The myth of choice in education ‘quasi-markets’: The nature and implications of the emergence of private schools in Punjab, Pakistan Renwick Irvine Dissertation MPhil Development Studies Institute of Development Studies 1st September 2004 -2- ABSTRACT Pakistan is experiencing a dramatic transformation in the way basic education services are being delivered due to an unprecedented growth in low-cost private schools. This paper analyses this phenomenon from the perspective of choice in the quasi-market, in which parents have to bear the costs of schooling. It first examines the factors driving the growth of the private sector in Pakistan on the supply side. Secondly, the research assesses how the quasi-market is manifesting itself within a specific environment. Thirdly it explores how choice is perceived from the demand side through investigating parental preferences. This paper shows that poor quality and differentiated access may result from relying on imperfect markets to deliver services in a highly unequal, feudal society. It reveals that choice is a myth for poor families in a non-universal education context such as Pakistan. This poses considerable problems for how government can and should respond. -3- CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES, FIGURES AND MAPS .............................................................................................. 5 LIST OF ANNEXES ........................................................................................................................... 5 LIST OF ACRONYMS AND ABBREVIATIONS ...................................................................................... 6 EXCHANGE RATE (AT TIME OF RESEARCH) ..................................................................................... 6 ACKNOWLEGDEMENTS 7 PREFACE 8 CHAPTER 1: CONTEXT AND TRENDS OF PRIVATE PROVISION IN PAKISTAN 10 1.1 THE POLITICS OF EDUCATION PROVISION IN PAKISTAN: THE SEEDS OF PRIVATE EXPANSION? ................................................................................................................................. 10 1.2 AN ENABLING ENVIRONMENT FOR PRIVATE PROVISION AT THE NATIONAL LEVEL...... 12 1.3 PROMOTING PRIVATE PROVISION AT THE PROVINCIAL LEVEL ...................................... 13 CHAPTER 2: CHOICE IN EDUCATION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS 15 2.1 THE RISE OF THE MARKET IN EDUCATION: THE BASIS FOR CHOICE? ............................ 15 2.1.1. EXPLAINING THE NATURE AND EXPANSION OF PRIVATE SCHOOLS ................................. 16 2.1.2 CHOICE AND RESPONSIVENESS IN EDUCATION QUASI-MARKETS ..................................... 17 2.2 MAKING CHOICES: RATIONAL AND PREDICTABLE OR CONTINGENT AND ARBITRARY? AN ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK ................................................................................................... 19 2.2 COUNTER POSITIONS TO THE RISE OF THE MARKET ....................................................... 21 2.2.1 QUESTIONING THE MARKET IN EDUCATION ...................................................................... 21 2.2.2 ACHIEVING BETTER EDUCATION? VALUE PERSPECTIVES ON QUALITY ............................ 22 2.2.3 WHOSE RIGHTS MATTER IN CHOOSING SCHOOLS? ............................................................ 24 2.2.4 DEBUNKING MARKETS: EQUITY AND THE POLITICS OF EDUCATION PROVISION .............. 25 CHAPTER 3: METHODOLOGY FOR RESEARCHING THE EDUCATION MARKET 27 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 RESEARCHING POLITICS AND POLICIES ............................................................................ 27 SELECTION OF SITES FOR FIELD RESEARCH ..................................................................... 28 CONSTRUCTING THE ‘QUASI-MARKET’ IN THE RESEARCH ............................................. 29 ASSUMPTIONS ..................................................................................................................... 29 EXPLORING SCHOOL RESPONSE IN THE PROVIDER DOMAIN ........................................... 29 EXAMINING CONSUMER PERSPECTIVES............................................................................ 30 STRENGTHS AND LIMITATIONS OF THE RESEARCH.......................................................... 31 CHAPTER 4: POLICY RESPONSES IN A HIGHLY POLITICISED CONTEXT 4.1 4.2 4.3 33 COMMUNITY PARTICIPATION IN THE GOVERNMENT SYSTEM ........................................ 33 LOCAL ELITES AND DEVOLUTION: INCENTIVES FOR SUPPORTING EDUCATION?........... 34 ENCOURAGING PRIVATE SECTOR OR LOSING CONTROL? ............................................... 36 -4- CHAPTER 5: SCHOOL RESPONSE: SUPPLY-SIDE DRIVEN GROWTH OR RESPONDING TO DEMAND? 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.6 UNDERSTANDING RESPONSIVENESS .................................................................................. 39 CHARACTERISTICS OF PRIVATE PROVISION ..................................................................... 39 THE EMERGENCE OF A NEW TYPE OF FOR-PROFIT SCHOOL ........................................... 40 PROFIT-MAKING ENTITIES: INCOME-ENHANCING AS A PRIME CONCERN?.................... 41 SUBSTANTIVE IMPROVEMENT: CHIMERA OR REALITY? ................................................. 45 DECEPTIVE APPEARANCES? .............................................................................................. 47 CHAPTER 6: PERSPECTIVES ON CHOICE: CONSUMER DEMAND? 6.1 6.2 6.3 6.4 6.5 6.5.1 6.5.2 6.6 6.6.1 6.6.2 6.6.3 6.6.4 6.7 6.8 6.9 50 RETHINKING CHOICE ......................................................................................................... 50 DEMAND FOR EDUCATION ACROSS THE SPECTRUM: VALUING EDUCATION .................. 50 SOCIAL DIFFERENTIATION MEDIATING CHOICE AND OPPORTUNITY ............................. 53 PRIVATE SCHOOLS: PROVIDING AN OPPORTUNITY FOR GIRLS? ..................................... 54 CHOOSING BETWEEN OPTIONS: WHO MAKES THE DECISION? ........................................ 56 COST: “A SACRIFICE WE HAVE TO MAKE” ........................................................................ 56 THE CLOSER THE BETTER? THE BENEFITS OF THE PRIVATE SCHOOL NEXT DOOR ............ 58 EXPLORING PARENTAL PERCEPTIONS OF QUALITY ......................................................... 60 PEER-GROUP REFERENCE AND (NON)INFORMATION ......................................................... 60 TEACHERS: GOOD BAROMETERS OF QUALITY? ................................................................. 61 PARENTAL PRIORITIES: DISCIPLINE AND PUNISH OR TEACHING AND LEARNING? ............ 62 MINIMUM FACILITIES: ‘THE CHILDREN CAN BEAR IT’ ...................................................... 64 CHILDREN’S DIFFERING PERSPECTIVES: “A SCHOOL SHOULD LOOK LIKE A SCHOOL” 65 CHOICE: SUBJECT TO EVER-PRESENT TRADE-OFFS ......................................................... 66 THE MYTH OF CHOICE ....................................................................................................... 67 CHAPTER 7: CONCLUSION AND IMPLICATIONS OF THE MYTH OF CHOICE 7.1 7.2 7.3 7.4 39 69 IMPLICATIONS FOR GOVERNMENT PROVISION AND POLICY ........................................... 70 IMPLICATIONS FOR POTENTIAL ENGAGEMENT WITH PRIVATE SCHOOLS ...................... 71 IMPLICATIONS FOR DEMAND-SIDE CHOICE ...................................................................... 71 WIDER SIGNIFICANCE OF THE MYTH OF CHOICE ............................................................. 72 BIBLIOGRAPHY 74 -5- List of tables, figures and maps Table 1: Gross enrolment ratio in Pakistan in primary schools: change in the 1990s 11 Table 2: Typology of potential school responses to the quasi-market 18 Figure 1: Theorising constructions of choice in the quasi-market through spatial domains Figure 2: Perspectives of quality spectrum 20 Map 1: Sheikhupura: location within Pakistan 28 Table 3: Sample characteristics by school type 31 Table 4: Taxonomy of providers catering to the urban and rural poor 40 Table 5: Summary statistics from mapping by school type 42 23 List of Annexes Annex 1 List of persons interviewed 78-80 Annex 2 School mapping with principals questionnaire Annex 3 Education officials semi-structured interview pro-forma Annex 4 Parents’ focus group discussion guiding questions Annex 5 PRA with children guidelines Annex 6 Teachers’ focus group discussion guiding questions 88 Annex 7 Income, expenditure and profit of a typical middle private school 89 81 82-83 84 85-87 -6- List of acronyms and abbreviations ADB BPS CRC DCO DFID DO DEO EDO FBS FGD FS FT GBHS GBPS GGHS GGPS GoP HT JICA MDGs MoE MSU MT MS P-ERSP PIHS PPP PRA NFE NGO Rs. Skp. SMC SSC STR UC UNDP UNESCO UPE Asian Development Bank Basic Pay Scale Convention of the Rights of the Child District Coordination Officer Department for International Development District Officer District Education Officer Executive District Officer Federal Bureau of Statistics Focus Group Discussion Female student Female teacher Government Boys High School Government Boys Primary School Government Girls High School Government Girls Primary School Government of Pakistan Head Teacher Japan International Cooperation Agency Millennium Development Goals Ministry of Education (Pakistan) Multi Donor Support Unit Male teacher Male student Punjab Education Sector Reform Plan Pakistan Integrated Household Survey Public-Private Partnership Participatory Rural Appraisal Non-Formal Education (Centre) Non Governmental Organisation Pakistani Rupess Sheikhupura District, Punjab School Management Committee Secondary School Certificate Student Teacher Ratio Union Council United Nations Development Programme United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organisation Universal Primary Education Exchange rate (at time of research) Approx. Rs. 100 = £ 1.00 -7- ACKNOWLEGDEMENTS The people who contributed in the process of researching and commenting on this paper are too numerous to mention. Thanks must go to all those who gave their time and experience in interviews and discussion groups. Saeed-ul-Hassan and Naima Saeed helped at every stage of the research in Pakistan, acting as collaborators, translators, and friends. Mohammad Younas and Abid Hussain Gill from Sudhaar-ITA deserve a special mention as they provided not only a floor to sleep on for six weeks but imparted their knowledge of local issues. Amna Wirk and Saima Zarina helped facilitate the PRA exercises, and provided many tips for working with children in Pakistan. Baela Jamil (ITA) was a constant source of support and constructive criticism. Mark Poston (DFIDPakistan) made context-relevant observations. DFID-Pakistan provided financial support for a study, out of which this emerged. Thanks must go to my supervisor Ramya Subrahmanian and to Robert Chambers, Pauline Rose, Alex Shankland, Joanna Wheeler and Emma Williams for comments and advice. Needless to say, all errors are my own and the opinions expressed herein reflect that of the author. -8- PREFACE Pakistan is experiencing a dramatic transformation in the way basic education services are being delivered. The size of the private sector in education has more than doubled in the 1990s, encompassing, at a conservative estimate, 30% of education intuitions by the end of the decade, the majority at primary level (MSU 2002). Concurrently, enrolment in the government schools has been declining (MSU 2002). Yet poverty in Pakistan, over the same period, has been growing (Hussein et al 2003: 45-47). The conundrum of why and in what way private school provision has expanded is explored in this paper by examining choice through the nexus of supply and demand dynamics in the local environment.1 Primary school level in the province of Punjab, where the growth has been most marked, is the focus of this paper, based on empirical research conducted over a six week period (Andrabi et al 2002). This unheralded expansion seems to take to an extreme the global pattern of marketisation, the adoption of free market practices in the running of schools, and privatisation, of both school ownership and administration, in education (Kwong 2000; Kitaev 1999; Carnoy 1999; ADB 2003). The theoretical underpinnings of the rise of the market are premised on improving efficiency, enhancing choice and delivering better quality education. The policy context in Pakistan of promoting public private partnerships in the state system and encouraging market entry to private schools appears to lie firmly within this trend. However, the development of a quasi-market in education provision, which is predicated on parents paying for school and making choices between options, could have serious consequences (Kitaev 1999). This paper shows that poor quality and differentiated access may result from relying on imperfect markets to deliver services in a highly unequal, quasi-feudal society. The central research question which this research addresses is unpacking the myth of choice in a context where universal education provision is non-existent and poor people lack the ability, either financial or otherwise, to exert choice. To do so, the paper explores three interrelated questions of why private schools have expanded, what 1 Private schools are taken to be for-profit institutions which are owned and managed privately. -9- characteristics they have and how they provide a service to parents. It first examines the factors driving the growth of the private sector in Pakistan on the supply side, requiring analysis of the prevailing policy environment and political economy of education. Secondly, the research assesses how the quasi-market is manifesting itself within a specific environment, and what characteristics it takes. Thirdly it seeks to understand how choice is perceived from the demand side through investigating parental preferences. By focusing on two overlapping domains, of producers (school ‘owners’) and consumers (parents and children), synergies and dissonances in perspective are highlighted. How they intersect to create particular patterns of market demand and supply have consequences for the type of education offered, to whom it is accessible and why it takes the form it does. The issues that have been uncovered in the empirical work, although based on a limited sample size, reveal unexpected findings, making it contribution to knowledge on the implications of extensive private school provision both in Pakistan and for other developing countries. The paper is divided into six chapters. Chapter one tracks the historical trends and maps the current education policy framings in Pakistan. Chapter two analyses the rise of the market and the existent critiques, offering a framework through which the growth and implications of private provision can be understood. Chapter three summarises the innovative methodological approach utilised to explore these dimensions. Chapter four unpicks the conventional understandings of the market by showing how the policy framings play out in the local environment. Chapter five explores how schools respond to the market from the supply side. Chapter six unpacks the perspectives on choice from the demand side, juxtaposing parental choice with the experience of children in the classroom. Chapter seven concludes, drawing together the threads of the argument to provide some tentative policy recommendations and highlight key areas for further research. - 10 - CHAPTER 1: Context and trends of private provision in Pakistan The availability of school choices are determined by the nature of education markets. Markets do not develop in a lacuna but are subject to historical developments and the present educational supply-demand dynamics mediated by policy (Kitaev 1999: 61). This chapter explores the context and trends of education provision in Pakistan. 1.1 The politics of education provision in Pakistan: the seeds of private expansion? The historical idiosyncrasies of Pakistan and education policies adopted at various stages have deeply affected the nature of private provision (Bengali 1999). At Independence in 1947, Pakistan was, in essence, an artificial country carved out of British India (Ziring 2003). State-driven mass education, as a mechanism to consolidate a country made up of diverse ethnic groups and different languages was targeted as a priority in education planning (Bengali 1999). However, insufficient political will to effectively address the question of providing mass education resulted in inadequate public provision (Warwick and Reimers 1995; Hoodbhoy 1998). Private provision, by contrast was substantial in the period prior to the nationalisation of schools (1972-73) by Zulfikar Ali Bhutto (Jamil 2003; Jimenez and Tan 1987). Although this policy was subsequently reversed under General Zia ul Haq, private schools took time to respond to new opportunities (ibid.). The policy of promoting and mixing secular and religious education under the Zia regime, together with the influx of Afghan refugees, enabled madaris to flourish alongside private schools (Nayyer 1998).2 Jimenez and Tan (1987) tracked this nascent growth in private provision, but did not foresee the exponential rise in for-profit private education that has subsequently occurred. Whilst the expenditure on education remained low in the 1990s (at about 2.7% GNP throughout the 1990s, compared to an average of 3.8% GNP for other low income 2 Religious schools in Pakistan, in Arabic, madrassah (pl madaris), have also grown exponentially from the 1980s, though it is thought for different reasons (Nayyer 1998). These are included in the study as they provide an alternative for parents, but remain on the periphery of the discussion due to the limited sample size. - 11 - countries during the same period), Pakistan has one of the highest birth rates in the world, with the average family having six children (Lloyd et al 2002). The result is that the population of 5-14 year olds has grown from 20.3 million in 1980 to 36.8 million in 2000 (ibid.). Although official figures, notoriously problematic in Pakistan, suggest that gross enrolment has increased during this period (table 1), given that over a quarter of children never attend school, considerable shortfalls remain. Table 1: Gross enrolment ratio in Pakistan in primary schools: change in the 1990s3 Year Gross Enrolment Ratio Both Male Female 1990 60.7 81.5 39 2000/2001 73 84 62 Source: UNESCO Institute for Statistics (http://www.uis.unesco.org) Poverty has been recognised as a key constraint to limiting school participation, with 35% of the population living below the poverty line and 15% on the margins (Lloyd et al 2002). Social demand for education was also considered low (Gazdar 1999). In spite of this, it seems likely that supply, through government schools, has been outstripped by demand, as private school growth demonstrates. The mushrooming of alternative provision throughout the 1990s is unprecedented. According to Pakistan Integrated Household Survey data, in 1983 there were only 3,300 private primary and secondary schools in the four main provinces, yet by 2000 this had increased over ten-fold (Andrabi et al 2002). Moreover, from being a predominately urban phenomenon in the 1980s according to Jimenez and Tan (1987), recent evidence suggests that private education provision is penetrating rural areas, especially in the Punjab (Andrabi et al 2002). Punjab been subject to the highest growth out of all provinces, with over 32% of primary school students enrolled in private schools (Alderman et al 2001; MSU 2002). A recent survey indicates that there are approximately 2,700 government and 3,400 private institutions providing education in Sheikhupura District, the focus-area of this study (Punjab EMIS, forthcoming). The 3 Net enrolment figures are unavailable, but are likely to reveal an even bleaker picture as to the state of education in Pakistan. - 12 - majority of these schools are low-cost, small private schools which appear to be catering to all socio-economic echelons (Andrabi et al 2002). However, it is unlikely that this kind of exponential growth can be attributed solely to excess demand. Politically, little has changed in Pakistan as Heward (1999) asserts that “despite fifty years of independence, Pakistan’s democracy is fragile, its power centres controlled by tiny feudal, military and industrial elites”. A rigid hierarchical administrative structure in the education bureaucracy predominates. As a result there seems to have been a collective sigh of fatigue at trying to make state education work, the problems of which have been extensively documented; corruption, bureaucratic bottlenecks, patronage appointments of teachers, strong yet conservative teacher unions, teacher absenteeism, ghost schools, poor quality of facilities and missing facilities to name but a few (Warwick and Reimers 1995). Investment during the 1990s was pushed through the Social Action Programmes (SAP-I and SAP-II); widely recognised as having failed to meet their original objectives, school provision remains inadequate (Gazdar 1999; interview Education Consultant 29/04/05). This is borne out in a low internal efficiency (high repetition and drop-out rates), pointing to the poor standards of government schools (UNESCO 2000). Therefore the limitations of the public system appear to have also prompted the growth of private schools. 1.2 An enabling environment for private provision at the National level Education in Pakistan is firmly on the policy agenda at national level. Progressive policy work undertaken in recent years, manifesting itself in the Education For All National Policy agenda (Ministry of Education 2003), coupled with the PRSP and 2001 Local Government Ordinances for devolution, has thrown up multiple options to reform a moribund state education system (MFP 2001). However, the influence of the World Bank in the education sector is shifting the discourse to promoting private alternatives: most of the recent studies on private provision have been funded by or attached to the Bank (Alderman et al 1999 and 2002; Andrabi et al 2002; Burnett 2002; Kardar 2001; MSU - 13 - 2002).4 Public-private partnership (PPP) is the new yet ill-defined mantra heard reverberating within the policy environment as a result (GoP 2004). Outlined in the national policy is “a strategic role” for the private sector: what this might be in practice, however, remains to be seen (Jamil 2003; GoP 2004).5 1.3 Promoting private provision at the Provincial level The Government of Punjab has, over the last two years, made significant efforts to increase provision of government schooling and augment community participation in the running of schools (interview provincial official 07/06/04).6 The setting up of school councils or school management committees (SMCs) is an attempt to involve communities in supporting the local government schools (Khan 2003). The problem of a lack of state responsiveness to local demands still remains, however. Resultantly, the government is looking to divest, delegate and devolve government involvement in at least the direct provision of services, while providing an encouragement to the private sector.7 The Punjab Education Sector Reform Plan (P-ERSP), the current policy framework, has earmarked funds allocated per district for government school improvement. This has developed alongside devolution to district level to facilitate more efficient service delivery (Jamil 2003).8 The P-ESRP has taken steps to encourage private provision by providing a package of incentives which includes the provision of land free of cost or at concessional rates in rural areas; utilities such as electricity and gas assessed at noncommercial rates; a liberal grant of charter; exemption of custom duties on import of 4 Significant multilateral and bilateral donor investment and a pro-market Government appear to be pushing reform down this path. 5 One example is the new provincial and national Education Foundations, designed to enhance private sector involvement, but have struggled to make a significant impact (interview government officials 16/06/04 and 07/06/04). 6 Education policy is largely determined at Provincial level, rather than Federal. 7 Programmes such as “Adopt-a-school”, in which NGOs manage government schools, and the Community Participation Programme (CPP), which requires the community to run upgraded high schools in the afternoon on government school premises, can be seen as delegation by franchise (Najam 2003). See Savas (2000) for a discussion of these forms of privatisation. 8 Devolution is attempting to shift responsibility for delivering services from provincial to lower levels. District, and sub-district, tehsil and union councils level have been reformed to create new opportunities for political representation and power sharing (Nadvi and Robinson 2004). However, devolution is also about creating a constituency for the incumbent President Musharraf, following the coup d’etat in 1999 (interview education consultant 15/05/04). - 14 - educational equipment; and exemption of 50% income tax to private sector institutions for faculty, management and support staff (GoP 2003). The devolution programme, encouragement to the private sector and community participation are conflated in policy thinking, forming a logic for less direct government involvement (GoP 2004). How these three policy framings, discernible at the macro and meso levels, play out at the local level are explored in chapter 4. In order to explain the rationale for adopting pro-private policies, they need to be situated within broader international trends. - 15 - CHAPTER 2: Choice in education: a framework for analysis It is no coincidence that Pakistan is facing a transformation in terms of how educational services are delivered: it is a reflection of global shifts towards privatisation and marketisation as “it is now increasingly difficult to understand education in any context without reference to the global forces that influence policy and practice” (Crossly 2000 cited in Apple, 2001: 409). This chapter tracks the rise of the market and unpacks how choice and competition should operate. A framework for analysing choice in Pakistan is subsequently developed and the limitations of choice in a non-universal education context examined. 2.1 The rise of the market in education: the basis for choice? Education provision, previously delivered by private actors, became subject to statedriven control over the 20th century as it became recognised as playing a pivotal role in national and economic development, especially in newly independent states in the postcolonial era (Brown et al 1997; Green 1997). Yet in recent decades, the idea of statedelivered universal education provision has been challenged from two directions (Brown et al 1997). Firstly, as low public spending and tight fiscal policies became the norm in economic policy in the 1990s, “the cornerstone of New Right education policy has been the introduction of market competition into all the education sectors” (Brown et al, 1997: 21). Secondly, the state was seen as failing to deliver appropriate services efficiently due to pernicious state monopoly (Offe 1984). As a solution, markets are heralded as being “natural and neutral, and governed by effort and merit” (Apple 2001: 413): parental choice is a central tenet of the education market. The rise of market-based education policies originated in Western countries which had already secured universal coverage (Carnoy 1999) but is being exported to developing countries, such as Pakistan, where universalism is a still a distant goal (Gazdar 1999). As a result, education is “increasingly considered a quasi-market (Levacic 1995) requiring families and communities to pay for education – directly or indirectly – as a social service” (Kitaev 1999: 41). By purchasing education as a commodity, parents (not children, importantly) are considered to have a ‘choice’, based on school selection in the - 16 - quality and quantity (i.e. number of years) of the service. Moreover, as the market has shifted the construction of citizens from being welfare beneficiaries to contributing consumers (Gaventa and Valderrama 1999), individual responsibilities of parents tend to be emphasised rather than common entitlements or state guarantees in accessing education. Atomised choice between schools, determined by price, is the outcome. This appears paradoxical given the prevailing international focus on achieving the Millennium Development Goal (MDG) of Universal Primary Education (UPE) by 2015. The international debates over UPE revolve around financing (UNESCO 2002): at the national levels the focus is on increased private sector involvement, the creation of internal and external markets in education and promoting community participation to plug resource gaps (World Bank 2003b; Mundy 2001; Klees 2002). Bringing services closer to the poor through decentralisation (Lauglo 1995) and enhancing ownership over schools through community participation (Bray 2000) are increasingly being conflated with private provision (Whitty et al 1998; World Bank 2003a). Private provision, governed by market principles, is designed to bring multiple benefits: efficiency improvements through competition, a removal of market distortions created by the state monopoly, increase cost effectiveness of schooling, and ultimately improve student performance who (or whose parents) value their education more because they are paying for it (Jimenez and Lockheed 1995). This assumption, based on principal-agent theory, is that benefit is obtained from a “separation of purchaser from provider and an element of choice between the providers” by circumventing the state (Levacic 1995, cited in Whitty et al 1998; World Bank 2003a). What choice actually exists, and how it has developed, is vital for understanding whether the expected benefits materialise. 2.1.1. Explaining the nature and expansion of private schools At this juncture, a clearer definition of what constitutes ‘private’ schools needs to be made. Schools can be private in terms of ownership, management and in a major share of funding and expenditure (Kitaev 1999: 43-44), yet as Bray (1997) points out, ‘privatisation’ can span a very wide spectrum of schools, including for-profit and not-for- - 17 - profit types. Religious, NGO and community schools are likely have different characteristics to profit-motivated private schools (Kitaev 1999). This paper focuses on low cost for-profit schools, the major growth area in Pakistan. Explanations for the expansion of private provision may be due to both demand and supply side factors, as illustrated in the case of Pakistan (Kitaev, 1999: 59). On the demand side, two distinct but overlapping rationales can be discerned; firstly, un-met demand from gaps in access and coverage; and secondly, diversified demand of parents for particular schooling conditions, values and quality. On the supply side, three causes are plausible: firstly, a redundant qualified teaching force creating a potential specific supply; secondly, efforts by profit-making school managers focused on specific target groups of population; and thirdly, as a result of inadequate public supply or a deliberate government policy to reduce pressure upon the existing schools. Several of these reasons may overlap. The reasons behind the expansion, moreover, determine to a large degree what characteristics private provision takes. Thus, it is important to understand why these markets have developed in context in order to arrive at some conclusions about what, if anything needs to or can be done about them. Government response to this phenomenon varies between restriction and promotion (Kitaev 1999). Most governments strike a balance between tighter control to maintain standards (through curriculum and evaluation) and lighter regulation to enable the private sector to flourish (Tooley 1999). In Pakistan, private schools are being positively encouraged by providing incentives and removing barriers to market entry (Jamil 2003) while excessive regulation and bureaucratic controls, which stifle private provision, are being removed (Kardar 2001). This is because private provision in Pakistan is seen to be providing a ‘choice’ for even poor families (Andrabi et al 2001). 2.1.2 Choice and responsiveness in education quasi-markets The idea of choice, the focal point of this paper, is inextricably linked to the functioning of the market. Gintis (1996) outlines several preconditions of the existence of an effective system of school choice and with it the effectiveness of promoting markets. - 18 - Choice is effective only if there are several alternative suppliers available to a significant proportion of families. Moreover, consumers need to be able to accurately assess the quality of the goods and services they purchase. Thirdly, consumers must be the best judge of their needs and these needs are reflected in their options. Finally, a competitive system is socially efficient if the good is a ‘private good’. Through this, choice is shown to result from the nexus of both demand-side issues and the ability to respond to this demand on the supply side. Response to demand operates in two main ways in a competitive environment: firstly the creation of new institutions or redefinition of existing ones to cater for unmet needs and preferences, thereby providing alternatives, discussed above (Kitaev 1999). Secondly, internal change within schools to attract and retain pupils occurs. This can be categorised by the typology outlined below (Woods 1994). Table 2: Typology of potential school responses to the quasi-market School responses Competitive responses Objective To increase or maintain number of children at the school Substantive change Attract students through quality improvements Environment scanning Understand consumer demand and recognising market niche of school Promotional activity Activities to raise profile of school to attract students Income enhancing and efficiency-incrementing To maximise the income from revenue streams and rationalise expenditure Political responses Lobbying at local level for changes to rules etc. Collaborative responses Working together (Source: Adapted from Woods 1994: 125) The behaviour of private school owners is influenced by the market, as funding is demand-driven. They try to understand what parents want, presenting and promoting their schools accordingly. Moreover, owners attempt to enhance their income and improve the efficiency of the school by managing their staff better, thereby retaining and developing a competitive edge as they have autonomy over decisions (Chubb and Moe 1990). They may also use political connections as a mechanism to access funds, lobby for - 19 - change of, or even circumvent regulation. The collaborative aspect means joining forces (with other providers) to complement each other, perhaps even providing services together. Whether private schools in Pakistan respond in this manner is explored in Chapter 5. It is upon satisfying these assumptions of choice and competition that the advantages of the market system are hung, which are critiqued below. A framework for analysis is constructed to show how the choice in the quasi-market can be understood. 2.2 Making choices: rational and predictable or contingent and arbitrary? An analytical framework Parental ability to exercise choice is critical to the functioning of the market. Quasimarkets in education are based on rational choice assumptions, yet as this paper will show, questions of choice are not driven by the neat individual rational calculus of classical economics, as it entails “messy, multidimensional, intuitive and seemingly irrational or non-rational elements of choice” (Gerwitz et al, 1995: 6). Choice of what, in terms of the availability and quality of alternatives, and for whom, are of prime importance. Whilst certain assumptions can be made as to what significant factors, either directive or contingent, might be important for parents, they will be both contextuallyspecific and heterogeneous. In quasi-markets, children will tend to “attend the school which is nearest and the most affordable” (Kitaev 199: 101). Choice is dependent on the resources of the family and the availability of schooling options. However, quality and perceptions of quality of schooling, and what education is believed to deliver, is an important variable in choosing. Expected benefits are not only direct material outcomes but also predicated on social expectations and aspirations. In Pakistan, caste, class, gender, and birth order of child may all be contingent factors to school choice. Informational factors, relationships and dominant discourses about education play a key role. As Gerwitz et al suggest it is “(o)nly by relating choice, response and distributional outcomes together in particular local market settings will it begin to be possible to - 20 - understand, evaluate and theorise the education market as a social, educational and political phenomenon” (1995: 3). In order to do this a spatial approach is helpful, as represented in figure 1. This portrays not discrete domains but interlocking and interdependent spheres that shape choice. The overlapping area represents the confluence of all the factors in decision-making outlined above, and potentially unexpected others, dictating choice, or rather, as will be shown, the myth of choice. Figure 1: Theorising constructions of choice in the quasi-market through spatial domains Macro environment Micro environment of locality Consumer domain Factors in Producer domain (Parents) decision-making (Schools) The consumer domain represents parents as the active (and quasi-independent) chooser within the household, in which intra-household power dynamics shape decision-making (Kabeer 1994).9 Providers are schools, or rather education options to which parents in a locality could conceive of sending their children.10 Likely responses have been expounded above in table 2. This diagram indicates that both schools and parents must be situated within the mirco and macro environments. The micro domain is the locality, catchment area or community, which has the traces of history, geography, local politics, 9 The very concept of the nuclear household is recognised as an artificial construct. However, for simplicity, it will be used here. 10 As a caveat, further options such as child labour and not sending the children to school are important considerations. It is estimated that 9-10 million children of school-going age are out-of-school in Pakistan (interview Ameena Khan, ILO 15/06/04). This is beyond the scope of the current paper, and subject to different debates. - 21 - socio-economic situation, as well as the socio-cultural aspects within an area or community. Far from being a neat division, it is contested, with communities being neither homogenous nor easily defined. Here, particular policy framings get played out: in Pakistan, the emphasis on encouraging community participation in government schools, devolution and the promotion of private options all heavily influence the local availability and quality of schools. There exists a significant overlap between the community and the market, as all viable options for schooling (the market) are located within a particular community, especially in rural areas. This implies that not only are they mutually-dependent but also that they are likely to reflect the politics and inequalities within the community. The macro environment encapsulates the broader policy framework regarding education, from the rise of the market and the pressure to achieve international targets, to the availability of concessions, incentives and the regulatory environment which have been explained in chapter 1. Through this framework, it will be possible to explore how parental ability to exert choice is determined within a non-universal context such as Pakistan. 2.2 Counter positions to the rise of the market Despite the strong claims for promoting the market in education, two different types of argument exist. One is an economist’s argument that is not critical of markets per se, but questions whether markets exist for education, given its public/social good elements. The second raises more fundamental questions about how markets operate from a sociological perspective. It raises questions as to whether private schools necessarily provide better quality, if parents are the best judges of their children’s needs and how education markets can operate in highly politicised environments. 2.2.1 Questioning the market in education Education can be seen ‘quasi-public good’, rather than a private good, which has spillover benefits as well as private returns (Colclough 1996). Accordingly, the state should invest due to the externalities or social benefits of education (Jimenez and Lockheed 1995). Investing in human resources is recognised as a crucial aspect to poverty - 22 - alleviation (ibid.). This is especially true at primary level when the social returns are highest (and private returns less significant). The market, by contrast, cannot guarantee the provision of all goods, as a right on a fair basis to all citizens (Colclough 1996). At the macro level, privatisation may result in “a highly differentiated school-structure which closely reflects the relative prosperity of different communities and geographical areas” (Colclough 1993: 175). At the household level, many studies show that “income and level of education of parents turn out to be significant determinate of education spending propensity” (Kitaev 1999: 104). Purchasing power allows parents to select the ‘better’ schools for their children: but some parents lack the resources to choose (Fowler 1992 cited in Kitaev 1999: 106). The ghettoisation following this exodus of more affluent children from the “poorer” schools is a serious problem that needs to be tackled not at the local level but nationally (Kwong 2000: 92). Some have argued that the demand for education is inelastic (less than unity) with respect to marginal increases in price (Jimenez 1987 cited in Colclough 1996). However this fails to take into account the differing elasticities among user groups, as for poor families the demand is highly elastic, thus a marginal increase in costs creates a tendency to withdraw from the purchase of that good. As a result, education is likely to be undersupplied by the market and access to schools will be uneven (Gintis 1996). 2.2.2 Achieving better education? Value perspectives on quality Exponents of private schools argue that it improves the quality of education provided, and increases the choice that parents have (Chubb and Moe 1990). Potential conflict between commercial considerations and wider educational and social concerns exists in promoting private schools, however.11 Merely aggregating individual preference may not lead to a better education system, which plays a role in cohering the social and transforming society (Green 1997; Kumar forthcoming). This appears to corroborate Whitty et al’s (1998: 97) analysis that “(g)overnment policy, at the state or national level, is about overseeing performance and consolidating cultural preferences. A proliferation of alternative schools will not only be more difficult to monitor but foster modes of - 23 - teaching and learning that produce ‘inappropriate’ outcomes”. Where the expansion of private schools is unplanned, leading to “privatisation by default” (Bray 1996 cited in Kitaev 1999), and the government lacks requisite control for securing quality, competition and choice may have deleterious results. Understanding values of quality is the core of education and imbues parental decisionmaking (Gerwitz et al 1995). Values are shaped by an interpretative process which continually absorbs and responds to the surrounding environment, both immediate (family, locale) and more distant (media, policy environment), making the understanding of how choice is made, and how quality in education is defined a reflexive process.12 Therefore value perspectives of education dictate the aspects of quality emphasised. Quality is notoriously hard to pin down (Kumar forthcoming). Thus, rather than determine quality measurements this paper adopts a value perspective approach to quality along a subjective spectrum (Woods et al 1998). The instrumental-academic perspective places an emphasis on the acquisition of particular skills resulting in quantifiable outcomes, in which education is seen as a means to a particular end. Conversely, the intrinsic-personal, or social ‘value’ perspective, encompasses the amalgam of factors which affect the development of a child, such as behavioural, atmospheric, etc. Figure 2 outlines these perspectives as a spectrum, along which it should be possible to situate discourses in policies and opinions of school owners, parents, children and teachers alike.13 Figure 2: Perspectives of quality spectrum Instrumental-academic Output-orientated Qualification focused Intrinsic-personal value Process-orientated Whole child focused The motivation driving private schools is contentious as “even proprietors of entrepreneurial schools are reluctant to admit that they are motivated primarily by profit” (Kwong 1997 cited in Kitaev 1999). 12 As Giddens (1984) points out, the recursive character of modern life, in which the medium and outcome of social life are irrevocably intertwined, makes identifying causality and direction of causality problematic. 13 Discourse in here understood as “a specific ensemble of ideas, concepts, and categorizations that are produced, reproduced and transformed in a particular set of practices and through which meaning is given to physical and social realities (Hajer 1995 cited in Keely and Scoones 1999: 24). 11 - 24 - These distinctions are of prime importance in understanding which aspects of quality are being ‘improved’ as a result of competition. Private schools have been documented to respond to the demands of parents for academic results, who are paying for education, skewing it towards the instrumental-academic end of the spectrum (Gerwitz et al 1995). However, parental ‘satisfaction’ is a relative notion, crucially linked to expectations and aspirations that are mediated through symbols and meanings (Rampal 2004; Schwalbe et al 2000). Thus how quality is construed needs to be unpacked. This implies that ‘what values’ as much as ‘whose values’ are fundamental questions in determining quality. 2.2.3 Whose rights matter in choosing schools? The right balance of rights is satisfied by no education system. The rights of parents to choose, based on individual freedom, counterpoised to the rights of citizens to education with the duty of public authority in providing free and comprehensive education is the crux of this tension.14 Nuancing this, the rights of the child imply that their ‘best interest’ be protected, but who will protect them better, the state or their parents? 15 Market theory assumes that individuals are the best judges of what is in their own interest; parents, however, are not clearly and indisputably the best judges of their child’s interests (Alder 1993). Adopting a rights perspective to the private schools issue, the fine balance between preserving the rights of parents and children to choose with the entitlement of every child to a ‘good’ school needs to be achieved. Whether markets or the state balance this better is the issue discussed below. According to the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (1948), Article 26(iii) states that “Parents have a prior right to choose the kind of education that shall be given to their children”. Equally, however, Article 26(i) states that “Education shall be free, at least in the elementary and fundamental stages” (Available from http://www.un.org/Overview/rights.html) 14 15 Article 3 of the Convention on the Rights of the Child (CRC) of 1989, to which Pakistan is a signatory, indicates that the child’s best interests should be protected at all times (available at http://www.unicef.org/crc/crc.htm). - 25 - 2.2.4 Debunking markets: Equity and the politics of education provision Markets are, as Ball (1990: 8) observes, “neither natural nor neutral phenomenon, they are socially and politically constructed”. The actual constructions reflect the power and interests of different actors in determining its distribution (Ball 1990). The market is built upon assumptions that are blind to deep-running inequalities which insidiously constrain choice and options. To reveal this requires that “both the formal properties of the market and informal arrangements within that market” be understood (Lauder et al 1994, cited in Gerwitz et al 1995: 5). Social geography, local history, politics, existing social inequalities, cultural and social norms, class and religion may all act to distort choice (by providers) and mediate choices (by consumers) along unexpected avenues. Deeper structural inequalities in society more broadly are also important. National education policy, enmeshed in complex political economy relationships, could be weighted against government provision as a result. Governments are likely to pursue policies which reward the interest groups upon which they depend for power and serve their own interests (Colclough 1996:606). Supporting private schools may do this. Moreover, the emphasis in Pakistan on community participation in government schools and the instigation of a programme of devolution, explored in chapter 4, can also be seen as a reflection of political interests of the elites rather than a concern for improving access and quality to government schools. The history of social provision indicates that “social equity and high levels of universal social provision have only been secured and retained when those services are available to and used by the middle class. It is the sharp elbow of the middle class…that has ensured good quality social provision” (Deacon, 2000: 38). When this ‘sharp elbow’ is removed, the likelihood of achieving better statedelivered education diminishes and the incentive for mobilising collective action to improve the quality of education for all rescinds. Inequalities can be reproduced through school choice in different ways. Credentialisim and the acquisition of ‘cultural capital’ in the form of academic certificates and social connections, can be seen as central to reproducing middle-class privilege (Brown et al 1997: 15). The different abilities of parents to transmit their cultural capital to their children by making good choices, based on their own knowledge, connections and - 26 - background is heightened by private school options (Whitty et al 1998). When this ‘choice’ can be bought, the effects are potentially even more divisive. The ideology of competitive individualism, compounded by the emergence of private schools, places a pressure on parents who can afford schooling to maintain the social boundaries (Schwalbe et al 2000: 430). Those who are unable to do so fall further behind. The interactive processes that reproduce inequality, Schwalbe et al (2000) argue, are not a static result of class, caste, race or gender differences. Rather, as “inequality cannot be understood apart from the processes that produce and sustain it” (Schwalbe et al 2000: 420), the actions of parents, school owners, officials and the configuration of mirco-level political networks are consequential. Private schooling not only provides an entry to higher social status and opportunities, but actually serves to reinforce and demarcate these divisions. The process of defensive othering may occur, whereby “subordinate groups seek safety or advantage by othering those in their own group” by adopting the symbols and belief system of the more powerful (Schwalbe et al 2000: 425). By sending children to private schools, parents seek to distinguish themselves from others in the community, thereby inadvertently aiding the reproduction of a larger system of inequality. Both mediated entry to, and defining quality of schools can have the effect of othering and boundary maintenance (ibid. 422). The wide-ranging debates on choice and private provision have tended to be dominated by research undertaken in a Northern context. The relevance of these arguments for a developing country such as Pakistan needs to be carefully examined. The empirical messiness of a case study is used to illuminate how choice - and the elements which feed into that choice - is understood, internalised, reflected and refracted through different domains. The next chapter explains how the empirical research was designed to capture this. - 27 - CHAPTER 3: Methodology for researching the education market This chapter outlines the methodological approach employed, including the reasons for using one a study and the data collection methods used. It also includes a brief discussion of the strengths and limitations of the study. The key questions surrounding the myth of choice are overlapping, as shown in figure 1. It first examines the factors driving the growth of the private sector in Pakistan on the supply side, requiring analysis of the prevailing policy environment and political economy of education. Secondly, the research assesses how the quasi-market is manifesting itself within a specific environment, and what characteristics it takes. Thirdly it seeks to understand how choice is perceived from the demand side through investigating consumer perceptions. A semi-inductive approach was taken, in which already-identified areas of interest were complemented by lassitude for new and unexpected results to emerge. During the data analysis stage, these three sections were cross-interrogated to suggest how choice is being constructed and point to the implications this may have for equity and quality. 3.1 Researching politics and policies Literature review from secondary sources and policy documents provided the background information to the growth of private education and the political economy surrounding it. This was complemented by open-ended interviews with knowledgeable people working in the education field in Pakistan as well as those from the NGO sector (annex 1). In order to explore the policy assumptions in context detailed semi-structured interviews were undertaken with education, administrative and elected officials at Federal, Provincial, District and Union Council levels (annex 1). These aimed to see how attitudes towards private schools, and the practical implications of this in terms of regulation and support, were being manifested (questions in annex 2). Moreover, given recent public sector reform through devolution, generating an understanding of roles and responsibilities was pertinent in these interviews. - 28 - 3.2 Selection of sites for field research Gauging how producers respond to this environment and, subsequently, how choices are made, a qualitative approach was adopted which focused on two localities, one urban and one rural within Sheikhupura District, Punjab (see Map 1). Sheikhupura, in Central Punjab, was selected as an area with rapid growth in private provision (Punjab EMIS forthcoming), but representative of Punjab in terms of education and literacy, as it is ranked 16th out of the 34 districts of Punjab in literacy rates (Government of Punjab at www.punjab.gov.pk/education/.htm). Map 1: Sheikhupura: location within Pakistan Accessed from www.encarta.msn.co.uk Moreover, having both rural and urbanised areas a suitable comparison could be made between them. One week was spent in an informal scoping survey to gain an overall picture of education provision within the district, in which many providers were visited - 29 - across two different tehsils (sub-division of district). It also provided an opportunity to test the methodology across different areas and with different sets of providers in order to hone the questions within the local context. The process for selecting the locations was deductive and relied to a certain degree on local knowledge.16 Locations were selected which had a ‘typical’ mix of provision, including a functioning government school which enabled a comparison to be made between them.17 1998 Census data confirmed the socio-economic profile of the communities. Gharibabad is an urban slum community on the outskirts of Sheikhupura town. Makki 460 is a village located approximately one hour drive from Sheikhupura, and 20 minutes away from the main road. 3.3 Constructing the ‘quasi-market’ in the research This research mapped, in totality, two distinct yet bounded localities, and investigated the driving forces dictating decision-making within them. Following the mapping, a smaller purposive sample of schools was then selected. This sample represented a range of providers, divided equally between rural and urban, in which more in-depth analysis was undertaken (table 3). 3.4 Assumptions Two key assumptions were implicit in the research: firstly, proximity being a key factor in school choice, parents were unlikely to send their children outside the community for primary education, thus the schools studied would constitute the entire market provision. Secondly, the selection of locations with at least one functioning government school, which is used as a comparator, and a range of other schools, may not be entirely representative. However these localities were chosen to investigate why parents select private schools even when government schools function, thereby making the findings even more pertinent. 3.5 Exploring school response in the provider domain 16 Sudhaar-ITA Alliance, an NGO working in Skp., proved an invaluable source of information as they has mapped all Government, NGO and NFE schools, and were able to draw up a shortlist of possible Union Councils to work in which I was then able to visit. 17 Functioning is taken to mean that the school is open and some teachers are present. - 30 - Owners and head teachers (HTs) represent the ‘providers’. Thus each school in the locality – effectively within reasonable (usually 2-4 km) distance from the government school - was mapped. This mapping exercise utilised in-depth questionnaires with the HTs or owners (annex 3) to extrapolate key characteristics of the school and teachers, rationale for existence, management structure, relationship with the state and modes of financing. Moreover, issues that owners/HTs faced were explored through probing questions in an unstructured manner as particular points of relevance arose: most were very free with their opinions. This facilitated the providers’ perspective on how they respond to meet the demand. Focus Group Discussions (FGDs) with teachers (annex 6) were utilised to not only cross-check owners’ response but also provide an insight into what is going on in the school, especially in terms of teacher motivation, support or obstacles from the community, teacher perceptions of the school and the quality of education that it provides. 3.6 Examining consumer perspectives Grade five (or children of equivalent ages in 10-12 year bracket, in the case of NFE schools) was selected as the comparative frame between schools given that it is an important year for several reasons.18 As an accreditation and exit year at the end of the primary cycle, the ‘choice’ of school is likely to be more marked than in early years, as pressure on performance would be greater. It would also enable the researchers to explore the educational history of the child, as they may have moved schools. Moreover, the maturity of grade five pupils meant that they would interact more comfortably with the researchers than younger students. To compare with the responses from owners and teachers, and delve into why parents ‘choose’ to send their children to particular schools, FGDs were organised. Parents of grade 5 students were called to the school by their child with the permission of the head teacher/ owner. Generally consisting of between 4-8 participants, the prompting questions asked why they had sent their children to a particular school, what their perceptions are of alternative options and what factors are important in choosing a school (annex 4). 18 In Pakistan, primary education lasts for five years (grades 1-5), preceded by two years preparatory classes (kachi, or nursery). Secondary education is divided into three cycles: three years' middle school (68), two years' secondary (high school grades 9-10) and two years' higher secondary (intermediate 11-12). On completion of the high school, pupils matriculate, taking the Secondary School Certificate (SSC). - 31 - In the same schools, PRA-style exercises with children of grade 5, or equivalent age in NFE Centres, were carried out (annex 5) (Cox and Robinson-Pant 2003). This exercise, which involved drawing the family and drawing the school, had multiple purposes: firstly, to build up an understanding of the socio-economic and familial background of the children for inferential quantitative comparisons; secondly, to map the education trajectory of the child and to encourage the child to talk about his or her school and past schools (Theis 1996). Where time permitted, discussions on aspirations were held, which frequently brought out many of the problems children faced in going to school. Participative observation, recorded in field notes, was an important tool utilised throughout, especially in regarding interactions between actors within the schools and in lesson observation. The range of methods reflect Booth et al’s (1998) appeal for ‘robust eclecticism’ in research, by triangulating findings with information gathered from a variety of different methods and sources. It also enables the setting up of different subject-perspectives in the different domains. Table 3 provides a breakdown of the sample characteristics of the research by school type. Table 3: Sample characteristics by school type Govt. Private Mapped schools 4 9 Parents FGD 2 4 Teachers FGD 2 4 PRA with children 2 4 Number of pupils in PRA 17 (2) 34 (12) (Number in brackets number of boys) NGO 1 0 0 1 4 (4) NFE 2 2 2 1 6 (1) Madrassah Total 3 19 1 9 1 9 1 9 4 (2) 65 (21) 3.7 Strengths and limitations of the research The strength of this research is that it looks in-depth at two localities, which gives a unique insight into how quasi-markets function in Pakistan from numerous subject perspectives. Its qualitative focus is the comparative advantage, as it provides space for different actors to voice their positions regarding private schools. Unlike other investigations into this field rely upon quantitative research utilising household surveys or census data (Andrabi et al 2002; MSU 2002), extensive school information gathering - 32 - (Kardar 2001) or pupil testing across schools to assess quality and, thus, efficiency (Kingdon 1996; ADB 2002), this study takes an innovative approach to analysing private schooling. Triangulation with secondary sources and quantitative data points to where the current research resonates with and differs from broader trends. Thus it aims to fill a significant knowledge-gap on private schools in Pakistan. Several limitations are worth noting. Firstly, research collaborators (one male and one female) undertook much of the research directly, as language and cultural barriers made this necessary. For this, training with PRA, FGD and interview technique was required, which only developed through practice. Secondly, access to schools was not always straightforward, and a significant degree of suspicion had to be overcome to gain access and trust. Anonymity and assurances that government officials would not be privy to the details were prerequisites to entry. Much time had to be spent in each school to merely gain access (and innumerable cups of tea drunk). In the urban locality access was denied to one private school and one madrassah. Thirdly, managing expectations of the school owners who hoped for a benefit in return for collaborating was problematic. This was done by carefully explaining the purposes and outcomes as a piece of academic work. Fourthly, the shortness of school timings meant that time in research was limited, especially when travelling significant distances to the rural location. Fifthly, due to government schools closing prematurely for the summer vacation due excessive heat, indepth work required much coordination with local leaders to call people to FGDs. Where necessary, all responses are made anonymous to protect privacy and school names have been coded alphabetically (Table 5 below).19 Where permissible, interviews are referenced by name of individual as follows: (interview name, date). Otherwise, post and level is substituted for name. 19 Abbreviations for government schools are GGPS (Government Girls Primary School), GGHS (Government Girls High School), GBPS (Government Boys Primary School) and GBHS (Government Boys High School). Other abbreviations used for respondees are covered in the list of abbreviations and acronyms. - 33 - Chapter 4: Policy responses in a highly politicised context This section picks apart conventional understandings of education markets in the Pakistani context in which devolution, private sector promotion and community participation are the driving policy influences.20 Comparing responses from officials with that of school owners uncovers how the policy framings are translated into reality. This leads to a questioning of how choice can operate effectively in a highly politicised context. 4.1 Community participation in the government system Policy emphasis on community participation is receiving a muted response and active involvement appears patchy. The setting up of school management committees (SMCs) has been mandated for government schools (Khan 2003). Yet, in the view of one district official, “the SMC members are illiterate, and create problems for teachers. Illiterate people don’t know the problems of schools, they just want to dominate a school as a choudhry21” (interview 13/05/04). Participation is having an unequal impact as parents value government schools differently for boys and girls. A significant degree of effective material participation occurred in the Government Boys High School in Makki 460: “the community participation in sprucing up the school and making it workable is touching - the government does not help at all, despite petitioning.” (Head Teacher (HT)) The school relies on the council, composed of a few enthusiastic people for school improvement. The GBHS is in a strong position of being functioning with teachers present and teaching (table 5). This saves parents the cost of sending boys to private school, especially as it goes up to grade 10. By contrast, the GGPS in the same community is seriously under-resourced and ill-supported by the community. According to the auxiliary teacher, the “parents are very uncooperative”. Yet many girls are being 20 The broader debates surrounding community participation (see Bray 2000) and decentralisation (see Lauglo 1995) are relevant to this discussion. Space here does not permit an examination of these; rather they have been highlighted as they directly impinge on the nature of choice available. Without illuminating these here the discussion in subsequent chapters would be incomplete and ungrounded. 21 Choudhury means local boss, and derives from the caste system. - 34 - sent to private schools close by. Why this occurs, rather than improving the government school, is partially due to the configuration of local politics. The discourse of community participation has so deeply permeated the thinking of education, that if schools are failing, the blame is shifted to the community itself. Officials emphasise the role that should be played by the community; curiously, they frame education as a private good to be organised and even managed ‘cooperatively’ but according to ones’ (the mythical community, the isolated parent?) own interest. According to a senior district official, “it is not the lack of money to ensure that schools run well, but rather that the local community give time to properly supervise the local school” (interview 22/05/04). This fails to take into account that the people left to use the government schools lack the wealth and influence within the social system to make change happen. As “the government never buys the land in a village for a school” (interview district official 13/05/04) the question of who is willing or able to donate land in a society where the poor are landless labourers and the rich hold extensive lands remains unanswered (Hussein et al 2003). The better-off in the community have no interest in the proper functioning of ‘free’ government schools as their children go the private schools, a poignant point of which local people are well aware: “There are some influential people in the area … but they don’t do any thing for the betterment of people. No one is ready to allot some land for school: everyone here is just ready to fill his own belly” (Father, NFE C). Resultantly, those left within the system, and reliant upon it, are those with the least resources. The system appears tilted against government schools so that they are bound to fail. Interestingly, no SMCs existed, or were demanded, in the private schools visited. Education thus becomes a commodity to be bought (and sold), removing the incentive for collective action. 4.2 Local elites and devolution: incentives for supporting education? This has been further complicated by the initiation of a process of devolution, in which local tiers of government have some control over education (see Lauglo 1995 on the - 35 - implications of decentralisation for education).22 Although beyond the scope of this paper, problems of accountability of the government schools the education department remain vis-à-vis the functioning (interview, district official, 13/05/04). Moreover, the elected officials at UC level who should be the most motivated and active are in fact, partly because of the presence of alternative education options, the least active with regards to supporting the government schools: “The [locally elected official] lives just close to government primary school but he is a hypocrite. His claims are high but he is good for nothing…. He doesn’t take interest in the welfare of people.” (Father, NFE C) One locally elected official from Gharibabad remarked, unblinkingly, that “(m)y own children are getting education from the eminent private school in the city. I am not only paying 5000 per month to the school but also 2000 Rs. to the tutor who comes to help my kids in studies” (interview 04/06/04). The locally elected officials (the new offices under devolution) were frequently related to owners of private schools (in the case above, a brother in law), and are more likely to lobby to support them than give resources to the direct competitor. Interestingly, as one district official (interview 13/05/04) pointed out sardonically, “politicians, policy-makers and bureaucrats have the remedy. A son of a Secretary or a Minister should be taught in Government Schools, not in private schools, to set an example and to boost the morale of Government schools”. A viscous circle is developing whereby poorly functioning government schools leads to desertion of those who can afford private schools, which in turn diminishes the “sharp elbow” (Deacon 2000) of pressure of those with the capacity to improve them. If devolution has given increased power to local elites as these findings suggest, whose interest in improving government schools appears minimal, it may have the opposite affect to the stated aim of increasing responsiveness and improving services. From bad, current policies may in fact make government schools worse. 22 A fuller examination of the impacts of devolution is too early to make, given the short time since it was made effective. Indeed, it may offer opportunities to improve service delivery (Nadvi and Robinson 2004). - 36 - 4.3 Encouraging private sector or losing control? The “socio-regulatory contexts” (Minogue, 1991: 8) illustrate the degree to which markets are embedded and conditioned by macro and meso forces. The strategic support for private schools outlined in the P-ESRP and summarised in chapter 1 appears to have had no noticeable impact on the running of private schools and none of the owners were aware of the potential support. It is clear that the measures are aimed at well-established and wealthy private establishments as the exemption of custom duties for the import of equipment bears out. Support appears on paper, but has no impact in practice. Moreover, although clear regulatory procedures exist, a significant confusion about who is responsible for registering and regulating private schools remains at the district level (Kardar 2001). When interviewed, the education officials suggested that the Executive District Officer was the indicated in-charge. Yet he claimed to have no record (or no knowledge of any record) of private schools. The actual process appeared from these interviews to bypass the education department in its entirety. The regulation that school owners were aware of was the need to register, which contradicts the above. Light but ineffective, or even negative, controls exist: “The government wants to know how much area the school has, the number of rooms and what all is on the premises. The land should be at least 10 marlas. You also need to have a health certificate. Then government people from Sheikhupura come and check the school, whether it comes up to the health standards or not and whether it is fit for registration. Then after the health inspection is passed the certificate goes to the DO office and then the school is recognized. Bribery is common as it is hard to convince the officials to come to a remote area. The entire process takes 6 months to a year. 1,500 Rs have to be given to the bank for renewal of registration after 3 years.” (Owner, Private School H) This shows that there is little or non concern for the quality of the education provided. The ease with which schools can be registered is frightening, as an informal process decided by bribery and connections exists: “My friend had some links in the Education Department. I gave him Rs. 8,000 and he got my school registered” (Owner, Private School B) The political influence of school owners comes through, even in regulation avoidance: “As I am a Lady Councillor (in the UC) of the area as well, it wasn’t a major problem for - 37 - me to get my institute registered” (Owner, Private School C). This emphasises the power of political lobbying at local level for changes to rules and lax application and the negative impact of patronage on healthy competition. Visits are also part of the mandate, but feed in to the mechanism of buttering up the officials to avoid interference: “Some officials visit the school and we have to arrange lunch for them…and usually their subordinates take a bribe.” (Owner, Private School E, Gharibabad) Although the state is unable to effectively monitor public schools (interview district official 13/05/04) they seem capable of visiting new private schools in urban areas. These visits appear to be driven by rent seeking which would be unavailable to them in public schools. Now that their mandate has been expanded to governing a growing private sector, interest in monitoring and improving government schools may diminish. In the face of private school growth allied with patronage connections, the state is too weak to respond. Government officials are cognisant of the negative effects of private schools on the public system but are incapable of taking action: “Sons and daughters of government teachers are in private schools - and some are even running their own schools. They sign the attendance sheet and then go into a private school, especially in classes 9 and 10. There may be a tuition centre - and they tell the whole class that they must attend” (interview district official 13/05/04). The impossibility of appropriately enforcing the regulatory framework and the acknowledgement of the importance of the private sector by the Government means that privatisation by both default and design is occurring (Bray 1996). The harsh reality of Pakistan’s quasi-feudal political economy coupled with recent policy impulses is having two interrelated impacts. Firstly, education is becoming atomised and personalised as it becomes a private good. Secondly, the distinction between the government schools and the private schools is being sharpened. In the words of a district official, “the people who have money are not concerned (about government schools) - poor families don’t have such opportunities (of opting out)” (interview 13/05/04). This intimates that the quasimarket is far from apolitical and that stratification within society is being entrenched. There seems to be a tacit recognition within policy circles that attempts to reform the government sector are doomed to failure and private schools offer the solution. To assess what kind of solution private schools are offering, the next two chapters analyse the ways - 38 - in which school owners respond to the quasi-market and how parents and children perceive the school choices. - 39 - CHAPTER 5: School response: supply-side driven growth or responding to demand? This section looks how schools respond to the market. This reveals what kind of choice of schools is available through a taxonomy of school type, and why the options emerged from the owners’ perspective. This balances supply side availability and market gaps with nuanced aspects of school response to demands for quality education. 5.1 Understanding responsiveness Two levels of responsiveness have been recognised in the theory. Firstly, there is a response to opportunities resulting in the creation of new or redefinition of existing institutions. The efforts by profit-making school managers, as well as NGOs and madaris, focused on specific target groups of population thereby responds to differentiated demand. Secondly, owners initiate change within existing schools to respond and appeal to parental preferences (Woods et al: 1998). Woods’ (1994: 125) categorisation of the way schools may respond in a ‘quasi-market’ (see table 2) is tested by empirical findings. 5.2 Characteristics of private provision Schools in the two localities can be situated along the spectrum of being financed and managed by the state (planned) to ‘pure’ private schools. However, four broad categories of school-type, evidenced in terms of rationale of existence, can be recognised which are catering to poorer families in the areas surveyed and more widely in Sheikhupura District (table 4).23 23 Numerous other types exits: highlighted here are the significant types which cater to poor communities and are found in both the scoping survey and as part of observation in different localities in the district (see P-EMIS, forthcoming). - 40 - Table 4: Taxonomy of providers catering to the urban and rural poor Rationale Type Government schools Public good Adopted schools Not-for profit24 Cost per month Nominal, but with hidden costs < Rs. 25 Non Formal Education (NFE) Centres NGO managed, ‘local ownership’ Nominal, with funding from NGOs NGO formal primary schools Head teacher, NGO managed Rs. 100- 175 plus scholarships for poor Private Private owners and management Rs 50-150 Tuition Centre Private owners, in private school or lone individual Madrassah Owned and managed by private religious group/ Mosque For-profit Religious values Stewardship/ management Ministry of Education (MoE) Owned by MoE, managed by NGOs Rs. 30+ depending and time and frequency, used as a supplement to all types of schools Free education shelter and food, with funding from political parties, community and foreign sources. 5.3 The emergence of a new type of for-profit school From the school mapping, it is clear that the majority of schools have been recently established, with 11 out of 15 private schools started in the last 5 years (table 5). Given this, it was pertinent to gauge the perspective of the owner as to why they set up the school in the first place. Private schools tend to be founded by, and are capitalising on, a redundant qualified teaching force creating a potential specific supply (Kitaev 1999). The plethora of unemployed qualified graduates means that there is no shortage of people who turn to teaching for a few years, whether as teachers or owners: 24 NGO schools and NFE centres are a relatively new phenomenon, representing the donor-driven agenda of encouraging NGOs to enter into service provision. As a non-contentious, ‘apolitical’ way of working in development, numerous NGOs, supported by multilateral and bilateral agencies are being co-opted into service provision, especially in the education sector (interview Fareeha Zafar 06/05/04). However, it is beyond the scope of the current study which focuses on for-profit private schools. - 41 - “I was completely free after my graduation and B.Ed. (unemployed) and I wanted to involve myself in some income generating activity, so I thought I would use my house as a school and charge a minimal fee of 10 Rupees per child”. (Owner, Private School A). Interestingly, about half of the owners are female. From informal discussions, and later visits to the schools, it was discovered that educated wives were encouraged to set up schools as an income-generating activity to supplement the earnings of their husbands or other family member. This was seen as a ‘safe’ occupation, as the wives did not have to leave the house; the teachers employed were frequently related to the owners, thereby keeping it in the family. Moreover, the status of becoming a head teacher within poor communities may be significant. Running a school, ostensibly to serve the poor, generates good will that could be transformed into political capital, which explains why school owners are the more active members of the community. 5.4 Profit-making entities: Income-enhancing as a prime concern? Business opportunities exist as market space encourages the proliferation of schools. Although both catchment areas were small and had government schools close by, many new schools had sprung up. This suggests that government provision was insufficient for the number of children living in the community. This market space was recognised by school owners, who highlighted distance between schools and physical boundaries as reasons for establishing schools, being aware of parental concerns for security: “Parents were anxious about their children as they had to go to [private school D] which is on the other side of the road…traffic and a lot of hustle and bustle made them think to have a school in their own mohalla so the establishment of our school lessened their anxiety”25 (Owner, Private School F). The HT of Private School H in Makki 460 suggested that “other private schools in the area were not doing the job correctly” was the rationale behind setting the school up. Established in 2001, Private School H already has 150 students. 25 Mohalla can be translated as a part of town or, as in this case, a small cluster of streets. - 42 - [INSERT TABLE 4 SUMMARY STATS] see end - 43 - It started off as a single room, but following some family investment the school grew to having three small classrooms within the same compound. The driving rationale behind private schools is profit. Yet the profit motive of the schools was frequently hidden behind rhetoric of providing education. One owner describes, with missionary zeal, the establishment of her school as part of “a vision to bring the people from the darkness of ignorance to the light of educational awareness” (Owner, Private School E). However, when one of the teachers who worked at the school was interviewed, she laughed at this, and suggested that the only vision was that of profit and the head teacher didn’t care about what happened in the school as long as parents paid their fees (FT NFE A).26 The fee level was relatively consistent across all private schools in both localities, with fees payable on a sliding scale dependent on grade (Annex 7). However, there are other costs involved, to which parents are very sensitive: “In private schools we have to pay heavy fee and buy expensive book. They charge additional funds like the cleanliness fund, picnic, study, recreational tour funds” (Father NFE A) Private schools do offer incentives in terms of fee concessions and reduction on fees for families with more than one child enrolled, although this is to attract new customers and retain valuable ones, rather than an altruistic concern for the poor. However, no schooling is entirely free: government schools are still charging a ‘nominal’ amount per pupil, but hidden costs are also involved.27 A case of extortion came out clearly in one government school, where parents had to pay more than the basic amount and pay for the ‘free’ textbooks. NGOs and NFE Centres both charge fees, but are more accessible to poor parents as they supply books and offer scholarships. Private schools appear to be providing services at substantially lower cost per unit than government schools (interview Shahid Kardar 09/06/04). This is achieved as the direct costs of school are kept low, as the private schools tend to be situated within people’s 26 One teacher taught in the morning at a private school and in the afternoon at a NFE Centre. The other taught at a different private school, which facilitated interesting insights into different perspectives on schools. 27 Primary education is supposed to be free and compulsory in Pakistan for the first five years, yet this is still not the case, especially when hidden costs are taken into account. - 44 - own homes, thereby minimising risks on investment. Expenditure is limited to utility bills, registration fees (where registered) and teacher salaries, as shown in annex 7 for breakdown of revenue and expenditures. Very little money is re-invested into schools, which means that the facilities are not upgraded. One hypothesis is that schools, being family businesses, mirror the traditional method of working along familial lines rather than as ‘businesses’ in the sense of maximising profit (pers. comm. Miguel Loureiro). This would explain the apparent glass ceiling on the size to which schools can, and in fact want to, expand. Private schools have, on average, only 125 students, spanning all grades, compared to 236 for government schools (table 5). The implications this has for cost-effectiveness and actual quality provided are significant, as the generally accepted ‘good’ size for a functioning primary school would be larger as economies of scale exist in primary schools.28 The result is poor facilities, with children packed into very small classrooms, with limited sanitation facilities: over 75% of private schools had sanitary facilities, but only a little over 50% had separate facilities for boys and girls. The limitation on both ready capital and aspiration to build a more substantial school encourages more schools to enter into the market rather than consolidate into larger entities. The market in education, with schools run along familial lines, can be considered antithetical to co-operative efforts (Woods 1994). Andrabi et al (2003: 16) argue that the most “effective way to decrease fees in private schools is through the competitive pressure that arises from the number of such schools providing education services”. However, the outcome may further squeeze the quality provided; owners are increasingly reticent to invest in facilities and teacher salaries, already abysmally low, may be pushed down further. Nor do schools compete on quality provided, as shown below. Adler (1994) argues that there is little evidence in the education sector “of the market functioning as a self-correcting mechanism”, as schools form into ‘natural’ layers or go out of business. The implication for sustainability of these private schools is a significant aspect that requires further (and longitudinal) examination. Ethical concerns about businesses being involved in service delivery yet paying dividends from profits to owners with the money that might be spent on classrooms creates a dilemma for possible government interventions. 28 There is very little work on this. However, small, multigrade classrooms may be the only option in remote rural areas, there seems little logical explanation for them in more densely populated rural or urban - 45 - 5.5 Substantive improvement: Chimera or reality? The expected superior quality of private schools derives from impact competition has on the accountability and responsiveness to demand (Chubb and Moe 1990). Quality is seen as vital in determining student participation. In developed countries, it has been argued that, with competition, there has resulted a sharpening of focus on the academic, manifested in academic output such as examination results which can be measured and understood by parents in comparison with other schools (Woods et al, 1998). Empirical work in South Asia indicates that both NGOs and private entrepreneur operators are more successful in attracting students due to their ability to ensure the proper functioning of the school (Kingdom 1999; Alderman et al 1999). Private schools appear to provide a better, more personalised service. From the sample, overt signs of private school quality such as student-teacher ratio at 22:1 (on average) and student classroom ratio of 25:1 are much lower than those of government schools (figures calculated from table 5). In all the private schools visited, teachers were present. By contrast, the motivation of government teachers is low. In a survey reported in Gazdar (1999), almost 50% of government schools visited were closed and 30% of the teachers absent in the schools that were open. Equally, private school teachers appear to be more accountable to the owners: “In private schools, teachers are compelled to cover the syllabus and they are instructed to engage the students in studies all the time. Teachers have to work under the strict supervision of the head teacher who is there to humiliate them for nothing.” (FT NFE A/ private school) However, as this quote indicates, teachers’ working conditions are poor and the individual teachers lack autonomy within the classroom. There is a predisposition to authoritarian styles of management in private schools. As a result, an atmosphere of fear is created within some schools. In a private school during the PRA with students, one student was recounting that “Mr X (owner) behaves in a rude way with our teachers…we don’t like it. Sometimes he hits us on the head with the book”, at which point Mr X reentered the room. The student became scared, quickly correcting herself “we don’t have any problems here. All our teachers are so good, they take much care of us” (Female ones. - 46 - student (FS), Private School A).29 Teaching (and learning) in this kind of environment would be problematic for even the best teachers (or the most diligent students). However, teachers in private schools are less well qualified and paid less than government school teachers (Kardar 2001). The majority of teachers are female, potentially providing an encouragement for girls to enrol. They are also young and inexperienced, selected for their enthusiasm. Teachers frequently remarked that they liked teaching for the respect it gave them in the community: “I love to be called Sirjee... we are respected by students and parents” (MT NFE C). The job frequently seen as a fill-in before they get married: “After a few years, teachers leave the school owing to marriage” (Owner, Private School A). Teacher turnover is relatively high as a result, as teachers regard the profession as “a chance for us to earn a bit of money for ourselves and step out of the house” (FT, Private School G). This, coupled with the reticence of owners to invest, means that teacher training is neither given nor contemplated by the owners. The fear is that teacher training will lead to demands for increased wages or poaching from other schools. An amorphous ‘academic quality’ was the dominant discourse from owners, looking at ‘academic achievement’, although only a few had evidence of results. Indeed, this emphasis came about as a result of head teacher involvement, as a female student comments: “sometimes the head teacher gives us a surprise test, and if we show bad performance she hits us with books and our note copies…last time she gave me a slap and I can still feel it” (Private School C). However, what this means for actual quality is problematic, as parents seemed unaware of quantifiable measurements of school quality, as shown in chapter 6. Any advances children made were a direct result of the hard work and dedication of the school: “In the very beginning we had to work hard on kids because they were getting education for the very first time in their life; bad accent and lack of guidance from homes lack of concentration were the major issues” (MT NFE C) 29 Setting up the PRA exercises in a way that would provide a neutral and safe environment for the students was a continual problem, due to the lack of free space in schools. Multi-grade teaching and noncompartmentalised classrooms resulted in a disruption to the school and a false environment in which the PRA could be undertaken. - 47 - A trend towards traditionalism can be observed in pedagogy as a result of the need to respond to parents’ wishes. From participant observation, rote learning was the norm, with children frequently hauled up in-front of the researchers to (painfully) recite a poem or refrain in Urdu, and for schools where English is promoted, in unintelligible yet memorised English. This was, the researchers were told by the owners, an example of the excellent education the children were getting. These children were the more presentable and were the ones best able to adapt to the necessity of memorising vast quantities of material.30 The private school phenomenon in rural Punjab, according to recent quantitative work, “is interesting as it has the largest fraction of teachers with only Matriculation” (of 45%), which, coupled the fact it has seen the most rapid expansion, the lowest per-pupil expenditure and the highest student teacher ratio means that “potential quality concerns tend to be more pronounced in rural Punjab” (Andrabi et al 2002: 19-20). 31 This, they observe, is exacerbated by a “lack of standardization of private schools in terms of values underlying education, the pedagogic philosophy and actual teacher ‘practice’ (Andrabi et al 2003: 21). This corroborates the findings of this research, but the conclusion they draw puts a more positive spin on the contribution of private schools. 5.6 Deceptive appearances? Private schools in Pakistan present an image to the prospective consumers in a manner which differs quite substantially from that of government schools. Although private schools and government schools are similar in that they use the same textbooks and are Urdu medium, differentiation derives from perceptions of quality difference. Imagemaking and projecting are done via visible external mechanisms such as signs outside the front of schools, flags, brightly coloured front walls. They adopt a ‘uniform’, designed by the owner, consisting of a coloured shirt and trousers for boys, a sash and coloured shirt for girls, a badge (with the name of the school) or a tie. This homogenised image of low cost private schools, perhaps in mimicry of an ‘idealised’ private school of the middle 30 Pedagogic styles in Pakistan tend to be reliant on rote learning in all academic institutions as a recent survey of education in Pakistan points out (SPDC 2003) 31 Matriculation is a grade 10 graduate who has completed high school, but without any professional training. - 48 - classes, seeks meeting a certain, unwritten yet instantly perceptible notion of what a school should consist of. Each private school looks like and sounds like the next, with highfalutin names (for example New Jinnah English Medium Public Model High School), pertaining to something which they are not. This appeals to parents who value ‘middle class’ traits. This resonates with the perceptions of what a quality education is on behalf of the parents wherein discipline, manners and cleanliness are the important ‘lessons’ children receive, discussed in chapter 6. However, visible signs are a hollow shell of a good school, given the absence of observable teaching. The profile of owners within the community is important for bolstering enrolment. The local Imam, patron of the Madrassah C in Makki 460, is, according to the head teacher (also his son), “deeply respected and considered a trustworthy person, so they (the parents) are sending their children to this school”. The school, established only in 2004, already has a quorum of nearly 150 students, bears this out. Private schools rely on personal contacts and ties for attracting students, and most owners seemed active on this front: “Me and my sister started our studies in G Public School. Study in that school was good but Sir F. (head teacher of H Public School) is my father’s fast friend…he forced my parents to send us in H School …so we are here for the last 2 years.” (FS, Private School H) Keeping up a reputation is harder than getting one - much gossip was unofficially discussed regarding scandals either within schools or about the teachers or owners, which seemed to dictate the relative ‘popularity’ of the school. The sustainability of private schools may well be a problem as they are so dependent on the fragility of individual initiative and reputation. Private schools market themselves and raise their profile through promotional events such as prize giving days: “We usually meet the parents in order to convince them to send their children to the school. Here the community is worse than backward villages. On the eve of annual prize distribution, parents are called to attend the ceremony, and at that moment most of the parents are attracted and decide to send their children to our school.” (Owner, Private School A) A positive spin-off of this effort is that private schools are actually mobilising demand by raising the profile of education within the community. Yet, paradoxically, the sales pitch - 49 - is aimed at parents whose children are already in school, either government or other private schools, as they will be the ones who can afford the fees. According to the HT of GGPS A “(d)uring the last two years 50 students have left the school to get admission in private schools. But in a very short period of time, 50 more students were enrolled here”. The impact that private schools have on either alleviating the pressure on government schools, given the continued high STRs and SCRs in government schools, or increasing access to education is questionable. Here, the role of NGO schools and NFE centres is important, as they target specifically the poor in their mobilisation campaigns and school provision (interview Abid Gill 10/05/04). Private schools appear to prefer to adopt measures which promote themselves rather than face up to any internal change which could be beneficial in terms of quality. The reason behind this is the nature of the demand coming from parents. In a situation where alternatives are not good, where government school is perceived in such a dim light, and where there is a high but un-met demand for schools, it is likely that the providers dictate choice and help shape the discourse around quality. - 50 - CHAPTER 6: Perspectives on choice: consumer demand? 6.1 Rethinking choice Markets in education are predicated on a demand; in the both the urban and rural areas studied, demand for education appeared high. This chapter will analyse why parents make certain decisions about schooling options, which shows that real choice is often absent. Education has certain values attached to it by parents, which reflect their sociocultural milieu and aspirations for their children. Hence as “(the) choice of school…cannot be made separate from the interpersonal relationships, patterns of parenting and material environments which constitute and constrain the lives and opportunities of families” (Gerwitz el al 1995: 50), so the analysis examines all factors that emerged as influencing choice. However, insights into the ‘black box’ of classroom activities from the perspectives of those most closely engaged with the process, children themselves, provides a unique perspective to set alongside reasons for parental decisionmaking and school response. Illuminatingly, three aspects can be juxtaposed: the rhetoric of improved quality by the owners discussed in chapter 5, the perceptions of quality by the parents, and the reality experienced by the pupils. The research reveals distinct perspectives. 6.2 Demand for education across the spectrum: valuing education Contrary to the perception of the education ‘problem’ in Pakistan being a lack of demand (Warwick and Reimers 1995), this research suggests that not only is the demand high, it is also high for girls. Until recently, it was a commonly assumed that high opportunity costs of educating girls due to their value of taking care of siblings, especially in rural Pakistan, coupled with the custom of exclusion, purdah, created barriers for the education of girls (Gazdar 1999; Heward 1999). The findings presented here resonate with recent work argues that it is supply-side constraints that are hampering expansion (Lloyd et al 2002). If the demand is high, for both boys and girls, this must be underpinned by a value attached to education, and the role it can play in the lives of the people. - 51 - The parents in the FGDs in all schools held positive views of education. The value they attached to education can be divided into five aspects, although parents themselves understood these benefits conjointly. Firstly, education is viewed as a form of escape from the poverty stricken life of the slum community or a way out of the village to the opportunities presented in the city. Much of this is a retrospective response to what the parents have missed out on as a result of being uneducated as only 60% of fathers and 31% of mothers of the children in the PRA exercises had received some education. “We are all well aware of the significance of education…I know if I had been provided all the educational opportunities by my parents, things would have been totally different” (Mother, GGPS B) Secondly, there is utility value attached to education (or functional literacy) as parents know that “an uneducated person doesn’t know how much bill (utility bills) he has to pay” (Father, NFE Centre A). Thirdly, education is perceived to bring benefits in direct monetary terms as parents believed that through schooling children have a brighter future, better employment opportunities and, as a result, a better standard of living. Most parents agreed that education enhances life chances: “Their life will be made and they will know how to start a business and earn money for themselves. Their thinking will become sharper and better…they will become intelligent people. What could be better than that?” (Father, Private School B) This is despite the reality of high unemployment rates for school graduates, and relatively small rates of return to additional schooling at primary level in Pakistan (Kastis et al 1999). The desire for their children (boys) to be army officers, doctors or high ranking government officials was pervasive, as these professions are held in high esteem within society. The result of these employment opportunities is that, according to a generally echoed view, “families would rather spend more on boys than girls as boys tend to be a source of income” (Father, Private School F). However, direct material benefits from investing in girls’ education appear to be changing as “educated girl tends to get better marriage proposals: people want educated wives and daughters-in-law” (Father, Private School H). Marriage transactions and employment opportunities for married girls may - 52 - partially explain why families are now prepared to pay fees in private schools for girls (see Kabeer 1997 on similar trends in Bangladesh). This deserves further investigation, as it is linked to changing social norms. Fourthly, education has intrinsic value in the positive impact it has on children which result from cultural shifts in the acceptance of education. Thus by comparing the opinion that “children become rude, hot tempered, and hollow if they are out of schools” (Mother, NFE Centre A) with the expected benefits of schooling, it would make children well-mannered, temperate and ‘whole’ people. As one father (Private School B) reflected, “(e)ducation makes a child son of man otherwise there is no difference between animal and a human”, echoing the teachings of the Quran. The influence of the media has greatly expanded their perceptions of how children should act and behave, creating a new standard, as one mother commented: “We watch television and we see all these boys and girls from all over the Pakistan speaking with such poise and grace. We want to see our children like that too” (Mother, Private School H). This signifies a shift in cultural attitudes towards education, which is beginning to be valued as an end in itself, showing that it education is becoming a social norm for all.32 Cultural attitudes have moved towards welcoming education even for girls as an Imam of a Madrassah C stated quite bluntly: “Our elders had old minds…they were not ready to accept new requirements and were reluctant to send their daughters in schools. They thought they have to ultimately take charge of their homes so they should remain inside the home….now we are all agreed at one point that our all kids must be educated.” (Imam, Madrassah C) In addition to this, finally, parents tended to associate education with status and power, as “(a)n educated person is respected” (Mother, NFE Centre A). This reflects the inferior status ascribed to the uneducated within Pakistan. Put together, these rationales for education create a strong feeling within the localities studied that education is essential for both the material benefits and transformative role it plays. Social differentiation and gender, explored below, however, remain barriers to entry. According to Kabeer (1997: 299), “Social change dos not occur as a single discrete moment of rupture with the past but as a gradual expansion of possibilities as more and more people are prepared to take risks and challenge the old way of doing things”. Sending girls to school is one of these challenges. 32 - 53 - 6.3 Social differentiation mediating choice and opportunity The affect of social class distinctions, such as the education of parents, caste and household income, appears important to determining both the quality of schooling opted for and whether children are sent to school in the first place (Sawada and Lokshin 2001; Gerwitz et al 1995). Indeed, for low income families, it has been suggested that “Pakistani households might adopt perverse informal self-insurance mechanisms by using child labour income as parental income insurance, sacrificing the accumulation of human capital” (Sawada and Lokshin 2001: 19). Rather than seeing these household decisions as “perverse”, it would be more useful to analyse if and how social differentiation is influencing demand, determining supply and, more insidiously, subtly shaping choice. As Bourdieu, describing class effects in Western education systems, rather pessimistically argues, “the symbolic struggles between the classes have no chance of being seen or organised as such, and are bound to take the form of competitive struggles helping to reproduce gaps which are the essence of the race” (1986: 251). Education is represented by parents as an opportunity for a different life, yet is bought like a commodity (Gazdar 1999: 53). In Punjab, the traditional caste status of biraderi has been associated with an occupational position (which developed from the close mix with the Hindu caste system pre-Independence). Thus, landless, agricultural labourers are strictly distinguished from landowners.33 According to Sawada and Lokshin (2001: 14), “(t)his system of caste has prevailed in the form of social norms, and members of each class are expected to act according to their social and economic status”. This would make the caste system a direct constraint on education opportunities for low caste children. Schools are simultaneously a mirror and reflection of society; not separate mechanisms but deeply embedded in society, thereby riven by inequalities and exclusion (Subrahmanian 2003). Thus while socio-cultural background would appear a strong influence on schooling (Sawada and Lokshin 2001), others suggest that “the concept of social class…does not apply well to Pakistan” (Warwick and Reimers 1995). It can be argued that, in their 1995 study using prior data, Warwick and Reimers did not look at the effect the emergence of new private 33 Very little sociological or anthropological work has been done on the biraderi system, especially in recent years. Useful starting, and ending, points are Ahmad, S. (1977) investigation into “Class and power in a Punjabi Village”, and the even older Elgar, Z., (1960) “A Punjabi Village in Pakistan”. - 54 - schools was having, as they argue that all government students come from the same class. With regard to caste, very little came to light directly in the research. One explanation for this is that, although present in Central Punjab, biraderi has a much greater hold in Southern Punjab. Gazdar (2000) points towards how the presence of functioning of government schools tends to eradicate caste-based differentials. A much more detailed anthropological study is required to undertake this level of analysis. However, parents, almost all either first generation literates or illiterates, have a basic unfamiliarity with both school and the process of schooling. It is an alien environment, which can seem intimidating and abstract, especially as teachers and owners are educated and therefore in a position of power. This affects their choice of school, the demands they place on the school in terms of facilities and the quality of the education expected. This research shows that not only are social class differences an important feature of shaping preferences, but they serve to create a hegemonic discourse around quality and symbols of quality. This presents a serious challenge to equity of opportunity under the current pattern of provision, and indicates that current policy prescriptions are leading down dangerous paths. Social class, although having less influence on parental willingness to educate children, mediates the actual uptake of opportunities.34 6.4 Private schools: providing an opportunity for girls? Girls have been systematically discriminated against in education in Pakistan, with one girls’ primary school built for every two boys’; resultantly, only 36.8% of women were literate in 2000–01 compared with a male literacy level of 61% (Lloyd et al 2002: 3; Heward 1999). However, private schools appear to offer an alternative. Indeed, more girls, as a percentage of the total students in each school type, enrol in private schools than in public at a national level (MSU 2002). This finding, corroborated by this research, is in spite of the fact that private schools are mixed. Moreover, although on 34 The locations may have been important in reflecting a high demand for education, as other villages visited seemed much more cynical about education and less reticent to support either government schools - 55 - average over 80% of the teachers are female, they have a mixed teaching staff (table 5). Parents stated that they have ‘no qualms’ about male teachers, and, at least until grade eight, no problems with mixed classes: “Boys and girls could study together till middle (grade 8) but not after that ….because too many scandals may be created as after middle the youngsters become too ‘aware’ and making them study together is asking for trouble” (Father, Private School B). This has significant policy implications for the Government, which has built at hugely additional costs, separate primary and middle schools (Warwick and Reimers 1995). It also suggests that the requirement to employ female teachers for girls is no longer the constraint it was, as long as there is a mixed teaching staff in the school. Furthermore, girls are better students than boys, a feeling which came across in every school regardless of type. Boys were not as “enthusiastic” (Mother, Private School B), whilst “(g)irls are more prudent…more intelligent and hardworking” (Father, NFE Centre C). One reason given for the lack of interest is that “they (boys) have lands and they will have to ultimately take care of their lands so there is no need for education” (Father GGPS C). Moreover, the disciplining of girls in that they remained in the home and were less likely to be playing in the streets produces better results: “Here girls are more seriously involved in education. Under the strict supervision of mothers girls find a better environment to focus on studies without any distraction.” (Father, Madrassah C) The dedication of the girls, especially when parents are paying for education, results in them being given more opportunity to study and parents are more willing to pay. However, the barriers remain as long as there are insufficient numbers and inaccessible high schools for girls: one mother aptly commented that, given the boys lack of enthusiasm “it is sad that they got the opportunities for higher education, not the girls” (Mother, Private School C). Menarche often marked the time when girls were no longer allowed to go to school. However, cultural norms, for example the practice of purdah in Muslim families, should not be seen as rigid and unchanging structures. Private schools appear to be offering girls more leeway to continue studying than was previously facilitated by public schools alone, especially after primary grades. or private schools. However, broad trends recognised elsewhere suggest the representative nature of this work (Gazdar 1999; Heward 1999; Lloyd et al 2002) as does triangulation via key informant interviews. - 56 - 6.5 Choosing between options: who makes the decision? The actual process of parental decision-making about schools is complex, and merits further research. Bargaining and negotiation can occur between husband and wife, parent and child (Kabeer 1994). The decision-making about education appeared to be made jointly within the household, with fathers deciding the price-range and mothers looking after the actual selection and monitoring of the school: “My mother scolds us when we don’t want to go to school. She forcefully sends us here” (Male Student (MS), Private School G). This division of responsibility, however, was far from neat, with conflict arising over the education: “My daughter has completed her 5th grade and is so passionate to continue her studies but we don’t have enough money to let her continue her studies. I fully understand the significance of education but my husband doesn’t do any thing (unemployed) and when I enrolled my son here in class prep without his father’s permission he punished me…he often beats me…my son is 7 years old and has been admitted here in class prep. His father wants to send him in some hotel but I categorically told him I will do anything, but I will send him to school and finally I succeeded.” (Mother, NFE A) This dilemma reflects the constant tension which poor parents face regarding costs of education and the benefits that their children could reap. Choice, in this situation, is of a very limited nature. There are multiple perspectives on what is important in making choices. Three key elements stand out, however: the material costs of the school, the location and the perceived quality. 6.5.1 Cost: “A sacrifice we have to make” No schooling is ‘free’ in Pakistan as direct, hidden and opportunity costs of the child not working need to be factored in. Countervailed to this is the high value given to education resulting in a significant demand, creating a tension in the struggles which poor people go through in trying to educate their children: - 57 - “Education is essential if you want to be successful in life and we’d rather spend money on our children’s schooling than ourselves; that’s a sacrifice that we have to make if we want to see our children flourish.” (Father, Private School H) It seems, rather than there being a surfeit of choice in the Pakistani education market as a result of the growth of private provision, choice is immediately curtailed by a lack of money (Gazdar 1999). This results in a ranking of schools according to costs, just to see whether it is within the price range of the family. The process of deciding according to cost is simple: many parents stated that “this school was not as expensive as other private schools” (Mother, Private School H). For parents who are unable to afford private schools, the other cheaper options are more viable “as we don’t have to pay anything …tuition and especially books are free” (Father, NFE A). Parents seem to be very price sensitive, both about fees and other costs. When the Government introduced free school books into primary schools, anecdotal evidence suggested that children enrolled into government schools from private ones, especially in the lower grades (pers.comm. HT GGPS A). Equally, in private schools, incentives and cost-management are prevalent: “The best thing about this school is (that) it lends books to parents, helping them cut costs (and) families are given leeway to pay fees late or in instalments” (Parent, Private School H). Social differentiation occurs between school-going children and those either out-of-school or in child labour, as well as between schools. According to one parent “only the really destitute don’t send their children to school” (Father Private School G), which shows how contingent opportunities are on material well-being. Even the madrassah option is subject to costs: in rural and urban areas alike, madaris were considered but discarded by many parents on the basis of cost: “We like madrassahs and have nothing against them, but what can we do? They are just additional costs.” (Father, Private School G). As a result, only very “religious minded people send their kids to madrassahs” (Mother, GGPS C). This runs counter to the generally held assumption that madaris have a social safety net function, their low or absent cost seen as an attractive feature (Nayyer 1998); however, no conclusions can be drawn due to the small sample size of madaris in this study. Surprisingly some parents felt that paying for education did not result in value for money and saw private schools as businesses: “(p)rivate school are here just to make a lot of - 58 - money” (Father, NFE A). Yet, private school parents viewed other options as determined by cost: “NFE is an option for people even poorer than us. Such families have an inclination to educate their kids but at the same time they want their children to help their parents in their work to increase the monthly income” (Mother, Private School H). The very fact that they were paying for education private school, some parents felt, would automatically lead to a better result, and as a result were complacent about the quality delivered. This may be one explanation for the apparent growth in ‘tuition’ centres. The more that is spent on education and the more a child is in school, the better are the expected learning outcomes. Even poor parents who send their children to NFE Centres also send their children to the tuition centres run by ‘qualified girls’ of the area. This is because parents feel they cannot help the children in their studies: “the parents who are educated to some extent, check the daily work of their kids and guide them accordingly… but uneducated parents who can afford….don’t find any other choice except sending them to tuition centres” (Mother, NFE Centre C). It is also a strategy for covering all bases, as tuition centres are a kind of diversification mechanism to spread the risk amongst schools: “I send my two daughters who are studying in government primary school to X private school who offers tuition after the school time is over. I pay Rs. 50 each (child) as tuition fee” (Mother GGPS C). Other literature alludes to the possibility that parents are being duped into paying additional fees for extra classes in the afternoon in the same school by unscrupulous owners who suggest that children need special attention, especially in the higher grades (Bray 2003). This is probably true, but begs the question as to why children actually pay to attend school in the first place where less qualified teachers in multi-grade classrooms struggle to ‘impart’ the required knowledge.35 6.5.2 The closer the better? The benefits of the private school next door If cost is the principal factor determining whether children go to school, location and proximity would be likely to be a key element in parents deciding which school to go to 35 The curriculum in Pakistan at Primary and Middle level is about learning and regurgitating facts. Time is required to do this effectively; hence tuition centres are prevalent in higher grades where more time is required. - 59 - (Gerwitz et al, 1995). Certainly, parents did tend to send their children to schools which were close by. Indeed, it ranks alongside cost and quality for some parents in choosing and changing schools, as this student commented: “I got admission here in prep [but] there were some domestic problems so my father transferred me to Government school. I studied there for just three months [but] Government school is far from here so my parents decided to send me here as we live in the next street” (FS, Private School B) Proximity was associated with safety, both in terms of the dangers of crossing main roads but also the idea that the social space of the street was dangerous and unknown. Furthermore, proximity for parents was conflated with knowledge of the school. Typical for many parents is the following comment from a mother in Gharibabad: “The good thing about this school is that it is nearby and we don’t have to worry about our children wandering away. Sending our children to a school that is far away is a risk because…who knows what the school may do to them?” (Private School B) Transport connections and distance severely restrict access, especially in the rural areas. At primary level, with government schools located within walking distance, access was not a problem. However, after grade five, children frequently had to travel significant distances for middle and high government school, or pay substantial fees for private schools or private tuition. “No one can imagine how traumatic it becomes when we send our young girls to high school which is 18 to 20 kilometres away from our area. We don’t have any proper transportation facility in our area. It is so miserable for young girls to go by local vans which are already fully packed. Our male family members are against girl’s higher education.” (Mother, GGPS C) This alludes to different cultural attitudes which come into play with older girls, which are frequently passed off as transport considerations, limiting access to post-primary opportunities (Gazdar 1999): “After middle girls are considered ‘young women’ and are expected to stay home and not step outside unless necessary. The boys have it better: they can travel to schools by vans or bicycles outside the village if they want to pursue higher studies” (Father, Private School H) The comparative advantage of private schools and tuition centres catering to this age group, especially for girls, is considerable as they are located close to the home. - 60 - However, unless the family has money, the child will be denied access to education. This suggests double discrimination, where opportunities are based on both social class and on gender. 6.6 Exploring parental perceptions of quality Parental perception of quality is shaped by an amalgam of different elements. How parents, who may not have that much experience of schools, actually rate the ‘quality’ is a complex phenomenon. Four aspects emerge as important in determining how parents choose schools based on their perception of quality: firstly, personal relationships, peer group reference and reputation; secondly, the role of the teacher; thirdly, the internal environment within a school matters of what is taught and how it is taught; and fourthly, the external environment of the facilities of a school. 6.6.1 Peer-group reference and (non)information Parents suggested that certain schools gave better results. The basis for this appears to be speaking with neighbours and family, and a process of trial and error in school selection. Unlike a ‘pure’ market, information about schools is difficult to attain, and for illiterate parents, difficult to understand; no parent looked at the results of schools (admittedly only recently made available at 8th grade). This means that people rely on reputation and trust. Government schools were subject to a poor reputation, which appears to be something deeply ingrained within Pakistani society (Warwick and Reimers 1995). Private school parents felt that government school was below them: “My kids have never been in government schools but I am well aware of the bad reputation of government schools as teachers hardly come to teach and when they come they barely teach and the students spent most of their time playing and wasting time.” (Mother, Private School C) However, private schools are not always held in high regard by parents. Securing trust also points to why private schools strive to get themselves registered: “We cannot trust private schools. Usually without any serious intentions people decide to set up a school with the help of their own young unemployed educated family members. When these youngsters get some - 61 - better employment opportunities they leave the school and ultimately, after one or two years, they have to close the schools.” (Father, GGPS C) Although this may smack of resentment because of a lack of material resources to afford private schools, there is often a deep scepticism about private schools. This lack of trust in private schools reflects a feeling that collusion between education officials and private owners, discussed in chapter 4, results in sub-standard education in which poor parents are being exploited (Sawada and Lokshin, 2001): “Most of the private schools are not registered. They just claim [to be] but in reality, with the underhand co-operation of education officials they are running schools…all these things cause trepidation....and parents don’t opt for private schools.” (Father, Madrassah C) Moreover, there is still a feeling that “a boy who completes his education from government school can get government job (more) easily than the student of an unacknowledged private school” (Father GGPS C). As a result, parents will frequently move their children between schools, basing decisions on how their children are doing and how other people’s children appear to be doing in other schools. Personal connections matter, however, in choosing schools, and private schools are often run and staffed by people from the community, whereas government schools have appointed teachers from outside. Chapter 5 shows how owners attract parents by paying personal visits and their profile in the community. This differs little from other research into parental choice, in which the head teachers’ style, personality, outlook and approachability is important for parents (Gerwitz et al 1995: Woods et al 1998). 6.6.2 Teachers: good barometers of quality? Teachers are seen as barometers of quality, and are most closely associated with the ‘results’ the child attains. The parents tended to focus on the role of the teacher, as they have daily dealings with the children. Both the attitude and the physical attendance of teachers mattered in judging a school. Unsurprisingly, government teachers came under much criticism as “(t)he major problem with govt. schools was that the teachers didn’t bother to be regular in their attendance… those schools are complete mess and they are run with no sense of responsibility” (Father, Private School F). Nor were they able “to pay individual attention” (Mother, GGPS C) to the children, due to the class size and lack - 62 - of teachers. Their ‘quality’, in terms of academic qualifications, was not an issue with most parents: they were seen to be good if they could maintain discipline, emerging as one of the key factors of ‘quality’ of a school. How this is achieved and maintained, however, is a matter of deeper concern. 6.6.3 Parental priorities: Discipline and punish or teaching and learning? Parental interest about what was being taught was notable by its absence. Issues of curriculum, levels of maths, science and languages or pedagogic methodology did not emerge in the FGDs. This may partly be due to the difficulties parents have engaging with an alien environment such as a school, and the power dynamics of parents speaking with head teachers or teachers. This made it problematic for them to measure student progression and school quality. Actual learning does not enter into the purview of parents, but the very fact that children go to school - especially when they are paying for it and can hear children chanting, in chorus, numbers or the alphabet, must mean they are learning something. Conversely, this research points to a set of values as prime qualitative concerns for parents. The ability of the school to provide discipline (and the appropriate punishment), create orderliness and ensure cleanliness dominated responses. This reflects the aspirations of parents for their children to lead a different kind of life from them. Although a natural concern, it is also modelled on a ‘middle class’ attitude and impressions gained from increased access to the media.36 According to Bourdieu, “(e)ven when it is in no way inspired by the conscious concern to stand aloof from working class laxity, every bourgeois profession of vigour, every eulogy of the clean, sober and neat, contains a tacit reference to uncleanliness, in words or things, to intemperance or imprudence” (1986: 246-7). Whilst this is written of a different society, the underpinning value-ordering process remains relevant. This sense of othering or bordering which reproduce inequalities through education is important for understanding not only the high 36 Whilst it has been noted that there is a very small middle class in Pakistan, I would argue that the image, seen everywhere on posters, TV and radio advertisements and programmes, is very powerful. The media has been highlighted as one of the key drivers of change in Pakistan (Nadvi and Robinson 2004). - 63 - demand for private schools, but also important for understanding why quality concerns take the form they do (Schwalbe et al 2000). Demand for discipline is double-edged sword for schools. Parents seek environments which ensure that their children are provided firm discipline, to make them educated and ‘polite’, through appropriate punishment. This is of express concern for boys, as girls, it was repeatedly said, were much more amenable: “Here boys are so rude. They don’t obey their parents. They are so insolent, they must be punished. We ourselves ask the teacher to punish our children …children study well only if they fear their teacher” (Father, NFE Centre C) Thus whilst fearing the teacher is seen as integral to the learning process, punishment should not extend too far. Parents seem relatively responsive to their children’s concerns about punishment, who become “totally fed up with the maltreatment of his teachers” (Mother, NFE Makki 460) and will remove their children from school if they are excessively beaten. This creates a fine line for schools to follow, who must have teacher and head teachers who are “strict disciplinarians” but not excessive: “One of the teachers in our previous school (private) slapped me so forcefully on my face that blood came out from my mouth…..now here in this school I am happy as our teachers do not punish us.” (MS, Private School H) The inculcation of manners and politeness in children was the aim for parents. Private schools were seen as having the advantage. As one mother stated, “by sending my children to a private school, I am ensuring that they learn manners and the proper way of speaking” (Private School C). This reflects the status symbol that education represents, and the trappings of ‘civility’ for which they strive. The advantage of having a uniform was apparent, yet is construed differently than previously recorded (Andrabi et al 2002; Alderman et al 2001). Children who are sent to private schools become clean; teachers ensure that the children’s appearance is spruced up in school, thereby giving the parents the impression that the children are improving. A package of ‘values’ is provided by schools, where cleanliness and manners were closely associated; “the uniform is regularly checked here and the children were taught proper manners and cleanliness” (Mother, Private School C). By contrast, government schools - 64 - were seen by private school parents in both localities as unreliable, dirty, a place to play and not to study, and unsafe; “(c)hildren just waste time and get filthy” in Government Schools (Mother, Private School B). 6.6.4 Minimum facilities: ‘the children can bear it’ The extent and standard of physical facilities have been seen to be determinates in sending children, especially girls, to school in Pakistan, as elsewhere in South Asia (Heward 1999). It is a commonly accepted assumption that parents are looking for security and respectability before they send their children in school (Lloyd et al 2002). Some responses corroborated this opinion; “We feel ashamed of sending our girls in a school where there is no security, no boundary wall” (Mother, GGPS C). From the mapping survey, the difference between government and private schools is not that significant: indeed, observed facilities - in terms of playground, water, sanitary facilities tended to be marginally better in government schools.37 However, the relative importance that parents gave to the facilities within private schools was surprisingly low. An oft-repeated remark was that children can make do with the minimum - and that minimum refers to security issues rather than anything else: as one mother from a private school (H) remarked, “(t)he Government Schools had bathrooms, but most private schools do not have good bathrooms. But it doesn’t matter: the children can bear it”. The same was said for water supply, which they could get from home, and limited classroom space. The benefits that private schools have, from this research seemingly the most crucial, is the constrained space and security of being inside a homelike environment. This has attractions for parents who expect their children to be neat, clean and tidy, which is easier to ensure by not letting children out. The parents’ subject perspective juxtaposed with that of the children reveals diverging priorities. 37 As a caveat, it is important to note that government school facilities have been found to be seriously deficient in other work (Gazdar 1999). Much depends on the locality. - 65 - 6.7 Children’s differing perspectives: “A school should look like a school” By contrast to their parents, children were much more aware of the quality of education. Quality is seen by some children in a more holistic way - indeed, their understanding of ‘good’ education appears to be far more sensitive and nuanced that that of either their parents or, indeed, the teachers. One student commented on his previous school that “their method of teaching was not good. Our English teacher used to skip important words” (Private School C). The physical environment matters to the students much more than for either their parents or the providers. This is due to the fact that the students have to suffer daily the frequently dreadful conditions of the schools. Reflecting on his previous private school, one student recoiled: “there were only 2 rooms…it was so difficult to concentrate on studies as there was a lot of noise.” (MS, NGO B). The NGO School, offering easily the best facilities and standard of teaching observed, was recognised by the children as a good school: “I was studying in a private school. Now here in NGO B…I like the capacious building and cleanliness of my school. Teachers are so kind: they teach us in an interesting way.” (MS, NGO B) A selection of the many observations from all types of schools furnishes a snapshot of general perception of other schools offering undifferentiated quality: “the site of our school is not proper. There are rubbish heaps outside the school” (MS, Madrassah C); “Our toilet is not good. Most of the time it is blocked” (FS, Private School G); “I wish the class had more classes; it just gets too crowded” (FS, GGPS C); “there are unlimited flies in the school” (MS, Madrassah C); “We have a hand pump here but it gives contaminated water” (FS, Private School H). Children yearn after the opportunity to play, desiring trees, a play ground, plants, and swings. Inside the classroom they want tables, chairs and charts. Overall, children wanted an atmosphere that matched their mental image of a good school. Their PRA drawings all showed their idealised picture. The following quote captures this succinctly: “I don’t like this school as it resembles home… A School should be like a school not like a home.” (MS, NFE A). Yet neither parents nor owners give much credence to this. This suggests that children lack agency to influence their parents, whilst owners place a low value on - 66 - improving facilities as long as parents still send their children. Children’s perceptions of schooling, and their degree of agency in decision-making, merits further research. 6.8 Choice: subject to ever-present trade-offs Choice of school is not a one-off decision for most parents, but an on-going balancing of different options permitted by their own situation. In tracking the education history of the children, it became apparent that many had changed school. From the PRA data, 31% of all children changes school at least once in their primary school career, rising to over 40% of children in private schools. Determined by both cost, proximity and quality considerations, one mother typifies the problems with paying for school: “My kid of grade 2 was in a private school, I was paying Rs. 30 as fee. But my husband fell prey to paralysis and we had no other choice except to take our child out of school. But when this school was opened here we thought it was the only choice for him.” (Mother, NFE Centre A) This reflects the dynamic nature of poverty within Pakistan, with households becoming transitorily poor (in which expenditure levels fall below the poverty line for a period), making household decisions about expenditure on schooling more acute for a short period (Baulch and McCulloch 1999). The outcome is that parents will remove children from school, and at a later date put them back in to either the same or a different school at a different price level. Whilst advocates of ‘choice’ in schooling would, perhaps, view this as exercising voice through exit, in reality the choice is a false one. It is not likely to push the prices down (as the market mechanism would indicate) as there are enough consumers to pay for the commodity at that price, given that household shocks and transitional poverty are idiosyncratic (household specific) rather than covariant risks. Children are likely to suffer from a disruption in their education as a result, as the following quotes bear out: “My father is a chronic victim of T.B. He gets fits sometimes. We all become so sad (because) our financial condition didn’t allow my elder brothers and sister to continue their studies. He (father) wants me to discontinue my studies but my mother encourages me to study properly.” (FS, Private School C) The prioritisation of education spending within the household basket, despite the high value, will take second place to more pressing concerns, such as debt: - 67 - “My parents cannot afford my fee so I will discontinue my studies…and when my father will pay all the debts then I shall re-continue my studies.” (FS, Private School B) Having dropped out, children often find it harder to re-enter the education cycle (Moore 2001). This makes for a fragmented education for the child and places a strain on the schools, given that are never sure of their sustainability. Moreover, a ‘herding’ between schools exists. One example is when a private school sacked their teachers and the new ones were not “as good”, according to several parents who had taken their children out of that school and put into others close by. Parents may have an instinctive belief whether their children are progressing well or not, due to the fact that they would involve their children in ‘school-hopping’ from one school to the next. However, as shown above, their criteria for choosing may not protect the ‘best interest’ of the child concerned. 6.9 The myth of choice The chronically poor, however, cannot afford any education: even that of the supposedly free government schools is beyond their means. Children have to “share the burden” of survival with their parents. This problem affects urban and rural poor alike: “We have a lot of domestic problems…there are more than 6 or 7 members in the family and the bread winner is only one. And one man cannot fulfil the requirements of the whole family so we are compelled to send our children to do some work to share the burden of their fathers.” (Mother, NFE C). This may lead to selecting, on birth order, perceived intelligence or diligence, which of the children is given the opportunity of schooling, issues which merit further research. However, child labour is more than an economic survival strategy but a means for a relevant training in skills necessary for life. Indeed, some parents recognise it as an education in itself, rather than child labour: “Our children are not involved in child labour. We send our kids to the fields and kilns where their fathers work to hand over lunch to them and they start working over there not only to help their fathers but also to learn the art of brick making or harvesting after their own accord.” (Mother, NFE A) - 68 - This may reflect the lack of relevance of what is taught in school to the daily lives of children (SPDC 2003). This questions the very fundamentals of what is taught and what is learned in school. The consumer domain is not homogenous, and many parents appeared to have contradictory reasons for choosing certain schools. This matches Lloyd et al’s (2002: 14) findings, which indicates that both “public and private (options of schooling) each have distinct features valued by parents”. However, access to schools, decided by a trade off between cost and dubious quality considerations, is neither transformative nor emancipatory (Gazdar 1999). Instead it appears to be entrenching inequality in curious ways. The result is the development of a pyramidal structure of school types by preference, determined by cost, with private schools elevated to a badge of status. The positive aspect is that private options augment female access to schools. Demand for education appears to be high, but how this willingness to educate their children translates into active demanding by the parents for a good quality in any school deserves further education. Initial findings suggest that parents feel a lack of agency in their ability to change facilities within all schools which develops into a fatalism about the standard of education: “Children of junior level sit on the ground under the trees...most of them without mats…we know our kids will have to study in the open area in scorching sunlight but we cant do anything” (Mother, GGPS A). Even when paying for education, parents did not exert voice nor pressure the school to deliver. Children, in all schools, lack agency. Thus choice in the quasi-market is not producing better quality as understandings of basic standards are absent and informational asymmetries pervade. - 69 - CHAPTER 7: Conclusion and implications of the myth of choice The emergence of low cost private schooling poses multiple challenges to the provision of quality universal basic education in Pakistan. This paper has attempted to disentangle the factors that have driven their growth and explore some the implications of a vibrant private sector. This paper took as its original premise that choice was increasing for poor people, even in rural areas (Andrabi et al 2002).38 Indeed, the range of education alternatives in Pakistan has expanded over the last decade through rising supply via private provision. Proponents of private provision argue that such an expansion is likely to, via competition, augment choice, improve the quality and increase the efficiency of the education delivered (Chubb and Moe 1990; Jimenez and Lockheed 1995). However, research undertaken in one urban and one rural setting in Punjab show that choice is a myth in quasi-markets in Pakistan as there are insufficient alternative suppliers available to a significant proportion of families (Gintis 1996). The poor, excluded from accessing private provision primarily by a lack of money but also through other socio-cultural constraints, are finding that government provision is worsening. This is a consequence of the withdrawal of the powerful from the use of these services. School owners, by contrast, are able to make significant profit without having to provide quality education, given that the government schools are so poor. Parents, even those who can afford private schools, are left with little choice between poor quality schools. Parents struggle to accurately assess the quality of the services they purchase due to information asymmetries mediated through patronage connections, and the quality they do demand is of an inferior type. The findings of this research and their related implications fall into three broad and interconnected categories: government level policy and state provision; potential engagement with private schools on the supply-side; and demand side issues. 38 The current literature trumpets the growth of private provision as providing a choice for poor parents, which was the starting point of the research. The subsequent questioning of the actual choice available to poor parents became apparent during the empirical and data analysis stage. - 70 - Connections to the wider debates on the promotion of choice through private provision are subsequently drawn. 7.1 Implications for government provision and policy Current government policy is merely reacting to unregulated, spontaneous provision caused by deficient schools and systematic under-provision by the state. Lax application of regulation by a disinterested state bureaucracy enables private schools to flourish. For national policy, state provision seems likely to be ineffective so long as the current policy trajectory continues without taking into account embedded inequalities. The education market is politicised in Pakistan, as elsewhere, but politics bites more deeply, reflecting the feudal and patronage-ridden environment. As a consequence, there is a negative impact on efforts to improve government schools, as those with power, influence and money within communities, including elected officials, bureaucrats and teachers, have bought out of the system by sending their children to private schools. The removal of the ‘sharp elbow’ to improve the state sector reflects deeper inequalities within Pakistan (Deacon 2000). No silver bullets exist to transform a moribund government sector: tentative policy recommendations need to be located within the bureaucratic, political and economic constraints. In areas where demand remains low, private provision will not develop, causing market failure. Equally, in the absence of competitive markets, private schools are allowed the luxury of sinking to the lowest common denominator, which at present is the government school (if one is functioning). Measures to reform government schools are beyond the scope of this paper, but would appear to be of utmost importance if overall access and quality improvements are to be achieved. In a context where universal provision is still a chimera, the government would appear hypocritical to enforce rigid quality standards and restrict private provision. However, regulation through districtlevel private education cells and capacity building on monitoring of all schools would be useful first steps. - 71 - 7.2 Implications for potential engagement with private schools In terms of Wood’s (1994) model of school response (table 2), schools attempt to understand and respond to parental preference. However, the use of political connections and lobbying through patronage networks is being played out in a way that undermines the basis of the competitive environment. Moreover, schools do not attempt to maximise the profit as they are run along the lines of small family businesses, and are therefore reticent to expand beyond a certain size or invest in facility upgrading. This minimises risk for the family but, as a corollary, private schools remain ill-conducive learning environments. The policy implications of this are significant. External efforts to improve private schools, such as providing teacher training, are likely to come up against owner intransigence, fearing that teachers will seek better employment or demand higher wages. How the government can engage effectively with diverse and numerous forms of provision deserves further research, but given the current prognosis, the opportunities for doing so appear limited. 7.3 Implications for demand-side choice Parental ‘choice’ is shown to be a complex and contingent process which is frequently constrained by cost. Even where different education options exist (and in the two communities studied, they are numerous) choice between them is not a realistic option for many. Four findings stand out as surprising on the demand-side. Firstly, parental perception of quality differed from the expected. Parental discourse on quality did not emphasise the instrumental-academic and outcomes as making a good school, as an expected response to a competitive environment (figure 2), nor veer towards the intrinsic-personal dimension of education being process-orientated (Woods et al 1998). Instead, the instillation of values of good manners, cleanliness and orderliness through firm discipline were dominant tendencies. This reveals that the values that parents in Pakistan hold differ from those understood in the literature on choice. In a comparison with empirical work in India, Rampal (2004) found that “poor parents may have good reason to be satisfied with a school where the teacher comes regularly…irrespective of what goes on in the name of teaching and, more crucially, the quality of learning”. One policy recommendation that emerges is the need to fill informational gaps about what - 72 - standards – a basic minimum or quality threshold – should be expected of any school. Bottom-up efforts and an exertion of parental voice to demand real quality would thereby be encouraged. The quality concerns of children are markedly distinct to that of their parents or the school owners. Children value space for playing and lay an emphasis on the school environment as well as the quality of the teaching. Whether the parents are the best judges in choosing the schools, however, needs to be situated within the context of nonuniversal and sub-standard provision. One interesting aspect that deserves further attention is the potential to make the children’s voices be heard in the running of schools and even in policy, as has happened elsewhere in South Asia (Williams 2004). Thirdly, parents are sending their girls to private school. Several reasons for this emerged: access of boys to better government schools; the proximity and security of private schools; the better study habits of girl students. It points to changing social norms, but also to the opportunities presented by private schools to expand female enrolment. One area of policy focus would be to assess the opportunity of subsidising girl students in registered and quality-assured private schools, especially at secondary school level. It also indicates that government policy of creating single-sex institutions should be revised. Fourthly, there is a temporal and dynamic aspect of choice that was not captured by the spatial framework of figure 1, as schooling decisions are subject to ever-present tradeoffs, resulting in children dropping out and shifting schools frequently. This suggests the need to establish mechanisms for tracking children in their education career to ensure that efforts to keep them in school are properly targeted. Further research would provide a better understanding as to the nature of this dynamic, and how it links with poverty cycles for poor families. 7.4 Wider significance of the myth of choice The private sector in education in Pakistan looks set to remain an important element in delivering basic services, even in poor communities. However, where various perverse - 73 - incentives combine to exclude quality-based competition and a diminution of support for government schools, the empirical evidence provided in this paper reveals an actual narrowing or even denying of choice. Thus a pragmatic approach that recognises the importance of successfully reforming the public sector while harnessing what private schools offer but mitigating their negative impact emerges as the most appropriate response. Yet given the current environment, there is a distinct danger that policy will further be pushed along the path towards privatising education provision. This critical analysis of choice in education quasi-markets has wider resonances, as private provision is increasingly been lauded as a mechanism for delivering good services cheaply (World Bank 2003a). The education market in Pakistan, despite its historical idiosyncrasies, is typical of a developing country context in which quasimarkets develop within a context of non-universal provision. Comparative research to highlight similarities and differences would help foster a more informed debate on the implications of private provision and the myth of choice. Efforts to make the myth of choice into a reality are both ideologically questionable and, until universal provision has been achieved, practicably impossible. Concentration on delivering free education to all in Pakistan, as elsewhere, should remain the highest priority. - 74 - Bibliography Adler, M., 1993, ‘Parental Choice and the enhancement of children’s interest, in Munn, P (ed.), Parents and schools: customers, managers or partners?, London: Routledge Alderman, H., Kim, J. and Orazem, P., 1999, ‘Can Private School Subsidies Increase Enrollment for the Poor? The Quetta Urban Fellowship Program’ World Bank Economic Review, vol. 13 (3). Alderman, H., Orazem, P. and Paterno, E., 2001, ‘School Quality, School Cost, and the Public/Private School Choices of Low-Income Households in Pakistan’, Journal of Human Resources 36 Andrabi, T., J. Das and A. Khwaja, 2002, The Rise of Private Schooling in Pakistan: Catering to the Urban Elite or Educating the Rural Poor? World Bank and Harvard University Apple, M., 2001, ‘Comparing neo-liberal projects and inequality in education’, Comparative Education Vol. 73/4 Asian Development Bank, 2003, Government and Nongovernment provision of primary education in Bangladesh, Indonesia and Nepal, Operations Evaluation Department, SS-52: Asian Development Bank, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/SES/REG/ses_reg_200305.pdf Ball, S., 1990, Politics and Policy Making in Education: Explorations in Policy Sociology, Routledge: London Baulch, B. and N. McCulloch, 1998 ‘Being Poor and Becoming Poor: Poverty Status and Poverty Transitions in Rural Pakistan’, Working Paper No. 79, Brighton: IDS Bengali, K., 1999, History of Educational Policy Making and Planning in Pakistan, Islamabad: SDPI Working Paper Series #40 Booth, D., J. Holland, J. Hentschel, P. Lanjouw, A. Herbert, 1998, Participation and Combined Methods in African Poverty Assessment: renewing the agenda DFID Issues Paper, available at: http://www.dfid.gov.uk/public/what/advisory/group7/pdf/sddafpov.pdf Bourdieu, P., 1986, Distinction: A social critique of the Judgement of Taste, London: Routledge Bray, M., 2003, Adverse effects of private supplementary tutoring: Dimensions, implications and government responses, Paris: IIEP/UNESCO Bray, M., 2000, Community partnerships in education: Dimensions, variations and implications. Dakar: EFA Thematic Study - 75 - Bray, M., 1997, Community financing of education: rationales, mechanisms and policy implications in less developed countries, in Colclough ed., Marketising Education and Health in Developing Countries, Clarendon Press Bray, M., 1996, Counting the Full Cost. Parental and Community Financing of Education in East Asia. Washington DC: World Bank Brown, P., Halsey, A.H., Lauder, H. and Wells, A., 1997, ‘The transformation of Education and Society’, in Halsey et al (eds) Education: Culture, Economy and Society, Oxford: OUP Burnett, N., 2002, Pakistan: Working with the Private Sector in Primary and Middle School Education, SASHD, World Bank, Mimeo Carnoy, M., 1999, Globalization and educational reform: what planners need to know, International Institute for educational Planning, UNESCO: Paris Chubb, J. and Moe, T., 1997, ‘Politics markets and equality in schools’ in Shapira, R. and Cookson, P (eds) Autonomy and choice in context, London: Pergamon Chubb, J. and Moe, T., 1990, Politics, markets and America’s Schools, Washington DC: The Brookings Institution Colclough, C., 1996, Education and the market: which parts of the neo liberal solution are correct? World Development, 24 (4): 589-610 Colclough, C., 1993,‘Who should learn to pay? An assessment of neo-liberal approaches to education policy’, in Colclough, C. & Manor, J. (eds), States or Markets? Neoliberalism and the development policy debate, Oxford: Clarendon Press Cox, S., and Robinson-Pant, A. (Eds), 2003, Empowering children through visual communication, School of Education an Professional Development: UEA Deacon, B., 2000, ‘Globalisation: A threat to Equitable Social Provision’, IDS Bulletin 31/4, Brighton: IDS Gaventa, J. and Valderrama, C., 1999, Participation, Citizenship and Local Governance, Background note prepared for workshop on Strengthening participation in local governance Institute of Development Studies, June 21-24, 1999 Gazdar, H., 2000, State, Community, and Universal Education: A Political Economy of Public Schooling in Rural Pakistan, Asia Research Centre, London School of Economics. Gazdar, H., 1999, ‘Universal basic education in Pakistan: A commentary on strategy and results of a survey,’ Working Paper no. 39, Islamabad: SDPI - 76 - Gewirtz, S., Ball, S. and Bowe, R., 1995, Markets, choice and equity in education, Buckingham: Open U.P. Giddens, A., 1984, The Constitution of Society, Cambridge, Polity Press Gintis, H., 1996, ‘School choice: the issues and options’, Prospects XXVI Government of Punjab, 2003, Punjab: Education Sector Reforms, Lahore: Government of Punjab Government of Pakistan, 2004, Public Private Partnerships in the Education Sector, Education Sector Reforms Action Plan 2001-2005, Islamabad, Ministry of Education Green, A., 1997, Education, Globalization and the Nation State, London, Macmillan Heward, C., 1999, ‘Closing the Gender Gap? The informal sector in Pakistan, in Heward and Bunwaree (eds), Gender, Education and Development: Beyond Access to Empowerment. London: Zed Books Hoodbhoy, P., 1998, ‘Out of Pakistan’s education morass: Possible? How?’, in Hoodbhoy (ed.), Education and the State, Karachi: OUP Hussain, A. with A.R. Kemal, A.I. Hamid, Imran Ali, Khawar Mumtaz, Ayub Qutub, 2003, Poverty, Growth and Governance: Pakistan HDR 2003, Islamabad: UNDP at http://www.un.org.pk/nhdr/ Jamil, B., 2003, Public Policy Options in Education: the case of Pakistan – Privatisation and equity and the emergent PPP in Education, Seminar by the Centre for Research on Poverty Reduction and Income Distribution (CRPRID), Islamabad Jamil, B., 2001, PPPs in Education: Perspectives form the political economy of education (draft), paper presented at National Symposium on International Experiences with Decentralisation and Education, Quetta Jimenez, E. and M. Lockheed, 1995, Public and Private Secondary Education in Developing countries: a comparative study. World Bank Discussion paper 309. Jimenez, E. and J. Tan, 1987, ‘Decentralised and Private Education: The case of Pakistan’, Comparative Education 23/2 Kabeer, N., 1994, Reversed realities: gender hierarchies in development thought, London: Verso Kabeer, N., 1997, ‘Women, Wages and Intra-household Power Relations in Urban Bangladesh’ Development and Change, Vol. 28. - 77 - Kardar, S., 2001, Private Sector in Education, Lahore: World Bank/ Systems (Private) Limited Katsis, A., Mattson, R. and Psacharopoulos, G., 1999, ‘Explaining Educational Development in Pakistan: An Analysis of the 1991 Household Survey’, Journal of Educational Planning and Administration 13(1). Keely, J. and Scoones, I., 1999, ‘Understanding environmental policy processes: a review’ IDS Working Paper 89, Brighton: IDS Khan, S., 2003, ‘Participation via collective action in government and NGO schools in Pakistan’, Development in Practice 13/4 Kingdon, G., 1996, ‘The quality and efficiency of private and public education: a case study of urban India’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 58.1, 57-81. Kitaev, I., 1999, Private Education in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Re-examination of theories and concepts related to its development and finance. Paris: IIEP/UNESCO Klees, S. J., 2002, ‘World Bank education policy: new rhetoric, old ideology’, International Journal of Educational Development, 22 Kumar, K., (forthcoming), Quality education at the beginning of the 21st century: Lessons from India, Background Paper for the EFA Global Monitoring Report on Quality 2005, http://www.unesco.org/education/efa/index.shtml Kwong, J., 2000, ‘Introduction: Marketisation and privatisation in education’, International Journal of Educational Development 20 Lauglo, J. 1995, ‘Forms of decentralisation and their implications for education’, Comparative Education 31(1) Levacic, R., 1995, Local management of schools: analysis and practice, Buckingham: Open UP Lloyd, C. B., Mete, C., and Sathar, Z. A., 2002, “The Effect of Gender Differences in Primary School Access, Type, and Quality on the Decision to Enrol in Rural Pakistan” Policy Division Working Paper of the Population Council, #164 Ministry of Finance and Planning (MFP), 2001, Interim-Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (I-PRSP) Government of Pakistan, Islamabad Ministry of Education in collaboration with UNESCO, 2003, National Plan of Action on Education for All (2001-2015) Pakistan, Islamabad, Government of Pakistan Minogue, M., Polidano, C., and Hulme, D. (eds), 1998, Beyond the New Public Management: Changing Ideas and Practices in Governance, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar - 78 - Moore, K., 2001, Frameworks for understanding the intergenerational transmission of poverty and well-being in developing countries CPRC Working Paper 8 University of Birmingham Multi-Donor Support Unit (MSU), 2002, Primary Education in Pakistan: Contribution of Public and Private Sectors, Islamabad: mimeo Mundy, K., 2002, ‘Retrospect and Prospect: education in a reforming World Bank’, International Journal of Educational Development Vol 22 Nadvi, K. and Robinson, M., 2004, Pakistan Drivers of change: Synthesis and policy implications, paper Commissioned by the Western Asia Department, DFID UK Najam, J., 2003, Community Participation Project (CPP) Journey to Success, Department of Primary Instruction, Lahore Nayyer, A.H., 1998, ‘Madrassah Education – Frozen in Time’, in Hoodbhoy, P. (ed.), Education and the State, Karachi: OUP Offe, C., 1984, Contradictions in the Welfare State, London, Hutchinson Punjab EMIS, forthcoming, 100% Enrolment Survey of Education Institutions in Sheikhupura District, Punjab, Lahore: Punjab EMIS Rampal, A., 2004, Unpacking the ‘quality’ of schools, available at http://www.indiaseminar.com/2004/536/536%20anita%20rampal.htm Savas, E.S., 2000, Privatisation and Public-Private Partnerships, New York: Chatham House Sawada, Y and M. Lokshin, 2001, Household Schooling Decisions in Rural Pakistan, Washington:World Bank at http://econ.worldbank.org/files/1400_wps2541.pdf Schwalbe, M., S. Godwin, D. Holden, D. Schrock, S. Thompson, M. Wolkomir, 2000 ‘Generic Processes in the Reproduction of Inequality: An Interactionist Analysis’ in Social Forces 79(2) SPDC, 2004, Social Development in Pakistan 2002-03: The state of education in Pakistan, Karachi: OUP Subrahmanian, R., 2003, ‘Exploring processes of marginalisation and inclusion in education’ in Subrahmanian, R., Sayed, Y., Balagopalan, S., and Soudien, C (eds)., Education Inclusion and Excusion, IDS Bullen 34/1, Brighton: IDS Theis, J., 1996, ‘Children and participatory appraisals: experiences from Vietnam’, PLA Notes 25, London: IIED - 79 - Tooley, J., 2001, Serving the needs of the poor: The private education sector in developing countries. Can the Market Save our Schools? Vancouver: The Fraser Institute Tooley, J., 1999, The Global Education Industry: Lessons from Private Education in Developing Countries. London: Institute of Economic Affairs UNESCO, 2002, Education for All, EFA Global Monitoring Report, UNESCO, Paris UNESCO, 2000, EFA 2000 Pakistan Country Report, Government of Pakistan, Ministry of Education: Islamabad Warwick, D. P. and Reimers, F., 1995, Hope or Despair? Learning in Pakistan’s Primary Schools. Westport, CT: Preager. Whitty, G., Power, S., and Halpin, D., 1998, Devolution and choice in education: the school, the state and the market, Buckingham:Open U.P. Williams, E., 2004, Children’s Participation and Policy Change in South Asia, CHIP Report No 6, Childhood Poverty and Research Centre Woods, P, Bagley, C. and Glatter R., 1998, School choice and competition: Markets in the public interest? London, Routledge Woods, P., 1994, School Response to the Quasi-Market, in Halstead, M. (Ed.) Parental Choice and Education, London: Kogan Page World Bank, 2003a, World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People, Washington: World Bank World Bank, 2003b, Public-Private Partnerships: a new paradigm for sustainable development in education, paper from the First Regional Conference On Secondary Education In Africa (SEIA), Washington D.C. World Bank, 1999, Education Sector Strategy, Washington DC: World Bank. Ziring, L. 2004, Pakistan: at the crosscurrent of history, Lahore: Vanguard - 80 - ANNEX 1: List of persons interviewed Officials/ Government Sector interviewees Date of interview 16/06/04 Person interviewed Post and place of interview Mr Qazi Afaaq Managing Director, Punjab Education Foundation, Islamabad Mr Afzal Ahmad District Officer, Planning, Skp. District, Skp. 15/05/04 Mr. Ch. Sardar Ali District Education Officer (DEO) Male Elementary Education, Skp. District 13/05/04 Mr. Mukhtar Ali Gill District Education Officer (DEO) Secondary, Sheikhupura District, Skp. 13/05/04 Prof. Javed Iqbal Executive District Officer (EDO) Education, Sheikhupura District, Skp. 13/05/04 Mr Afzul Haq Managing Director, National Education Foundation, Lahore 07/06/04 Mr Mohammad Khokhar Provincial EMIS Co-ordinator, Punjab, Lahore 04/05/04 (multiple) 04/06/04 Mrs. S. Naheed Munawar Lady Councillor, Union Council 62 Urban 4, Skp., Gharibabad Mr Muhammad Jamil Najam Director, Public Instruction (Elementary Education) Punjab/ Director, Community Participation Project (CPP), Lahore 07/06/04 Mr Tariq Najeeb Najami District Co-ordinating Officer (DCO), Sheikhupura 22/05/04 Mr Yawar Saeed Naib Nazim, Union Council 83, Makki 460 01/06/04 Dr. Muhammed Saleem Director EFA Wing, MoE, Islamabad Mrs. Iffat Anwar Shah District Education Officer (DEO) Female Elementary Education, Skp. District, Skp. 13/05/04 Mr. Malik Muhammad Sharif Executive District Officer (EDO) Literacy and IT, Skp. District, Skp. 14/05/04 Mr Sana Ullah Virk UC Nazim, Union Council 62 Urban 4, Skp, Gharibabad 04/06/04 - 81 - NGO sector interviewees Person interviewed Post Date of interview 07/06/04 Lt. Col. M. Anwar Awan Regional Manager, The Citizens Foundation, Lahore Ms. Nadia Ejaz Co-ordinator PULSE-NGO Project, Lahore 04/0/5/04 University of Management Sciences, Lahore Mr Abid Gill District Manager, Sudhaar-ITA Alliance, Skp. 10/05/04 (multiple) Mrs Nasira Habib Khoj’ - Society for People’s Education (NGO), Lahore 07/05/04 Mr Randy Hatfield Programme Manager Education, Aga Khan Foundation (Pakistan), Islamabad 16/06/04 Mrs Zibha Hussein Director, Child Resources International 15/06/04 Ms. Baela Jamil Director, ITA (Centre for Education and Consciousness) NGO, Lahore 28/4/04 (multiple) Mrs Zarina Jillani Research Co-ordinator, Society for the Protection of the Rights of the Child, Islamabad 15/06/04 Hamib Khawaja Co-ordinating Director, Co-operative for Advancement, Rehabilitation and Education (CARE), Lahore 07/05/04 Mrs Beena Manza Co-ordinator, School Improvement Network 15/05/04 Programme, Lahore Mr Fiaz Shah Programme Officer Education, Save the Children (UK), Islamabad 15/05/04 Dr. Fareeha Zafar Director, Society for the Advancement of Education (SAHE), Lahore 06/05/04 Mr Fawad Usman Executive Director, Sudhaar NGO, Lahore 01/05/04 Mrs Tracey WagnerRizvi National Co-ordinator, Society for the Protection of the Rights of the Child (SPARC), Islamabad 15/06/04 - 82 - People working in/ researching the sector Person interviewed Post Mrs Monazza Aslam DPhil candidate, Wolfson College, Oxford (researching private schools on field work), Lahore Dr Faisal Bari Professor, Lahore University of Management Sciences, Lahore 04/05/04 Mrs Maliha Hussein Independent Education Consultant, Islamabad 29/04/04 Mr Rafiq Jaffer Consultant, Institute of Social Studies, Lahore 15/05/04 Mr Shahid Kardar Independent education consultant, Systems Private Limited, Lahore 09/06/04 Ms. Ameena Khan Project Officer, ILO, Islamabad Takumi Koide JICA Expert, Punjab Literacy Programme, Lahore 08/05/04 Lahore University of Management Sciences, Lahore 11/06/04 District Empowerment Through Community Participation (DETCP), UNDP, Islamabad 14/06/04 Miguel Lourerio Mr Paul Oquist Date of interview 04/05/04 15/06/04 Dr. Masako Ota JICA Expert, EFA Wing, MoE, Islamabad Dr. Mark Poston Education Advisor, DFID-Pakistan, Islamabad/ 29/04/04 Skp. (Multiple) Mr Maurice Robson Chief, Education and Child Protection, UNICEF, Islamabad Mrs Sofia Shakeil Independent education consultant, Islamabad Dr Gulzar Shah Associate Professor, Lahore University of Management Sciences, Lahore 29/04/04 16/06/04 29/04/04 11/06/04 - 83 - ANNEX 2: Government Officials (district level and below) semi-structured key informant interviews pro-forma Date of visit/time:___________ Interviewer:__________________________ Name of interviewee:____________________________ Post: ________________________________________________________________ Held from/ until: _______________________ 1. Responsibilities (i.e. what is your mandate, what do you do on a daily basis etc) 2. Relationship with other levels of administration (issues of accountability, autonomy, problems arising) 3. Attitude towards Government Schools (failing/ working, reform initiatives undertaken) 4. Attitude towards Private Schools (Are private schools a ‘good thing’? levels of regulation, data collected) 5. Attitude towards NGOs (Is there close collaboration/ rivalry, NGO adopting schools, good service providers, sustainability) 6. Incentives to non-state and non-government sector - how do these work? (taxation, land, books) 7. Attitude towards Madaris (What role do madaris/ madrassah education play in Pakistan? What is the impact at the UC/Tehsil/District level) 8. Perspective on Community Participation (Is it good that the Community participates in education? How should they do so? Are there any drawbacks to this?) 9. Impact of devolution (How has devolution affected your role? What has changed/ stayed the same?) - 84 - ANNEX 3: School mapping with principals questionnaire Principals/ managers/ owners semi-structured pro-forma for mapping exercise Date of visit/time:___________ Interviewer:__________________________ Name of interviewee:____________________________ 1.School details: 1.1.Name 1.2.Address 1.3.Teshil: 1.4.Date of establishment: Markaz: 2.Rationale for existence (cultural, economic, social - FP/NFP) 3.Location 3.1.R/U 3.2.Socio-economic locale 3.3.Proximity to closet available alternative 4.School characteristics: 4.1.Cooed/ Single sex 4.2.Grades served 4.3.Number of students/ gender division 4.4.Register available? 4.5.Language medium 4.6.Textbooks used 4.7.Accreditation/ certification 5.School facilities 5.1.Number of classrooms 5.2.Sanitary facilities (y/n, mixed) 6.Management structure 6.1.By whom (NGO, religious, entrepreneur) Village/area: - 85 - 6.2.Links with community 7.Stewardship 7.1.I/C 7.2.Autonomy in decision-making 7.3.Regulation/ relations with gvt. 7.3.1.Registered? Details 7.4.Visits/ supervision 7.5.Incentives received/ barriers confronted 8.Teachers 8.1.Number/ grade and total 8.2.Gender 8.3.Level of experience/ qualifications 8.4.Turnover rate 8.5.Pay (monthly Rs) 9.Financing and financing 9.1.Fees/ month 9.2.Costs covered/ not covered (uniforms, food, books) 9.3.School expenditure/ revenue per child total 9.4.Surplus generated/ reinvested 9.5.External financing (donors/ gvt/ philanthropists) 9.6. Government aid received Other comments: - 86 - ANNEX 4: Parents FGD: key questions and prompts Introduction of who we are and what we are doing 1) Why are your children in [ ] centre/ school? what was your child doing before school? what is education/ why is it important? Is there a difference between the education of boys and girls? Are they in different schools? What problems have you encountered in getting your child educated? 2) What do you think about the other education options nearby? Govt School Private School Madrasah NFE What about not being in school at all - is that a viable option? 3) What factors are important for choosing a school Possible prompts: Proximity female teachers teachers qualifications attendance of teachers head teacher/ organiser motivation School buildings Number of classrooms latrines water electricity fans boundary wall cost textbook provision uniform popularity within community separation of boys and girls language medium - 87 - ANNEX 5: PRA Exercise with Children: “This is my family”39 What is PRA? Participatory Rural Appraisal (sometimes called Participatory Reflection and Action), commonly known as PRA, is a research tool which attempts to let people speak through exercises and activities. In the case of adults, these can be done through village mapping, seasonal charts, matrix and preference ranking. For children, activity-based and play exercises, such as drawing and singing are commonly used. This allows the children to express their thoughts, feelings and experiences in a more relaxed manner, and can produce some rich data as children have a unique and personal position both within the family and within the school. They are the ones who really know what life is like for them. One of the key elements is handing over control to the children and allowing free expression. However, as they are children there must be some framework for guidance provided. This is done by the facilitators in a sensitive and relaxed manner: a sense of fun is imperative! Purpose The purpose of this exercise is to find out what the children think about their schools, discovering in the process key elements which stand out for them. This is not predetermined but should emerge throughout the process. An auxiliary purpose of this exercise is to understand the decisions that parents, and children as active agents within the household, make in selecting certain schools. Important factors could be: the socio-economic profile of the child’s family (occupation father/ other relatives) the education attainment of parents the gender of the children/ and of brothers and sisters the birth order of the child (i.e. first born opportunities may differ from last born) the nature of the school (environment, teachers attitude etc) Through describing their family, the facilitators should probe as to what is important, and pursue avenues of discussion as they arise. This exercise should also provide a form of retrospective mapping of educational life of children - both the child taking part and his/her siblings. This will capture which schools (if any) the children have gone to previously and establish why changes have occurred (such as household shocks, changes in familial circumstances, changes in schools and increased opportunity). This will be done via informal probing and recorded by the facilitators. Methodology PRA is a flexible means of investigation. There are no set rules, and the facilitator should adapt to the situations which arise. In every situation they should select what they consider to be the most appropriate approach, and be prepared to change to arising circumstances. However, when working with children, it is vital to provide a framework of activities from which they can work off. This can be through games, discussing, drawing and feedback. The main PRA activity selected is communication through 39 This sheet was distributed to the facilitators. A clear briefing and trial run was done to practice and change the questions. The number of activities was increased to keep the children occupied. Photographic examples of the environments in which the PRA was conducted are appended. - 88 - drawing with probing questions used, supplemented by ice-breakers and one-on-one discussions, which are recorded on paper. The following steps should be used as a guideline and reminder: Step 1: Outline of exercise. Explain purpose of research and why we want to speak with the children. The facilitator with wall chart of his/her family will explain the drawing of the family, and the questioning that occurs simultaneously. Step 2: Icebreaker games with children (clapping, miming game, role play of acting as your teacher/ parents) Step 3: Distribution of charts and crayons. Encourage the children to draw family on the sheet, beginning with the parents and the siblings in age order. Step 4: Simultaneously, probing questions should be asked. These are outlined below, with a suggested sequencing. Step 5: In-depth conversations with children using the pictures as a framework for discussion. Step 6: Drawing of school and further discussions about likes and dislikes. Step 6 (optional, depending on time): Aspirations in a FGD with the children. What do they want to do next year, what are they likely to do? What they want to be in 10 years time (this could be done via another picture session, time permitting). Step 7: Wind up and post charts on walls. Outline questions: These questions should serve to jog the memory, and not be used as a concrete format. They ensure that all the areas are covered. However, if one aspect seems interesting, it is worth pursuing this. They should be used throughout the process of drawing, as people emerge. The names of the children should be recorded on the blank piece of paper - both on the chart sheet and facilitators’ note pad. Prompts: 1) Parents background (questions to ask at time of drawing): What does your father/ mother do? Did he/she go to school? Is your home near here? Do they like you going to school? Who encourages/ discourages you going to school? (mother/ father) 2) Siblings (questions to ask at time of drawing) Does your elder/ younger brother/sister go to school? Where, and have they always been in that school? Do your parents like your sisters going to school? What do they work as now (if elder)? If in different schools, why? If dropped out/ working, why and what are they doing? 3) Child in exercise (at time of drawing themselves) Were you always in this school? (track educational history of child if been in different schools - probe to why they moved) What do you like/dislike about this school? (encourage them to expand on answers e.g. nice teachers, good environment, good friends, close to home etc) - 89 - Step 6: (optional, given time) FGD on aspirations What do you want to do after this year? What do you want to be in 10 years? [This can be done via subsequent drawings on A4 sheets of paper a picture of what they would like to be. This will reveal gender stereotypes and also provide data on internal limitations of child’s perspective] Practical and ethical issues Working with children is very sensitive. If you feel it inappropriate to ask questions, or probe more deeply, DONT. We must have the child’s best interests in mind at all times. It is important to avoid exposing children or putting them in awkward positions. This exercise should be fun and like a conversation - give something of youself and provide encouragement and support to the children in undertaking the exercise (such as complements). The work should, if possible, be carried out in a shady area without the (close) presence of teachers or other students, as this will both distract them and make them reticent to talk. Informal discussion with children with facilitator Amna in NFE Centre, Gharibabad Amna, Saima Saeed (L-R) suggesting ways to draw the families in GGPS Gharibabad - 90 - ANNEX 6: Teachers FGD prompting questions pro-forma40 This focus group discussion is aimed at exploring several key threads in the research from the perspective of the teachers. The purpose is to get to the root of the issues of why parents are choosing certain schools. Teachers have unique insights as they are at the chalk face on a daily basis, having direct contact with the children and frequent contact with parents and community members. It will also allow us to triangulate (i.e. check) what the head teachers say in the mapping, and confirm opinions, doubts etc of the parents. However, as a starting point the teachers’ perspectives on motivations are explored, as this will allow a space for comfort and will enable all participants to speak. The questions are semi-structured which should allow for debate and disagreements. It is important to let the conversation flow; question prompts are offered below. 1. Why did you choose to become a teacher? - how long have you been teaching - past experience/ different schools - education attainment and from where 2. Do you enjoy it? - if so, why – what is it you enjoy? - If not, why not? 3. What support do you get? - from parents/ community - from institution - from government - from own family 4. What kind of children go to your school? 5. Why do you think they go to that school Prompts: - Reputation - Cost - Teachers - Atmosphere - Facilities - etc. 6. Do the children enjoy school? - What could be improved for them? - Do many drop out? - Do many repeat the year? 7. Any other comments (try to make sure that what the teachers say is the same as the principal’s etc. If there are differences, probe). 40 This blurb was given as an explanatory note to the facilitators, and has been included here for reference. - 91 - ANNEX 7: Monthly income, expenditure and profit of a typical middle private school Income - direct Grade Nursery 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Total Number Cost per (Rupees) class 25 50 30 60 20 70 12 100 12 120 9 150 7 200 6 250 5 300 126 Total 1,250 1,800 1,400 1,200 1,440 1,350 1,400 1,500 1,500 12,840 Expenditure per month Teacher salaries Qualification BA FA PTC Matric Matric Matric Total Utility bills Upkeep Registration Expenditure total Profit margin: Monthly salary (Rs.) 1200 800 600 600 600 3800 1500 500 150 5950 Rs. 6,890 Using data from table 5 and the questionnaire surveys, a ‘typical’ private school has been designed to indicate how monthly income and expenditure work out. From this, the monthly profit margin can be deduced. - 92 - - 94 - Table 5: Summary statistics from mapping by school type School Type Level served Registered Student population StudentTeacher ratio Student Classroom ratio Percentag e of male teachers Primary Yes 400 67 133 0% Primary Primary High42 Yes Yes Yes 175 170 200 88 85 18 88 85 40 0% 0% 100% 3180 4150 1000 7000 BPS41 BPS Yes Primary Yes 72 36 36 0% 1350 2001 2003 Yes Yes Primary Primary Yes Yes 175 65 16 33 22 33 0 100% 3200-2800 1450 Urban Urban Urban Urban Urban Urban Rural Rural 1992 1993 1996 2000 2000 2003 2001 2001 Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Middle High Middle High Middle Middle Middle Middle Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes 225 109 125 125 110 110 150 113 19 16 16 31 28 28 25 19 38 18 31 42 37 55 30 38 17% 29% 13% 50% 25% 0% 33% 0% Rural 2004 Yes Primary No 60 20 30 0% 500 - 1000 1000-1200 600- 1000 750-1000 500-1000 500 - 600 700 - 2000 500-1000 1000 1500 Location Established Mixed GGPS A Urban 1988 GGPS B GGPS C GBHS Urban Rural Rural 1989 1985 1922 Yes (partially) Yes (partially) No No NFE Centre Urban 2003 NGO School NFE Centre Rural Rural Private A Private B Private C Private D Private E Private F Private G Private H Private I 41 Basic Pay Scale for teachers, dependent on qualifications and years of service, generally from Rs.3000-6000. 42 Madrassah A in 1995 Urban No scholarships Middleforand religious No 4Mixed private 100 and madrassah 11 14site Upgraded to Middle 1998 3 With 100% about 60% of students in same 11% Madrassah B Madrassah C44 0% 25% Rural Rural 2002 2004 Yes Yes Religious and 1-3 Primary and religious No No 50 147 50 18 50 37 Teacher pay (Rs./mth) 1500 3000 yet to receive 500 - 1000 Fees (Rs./ month) 5 5 5 5 5 100 – 17543 5 30 - 100 50 - 300 50 - 150 25 - 300 100-150 30 - 200 50 - 200 50 - 150 40 - 70 0 50 - 100 50 - 95 - Basic Pay Scale for teachers, dependent on qualifications and years of service, generally from Rs.3000-6000. 3 Upgraded in 1995 to Middle With 100% scholarships for about 60% of students 4Mixed private and madrassah in same site