to roughage for
animal feed. Crop farms make up almost half of the numbers, and two thirds of the area, in
the Eastern Islands, with Northern Jutland showing the lowest percentages of under 10 per
cent of number of crop farms, and under 15 per cent of total area.
Table 5.1. Area per farm and total by region and sector (1995-96)
Farm size
Total area
Regional
National
------------- % -----------
---- ha ----
- ’000 ha -
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
104
51
57
78
238
54
83
376
63
14
22
100
12
3
4
19
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
103
51
67
68
145
147
167
458
32
32
36
100
7
7
8
23
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
106
59
67
67
134
346
156
637
21
54
24
100
7
18
8
32
99
55
65
62
70
268
160
498
14
54
32
100
4
14
8
25
104
56
65
68
588
815
566
1969
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
TOTAL
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Source: SJFI data and own calculations.
30
41
29
100
- 48 -
Average farm size is partly determined by the amount of land necessary to provide a suitable income for the predominantly family farms. The size of particular enterprises is rather
similar in the different regions, but there is a rather large difference between the crops and
the two livestock sectors. The crop farms are considerably larger than farms in the other
sectors, in two of the four regions more than double the size of the dairy farms in the same
regions. The pig farms are larger than the dairy farms, but are more similar to dairy than
crop farms in size.
Although, for the purpose of this study, the organic farms are assumed to be of the same
size as the conventional farms, the survey on organic dairy farms shows that, at 76 hectares,
the established organic farms are considerably larger than the average conventional farm.
Compared with conventional dairy farms in Southern and Western Jutland, the organic
farms are 28 per cent larger. Those in the conversion stage at present do not show a change
in this characteristic.
5.2. Input costs
The average variable and fixed costs per farm (organic and conventional) in Denmark, as
surveyed or as calculated under assumptions discussed in Section 4, are shown in Table 5.2.
They are portrayed graphically in Figure 5.1. In general, for farms of comparable size, both
variable and fixed costs are lower on the organic than on the conventional farms. The exception is the variable costs on organic pig farms, which is for a large part due to premiums
on organic feed concentrates. The less intensive nature of organic animal rearing, and in
particular pig farming, and the husbandry requirements for organic pigs, means that a lower
investment in housing results in relatively low fixed costs.
Regional differences between organic and conventional farms in average farm costs are
shown in the final column of Appendix Table A.1. The differences are more variable in the
crop and dairy sector than in the pig sector, ranging from 78 to 89 per cent for crop farms,
from 78 to 91 per cent for dairy farms, and from 93 to 95 per cent for pig farms. Variable
costs on the two types of farms are more similar than fixed costs. There are no significant
differences in input costs between regions. The most notable exception is the pig sector on
the Eastern Islands, where average farm costs are well below costs in other regions. This
reflects smaller farm size rather than greater efficiency in this region.
- 49 -
TABLE 5.2. Average input costs by sector at baseline
Organic
VARIABLE COSTS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Conventional
Org./Conv.
----- DKr. ‘000 per farm -----
---- pct. ----
453
820
1381
516
946
1445
88
87
96
351
398
459
451
523
606
78
76
76
804
1218
1840
967
1469
2050
83
83
90
FIXED COSTS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
TOTAL
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Source: Derived from SJFI data and own calculations.
FIGURE 5.1: Average input costs by sector at baseline
2500
Dkr '000 per farm
2000
1500
Fixed
Variable
1000
500
0
Org
Conv
Org
Conv
Org
Conv
crop
crop
dairy
dairy
pigs
pigs
- 50 -
The most reliable comparison of cost structures in this study is in the dairy sector where
there are a reasonable number of organic farms in the SJFI survey. It is for this reason that a
more detailed breakdown of the costs is shown for this sector in Table 5.3 with averages for
the national level. The comparison between the conventional and organic farms in the four
regions is shown in Appendix Table A.2.
TABLE 5.3. Average input costs on dairy farms at baseline
Organic
Conventional
Org./Conv.
----- DKr. ‘000 per farm -----
---- pct. ----
VARIABLE COSTS
Seed
Fertiliser
Manure
Pesticides
Energy
Co2-tax
Labour: hired
Maintenance: machinery
Contract operations
Other: plant production
Concentrates
Roughage
Vet. Costs
Insemination
Other costs: livestock
Total
28
1
40
0
25
3
127
63
83
8
213
214
19
9
26
858
22
33
38
18
21
2
100
59
61
7
253
258
27
12
35
946
125
3
108
0
116
109
128
106
135
106
84
83
72
72
76
91
FIXED COSTS
Depreciation
Labour: family
Other
Total
125
222
68
416
128
327
67
523
98
68
101
80
1274
1469
87
TOTAL
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
As expected, the data show not only lower fertiliser and pesticide costs, but also lower
expenditure on animal related inputs (such as concentrates, roughage and animal health).
The methodology presently employed in the SJFI analysis of surveys (see Section 4.2.1),
means that expenditure on manure on organic dairy farms is calculated to average
DKr.40,000, as compared with DKr.38,000 on the conventional dairy farm. In addition to
the manure, DKr.1,000 and DKr.33,000 was spent on fertiliser on the organic and conventional farms, respectively. The value of the manure produced on the conventional farm was
similar to that used. On average, organic dairy farmers imported for DKr.2,000 onto their
- 51 -
farm, or 5 per cent of total requirement. The picture of organic dairy farmers using considerably less nutrients (calculated as expenditure on synthetic fertilisers and manures) than
conventional farmers can also be seen in Plantedirektoratet (1997, Table 6.3). 95 per cent of
organic (dairy) farmers used 60 per cent or less of the nitrogen norm (the amount allowed to
be used).
Estimates in the pig sector (based on use in the conventional pig sector and relative use on
organic and conventional dairy farms, see Section 4.2.1) resulted in a similar picture. For
example, in Southern and Western Jutland, both conventional and organic pig farmers spent
approximately DKr.40,000 on manure. DKr.29,000 is spent on fertiliser on the conventional
farm. In monetary terms, conventional pig farmers export approximately 30 per cent of their
manure off the farm. This brings the remaining quantity close to what is produced on organic farms, where the stocking rate (and therefore the on-farm manure production) is just
under 60 per cent of that on the conventional farm. On the crop farms, most of the nutrient
requirements have to be purchased off-farm. A decrease in yield on the organic pig farm as
compared with the conventional pig farm (10 per cent below the relative yield on dairy
farms) and crop farms (20 per cent below the relative yield on dairy farms) was to compensate for lower nutrient availabilities (both in the form of applied nutrients and those supplied within the rotation system).
Although dairy farmers do not import much manure under present conditions, and pig
farmers are estimated to do the same, especially crop farmers will find it difficult to find
sufficient manure when many farmers have changed to organic management. This means
that, in the process of more farmers adopting organic practices, manure is likely to become
scarcer, and therefore more expensive. Imports from other countries with manure excesses
(such as The Netherlands) has all sorts of problems attached to it, apart from the increase in
costs due to transport. Organic agriculture strives to contain the production requirements as
much as possible within the farm, and a massive import of manures would certainly negate
the possibility of obtaining such a goal.
Other sources of nutrients, however, can be used in organic agriculture, such as ground rock
dust (for example, rock phosphate), and an increase in nitrogen-fixing crops in the rotation.
Nutrient sources which may well become possibilities in the future include recycled household wastes and human sewage. The possibility that crop-only farms will become scarce in
an organic agriculture future should also be considered. For the purpose of this study similar expenditure on manure, and effect on yield, over the time were modelled as in the baseline. For dairy farms, there is no reason why this should not hold, as they are selfsufficient
- 52 -
(with yield penalties) at the baseline. For pig farms, the estimated production of manure on
organic farms is more than 84 per cent from what is being used on conventional pig farms
at present. It is therefore reasonable to expect that the presently assumed yield penalty at the
baseline (10 per cent less than the relative yield on organic/conventional dairy farms) will
not drop greatly at increasing rates of adoption of organic management. For crop farms,
yield levels at the baseline are more likely to drop at higher levels of conversion.
The difference between organic and conventional producers in feed costs is partly due to
fewer animals per unit of land on organic farms, although the premium prices for organic
feed is a cost-increasing factor. Fewer animal health problems occur on organic farms, a
well-established characteristic (Lampkin 1990) leading to lower costs (see, for example,
Wynen (1994)).
In terms of contribution to total costs, the largest difference is in expenditure on labour.
Although hired labour costs are higher on organic farms, the total labour cost (including
family labour) is considerably lower on organic farms. When contract operations, which are
higher on organic farms, are included, the difference between the two management system
is still DKr.56,000 per farm on the national level, and DKr.35,000 per farm in Southern and
Western Jutland, the most relevant comparison. This difference between the farm types
could be due to a difference in demographic factors, such as age of the farmer or proximity
to centres which facilitate off-farm employment. It should be noted that family labour has
an imputed value which may be higher than that necessary to keep labour in the sector. If
this is the case, the high values attributed to family labour may overestimate the differences
between the cost structures on organic and conventional farms.
In total, these differences in costs amount to lower variable and fixed costs on the organic
farm, as discussed above. The differences in relative costs on the national level and in the
four regions is due to the assumption that costs on organic farms per hectare are the same in
all regions, as noted in Section 4.1.2.
5.3. Rotations and total land use
The rotations on each farm are assumed to be unsynchronised, so that each year the region
uses land as described by the average area per farm in the table. As noted earlier, although
organic farmers have somewhat less flexibility within these rotational constraints than their
conventional counterparts, considerable scope remains for the sector as a whole, and therefore price changes lead to changes in regional land use and output.
- 53 -
Table 5.4 shows the average land use on a conventional farm in the three sectors nation-wide with most farmers producing under a conventional system. As rotations are rather
dependent on local circumstances, such as soil type, regional variations exist. They are
shown in Appendix Table A.3.
Although spring barley is important on all farm types at one fifth of the total area on average, winter wheat is of greater importance in some sectors, in particular on crop and pig
farms, comprising almost one third of total area nationally. This is the case especially on the
heavier soils (on Eastern Islands, Funen and Eastern Jutland). This percentage is half or less
on dairy farms on clay soils, and on the lighter soils of Southern and Western Jutland and
Northern Jutland winter wheat is of minor importance in that farm sector. In the dairy sector, area under roughage (fodder beet, grass, silage) is important, especially on the lighter
soils (over half of the area), but also on the heavier soils. The production of roughage impinges mainly on winter grains, while the area in spring grains is rather similar in all sectors. In the crop and pig sectors almost no area is devoted to roughage and of what there is,
most is in permanent grass, presumably because that land is not suitable for any other use.
Around 10 per cent is in set-aside (somewhat lower in the dairy sector), although this decreases in the next year with changes in subsidy policies.
The total area used for the different enterprises in Denmark is also shown in Table 5.4.
Winter wheat was clearly the most important crop in 1995-96, and spring grains the second
most important. Together with set-aside land, these three enterprises comprised more than
half of the agricultural area. Grass, either in rotation or permanent, makes up another important category.
As a different rotation is a distinctive characteristic of organic farming, a comparison of
rotations in the two systems is shown in Table 5.5 for the three sectors in Southern and
Western Jutland.
Data for the organic sector are national figures, adjusted to the size of the conventional farm
in Southern and Western Jutland. The figures for crop and pig farms are the result of calculations based on the assumptions discussed in Section 4. It can be seen that organic dairy
farmers grow considerably less grain than conventional dairy farmers. If silage made from
grain is included, however, the total figures are not that dissimilar. Although the conventional dairy farmers grow considerably less winter than spring grains, organic dairy farmers
TABEL 5.4. Crop rotations on full-time conventional farms and total land use by enterprise at the baseline (1995)
Grains Barley Wheat Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rape- Set- Nonspring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass seed aside food
Fod- Grass Grass
der rota- perma Silage Silage
beet
tion nent maize cereal Total
---------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage of total hectares per farm ------------------------------ ---ha-CROP ROTATIONS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
19
20
21
20
4
3
11
5
31
9
32
20
4
2
3
2
4
2
4
3
4
1
2
2
6
1
2
2
6
0
3
2
6
1
7
4
11
7
9
8
2
0
3
1
0
6
0
3
1
20
1
11
2
12
3
7
0
3
0
2
65
55
52
172
9
4
17
30
0
50
1
51
4
167
5
175
11
95
15
121
0
27
0
27
0
13
0
6
104
56
65
68
---------------------------------------------------------------------- ‘000 hectares
---------------------------------------------------------------------TOTAL LAND USE
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
114
164
122
400
26
20
60
107
181
71
178
429
23
14
16
53
21
18
23
63
23
9
9
41
35
8
11
54
34
2
14
50
38
9
42
89
2 588
103 815
2 566
106 1969
Source: Derived from SJFI data and own calculation.
TABEL 5.5. Rotations by sector and farm type in Southern and Western Jutland at baseline
Grains Barley Wheat Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rape- Set- Nonspring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass seed aside food
Fod- Grass Grass
der rota- perma Silage Silage Underbeet
tion nent maize cereal sown Total
--------------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage of total area per farm ---------------------------------------- ---ha-CROP
Conventional
Organic*
27
29
5
2
17
6
6
6
6
5
12
5
1
0
3
0
7
8
12
12
1
0
0
0
2
25
1
1
0
0
0
0
1
1
106
106
DAIRY
Conventional
Organic
21
11
1
1
6
3
2
3
2
1
2
2
0
0
0
0
1
2
7
5
0
0
6
0
23
31
11
13
3
1
14
26
13
16
59
59
PIGS
Conventional
Organic*
31
30
10
2
21
7
4
7
4
4
5
5
0
0
3
0
8
6
11
11
2
0
0
0
1
25
3
3
0
0
0
0
1
1
67
67
Source: SJFI and derived.
Note: * = Assumed values.
- 54 -
- 55 -
grow even less winter grains, reflecting relatively lower yields (see below). In addition, organic farms use spring barley as an opportunity to undersow grass. For the organic crop and
pig sectors, a decrease in winter grains is also evident, though the area of spring grains is
similar to that on conventional farms. The area in potatoes is also larger than on dairy
farms.
5.4. Yields
Yields on organic farms in general are lower than on conventional farms. The reduction in
yields depends on the crop, soil type, seasonal conditions and other factors. Estimates from
the SJFI survey and other sources are shown in Table 5.6. SJFI data for the conventional
sector are shown for 1995, with additional data for some crops for 1996. In the dairy sector,
yields on conventional farms were fairly similar for the two years, although a reduction was
evident in some winter crops in 1996. Data included for the average organic dairy farm
were for the year 1996. This means that yields on organic farms are likely to be underestimated for the winter grains and fodder peas, and overestimated for rapeseed in this study.
On average, the yield on organic dairy farms is 3 percentage points lower as compared
with conventional dairy farms than if 1996 data had been used for the conventional farms.
Yields on organic crop and pig farms are taken as a percentage of the relative yields of the
conventional and organic dairy farms (see Section 4.2.4).
In general, winter wheat performs worst on organic farms relative to on conventional farms.
Fodder peas do rather well under organic management, with higher yields, as opposed to
potatoes and rapeseed, which yield approximately half or less on organic farms as compared
with conventional farms. The yields on organic dairy farms (1996) as compared with those
on conventional farms (1995) are depicted in Figure 5.2.
Apart from SJFI survey data, other sources of yield comparisons provide an additional
guide. Halberg and Kristensen (1997) measured yields on three soil types for two cash
crops, spring grains and winter wheat, and two fodder crops, fodder beets and grass in rotation, for the years 1989-93. Yields on conventional farms for the cash crops are similar or
higher than those of SJFI in 1995. For spring grains, their estimate of yields on organic
farms are similar or lower than SJFI’s survey data. This combination of higher conventional
and lower organic yields results in low relative organic yields, up to 10 percentage points
lower than SJFI estimates. For winter wheat the organic yields are higher than in the SJFI
survey, so that the result is higher or similar relative yields on organic farms for this crop.
The lowest yields are recorded on sand, as can be expected.
TABEL 5.6. Actual and estimated yields of different enterprises and management systems in Southern and Western Jutland
Farm type
Year
DAIRY (SJFI)
Conventional
Conventional
Organic
Org./conv
Org./conv.
1995
1996
1996
1995
1996
Soil
type
Grains Barley Wheat Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rape- Set- NonUnit spring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass seed aside food
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
%
%
4.8
4.8
4.2
87
87
DAIRY (Halberg and Kristensen 1997)
Conv.
1989-93
clay
Organic
Conv.
sand
Organic
Conv.
irr.sand
Organic
Org./conv
clay
Org./conv
sand
Org./conv
irr.sand
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
%
%
%
5.7
4.4
4.6
3.6
5.9
4.4
77
78
75
CROP (SJFI)
Conventional
Organic (estimated)*
Organic (established)
Org.(estimated)/conv
Org.(established)/conv
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
%
%
4.9
3.4
3.7
69
75
5.6
4.0
t/ha
t/ha
t/ha
%
%
5.4
4.2
3.7
78
68
5.9
4.8
5.8
80
97
PIGS (SJFI)
Conventional
Organic (estimated)*
Organic (established)
Org.(estimated)/conv
Org.(established)/conv
1995
1996
1995
1996
5.5
5.0
5.0
89
100
6.7
5.9
3.9
58
65
4.8
4.4
4.4
93
100
3.5
3.0
4.0
114
133
29.3
42.5
35.8
0.8
15.3
52
1.7
2.1
0.9
53
41
1.9
9.3
6.5
6.8
4.6
8.5
5.4
70
68
64
71
7.0
3.2
3.8
46
55
4.7
3.5
3.9
74
82
3.2
2.9
1.4
91
44
28.5
11.9
20.1
42
70
48.2
7.4
3.8
4.8
52
65
5.1
4.2
1.6
84
32
3.9
4.0
31.5
14.8
47.5
102
47
1.4
1.7
0.7
1.5
42
1.2
1.9
0.9
47
Source: SJFI surveys, Halberg and Kristensen (1997) and own calculations.
Notes: * = author’s estimates (see text) irr.sand = irrigated sand.
Data from other regions shown if no data available for Southern and Western Jutland (fodder beet and silage maize).
Fod- Grass Grass
der rota- perma Silage Silage
beet
tion nent maize cereal
13.3
6.9
4.0
8.1
6.2
10.3
77
4.8
71
3.0
76
5.5
68
5.0
80
12.2
10.5
10.2
9
11.3
9.7
86
88
86
6.9
6.1
6
5.2
7.1
5.9
88
87
83
4.1
2.5
3.0
61
72
8.5
4.6
5.5
3.5
4.7
64
4.3
2.9
2.7
68
63
7.7
4.7
12.6
7.8
62
2.1
14.8
10.3
7.0
70
47
54
61
5.8
4.2
6.1
72
104
- 56 -
- 57 -
FIGURE 5.2: Yields on organic farms (1996) relative to yields on conventional farms
(1995)
120
Per cent
100
80
60
40
20
Rape
seed
Potato
Peas
Rye
Winter
wheat
Winter
barley
Spring
grain
0
Enterprise
The relative yields of the fodder crops in Halberg and Kristensen (1997) are between 80 and
90 per cent. For fodder beet this is lower, and for grass higher than the 10 and 20 per cent
yield reductions, respectively, assumed by SJFI (see Section 4.2.4). Part of the reason for
the SJFI figures in Table 5.6 showing less than 80 per cent yield on organic farms of yields
on conventional farms, is the high yields on conventional farms in Southern and Western
Jutland as compared with other regions in 1995.
The yields in the crop and pig sectors (for the conventional and estimated organic) are also
shown in Table 5.6. Another row is included to show the actual yield data on organic farms
surveyed by SJFI in the different sectors. The last two rows under each sector heading show
the estimated and actual yields of established organic farms (1996) relative to actual yield
on conventional farms (1995). That is, the row indicating the estimated relative yields is the
figure used in this report. The actual figure (although considered not appropriate for the
purposes of this report, see Section 4.2.4) is included for reference only. For the grains on
crop farms, the figures for estimated and actual yields on established organic farms are
fairly similar, with estimates used in this report lower than those obtained in the survey. The
large disparities are, however, in those crops which are grown least. The yield of organically grown fodder peas, a low-value crop, is estimated to be relatively high in this study, and
potatoes, a high-value crop, low. The comparison on the pig farm shows more mixed results. The survey data for spring grains (mainly barley) and winter rye are lower, and for
winter barley and wheat higher, than those estimated in this study.
- 58 -
Some production data in dairy are shown in Table 5.7 for Southern and Western Jutland.
The combination of 12 per cent less cows per hectare and 6 per cent less milk per cow leads
to a 17 per cent reduction in milk per hectare.
TABLE 5.7. Productivity and prices on dairy farms
Conventional*
Organic
Org/conventional
Year
Area
Total
Cows
Total
Cows/
ha
Milk/
cow
Milk/
ha
Price/
litre
1995
1996
- ha 60
77
- no. 47
53
- no. 0.79
0.69
litres
6675
6258
litres
5253
4348
DKr.
2.33
3.05
-------------------------------- % ---------------------------------128
113
88
94
83
131
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
Note: Figures are not adjusted for breed
* = Southern and Western Jutland.
The yield reduction of 17 per cent per hectare seen in Southern and Western Jutland also
holds for Northern Jutland. However, the approach adopted in this study of allocating the
same yield figures on dairy farms for all regions means that in the Eastern Islands the relative yield only reaches 63 per cent on organic farms, and in Funen and Eastern Jutland 73
per cent.
With respect to relative yields two further issues bear mentioning:
relative yields on organic and conventional farms can differ greatly between years, as
outside factors (such as the weather) influence the different systems in different ways.
in this study yields are assumed not to increase with the rate of adoption of organic
management. In reality, one could imagine that, as organic agriculture becomes more
widespread, technologies would evolve to improve productivity and reduce the yield
difference somewhat.
5.5. Output
The combination of land use and yields, described above, determines production. The total
crop production in Denmark on full-time farms in 1995 is shown in Table 5.8.
TABEL 5.8. Total crop production on full-time conventional farms (1995)
Grains Barley Wheat
Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rape- Fodder Grass Grass Silage Silage Underspring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets Grass Seed
beet rotation perm. maize cereal sown
Eastern Islands
Funen and Eastern Jutland
Southern and Western Jutland
Northern Jutland
TOTAL
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
Note:
1 feed unit = equivalent to 1 kg barley
--------------------------------------- ‘000 tonnes ------------------------------------- ----------------- Million feed units -------------------369
124 1127
26
19
50 1881
23
49
26
40
25
32
37
5
412
241 1026
79
40
104
458
23
56
114
181
82
62
92
21
794
155
547
103
74
730
61
11
47
295
568
179
90
300
66
499
124
572
65
94
274
0
10
35
198
376
178
30
210
45
2074
645
3273
273
227
1158
2400
66
187
634
1166
464
214
639
137
- 59 -
- 60 -
By quantity, the production of wheat is the more important of the grains, although the winter and spring barley together reach over 80 per cent of the wheat production. Potatoes tend
to be grown more on the lighter soils, and sugar beets on the heavier soil. The production of
fodder crops and dairy (not shown in the table) happens predominantly on the lighter soils,
that is, in Jutland. Pig production is more evenly spread over the different regions.
Total national production for cash crops is shown in Figure 5.3.
FIGURE 5.3: National production by crop, 1995
3500
3000
mmt
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
Rape
seed
Grass
seed
Sugar
beets
Potato
Peas
Rye
Winter
wheat
Winter
barley
Spring
grain
0
Enterprise
5.6. Output prices
Average national output prices for cash crops on conventional and organic farms at the current level of adoption of organic management are shown for 1995 in Table 5.9. In addition,
the 1996 prices for Southern and Western Jutland are shown, as they serve as comparison
with the prices for organic produce to arrive at percentage premiums.
The organic premiums vary by crop. Prices obtained via the 1996-97 survey (some of which
are almost double the price of conventional products) are likely to reflect the difference in
quality of product, although the scarcity of the product may also play a role. Organic rye
and winter wheat, in particular, command considerably higher premiums than barley. This
could be because organic farmers tend to grow relatively much barley for feed, or because
- 61 -
the other crops (wheat) are grown less in the rotation, or are used in organic products in
high demand (rye bread). The organic premiums for crops are shown in Figure 5.4.
TABLE 5.9. Average national output prices at baseline and as percentage of baseline (1995 and 1996)
Grains Barley Wheat
Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rapespring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass seed
Conventional
Conventional
Organic
1995
1996
1996
----------------------------------- DKr. per tonne -----------------------------------1056 1003
990
861
940
870
323 4513 1343
989
974
948
868 1088 1141
319 4237 1589
1765 1771 1859 1696 1796 1608
2383
Org./Conv.
1996
---------------------------------- percentages ------------------------------------178
182
196
195
165
141
150
Source: SJFI surveys and own calculations.
Note: Conventional prices for 1996 are taken from dairy sector in Southern and Western Jutland.
FIGURE 5.4: Organic price premiums for selected crops
120
100
Per cent
80
60
40
20
Peas
Rye
Winter
wheat
Winter
baley
Spring
grain
0
Premiums in 1996 were highest for grains, with close to a 100 per cent premium for wheat.
The lowest premium was recorded for rapeseed at 4 per cent, which is likely to be due to
the fact that there is no demand for organic rapeseed at present. However, it is assumed that,
if more farmers were to adopt organic management, an increased supply would create demand. For this reason it was decided to impute a premium of 50 per cent for this product, a
value which seemed more realistic.
- 62 -
Prices vary by region (see Appendix Table A.4.). The main reasons for the regional differences are that farmers do not sell all produce at the same time of the year. Prices rise
throughout the season to reflect the cost of storage, a reason why the EU raises intervention
prices over the season. The differences between the regions are maintained in absolute values in the model. This is because it is assumed that the reasons for price differentials between regions do not alter with a change in product prices.
Quality differences may also be a factor in price differences between regions. For barley,
differences in proportion of production of malting and feed varieties exist between regions,
and these are expressed in the average price. The same is valid for regional variations in
consumption of factory potatoes. A high percentage of potatoes grown on conventional
farms in Southern and Western Jutland are sold to factories, while those on organic farms
are, at least at present, mainly sold as potatoes for consumption. It is for this reason that the
premium for organic potatoes has been calculated on the basis of national consumption potato prices (SJFI 1997).
For dairy products, the SJFI survey shows a difference in national output prices of over 30
per cent in 1996-97 (see Table 5.7). This higher average is partly due to the fact that previous contracts, some of which are still valid, allocated a considerably higher premium than is
generally the case at the time of writing. Pigs were assumed to receive a 70 per cent premium.
5.7. Returns to farming
Financial returns per farm at the national level for the different sectors are shown in Table
5.10. More details about returns in the different regions are shown in Appendix Table A.5.
These are net returns and take account not only of inputs, outputs and prices, but also subsidies (not discussed as yet). Costs include depreciation and a return to labour (see Table 5.3),
but not tax on income. A zero or negative return does not mean that the farmer is not making a living, but merely that there is no return on capital. There is no account here of appreciation of land values.
There are large differences in returns per farm both between the sectors and regionally. In
general, 1995 was a better year for pig than for crop farmers, while the profitability on dairy
farms was considerably lower in all regions. Whereas on the Eastern Islands farming was
rather profitable for all farm sectors in 1995, in the two regions in Jutland this was not the
- 63 -
case, with a negative margin for dairy farmers in those regions. As the majority of dairy
farmers live in those two regions, the national average net financial return in this sector was
also negative in 1995.
TABLE 5.10. Financial net returns on full time farms at the baseline
------- Per farm ----Conv.
Org.
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
ALL SECTORS
----- DKr. ‘000 ----197
212
-8
61
284
290
120
159
--------- Total ------Conv.
Org.*
Total
------------- DKr. Million -----------1,113
0
1,113
-116
0
-116
2,483
0
2,483
3,480
0
3,480
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
*: Simulated values, as baseline is assumed to be zero per cent organic management
Table 5.10 also contains the results of organic management in the three sectors, and Appendix Table A.5 in the four regions. It is clear that, at the 1995 levels of input and output
prices and technical knowledge, organic crop and dairy farming can be more profitable than
conventional farming, while pig production shows a more varied picture. Summing across
all sectors, national per farm returns to organic agriculture are considerably higher than
those to conventional farming (DKr.159,000 per farm as opposed to DKr.120,000). However, a number of conditions are likely to change if many farmers become organic managers, and aggregated returns to organic agriculture as calculated here are not realistic. The
changes in conditions and the effect on the returns are the subject of the next Section. Returns in the different sectors and regions are shown in Figure 5.5.
The regional differences in per farm income in the crop and pig sectors are due to a combination of factors. Analysis of the organic pig sector reveals that differences in feed used on
conventional farms is an important contributor to the discrepancies. But also differences on
the conventional farms in stocking rate, with a difference in need for concentrates and
therefore costs due to premiums paid for organic feed, the ratio of sow – baconers and differences in yields and output contribute.
As organic management seems to be more and more contemplated by dairy farmers, it may
not be surprising to see the returns on organic dairy farms to be higher than on the conven-
- 64 -
FIGURE 5.5: Returns on conventional and organic full-time farms at baseline
300
200
Conv.
100
NJ Pigs
SWJ Pigs
FEJ Pigs
EI Pigs
NJ Dairy
Dairy
Dairy
SWJ Dairy
FEJ Dairy
Crop
EI Dairy
NJ Crop
Crop
-100
SWJ Crop
0
FEJ Crop
Org.
EI Crop
Dkr '000 per farm
400
Sector
tional farms. However, to see that same picture for crop and some pig farms is less expected, although other SJFI work referred to earlier (Poulsen and Folkmann, forthcoming)
also shows that, under present conditions of farming, all three organic sectors can be profitable. It may mean that, with high premiums for crops and not for dairy products, the risk
for crop farmers to take on this new management system is higher. When a large component
of the cost is in investments, as in pig farming, a change in management system could well
be a risk considered not worth taking, especially when the returns are high anyway. It may
also mean that the assumptions in this report are further from reality than is expected.
Total returns for the country as a whole are also shown in Table 5.10, with some details in
the different regions in Appendix Table A.5. In total, Denmark received DKr.3.5 billion
from the full-time agricultural sector net of costs as indicated in Section 5.2. Most of this
came from the pig sector, with Funen and Eastern Jutland the region with the highest contribution.
In the light of the earlier discussion on the economic rationale for organic agriculture, with
externalities and consumer preferences, it is of interest to discuss the make-up of the returns
to farming. In Table 5.11 the gross returns to farming are shown on the national level, both
for conventional and organic farms, and decomposed into conventional output prices, sub
TABLE 5.11. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at baseline
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
-------- DKr. ‘000 per farm -------927
236
1164
1358
103
1461
2166
168
2334
--------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ----------------------- -- Pct. --472
275
190
79
1016
27
936
259
96
45
1336
19
1229
823
129
50
2231
37
ALL SECTORS
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
1517
149
1666
-- Pct. -20
7
7
9
934
432
124
53
1543
26
Organic/
conv.
Subsidy
Total
-- Pct. -27
11
8
--Pct.-114
137
106
11
119
- 65 -
- 66 -
sidies and organic premiums. A regional disaggregation can be found in Appendix Table
A.6. When most producers are farming conventionally, the subsidies for conventional
farming can be substantial. Indeed, across all sectors per farm subsidies (Dkr.149,000) exceed net returns (Table 5.10), implying that these farmers and tax payers would have been
better off in this year had they not been required to produce before collecting the subsidy.
Crop farmers topped the list with Dkr.236,000 per farm. Subsidies for dairy farmers also
exceeded net returns. Apart from being relatively small in farm size, dairy farmers generally
have a lower percentage of area in crops for which subsidies are available, at least compared with crop farms, hence their relatively low total subsidies. In the pig sector net returns
in 1995 exceeded subsidies. However, per farm subsidies at Dkr.168,000 are higher per
hectare than on crop farms. The low percentage of subsidies on pig farms relative to crop
farms is due to the fact that their gross returns (but also input costs) are relatively high.
Organic farmers, likewise, receive considerable subsidies, also exceeding net returns per
farm in the crop and dairy sectors, but not in the pig sector. Also here it is the crop sector
which receives the highest payments per farm. As can be seen in the last column in Table
5.11, total subsidies received by organic farms are on average 37 per cent higher on dairy
farms, 14 per cent on crop farms and 6 per cent on pig farms than those on conventional
farms. It is noteworthy that, while organic producers receive an additional subsidy because
they practise organic management, they claim far less of the compensatory payments (EU
subsidies) that flow to conventional farmers. This is because they have less crop and more
pasture in their rotation. Regionally, the highest and lowest relative subsidies can be found
in Southern and Western Jutland for dairy and pig farming, respectively. The high relative
figure in the dairy sector indicates that conventional dairy farmers also have a rotation
which does not allow high subsidy payments relative to the other sectors.
Organic farmers receive premiums, which are considerably higher than the total subsidies.
In all cases the premiums exceed the net returns (Table 5.10), illustrating their importance.
In the absence of premiums many farmers would experience negative net returns.
In conventional farming there is a correlation between returns to farming and age of the
farmer. The average age of the organic dairy farmers was 44, and that of the conventional
dairy farmers 48. The difference in returns per farm between these two age groups on conventional farms was DKr.33,000 in 1996 and similar (DKr.32,800) in 1995. As the
younger group of farmers manage larger farms, and the comparison between organic and
conventional farms in this study is based on farms of equal size, the difference needs to be
adjusted for farm size, which yields approximately Dkr.2,000 per year, or DKr.8,000 per 4
- 67 -
years age difference in 1996. Comparative figures for 1995 are DKr.2,500 or DKr.10,000
per 4 years of age difference. However, a more important issue is that it is not clear to what
the difference in returns is due, which implies that attributing the difference in returns to
age per se can be spurious. For example, if the increase in returns is due to the younger age
group being more up to date with spraying techniques and knowledge of synthetic pesticides, then a difference in farm returns is not due to age itself, but age is a proxy for education, technology or capital. In this particular case such a difference can’t be expected within
the organic farm population. There may be many other reasons why differences in age
groups exist, and as long as these are not clearly understood, care should be taken with attributing the farm returns to age per se.
Returns to farming are often expressed as returns to capital. Although not included in this
study, it is worth pointing out that this variable would show organic agriculture in a more
positive light. The reason is that on organic farms in general capital invested per hectare is
often lower than on conventional farms. For example, stocking density is lower on organic
farms, and investments in buildings (for example in the pig industry) can also be considerably lower.
- 68 -
- 69 -
6. Moving towards organic agriculture
In the baseline version of the model described in the previous section there are essentially
two distinct production systems, conventional and organic, each with their different rotations, yields and cost structures. Most of the farmers can be characterised by the conventional methods, and a small number by the alternative approach. Sectoral, regional and national aggregates are obtained by multiplying the costs, production, gross margins, etc. by
the number of farms using the particular method. To simulate the effects of an agricultural
sector where organic farming methods are widely adopted, in this section different proportions of farms are assumed to follow organic methods. These proportions, 10, 20, etc. to 80
per cent, are the same in each sector and in each region. At each step, production of each
crop is aggregated at the national level and a new set of market clearing prices and output
levels found.
There is no attempt to model the conversion process from the status quo to predominantly
organic. For each level of adoption, say 20 or 40 per cent, it is assumed that an equilibrium
has been reached. There is no time dimension in the conversion process, and therefore there
is no linking of periods in the model. Although variables such as output or gross revenues
can be graphed so that a smooth transition appears to occur it should not be assumed that, to
achieve the results shown at 80 per cent rate of adoption, the economy would necessarily
progress through the previous levels as depicted. In addition, in reality the widespread
adoption of organic methods would take several, if not many, years during which time
changes in population, tastes and preferences, production technology and other factors
would occur. Such factors would influence the model results, but for simplicity are ignored
here.
It should be noted at this point that the results are likely to be more reliable at the lower
rates of adoption. Certain assumption, such as the absence of economies of scale, are less
likely to be valid at greater rates of adoption, when larger throughput or demand for inputs
would bring forth new technologies and new capital. As a result of these deficiencies, the
endpoint for adoption in this study is chosen as 80 per cent. Simulations of this rate of
adoption are reported first.
6.1. Inputs
The input costs of the different sectors at the national level at 80 per cent adoption of organic agriculture are shown in Table 6.1, together with the percentage differences in costs
- 70 -
from the baseline. Figure 6.1 shows the input cost per sector graphically. Data for the four
regions can be found in Appendix Table B.1.
TABLE 6.1. Average input costs at 80 per cent of organic management, by sector
Org.
Conv.
Org./conv.
------- DKr. ‘000 per farm -----VARIABLE COSTS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
FIXED COSTS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
TOTAL
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Org.
Conv.
Org./conv.
---- percentage of baseline ----
404
743
1143
528
978
1558
76
76
73
89
91
83
102
103
108
87
88
77
351
398
459
453
522
606
77
76
76
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
755
1141
1601
981
1500
2164
77
76
74
94
94
87
101
102
106
92
92
82
Source: Derived from SJFI data and own calculations.
It is clear, both at the national and regional level, that the changes in relative costs occur
mainly in the variable costs. Fixed costs are unchanged because farm size is unaffected.
Expenditure on variable inputs is influenced by factors such as the area planted in different
crops (each with different input costs per hectare) and costs of feed for livestock. The
change in output mix from fodder peas to rapeseed (see Section 6.2) leads to a slight increase in variable costs for crop and dairy producers. The largest changes, both in the organic and conventional system, are in the pig sector. This is explained by the importance of
feed in the cost structure of this sector, where animal feed is by far the most important input. With rising conventional prices (see Section 6.4), both conventional and organic pig
farmers increase their variable cost. For organic farmers, this effect of a small increase in
conventional grain prices is outweighed by the drop in organic premium. Livestock producers now pay lower prices for their feed so that their variable input costs decrease substantially with an increasing number of farmers adopting organic practices.
- 71 -
FIGURE 6.1: Average input costs by sector at 80 per cent organic management
2500
Dkr '000 per farm
2000
1500
Fixed
Variable
1000
500
0
Org
Conv
Org
Conv
Org
Conv
crop
crop
dairy
dairy
pig
pig
In order to illustrate the detailed changes in input costs, Table 6.2 shows details for the
dairy sector nationally. Apart from a decrease in feed costs (concentrates), also the cost of
seed is affected by the decrease in organic premiums at this level of adoption of organic
management. The relative use of pesticides and fertilisers stays the same as compared with
the baseline, as it is at a very low level.
On average, the variable costs on organic farms decrease to 88 per cent, and the total to 92
per cent of the relative level measured at the baseline.
6.2. Rotations and total land use
Land use on conventional farms when 80 per cent of farmers are organic, and total land use
combining areas under the different enterprises on conventional and organic farms, are
shown in Table 6.3. Regional details can be seen in Appendix Table B.2.
A comparison with Table 5.4 (also shown as percentage change in Table 6.3) shows that a
change in national emphasis on management practice, with changes in output prices, makes
- 72 -
TABLE 6.2. Average input costs on dairy farms at 80 per cent of organic management
Org.
Conv.
Org./conv.
Org.
Conv.
Org./conv.
------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ------ ---------- percentage of baseline--------VARIABLE COSTS
Seed
Fertiliser
Manure
Pesticides
Energy
Co2-tax
Labour: hired
Maintenance: machinery
Contract operations
Other: plant production
Concentrates
Roughage
Vet. Costs
Insemination
Other costs: livestock
Total
24
1
40
0
25
3
127
63
83
8
165
184
19
9
26
777
22
33
38
18
21
2
100
59
61
7
285
258
27
12
35
978
111
3
108
0
116
109
128
106
135
106
58
71
72
72
76
79
88
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
77
86
100
100
100
91
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
113
100
100
100
100
103
88
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
69
86
100
100
100
88
FIXED COSTS
Depreciation
Labour: family
Other
Total
125
222
68
416
128
327
67
522
98
68
101
80
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
1193
1500
79
94
102
92
TOTAL
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
little difference to rotations on conventional farms. The largest shift, percentage-wise, is in
fodder peas, the area of which decreases by 7 per cent as compared with the baseline.
There are several reasons for the lack of change. First, the changes in production have little
impact on prices received by farmers (see Section 6.5), reflecting the high price elasticities
of demand in the model. These price changes in turn affect production only marginally.
Together with the fact that prices of substitutes, such as of the main grains, change in the
same direction (increase) and magnitude, this provides farmers with little incentive to
change the percentage of a particular crop in the rotation. Third, in this version of the model
unused milk and sugar beet quotas are not reallocated and expansions of farm area of existing dairy farmers are not permitted. Hence the area under crops grown on conventional
farms is 20 per cent of the total when 80 per cent of farmers are organic managers.
TABLE 6.3. Crop rotations on full-time conventional farms and total land use for different sectors at 80 per cent of organic management
Grains Barley Wheat
Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rapespring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass seed
Setaside
Non- Fodder Grass Grass Silage Silage
food
beet rotation perm. maize cereal
Total
----------------------------------------------------------- percentages of total hectares per farm ------------------------------------------------------ha-CROP ROTATIONS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
19
20
21
20
4
3
10
5
32
9
32
21
4
2
3
2
3
2
4
3
4
1
2
2
6
1
2
2
6
0
3
2
7
1
8
4
11
7
9
8
2
0
3
1
0
6
0
3
1
20
1
11
2
12
3
7
0
3
0
2
0
13
0
6
104
56
65
68
------------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage of baseline-----------------------------------------------------------------------98
99
103
96
93
100
100
101
103
96
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
98
99
103
96
93
100
100
101
103
105
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
99
99
103
96
93
100
100
101
103
97
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
98
99
103
96
93
100
100
101
103
99
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
------------------------------------------------------------------------- ‘000 hectares ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------
TOTAL LAND USE
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
159
107
164
430
14
9
22
46
68
32
70
170
32
19
33
84
26
11
21
58
27
12
24
64
7
2
2
11
7
0
3
10
47
16
38
101
66
47
53
167
2
1
3
6
0
12
1
13
118
238
114
471
11
106
15
132
0
15
0
15
2
188
2
191
588
815
566
1969
------------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage of baseline ----------------------------------------------------------------------139
54
37
140
123
117
20
20
124
102
20
100 3317
100
100
100
100
65
46
46
134
61
140
20
20
170
85
20
24
143
112
55
182
100
135
37
39
206
90
262
20
20
90
103
20
100 2529
100
100
100
100
113
46
41
160
92
173
20
20
128
97
20
75 1996
104
85
127
100
Source: Derived from SJFI data and own calculations.
- 73 -
- 74 -
At the average farm level there are substitutions from rye and fodder peas to winter wheat
and rapeseed. Set-aside area stays similar on average, although it increases somewhat in the
dairy sector, and decreases in the crop and pig sectors. Although the changes are marginal,
they give an indication of the direction to be expected. Changes in rotations on the organic
farms occur in a similar fashion to those on conventional farms.
Despite the small changes in rotation on conventional farms when 80 per cent of farmers
practise organic management, Table 6.3 shows a considerable change in total land use in
such a situation. Not surprisingly, the shift is especially towards forage crops, such as pastures and, to a less degree, cereal for silage. Area in spring grains (mainly barley), rye, potatoes, and rapeseed would increase. The winter grains would be grown on less than half of
the area used for those crops in 1995.
6.3. Yields and output
To simplify the analysis, yields on both the conventional and organic farms are assumed not
to change with a changing pattern of farm management. This is probably not realistic for
several reasons. First, improvements in technology make it likely that yields will increase
both in conventional and organic agriculture in the future. In addition, more experience in
organic farming methods would make such improvement especially likely under organic
management, at least in the near future. Third, changes in demand for a particular input, for
example manure, will change the input price of that input. This will affect the use of that
input and demand for other inputs, for example for composted kitchen waste and sewage.
Those new developments will affect yields. Nonetheless, the effects on output of a substantial shift to organic agriculture are calculated under present assumptions, and are shown in
Table 6.4.
Of the grains, only spring barley and fodder peas are produced at approximately the baseline level (89 and 94 per cent of previous levels, respectively). The production of rye, a minor grain, is increased by almost 40 per cent. The production of winter wheat, the single
most important grain grown in Denmark in 1995, will decrease to about one third of its
volume with a change to organic management on 80 per cent of farms.
On the other hand, more feed is produced on organic farms. Total feed units produced increases by 20 per cent as compared with the baseline. The production of grass grown as part
of the rotation almost doubles, to some extent replacing permanent grass and fodder beets.
The production of cereal silage increases by over 50 per cent. Together with the silage
TABLE 6.4. Total crop production on full-time farms with 80 per cent of farms under organic management
Grains
spring
Barley
winter
Wheat
winter
Rye
winter
Peas
fodder
Potato
Sugar
beets
Seeds
grass
Rape- Fodder Grass
seed
beet rotation
Grass
perm.
Silage
maize
Silage Undercereal
sown
Eastern Islands
Funen and Eastern Jutland
Southern and Western Jutland
Northern Jutland
TOTAL
--------------------------------------------- ‘000 tonnes ----------------------------------------- ---------------------- Million feed units ---------------------437
51
308
86
49
144
381
5
33
7
303
28
11
64
9
447
79
292
98
51
193
93
5
32
29
476
75
22
171
26
554
63
198
107
59
364
12
2
28
71
777
160
40
419
64
403
50
183
86
54
233
2
22
49
586
144
24
322
49
1,841
243
981
376
213
933
486
13
116
157 2,142
407
98
975
148
Eastern Islands
Funen and Eastern Jutland
Southern and Western Jutland
Northern Jutland
TOTAL
----------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage of baseline ---------------------------------------------------------------------118
41
27
325
257
290
20
20
68
28
753
114
35
172
178
109
33
28
125
128
185
20
20
57
26
263
91
35
186
125
70
41
36
104
80
50
20
20
60
24
137
89
45
140
97
81
40
32
132
57
85
20
63
25
156
81
79
153
107
89
38
30
138
94
81
20
20
62
25
184
88
45
153
107
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
Note:
1 feed unit = equivalent to 1 kg barley
- 75 -
- 76 -
maize, this adds up to an increase of 26 per cent in feed units (one feed unit is equivalent to
1 kg of barley). Although livestock intensity is reduced in organic farming, organic farmers
tend to feed their livestock more fodder (for example, to pigs). Surplus is supposed to be
exported.
Pig production changes with the same percentage in each region. This is because the stocking rate on crop and pig farms is taken as a percentage of that on the conventional average
farm. Thus, the total production at 80 per cent organic management is 20 per cent (the conventional production) plus 59 per cent (relative stocking rate on crop and pig farms) of 80
per cent (organic production), which is 67 per cent. In the case of milk production the approach, and result, is different. Survey-based data of national organic milk production per
hectare are used in each region, that is, yield per hectare on organic dairy farms is assumed
to be the same in each region. As the production on conventional dairy farms differs between the regions, so does the relative milk production on organic and conventional farms.
A high milk yield on the conventional dairy farm on the Eastern Islands as compared with
Jutland, for example, means that the percentage of milk yield on organic farms in that region is low as compared with Jutland. When 80 per cent of farmers farm organically, the
total milk production on the Eastern Island is 70 per cent as compared with the baseline.
The use of this method of analysis results in an overall reduction of national production of
milk by 17 per cent when 80 per cent of farmers are using organic production methods, instead of the 14 per cent observed in Southern and Western Jutland.
Relative crop production data are shown in Figure 6.2, which illustrates substantial decreases in sugar beet and grass for seed. The assumption that organic farmers do not grow
these crops means that, at an adoption rate of organic agriculture of 80 per cent, production
is only at 20 per cent of previous levels. Sugar beet is grown under quota, which has not
been reallocated from organic to the remaining conventional farmers.
6.4. Output prices
Output prices change for two reasons in particular. One is the change in production affecting the price on the conventional market. Conventional product prices at 80 per cent acceptance of organic methods are shown in Table 6.5, in which also is shown the percentage
change of these prices relative to the baseline. For the grains in the conventional market,
changes of up to 13 per cent are recorded. Other crops, such as sugar beets and grass for
seed, show larger changes, reflecting the absence of these crops in organic rotations.
- 77 -
FIGURE 6.2: National production relative to baseline at 80 per cent rate of adoption of organic management
100
Rape
seed
Grass
seed
beets
Sugar
Potato
Peas
Rye
Winter
wheat
-
Winter
barley
50
Spring
grain
Per cent
150
Sector
The other reason for a change in output prices, at least on organic farms, is the change in
organic premium. As mentioned, the premium is assumed to decrease with an increasing
number of farmers moving to organic management. With an increase from a negligible
number of organic farmers to an increase to 80 per cent, the prices of organic products decrease considerably, for some crops (especially grains) to less than two thirds of the baseline. The least affected are those with the lowest premium at the baseline, such as potatoes
and rapeseed.
It should be noted that subsidies, both for conventional and organic agriculture, are assumed
not to change in this scenario. The sensitivity of the results to a change in subsidy levels, as
in conventional output prices and organic premiums, is tested in Section 7.1.
TABLE 6.5. Average national output prices at 80 per cent of organic management
Grains Barley Wheat
Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rapespring winter winter winter fodder Potato beets grass seed
Conventional
Organic
Conventional
Organic
Source: SJFI survey and own calculations.
1995
1996
--------------------------------- DKr. per tonne ------------------------------------1069 1106 1114
834
946
882
372 5138 1406
1144 1133 1130 1034 1230 1234
1748
-------------------------------- percentage of baseline ------------------------101
110
113
97
101
101
115
114
105
65
64
61
61
68
77
73
- 78 -
6.5. Returns to farming
6.5.1. Returns at 80 per cent rate of adoption
At 80 per cent of farms under organic management, net private returns to farming have
changed considerably, as shown in Table 6.6 to be compared with Table 5.10. Regional details are shown in Appendix Table B.3 and can be compared with data in Appendix Table
A.5. Returns to conventional crop and pig farmers increase somewhat as compared with the
baseline, mainly because of the slight increase in output prices. Whereas in the baseline organic farmers receive higher incomes than their conventionally farming counterparts, at 80
per cent of adoption this is no longer the case. Indeed, average incomes on organic dairy
farms are negative in all regions, and in Northern Jutland all sectors record losses. Northern
Jutland is the only region where returns on the organic dairy farm are higher (or less negative) than on the conventional farm.
TABLE 6.6. Financial net returns per full-time farm and total returns in agriculture at 80 per
cent organic management
------- Per farm ----Conv.
Org.
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
ALL SECTORS
----- DKr. ‘000 ----255
53
-19
-52
325
-18
138
-21
--------- Total ------Conv.
Org.
Total
-------------- DKr. Million ----------289
241
530
-57
-611
-668
569
-127
442
801
-496
304
Source: Derived from SJFI data and model simulations.
At 80 per cent adoption of organic management, total net financial returns to agriculture in
Denmark are estimated at Dkr.304 million, dramatically down on the Dkr3.5 billion in the
baseline. Of this, crops now comprise the major share, although returns are less than half of
the baseline levels. The dairy sector makes a significant negative contribution. The pig sector income is decimated.
The national returns from organic agriculture are severely depressed. The organic crop sector contributes less to the total returns than the conventional sector, even though it has 4
times the number of farms. Both the organic dairy and pig sectors contribute negatively to
the total at that level. Overall, total returns to organic farmers are negative. On a regional
- 79 -
basis (Appendix Table B.3), total returns to organic agriculture across the three sectors are
negative in both regions in Jutland.
Gross returns to farming is composed of payments for the products, subsidies for the area
under certain crops (both conventional and organic) and product premiums. At the 80 per
cent level of organic management, the composition of gross returns is rather different from
the baseline (see Table 6.7 as compared with Table 5.11).
In Table 6.7 and Appendix Table B.4 the first column under each management heading indicates the contribution to farm returns by the product sales excluding subsidies and, for
organic producers, premiums. On organic farms, the premium decreases to 20 per cent of its
original level. Subsidies are based on area planted rather than on production, and therefore
are not reduced with declining production, although changes in the rotation may change the
overall level of subsidies received. However, neither for the conventional, nor for the organic average farm did this change the subsidies. As the total returns decrease considerably
on the average organic farm with an increasing number of farms under organic management
(due to a decrease in premium) the subsidies become a larger part of the total returns. With
conventional farming there is almost no change in this percentage, as the total returns increase only marginally.
6.5.2. Returns at varying rates of adoption
It is unlikely that farmers in all sectors and regions would convert to organic methods at
similar rates, particularly if negative returns started to appear. It is therefore of interest to
identify when the point of negative return may be reached. Table 6.8 and Figure 6.3 show
the returns to farming for the different sectors, and the total, at different levels of adoption
of organic management. At the 10 per cent rate of adoption, national returns (Dkr.3.6 billion) are actually 3 per cent greater than at the baseline (Dkr.3.48 billion). The national returns become lower only at around 25 per cent of adoption of organic management. The
initial increase occurs as unprofitable conventional dairy farmers switch to profitable organic production. In fact, in each sector returns peak between 10 and 30 per cent, and are
similar to pre-organic management between 10 and 20 per cent for pig farming, between 20
and 30 per cent on crop farms, and between 40 and 50 per cent on dairy farms 4.
4
Simulations are based on rate of adoption in 10 percentage point increments. Finer increments are of
course possible but, given the uncertainties surrounding some of the parameters in the model, would provide spurious accuracy.
TABLE 6.7. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at 80 per cent organic management
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
-------- DKr. ‘000 per farm -------1000
236
1238
1378
103
1481
2321
168
2490
--------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ----------------------- -- Pct. --485
54
190
79
808
7
948
52
96
45
1141
5
1325
164
129
50
1668
10
ALL SECTORS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1589
1737
9
----- percentage of baseline ----108
100
106
101
100
101
107
100
107
94
99
94
ALL SECTORS
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
105
149
-- Pct. -19
7
7
100
104
96
972
14
119
------------------------ percentage of baseline----------------103
20
100
100
80
101
20
100
100
85
108
20
100
100
75
25
23
27
126
117
134
114
136
107
25
125
100
100
53
--Pct.-114
136
107
7
20
124
-- Pct. -33
12
11
1235
104
86
Org./conv.
Subsidy
Total
100
80
- 80 -
- 81 -
TABLE 6.8. Net returns per sector at different rates of adoption of organic management
Crop
Baseline
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Dairy
Pig
Total
Change
------------------ DKr. ‘000 Million ---------------1,113
-116
2,483
3,480
1,132
-39
2,505
3,598
1,125
-6
2,447
3,566
1,093
-16
2,309
3,387
1,035
-67
2,094
3,062
951
-159
1,801
2,593
839
-290
1,430
1,980
699
-459
979
1,219
530
-668
442
304
-- Pct. -100
103
102
97
88
75
57
35
9
Source: Model simulation.
FIGURE 6.3: National net returns at different rates of adoption of organic management
4000
Dkr million
3000
Total
2000
Crop
1000
Dairy
0
-1000
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Pigs
-2000
Rate of adoption
It should be noted that the age structure of farmers is assumed to be the same as in the baseline, that is, organic producers are somewhat younger than conventional producers at all
levels of conversion. In reality, such age differences would level out over time. Therefore,
in as far as a difference in farm returns is attributable to age per se (see Section 5.7), the
figures tend to underestimate the fall in total income.
The main conclusions from this section are that the widespread adoption of organic practices at the current state of technology would involve substantial losses. However, a lesser rate
- 82 -
of adoption would involve fewer losses, and gains in the early stages of conversion. In the
crop sector, gains would be made to over 20 per cent conversion, and in the dairy sector to
over 40 per cent. In the pig sector the equivalent stage would be just over 10 per cent.
- 83 -
7. Sensitivity analysis and limitations
7.1. Sensitivity analysis
DOAP is reasonably detailed and its level of disaggregation provides some assurance as to
the robustness of the results. Nonetheless, it is dependent on several assumptions or observations based on limited data. As more data, on yields or prices for example, become available, model results may change. It is useful at this point to assess the sensitivity of the results to changes in the key assumptions. This will provide an indication of the validity of
the model and its usefulness as a policy decision tool. In addition, DOAP can also be used
to assess the effects of changes in certain policies, such as the use of taxes or subsidies. The
results of a change in parameters or policies on net returns on organic farms in the standard
are shown in Table 7.1. Impacts on gross returns and the comparative position of subsidies
in the standard can be seen in Table 7.2, and the effect on sectoral returns at various rates of
adoption of organic methods is shown in general in Table 7.3. These tables are comparable
to Table 5.10, Table 5.11 and Table 6.8 which, for ease of comparison, are summarised at
the start of the tables in this section. After the analysis, the limitations of the work are discussed.
Yields
In general, yields are a crucial determinant of overall profitability of farming. Differences
between organic and conventional yields in the crop and pig sector are calculated as a percentage of the relative yields in the dairy sector (see Section 4.2.4). The data available in
the dairy industry have been taken from two different years (1995 for the conventional data
and 1996 for organic). This is not ideal. A second issue is relative yields between organic
and conventional production, which are not static, but may change depending on the production circumstances in a particular growing season. For example, yields on conventional
farms may be relatively high in wet years, as herbicides and fungicides can limit the damage done by increased weed and disease pressures. Thus, apart from the problem of using
yields in two different years (see Section 5.4), there is the difficulty of changing relativities
between the two systems in different years. In other words, in order to have a good picture
of the relative yields obtained under different conditions, comparison need to be made in a
number of years. Analysis of data to be gathered in the future, or even when 1996 data are
available for the dairy sector, is likely to result in changes in relative yields from those used
in this study. For these reasons, a sensitivity analysis is warranted, and includes a decrease
or increase in organic crop yields of 10 percent of the yields in the standard simulation. This
means that, where organic yields are 80 per cent of conventional in the standard scenario,
- 84 -
they are altered to 72 per cent and 88 per cent for this analysis. Livestock yields are unchanged.
A difference in crop yields of 10 per cent is worth approximately DKr.60,000 per farm on
average for all sectors over the whole of Denmark (see Table 7.1), but varies between sectors and areas (not shown in the tables). As yields of livestock have not been changed, those
farms which are most dependent on crops have the biggest change in returns. For example,
in crops on the Eastern Islands, the difference is on average over DKr.130,000 per farm; in
the pig sector the difference is around DKr.80,000; whereas the dairy sector varies least
with changes of around DKr.30,000 per farm. As yields of livestock have not been changed,
those farms which are most dependent on crops have the biggest change in returns. In terms
of subsidy levels, the change in returns on organic farms means subsidies, which stay the
same, become (marginally) higher, or lower, percentage of the total returns (Table 7.2),
though the relative subsidies to the different systems stay the same. The effect on returns to
the industry as compared with the baseline is shown in Table 7.3. It shows that the total net
returns are slightly below 100 per cent at the 10 per cent level of adoption, and are at 84 per
cent at 30 per cent of adoption. If yields were to be 10 per cent higher, the returns would be
higher for the whole industry up until about the 50 per cent level of adoption of organic
management.
TABLE 7.1. Financial net returns per full-time farm at baseline in three sectors under different scenarios
Scenario
Standard
Low crop yields
High crop yields
Rotation
Organic feed
Low grain prices
Low premiums
No organic subsidies
Low elasticity
Source: Model simulations.
----- Crop ----Conv.
Org.
------ Dairy ---Conv.
Org.
------ Pig -----Conv.
Org.
-------------------------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm
197
212
-8
61
284
197
98
-8
31
284
197
338
-8
92
284
197
262
-8
61
284
197
201
-8
40
284
111
150
31
96
440
197
212
-8
61
284
197
133
-8
17
284
197
212
-8
61
284
--- Average --Conv.
Org.
-------------------------------290
120
159
211
120
98
376
120
226
318
120
178
184
120
114
487
169
224
290
120
159
240
120
107
290
120
159
TABLE 7.2. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at baseline with different scenarios
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
-------- DKr. ‘000 per farm --------
--------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ----------------------- -- Pct. ---
-- Pct. --
Org./conv.
Subsidy
Total
-- Pct. --
STANDARD
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
472
936
1229
934
275
259
823
432
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
1016
1336
2231
1543
27
19
37
26
27
11
8
11
114
137
106
119
LOW CROP YIELDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
399
910
1179
892
234
254
795
413
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
902
1305
2153
1481
26
19
37
26
30
11
8
12
114
137
106
119
HIGH CROP YIELDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
553
962
1285
979
321
264
854
452
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
1143
1366
2318
1609
28
19
37
26
24
10
8
11
114
137
106
119
ROTATION
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
473
936
1234
936
298
259
839
441
216
96
143
133
79
45
50
53
1066
1336
2266
1563
28
19
37
26
28
11
9
12
125
137
115
125
ORGANIC FEED
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
472
936
1229
934
275
259
823
432
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
1016
1336
2231
1543
27
19
37
26
27
11
8
11
114
137
106
119
LOW GRAIN PRICES
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
819
1333
2095
1463
236
103
168
149
1056
1436
2264
1611
22
7
7
9
424
926
1196
910
236
250
795
411
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
929
1317
2170
1498
25
19
37
26
29
11
8
12
114
137
106
119
continued
TABLE 7.2. (continued)
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
-------- DKr. ‘000 per farm --------
--------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ----------------------- -- Pct. ---
-- Pct. --
Org./conv.
Subsidy
Total
-- Pct. --
LOW PREMIUMS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
472
936
1229
934
275
259
823
432
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
1016
1336
2231
1543
27
19
37
26
27
11
8
11
114
137
106
119
NO ORGANIC SUBSIDIES
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
472
936
1229
934
275
259
823
432
190
96
129
124
0
0
0
0
938
1291
2181
1490
29
20
38
27
20
7
6
8
81
93
77
84
LOW ELASTICITY
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
927
1358
2166
1517
236
103
168
149
1164
1461
2334
1666
20
7
7
9
472
936
1229
934
275
259
823
432
190
96
129
124
79
45
50
53
1016
1336
2231
1543
27
19
37
26
27
11
8
11
114
137
106
119
Source: Model simulations.
- 85 -
- 86 -
- 87 -
TABLE 7.3. National net returns at different rates of organic management with different
scenarios
Adoption rate
Crop
Pct.
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Change
--------------------- DKr. Million --------------------
-- pct. --
STANDARD
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1113
1132
1125
1093
1035
951
839
699
530
-116
-39
-6
-16
-67
-159
-290
-459
-668
2483
2505
2447
2309
2094
1801
1430
979
442
3480
3598
3566
3387
3062
2593
1980
1219
304
100
103
102
97
88
75
57
35
9
LOW CROP YIELDS
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1113
1072
1010
927
822
695
546
373
174
-116
-83
-92
-143
-234
-365
-534
-741
-986
2483
2439
2319
2124
1855
1512
1095
599
20
3480
3428
3236
2907
2442
1842
1107
232
-793
100
99
93
84
70
53
32
7
-23
HIGH CROP YIELDS
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1113
1199
1253
1277
1270
1231
1161
1058
920
-116
5
80
112
100
48
-46
-178
-349
2483
2578
2588
2514
2357
2118
1797
1393
901
3480
3781
3921
3902
3727
3397
2913
2272
1471
100
109
113
112
107
98
84
65
42
ROTATION
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1113
1158
1175
1164
1125
1058
962
836
678
-116
-39
-7
-17
-68
-159
-289
-457
-663
2483
2528
2492
2374
2177
1900
1545
1108
586
3480
3647
3659
3521
3234
2799
2217
1486
601
100
105
105
101
93
80
64
43
17
continued
TABLE 7.3. (continued)
- 88 -
Adoption rate
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
Change
Pct.
ORGANIC FEED
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
---------------------- DKr. million -------------------
-- pct. --
1113
1127
1116
1080
1020
935
824
686
519
-116
-68
-59
-87
-149
-246
-375
-535
-727
2483
2420
2293
2105
1856
1549
1184
760
271
3480
3478
3350
3098
2727
2238
1633
910
64
100
100
96
89
78
64
47
26
2
628
660
670
658
624
568
488
385
256
448
525
556
541
482
378
231
41
-192
3846
3913
3891
3780
3580
3291
2911
2437
1866
4922
5098
5117
4979
4685
4236
3630
2863
1930
100
104
104
101
95
86
74
58
39
LOW PREMIUMS
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1113
1121
1080
990
853
666
566
462
350
-116
-58
-81
-182
-357
-604
-706
-812
-924
2483
2473
2320
2031
1608
1053
733
392
19
3480
3535
3319
2840
2104
1115
594
42
-556
100
102
95
82
60
32
17
1
-16
NO ORGANIC SUBSIDIES
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1113
1088
1037
960
857
728
572
388
174
-116
-104
-137
-212
-329
-487
-683
-919
-1192
2483
2461
2359
2178
1920
1583
1168
673
93
3480
3444
3259
2926
2447
1825
1057
143
-926
100
99
94
84
70
52
30
4
-27
LOW GRAIN PRICES
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
continued
TABLE 7.3. (continued)
- 89 -
Adoption rate
Crop
Total
Change
Pct.
LOW ELASTICITY
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
---------------------- DKr. million -------------------
-- pct. --
1113
1154
1168
1154
1112
1041
939
804
632
Dairy
-116
-43
-19
-42
-110
-220
-372
-564
-796
Pigs
2483
2558
2540
2432
2233
1945
1565
1087
496
3480
3669
3689
3544
3236
2766
2132
1327
332
100
105
106
102
93
79
61
38
10
Source: Model simulations.
Rotations
Another variable related to total production is rotations. For the crop and pig farms it is assumed that 25 per cent of their arable land is under pasture in rotation. This is in addition to
their area in permanent grass and in land under set-aside arrangements, and represents quite
a large proportion of their area. For example, in Southern and Western Jutland, this assumption means that close to 40 per cent of total area is under grass or similar arrangements in
any one year (see Table 5.5). A more intensive rotation, where only 15 per cent of the area
goes into rotational grass (still leaving close to 30 per cent of the farm uncultivated) sees the
average returns per farm increase by DKr.19,000 (Figure 7.1), and the total returns for the
whole agricultural sector decrease more slowly than under the standard assumptions (Table
7.3). Compared with the standard scenario, national net returns increase longer, and decrease less sharply at the later stages of adoption of organic practices. With the change in
rotation the total premium and (EU) subsidies for organic crop and pig farmers increase as
compared with the standard (Table 7.2).
Input costs
Effects of changes in input costs due to a decrease in demand for those used in conventional
farming, and an increase for inputs in organic agriculture were not modelled here. However,
there is one input, which is likely to change in price in the not too distant future, that can
impact considerably on overall costs and therefore net returns. This is the feed costs in organic agriculture. In the near future, only 80 per cent needs to be from organic sources, but
it is likely that this will change to 100 per cent at some stage. The increase of costs for organic farmers in such a case, in this study, is that profitability per farm decreases, especially
on pig farms (Table 7.1). On a national level this means that the returns only stay around
- 90 -
the same level as the standard run for 10 per cent of farmers adopting organic management
(Table 7.3).
The political climate in Denmark at present makes increases in inputs costs, for example
through taxes on fertilisers and pesticides, on conventional farmers possible. Although the
effect of such increases could be tested in this model, it would only record the worst-case
scenario for conventional farmers, as the model does not allow for changes in management
due to changes in input prices. For example, it can be expected that, with increases of pesticide prices, farmers will adopt other practices to cope with pest problems, such as changing
their rotations. Work to incorporate such changes is carried out by SJFI at present (Oerum
forthcoming). It suffices here to say that such increases would make returns in organic agriculture higher relative to those in conventional agriculture, compared with the standard.
Grain prices
Output prices are set to change in the EU in the future. Different price levels will influence
the two management systems in different ways. A decrease in grain prices by 25 per cent,
for example, means that the total returns from farming in Denmark are higher or equal to
the baseline until after 30 per cent of adoption of organic management practices (Table 7.3).
Note that the baseline under these conditions is considerably higher than with high prices.
Nationally, the loss to crop farmers is compensated by the gain to dairy farmers (through
their savings on expenses for feed), and especially by gains to pig farmers. As by far their
highest cost is on feed, this is hardly surprising.
Organic premiums
In the standard scenario one determinant of organic output prices, organic premiums, was
assumed to decrease by one per cent with every one per cent increase in adoption of organic
management. However, premiums may erode at a different pace. For example, in a similar
study in Australia, crops were found to receive approximately 15 per cent premium at the
baseline. Because of conditions in Australia, where organic agriculture is considerably less
popular than in Denmark and a small increase in number of organic farmers could flood
the (export) market of certain crops, it was then assumed that the premium decreased by one
percentage point for every per cent of farmers changing to organic management (Wynen
1997). Thus, no premium was received when 30 per cent of farmers had converted. In the
simulation in this report, premiums are assumed to fall by two per cent for each one per cent
increase in adoption, implying that the organic premium is half of the present premium
when 25 per cent of farmers have adopted organic management, and zero when the rate of
adoption reaches 50 per cent. The results indicate that total returns to farming would still
- 91 -
increase over the first 10 per cent of adoption of organic agriculture (see Table 7.3), but fall
away rather rapidly later. At 30 per cent of adoption (and 40 per cent of the premiums received at present) the returns to farming would be 80 per cent of what they are in the standard situation. At 70 per cent of adoption returns would be negligible. The fall in returns
slows after the 50 per cent rate of adoption is reached, illustrating the zero premium at that
point. The effect on net returns for the whole industry are quite distinct from those of low
yields. With low yields, organic farmers are affected at all levels of adoption. With a rapidly
diminishing premium, returns fall more rapidly up until the 50 per cent adoption rate than
after this point.
Subsidies
Although subsidies per hectare for organic production have recently increased, there may be
a time when such subsidies are going to be reduced or abolished, especially if or when
many farmers adopt organic practices. The abolition of subsidies for organic management
per se, other things being equal, would decrease net returns per farm considerably (Table
7.1). Crop farmers suffer most, as their farms are largest. For organic farmers it means that
they would receive, on average, 16 per cent less in total subsidies (compensatory payments)
than conventional farmers, with dairy farmers closer to the conventional counterparts than
the other two sectors (Table 7.2). Nationally, it would mean that only the dairy sector would
increase its contribution (or decrease its losses) to the national returns. This would occur to
between 0 and 15 per cent of adoption (Table 7.3). The other two sectors would record a
loss before 10 per cent adoption.
Price elasticity
The price elasticities for conventional products are also open to question. Although there
are plenty of empirical estimates of the elasticity of demand, they tend to vary somewhat
and are subject to policy changes, in particular trade liberalisation, where more open trade
generally means less ability to influence prices. The recent move towards decoupled policies (where support is unrelated to current production) is also likely to date the supply elasticities used in this study. The price elasticities of demand used here (10 for most products)
tend to be rather high, resulting in a decreased impact from a given production shock (such
as caused by many farmers adopting organic management techniques). Many would claim
that open markets are not yet the reality, and lower elasticities would be more appropriate.
To assess the impact of this assumption, all demand elasticities are reduced by half, and the
model re-calibrated to generate the standard baseline prices and quantities. As production
falls with the adoption of organic methods, rising prices compensate to a greater extent than
in the standard scenario, holding up farm returns somewhat. Hence, adoption of organic
- 92 -
agriculture increases net returns to the country until over 30 per cent of adoption (see Table 7.3).
7.2. Limitations
It should be emphasised that this study is a preliminary assessment of the effect on the
primary agricultural sector of widespread adoption of organic farming. A major problem in
the analysis is the lack of data for organic farmers in some of the sectors (crop and pigs).
Organic dairy farming is practised to the extent that actual data are available, and the results
in the baseline for this sector are based on survey results. However, not enough farms are
available in this category to stratify on a regional basis, so that national data had to be used,
which may be a source of distortion. In the crop and pig sectors, however, survey data were
not available, so that a number of assumptions needed to be made, based partly on data
available on the conventional farms in their sector, and partly on relativities found between
the organic and conventional dairy farms. Questions can be raised about the validity of such
an approach, but care has been taken to detail all assumptions, so that the reader can form
an opinion about the accuracy of estimates.
In the case of manure, in particular, estimates should be treated carefully. It is questionable
whether, under widespread adoption of organic farming methods, sufficient manure can be
produced to maintain production levels, especially in the crop sector. Due to the many different sources of nutrients this is a complicated question which has not been investigated in
this analysis. Consequently, the figures on crop farms in particular should be used with caution. As more producers convert to organic farming these problems may be solved, but at
present effects on input prices and production, and thus on the financial results, are not
known. As better data become available over time, the accuracy will improve. Looking at
the list of farmers presently in the conversion stage (Table 4.1), who are potential inclusions
in future surveys, more reliable dairy farm data, especially differentiated on a regional basis, may become available before data from crop and pig farms.
In the analysis it has been necessary to use data for 1995 (conventional farms) and 1996
(organic farms). This may have lead to distortions, especially in yields.
Lack of data also limits accurate modelling of prices, although 1996-97 data were used to
calculate the relative figures for the price premium in the crop and pig sectors. Here the
organic price premium is assumed to fall in a linear fashion in proportion to the rate of
- 93 -
adoption, but there is little empirical basis for this assumption, which is also crucial to the
results.
A further simplifying assumption is that farmers cannot change their enterprise type. Pig
farmers must stay pig farmers, and dairy farmers must produce predominantly milk, even
though they can switch between crops within their enterprise. This constraint overstates the
costs of the widespread adoption of organic methods.
Another limitation concerns quotas. Dairy and sugar quotas are assumed to remain unfilled
if organic producers are unable or unwilling to fill them. Ignoring the possibility of quota
(and therefore not allowing farmers to carry out the most profitable enterprises) transfer
overstates the costs of organic production at the national level. Capital gains and losses incurred by this limitation as well as other capital gains and losses are ignored in this study.
The present DOAP does not permit a change in farm size. The average size of existing organic dairy farms presently is considerably larger than the conventional farm. The lower
livestock density on organic farms does indicate that optimum-size organic farms could
well be larger than conventional farms. To adjust to the requirement in this study that farm
sizes be similar, the costs and returns on organic dairy farms are adjusted from the larger
organic acreage to the smaller conventional unit. In reality, income per organic farm relative to on a conventional farm is therefore likely to be larger than shown in this study. The
number of farms would be reduced. However, the relative farm size may have been influenced by differences in dairy quota allocation between organic and conventional farms.
DOAP does not include any provision for endogenous technological change. If organic
farming were to become the dominant form of agriculture, production costs would be lowered through innovation and applications of new technology specifically designed for organic methods (see Rosset and Benjamin (1994) for innovations in Cuba under conditions
which forced organic management on a large part of agriculture).
Constant returns to scale have been assumed both on the input and output side. With
greater demand for organic inputs, costs are likely to be reduced. This is even more important on the output side, given that most of the payments by consumers accrue not to the
producer but to the processor, wholesaler or retailer (including payments for transport, insurance, packaging, etc.). Organic marketing typically requires individual packaging to reduce the scope for substitution with uncertified products. Economies of size within the
marketing sector may well be quite significant over time. For example, packaging is not an
- 94 -
intrinsic cost of marketing organic products. If marketing costs of organic products could be
brought down to conventional levels, final prices for many products would be considerably
lower than today. This potential for decreases in consumer prices over time without affecting the producer prices has not been included in estimates in this study.
At present, part-time farmers are excluded from the analysis. Part-time farmers are likely
to have higher costs of production, but are often better able to maintain their livelihood
through off-farm income. Inclusion of these farmers would make the analysis more complete.
No work has been carried out on either externalities to farming or the effects on the
macro-economic variables. Reduction in production (at 80 per cent conversion to organic
farming this is close to one third in pig production, around 15 per cent in milk production
and a considerable reduction in crop sales) can be expected to have substantial up- and
downstream effects. In addition, the budgetary costs of reduced export restitutions as a
result of lower production have not been accounted for in this study. Although they are not a
cost to Denmark, they are a cost to taxpayers somewhere, and make products of conventional agriculture cheaper compared with products grown under organic management.
In spite of its limitations, there are several useful applications of DOAP that were beyond
the scope of the present study. As yet no attempt has been made to find the optimal rate of
adoption, nor the optimal way of implementing a given reduction of fertiliser and pesticide
use. Without valuing the environmental damage, it would not be possible to calculate the
optimal reduction in pollution. However, it is clear that different rates of adoption in different sectors would result in similar environmental impacts at lower costs. An iterative procedure could readily be developed to find the least-cost approach.
DOAP is a market-oriented model, and would be useful for assessing the effectiveness of
market-based instruments such as taxes and subsidies in different sectors or regions. For
example, would an output or input-based organic subsidy be most effective? It could also
show the price impacts of certain regulatory constraints such as quotas. However, at this
point it lacks substitution between most of the inputs, so in most cases input use responds to
shifts in area.
In summary, lack of data and the need to make use of assumptions, especially regarding the
crop and pig sector, means that the study needs to be seen as a preliminary assessment of the
situation of a change towards organic agriculture in Denmark. On the other hand, inherent
- 95 -
limitations in the model may well have lead to an over-estimation of the costs of organic
management. Lack of flexibility between the allocation of quotas, the use of inputs, in
changing farm size or between enterprise types, and the absence of technological change are
factors which, while possibly small individually, may aggregate to a significant revision of
the estimated costs.
- 96 -
- 97 -
8. Summary and concluding comments
8.1. Summary
To assess the effects of a hypothetical widespread adoption of organic practices in
Denmark, a four-region, partial equilibrium model of the Danish agricultural sector, DOAP;
was constructed. DOAP contains 3 farm sectors, crops, dairy and pigs, and permits farmers
to have up to 16 cropping activities. Detailed costs of production are modelled in each
sector and region. DOAP contains two production structures, one conventional and one
organic, currently representing less than 2 per cent of Danish farms. By exogenously
specifying the number of farms using each method of production, the impact of a switch to
organic methods on national outputs and farm returns can be estimated.
SJFI survey data indicate that conventional and organic dairy farms differ in their physical
and financial structure. Most obviously, synthetic fertiliser and pesticide use is minimal on
Danish organic farms. What is registered under this heading presumably falls into categories
allowed by the national organic standards. The use of certain other inputs such as animal
feed and labour is also lower on organic farms. Other input use, including manure and
depreciation on machinery, is similar to that on conventional farms. On the output side
yields on organic farms in Denmark are lower than those on conventional farms, and thus
farmers require a greater land area if they are to maintain per farm production. To maintain
a given livestock output, a greater area in fodder production is required. Farmers respond by
reducing their production of non-feed crops, such as wheat. At present, organic producers
also grow less sugar beets and grass for seed, rapeseed and green peas because of agronomic
constraints in the absence of pesticides and because of an absence of organic markets.
Financial data indicate that existing organic dairy farmers can outperform conventional farmers.
Lower production per hectare (through changes in yields and rotation) on the one hand, and lower
production costs and higher output prices (mainly through premiums) on the other, result in favourable net farm income comparisons for farms under organic management. Estimates of organic
crop and pig farms suggest a similar story, although yields there are lower and prices for the livestock enterprise are higher than on dairy farms. This performance is turned around over time, as
premiums are estimated to fall with increased supply of organic products. This assumes that present
conditions of marketing structures (for inputs and outputs) and technology are maintained at present
levels.
- 98 -
The main conclusion from the analysis of the model results is that primary agricultural
sector income may stay the same, or rise slightly if less than 25 per cent of Danish farmers
across all sectors adopted organic methods, but that considerable losses could accrue if a
high percentage of farmers followed this approach. It must be stressed that this estimate is
valid under present conditions of input and output prices, level of technology, and estimates
in the crop and pig sector and future values. The slight initial gains occur because, according
to the latest (1995 and 1996) SJFI survey data in the dairy sector and estimates in the crop
and pig sector, organic producers - especially in the dairy sector which comprises half of the
total number of organic farmers - are making greater profits than their conventional
counterparts. This result of higher net returns per hectare does not hold as more and more
farmers convert, because the organic price premiums that currently exist would be
substantially or wholly eroded. Considerations of increased knowledge over time in organic
management, possibilities in technological change, changes in combination of enterprises,
sector and farm size, and especially increased efficiencies in the marketing of organic
produce are not properly accounted for here. They are likely to enhance the financial
position of organic producers to some extent. If age per se influences financial results, the
difference in age between organic and conventional farmers would overestimate the relative
financial position of organic farmers. The limitations of the data in the crop and pig sectors
call for some caution in interpreting the results.
Using the model enabled several factors to be identified as key variables determining costs,
production and net returns. The rotational constraints, the yield reductions, subsidies and
the existence of the price premium on organic products are main factors. Changes in input
prices were not modelled, except where the inputs are outputs (for example fodder crops)
used in the livestock enterprise. An exogenous drop in output prices (as can be expected in
the organic market) is found to be significant in decreasing the gap between organic and
conventional farms at higher rates of conversion.
8.2. Policy implications
Given the environmental costs commonly associated with the use of pesticides and fertiliser, governments may conclude that the widespread adoption of organic farming practices
are worth encouraging. Good policies should above all be effective, efficient and equitable,
and also meet other criteria such as simplicity and transparency. The results of the analysis
of the organic industry in this study provide a few guidelines as to how to formulate such a
policy in agriculture. Forthcoming SJFI studies will provide further guidelines.
- 99 -
It should be noted that a geographically limited change, such as increased organic farming
in Denmark, creates different effects than if more countries follow the same strategy. A
widespread international adoption of organic farming may be expected to put pressure on
food supply and prices.
Given the present policies there is some merit in moving at least some way towards greater
organic production in Denmark, as the first 20 per cent conversion is not likely to make a
large difference in net financial returns to farming in any of the sectors. The question is:
should the government have a role in stimulating organic agriculture and, if so, how?
Optimal policies usually involve tackling the problems as directly as possible. Imposing
taxes and charges on the use or disposal of pollutants is the most direct. Taxing inputs to
reflect the full cost has the added advantage of showing the true competitiveness of the systems. However, the response to fertiliser and pesticide use to changes in prices has been
limited, and farm income can be reduced substantially before the policy objectives are
achieved. In the extreme case where there is no price response whatsoever by adjusting the
management system, a 100 per cent tax on the cost of fertilisers and pesticides reduces farm
income by Dkr.62,000 per farm on average in the model employed in this study. This is a
gross over-estimate, however, as assuming no management response is rather unrealistic.
What an over-simplification like this shows, though, is that such a policy increases returns
to organic farming relative to conventional agriculture. While all tax revenue should be
spent as efficiently as possible, regardless of source, political expediency may require that
the tax raised be hypothecated to particular uses, such as cleaning up environmental damage. Hypothecated taxes can be given special names, such as ’environmental levy’, to raise
awareness of the issue and to promote the objectives of the tax.
The use of subsidies to promote organic production is a second best policy, but one with
advantages over some regulatory methods. Subsidies encourage those farmers who can
most readily convert to organic production to do so, without requiring a similar response
from those farmers who would find the transition difficult and expensive. It is not surprising
that in Denmark it is mostly dairy producers who have converted to date. However, the subsidies policy does not target environmental damage, so that change does not occur on farms
where the most damage is done. In other words, the policy may not be particularly effective
in achieving the aim of preventing pollution.
The current policy to promote organic agriculture includes the payment of subsidies to
farmers involved in organic production. In the 1995 base year, average subsidies per farm
- 100 -
for full-time organic producers in Denmark amounted to Dkr.177,000, 19 per cent greater
than subsidies for conventional farmers (Table 5.11). This includes the special subsidies for
organic production paid partly by the national government and partly by the EU, which
amounted to Dkr.53,000 per farm in 1995, and compensatory payments (paid by the EU and
due to all producers) of Dkr.124,000. Organic farmers receive fewer compensatory payments than conventional farmers (DKr.149,000 per farm) because of their different rotational structure which includes less of the crops with high subsidies. The question here is,
though, whether organic farmers will continue to receive subsidies for practising organic
management if widespread adoption of these methods occurs.
Clearly, the adoption of organic farming methods involves different costs to different agricultural sectors or regions. Whereas the organic dairy sector achieves total returns similar to the conventional sector at over 40 per cent adoption of organic management, the pig
sector is estimated to be in a similar situation up until only 15 per cent of conversion. An
efficient policy is one that achieves its objectives at least cost. If considering only the differences in production costs and ease of conversion, policies should focus on converting
dairy farms first. However, such a policy does not take into account the gains made in environmental terms from conversion in different sectors or regions. In other words, achieving environmental benefits is likely to be increasingly costly. The conversion of the first
farms to organic practices would be relatively cheap, and may even result in private financial gains for the first 25 pert cent.. The conversion of the last 10 or 20 per cent would be
much more expensive. It is likely that the first farmers to convert to organic agriculture are
those who are closest to that management system in any case, with least negative externalities, so that environmental gains made from their conversion are relatively low. It seems
probable that the final environmental benefits are the most difficult to achieve, and will
therefore need more encouragement than the first. A policy requiring an across-the-board
conversion, as modelled in this report, is likely to be inefficient. The cost of practising organic agriculture is probably directly related to the environmental benefits from such a
change. If subsidies are to be given, differentiation between the different farm sectors, and
probably regions, is likely to be warranted.
While sectoral differences are significant, the nature of the data employed here does not
allow analysis of regional differences within sectors. Therefore, at this stage of data availability it is difficult to say whether policies encouraging organic agriculture could be applied nationally without undue concern for the differential effects on regional income or
employment.
- 101 -
Funds earmarked for supporting organic agriculture could perhaps more usefully be spent
on subsidising research and development (for research needs in organic agriculture, see
Wynen (1996) and Krell (1997)). This would have the effect of reducing the productivity
losses associated with organic methods at present. Furthermore, Denmark may be able to
sell such technology abroad, or at least retain the first mover advantages from being one of
the global leaders in organic production methods. Cuba, forced to adopt organic practices in
large parts of its agriculture with the change in political winds in the early 1990s, is a good
example of developing exportable skills in the area of advanced technology associated with
organic agriculture, which can also be exported (Rosset and Benjamin 1994).
Another area where governments could play a role is marketing margins. The difference
between prices paid by consumers and received by producers is often much higher for organic than conventional produce. Much of this can be attributed to the absence of economies of scale. If the marketing process of organic products can increase its efficiencies,
which increased supplies would facilitate, the price premium consumers pay could drop
without affecting producer prices. Governments could facilitate such efficiencies by assisting the development of information networks, removing impediments to trade and the like.
Perhaps the main area for further work should be the organic price premiums. Little is
known about how organic prices will respond as supply increases, yet this is a key variable
determining the results. Further research in this area is of prime importance.
Where policy changes are contemplated, equity considerations are important: who gains
and who loses? With falling organic product prices, and reasonably stable conventional
prices in the absence of any real ability to raise prices as production falls in Denmark, present organic producers and suppliers of inputs in conventional agriculture would find themselves bearing the brunt of the burden of the change. Producers who remain conventional
growers will gain from the slight increase in prices and possible decrease in prices of fertilisers and pesticides, to the disappointment of the polluter-pays enthusiasts. Present consumers of organic products would benefit from the lower prices, though present consumers
of conventional products would lose in financial terms – they would presumably gain in
non-financial terms if they decided to change towards purchasing organic products. To the
extent that organic farming provides environmental benefits at least cost, it provides an argument for financing through taxes.
In summary, an effective, efficient and equitable policy would aim to reduce output of the
most damaging pollution in a way that involves least cost. Taxing polluting inputs, with all
its problems, is one way to handle pollution from conventional agriculture. Subsidising or-
- 102 -
ganic production is a second best instrument that nonetheless retains elements of efficiency.
Adoption of organic practices occurs especially in the dairy sector at present, where it is
safe to assume that costs are least. However, the policy is not particularly effective because
the benefits from changes in the dairy sector are likely not to be as great as similar changes
in the crop and pig sector. A closer relationship between policy instruments (subsidies) and
targets (reduced emissions) would be desirable. The environmental benefits from a move to
organic agriculture are likely to be paid for by those farmers who convert, consumers who
pay premiums, and taxpayers who provide the necessary support through subsidies. Suppliers of fertiliser and pesticides would find their markets severely reduced. Some degree of
adoption of organic agricultural methods presents the possibility of a double dividend –
lower environmental costs and lower budgetary costs. Further analysis along the lines outlined in this report, as well as in the area of environmental valuation, will provide the basis
for sound policy-making in this controversial area.
- 103 -
References
Danmarks Statistik (1996), Landbrugsstatistik 1995, Copenhagen.
EC (1991), Council Regulation (EEC) No 2092/91.
Egmont-Florian, D. van (1997), ‘Unsafe drinking water leads to government organic
conversion, France’, Ecology and Farming (14), p.25.
FAO (1996), ‘Environment, sustainability and trade linkages for basic foodstuffs’,
Rome.
Finansministeriet (1996), Finanslov 1996, Copenhagen
Finansministeriet (1997), Finanslov 1997, §24.23.25.10, Copenhagen.
Folkmann, P. and Nørgaard N. (1996), ‘Økonomien ved økologisk svineproduktion – en
modelanalyse’, Notat 1996-7, SJFI, Copenhagen.
Halberg and Kristensen (1997), ‘Expected crop yield loss when converting to organic dairy
farming in Denmark’, Biological Agriculture and Horticulture, 14 (1), February.
Heid, P. (1997), ‘Organic farming protects drinking water around Munich, Germany’,
Ecology and Farming, (14), p.24.
IFOAM (1996), ‘IFOAM Standards’, Tholey-Theley.
Krell, R. (ed.) (1997), Biological Farming Research in Europe, REU Technical series No.
54, Proceedings of an Expert Roundtable held in Braunschweig, Germany, 28 June
1997, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome.
Lampkin, N. (1990), Organic Farming, Farming Press, Ipswick, UK.
Lampkin, N. and Padel, S. (1994), The Economics of Organic Farming - An International Perspective, CAB International, Wallingford, UK.
Nørgaard, N. and Olsen P. (1995), Nye produktionssystemer til svin, report no. 83, SJFI,
Copenhagen.
OECD (1991), ‘The OECD Ministerial Trade Mandate Model for Policy Analysis:
Documentation’, GD (91) 159, Paris.
- 104 -
Pimentel, D., Acquay, H., Biltonen, M., Rice, P., Silva, M., Nelson, J., Lipner, V.,
Giordano, S., Horowitz, A. and D'Amore, M. (1993), ‘Assessment of environmental
and economic impacts of pesticide use’. In D. Pimentel and H. Lehman (eds.), The
Pesticide Question: Environment, Economics and Ethics, Chapman and Hall, New
York, pp. 47-84.
Plantedirektoratet (1997), ‘Saedskifte- og goedningsplaner Statistik 1995/96’, Ministeriet
for Foedevarer, Landbrug og Fiskeri, September, Copenhagen.
Poulsen and Folkmann (forthcoming), ‘Produktionsmuligheder og økonomi på økologiske
jordbrugsbedrifter – en modelanalyse’, SJFI, Copenhagen.
Redman, M. (1996), Industrial agriculture: counting the costs, Soil Association UK.
Rosset, P. and Benjamin, M. (eds.) (1994), The Greening of the Revolution – Cuba’s Experiment with Organic Agriculture, Ocean Press, Melbourne.
SJFI (1997), Agricultural Price Statistics, Copenhagen, Denmark.
SJFI (1997), Landbrugsregnskabsstatistik 1996-1997, Series A, No. 81, Copenhagen,
Denmark.
SJFI (1998), Regnskabsstatistik for økologisk jordbrug 1996/97, Series G nr. 1,
Copenhagen, Denmark.
US Department of Agriculture (1980), Report and Recommendations on Organic Farming,
US Government Printing Office, Washington D.C.
Wynen, E. (1994), 'Bio-dynamic and conventional dairy farming in Victoria: a financial
comparison'. Appendix 6 in: D. Small, J. McDonald and B. Wales, Alternative farming practices applicable to the dairy industry, Victorian Department of Agriculture
(Kyabram) and the Dairy Research and Development Corporation (Melbourne).
Wynen, E. (1996), 'Research Implications of a Paradigm Shift in Agriculture: The Case of
Organic Farming', Resource and Environmental Studies, No. 12, Centre for Resource
and Environmental Studies, Australian National University, May.
Wynen, E. (1997), 'Impact on Australian Broadacre Agriculture of Widespread Adoption of
Organic Farming', Resource and Environmental Studies, No. 14, Centre for Resource
and Environmental Studies, Australian National University, April.
Wynen, E. and Fritz, S. (1987), Sustainable Agriculture: A Viable Alternative. Discussion
Paper No. 1, National Association for Sustainable Agriculture, Australia, Sydney.
- 105 -
Appendix A
TABLE A.1. Average input costs under different management systems at baseline, by region and
sector
------ Variable costs --Org./
Org. Conv.
conv.
------- Fixed costs -----Org./
Org. Conv.
conv.
’000
DKr.
---------- Total ----------Org./
Org. Conv.
conv.
’000
- Pct. -DKr.
-- per farm --
’000
- Pct. -DKr.
-- per farm --
- Pct. -- per farm --
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
460
782
1142
540
971
1139
85
80
100
366
379
446
469
515
576
78
74
77
827
1161
1588
1009
1486
1715
82
78
93
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
434
781
1492
473
909
1457
92
86
102
366
379
446
443
496
585
83
76
76
800
1160
1938
916
1405
2042
87
83
95
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
451
915
1599
540
957
1557
83
96
103
316
444
492
440
541
645
72
82
76
767
1359
2091
979
1498
2202
78
91
95
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
473
852
1542
477
951
1506
99
90
102
336
413
467
431
518
607
78
80
77
809
1265
2010
909
1468
2113
89
86
95
Source: Derived from SJFI data and model simulations.
.
TABLE A.2. Input costs on dairy farms in different regions at baseline
-------------- Organic --------------EI
FEJ
SWJ
NJ
----------- Conventional ----------EI
FEJ
SWJ
NJ
----- Organic/conventional -----EI
FEJ
SWJ
NJ
------- DKr. ’000 per farm -------
------- DKr. ’000 per farm -------
------------------ Pct. ----------------
VARIABLE COSTS
Seed
Fertiliser
Manure
Pesticides
Energy
Co2-tax
Labour: hired
Maintenance:machinery
Contract operations
Other: plant production
Concentrates
Roughage
Vet. Costs
Insemination
Other costs: livestock
Total
25
1
37
25
1
37
29
1
43
27
1
40
25
21
32
20
27
35
24
40
40
21
32
37
99
4
113
126
3
104
125
2
108
132
3
108
23
2
116
57
76
7
194
195
18
8
24
782
23
2
116
57
76
7
194
194
18
8
24
781
26
3
136
67
89
8
227
228
21
9
28
915
25
3
126
62
82
8
212
212
19
8
26
852
22
2
143
78
58
7
235
220
31
18
54
971
19
2
104
61
56
8
251
232
28
13
36
909
23
3
87
58
68
8
238
282
27
12
32
957
21
2
103
57
58
7
277
253
25
10
33
951
101
97
81
73
130
110
83
89
57
43
44
80
117
112
111
94
136
93
77
84
63
61
66
86
115
104
156
116
130
107
96
81
76
77
89
96
119
116
123
110
143
113
77
84
77
83
78
90
FIXED COSTS
Depreciation
Labour: family
Other
Total
114
203
62
379
114
203
62
379
134
237
73
444
125
221
68
413
132
297
86
515
122
310
64
496
134
342
65
541
123
327
68
518
86
68
73
74
94
65
97
76
100
69
112
82
101
68
99
80
1161
1160
1359
1265
1486
1405
1498
1468
78
83
91
86
TOTAL
Source: Derived from SJFI and model simulations.
EI = Eastern Islands FEJ = Funen and Eastern Jutland
SWJ = Southern and Western Jutland
NJ = Northern Jutland
TABLE A.3. Crop rotations and total area per farm at baseline, by region and sector
Grains Barley Wheat
Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rapespring winter winter winter fodder Potato Beets grass Seed
Non- Fodder Grass Grass Silage Silage Under
Food
beet rotation perm. maize cereal sown
Total
--------------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
- ha -
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Setaside
17
18
15
3
3
12
39
20
41
1
0
1
1
1
2
1
0
0
12
11
8
6
1
3
6
2
6
10
6
8
2
0
3
0
4
0
0
10
1
1
7
1
0
7
0
0
9
0
0
6
0
104
51
57
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
16
Dairy
17
Pigs
17
6
6
13
33
14
37
5
2
3
3
1
3
1
1
1
3
1
2
9
0
3
7
1
8
12
6
9
2
1
4
0
6
0
0
18
0
2
11
2
0
6
0
0
9
0
1
9
0
103
51
67
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
27
5
Dairy
21
1
Pigs
31
10
17
6
21
6
2
4
6
2
4
12
2
2
1
0
0
3
0
3
7
1
8
12
7
11
1
0
2
0
6
0
2
23
1
1
11
3
0
3
0
0
14
0
1
13
1
106
59
67
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
26
6
31
5
2
3
9
3
7
4
1
3
0
0
0
4
0
2
7
1
6
12
7
9
1
1
4
0
6
0
1
21
1
7
13
4
0
1
0
1
14
0
1
11
1
99
55
65
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
20
21
21
3
2
9
- 106 -
- 107 -
- 108 -
TABLE A.4. Regional crop prices at baseline (1995)
Grains
spring
Barley
winter
Wheat
winter
Rye
winter
Peas
fodder
Potato
Sugar
beets
Seeds
grass
Rapeseed
------------------------------------------ DKr. per tonne ---------------------------------------EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1203
1075
1120
978
985
1028
987
928
1000
851
781
830
920
1050
857
1319
1319
1293
380
373
367
4752
5135
3647
1422
1301
1232
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1158
1060
1063
999
989
987
1028
970
1004
914
850
841
947
922
930
718
702
701
367
342
364
3982
4119
4183
1386
1316
1378
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1040
1010
1051
1021
1003
1015
1018
971
1018
942
826
890
963
920
985
828
574
682
294
283
334
3923
3612
5215
1375
1302
1295
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1085
1011
1011
1076
995
1028
1013
994
988
921
865
909
1018
965
906
1186
1155
709
294
294
294
4909
6056
4249
1440
1354
1398
Source: SJFI surveys.
- 109 -
TABEL A.5. Financial net returns per farm and total returns in agriculture at the baseline, by
region and sector
Conventional
Organic
- DKr. ’000 per farm -
Conventional
Organic
Total
-------------- DKr. million --------------
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
273
54
264
280
66
347
624
58
384
1066
0
0
0
0
624
58
384
1066
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
178
11
337
200
53
357
251
31
836
1117
0
0
0
0
251
31
836
1117
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
160
0
325
180
62
294
202
-1
762
963
0
0
0
0
202
-1
762
963
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
53
-42
203
72
65
184
37
-204
500
334
0
0
0
0
37
-204
500
334
Source: Derived from SJFI data and model simulations.
*=
Simulated values, as baseline is assumed to be zero organic management
TABLE A.6. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at the baseline, by region and sector
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
-------- DKr. ‘000 per farm --------
--------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ----------------------- -- Pct. ---
-- Pct. --
Org./conv.
Subsidy
Total
-- Pct. --
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1056
1439
1834
227
101
145
1283
1540
1979
18
7
7
524
867
1064
315
232
711
188
87
115
80
41
45
1107
1227
1935
28
19
37
24
10
8
118
127
110
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
844
1322
2205
250
94
174
1094
1416
2379
23
7
7
462
852
1263
268
233
848
193
87
132
77
41
52
1001
1213
2296
27
19
37
27
11
8
108
136
106
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
903
Dairy
1389
Pigs
2348
236
108
180
1139
1498
2527
21
7
7
423
987
1317
244
284
880
199
102
137
80
48
51
947
1421
2385
26
20
37
29
11
8
118
139
104
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
241
102
166
962
1426
2316
25
7
7
413
940
1210
217
251
807
176
95
127
74
44
50
881
1330
2194
25
19
37
28
11
8
104
136
107
721
1324
2150
Source: Derived from SJFI data and model simulations.
- 110 -
- 111 -
Appendix B
TABLE B.1. Average input costs under different management systems at baseline, by region and
sector
------ Variable costs --Org./
Org. Conv.
conv.
------- Fixed costs -----Org./
Org. Conv.
conv.
’000
DKr.
’000
- Pct. -DKr.
-- per farm -EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
---------- Total ----------Org./
Org. Conv.
conv.
’000
- Pct. -DKr.
-- per farm --
- Pct. -- per farm --
408
709
945
556
1003
1227
73
71
77
366
379
446
472
515
577
78
74
77
774
1088
1391
1027
1518
1803
75
72
77
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
388
707
1234
486
941
1572
80
75
79
366
379
445
445
496
586
82
76
76
753
1086
1680
931
1437
2158
81
76
78
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
400
829
1322
550
987
1678
73
84
79
315
444
492
439
540
645
72
82
76
715
1272
1814
989
1527
2324
72
83
78
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
433
771
1279
486
985
1625
89
78
79
335
413
467
432
517
607
78
80
77
768
1184
1746
918
1502
2232
84
79
78
--------------------------------------------- percentage of baseline----------------------------EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
89
91
83
103
103
108
86
88
77
100
100
100
101
100
100
99
100
100
94
94
88
102
102
105
92
92
83
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
89
91
83
103
104
108
87
87
77
100
100
100
100
100
100
99
100
100
94
94
87
102
102
106
93
92
82
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
89
91
83
102
103
108
87
88
77
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
93
94
87
101
102
106
92
92
82
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
91
90
83
102
104
108
90
87
77
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
95
94
87
101
102
106
94
92
82
Source: Model simulations.
TABLE B.2. Crop rotations and total area per farm at 80 per cent organic management, by region and sector
Grains Barley Wheat
Rye Peas
Sugar Seeds Rapespring winter winter winter fodder Potato Beets grass Seed
Non- Fodder Grass Grass Silage Silage Under
Food
beet rotation perm. maize cereal sown
Total
--------------------------------------------------------------------------- percentage ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
- ha -
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Setaside
16
18
14
3
3
11
40
20
42
1
0
1
1
1
2
1
0
0
12
11
8
6
1
3
6
2
6
9
6
7
2
0
3
0
4
0
0
10
1
1
7
1
0
7
0
0
9
0
0
6
0
104
51
57
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
16
Dairy
17
Pigs
16
6
6
12
34
15
38
5
2
2
3
1
3
1
1
1
4
1
2
9
0
3
7
1
9
11
6
8
2
1
4
0
6
0
0
18
0
2
11
2
0
6
0
0
9
0
1
9
0
103
51
67
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
27
5
Dairy
21
1
Pigs
30
10
17
6
22
6
2
4
5
2
3
12
2
2
1
0
0
3
0
3
8
1
9
12
7
11
1
0
2
0
6
0
2
23
1
1
11
3
0
3
0
0
14
0
1
13
1
106
59
67
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
27
7
32
5
2
3
8
3
7
4
1
3
0
0
0
4
0
2
7
1
6
12
8
9
1
1
4
0
6
0
1
21
1
7
13
4
0
1
0
1
14
0
1
11
1
99
55
65
Source: Derived from SJFI data.
19
20
21
3
2
9
- 112 -
- 113 -
TABEL B.3. Financial net returns per full-time farm and total returns in agriculture at 80 per
cent of organic management, by region and sector
Conventional
Organic
- DKr. ’000 per farm -
Conventional
Organic
Total
-------------- DKr. million --------------
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
357
61
325
95
-35
54
163
13
95
270
173
-30
63
206
336
-17
157
476
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
236
3
391
45
-48
35
66
2
194
262
50
-112
70
8
117
-111
264
270
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
190
-12
354
48
-65
-31
48
-14
166
200
49
-305
-58
-314
97
-319
108
-115
NORTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
Total
81
-59
232
-55
-42
-102
11
-57
115
69
-31
-164
-201
-396
-20
-221
-87
-327
Source: Derived from SJFI data and model simulations.
TABLE B.4. Gross financial returns, subsidies and premiums per full-time farm at 80 per cent organic management, by region and sector
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
-------- DKr. ‘000 per farm --------
--------------------- DKr. ‘000 per farm ----------------------- -- Pct. ---
-- Pct. --
Org./conv.
Subsidy
Total
-- Pct. --
EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
1158
1478
1984
226
101
145
1384
1579
2128
16
6
7
538
878
1143
62
46
142
188
87
115
80
41
45
868
1053
1445
7
4
10
31
12
11
119
127
111
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
917
1346
2375
250
94
174
1167
1440
2549
21
7
7
475
863
1362
53
46
169
193
87
132
77
41
52
798
1038
1715
7
4
10
34
12
11
108
136
106
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
943
Dairy
1407
Pigs
2497
236
108
180
1179
1515
2677
20
7
7
435
1000
1420
48
57
175
199
102
137
80
48
51
763
1207
1783
6
5
10
37
12
11
118
138
104
NOTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
240
102
166
999
1443
2464
24
7
7
421
952
1306
42
50
161
176
95
127
74
44
50
713
1141
1644
6
4
10
35
12
11
104
136
107
continued
758
1340
2299
TABLE B.4. (continued)
------------------- Conventional -----------------Subsidy/
Enterprise Subsidy
Total
Total
------------------------------------------ Organic --------------------------------------------Subsidy Subsidy
Premium/ Subsidy/
Enterprise Premium
Conv. Organic
Total
Total
Total
Org./conv.
Subsidy
Total
------------------------------------------------------------------------ Percentage of baseline
--------------------------------------------------------------------EASTERN ISLANDS
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
110
103
108
100
100
100
108
103
108
93
98
93
103
101
107
20
20
20
100
100
100
100
100
100
78
86
75
25
23
27
255
233
268
200
200
200
FUNEN AND EASTERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
109
102
108
100
100
100
107
102
107
94
98
93
103
101
108
20
20
20
100
100
100
100
100
100
80
86
75
25
23
27
251
234
268
200
200
200
SOUTHERN AND WESTERN JUTLAND
Crop
104
Dairy
101
Pigs
106
100
100
100
103
101
106
97
99
94
103
101
108
20
20
20
100
100
100
100
100
100
81
85
75
25
24
27
248
235
268
200
200
200
NOTHERN JUTLAND
Crop
Dairy
Pigs
100
100
100
104
101
106
96
99
94
102
101
108
19
20
20
100
100
100
100
100
100
81
86
75
24
23
27
247
233
267
200
200
200
105
101
107
Source: Derived from SJFI data and model simulations.
- 114 -
- 115 -
- 116 -
Download