EU Multi-level Governance Equals Regional Empowerment? Anna-Lena Hogenauer PSA Northern Postgraduate Conference, 6 June 2008 Draft – Please do not cite In the early 1990s, Gary Marks applied the concept of multilevel governance to EU policymaking, arguing that EU policies were subject to a complex system of negotiations of different levels of government in various arenas. However, while multi-level governance (MLG) suggests that regions can influence EU policies and, in the process, strengthen their position vis-à-vis the central state, doubts as to whether strong legislative regions – and in particular the regions1 of federal states – are really strengthened have grown over the past years. The aim of this paper is to establish to what extent regions have become empowered/disempowered by European integration. It will be argued that MLG relies on an oversimplified model of EU policy-making based on a very specific type of policy and that the effect of EU policy-making on regional power and authority will vary according to a regions domestic competences, its wealth and the type of policy-making. Multi-level Governance as a Theory of the EU as a Political System In the early 1990s Gary Marks developed the concept of multi-level governance in the context of EU structural policy. While the concept of MLG is not yet explicitly used in his 1992 chapter on structural policy in the European Community, Marks already addresses the ‘distribution of authority, and decision-making powers across the Community, member states, and regional governments’, thereby referring to several levels of government (Marks 1992: 192). In his 1993 chapter on ‘Structural Policy and Multilevel Governance in the EC’, Marks elaborates on the distinction between formal, constitutional powers and everyday politics and defines the concept of MLG as ‘a system of continuous negotiation among nested governments at several territorial tiers – supranational, national, regional and local - as the result of a broad process of institutional creation and decisional reallocation that has pulled some previously centralised functions of the state up to the supranational level and some down to the local/regional level’ (Marks 1993: 392). Thus, different levels of government negotiate on several levels in a process that goes beyond formal relationships to include informal interaction. The term ‘region’ can refer to a variety of territorial entities ranging from relatively small sub-state units to cross-border regions to ‘global’ regions such as West Europe or North America (Loughlin 1997: 154-5). In this study, the term ‘regions of federal states’ refers to political regions, i.e. territories with regional governments/administrations. In the case of the federal states it refers to the German and Austrian Länder and Belgian régions. 1 The two main hypotheses of MLG are that in EU policy-making there will be direct interaction between sub-national and the supranational actors unmediated by central governments and that this interaction will undermine the authority of central governments. In this centrifugal process, some authority will be shifted ‘upwards’ to the European level and some ‘downwards’ to the sub-national level (Marks 1993: 407). Thus, while MLG acknowledges that member states remain in the foreseeable future “the most important pieces of the European puzzle” (Marks, McAdam and Blank 1996: 4; Jeffery 1997: 184), it is closer to neofunctionalism in that it recognizes that the EU’s supranational bodies, and in particular the Commission, are capable of exerting independent influence by forming alliances with subnational actors that result in some loss of control on the part of central governments (George 2001: 111-13). Over time, a more precise set of hypotheses has been developed, especially in relation to the question of regional influence on EU policy-making. Marks, Haesly and Mbaye (Marks, Haesly and Mbaye, 2002) argue in a study of sub-national offices in Brussels that an office’s lobbying activity increases with the funds available, which is in turn linked to the constitutional competences of the region. Jeffery’s study of the influence of sub-national authorities in EU policy-making specifies four variables that have an impact on the level of influence of SNAs both within and across member states. Firstly, a strong constitutional position allows for more regional influence. Secondly, formal structures of intergovernmental relations are seen as leading to more influence than informal structures. Thirdly, administrative adaptation, leadership and coalition-building have an impact on the level of influence and, finally, legitimacy and social capital (historic background of a SNA, sense of identity, a well developed civil society, etc.) give greater credibility to sub-national demands (Jeffery 2000: 14-7). On the other hand, Bauer (Bauer 2006) argues with regard to the German Länder’s strategy in the European constitutional debate that “the more resources the particular Land has at its disposal, the greater seems the likelihood that it opts for the autonomy-orientated position.” (34). In other words, the wealthier a Land is the more it will strive for a separation of European and regional competences instead of further Europeanisation of its sphere of influence. In addition, one of Bauer’s concluding hypotheses is that “[a] sub-national government is expected to favour a more autonomy-orientated relationship with the European Union, the more its actual political room for manoeuvre is affected by further European integration” (35). The ‘actual’ political room for manoeuvre are constitutional competences and economic resources, as those determine to what extent a region can make full use of those constitutional competences. Bauer also points out that if a perception of regional identity/distinctiveness or even a regional party system is involved, this makes the autonomy option more likely (34). In a similar vein, Jeffery’s recent work on the German Länder shows that the Länder have come to see European integration as a threat that cannot be reined in by participation rights and have therefore moved to a strategy of disentanglement of competences. Jeffery argues that “while regional governments set out 20 years ago with a transformative project designed to challenge the centrality of the member state in the EU, legislative regions have in the last few years come to endorse, even buttress the centrality of the member state” (Jeffery 2007). Thus, while their first strategy was about escaping the member state and the second about greater participation within it, the third strategy focuses on the potential of the member state as a barrier against European influence. Legislative regions are seen as having a distinctive interest in the preservation of “the meaning of regional lawmaking powers in the context of European integration”. Thus, Jeffery argues that the German regions, with the support of the Belgian and Austrian regions, developed a defensive strategy during the European constitutional debate with demands for the introduction of the ‘new early warning system’ for national parliaments and a detailed catalogue of competences. The aim was to prevent further Europeanization of regional legislative competences and, if possible, to roll back existing EU powers. A strong member state structure is seen as the best guarantee of regional autonomy (Jeffery 2005; Große-Hüttemann and Knodt: 596-7).2 Thus, Jeffery argues that it reflects the Länder’s wish to achieve maximum autonomy within the member state, to limit the EU’s competences to their current scope and ‘to be left alone’ by the European Union. Thus, while the first two articles suggest that the constitutionally strong regions with a long history will have the greatest influence in EU policy-making amongst European regions, Bauer’s theory and Jeffery’s analysis of Germany suggest that these same regions will not support further integration but demand autonomy from the European Union – especially if they are also economically strong. It does not seem that – from the point of view of constitutionally strong regions – European integration is a centrifugal process leading to a distribution of powers both ‘upwards’ and ‘downwards’, but rather a one-way street where competences move upwards. An Incomplete Picture – The Empirical Basis of Multi-level Governance The conflict between the assumption that European integration is part of a centrifugal process and recent studies that underline the desire of strong regions to limit European integration can best be explained by looking at the empirical basis of MLG. At its origin, multi-level governance has been closely linked to empirical findings, albeit in a specific area of EU policy-making. It has resulted out of Marks’ analysis of EU regional and structural policy (Marks 1992; Marks 1993) and was initially developed as a concept for EU policy-making in this field only (George 2004: 107). While it gradually developed into a general theory of EU policy-making and even European integration, many case studies still focus on structural policy. In his study of EU regional policy, Conzelmann has analysed ERDF procedures in North Rhine-Westphalia (NRW), Nord-Pas de Calais and the North West, three declining industrial regions receiving Objective 2 aid from 1989 to 1993, to see what difference national politicoinstitutional settings make with regard to the operation of the ‘partnership’ principle (Conzelmann 1995). In the case of NRW, the Commission was a source of additional funding, See also Rudolf Hrbek (1999). Hrbek argues that ‘their priority of developing internal channels of participation – rather than in establishing institutionalised channels of participation and codetermination at the European level, e.g. in the Committee of Regions – is unmistakable.’ 2 but also placed restrictions on the region’s own efforts in the field through its competition policy. While direct links between NRW and the Commission led to a multilateral pattern of relationships between supranational, national and regional actors which challenged the gatekeeper function of the federal government, this did not lead to a noticeable change in centre-regions power relations. As German structural policy-making relied already on partnership, the European partnership principle did not lead to noticeable changes in the relationship between actors (149-50). Ironically, it was in the UK, the least regionalised country of the three at the time, that the Commission had the biggest impact with its support for the emergence of the public-private group ‘North West Regional Association’ and its threat that the region might lose funding in the absence of more internal coherence on a regional level (p.159-64). While there was no conflict between the regional and central levels for NRW or Nord-Pas de Calais, the conflictual relations in the UK appeared to be linked to the generally conflictual relations between the central government and the regional and local level at the time (165). Thus, overall, in the case of NRW, the enabling and constraining effect of EU policy-making counterbalanced each other. The absence of conflictual relations between the national and regional levels limits the applicability of the assumption of MLG that regions can and will become allies of the Commission in its struggle to gain independence from the central governments. In addition, European structural policy only empowered a region in the most centralised case. Bache (2004: 155-6) confirms Conzelmann’s findings that, in the UK, sub-national involvement in EC structural policymaking was limited and that the central government could still act as a flexible ‘gate-keeper’. Structural policy was a case of multi-level participation, but not multi-level governance (174). Tömmel argues with regard to structural policy that the Commission in the most powerful actor in structural policy and uses this position often to strengthen regions. In addition, “the more dependent recipient institutions are on external subsidies, the stronger the position of the Commission” (Tömmel 1998: 59-60). Also in apparent contradiction to Conzelmann, Anderson finds that the German Länder have been empowered by the Europeanization of cohesion policy. He points out that especially the eastern Länder have formed ‘a new territorial constituency in Germany, one that has had the opportunity, the desire, and the means to avail itself of Commission resources’ (Anderson 1996: 164). In the light of Tömmel’s (1998) argument, this contradiction might be resolved if one takes into account the economically extremely weak position of the east German Länder. The enabling effect of the much needed resources may outweigh the constraining effect of the conditions attached to them and may have been more important than in the case of NRW. The impact of the degree of a Land’s dependence on financial support on its attitude towards European integration clearly emerges from Jeffery’s analysis of two German Länder, Bavaria and Saxony-Anhalt. It shows that Bavaria, a wealthy and historically rooted Land, would like to limit competences of European Commission, especially in media policy, agricultural policy and structural policy and, in particular, see a renationalization/reregionalisation of agricultural and structural policy. Saxony-Anhalt, by contrast, having a strong interest in Objective 1 of the structural funds, does not desire to limit the role of the EU (Jeffery 1998). Finally, with regard to structural policy in Austria, Ficzko’s study reveals that European structural policy did lead to a considerable strengthening of the regional level compared to Austrian structural policy pre-accession (Ficzko 2001). While the central government tended to act like a hegemon and showed little interest in involving the regional level, Europeanization undermined its position (222-4). The main factors in this process were the new obligation for multi-annual planning, European financial support, the partnership principle led to more direct regional engagement with the EU, but also regional mobilisation from below (229-30). Overall, it appears that the impact of European structural policy on regions with strong powers in the field tends to be smaller than on weak regions. It only undermines central governments where these governments did previously practically monopolise structural policy-making. By contrast, in the case of regions with important powers in the field, the only empowering impact stems from the additional financial resources available to the regions, with the result that the poorer a region is, the more it depends on EU resources and the more it is in favour of EU involvement. The assumption that there are tensions between the regional and national levels is not universally true, with the result that regions cannot be expected to systematically ally themselves with the Commission. The number of case studies of regional engagement in other EU policy-making areas is very limited and provides only a patchy picture. Thus, Thielemann’s study of German state aids showed that Länder-Commission relations can be strained (Thielemann 1999). His analysis of the dispute about state aid given to Volkswagen by the government of Saxony reveals a bitter confrontation between the Land and the Commission in which the federal government was unable to defend the Land. At the centre of the tensions – from a German perspective – were the Commission’s disregard for the internal allocation of competences in Germany, and its inconsistent dealings with the special economic situation of the eastern German Länder. Weatherill (Weatherill 2005) gives a further example of the Commission’s occasional disregard for domestic structures citing the proceedings against Germany for the incorrect implementation of harmonising Directive 89/686 on protective equipment for fire-fighters. Again, the breach was actually caused by the Länder. These studies confirm that the assumption of a near natural alliance between the regional and the European level does not apply to all sectors of EU policy-making and hence further confirms the need to rethink and refine MLG assumptions about the relationship between the regional, national and European level. With regard to environmental policy, Streb’s study of Bavaria, Upper Austria and Flanders shows how the negative integration in state aids has abolished sub-national competencies for autonomous structural and regional policy. Regions now have to translate their goals into supranational objectives (Streb 2007: 222-3). He also argues that the Wild Birds Directive and FFH-Directive illustrate the severe restrictions that strong regions face at the implementation stage. Thus, in his eyes, European integration leads to a disempowerment of strong regions that undermines the federal structures of member states. Overall, looking at the case studies, one notices that the picture is incomplete. First of all, most case studies focus on structural policy, i.e. a distributive policy that is explicitly built upon the principle of partnership, while most of the EU’s policies are regulatory. Thus, they focus on a policy that is more likely to be enabling than the average EU policy. Secondly, by looking at EU structural policy, authors tend to focus on economically weaker regions. Thus, the two distinct questions of whether EU funds have an enabling effect on regions or whether EU structural policy leads to genuine reforms in the distribution of competences are being conflated. Also, the attitudes of economically strong regions are neglected, which is problematic in so far as the enabling effect of EU financial support falls away for this type of region. Thirdly, many of these studies focus on implementation rather than policy-making in the usual sense. If one is interested in the regions of federal states, this distinction matters, as, domestically, regions would often have a say in the earlier stages of policy-making and are thus likely to mobilize during the earlier stages of EU policy-making as well. The question is therefore: how influential are these regions across all stages of the EU policy-making process? Fourthly, many studies take – explicitly or implicitly – a ‘top-down’ approach, analyzing the role of the Commission in mobilizing regions rather than at the ways in which regions themselves mobilize in EU policy-making. The assumption appears to be that regions are empowered when they play a role in the implementation/policy-making. The real question is whether this empowerment really gives them new powers or just allows them to regain powers on the European level that they already possess in the domestic arena. As a result, there is need for research on a more diverse set of policy areas and for the development of more specific hypotheses. In the following three hypotheses will be suggested for future research. Who is Empowered by Multi-Level Governance? H1: The extent to which a region is empowered/disempowered by European integration depends on its domestic competences. Strong legislative regions will find the channels of participation in EU policy-making an insufficient compensation for the loss of domestic powers. Regions from highly centralized states may find the openness of the European Parliament and Commission towards lobbying and interest representation by sub-state and non-state actors enabling. Also, participation in the Committee of Regions, a European advisory body, may seem attractive. Participation in the implementation of EU policies may strengthen their position, especially if their financial and administrative resources need to be upgraded for this purpose. However, strong legislative regions will find the advisory nature of European channels of regional interest representation and the collective exercise of national channels of regional interest representation frustrating, in particular in areas where they could previously co-determine the national policy or even make their own policy. In addition, they do not benefit from their role of implementers of EU policy, as this is merely an extension of their domestic powers and as the necessary resources and administrations are already in place. H2: Economically strong regions will find EU integration less empowering than economically weak regions. Economically strong regions do not benefit from the structural funds and can only obtain limited funding through specific programs. As they have extensive resources at hand, they are able to steer regional development projects themselves. However, they currently have to work within the Commission’s guidelines for state aid and within its competition policy. Economically weak regions, by contrast, may need external funding in order to make full use of existing competences such as in the area of regional development. H3: Redistributive areas of EU policy-making will witness greater regional empowerment than regulatory areas. First, one could argue that distributive policies differ from regulatory policies in that they have an inherent potential for an enabling impact on regions by providing resources (Moravcsik 1994: 53). Second, the partnership principle and the management of funds may lead to a strengthening of the regional level in relatively centralised states where the regions hitherto lacked the administrative resources and powers to manage regional projects (Conzelmann 1995). However, the regions of strongly regionalised or federalised states will already possess these powers and will generally have already been involved in regional development prior to the EU structural policy. The general effect of regulatory policies (the bulk of EU policy), by contrast, can be seen as rather constraining. In sectors where regions had formerly co-decision powers at the national level or even exclusive powers, the new European rules restrict their political margin of manoeuvre in future policy-making at the regional and national level. Where European and regional policy goals are conflicting, European legislation may effectively force regions to change their course. Conclusion While the strength of multi-level governance lies in its attempt to provide a theory of European policy-making that reflects the role of both the supranational and the sub-national levels in addition to the member state governments, it currently relies on over-generalisations from one particular policy area. In particular, the assumption that European integration is part of a centrifugal process that distributes power ‘upwards’ to the supranational level and ‘downwards’ to the sub-national level stands in stark contrast with the demands of some regions for less European integration. In fact, European integration cannot be labelled either ‘empowering’ or ‘disempowering’ for regions. Instead, whether it is one or the other needs to be assessed on a case-by-case basis. In particular, there is a strong need for further research on a wider variety of policy areas and for a systematic comparison of the impact of European integration on the powers of various types of regions. Bibliography Anderson J. (1996), “Germany and the Structural Funds: Unification Leads to Bifurcation”, in L. Hooghe (ed.), Cohesion Policy and European Integration: Building Multi-level Governance, Oxford, Clarendon Press. Bache I. (2004), “Multi-level Governance and European Union Regional Policy”, in I. Bache and M. Flinders (eds.), Multi-level Governance, Oxford, Oxford University Press. Bauer M.W. (2006), “The German Länder and the European Constitutional Treaty: Heading for a Differentiated Theory of Regional Elite Preferences for European Integration”, Regional and Federal Studies, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp. 21-41. Conzelmann T. (1995), “Networking and the Politics of EU Regional Policy”, Regional and Federal Studies, Vol. 5, No. 2, pp. 134-173. Ficzko M. (2001), Regionale Strukturpolitik in Österreich im Zuge des Beitritts zur Europäischen Union, Dissertation, Berlin, Humboldt Universität. George S. (2004), “Multi-level Governance and the European Union”, in I. Bache and M. Flinders (eds.), Multi-level Governance, Oxford, Oxford University Press. Große Hüttemann M. and Knodt M. (2006), “’Diplomatie mit Lokalkolorit’: Die Vertretungen der deutschen Länder in Brüssel und ihre Aufgaben im EU-Entscheidungsprozess”, Jahrbuch des Föderalismus, Vol. 7, pp. 595-605. Hrbek R. (1999), ‘The Effects of EU Integration on German Federalism’, in C. Jeffery (ed), Recasting German Federalism – The Legacies of Unification, London, Pinter. Jeffery C. (1997), “Regional Information Offices in Brussels and Multi-level Governance in the EU: A UK-German Comparison” in C. Jeffery (ed.), The Regional Dimension of the European Union – Towards a Third Level in Europe?, London, Frank Cass. Jeffery C. (1998), “Les Länder allemands et l’Europe: intérêts, stratégies et influence dans les politiques communautaires”, in E. Négrier et B. Jouve (eds.), Que gouvernent les régions d’Europe?, L’Harmattan, Paris, pp. 55-84. Jeffery C. (2000), “Subnational Mobilization and European Integration: Does it Make any Difference?”, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp. 1-23. Jeffery C. (2005), “Regions and the European Union: Letting them In, and Leaving them Alone”, in S. Weatherill and U. Bernitz (eds.), The role of Regions and Sub-National Actors in Europe, Oxford, Hart Publishing. Jeffery C. (2007), “A Regional Rescue of the Nation-State: Changing Regional Perspectives on Europe”, EUSA Tenth Biennial International Conference, Montreal. Loughlin J. (1997), “Representing Regions in Europe: The Committee of the Regions” in Jeffery C. (ed.), The Regional Dimension of the European Union – Towards a Third Level in Europe?, London, Frank Cass. Marks G. (1992), “Structural Policy in the European Community”, in A. Sbragia (ed.), The Political Consequences of 1992 for the European Community, Washington D.C., The Brookings Institution. Marks G. (1993), “Structural Policy and Multilevel Governance in the EU”, in A. Cafruny and G. Rosenthal (eds.), The State of the European Community, New York, Lynne Rienner. Marks G., Haesly R., Mbaye H.A.D. (2002), ‘What Do Subnational Offices Think They Are Doing in Brussels?’, Regional and Federal Studies, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 1-23. Marks G., McAdam D. And Blank K. (1996), “European Integration from the 1980s: State Centric v. Multi-level Governance”, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 34, No. 3, pp. 341-78. Moravcsik A. (1994), “Why the EC Strengthens the State: Domestic Politics and International Cooperation”, Centre for European Studies Working Paper 52, Cambridge, MA: Department of Government, University of Harvard. Streb H. (2007), Supranational Integration, National Federalism and Subnational States: A Constitutional Approach to the Impact of European Integratoin on Territorial Relations in Federal Member States, Thesis for the University of London Degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Politics. Thielemann E.R. (1999), “Institutional limits of a ‘Europe with the Regions’: EC state-aid control meets German federalism”, Journal of European Public Policy, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp.399-418. Tömmel I. (1998) “Transformation of Governance: The European Commission’s Strategy for Creating a ‘Europe of the Regions”, Regional and Federal Studies, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 52-81. Weatherill S. (2005), “The Challenge of the Regional Dimension in the European Union”, in S. Weatherill and U. Bernitz (eds.), The role of Regions and Sub-National Actors in Europe, Oxford, Hart Publishing.