Book Review The Asymmetric Society Xiang How to understand the rapid social change and its effect on the average individuals? Coleman’s Asymmetric Society gives us some directions. In this book, Coleman describes to us a view of the changing organizational structures of society and the implications of these emerging structures for the lives of ordinary people. Comparing to some ideas that certain external forces change the society, Coleman thinks that the social change is goaldirected and the social system has the reflexive character. “Theories of social change can, ……contain a conception of directed change, not a conception of change arriving independent of man’s will, with technology, ……as the engine of change” (p.2). Goaldirected persons, as the basic elements of the social system, could affect the direction of the social structure changes. Coleman presents his views by five sections. In the first section, he describes a framework of the components of the society. Coleman states that the social structure has changed from hundreds of years ago with the appearance of a new actor in society. Then the society consists of two actors: the natural person, like you and me, and the corporate actor, a legal person which could act and be acted upon like natural persons. The emergence of the modern corporate actors could be traced back to the 13th century. With the emergence of functional towns, churches as well as corporations with limited liabilities, corporate actors become a rapidly growing component of modern society and play an increasing role. This growth in the numbers and legal status of corporate actors and the widespread implications of this growth result in “asymmetric” present in the relations between natural persons and corporate actors. The main component of the society has changed from the natural persons to corporate actors. This change brings up the asymmetry of relations between the two actors. There are 1 three kinds of relationships between them, natural persons to natural persons, natural persons to corporate actors, and corporate actors to corporate actors. The relationship between the natural persons and the corporate actors is asymmetric since the latter nearly always control most of the conditions surrounding the relation and much of the information relevant to the interaction. This asymmetry results that two parties beginning with normally equal rights in a relation, but coming to it with vastly different resources, end with very different actual rights in the relation. This asymmetry of the power gives the persons two choices, getting opportunities for malfeasance or using the state to redress the balance. Spreading widely across all areas of action, corporate actor becomes one actor with an internal structure composed of positions, while the natural person could merely occupy the positions through some kinds of contracts. When we look at the corporation, a representative of the corporate actors, we could find that the related parties inside the company (a group of people who participate in the corporation) or outside the company each has its own interests. Owners expect for the returns, employees want to get salaries and customers need goods on service. The counteracts bind them together and coordinate the relations between them. Although the corporate actors dominate the contemporary social life, persons have the capacity to influence them. In a corporation, as natural persons, owners could choose managers to control the company or even dissolve the organization, and managers could control the company purposely or even make malfeasance. To protect their interests against managerial incompetence and malfeasance, owners ask the auditor to verify the manager’s performance. Gradually there form equilibrium among the interests of the organization participants. Section two examines the legal rights and constitutional history of the acquisition of excessive rights by corporate actor. First, Coleman explains how we reach the present state of society by from the Holy Roman Empire through the Middle Ages to the present, 2 through a “descending theory” of government to the “ascending theory” of government. Here, Coleman discusses four structures, for the flow of right to the corporate actor, from the divine rights of kings, the Middle Ages, modern state socialism to pluralist democracy. For “state socialism, all sovereignty originates with natural persons individually, and all is transmitted upward to the central state apparatus. Then, for purposes of governing, parts of those rights are delegated down to subordinate actors which in effect become agents of the states” (p.56). Here we can look at the status of the former Soviet Union and China. Since all sovereignty and property belong to the state, no one could be the real owner of the corporations, including the CEO or manager. Lack of necessary supervision results in the operation inefficient and managerial malfeasance. For “the pluralist democracy, sovereignty originates with natural persons individually. But here only a portion is transmitted to the state as corporate actor; part continues to be held individually and part is transmitted to other corporate actors” (p.57). Although corporate actors require some acquiescence from the state apparatus, a portion of the original sovereignty never passes into the hands of the state but is lodged directly in the other corporate actors. Thus, we get that all corporations in liberal democracies gain their rights and resources through a combination of two routes: owner’s equity and charter from the state. Coleman points out that the acquisition of excessive rights by corporate actors results from the separation of the usage rights (the right to control the use of the property for the pursuit of a given purpose) and the benefit rights (the right to benefit from the use of the property). He argues that even where no illegal actions are undertaken, the corporate actors’ resources tend to be diverted to those exercising usage rights at the expense of all other natural persons in society. The last three sections focus on the influence of the emergence of the corporate actor in various areas of society. Coleman explains some actions taken by corporate actors that have serious consequences (or risks) for natural persons and how reallocation of rights can 3 be used to restrain those actions. He observes the implications of the asymmetric society on raising children, and further investigates the need for changes in the present system of new information rights given the new corporate dominated social structure. Making corporate actors more likely to consider the consequences for persons in their actions result in some structural changes within corporate actors. Certain actions by corporate actors impose risk on person and arouse focus of attention on them. For a pecuniary incentive, large actors, like Hooker Chemical Company could take actions with little regard for their consequence (risks) for small natural persons. For a bureaucratic incentive, the risk to the people of Cracow in Poland continuous because the bureaucratic structure of the state means the subordinate cannot against the order of superior. The problems exist for them created by an asymmetric society, the natural actors are too small respect to the large corporate actors. To vest countervailing power in natural persons within the corporate actors is one way to deal with asymmetry without creating regulatory agencies that themselves become powerful corporate actors. As Coleman analyzed, the changes in governance and social organization within corporate actors to restore imbalance have different effects for persons with different relations to corporate actors. They work best when natural persons are employees with a readily available collective action infrastructure. Then the effect becomes more and more inefficient as the relationship between natural persons and corporate actors become more and more estranged. However, the corporate actor which changed the structure of society is its own changing. By restructuring organizations from within, toward decentralization and by introducing market mechanisms into hierarchy, corporate actors began to reduce the disparity between interests of them and those of natural persons. The widespread practice of franchising is a business trend that favors restoring balance between corporate actors and natural persons. As we know, one main consequence of asymmetry is that corporate actors nearly control most of the conditions and information surrounding the relation. The imbalance in 4 information results in uneven rights and risks. In a corporation, managers control the information and could disseminate it selectively. Owners need accurate and complete information to protect their interests. To redress the imbalance in information, owners ask auditors to verify the information so that the different interests of participants of the companies could be satisfied and realized equilibrium. This book is not a book merely on sociology. It raises some interesting issues and provides a framework for further studies in today’s social science. What’s the way society is coming to be organized? How to direct the social change toward a social system that will better serve us under an asymmetric society? Coleman’s work provokes much reconsideration in the changing world. 5