Multilateral Institutions Can Help Attract Significant Private Capital for Infrastructure Financings Through Higher Leverage for their Guarantees -- Mahesh Kotecha What Can "Official" Institutions do to Enhance Infrastructure Financings? The private sector and emerging market countries both value the expertise and neutrality of multilateral institutions to which both look to play a role as an "honest broker". This role could become critical in all phases of infrastructure development - from needs assessment to setting policy objectives, to establishing sector policies, regulation, bidding and concessioning, financing, dispute resolution, etc. It needs to be considered and structured so as to be well understood and easy to use. The private markets value the role of multilateral institutions in infrastructure financings not simply as yet another source of financing but for their important impact on limiting host government misbehavior, whether directly as guarantors or indirectly as participants in the financings. A multilateral institution's participation, even after Argentina, is considered to increase the likelihood that contractual obligations of the host government will be honored. Such a "halo" can take a more direct form when the multilateral is participating through a PCG or a PRG, providing certain explicit credit or political risk cover. Risk mitigation is a role where multilaterals have perhaps a greater competitive edge than in lending. However, with the exception of MIGA, there are no major multilateral institutions for which risk mitigation is their core product. The World Bank, ADB and IFC think of themselves as lenders first and guarantors or risk mitigators second. A key market need is for multilateral institutions to offer risk mitigation in greater abundance and with greater ease of use. Though there is wide agreement that risk mitigation is multilateral institutions' core value added, the risk mitigation instruments that the multilaterals offer - PRGs and PCGs -have been used only to a limited extent. There is no easy explanation of this paradox. First, as MIGA statutes permit guarantees of debt only when there is some equity investment guarantee, this can become a limiting factor though generally MIGA tends to be flexible on what it is prepared to regards as equity. Second, it may be helpful if multilaterals market themselves more effectively, responding swiftly to market inquiries, meeting often and face-to-face with market participants and being more swift in product modifications to meet market needs, and hire professionals from the private sector. Third, it may help multilateral financial institutions to partner with monoline guarantee industry, the most prolific guarantors by far, to offer emerging market cost-effective guarantee products that use multilateral institutions' risk mitigation capabilities to bring transactions from non-investment grade countries up to investment grade so the monolines can guarantee them to the triple-A level. Finally, it is entirely possible that guarantees are just difficult for multilaterals to get excited about since they are subject to the same leverage as for loans, even if contingent risks may be lower than lending risks. The mindset of multilateral institutions such as the World Bank and African Development Bank as that of a lender first and a guarantor second, is an impediment to expanded use of the guarantee capacity for African projects. Two points illustrate this. First, multilateral lenders sometimes believe (though this is not a statutory requirement but a matter of interpretation) that they are required under their articles of agreement to set aside the same amount of capital for each loan as for a guarantee. As the leverage of the World Bank and the regional development banks is one to one (one dollar of loan must be typically be backed by one dollar of capital), their guarantees can be expensive relative to private sector providers, who can apply much greater leverage. Secondly, the Treasury groups of such multilateral lending institutions are often concerned about the potentially inferior trading values for issues they guarantee relative to their straight corporate debt. They fear that poor trading value of guaranteed issues might contaminate the trading levels of their corporate or stand-alone debt issues. However, such fears may or may not be justified, as the markets are generally quite capable of distinguishing between structured or guaranteed and stand-alone or triple-A rated corporate obligations. SCIC believes that the development banks with one to one leverage could increase such leverage to a multiple as high as four times for purposes of guarantees, probably without jeopardizing their triple-A ratings. If they were to do so, and offer better guarantee products in collaboration with the private sector, they could help expand substantially the investments flowing into infrastructure development in the emerging markets. Mahesh Kotecha President August 26, 2004